Introduction: Ethnic conflicts and religious divisions are found in most countries and on all continents (Azam, 2001). Of late, many studies have addressed the issue of ethnic diversity and its effects on social conflicts and civil wars. Political scientists, through increasing study on ethnic diversity, have come to realize the importance of institutions in attenuating ethnic conflicts in ethnically divided societies (Garcia-Montalvo and ReynalQuerol, 2002). Recently, economists have become increasingly interested in these issues and emphasize the connections of ethnic diversity to investment, quality of government and growth (Mauro, 1995, Easterly & Levine, 1997, and Alesina, Devleeschauer, Easterly, Kurlat & Wacziarg, 2003). Many Sub-Saharan African countries find themselves engulfed in ethnic conflicts. In addition to human cost, these violent conflicts eat away at “meager financial resources” of African countries (Mengisteab, 2001, p. 20). In other words, ethno-linguistic fragmentation has been shown to have adverse effects on income, growth and overall macroeconomic policies, which is one explanation for Africa’s poor growth performance and an indirect cause of underdevelopment. While the literature tells us that ethnic diversity by its mere fact is not a negative attribute, it becomes more problematic in a situation where governance is based on weakly institutionalized politics. Ethnic diversity coupled with weak institutions is a recipe for underdevelopment, because it breeds an ethnically divided society posing risks for corruption, political violence, and civil wars. These adverse effects of ethnic conflict translate into poor macro-economic growth performance—a fact that bedevils development (rendering African development less effective). Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 2 However, studies and concrete evidence from examples of western countries have shown that strong political institutions can reduce the adverse effects of ethnic conflict. The U.S is one of the countries where strong institutions have overcome adverse effects of ethnic conflicts. Quinn and Woolly (2001) hypothesized “that democracies ameliorate social conflicts in a way that produces stability” (p. 635). Thus, ethnic diversity is not a problem in a society where fundamental institutions are functioning. It only becomes troubling and causative in countries where formal institutions are inadequate and weak. It is said that ethnic and religious identities are realities in Africa and, as such, should not be condemned as pathological to development and democratization. Africa, rather, should adopt a principle of inclusivity and constitutionalism: reinforcing the rule of law, participation, autonomy, equity and recognition of ethnic groups. Hence, to avoid anarchy and genocidal politics, Abubakar (2001) recommends that Africa should foster democratization and acknowledge various ethnic groups as stakeholders in national building. This project examines the links between ethnic diversity, formal political institutions, and economic development. It focuses on how formal political institutions and ethnic conflicts affect development. The paper is divided into four major components. Part I examines the literature on diversity, institutions and economic development, leading to the hypotheses. Part II presents statistical evidence on ethnic diversity, income levels, and income growth rates for all African nations. Part III examines the correlation between ethnic diversity and growth. Part IV presents case studies of the design of political institutions to lessen the effects of ELF. Some preliminary explanations regarding how “high growth, high diversity” outliers have achieved their successes is provided as well. Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 3 Part I: Theories of Africa’s Underdevelopment Given its abundance of natural resources and sweeping democratization since 1960s, it is unfortunate that Africa has not reached its anticipated development level. East Asian nations which were at equal footing with Africa have bypassed that continent. In retrospect, it was a gross miscalculation on the part of scholars, policymakers and donornations that once democracy and multiparty politics took hold, the whole continent would move towards the undeviating road of development. That never happened; instead underdevelopment set in. It is not consoling that a few countries such as Uganda, Mauritius, Botswana, and Tunisia continue to develop relatively well while most nations such as Rwanda, Sudan, Somalia, Congo and Madagascar get poorer and poorer. Today, 32 countries in Africa are poorer than they were in 1980 while Sub-Sahara Africa is the lowest income region in the world (Collier and Gunning, 1999). Although almost all scholars agree that Africa is in crisis, there is disagreement about the actual cause of this crisis (Chabal, 1991). At the 2005 G-8 Summit, for instance, European leaders emphasized a variety of causes of Africa’s underdevelopment and also a variety of solutions (Jeffrey, 2005). France’s Jacques Chirac called for canceling debts to developing countries, Britain’s Tony Blair set up the African commission, which proposed eliminating trade barriers and combating corruption, while the UN presented a paper written by American economist Jeffrey Sachs, which optimistically envisioned that more development aid would create a world without poverty (Visscher, 2005 July/August 26). All in all, the following are said to be responsible for underdevelopment in Africa. Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 4 A. External Factors Colonial Legacy: European colonialism sowed seeds for ethnic conflict in post-colonial Africa. At the onset of colonization (1885), boundaries were drawn with little or no consideration of distributions of actual indigenous people (Blankton, Mason and Athow, 2001). With the fall of colonial rule, some of these fragmented societies were transformed into states. Hence, in partitioning Africa, each colony showed no regard to existing natural ethnic boundaries. That is, by fragmenting the traditional ethnic groupings within Africa in their quest to divide up the continent for themselves, the European powers created the potential for ethnic conflicts. Simply put, “colonialism was not aimed at creating strong, viable autonomous states” (Errol, 2000, p. 2). Because of this colonial heritage, African states are smaller, on average, than countries in other regions in terms of population. This small size is disadvantageous. First, smaller markets are less competitive and are perceived by investors as risky. In addition, they have a slower rate of “technology innovation and diffusion” (Collier and Gunning, 1999, p. 9). Each colonial style is blamed as a source of underdevelopment. European powers, especially the British, are to blame for the policy of power decentralization. Britain governed her colonies using a “divide-and -rule” policy— local chiefs, though answerable to colonial government, ruled their people along ethnic lines. The resulting ethnic divisions led to ongoing conflict and unstable governments (Blankton et al., 2001). In turn, these ethnic conflicts create negative effects on development. Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 5 External Economic Constraints Some sources cite foreign debts, falling world prices of primary export products, and stringent structural adjustment as contributing to Africa’s underdevelopment (Chabal, 2002). This phenomenon, according to Standard Bank Research (SBR, 2005 January), originated in the 1970s and 1980s when volatile commodity prices, oil price shocks, and high interest rates dominated the world market. These factors led to African economic crises: health, environmental and transport problems amongst others. Many nations then became slaves to servicing debts owed to the World Bank or IMF. In other words, servicing of loans and implementation of stern structural adjustment programs has a bearing on Africa’s development. B. Internal Factors Dependence on Natural Resources It has been said that too much dependence on agriculture and natural resource export is a curse to the African economy. It is a phenomenon known as “the curse of tropics.” Africa’s adverse climate causes poor health and so reduces life expectancy and this puts Africa at disadvantage (Collier and Gunning, 1999). Also the adverse climate leads to unreliable rainfall combined with poor soil quality, which leads to unpredictable crop failure. Adverse climate and poor soil quality lead families to care for household consumption and ignore investment, making households become trapped in “low-income, high-liquidity equilibria” (Collier and Gunning, 1999, p. 8). Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 6 Negative factors such as volatile commodity prices, oil price shocks, and high interest rates lead to slow growth (SBR, 2005 January). As a presumed self-reinforcing endogenous process, weak economic growth accounts for a lower saving rate and higher proportion of capital flight for Africa compared to other parts of the world. The negative market shocks (rising prices of commodities such as oil) of the 1970s, for example, not only affected Africa but also high performing economies. Weak Institutions and Corruption Another cause of Africa’s underdevelopment is corruption and the neopatrimonial nature of politics [much of politics is carried out in the informal sector and politics rests on personalities instead of institutions] (Stasavage, 2001). This creates a clientele base for some politicians to exploit for personal gain (Woods, 1994). In the literature, it is assumed that less corrupt or more democratic governments are to be desired because democracy reduces the scope of conflict and produces good governance, ensures political stability, consolidates rule of law and installs competent institutions, thus providing a favorable environment for investment and growth. Most recent ethnic conflicts occurred in countries where the regime was unstable (Sadowski, 1998). President Yoweri Museveni of Uganda, for instance, blames underdevelopment on tribalism, religious sectarianism and greed (Kigozi, 2004). In Uganda, for instance, as Kigozi (2004) noted, greed, tribalism and nepotism dictate who will get employment [what he calls “strangulation of meritocracy”] (p. 1). It is alleged that some corrupt Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 7 ministers observe regional ties and tilt employment towards those who are closer to their ethnic groups. Hence, employment is based not on merit but on favoritism. The public sector, which is the main employer everywhere in Africa, exhibits high expenditure, and poor governance: it (public sector) is virtually less accountable to the broader public. Collier and Gunning (1999) argued that, as a result, Africa experienced a paradox of poor public services despite relatively high public expenditure. In turn, poor public service delivery causes inefficiency in health, education, and extension of services. Employment occurs on a whom –you- know rather than on a what -you -know basis. If politicians favor their kin when it comes to employment and appropriating public expenditure, they interfere with growth indirectly. This kind of practice is a ground for underdevelopment in Uganda and everywhere on the continent. In his analysis, Mauro (1995) did find that corruption lowers private investment, thus further reducing economic growth. Speaking recently at Harvard’s graduation commencement, the Ethiopian prime minister, Melees Zenawi, summarized the fate of African economies as characterized by rent-seeking behavior. Discriminatory employment practices, corruption, and nepotism adversely affect economic growth performance and development indirectly, interfering with efficiency of production (Easterly, 2001). Greed for personal aggrandizement and riches overrides provision of public goods. Those in power embezzle funds which affects economic performance. This situation was vividly captured by Kigozi (2004) when he said, “we are in a quagmire which is very difficult to overcome” (p. 1). This statement is important because the failure of Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 8 politicians, doctors, teachers and all kinds of administrators to discharge their duties with maximum efficiency is to blame for Africa’s miseries and eventual underdevelopment. Likewise, corruption in the government encourages regional bias, creating greater disparity between rural and urban settings in Africa. Most politicians and ruling parties are more responsive to urban demands than to rural demands. A development bias is caused by this behavior. Most people in Africa live in rural areas, which are less developed. Rural folks make up a large percent of the total population. Rural folks therefore lack major investment expenditure which is essential for growth and development. Ethnic Conflict as Source of Underdevelopment While the effects of colonialism, external policy constraints, reliance on natural resources and corruption all matter, researchers are increasingly focusing on ethnic fragmentation as a source of underdevelopment. In other words, accusing fingers have been pointed to religious and ethnic diversities as the root causes of social tensions, political unrest and an apparent lack of development on the continent. It is believed that a highly fragmented society exhibits a high incidence of civil wars and genocide. Ethnic diversity and conflicts make it harder to have an interconnected economy (Collier and Gunning, 1999). Likewise, Dion Douglas (1997) wrote, “Ethnic competition breeds ethnic conflicts” (p. 638). As each ethnic group tries to better itself, it is bound to compete and engage in a conflicting endeavor with other groups. As Easterly (2001) pointed out, ethnic groups maximize their own self-interest or ethnic capital. Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 9 According to research conducted by Easterly (2001), lower trust between diverse ethnic groups makes it difficult to form social networks essential for growth promotion. These groups have difficulty agreeing on types of public goods, leading to less spending on growth-promoting public goods (Easterly, 2001 and Alesina et al., 2003). On the other hand, Easterly (2001) argues that ethnic homogeneity raises “social capital” (p. 687). In other words, in a situation where the level of trust among ethnic groups is high, more cooperation on development agendas and policy implementation is probable. Evidence from Sudan to Iraq and Afghanistan suggests that ethnic fractionalization at times correlates with civil war. Moreover, through effects on macroeconomic policies, ethnic conflicts indirectly and directly affect development. Costs of conflict management, lack of cooperation, interaction breakdown, wars and genocide negatively affect development. Violence, as Lake and Rothchild (1996) write, is parasitic because resources which might have been invested in economic growth are instead diverted to destructive ends. Public infrastructure and government expenditure tend to favor some ethnic groups to the detriment of others (Garcia-Montalvo and Reynol- Querol, 2002). This can lead to poor policy choice and transform economic policy into a rent-seeking mechanism— corruption. Also, the behavior of an African state towards her citizens exacerbates the corruption and ethnic division through alienation. For example, after having won independence, most African nations were not concerned with the luxury of democracy but with development and national integration, a fact that led to justification for one-party rule, autocracy, and military dictatorship on the continent (Abubaker, 2001). With devotion to national integration, African states became exploitative, authoritarian, and threatening to Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 10 everyone except those in power. Thus, instead of protecting everyone, the state protects a few elites, which leads various people to seek solace and comfort in their ethnic groups or to turn away to seek fulfillment in their ethnic groups (Abubaker, 2001). The benefit of affiliating with one’s ethnic group in this scenario outweighs the cost. As Ayalon, Rafael and Sharot (1986) showed, people seek to obtain maximum net advantage respecting to “rational-choice theory” (p. 551). In Africa, group polarization and ethnic fragmentation are blamed for breeding rent-seeking behavior and overspending, undermining public goods provision, and creating positive incentives for growth-retarding policies such as financial repression and overvalued exchange rates that create rents for the groups in power at the expense of society at large (Easterly & Levine, 1997). Strikingly, Africa experienced unusual cases of ethnic conflicts from the 1960s through the 1990s. Some of these conflicts grew into wars and loss of lives. The literature shows that such conflicts are detrimental to both economy and civil society. Lorentzen, McMillan, & Wacziarg (2005) show in the working paper, “Death and Development”, that mortality is inversely related to investment, human capital, fertility and ultimately economic growth (p. 1). This research paper links deaths, resulting from war and natural causes, to economic growth, and hints that the mortality-growth relationship could be the source of poverty trap in Africa, what Easterly calls “Africa’s Growth Tragedy” (Lorentzen et al. 2005, p. 10). Although Africa’s high ethnic diversity is blamed as the primary cause for a high incidence of civil wars, some scholars believe that religious and ethnic conflicts are symptoms of the real variable of lack of development. Azam (2001) attributed the presence of ethnic conflicts as a failure of the state to perform its fundamental functions. Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 11 He blamed ethnic division on institutional endowment, being cognizant of the fact that it is a failure of governments to deliver public expenditure that escalates civil wars. In the same vein, notable authors such as Ibrahim Elbadawi and Nicholas Sambanis (2000) argued that ethno-fragmentations in Africa are not the root cause of the civil wars and social unrest that impede development. Rather high levels of poverty, failed institutions, and, to some extent, dependence on natural resources are the real causes of underdevelopment (Elbadawi and Sambanis, 2000). In the same manner, they argue that ethnic diversity by itself is not the cause of civil wars. In fact, it is said to have an offsetting effect. A very diverse society might even reduce violent conflict because “rebel cohesion” may be harder to create (Sambanis and Elbadawi, 2000, p. 247). They argue political and economic failures cause wars (Sambanis and Elbadawi, 2000). They claim that ethnic diversity is only problematic in such cases where one ethnic group accounts for 40-60% of the total population and dominates others. When the largest ethnic group surpasses 44% of total population, the incidence of coups is high (Dion, 1997). Thus, if the institutions work and protect minorities, then ethnic diversity may have no effect. As Easterly and Levine (1997) indicated, formal institutions that protect minorities and establish clear legal rules for business may be more valuable in ethnically divided societies than in homogenous ones. The presence of poor institutions in Africa encourages ethno-linguistic fractionalization and accounts for poor economic growth performance. Good institutions are likely to offset ethnically-based social conflicts that lower growth. This is the ground upon which U.S assistance for Africa’s democratization has been concerned with civil society, political parties, constitutional reform and executive branch reform (Harbeson, 1993-1999). Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 12 Evidence on Growth-retarding Effects of Ethnic Fragmentation Ethnic fractionalization increases the likelihood of war while good institutions mitigate it. This is why ethnic differences lead to civil wars in Sudan, Rwanda, and Kosovo but not in Canada, Belgium, or Switzerland because the latter have strong political institutions. From 1960 to 1990, there were 16 nations across the globe with genocidal cases, and the majority of these cases took place in ethnically divided societies (Easterly, 2001). That being said, studies have shown that ethnically diverse cities and counties in the U.S spend less on education, show little support for higher education and exhibit lower graduation rates (Easterly, 2001). This is because “when individuals have different preferences, they want to pull fewer resources together for public projects such as public goods – education, and roads. Alesina, Baqir and Easterly, 1999 found that sewers supplied by U.S cities are inversely related to ethnic fragmentation. Where ethnic groups are polarized and politicians have ethnic constituencies, spending that goes to public goods is low. Alesina et al. (1999) concluded that more ethnically diverse jurisdictions in the U.S have higher spending and higher deficits per capita but lower spending on public goods such as education and roads. Ethnic fragmentation not only affects investment but may also increase corruption and political instability. Directly, it may slow down diffusion of ideas and technological innovation within the country (Mauro, 1995). This finding is consistent with political economy theory which characterizes heterogeneous and polarized societies as valuing public goods less, and patronage more, while being careless about fiscal discipline. Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 13 Ethnic conflict creates ethnic mobilization (organization of ethnic groups along ethnic lines for political ends) which threatens the stability of many countries (Nagel and Olzak, 1982). As Nagel and Olzak (1982) noted, this ethnic mobilization becomes widespread when there are many competitive advantages attached to ethnic identity. An example is seen amongst agricultural communities in West Africa. In essence, they asserted that dialectical aspects ( the Marxian concept of reality in which material things are in the constant process of change brought about by the tension between conflicting or interacting forces, elements, or ideas ) of ethnic mobilization affect development (1982). In Kenya for instance, more ethnically diverse districts spend less on education— meaning ethnically diverse societies are a predictor of poor quality of government service and project a likelihood of political instability and higher government consumption (Easterly, 2001). Part II: Measures of Ethnic Fractionalization in Africa Measuring ethnic diversity continent-wide is a hard task. Various measures such as the Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation index (ELF) are frequently used. ELF measures a likelihood that two people chosen at random will be from different ethnic groups. It is n calculated using a simple Herfidahl concentration index whose formula is ( 1 s 2 ), i i 1 where Si is the percentage share of population in each ethnic group, n is the number of ethnic groups and i indexes the ethnic groups. The closer the result is to 1, the more fragmented is that country. Algeria, For instance, has one major ethnic group (Arab- Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 14 Berber) containing 99% of the population and one minority group accounting for 1%. Its ELF can be calculated as follows: 1 – (0.992 + 0. 012) = 0.0099. This means that Algeria is not very fragmented. The ELF’s popularity stems from its simplicity to use and general acceptance. However, as Posner pointed out, two major problems are associated with ELF. First, since ethnic groups are recognized as social functions, they can change, expand or contract. It is logical to argue that if a change in ethnic group (shrinkage, expansion) occurs, then the index is not likely to reflect that country’s ethnic landscape (Posner, 2004 ). Fundamentally, there is no objective dividing line between one ethnic group and another (Alesina et al., 2003). Secondly, Posner (2004) said that ELF suffers from what he calls the “grouping problem” (p. 850). Nigeria, for instance, is said to have 250 ethnic groups. Yet the data from which ELF is constructed for Nigeria comes from a few ethnic groups that are lumped together. Even the groups that are lumped as one might have a history of rivalry themselves (Posner 2004). However, despite the shortcomings of ELF, it will still be used in this paper due to its simplicity and wide acceptance1. For simplicity, I have used ELF values generated by William Easterly. The years of the data range from 1983 to 2001(Easterly, 2001). The correlation of the ELF with growth in GDP per capita between 1993 and 2003 is examined below. 1 Despites his criticism of measure by ELF, Posner (2004) did in fact establish a correlation which states that ethnic diversity affects growth through macro-economic policies. 2 GDP stands for Gross Domestic Product. The GDP data comes from Countrywatch. Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 15 Part III: Data Analysis Table 1 shows data on Africa. All 53 countries, except Sao Tome Principe, whose ELF value was missing from Easterly’s data, are included. In table 1, I present GDP2 per capita in 1993 and 2003, along with the growth rates of GDP per capita for the decade. Likewise, figures for Latin America and Asia and the Pacific (see tables 2 and 3) are presented for comparison. As is evident from the table 1, Africa has a higher average ELF (0.6305) compared to Latin America (0.4019) and Asia and the Pacific (0.3345). Also, evident in tables 1, 2, and 3, are average growth rates for Africa, Latin America and Asia and the Pacific: 0 .77%, 0.93% and 1.21% respectively. It is obvious that out of the three regions, Africa’s growth rate is the slowest. Figures 1, 2 and 3 show the raw relationship between ELF and growth in Africa, Latin America and Asia and the Pacific. It can be deduced from the graphs that African countries tend to cluster in the high ELF region. This fact is visible from the right hand side of the graph. On the other hand, Latin American countries have more dispersed ELF values. Asia and the Pacific are the least fragmented regions. Table 4 presents the results of a simple regression of per capita growth on ELF for African countries. The result is essentially the formula for the trend line plotted in figure 3. The relationship between ELF and growth is negative, though statistically weak. Table 5 uses this regression to calculate “predicted’ growth rates for each country based on that country’s ELF value. The difference between actual growth and predicted growth then gives us a residual measure, indicating which countries are “overachievers or underachievers” relative to their ELF values. The overachievers include Botswana, Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 16 Mauritius, Equatorial Guinea, and Uganda. Some of them will be examined in qualitative case studies to determine why they were able to avoid potential pitfalls of high ethnic diversity. That being said, this analysis is limited in a number of ways. First, as noted in the preceding paragraphs, calculation of ELF may be affected by a ‘grouping problem’. That is, the definition of ethnic group is subjective and less clear cut than we would like. In addition, the starting level of income seems to play a role in the results. Very low income countries may appear to be successful in terms of growth simply because there are many basic improvements that can be adapted to generate increase and because any increases appear larger in percentages given the smaller base. Equatorial Guinea is a good example. Likewise, limitation of the study to particular years may affect the result. In other words, growth rates could be different for instance from 1994 to 2004. A look at world events would tell that 1994 was full of political upheavals such as the genocide in Rwanda, and civil wars in Somalia, Sudan, and Sierra Leone. In the end, this quantitative analysis is just a first step. It has helped in identifying the negative relationship between ELF and growth. It has also aided the process of identifying countries that are ‘high- and low-achievers’, given their relative ELF values. The next step will be to choose cases from this group. These qualitative case studies will be used to examine how political institutions overcome fragmentation. Although the literature has at length addressed the positive effect of institutions, we can not say for sure whether countries with large residuals are also countries with the best institutions. Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 17 Part IV: Institutional Approaches to Dealing with Ethnic Diversity According to Robert H. Bates (2000), study after study of modern Africa highlights three major shocking catchwords: poverty, instability and ethnic diversity. While ethnic conflicts are as old as mankind is, recent years have seen increased conflict across the globe especially in Africa. There were, from 1989 to 1998, 108 armed conflicts in the world, including conflicts in Kosovo, Ethiopia, Rwanda, Sudan, Afghanistan, Sri Lanka, Somalia, Angola, and Congo just to name a few (Wallensteen & Sollenberg, 1999). These examples confirm that armed conflicts are not confined to one nation or region. Notably, it is a stark reality that these wars are of ethnic origin. While there are many competing variables that are linked to Africa’s poverty trap/growth tragedy, ethnic conflict is shown to play a major role in poor growth. Study after study suggests that controlling ethnic conflicts could be one way of boosting growth. That being said, it is a general consensus that ethnic diversity is a reality of Africa in the past, present and future. So, ethnic diversity and political instability resulting from ethnic conflict is to be lived through and coped with (O’Connell, 1967). By the same token, it is more consoling to assert that ethnic diversity in itself is not a bad thing; its consequences are. How African States Accommodate Ethnic Diversity From the regression results (see table 4), we can infer that ethnic conflicts have an impact on growth. Ethnic conflicts slow down the creation of nationalism, widen social Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 18 distrust among groups and elites seeking to maximize their power and impede development (O’Connell, 1967). African countries have used various tactics to address these costs of ethnic conflicts. First, it must be stated as given that after independence in the 1960s, African leaders approached national building in different ways. Some used divide- and- rule tactics as they were used by colonial masters. Thus, the colonial legacy has played a role in some countries. As a result, opposition voices or dissents were liquidated in the name of national building (Kalinga, 1998; Fegley, 1981). Constitutional codes were abolished and in most cases, post- independence leaders declared themselves as life-presidents. These approaches alienated people, causing them to seek help in their ethnic groups, creating divisions and ethnic violence (Woods, 1994; Ndegwa, 1997)). In pronounced cases, wars were fought. Overall, politicians in power either excluded some ethnic groups or granted them limited participation (Shultz, 1995). For the states that do not seek to accommodate diversity but consolidate power, politics is characterized by corruption, favoritism, ethnic politics, lack of cooperation among various groups, immobility of resources, and lack of diffusion of ideas, ethnic violence, and political instability. These factors have their share in African growth impairment. Nonetheless, for those states that grant limited participation to various groups, some progress is made. This is what I call a “limited inclusive” approach to politics. Some of these states are characterized by some formation of social capital, quasi-freedom, stability, a move towards multiparty politics, and a promising development paradigm (Abdalla, 1991). Examples in this category are Egypt and Uganda. Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 19 In the same token, states exhibiting fully inclusionary policies are characterized by multiparty politics, stability, openness to trade and a promising development paradigm. An example in this category is Botswana. Given the fact that ethnic diversity is a reality of Africa, various governments have used diverse means to address it. However, not all methods worked. Some that have worked are worthy of emulation. The inclusionary approach to politics is worthy of embracing. This is because it tends to produce an environment conducive for consensusbuilding and development. A move towards multiparty politics, formation of social capital, and stability are themselves desirable variables for development. The full inclusive approach to politics constitutes power-sharing, constitutional codes, institutional accountability, and an expansive role of media. These approaches should be embraced if Africa is to reduce her number of ethnic conflicts, which in turn can stabilize the continent and usher in an environment conducive for growth, investment and development. It is undeniably true that Africa since independence is characterized by ethnic conflict arising from actions and aspirations of a dissatisfied and disenfranchised populace. The effects of these conflicts are far reaching and they vary from nation to nation. Based on their relative ethnic fragmentation, African nations seemed to have performed differently over the course of the years especially after independence from various European powers. In this paper, I am interested in what has been done or not done to reduce the negative effects of ethnic conflicts in the following five countries: Libya, Cameroon, Somalia, Democratic Republic of Congo (Zaire) and Uganda. Each country shall be examined in terms of the type of policies taken to address ethnic conflict. In each case study, I shall Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 20 earnestly examine conditions at independence, post colonial policies, and past and present power structures. 1. Libya Libya, which is in northern Africa and borders the Mediterranean Sea between Egypt, and Tunisia, achieved independence from Italy on December 24th, 1951. Libya is an Islamic state for it is a 97% Sunni Muslim; Berber and Arab make up 97% of the population of about 6 million people while others- Greeks, Maltese, Italians, Egyptians, Pakistanis, Turks, Indians, and Tunisians -comprise 3% (CIA, 2006). Based on the ELF growth regression (see table 5), Libya is an underachiever since it has a growth residual of negative 2.28%. Theories of underdevelopment suggest poor growth performance is a function of institutions and ethnic diversity. Thus, it makes sense to examine the kind of institutions that are in operation in Libya as well as what the state has done to abate ethnic conflicts and divisive politicking. Like most governments on the continent, the Libyan regime attained power through underhanded methods. In 1969, Muammar Gaddafi led a revolution, seized power and established a dictatorship. Since then, Gaddafi’s ruling party, “The Great Socialist People's Libyan Arab Jamahiriya”, has been in power. Jamahiriya is a state of the masses, governed by the populace through local councils. Given this unsanctioned ascension to power, Gaddafi has consolidated his grip on authority, via suppression of political dissents; his policies since the 1980s have caused international concern: human Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 21 rights violations, terrorist acts, an alliance with Russia and aggression towards neighboring countries such as Chad and Niger (Ogunbadejo, 1983). Given the nature of his government, Gaddafi is a chief of state, leader of the executive branch, and commander in Chief of the armed forces. The Libyan legal system is based on Italian civil law and Islamic law while the legislative branch (unicameral) is called the General People's Congress, to which members are elected indirectly through a hierarchy of people's committees. Under Gaddafi, non-free national elections are done indirectly through a hierarchy of people's committees (CIA, 2006). Blatantly, there are no political parties in Libya, which translates to a lack of checks and balances. There is a wanting of political freedom in Libya and Gaddafi’s dictatorial government has compensated for this political oppression in several ways. First he brands capitalism as exploitative and communism as godless. This characterization grants him a chance to throw these two ideologies out of Libya, leaving Gaddafi with what he christened as “The Third Universal Theory” (TUT). TUT was expounded in his Green book as an alternative system to capitalism and communismatheism (Ogunbadejo, 1983, p. 155). The TUT is a state of the masses, which in theory is governed by the populace through local councils. The enactment of this theory led Gaddafi to claim that he is distributing wealth evenly throughout the society. By using oil riches to build a welfare state where every citizen is guaranteed food, housing, and clothing, he showed the feasibility of his theory and silenced his opponents at home. Consequently, this generous nature of the state under Gaddafi has resulted into mass apathy; few people are opposed to his policies. But any opposition or coup attempts by Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 22 dissidents are mercilessly liquidated. For instance, in 1980, over 2000 arrests were made while 800 executions of a political nature were carried out (Ogunbadejo, 1983). That aside, the question is why there is no ethnic conflict despite lack of political freedom and weak institutions in Libya. Though there is no definitive answer, suffice it to say that the fear of Libyan government, mass apathy and Gaddafi’s overweening personality (Gaddafi has always seen himself as a revolutionary and visionary leader) have combated any ethnic conflict. With all state power at his disposable, Gaddafi relied on trepidation and ruthlessness to garner allegiance and peaceful-coexistence among major ethnic groups in Libya. Thus, institutions in Libya are weak because power rests on Gaddafi. However, ethnic conflict seems not to be the major cause of poor growth performance but rather the presence of bad policies. For, example, aggression and meddling with affairs in neighboring states (Sudan, Morocco, Tunisia, and Algeria), sanctions (resulting from Gaddafi’s ambitions to build nuclear weapons), lack of individual freedom and an environment conducive for investment, growth and development could have affected the growth residual in Libya. Put differently, there has never been a civil war in Libya due to homogeneity (two major ethnic groups), mass apathy and heavy-handedness of the government. The fear of the government, corruption and bad policies affect Libya’s economic policies and that could have led to negative residual growth for the period spanning this study (1993-2003). For instance, UN sanctions were imposed on Libya in 1992, suspended in 1999 and finally lifted in 2003 when Libya announced its abandonment of programs to develop weapons of mass destruction. Economically and Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 23 politically, Libya was isolated and that could have contributed to the negative growth from 1990s to early 2000s. 2. Cameroon Cameroon, a Western African state, borders the Bight of Biafra, between Equatorial Guinea and Nigeria. Cameroon attained independence from the French in 1960. The former French Cameroon and part of British Cameroon merged in 1961 to form the present country, which has generally enjoyed stability and has permitted the development of agriculture, roads, and railways, as well as a petroleum industry. Despite movement toward democratic reforms in recent years, political power remains firmly in the hands of an ethnic oligarchy headed by President Paul Biya (CIA, 2005). In this study, Cameroon emerges as a moderate achiever (see table 5) for it has a positive mild growth residual of 0.93%. Recognizant of the proposition that institutions and ethnic diversity play a role in macroeconomic policies and growth performance, it is a good idea to examine the kind of institutions that are in Cameroon. First, there are three branches of government in operation. In Cameroon, there is only one legislative chamber, whose members are elected by direct popular vote to serve for five-year terms. However, the president, Paul Biya, has more room for maneuver as to the stability of the legislature. He can, at will, either elongate or shorten the term of the legislature. This is a sign of weak institutions (CIA, 2005). Overall, the legal system is based on the French civil law system with common law influence. But the president has another power when it comes to judicial nominees. The Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 24 President has the prerogative power to appoint the Supreme Court judges. There is no legislative oversight respecting to his appointees. Thus, these judges are likely to be loyal to the president. Only high courts justices are elected by the National Assembly. This is another lack of judicial independence. Unlike Libya, political parties are legal in Cameroon. Some of the political parties and their respective leaders include the following: the Cameroonian Democratic Union (Adamou Ndamnjoya); the Democratic Rally of the Cameroon People (Paul Biya); the Movement for the Defense of the Republic (Dakole Daissala); the Movement for the Liberation and Development of Cameroon (Marcel Yondo); the Movement for the Youth of Cameroon (Dieudonne Tina); the National Union for Democracy and Progress (Maigari Bello Bouba); the Social Democratic Front (John Frundi) and the Union of Cameroonian Populations (Augustin Frederic Kodock) (CIA, 2005). Besides institutions, ethnic diversity is also a factor to reckon with in Cameroon. It is wise to assess what the state has done to combat ethnic conflicts that arise in a multiethnic and multi-religious society. Primarily, Cameroon’s population (about 16 million) is comprised of Cameroon Highlanders (31%), Equatorial Bantu (19%), Kirdi (11%), Fulani (10%), Northwestern Bantu (8%), Eastern Nigritic (7%), other African (13%), and non-African (less than 1%) (CIA, 2006). Each of Cameroon’s ethnic group has less than 44% of the population. This might have accounted for lack of domination by one major ethnic group. It is said that whenever one ethnic group exceeds 44% of the entire population, it is likely to dominate others and cause conflict (Sambanis & Elbadawi, 2000). Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 25 Cameroon has combated ethnic conflicts with an assortment of choices. First, since the 1990s, the government has embarked on sound economic policies, such as various IMF and World Bank programs designed to spur business investment, increase efficiency in agriculture, improve trade, and recapitalize the nation's banks, raising hope for every Cameroonian. In June 2000, the government completed an IMF-sponsored, three-year structural adjustment program. Still, the IMF is pressing for more reforms, including increased budget transparency, privatization, and poverty reduction programs (CIA, 2006). Secondly, no ethnic group has been singled out as the “enemy of state”. This alienates no one and reduces ethnic mobilization. Also, politicians, few as they are, have not incited one ethnic group against another. The instigation of one group against another is the root cause of civil wars in Somalia and Rwanda. Democratic reforms might have also helped to boost growth. These could account for the lack of full flown civil war in Cameroon. Thus, regardless of high ELF, Cameroon experienced no civil conflicts. These mild reforms, lack of civil war and weak yet gradually improving institutions might have accounted for a modest growth residual of 0.93%. In short, the small positive growth residual in Cameroon could be a combination of a number of factors. Political stability since independence, and sound economic programs, could have reduced any potential ethnic conflicts. Notwithstanding, concentration of power in a few hands means lack of accountability and transparency necessary for investment and more rapid growth. This could also have accounted for the moderate economic performance observed in this study. Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 26 3. Somalia Somalia is an Eastern African country, bordering the Gulf of Aden and the Indian Ocean. It is also located east of Ethiopia and northeast of Kenya. Somalia got independence from Britain and Italy in 1960. Somalia has an estimated population of 9 million people. Studying what the state has done to combat both ethnic conflicts and to strengthen institutions speaks volumes in the case of Somalia. Let us examine the kind of institutions Somalia has to begin with. Admittedly, there are no formal political parties in Somalia. Worse still, there is no permanent national government, but only various fleeting transitional, parliamentary federal governments have been operating since the breakdown of the central government in 1991 (Rigol, 2004 October). The mandate of the Transitional National Government (TNG), created in August 2000 in Arta, Djibouti, expired in August 2003. President Abdullahi Yusuf Ahmed has formed a new Transitional Federal Government (TFG) consisting of a 275-member parliament. This body was established in October 2004 to replace the TNG but has not yet moved to Mogadishu because numerous warlords and factions are still fighting for control of the capital city as well as for other southern regions. Additionally, there is no national legal system except Shari'a and secular courts which are in some localities. This translates to lack of uniformity in the criminal justice system. In other words, each region or clan resorts to local conflict resolution based on traditional or sharia law. Currently, the judicial branch is malfunctioning due to the breakdown of the central government in 1993. Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 27 Altogether, the central government is ineffectual and conflict-ridden. Since independence, Somalia has been embroiled in ethnic politics culminating in the war of 1991. But at independence, colonial leaders assumed that given one religion, Somalia would hold together because of homogeneity: major ethnic clans are Somali (85%), Bantu and other non-Somali (15%). They were wrong because clan differences became the source of conflicts, tearing Somalia apart. Inter- and sub clan warfare tore Somalia because clans sometimes control different regions and natural resources (Rigol, 2004 October). These tensions continued until the regime of Mohamed Siad Barre was ousted in January 1991, and turmoil, factional fighting, and anarchy have followed in the years since. Rigol (2004, October) blamed this on Siad Barre’s “notorious divide- and –rule approach supplemented by the ruthless slaughters of opposition members and clans” (p. 1). In May of 1991, northern clans declared an independent Republic of Somaliland that now includes the administrative regions of Awdal, Woqooyi Galbeed, Togdheer, Sanaag, and Sool. Although not recognized by any government, this entity has maintained a stable existence, aided by the overwhelming dominance of a ruling clan and economic infrastructure left behind by British, Russian, and American military assistance programs. The regions of Bari and Nugaal and northern Mudug comprise a neighboring selfdeclared autonomous state of Puntland, which has been self-governing since 1998. Puntland also has made strides towards reconstructing a legitimate, representative government, but has suffered some civil strife. Puntland also disputes its border with Somaliland as it claims portions of eastern Sool and Sanaag (CIA, 2005). Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 28 Lack of central authority, political parties and divisions of power formed along ethnic lines have hurt Somalia. First, a weak central government has done nothing to enfeeble ethnic conflicts. On the contrary, each region under any warlord wanted to maximize their ethnic capital and this heightens clan tensions and hostilities. Hence, following the breakdown of the central government, most regions have reverted to local forms of conflict resolution, either secular, traditional clan-based arbitration, or Islamic (Shari'a) law with a provision for appeal of all sentences. This precedent has led scholars, Shultz (1995) among others, to describe Somalia as a “prototype of state disintegration and ungovernability”. The state has done nothing to combat but rather spurs clan conflicts. Politicians in power have maximized their gains using the state apparatus. In other words, Somalia practices an exclusionary approach to politics because every clan, at the expense of others, is hell-bent on furthering their interests. Politicians who come to power only favor their clansmen. Apart from the ruling party, everyone else is excluded from participating in politics. Hence, the lack of social capital, diffusion of ideas, black markets with high premiums, and weak institutions could have contributed to the negative growth residual of 5.75%. Also, the latent or lag effects of the civil war in 1993 could have impacted the data chosen. In short, Somalia with its exclusive approach to politics aggravates the effects of ELF, making it an underachiever. Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 29 4. Democratic Republic of Congo (DR) The Democratic Republic of Congo is located in Central Africa, northeast of Angola. Established as a Belgian colony in 1908, the Republic of the Congo gained its independence in 1960. All in all, DR has over 200 African ethnic groups. The four largest tribes are Mongo, Luba, Kongo (all Bantu), and the Mangbetu-Azande (Hamitic) which make up about 45% of the estimated population of 60 million people. Like many nations on the continent, Congo’s early years were marred by political and social instability. Colonel Joseph Mobutu seized power, declaring himself as a president in a November 1965 coup. He subsequently changed his name - to Mobutu Sese Seko -as well as that of the country- to Zaire. Mobutu maintained his position for 32 years through several subsequent sham elections as well as the use of brutal force against political opponents. However, ethnic strife and civil war were fueled by the massive inflow of refugees in 1994 from Rwanda and Burundi. These events eventually caused the toppling of the Mobutu regime in May of 1997 by a rebellion led by Laurent Kabala, who renamed the country the Democratic Republic of the Congo (Reybtjens, 1999). Although the government of Laurent Kabila was moving to democratic reforms, external aggression had a destabilizing effect. Like his predecessor, Kabila’s regime was itself challenged by an insurrection backed by Rwanda and Uganda in August, 1998. Troops from Zimbabwe, Angola, Namibia, Chad, and Sudan intervened to support the Kinshasa regime. A cease-fire was signed in July 1999 by the DR, Zimbabwe, Angola, Uganda, Namibia, Rwanda, and Congolese armed rebel groups. Tragically, Laurent Kabila was assassinated in January 2001 and his son Joseph Kabila was named head of the state. In October 2002, the new president was successful in Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 30 negotiating the withdrawal of Rwandan forces occupying eastern Congo, and two months later the Pretoria Accord was signed by all remaining warring parties to end the fighting and establish a government of national unity. A transitional government was set up in July 2003 and Joseph Kabila remains as president and is assisted by four vice presidents representing the former government, former rebel groups, and the political opposition since independence. Let us examine what the state has done to reduce ethnic conflict. First, under Mobutu, political activities were illegal, unlike now under Kabila. Under Kabila, DR has the following parties: Democratic Social Christian Party, Forces for Renovation for Union and Solidarity, the National Congolese Lumumbist Movement, the Popular Movement of the Revolution, the Unified Lumumbast Party, the Union for Democracy and Social Progress, the Union of Federalists and Independent Republicans (CIA, 2006). As of 2003, a National Assembly and Supreme Court were running. DR has a new constitution adopted 17 July 2003 with a legal system based on Belgian civil law and tribal law. It also has a 500-member National Assembly and a 120-seat Senate established in June 2003. It is hoped that the first free elections will be held in early 2006. The institutions inherited from Mobutu were weak. The country has also suffered from the war of 1998. Thus, Despite natural endowments with vast potential wealth (cobalt, copper, niobium, tantalum, petroleum, industrial and gem diamonds, gold, silver, zinc, manganese, tin, uranium, coal, hydropower, timber), the war, which began in August 1998, dramatically reduced national output and government revenue, increased external debt, and resulted in the deaths of perhaps 3.5 million people. Foreign businesses Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 31 curtailed operations due to uncertainty about the outcome of the conflict, lack of infrastructure, and the difficult operating environment. Although ethnic conflict played no major role in this, weak institutions and devastating civil war could have accounted for the DR’s negative growth residual in this period. Under Mbotu, Congo exercised an exclusive approach to politics. However, it became less dictatorial under Laurent Kabila and his son, Joseph. Thus, political instability, an unfavorable environment, uninvited aggression by sister countries, and lack of social capital could have accounted for Congo’s negative growth residual. 5. Uganda: The Republic of Uganda is a country in East Africa bordered in the east by Kenya, in the north by Sudan, by the Democratic Republic of Congo in the west, Rwanda in the southwest and Tanzania in the south.. Uganda takes its name from the historical Buganda kingdom, which encompasses a portion of the south of the country, including the capital Kampala (CIA, 2005). Uganda achieved independence from Britain in 1962. The transfer of power from colonial masters to African elite was a smooth one. However, by 1966, the first Prime Minister, Milton Obote, had overthrown the constitution and declared himself president, ushering in an era of coups and countercoups which would last until the mid-1980s. 1971, for instance, saw Idi Amin take power, ruling the country with an iron fist. During Amin and Obote’s dictatorial regimes, it is estimated that about 300, 000 and 10,000 lives were lost respectively. But in 1986, there was a change in government and that change saw the rise to power of Yoweri Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 32 Museveni. Ever since, Museveni is generally viewed as being part of a new generation of African leaders (Nystrom, 2000). According to the regression (see table 5), Uganda seemed to have done well relative to its ELF. As indicated in the foregoing paragraph, Uganda is an overachiever. This growth performance took place under the reign of Museveni. It is befitting to examine factors that might have reduced the effects of ELF: what has the government done to help lessen adverse sides of diversity and what sort of institutions are in Uganda. First, Uganda is a republic which had never held popular elections since independence until 1996 under Museveni. The President, who is the head of the government and chief of state, appoints both cabinet members and a prime minister to help him rule the country. He is elected by popular vote to a five year term. There are checks and balances in Uganda. High court judges are appointed by the president and approved by the legislature. Legislators are elected by popular vote in direct elections. There are also political parties, though they are not allowed to campaign on behalf of any candidates. Political campaigns were permitted in July 2005 through referendum (Nystrom, 2000). It appears that presence of some checks and balances in the constitution is a sign of competent institutions. Besides institutions, it is also healthy to investigate what has been done to reduce ethnic conflicts which could have resulted from Uganda’s ethnic diversity. The composition of the population is as follows: Baganda (17%), Ankole (8%), Basoga (8%), Iteso (8%), Bakiga (7%), Langi (6%), Rwanda (6%), Bagisu (5%), Acholi (4%), Lugbara (4%), Batoro (3%), Bunyoro 3(%), Alur (2%), Bagwere (2%), Bakonjo (2%), Jopodhola (2%), Karamojong (2%), Rundi (2%), non-African (European, Asian, Arab) (1%), and Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 33 other (8%) (CIA, 2006). With the intent to thwart corruption, ethnic violence, ethnic politics and sectarian violence, political parties were restricted in their activities from 1986 only to be reinstated in July 2005 during a referendum. No ethnic group or political party is allowed (1986-2005) to campaign for any candidates because political party activities are seen as confrontational and divisive (Stasavage, 2001; Makinda, 1996). More telling, the state tries to be inclusive. None of any ethnic group is isolated or singled out as the enemy of the state. Because of its respect toward human rights, equitable development, single-party politics, and an independent judiciary, Uganda has few ethnic conflicts within its borders. Most of scarce public resources go toward constructive ends (development). Since 1986, the government - with the support of foreign countries and international agencies - has acted to rehabilitate an economy decimated during the regime of Idi Amin and subsequent civil war (CIA, 2005). Thus, it is possible that Uganda is an overachiever because there were no wars which would have led to misallocation of resources. Secondly, the period of this study (19932003) falls within the years of political stability in Uganda. What's more, corruption and ethnic politics were discouraged, and that could be the cause of the growth residual of 2.43%. Besides, unlike Somalia, or Congo, transparency and stability are counted on in Uganda. Thus these factors could be the grounds for observed growth performance. In short, under Museveni’s leadership, relative stability has been brought to the country with the exception of the North, which continues to struggle with a rebel insurgency. Sufficient institutions and a limited inclusive approach to politics accounts for good growth. Uganda, under Museveni, exhibits a limited inclusive approach to politics. Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 34 Policy Implications Although research like this has limitations, there are inferences to be made from it. First, this study has shown that ethnic fragmentation and growth are inversely correlated though, the correlation is somewhat weak (see table figure 4). Secondly, it is assuredly clear that the nature of institutions affects the importance of ELF. Only two out of the five countries studied in detail, have done relatively well given their ELF values. There are similarities among the two: there were no full scale wars in those countries and their institutions, such as the legislature, executive branch and judiciary are functioning. Both countries have sought ways that did not alienate ethnic groups. But in the case of Somalia, Congo and Libya, there are imbalances of power. In Libya, the executive branch wields too much power. While in Somalia, lack of central government is a handicap. For the case of Congo, bad policies from the former government, and bothersome neighbors impacted growth. In short, institutions are stronger in Uganda and Cameroon but somewhat weaker in Somalia and Congo. While in Libya, lack of freedom has meant slower diffusion of ideas, technology innovation and cooperation. This might have affected investment and growth. Thirdly, Somalia and Libya, both underachievers, differ in their approaches to addressing ethnic diversity. In Libya, Gaddafi has used trepidation and ruthlessness to ensure stability and hold the country together. For the case of Somalia, lack of an authoritative figure like Gaddafi has meant that each war lord garnered allegiance from his immediate group. These cases show that it is possible to fail in dealing with ethnic fragmentation both by exerting excessive external control and by failing to hold the center together. Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 35 Fourthly, this paper hints that corruption is likely to flourish in places where there is lack of accountability. In a corrupt government, even good intentions do not necessarily result in public goods. For instance, foreign aid, which is intended to reduce poverty, improve training and increase salaries for public employees, erodes quality of governance in unstable regimes (Knack, 2001). Aid also increases political instability when various parties compete for control of large scale food aid, as was the case in Somalia’s civil war (Knack, 2001). In other words, under regimes with weak institutions, a high level of aid dependence makes government accountable to donors and not the public, and when funding stops, institutions break down. Thus, aid is not effective on the continent because of the weak institutions and lack of accountability. Although as of January 2005, the U.N asked the world’s wealthiest nations to forgive debts and give more aid to the poorest nations with the intent to halve extreme poverty by the year 2015, not much will be achieved unless corruption is eliminated (Jeffrey, 2005). The presence of corruption and poor governance leads to misuse of funds. Fifthly, it seems that fear under tyrannical regimes breeds fake loyalty, sycophancy and boot-licking. These makings of dictatorial regimes do not last. For instance, Mobutu wielded power through brutality. But when his time came, his government crumpled within days. General Siad Barre did the same thing in Somalia. Libya is also being held together by fear of Gaddafi. The point here is that some nations are not experiencing civil wars or falling apart because an oppressive personality holds them at least for the time being. Sixthly, other factors beside ELF could have affected growth rates in this case studies. Libya is 97% Sunni Muslim (though its ELF is higher than average.792). Religion could Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 36 have been a uniting factor and thus help to reduce ethnic conflict. In other words, there could be many ways of categorizing a particular group of people. ELF could not capture the changing effect of religion. Thus, “grouping problem” merits consideration. Unreliability of African Politics It should be noted that African politics is fluid; nothing is fixed so to speak. Countries in Africa may be inclusive for a while under certain regimes but exclusive under other regimes. They may be underachievers today and overachievers tomorrow. For instance, Uganda under Iddi Amin was oppressive and divisive. However, under Museveni, it is united and freer. The same is also true of Zaire, the Democratic Republic of Congo. Moreover, another distinctive characteristic of African politics is its high number of states. This means Africa is highly fragmented and, if the ELF theory holds, then it is an indication of more political and ethnic divisions (Wallensteen & Sollenberg, 1999), which breeds an unfavorable environment for investment and growth. Out of these numerous political and ethnic divisions, some regimes cause ethnic groups to fight one another while some do not. Some regimes can be dictatorships today but might not be tomorrow (see the case of Democratic Republic of Congo and Uganda). This changeability in the forms of governments has a bearing on development because it interferes with growth and investment. Growth may improve in a country with stronger institutions and harmonious ethnic relationships and may drastically suffer under another. Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 37 Conclusion This research finds that growth and ELF are negatively correlated though the strength of the correlation in Africa requires further study. It also finds that African politics is unstable. Countries in Africa may be inclusive for a while under certain regimes but exclusive under other regimes. This fluidity might have led some countries to either embrace or shun ethnic plurality. Many countries might have either embraced ethnic diversity but excluded politicians that embrace ethnic votes (Liberia, Uganda) or have shunned diversity and singled out some tribes ( Malawi, Somalia, Congo). Also, evidence from this study shows that some countries have made efforts to weaken or exacerbate ELF effects by choosing inclusive or exclusionary approaches to politics. Finally, this paper does not find a “Silver bullet” in dealing with ethnic conflicts. The variety of approaches undertaken by Somalia, Congo, Libya, Uganda and DR affirm this claim. Uganda abolished campaigns on behalf of candidates; it thus alienated no one but boosted growth. Libya exploited fear and religion to fight ethnic conflicts and it suffered poor growth. Somalia used ethnic mobilization and thus reaped disintegration and poor growth, while DR adopted sound policies and appeased meddling neighbors, though a decade of instability resulted in poor growth. . Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 38 Works Cited Abdalla, A. (1991). “Mubarak’s Gamble”. Middle East Report, 168:18-21. Abubakar, D. (2001). “Ethnic Identity, Democratization, and the Future of the African State: Lessons from Nigeria”. Ethnicity and Recent Democratic Experiments in Africa, African Issues, 29(1/2):31-36. Alesina, A., Baqir, R., & Easterly, W. (1999). “Public Goods and Ethnic Divisions”. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(4):1243-1284. Alesina, A., Devleeschauwer, A., Easterly, W., Kurlat, S., & Wacziarg, R. (2003). “Fractionalization”. Journal of Economic Growth, 8: 155-194. Ayalon, H., Ben-Rafael, E., & Sharot, S. (1986). “The Costs and Benefits of Ethnic Identification”. British Journal of Sociology, 37(4): 550-568. Azam, J. (2001). “The Redistributive State and Conflicts in Africa”. Journal of Peace Research, 38(4): 429- 444. Bates, R. (2000, May). “Ethnicity and Development in Africa: A reappraisal”. The American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings one of the Hundred Twelfth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association, 90(2): 131-134. Blanton, R., Mason, T. D., & Athow, B. (2001). “Colonial Style and Post-colonial Ethnic Conflict in Africa”. Journal of Peace Research, 38(4): 473-491. Chabal, P. (2002). “The Quest for Good Government and Development in Africa: Is NEPAD the Answer?” International Affairs, 78(3): 447-462. Chabal, P. (1991). “Africans, Africanists and the African Crisis: Africa”. Journal of the International African Institute, 61(4): 530-532. CIA. (2005; 2006). The World Factbook. Washington, D.C: Central Intelligence of The United States. Collier, P., & Gunning, J. W. (1999). “Why has Africa Grown Slowly?” The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 13(3): 3-22. Dion, D. (1997). “Competition and Ethnic conflict: Artifactual?” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 41(5): 638-648. Easterly, W. (2001). “Can Institutions Resolve Ethnic conflict?” Economic Development and Cultural Change, 49(4): 687-706. Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 39 Easterly, W., & Levine, R. (1997). “Africa's Growth Tragedy: Policies and Ethnic Divisions”. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(4): 1203-1250. Elbadawi, I., & Sambanis, N. (2000). “Why are There So Many Civil Wars in Africa? Understanding and Preventing Violent Conflict”. Journal of African Economies, 9(3): 244-269. Errol, A. H... (2000). “When States Implode: The Correlates of Africa’s Civil Wars, 1950-1992”. Studies in Comparative International Development; Summer, 35(2):1-18. Fegley, R. (1981). “The U.N. Human Rights Commission: The Equatorial Guinea Case”. Human Rights Quarterly, 3(1):34-47. Jeffrey, G. (2005, March 7). “Do not Just Throw Money at the World’s Poor”. Business Week, Issue 3923, p. 30. Harbeson, J. W. (1993-1999, and 1998). “The Clinton Administration and the Promotion of Democracy: Practical Imperatives for Theoretical Exploration”. Issue: A Journal of Opinion, the Clinton Administration and Africa, 26(2):36-40. Kalinga, O. (1998). “The Production of History in Malawi in the 1960s: The Legacy of Sir Harry Johnston, the Influence of the Society of Malawi and the Role of Dr. Kamuzu Banda and His Malawi Congress Party”. African Affairs, 97(389): 523-549. Kigozi, A. (2004, October 13). “Greed Explains Why Politicians are Richer Than Businessmen!” International Customwire, 1-2. Knack, S. (2001). “Aid Dependence and the Quality of Governance: Cross-Country Empirical Tests”. Southern Economic Journal, 68(2): 310-329. Lake. D & Rothchild, D. (1996). “Containing Fear: The Origins and Management of Ethnic Conflict”. International Security, 21(2): 41-75. Lorentzen, Peter et al. (2005). “Death and development. Center for Global Business and the Economy at the Stanford School of Business”. Working paper, p 1-70. Makinda, S. (1996). “Democracy and Multi-party Politics in Africa”. The Journal of Modern African Studies, 34(4): 555-573. Mauro, P. (1995). “Corruption and Growth”. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(3): 681-712. Mengisteab, K. (2001). “Ethiopia's Ethnic-Based Federalism: 10 Years After”. African Issues: Ethnicity and Recent Democratic Experiments in Africa, 29(1/2): 20-25. Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 40 Montalvo, J. G., & Reynal-Querol, M. (2002). “Why Ethnic Fractionalization? Polarization, Ethnic Conflict and Growth”. Department of Economics and Business, Universitat Pompeu, Fabra, Economics Working Papers. . Nagel, J., & Olzak, S. (1982). “Ethnic Mobilization in New and Old States: An Extension of the Competition Model”. Social Problems, 30(2): 127-143. Nystrom, Christina. (2000, June-August). “Uganda: The Party System from 1963 to 2000”. Northwestern University’s Summer Camp for Political Party Research. Ndegwa, S. (1997). “Citizenship and Ethnicity: An Examination of Two Transition Movements In Kenya Politics”. The American Political Science Review, 91(3): 599-616. O’Connel, J. (1967). “The Inevitability of Instability”. The Journal of Modern African Studies, 5, (2) 181-191. Ogunbadejo, O. (1983). “Qaddafi’s North African Design”. International Security, 8(1) 154-178. Posner, D. N. (2004). “Measuring Ethnic Fractionalization in Africa”. American Journal of Political Science, 48(4): 849-863. Quinn, D. P., & Woolley, J. T. (2001). “Democracy and National Economic Performance: The Preference for Stability”. American Journal of Political Science, 45(3): 634-657. Reybtjens, F. (1999). “Briefing: The Second Congo War: More than A Remake”. African Affairs, 98(391): 241-250. Rigol, N. (2004, October). “Clash of Clans: Challenges to Somalia Government”. Harvard International Review, summer, No. 7 Sadowski, Y. (1998). “Ethnic Conflict”. Foreign Policy, 111: 12-23. Shultz, R. (1995). “State Disintegration and Ethnic Conflict: A Framework for Analysis”. Annals of the American Academy of political and Social Science, 541: 634-657. Sollenberg, M. & Wallensteen, P. (1999). “Armed Conflicts, 1989-98”. Journal of Peace Research, 36(5): 593-606. Standard Bank Research (2005, January 21). “Sub-Saharan Africa's Growth Record and Indebtedness”. International CustomWire, CX200502119853, p. 1. Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 41 Stasavage, D. (2005). “Democracy and Education Spending in Africa”. American Journal of Political Science, 49(2): 343-358. Visscher, M. (2005). “Champion Poverty Fighter of the World: Muhammad Yunu”. ProFourth World, 16th Annual Conference, 26-61. Woods, D. (1994). “Elites, Ethnicity, and ‘Home Town’ Association in the Cote d’Ivoire: An Historical Analysis of the state- Society Links”. Africa: Journal of the International African Institute, 64(4): 465-483. Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions Table 1: GDP per Capita and ELF in Africa Country 1993 GDP Per 2003 GDP Capita (2000$) Per Capita (2000 $) Annual Growth Rate ELF Uganda 796 1024 0.025 0.9302 Liberia 351 698 0.069 0.9084 Madagascar 737 610 -0.019 0.8791 Congo (RC) 1573 1433 -0.009 0.8747 Congo (DRC) 1069 612 -0.056 0.8747 Cameroon 1868 2099 0.012 0.8635 Chad 907 954 0.005 0.862 Kenya 1374 1385 0.001 0.8588 Nigeria 951 819 -0.015 0.8505 Central African Republic 1464 1544 0.005 0.8295 Cote D’ Ioire 1358 1459 0.007 0.8204 Sierra Leone 742 473 -0.045 0.8191 Somalia 1540 898 -0.054 0.8117 Guinea-Bissau 1040 741 -0.034 0.8082 Djibouti 1390 1203 -0.014 0.7962 Libya 8463 7012 -0.019 0.792 Benin 1104 1233 0.011 0.7872 Angola 823 1244 0.041 0.7867 Gambia 1001 998 0.000 0.7864 Zambia 1010 847 -0.018 0.7808 Gabon 5621 5851 0.004 0.769 South Africa 6094 6879 0.012 0.7517 Guinea 978 1055 0.008 0.7389 Burkina Faso 924 1000 0.008 0.7377 Tanzania 653 691 0.006 0.7353 Ethiopia 449 540 0.018 0.7235 Sudan 774 910 0.016 0.7147 42 Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions Togo 1394 1601 0.014 0.7099 Senegal 1434 1630 0.013 0.6939 Mozambique 712 1264 0.057 0.6932 Mali 710 783 0.010 0.6906 Malawi 691 753 0.009 0.6744 Ghana 1573 1795 0.013 0.6733 Eritrea 612 706 0.014 0.6524 Niger 858 922 0.007 0.6518 Namibia 3695 3686 0.000 0.6329 Mauritania 1623 1768 0.009 0.615 Morocco 3198 3611 0.012 0.4841 Mauritius 7841 10832 0.032 0.4634 Cape Verde 1073 1540 0.036 0.4174 Botswana 2841 3637 0.025 0.4102 Zimbabwe 1915 1583 -0.019 0.3874 Equatorial Guinea 607 3435 0.173 0.3467 Algeria 4341 4472 0.003 0.3394 Rwanda 714 825 0.014 0.3238 Burundi 781 701 -0.011 0.2951 Lesotho 1976 2645 0.029 0.255 Seychelles 6534 6186 -0.005 0.2025 Egypt 2420 2723 0.012 0.1836 Swaziland 3619 3536 -0.002 0.0582 Tunisia 4273 5379 0.023 0.0394 Comoros 922 655 -0.034 0 Mean 1950 2132. 0.0077 0.6305 n Notes: ELF = 1 si i 1 Source: Easterly (2001). 2 43 , where si = the share of the population accounted for by group i Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 44 Table 2: GDP Per Capita and ELF in Latin America Country Name 1993 2003 Annual Growth Rate ELF values Bolivia (BL) Suriname (NS) Belize (BH) Peru (PE) Ecuador (EC) Trinidad and Tobago (TD) Guyana (GY) Colombia (CO) Cuba (CU) Panama (PM) Mexico (MX) Brazil (BR) Guatemala (GT) Nicaragua (NU) Dominican Republic (DR) Bahamas (BF) Jamaica (JM) Saint Vincent and the Grenadines (VC) Grenada (GJ) Argentina (AR) Uruguay (UY) Costa Rica (CS) Dominica (DO) El Salvador (ES) Honduras (HO) Chile (CI) Saint Kitts & Nevis (SC) Saint Lucia (ST) Paraguay (PA) Antiqua (AC) Barbados (BB) Haiti (HA) Mean 2521 2787 2910 3359 4382 5849 1820 5890 1324 6460 7583 5330 3380 2306 3784 17179 3347 2126 2816 8612 7055 6127 2759 2551 2083 9130 4497 3841 3334 6508 8998 1312 4749 2783 3442 2905 4113 4108 8714 2570 5765 1645 6788 7884 5662 3456 2431 5079 18773 3186 2536 3840 7636 6691 6598 2823 2778 2135 11737 6137 3782 3125 6963 9821 1150 5221 0.0099 0.0211 -0.0002 0.0202 -0.0065 0.0399 0.0345 -0.0021 0.0217 0.0049 0.0039 0.0060 0.0022 0.0053 0.0294 0.0089 -0.0049 0.0176 0.0310 -0.0120 -0.0053 0.0074 0.0023 0.0085 0.0025 0.0251 0.0311 -0.0015 -0.0065 0.0068 0.0088 -0.0132 0.0093 0.7396 0.7332 0.7015 0.6566 0.6550 0.6475 0.6195 0.6014 0.5908 0.5528 0.5418 0.5408 0.5122 0.4844 0.4294 0.4228 0.4129 0.3066 0.2661 0.2550 0.2504 0.2368 0.2003 0.1978 0.1867 0.1861 0.1842 0.1769 0.1689 0.1643 0.1423 0.0950 0.4019 Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions Table 3: GDP Per Capita and ELF in Asia and the Pacific Annual GDPPC GDPPC Growth Country Name 1993 2003 Rates Indonesia Pakistan Micronesia Nepal Thailand Bhutan Malaysia Nauru Fiji Brunei Laos Palau India Sri Lanka Singapore Mongolia Papua New Guinea Philippines Vietnam Cambodia Tuvalu China Samoa Solomon Islands Tonga Marshall Islands Kiribati Bangladesh Vanuatu Korea (North) Japan Korea (South) Mean 2547 1776 2052 979 5566 829 8307 10553 5913 16251 978 5494 1297 1989 19374 1952 2436 3050 1267 598 780 2236 1991 2565 2141 2426 693 1143 1186 1133 20891 9781 4291 2648 1938 1737 1047 6118 1078 9883 10882 7025 15924 1267 7249 1786 2470 20556 2231 2053 3434 1847 662 986 4072 2985 2210 2399 1833 750 1419 1144 1019 21891 13349 4776 0.0039 0.0087 -0.0167 0.0068 0.0095 0.0263 0.0174 0.0031 0.0172 -0.0020 0.0259 0.0277 0.0320 0.0216 0.0059 0.0133 -0.0171 0.0119 0.0377 0.0101 0.0234 0.0599 0.0405 -0.0149 0.0114 -0.0280 0.0079 0.0216 -0.0036 -0.0106 0.0047 0.0311 0.0121 ELF Values 0.7351 0.7098 0.7005 0.6632 0.6338 0.6050 0.5880 0.5832 0.5479 0.5416 0.5139 0.4312 0.4182 0.4150 0.3857 0.3682 0.2718 0.2385 0.2383 0.2105 0.1629 0.1538 0.1376 0.1110 0.0869 0.0603 0.0511 0.0454 0.0413 0.0392 0.0119 0.0020 0.3345 45 Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions Table 4: Africa’s Regression Results Constant Coefficient 0.0219 Standard Error 0.0127 t-statistics 1.72 ELF -0.0226 0.0187 -1.21 Dependent variable = Growth rate of GDP per capita 1993-2003. N = 50, R2=0.033, F=1.4571. Table 5: Growth Residuals for Africa Annual Country Growth Rate Predicted Growth Residuals Equatorial Guinea Liberia 0.173 0.069 0.0141 0.0014 0.1592 0.0673 Mozambique 0.057 0.0063 0.0511 Angola 0.041 0.0041 0.0372 Uganda 0.025 0.0009 0.0243 Cape Verde 0.036 0.0125 0.0237 Mauritius 0.032 0.0114 0.0209 Lesotho 0.029 0.0161 0.0130 Ethiopia 0.018 0.0056 0.0129 Botswana 0.025 0.0126 0.0121 Sudan 0.016 0.0058 0.0104 Cameroon 0.012 0.0024 0.0093 Togo 0.014 0.0059 0.0080 South Africa 0.012 0.0049 0.0072 Eritrea 0.014 0.0072 0.0071 46 Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions Table 5 (continued) Benin 0.011 0.0041 0.0069 Senegal 0.013 0.0062 0.0066 Ghana 0.013 0.0067 0.0065 Cote D’ Ioire 0.007 0.0034 0.0038 Mali 0.010 0.0063 0.0035 Burkina Faso 0.008 0.0052 0.0027 Chad 0.005 0.0024 0.0026 Guinea 0.008 0.0052 0.0024 Central African Republic 0.005 0.0032 0.0021 Tunisia 0.023 0.0210 0.0020 Malawi 0.009 0.0067 0.0019 Morocco 0.012 0.0110 0.0012 Mauritania 0.009 0.0080 0.0005 Tanzania 0.006 0.0053 0.0004 Niger 0.007 0.0072 0.0000 Rwanda 0.014 0.0146 -0.0001 Gabon 0.004 0.0045 -0.0005 Kenya 0.001 0.0025 -0.0017 Gambia 0.000 0.0041 -0.0044 Egypt 0.012 0.0178 -0.0060 Namibia 0.000 0.0076 -0.0079 Algeria 0.003 0.0142 -0.0113 Congo (RC) -0.009 0.0022 -0.0115 Nigeria -0.015 0.0027 -0.0176 Djibouti -0.014 0.0039 -0.0184 Madagascar -0.019 0.0021 -0.0210 Zambia -0.018 0.0043 -0.0219 Seychelles -0.005 0.0173 -0.0228 Libya -0.019 0.0040 -0.0228 Swaziland -0.002 0.0206 -0.0229 47 Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 48 Table 5 (continued) Burundi -0.011 0.0152 -0.0261 Zimbabwe -0.019 0.0132 -0.0322 Guinea-Bissau -0.034 0.0037 -0.0376 Sierra Leone -0.045 0.0034 -0.0484 Comoros -0.034 0.0219 -0.0561 Somalia -0.054 0.0036 -0.0575 Congo (DRC) -0.056 0.0022 -0.0579 Source: See text Figure 1: Africa’s Growth Rates ELF Vs. 1993-2003 Growth Rates 0.200 Growth Rates 0.150 0.100 0.050 0.000 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 -0.050 -0.100 ELF Values Source: See text 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions 49 Figure 2: Latin America’s Growth Rates ELF Vs. 1993-2003 Growth Rates 0.05 0.04 Growth Rates 0.03 0.02 0.01 0 0.0000 -0.01 0.1000 0.2000 0.3000 0.4000 0.5000 0.6000 0.7000 0.8000 -0.02 ELF Values Source: See text Figure 3: Asia and the Pacific’s Growth Rates Asia and the Pacific: ELF Vs. 1993-2003 Growth Rates 0.07 0.06 0.05 Growth Rates 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01 0 0.0000 -0.01 0.1000 0.2000 0.3000 0.4000 -0.02 -0.03 -0.04 ELF Values Source: See text 0.5000 0.6000 0.7000 0.8000 Ethno-Linguistic Fragmentation and Political Institutions Name of Candidate: James Alic Garang Birth Date: 1976Birthplace: Ajokrenge, Marialbai, Sudan Address: 1638 West Secret Garden # 200 Salt Lake City, UT 84104 50