Rivers of Diversity: Evolving Water Regulation in California and the European Union Gabrielle Bouleau (1), Matt Kondolf (2) (1) UMR G-EAU, Cemagref, 361 rue Jean-François Breton, F-34196 Montpellier, France gabrielle.bouleau@cemagref.fr (2) LAEP, University of California, Berkeley, kondolf@berkeley.edu 1. Introduction Aquatic and riparian areas have long been recognized as biodiversity ‘hotspots’ in the landscape, and thus have been the focus of many environmental regulations. Principal threats to aquatic biodiversity have been water quality degradation from pollution, morphological modifications and reduction in water quantity from diversions for human uses. Adequate flows in rivers are increasingly recognized as essential to maintain or restore aquatic ecosystems1, and such ecosystem flows must be implemented in the context of water rights. With changes in runoff regimes anticipated from climate change, threats to aquatic biodiversity will be severe if water rights and regulations established in past eras cannot be modified to reflect emerging objectives of biodiversity and ecosystem health2. Rivers and their floodplains support a wide range of conditions (reflecting variations in vegetation, substrate, groundwater levels, frequency and seasonality of inundation, and microclimate), which in turn provide a wide range of habitats and thus support many, diverse species. Riparian zones are arguably the most diverse parts of many landscapes3. From a human perspective, rivers and floodplains have multiple functions besides supporting biodiversity: water supply, flood storage and conveyance, groundwater recharge, improvement of water quality, and corridors for wildlife migration. Artificial changes to river morphology (such as straightening for navigation or drainage) reduce habitat complexity. Water diversions reduce river flows, commonly reducing available aquatic habitat, and in extreme cases, drying out rivers. Even less extreme reductions in flows can affect water quality by affecting temperature and reducing dilution of contaminants. The combination of such pressures threatens biodiversity. Regulations targeting water quality have also implications on water quantity through these linkages. To find inspiring examples of regulatory adaptation, scholars often look to comparisons among developed countries of the European Union (EU) and states of the United States of America (US), notably California4. Political analysts5 and environmental historians6 have 1 G. Mathias Kondolf et al., "Process-Based Ecological River Restoration; Visualizing Three-Dimensional Connectivity and Dynamic Vectors to Recover Lost Linkages," Ecology and Society 11, no. 2 (2006), N LeRoy Poff et al., "River Flows and Water Wars: Emerging Science for Environmental Decision Making," Frontiers in Ecology and the Environment 1, no. 6 (2003), N. Ward, P. Lowe, and H. Buller, "Implementing European Water Quality Directives: Lessons for Sustainable Development," in The Politics of Sustainable Development, ed. S. Baker, et al. (London: Routledge, 1997). 2 Joseph B. Knox and Ann Foley Scheuring, Global Climate Change and California: Potential Impacts and Responses (University of California Press, 1991). 3 Robert J. Naiman et al., Riparia: Ecology, Conservation, and Management of Streamside Communities (Amsterdam: Elsevier Academic Press, 2005). 4 David Vogel, "The Hare and the Tortoise Revisited: The New Politics of Consumer and Environmental Regulation in Europe," in Environmental Policy in the European Union, ed. Andrew Jordan (Earthscan, 2005). 5 Philipp Genschel and Thomas Plumper, "Regulatory Competition and International Co-Operation," Journal of European Public Policy, Volume 4, Issue 4 December 1997 , pages 4, no. 4 (1997), Giandomenico Majone, Regulating Europe (Routledge, 1996), Aseem Prakash and Matthew Potoski, "Racing to the Bottom? Trade, Environmental Governance, and Iso 14001," American Journal of Political Science 50, no. 2 (2006), Sebastiaan Princen, "Trading up in the Transatlantic Relationship," Journal of Public Policy, no. 24 (2004), David Vogel, 1 recognized the EU and California as cutting-edge regulators for the environment. Yet, apart from general statements on economic wealth and cultural green awareness, common explanations for their regulatory innovation have not been articulated. This paper shows that the EU and California have experienced similar challenges in the politics of water that may account for their regulatory innovation. In order to justify the relevance of the comparison, we start by laying out the institutional and political context of our case-studies. We then argue that California’s water law is predicated upon water efficiency. We show that competing definitions of efficiency arose as population grew and the relative importance of various economic sectors evolved. However, as we describe the resulting situation today, there are shortcomings in implementation of doctrines and this may hamper adaptation to climate change. We then turn towards the EU using France as an example of a Member State. We show that water allocation in France mainly results from historical governmental choices in which efficiency was never assessed by external review. Facing strong and conflicting interests in water supported by powerful economic states, the EU’s regulation of water is similarly based on efficiency assessment. We conclude with a comparison of the two cases, arguing that diversities faced by the EU and California have had comparably stimulating effects on efficiency-seeking policy. Yet both entities could learn from each other’s regulatory experience to better address climate change and social acceptability. 2. Why is it relevant to compare California and the EU? Both California and the European Union are considered as places where - despite significant economic and demographic stakes - environmental protection in general, and instream flow restoration in particular, benefit from innovative thinking. Major elements contributing to their reputations in this domain include the following. As far as environmental law is concerned, analysts refer to California as a super-regulator and a policy-pioneer7. Only one year after the US Congress had approved the first federal environmental protection statute, the National Environmental Policy Act (NEPA) in 1969, California supplemented it through state law. The legislature passed the California Environmental Quality Act (CEQA) in 1970 which expands environmental review requirements to state projects and projects requiring state agencies approval. Whereas NEPA requirements are alleged to be mainly procedural, the significance of substantive evidence in environmental impact reviews under CEQA, especially in water-related projects, has been confirmed by the Supreme Court of California since then. California has also become famous for the dramatic decision of its Supreme Court in the Mono Lake litigation, holding that the public trust doctrine required the reduction of the long-existing water rights of Los Angeles Department of Water and Power (National Audubon society v. Superior Court 1983). The "Environmental Regulation and Economic Integration " Journal of International Economic Law 3, no. 2 (2000), David Vogel, "Trading up and Governing Across: Transnational Governance and Environmental Protection," Journal of European Public Policy 4, no. 4 (1997). 6 Robert Gottlieb, Forcing the Spring: The Transformation of the American Environmental Movement (Washington: Island Press, 2005), Richard Walker, The Country in the City: The Greening of the San Francisco Bay Area (University of Washington Press, 2008), Donald Worster, ed., American Environmentalism. The Formative Period, 1860-1915, Wiley Sourcebooks in American Social Thought (Wiley, 1973). 7 See for instance in this volume, Roland-Holst, David, and David Hanneman. "Energy Efficiency and Economic Growth: Lessons from California." and Hioureas, Christina G., and Bruce E. Cain. "Transatlantic Environmental Regulation-Making: Strengthening Cooperation between California and the European Union." 2 efficiency of Los Angeles's water conservation programs have been acclaimed worldwide, and as described below, the streams of Mono Basin and the Owens Valley, which Los Angeles largely dried up to divert their flow southward through most of the 20th century, are being given back part of their natural flow to restore their aquatic ecosystems. First attempts to re-allocate water through water rights trading occurred initially in California, although observers are still doubtful whether this reallocation may support ecological restoration8. Finally, California is one of the most active theatres of river restoration in the US, with over 4000 distinct projects identified in a recent survey9. The single most important motivation for river restoration in California is restoration of habitat for native salmon species, whose populations have declined dramatically in response to human impacts. From 1996-2004, the CALFED Bay-Delta Program funded over $500 million USD in restoration projects, many for salmon or other threatened native fish, and a comparable amount again was spent over the same period by the US Bureau of Reclamation and the US Fish and Wildlife Service for salmon-related restoration10. At the time of NEPA and CEQA, the European Economic Community did not play a significant role in environmental policy. Its competence in that domain dramatically expanded after massive pollution of the Rhine in 1986, which killed fish for 100s of km downstream from Switzerland to the Netherlands, even threatening the Dutch water supply. Attention given to this event made water policy the “jewel in the crown” of the EU environmental policy11. Through the 1990s, the European Union gradually developed a set of directives that are heralded as highly integrated water resources policies. Some, such as the Urban Waste Water and Bathing Water initiatives were not considered very innovative when issued, because most of their provisions had prior US equivalent under the Clean Water Act of 197312. But the scope of their binding conditions became obvious recently when the EU Court of Justice fined Spain €624,150 per year for every 1% of inshore Spanish bathing waters that continue to fail to meet the quality standards set in the Bathing Water Directive. Similarly several Member States are threatened by pendant litigations for poorly enforcing the Urban WasteWater or the Nitrate directives. With the Water Framework Directive adopted in 2000, the EU was heralded as the international leader in river basin management. This statute combines institutional settings, economic tools, and biological requirements to foster integrated water management at the river basin scale, in all Member States, with binding and short deadlines (2015). The State of California and the European Union have developed significant pieces of law that are very demanding in term of ecological standards. Such elements account for the interest of water experts toward California and the EU. Yet to fully appreciate these examples requires in-depth understanding of the conditions that made innovative approaches possible. We 8 Juliet Christian-Smith, "The Politics and Practice of Watershed Restoration: Insights from the Russian River Basin, Northern California " (UC Berkeley, 2006). 9 E.S. Bernhardt et al., "Synthesizing U.S. River Restoration Efforts. ," Science, no. 308 (2005), G. M. Kondolf et al., "Two Decades of River Restoration in California: What Can We Learn?," Restoration Ecology 15, no. 3 (2007). 10 G.M. Kondolf et al., "Prioritizing River Restoration: Projecting Cumulative Benefits of Multiple Projects: An Example from the Sacramento-San Joaquin River System in California," Environmental Management no. 42 (2008). 11 David Aubin and Frédéric Varone, "European Water Policy. A Path Towards an Integrated Resource Management," (Louvain-la-neuve: EUWARENESS, 2002), Giorgos Kallis and Peter Nijkamp, "Evolution of Eu Water Policy: A Critical Assessment and a Hopeful Perspective," Zeitschrift für Umweltpolitik und Umweltrecht (ZfU), no. 3 (2000). 12 Gabrielle Bouleau, "The Wfd Dreams: Between Ecology and Economics," Water and Environment Journal 22, no. 4 (2008). 3 propose that drivers for change in favour of aquatic biodiversity in California and the EU are similar, despite many differences in institutional, legal and political settings. Scholars in political sciences and law usually apply different categories to describe institutions of the State of California and those of the EU. First, from a governmental point of view, California is one of the fifty states of the Federal Union, whereas the European Union is a non-federal institution gathering twenty five sovereign states, some of them being federations. Thus the comparison seems to overlook a fundamental inconsistency in institutional hierarchy. Second, the role of both entities in the governance of water significantly differs. The state of California has sovereign power to allocate water resources in the public interest whereas the European Union only exerts a non-exclusive competence over water regulation, whose scope is restricted to quality; water quantity allocation remains the competence of member states. At first glance, California seems in a better position to rule water uses than the EU. Third, California recognizes both riparian rights and appropriate rights (as discussed below), whereas most European countries guarantee the right of riparian owners to receive, without diminution, the natural flow of the stream. Thus basic provisions of water law in California and in the European countries point to opposite directions. With so many structural differences, it is hard to imagine that California and the EU have commonalities that could account for their innovative practices for governing aquatic biodiversity. But they do. Firstly, California is comparably diverse in landscapes to Europe, with elevations from 80 m below sea level to over 4000 above, from desert to humid temperate forests. Such diversity of physical features induced comparable biodiversity. In Europe, aquatic biodiversity is the highest around the Mediterranean Sea. It is also there that aquatic biodiversity is most threatened by water diversion. Similarly most Californian population settled in Mediterranean-climate coastal landscapes where biodiversity is high but seriously threatened by human activity. Secondly, both regions provide success stories of river restoration after a long period of degradation. Pollution similarly increased in rivers during the nineteenth and the first part of the twentieth century in the United States and the European Union, as in many industrial countries. But dramatic events largely covered by media in the last part of the century reversed this trend, at least its social perception. For instance, fires had erupted on Cuyahoga River (Ohio) several times before June 22, 1969, when a river fire captured the attention of Time magazine. This press report helped to spur the environmental movement nationwide and to support the demand for river restoration. In the same way, in 1986, the Sandoz factory in Switzerland caught fire, resulting in a chemical spill in the Rhine, which caused massive fish mortality in all downstream riparian countries down to the Netherlands. Pictures of dead eels shocked the Europeans and stimulated environmental movements. It encouraged public policies in favour of river restoration. Interestingly, in California and in the European Union, salmon were used as flagship species, drawing attention to successful restoration projects. Salmon are a ‘charismatic megafauna’ by virtue of their size, their compelling life history, their gastronomic popularity, and the popularity of salmon fishing (which attracts tourists worldwide, while other species tend to draw attention only locally). Yet this communicating strategy would not have succeeded without political power, provided by intellectual elites (in both California and the EU) with few ties to industry. After World War II, western universities educated more young people than industry could employ. While industrial employees were reluctant to criticize pollution practices bound to their job, the highly 4 educated generation not held by such bonds supported environmental initiatives13. Environmental movements succeeded in changing the law and providing funds to restore rivers. Success stories of river restoration on both sides of the Atlantic probably became popular because they took place in democratic and market-oriented countries. They were used to argue that nothing prevented other western countries from combining economic growth and environmental protection. Today, California’s growing population is significantly composed of white-collar workers becoming more sensitive to environmental issues as they become home owners. They pay more attention to factors that may raise or decrease the value of their assets. Ironically the growing real-estate market largely contributes to the deterioration of the environment. In this context, most inhabitants are happy to find a place to settle but they wish they were the last new-comers. Last, as the EU and the State of California develop rules to protect aquatic biodiversity, they similarly face powerful reluctant actors. Beyond such success stories, aquatic biodiversity is still threatened in both regions. Many fish species are still endangered. Legal innovations and dramatic jurisprudence must be confronted to implementation and results. The enforcement of courts’ decisions and state agencies’ policies mainly depend on local stakeholders who enjoy many opportunities to open gates, pump, divert, discharge water without being effectively controlled. Empirical observations reveal that California and the European Union have much in common in this respect. California and the EU have in common the challenge of dealing with powerful corps of water engineers who are not under their authority and who traditionally promote subsidized uses of water. In California and other western states, large irrigation schemes were built and are still operated by the US Bureau of Reclamation, while navigation and flood control projects have been the purview of the US Army Corps of Engineers, an agency with unusual power and autonomy14. Similarly the EU experiences difficulties interacting with corps of water engineers in countries like France and Spain15. As the main spokesmen of their countries for water management, these corps of engineers are reluctant to transfer prerogatives obtained from a long tradition of centralised water management, paralleling systems used to develop their former colonies. There is neither such a thing as a Californian State corps of engineers nor a European one. In both areas, irrigation is responsible for 80% of water consumption and is supported by public policies serving political coalitions stronger than those defending the environment. In California, the cost of water and energy is subsidized in federal irrigation districts. In the EU, irrigated corn production is subsidized by the Common Agricultural Policy. But at the same time, urban claims for water supply and leisure activities are increasing in both areas, as agriculture weighs less in the overall production and payroll. 13 Mary Douglas and Aaron Wildavsky, Risk and Culture. An Essay on the Selection of Technical and Environmental Dangers (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1982), Henri Mendras, La Seconde Révolution Française 1965-1984 (Gallimard, 1994). 14 Wendy Nelson Espeland, The Struggle for Water: Politics, Rationality, and Identity in the American Southwest (Chicago: University of Chicago press, 1998), Theodore Porter, Trust in Numbers: The Pursuite of Objectivity in Science and Public Life (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1995). 15 Gabrielle Bouleau, "La Gestion Française Des Rivières Et Ses Indicateurs À L'épreuve De La Directive Cadre." (Thèse de doctorat, AgroParisTech - ENGREF, 2007), Erik Swyngedouw, "Modernity and the Production of the Spanish Waterscape, 1890-1930," in Political Ecology. An Integrative Approach to Geography and Environment-Development Studies, ed. Karl S. Zimmerer and Thomas J. Basset (New York: Guildford, 2003). 5 Environmentalists in California and the EU are influential minorities. Both regions are divided by internal linguistic, social and ethnic heterogeneity. It is well acknowledged by political ecologists that social identities strongly influence how nature is perceived and what biological species people desire to preserve. In the EU, the economic gap between wealthy Northern countries and relatively poorer Southern countries matches both the cultural divide between Anglo-Saxon and Latin countries, and between non-irrigated and irrigated lands. Therefore EU’s environmental regulation is broadly understood as imposed by Northern countries to the Southern ones. Similarly, the American environmental movement has always been divided and weakened by opposition between middle-class wilderness lovers and working-class environmental justice activists16. Nowhere in the US is this divide more conspicuous than in California where great natural areas adjoin poor neighbourhoods threatened by industrial hazards17 In both regions, cultural diversity weakens the political legitimacy of environmental claims, because different social groups have different priorities. Yet the federal/international scale historically happened to be strategic arenas for Californian or European Member states’ environmentalists. Last, neither governmental body can rely on stable constituencies to support its agenda, and neither employs large numbers of civil servants to enforce the law. California has a tradition of direct democracy which gives citizens the right to take legislative initiatives, for the worse and the better. In contrast, European citizens encountered huge transaction costs to get heard at the EU level. However no stable coalitions drive the EU legislative process due to uncertain agendas, shifting alliances and mistrust between Member States18. To enforce the law, the EU has no staff in Member States and most water litigations arose from NGOs. In California, the staff in charge of water rights deals mainly with issuing permits (with long delay) and has essentially no time to field-check the reality of uses19. For both entities, public support is critical. They must continuously justify their decisions and the relevance of existing rules as unpredictable challenges arise. Hence the State of California and the EU experience very similar hurdles when they come to try to restore aquatic biodiversity of their rivers. Neither California nor the European Union has its own corps of engineers to forge a unitary environmental management of rivers. Both governmental bodies experience strong internal opposition of irrigators in their attempt to secure more water for aquatic species. Neither can rely on social cohesion to promote environmental values, because social diversity leads to a diversity of environmental expectations. For all these reasons, the power of enforcement and persuasion of the EU and the State of California is similarly fragile. Climatic and social diversity undermines their legitimacy. Strong economic and political institutions do not need innovative legal instruments. Weak institutions looking for public support may be more creative in this domain. California and the EU have largely counted on law to put constraints on water rights, in the name of efficiency and to restore aquatic biodiversity. 16 Gottlieb, Forcing the Spring: The Transformation of the American Environmental Movement. Martha Matsuoka, "Building Healthy Communities from the Ground Up: Environmental Justice in California," (Asian Pacific Environmental Network, Communities for a Better Environment, Environmental Health Coalition, People Organizing to Demand Environmental & Economic Rights, Silicon Valley Toxics Coalition/Health and Environmental Justice Project., 2003). 18 David Earnshaw and David Judge, "No Simple Dichotomies: Lobbyists and the European Parliament," Journal of Legislative Studies 8, no. 4 (2005), Jeremy Richardson, "Eu Water Policy: Uncertain Agendas, Shifting Networks and Complex Coalitions," Environmental Politics 3, no. 4 (1994). 19 Reed D. Benson, "So Much Conflict, yet So Much in Common: Considering the Similarities between Western Water Law and the Endangered Species Act," Natural Resources Journal 44, no. 29 (2004). 17 6 3. Evolution of water regulation in California Many of the western states of the US rejected the riparian doctrine of water law still prevailing in the Atlantic and Midwestern states. California is the exception in that it adopted the “common law of England” when it entered the Union in 1850 and conformed to the American reasonable rule of the riparian doctrine, but it also adopted the prior appropriation system during the 19th century gold rush, and is now governed by both20. In addition, the concept of pueblo rights for cities such as Los Angeles over the nearby rivers was inherited from Spanish colonization21. Thus, unlike a state such as Colorado, where the appropriative rights doctrine always reigned supreme, in California there has always been a competition among different rights and claims. This situation only grew more complicated with the advent of large water transfer projects in the mid-20th century, passage of environmental protection laws, and application of the public trust doctrine to protect environmental values in the late 20th century, and recent efforts to create legal frameworks to transfer water rights from beneficial uses to instream flows for the environment. These diverse doctrines gave rise to piecemeal litigations, and led to more challenges to existing water rights than occurred in other Western states. The state government lacked the legitimacy to favour one water use at the expense of another, but instead sought support from coalitions of powerful actors through shared values such as efficiency. Efficiency nowadays is assessed in reference to a large set of beneficial uses including economic sectorial uses (aquaculture, power generation, irrigation, mining, …), community water needs (fire protection, recreation, municipal uses, …), and environmental requirements (fish and wildlife, maintaining water quality). Since its establishment in 1914, the State Water Board has had the authority to restrict water appropriation through permit process (1) to limit harm suffered by other water rights holders (such as subsidence or water table lowering), (2) to secure the public trust (following the case Audubon National Audubon Society v. Superior court, 1983) and (3) to restore environmental in-stream flows. However, the Board has lacked the political will to exercise its authority22. Existing water rights often exceed what would be a sustainable use with regards to the preservation of aquatic biodiversity. The “use it or lose it” rule is enough to motivate most farmers to put their water rights in use. Moreover, groundwater is unregulated in the state. Rather than treated as a public good connected to rivers through the hydrologic system, groundwater is treated as a private property right that accompanies the land under which it lies, based on a convenient fiction that surface and groundwaters are not connected. Exceptions are certain river basins in which uses have been so intense that the state has recognized that the alluvial aquifers are connected to surface waters, and all uses are adjudicated. Much of the agricultural water used is grow crops with relatively low economic yield per unit water applied. The inconsistency between this situation and the need for waters in the rivers to maintain the aquatic ecosystem and needs for water to support high-value urban uses has 20 Joseph L. Sax et al., Legal Control of Water Resources. Cases and Materials. Fourth Edition, American Casebook Series (St Paul, MN: Thomson West, 2006), 328. 21 W. Kahrl, Water and Power: The Conflict over Los Angeles’ Water Supply in the Owens Valley (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1982). 22 Hanemann, M. and C. Dyckman "The San Francisco Bay-Delta: A Failure of Decision-Making Capacity." Environmental Science and Policy. (forthcoming). 7 motivated the transfer agricultural water rights to instream flow and urban use. The problem has been to find a mechanism with which to do this, given the legal framework of appropriative rights and the ‘use it or lose it’ rule. After five years of drought, in 1991, the California Department of Water Resources (DWR) established a Drought Water Bank, which purchased water from farmers willing to sell it, and resold the water to other users. The price offered was better than returns from farming many crops, so a number of farmers sold their surface water to the Drought Bank. Some fallowed their land, but others took the money for their surface water, pumped groundwater, and continued farming. Another recent innovation is the Water Code section 1707, which permits the transfer or dedication of all or part of existing water right specifically for environmental purposes, so farmers can forego some diversions while maintaining their water rights23. However this provision does not prevent riparian rights holders and downstream appropriators with a senior water right to divert the “dedicated” water. Passage of the federal Clean Water Act (CWA) and the Endangered Species Act (ESA) confounded the complexities of water law in California. While the state of California never had the political legitimacy to impose strong command-and-control legislation, the federal government did. Californian social and environmental activists were largely behind recognition of these issues and building political coalitions supporting passage of the federal legislation24. Under CWA, federal agencies set water quality standards supporting ‘designated’ uses in all US waters, such as fishing, swimming, and, if attainable, biological integrity. Defining water quality standards is the duty of state agencies, but the federal Environmental Protection Agency may promulgate substitutes. In any case, existing uses must be maintained. Environmental agencies may define less stringent objectives to avoid high social and economic costs. CWA conflicts with existing water rights but says little about possible solutions. In addition to its command-and-control functions, federal funds authorized under CWA (with a mandatory 20% state match) support projects to improve water quality under the Water Pollution Control Revolving Fund. The federal Endangered Species Act (ESA) of 1973 protects endangered species and the ecosystems on which they depend. ESA prohibits federal agencies from actions that may cause jeopardy to a listed species and prohibits “take” of any member of a protected species of fish or wildlife, meaning to harm or to degrade its habitat. Neither CWA nor ESA restrict water uses directly and permanently, but represent on-going threats. For example, when the US Fish and Wildlife Service determined that winter-run Chinook salmon and the Delta smelt were affected by large diversions by the Central Valley Project and the State Water Project, a US District Judge imposed short-term curtailments on water deliveries from both projects. The US Bureau of Reclamation and Fish and Wildlife Service frequently clash over issues in California. The leeway for action between these federal agencies consists of revising permits, expanding the scope of consultation for projects and defining procedures of hearings and negotiation. The California Environmental Quality Act (CEQA) of 1970 expanded the scope of federal laws by giving biologists opportunities to challenge plans that otherwise may proceed unnoticed. Thusly, the State of California multiplies opportunities to revise water allocation. 23 Hanemann, M. and C. Dyckman (ibid.). Douglas and Wildavsky, Risk and Culture. An Essay on the Selection of Technical and Environmental Dangers, Espeland, The Struggle for Water: Politics, Rationality, and Identity in the American Southwest, Gottlieb, Forcing the Spring: The Transformation of the American Environmental Movement. 24 8 Another innovation was the CALFED Bay-Delta program, which was launched by federal and state agencies to resolve persistent conflicts over water and environment in the SacramentoSan Joaquin Delta (including curtailment of diversions due to impacts on endangered species). CALFED sought to increase reliability of water supply through increased storage and also through an ecosystem restoration program, which undertook physical actions in river and tidal channels with the aim of increasing populations of key fish species so that their survival would no longer be threatened by losses at the large diversions, and thus eliminating the threat of curtailments of pumping. Unfortunately, the CALFED program lost political support in 2005, was unable to reach an agreement on funding commitments25, and suffered from fundamental weaknesses in institutional structure26. While still extant, the program is much diminished from its former role, and the efforts to develop solutions to the problems of the Sacramento Delta are now concentrated in the Delta Vision program, led by a Task Force appointed by the governor27. There is no clear-cut doctrine firmly establishing water rights in California, as courts have redefined ‘efficiency’, and conflicts among strong economic interests have motivated technological innovations in areas of sharp water conflicts. A relative lack of stream flow and groundwater data weakens enforcement. The beneficial and reasonable use of appropriated waters has clashed with the protection of endangered species under ESA28. Enforcement is difficult, but California opened doors to civil actions under CEQA. A high-profile case study illustrates the evolution of public policy towards water diversions and environmental protection. The waters of the Owens River and Mono Basin in eastern California have been diverted via aqueduct to City of Los Angeles since the first half of the 20th century, effectively drying up some formerly productive streams and causing the level of Mono Lake (a terminal lake) to fall 7m from 1940-198029. The California Fish and Game Code requires that operators of dam and diversions release sufficient water to maintain fish in good condition downstream. However, in the era of the 1940s, there was little public or institutional support to maintain fish at the expense of public water supply, and the City was allowed to dry up Rush Creek. But by the 1980s, went water was released down Rush Creek during wet years, trout re-established themselves in the creek, and environmental NGOs successfully sued to prevent the City from shutting off the flow and killing the fish. Similarly, to save the ecological resources of Mono Lake from excessive water level decline and consequent increased salinity, NGOs successfully sued, leading to the landmark ruling in Audubon case (National Audubon Society vs Superior Court, 1983), which affirmed the applicability of the public trust doctrine to protection of ecological values of waters. The change from the 1940s to the 1980s largely reflects changes in public values, with the rise of 25 Richard Howitt, "Delta Dilemmas: Reconciling Water-Supply Reliability and Environmental Goals," Giannini Foundation of agricultural economics. Agricultural and Resource Economics Update 10, no. 4 (2007), Jay Lund et al., Envisioning Futures for the Sacramento-San Joaquin Delta (San Francisco: Public Policy Institute of California, 2007). 26 Little Hoover Commission, "Still Imperiled, Still Important: The Little Hoover Commission’s Review of the Calfed Bay-Delta Program. Report No.183," (Sacramento, CA. : Little Hoover Commission, 2005). 27 P Isenberg et al., "Our Vision for the California Delta. Report of the Delta Vision Blue Ribbon Task Force," (Sacramento, California, 2008), P. Isenberg et al., "Delta Vision Strategic Plan. Report of the Delta Vision Blue Ribbon Task Force," (Sacramento, California: 2008). 28 Benson, "So Much Conflict, yet So Much in Common: Considering the Similarities between Western Water Law and the Endangered Species Act." 29 Kahrl, Water and Power: The Conflict over Los Angeles’ Water Supply in the Owens Valley, National Research Council, "The Mono Basin Ecosystem: Effects of Changing Lake Level," (Washington: National Academy Press, 1987). 9 environmental concerns motivating application of laws and legal doctrines that existed before, but which had not been enforced or applied. California water laws include ample provisions to restrict existing water rights in order to meet new ecological objectives, but enforcement mainly relies on public participation and NGO lawsuits. 4. Evolution of water regulation in Europe European law challenges European nation-state sovereignty that member states have enjoyed since the Peace of Westphalia30. What happened in France for river management is a good example of this shift. Unlike California, France has a long tradition of centralization, and allocating water was a source of power for the state, and a reflection of its priorities. Efficiency was not considered. During the Middle Age, water rights were part of the “moral economy”. In practice, a “first in place, first in rule” doctrine prevailed. As different political powers claimed sovereignty on water, the conflicting influences provided leeway for villages to use water in mills, canals and ditches31. Community water rights were entrenched into water management structures through written titles, with builders of infrastructure or their heirs as beneficiaries. With development of colonial empires, market competition and the Reform, European sovereigns started to consider the efficient use of natural resources32. King Henri IV claimed that common wetlands abandoned by abbeys during religious wars were vacant, inefficient, and needed development. He appropriated such “vacant” swamps and leased them to Flemish merchants for reclamation projects. Communities lost their properties and water rights. Royal strategy more than comparative effectiveness ruled water allocation. As the Revolution replaced the King’s discretion by the ideology of “public utility”, navigable waterways previously appropriated by kings for trade and water-logging became state’s property, possibly allocated to private parties through leasing. Napoleon’s civil code of 1802 established a riparian doctrine for non-public water-courses in Article 644. But due to the claims of irrigating farmers in the south of France, Article 645 acknowledged former rights to divert water as local custom rights that should be taken into account33. Such water rights “based on titles” were acknowledged to the owners of water structures built during monarchy. France did not adopt an equivalent to the American “beneficial use” doctrine to restrict inefficient water rights, but promoted the “public utility”, which restricts private property in the name of the general interest. Landowners reluctant to invest in reclamation projects deemed to produce higher yields could be expropriated. Since the 19th century, the state has set itself as a master to define “public utility”, advised by a corps of engineers with a monopoly on public expertise34. As industrialization progressed, several Corps of engineers came into being to rule different sectors. Unchallenged by civil society, strongly subjected to internal peer-review processes, each Corps developed its one-best-way to manage water. 30 Hioureas, Christina G., and Bruce E. Cain. "Transatlantic Environmental Regulation-Making: Strengthening Cooperation between California and the European Union." In this volume. 31 Dante Caponera, Principles of Water Law and Administration: National and International (Rotterdam: A.A. Balkema, 1992), Jean-Louis Gazzaniga and Xavier Larrouy-Castera, "Le Droit De L'eau Et Les Droits D'eau Dans Une Perspective Historique," in Histoires D'une Eau Partagée, ed. O. Aubriot and G. Jolly (Provence Alpes Pyrénées. Université de Provence, 2002). 32 Jean-Paul Haghe, "Les Eaux Courantes Et L'etat En France (1789 - 1919). Du Contrôle Institutionnel À La Fétichisation Marchande" (Thèse de doctorat, EHESS, 1998). 33 Alice Ingold, "Les Sociétés D'irrigation : Bien Commun Et Action Collective," Entreprises et histoire, no. 50 (2008). 34 Laurent Cohen Tanugi, Le Droit Sans L'etat (Paris: Quadrige/ Presses Universitaires de France, 1985), Porter, Trust in Numbers: The Pursuite of Objectivity in Science and Public Life, 121. 10 The management of aquatic biodiversity had long focused on trout, and depending on restocking. Chronic pollution was tolerated by the administration, reflecting a prevailing view that society’s needs required that some rivers to be used as sewers35. Losses were compensated for by restocking. Pollution and habitat degradation continued into the 1970s, and by the time water quality improved, irretrievable biodiversity losses had already occurred. The fish protection act (loi pêche 1984) improved instream flows except in the ‘international’ Rhône and the Rhine rivers. With the advent of the European Union, a first wave of European law in water quality (between 1972 and 1986) aimed at protecting consumers’ health through negative and reactive regulation36 limiting activities recognised as harmful and introducing reporting requirements that allowed public scrutiny. Following the 1986 Sandoz chemical spill on the Rhine, there was broad public support to improve the ecological quality of European waters, including an impetus for positive environmental regulations setting water quality standards37: the Urban Waste Water directive, the Nitrate Directive, and the Integrated Pollution Prevention and Control Directive38. The Water Framework Directive (WFD, 2000/60/EC) requires water bodies to achieve ‘Good Ecological Status’ and ‘Good Chemical Status’. ‘Good status’ means compliance with relevant EU water quality standards, and only minor deviation from the natural status of a comparable water body. The WFD addresses the ecological quality of waters for the first time39, promoting systematic planning with uniform, scientific, European-wide river monitoring to distinguish ecological changes from factors such as climate change from human impacts. This landmark legislation considerably limits States’ discretion on water management, with noticeable effects on Member States’ policies. In France, the directive put water quality standard on the political agenda at national level and forced the state to publish more data on the water quality, including maps showing the status of individual parameters. The designation of quality objectives, which was previously under the discretion of the administration, became a political claim. Anticipating unpredictable restrictions in their diversion permits, as more stringent instream flow would be required, power producers joined the water agency tax system to negotiate compensating payments in 2000. Multiple economic studies have been ordered by the state or the basin agencies to value environmental assets and to assess benefits and employment induced by water usages. The state is drafting a method to assess the volume of water available per basin each year to review permits accordingly. Be it governed by kings or elected officials, the French state has long exercised substantial discretion in water allocation. Dramatic changes in land and water uses were mostly initiated or managed by rulers. State politics was never challenged by water problems. Therefore water rights in force do not reflect a shared vision of an optimum allocation, but rather some kind of national heritage with which social actors must cope. Were outsiders to assess effectiveness and efficiency of existing water rights and water management, they would lack information. They would also lack political support, since the state overcame domestic contradictions by Romain Garcier, "Rivers We Can’t Bring Ourselves to Clean – Historical Insights into the Pollution of the Moselle River (France), 1850–2000," Hydrol. Earth Syst. Sci. Discuss., no. 4 (2007). 36 William Howarth, "The Progression Towards Ecological Quality Standards " Journal of Environmental Law 18, no. 1 (2006). 37 Ibid. 38 Aubin and Varone, "European Water Policy. A Path Towards an Integrated Resource Management." 39 Howarth, "The Progression Towards Ecological Quality Standards ". 35 11 implementing costly mitigation policies. Until imposition of the WFD from the European level, river water quality objectives were never designated. 5. Fostering comparison between EU and California water laws in regards to future challenges Aquatic biodiversity in freshwater is primarily threatened by water diversions and their consequences, most of them legally performed. As snow packs shrink and evaporation increases due to climate change, pressures increase on water resources at the river basin level. Instream flows will be required to secure life cycles of aquatic species. This cannot be achieved by other means than curtailing existing water rights for environmental purposes. In this context, clear-cut legal doctrines assuring water allocation defined once and for all are not the best adapted to the situation. On the contrary, juridical systems with overlapping principles requiring interpretations and negotiations are more likely to achieve the needed reallocation. In this respect, the European Union and the US state of California have much to teach. Similarly confronted to powerful stakeholders exercising substantial discretion on water allocation, California and the European Union developed parallel strategies to counter their power. Just as the environmental European law benefited from competition and mistrust between member states, the environmental review required under CEQA offered opportunities for renegotiating water allocation between in California, notably among federal agencies. Despite their institutional differences in level of governance, California and the European Union have much to learn from each other in the area of aquatic biodiversity. To date this institutional gap between California and the EU has limited previous trans-Atlantic exchange to federal agencies (EEA and EPA) with little commitment of the Californian state. As a consequence, such projects have mainly focused on ecoinformatics and have failed to address water rights as a driving force for aquatic biodiversity40. As a conclusion, this section examines what California and the EU have developed in common and what they could learn from each other. First we explain the relevance of their common reference to undisturbed conditions in the face of climate change. This leads us to outline the limitations of the public participation under the European regulation and the lack of provisions to address the specificity of Mediterranean conditions. Then we address the weaknesses of US and California’s law which could benefit from the EU experience in providing comprehensive economic and ecological data. Although the EU celebrates traditional agriculture as a main component of its landscape and biodiversity, it is striking that the water framework directive distinguishes between highly modified water bodies and water bodies which shall achieve a good ecological status defined as minor deviations to undisturbed conditions. The relevance of such a notion has been questioned by European scholars as ecological science increasingly recognizes instability of 40 See for instance, the Agreement for Scientific and Technological Cooperation between the European Community and the Government of the United States of America of 1998 and the Implementing Arrangement between the European Commission and the United States Environmental Protection Agency to Promote Cooperation on Environmental Research and Ecoinformatics of 2007. 12 ecosystems41. But Europeans should look at the American experience in this domain. As proved in the US, the reference to pristine conditions acts as a radical critique that may be useful to fulfil new societal preferences. In 1978, the U.S. Supreme Court declared that the ESA requires that species losses must be stopped “whatever the cost” (TVA v. Hill, 437 U.S. 187). This extreme standpoint proved to be effective in opening public debates in order to reconsider public expectations in regards to ecological objectives. In the face of climate change, the natural variability of ecosystems is going to change. It is crucial then that the public participates to the definition of new ecological objectives. This requires widening the scope of possible futures while economic interests would rather maintain the status quo. ESA and WFD converge in this respect as they require that radical options such as pristine conditions be considered. Public debates also require envisioning situations that resonate in the public mind. In this respect, the EU has much to learn from the vitality of public debates in California. The EU provisions are highly technocratic, using complex language and expert criteria. Biological metrics used to define the good ecological status are highly esoteric for lay people. The WFD is largely unknown by the public. The EU spends a tremendous budget to foster public participation in the implementation of the WFD. The EU could learn from the experience of Californian NGOs in public participation in watershed restoration the significance of charismatic species in building public support for environmental protection. Flagship species and past experiences of recreational uses like bathing, fishing or canoeing resonate much more in the public mind than complex biological metrics. The WFD contains provisions to revise ecological assemblages. Experts are asked to determine deviations appearing in biological samples that can be related purely to variations in climate and geology. CrossEuropean monitoring may help to diagnose such deviations. Experts may be able to change ecological references without major civil oppositions given the existing complexity of the good ecological definition. However, as EU law progresses, suspicion over the lack of democratic control increases. The technocratic provisions of the WFD weaken the social support for its implementation. The WFD requires national protocols to assess ecological quality to be inter-calibrated among Member States. This provision aims to limit discrepancies between States and to set a common measurement of biodiversity comparably fine-grained in the North and South. Yet, biodiversity is not equally distributed among European regions. Mediterranean regions are endowed by much more endogenic species than Northern countries. It is not clear whether such species will be correctly represented in Europe-wide calibrated indicators. More tailored approaches to biodiversity like Natura 2000 and Californian experiences may complement the WFD limitations in this respect. California laws and European directives empowered civil society as a means to counter influential developers. By requiring consultation for all projects subjected to state agency’s approval, CEQA gave opponents more opportunities to voice their claims. Through mandatory reporting, the EU provided citizens with much more information than their domestic states were used to provide, reducing states’ discretion. In both contexts, challenging existing water rights or ineffective water allocation means costly litigations not everybody can afford. However in the European Union, information provided through reporting has a cumulative effect that CEQA does not. It forces member states to operate monitoring systems 41 Howarth, "The Progression Towards Ecological Quality Standards ", Patrick Steyaert and Guillaume Ollivier, "The European Water Framework Directive: How Ecological Assumptions Frame Technical and Social Change," Ecology and Society 12, no. 1 (2007). 13 on a regular basis, providing science and expertise with long-term free available data. California could learn from this as it experiences a dearth of monitoring stations and longterm data bases. Last, but not least the European directive economic requirements will produce a whole set of economic studies in European countries concerning water uses. From this set, scientists and experts worldwide may draw average figures and extrapolate them as proxy to initiate economic assessments in areas where economic performances of water uses remain hardly known. The WFD requires that Member States disclose financial transfers related to water uses in order to assess the cost-recovery of services. It may hamper the further development of highly subsidized projects and simultaneously encourage water-saving technologies. This should not leave the Californian green sector indifferent. The histories of water regulation in California and the EU have much to teach to the US and the rest of the world. While states typically protect property rights, California and the EU are unusual in that their laws submit water rights to the tests of reasonable and beneficial use (California) and to cost-effectiveness (EU). This limitation is not bounded, so one can never be sure that his use will always be reasonable or cost-effective: it will depend on evolving societal values and the context of water use more broadly, including how efficiently others are using water and for what. This “illimited limitation” may provide the flexibility we need to face changing water availability and the lack of certainty of supply that will inevitably come with profound changes in climate. 14