WASHINGTON DC OFFICE 1744 KILBOURNE PLACE, NW WASHINGTON, DC 20010 TEL: 202.588.0632 OAKLAND OFFICE 436 14TH STREET, SUITE 820 OAKLAND, CA 94612 TEL: 510.844.0010 FAX: 510.288.1325 | WWW.THEBREAKTHROUGH. ORG A project of Rockefeller Philanthropy Advisors, Inc., a not-for-profit 501(c)(3)corporation Fast, Clean, & Cheap: Cutting Global Warming’s Gordian Knot © Ted Nordhaus, Michael Shellenberger, Jeff Navin, Teryn Norris, and Aden Van Noppen, 2007 Any citation of this paper must mention that this article will appear in the Harvard Law and Policy Review, January 2008. The authors would like to thank the Nathan Cummings Foundation for generously supporting the research and writing of this article. Fast Clean Cheap 1 Table of Contents I. The Goal: Decouple Energy Consumption from Greenhouse Gas Emissions _____ 4 A. A Pivotal Moment in the History of Energy Consumption ______________________ 4 B. The Urgency of Global Warming ___________________________________________ 5 C. The Real Problem: Lack of Innovation in Energy _____________________________ 6 II. The Failure of the Pollution Paradigm and the Regulation-Centered Approach__ 6 A. Assumptions Behind the Pollution Paradigm _________________________________ 8 B. The Failure of the Regulation-Centered Approach____________________________ 11 1. Obstacles to Innovation _________________________________________________________ 11 2. Regulation-centered approaches to global warming will result in modest, not deep, reductions in carbon emissions. ________________________________________________________________ 13 3. Governments will set a low price for carbon, which will prevent clean energy technologies from becoming cost-competitive. ________________________________________________________ 16 4. Developing nations like China will not sacrifice their economic growth to reduce its emissions. 20 5. Dramatic and rapid technological breakthroughs will not be primarily driven by the private sector. ______________________________________________________________________________ 21 6. There are not sufficient low cost clean energy alternatives. _____________________________ 21 III. Cutting the Knot: Towards an Investment-Centered Paradigm ______________ 23 A. The Case for Public Investment ___________________________________________ 23 B. The Historical Precedent for an Investment-Centered Framework ______________ 25 C. Investment for Tech Innovation to Bring the Cost of Clean Energy Down ________ 27 D. A Policy that Works Politically ____________________________________________ 28 E. The Role of Regulation_____________________________ Error! Bookmark not defined. IV. Specific Recommendations ___________________________________________ 29 A. Establish a carbon price consistent with what present technology can accomplish. _ 29 B. Establish a dedicated source of public funding for clean energy investment that can rapidly drive down the deployed cost of clean energy technologies. _________________ 29 C. Ramp Up: Invest $300 Billion In Research, Development, and Deployment Of Clean Energy Technolologies. _____________________________________________________ 30 D. Insulate federal clean energy investments from pork-barrel politics. _____________ 31 E. Buy down the price of solar like we did with microchips _______________________ 31 F. Play the Field: Make Strategic Investments in Key Energy Sectors and Technologies _________________________________________________________________________ 32 G. Create a framework for global carbon regulation tied to living standards. ________ 33 V. Conclusion ________________________________________________________ 33 Bibliography __________________________________________________________ 34 Fast Clean Cheap 2 Introduction There is a dilemma at the heart of any effort to deal with global warming. If policymakers limit greenhouse gases too quickly, the price of electricity and gasoline will rise quickly, triggering a political backlash from both consumers and industry. But if policymakers limit greenhouse gases too slowly, clean energy alternatives will not become cost-competitive with fossil fuels in time to prevent catastrophic global warming. This dilemma can be understood as a "Gordian Knot," a concept we borrow from the Greek legend. In that ancient story, King Midas used a complicated knot to tie his father’s ox cart to a post. An oracle prophesied that the one who untied the cart, which symbolized Apollo's father, Zeus, would rule the kingdom. For many years the knot stymied many who attempted to untie it. Then, one day, the young Alexander cut the rope with his sword. Alexander went on to become a brilliant military commander and, eventually, King of Macedon. The story is traditionally interpreted to mean that one can often solve seemingly impossible problems with a single and simple bold stroke. But there is an additional moral to the story: one must see old problems in new light in order to find the solution. Alexander saw the problem not as untying the knot but rather as freeing the ox cart from the post. Alexander's new perspective — what is sometimes called a "gestalt shift" — was a prerequisite to cutting the Gordian Knot. And there is an additional meaning to the story. The oracle's prophecy was specifically to untie the knot. In cutting the knot Alexander had to, paradoxically and audaciously, violate the (conventional interpretation of the) oracle's prophesy in order to realize it. We believe that both a gestalt shift and a bold stroke are required to cut the Gordian Knot at the heart of today's energy challenge. Global warming is widely viewed as a problem of pollution, like acid rain, smog and the ozone hole, which can be solved through new pollution limits. But unlike acid rain, smog and the ozone hole, global warming threatens to impact economic development and national security, and to do so at a global level. And whereas dealing with the ozone hole required a simple and inexpensive chemical substitute, global warming demands a totally different way of producing energy. We were able to fight smog without replacing oil. We dealt with acid rain without dismantling our power plants. And we will phase out ozone-depleting chemicals without affecting any of our energy sources. But to deal with global warming, we will need an almost entirely new energy infrastructure. Creating a new energy infrastructure is more comparable to the creation of the railroads, the inter-state highway system, personal computers, the Fast Clean Cheap 3 Internet, the space program, and biomedicines than it is to installing catalytic converters, installing scrubbers, or phasing out ozone-depleting chemicals. In the end, it was impossible — and unnecessary — to untie the Gordian Knot. All that was needed was to free the Ox Cart. What's required in the case of global warming is that we free energy consumption from greenhouse gas emissions, and thus from fossil fuels. Environmentalists have so focused on making dirty energy expensive to make clean energy relatively cheaper, that they overlook that there is a strategy to cut the Gordian Knot by making clean energy cheaper more directly: major investments in technology innovation. The good news is that making the transition from fossil fuels to clean energy will not only avert dangerous levels of global warming, which threatens food and water supplies, especially for the world's most vulnerable people. It will also increase prosperity, strengthen national security, and increase international cooperation. But for this accelerated transition to a clean energy economy to occur, we must first break free from three older ways of thinking and doing things: the politics of limits, the pollution paradigm, and the regulation-centered framework. I. The Goal: Decouple Energy Consumption from Greenhouse Gas Emissions Energy is the lifeblood of every society. Rising energy consumption is strongly correlated with longer life spans and higher quality of life.1 But rising energy consumption has also resulted in rising greenhouse gas emissions and global warming, which threatens to trigger droughts, food shortages, and resource wars. Moreover, America's dependence on fossil fuels has led to expensive and dangerous military entanglements that have compromised America's economic and military security. Given all of this, a top goal for humankind in the 21st Century challenge will be to increase energy consumption so the world's poorest people can climb out of poverty while moving toward more secure, and cleaner, sources of energy. A. Pivotal Moment in the History of Energy Consumption In 2007, human beings consumed roughly 15 terawatts (trillion watts) of energy. Humans will need to produce and consume roughly 60 terawatts of energy annually by 2100 if every human on earth is reach the level of prosperity enjoyed today by the world's wealthiest one billion people.2 Even were economies to become 30 percent more efficient — an increase that few experts believe likely — Fast Clean Cheap 4 the total terawatts needed to bring all of humankind out of poverty would still need to roughly triple by century's end. The case of China quickly puts to rest any idea that greenhouse gases can be regulated away by making dirty energy more expensive. This year China passes the U.S. as the largest emitter of greenhouse gas emissions.3 By 2050, the contributors of emissions in order will be China at 25 percent, U.S. at 15 percent, India at 11 percent, and EU at nine percent.45 The Energy Information Administration (EIA) predicts that, under a business as usual ("BAU") scenario, global emissions will grow 75 percent from 2003 until 2030, an increase of about 2.1 percent every year.6 China's emissions will grow 4.2 percent annually – double the global average. The EIA estimates that, between 2004 and 2012, China, India, and the United States will build over 850 coal power plants which will put more than five times as much carbon dioxide into the atmosphere as the Kyoto protocol aims to reduce. Over 550 of those plants will be built in China.7 Coal provides about 70 percent of China’s energy, and China builds roughly one new coal-fired power plant every week.8 China’s total coal-related emissions are projected to increase by 232% between 2004 and 2030. 9 Total cumulative global emissions between 2003 and 2050 will be roughly 2,353 billion tons of CO2 emissions.10 America's cumulative CO2 emissions between 2003 and 2050 will be 341 billion metric tons while China's will be 451 billion.11 China has repeatedly made it clear that it will not restrict its emissions without an economic reason to do so. Thus, the only way to achieve a rapid, inexpensive, and quick transition to clean energy in China is to satisfy the public’s desire and the government’s need for rising security, stability, and economic growth. This is not to say that the Chinese government will never agree to emissions limits or a tax on carbon. But any agreement to do so will need to be in China’s economic interests. The present moment is extraordinarily important because once China, India, and other developing nations have built their coal-fired infrastructure, it will become extremely expensive and complicated to shift them to cleaner fuels — unless those cleaner fuels are cheap. The urgency of this point can not be stressed enough. Failure to make clean energy available as soon as possible for use by countries such as China may result in catastrophic global warming by the second half of the 21st Century. B. The Urgency of Global Warming Fast Clean Cheap 5 There is today an emerging international consensus that greenhouse gas emissions (the bulk of which are carbon dioxide) must be reduced by roughly 80 percent in the developed world, and 50 percent worldwide, by 2050 if we are to avoid dangerous levels of global warming (Stern Review, 2006; United Nations IPCC, 2007). During the 20th Century, total atmospheric carbon dioxide increased from roughly 270 to 370 parts per million (ppm). Total atmospheric carbon will pass 550 ppm by 2100 if nothing is done to change today's energy trajectory. Many scientists believe that total atmospheric carbon dioxide must be stabilized at between 450 ppm and 550 ppm if we are to avoid catastrophic global warming impacts. C. The Real Problem: Lack of Innovation in Energy The central obstacle to achieving universal prosperity through clean energy is that energy is the least innovative sector of the economy. Coal has been in widespread use for 150 years, and oil for 80. Our houses, cars, clothes, communications, and consumer technologies have all improved dramatically over the last century, but our energy sources have not. While the price of solar energy has declined 20 percent with every doubling of its production, it remains between three to fifty times more expensive than coal and natural gas in most of the world. Moreover, clean energy technologies such as solar and wind cannot become anything more than supplemental energy sources until there are improvements to battery and storage technologies, improvements to the grid, and new transmission lines. For thirty years elites in both the developed and developing world have recognized serious national security, environmental, and economic problems created by our dependence on fossil fuels, and yet our dependence on them has only increased. While some view this as a problem of the fossil fuel industry's corruption of the political process, the central problem is that fossil fuels are today still far cheaper than cleaner forms of energy, and thus offer more rapid prosperity for economies seeking growth, whether the U.S., Europe or China. For clean energy to become cost-competitive with fossil fuels ("dirty energy"), a new global politics focused on national security and economic development is required. II. The Failure of the Pollution Paradigm and the Regulation-Centered Approach Carbon dioxide is unlike traditional air pollutants. Unlike smog, it is invisible and does not stink. It is naturally occurring and is the lifeblood of the earth’s vegetation. And unlike carbon monoxide and ozone-depleting chemicals, it cannot be easily replaced. Fast Clean Cheap 6 The differences between greenhouse gases and other pollutants doom regulatory efforts to failure. There is an economic reason and a political reason for this. The economic reason is that emissions trading systems direct private investment toward the least expensive emissions reductions. It does not direct investments toward newer, more expensive, but potentially disruptive clean energy technologies, such as solar energy and carbon capture and storage (CCS). Under future emissions trading regimes, managers of firms will have an economic incentive to purchase emissions credits as cheaply as possible, such as from projects that burn methane from landfills, purchase forest land for sequestration, buy wind energy, or make plants and buildings more efficient. The problem is that very little of the 80 percent reductions in greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions can be achieved through these inexpensive technologies alone. Another economic and technical problem with the regulation-centered approach is that many of the new technologies that are crucial to the creation of a new clean energy economy -- such as new transmission lines and ways to store solar and wind power -- will not receive investment capital from emissions trading because they do not directly lead to reduced emissions. The political reason that regulatory-only approaches — whether renewable portfolio standard (RPS), cap and trade, or a carbon tax — cannot approach large-scale emissions reductions is because their success depends on doing something highly unpopular with the public, industry, and elites alike: raising the price of energy. New energy regulations will increase the cost of gasoline and electricity and everything else that requires energy for its production, from food to homes to consumer products. Many industries — from building to transportation to retail to manufacturing — not just energy industries, may have genuine reason to fear and oppose price increases. Political realities make it likely that emissions regulations will be repealed or weakened by Congress or, more likely, enforcement agencies (e.g., the Environmental Protection Agency). The most likely scenario is that legislation capping and allowing for the trading of emissions will pass, but that it will set the price of carbon far below what is required for clean energy to become cost-competitive and widely adopted so that emissions can be reduced on the order of 80 percent by 2050. If carbon is priced inaccurately due to political considerations, then the central assumption of the regulation-centered framework –- that industry will find the optimal solution once it is forced to absorb the costs of its externalities -- breaks down. The regulation-centered framework therefore creates a Gordian Knot. If government prices carbon high enough, either through an emissions cap or a tax, to make currently expensive clean energy solutions, including solar and carbon capture, cost competitive, then energy prices will rise dramatically and will likely trigger a popular, industry, and elite backlash. But if government prices carbon too low, private sector investments will flow almost exclusively to inexpensive Fast Clean Cheap 7 emissions reductions, such as efficiency, rather than to potentially breakthrough –- if currently expensive –- technologies, such as clean energy and carbon capture and storage. The Gordian Knot is not an argument per se against emissions trading, carbon taxes, or other measures that raise the cost of energy. Rather it is an argument against the regulation-centered approach. Without large public benefits — such as lower prices for clean energy, energy independence, new jobs, and economic growth — the regulation-centered approach cannot succeed in raising the price of dirty energy high enough to make clean energy cost-competitive. A. Assumptions Behind the Pollution Paradigm It is tempting to look at greenhouse gases as just another air pollutant, and global warming as just another pollution problem. After all, greenhouse gases come from the same place as other pollutants, they are gases like other pollutants, and their principal impacts are environmental, just like other pollutants. Just last Term, for example, the Supreme Court examined the definition of an air pollutant under the Clean Air Act and held that greenhouse gases obviously fit the definition.12 Given all this, the vast majority of public policy proposals aimed at global warming treat GHG emissions like any other pollutant: the proposals focus on regulation, from carbon caps and emissions trading, to renewable portfolio standards (RPS) mandating that utilities use clean energy sources to produce a certain percentage of their output, to taxes on carbon. The regulation-centered approach treats the challenge centrally as a) limiting emissions and b) increasing the cost of dirty energy, rather than lowering the cost of clean energy. Part of the appeal of the regulation-centered approach lies in its mathematical elegance: to reduce emissions by 80 percent by 2050, the logic goes, we need simply to set a cap on emissions that is then reduced annually at a fixed rate (e.g., two percent per year). Another appealing aspect of the regulation-centered approach is that it worked well in dealing with acid rain in the United States, and the widening ozone hole due to CFC emissions internationally. Last year, the world celebrated the 20th Anniversary of the international treaty that phased out ozone-destroying chemicals. For environmentalists, the Montreal Protocol was a model for action on global warming. In the words of David Doniger, the climate director of the Natural Resources Defense Council, "The lesson from Montreal is that curbing global warming will not be as hard as it looks."13 Fast Clean Cheap 8 And indeed, when one looks back at the pollution problems of old, none of them were as hard or as expensive to solve as the affected industries claimed they would be. Scrubbers on smokestacks, catalytic converters on cars, lead out of gasoline, and alternatives to ozone-depleting chemicals — these technical fixes came at a very low cost to the economy, industry, and consumers. The same will be true, environmentalists say, when it comes to global warming. All the alternatives we need — efficiency, conservation, renewables, sequestration, and even nuclear — already exist. We just need to scale them up. Sure, global warming is a bigger problem, they acknowledge. But it will be solved just like we solved acid rain: by auctioning emissions permits and allowing firms to trade them. To reduce U.S. emissions by 80 percent between 2010 and 2050, we simply need to reduce the total allowable emissions by two percent each year. By limiting the amount of emissions each year, and auctioning or giving away a limited number of emissions permits to firms, governments will effectively create a price for carbon dioxide emissions. This price will create value for reducing emissions, and the free market — firms trading emissions permits for emissions reductions — will find the most efficient way to reduce our greenhouse gases by 80 percent by 2050. And as dirty energy sources like coal and oil become more expensive, clean energy sources will become cost-competitive and more widely used. Emissions trading is regarded as an efficient way for firms and the economy to reduce overall GHG emissions because it taps the collective intelligence of private investors and firms and avoids problems associated with having the government “pick winners and losers” in the marketplace. Emissions capping and trading works by giving firms a certain number of permits to pollute, a number that is then reduced in subsequent years. For example, during the first year of a cap and trade regime a coal-fired power plant could be given a permit equivalent to 100 percent of its existing emissions. In order to achieve an 80 percent reduction over a 40-year period, from 2010 to 2050, the plant would receive a progressively smaller emission permit each year until its emissions were, in 2050, 20 percent of what they were in 2010. With emissions trading, firms could choose to take measures to reduce their overall emissions directly, by purchasing clean energy or adopting efficiency measures, or they could purchase their emissions reductions from firms that decrease their emissions beyond what is required by law and thus have credits to sell on the open market. In the case of acid rain, a 1990 amendment to the Clean Air Act capped the amount of allowable sulfur and other emissions from coal-fired power plants that were causing acid rain, and allowed the credits for emissions to be traded on in the marketplace. This “cap and trade” mechanism was overwhelmingly Fast Clean Cheap 9 successful in reducing sulfur emissions and came to be viewed as a model for reducing carbon emissions. Economists overwhelmingly favor clear and consistent incentives for firms. Energy and environmental economists favor solutions that "internalize" into prices the external "costs" of things like disasters, drought, forest fires, disease, higher sea levels, and war caused by global warming and oil dependency. These approaches all effectively establish a price for carbon. Once a price is established for carbon, the thinking goes, the most cost-effective and efficient low-carbon alternatives will emerge from the free, albeit newly constrained, marketplace. All of these assumptions lead to the conclusion that action on global warming demands raising energy costs and thus changing the behavior of firms and consumers. The regulation-centered model also assumes that new government regulations are more politically viable than new government investments. The new Democratic Congress, sensitive to charges that the Democratic Party is the party of “big government” and “tax and spend liberals,” adopted in early 2007 a “payas-you-go” rule that requires that all new public investment and spending to be paid for by new sources of revenue. Republicans, for their part, have shown a willingness to make large public investments into national security and old energy sources, but maintain a discourse against public spending, including against spending on renewable energy. The political assumption among regulation-centered advocates is that while cap and trade will increase energy costs both for consumers and producers, it will do so gradually over many decades, and imperceptibly. This pollution regulation framework offered by environmentalists for dealing with global warming is thus, for many policymakers, a reassuring one. For 15 years it has provided policymakers, the media, and the public with a mental model for understanding how such a massive problem like climate change could be solved in an organic way by the market, perhaps the most powerful institution ever created by human beings. There's just one problem: it won't work. Fast Clean Cheap 10 B. The Failure of the Regulation-Centered Approach 1. Obstacles to Innovation Energy is arguably the least innovative sector of the economy. The two dominant energy sources, coal and oil, have been in widespread use since the midnineteenth century and early twentieth centuries, respectively. There are several reasons specific to energy for this lack of innovation. Any strategy to spur public investment and technological growth must consider and respond to these concerns. The first is it takes decades before new energy sources become profitable. Energy production is what analysts call “lumpy,” requiring of large power plants and investments. Energy companies and investors are thus deterred from spending much of their revenue on risky, innovative, and costly ventures without government regulation or incentive to reduce their risks. Private firms tend to be focused on generating returns in the short term (~5 – 10 years) and not the long term (~10 – 30 years). Renewable resources such as wind and solar depend on the vagaries of the weather, and most electricity systems are not set up to take advantage of their incremental nature. National electric grids are tailored for large, centralized plants. Many renewable electricity sources, such as wind, are located far from current power lines, and their integration faces regulatory and technical challenges. “As a result, the electricity system is operated inefficiently and wind, solar and wave selling their output in the general energy market receive lower than justified prices” (Neuhoff 2005: 9). Moreover, the transportation infrastructure is geared to oil. Alternatives like biofuels or hydrogen depend on public investment in public infrastructure (Grubb 2004). Meanwhile, the comparatively small scale of renewable projects makes the cost of regulatory compliance relatively more expensive than larger projects (Neuhoff 2005: 11) One dramatic related consequence of the lumpy nature of energy production is “technological lock-in,” the second obstacle to energy innovation. The classic example is QWERTY keyboard. More efficient layouts for faster typing exist, but none have been able to gain foothold. Other examples include the Windows operating system, sometimes criticized by computer programmers as a technologically inferior platform. In the case of energy, the dominant energy sources -- coal, gasoline, and natural gas -- continue to exist, in part, because they are "locked-in." These older technologies benefit from a range of factors, from lower adoption cost to lower production cost than newer, cleaner energy sources (Neuhoff 2005, 12). Fast Clean Cheap 11 These old energy sources are also locked in politically: fossil fuel industries have proven adept at controlling the political process through campaign contributions, media and advertising campaigns to influence elite opinion, and other forms of lobbying all aimed at locking older energy in and newer technologies out. Of the roughly $33 billion invested each year into clean-energy technological deployment (an amount that includes nuclear) is, in the words of the Stern Review, “dwarfed by the existing subsidies for fossil fuels worldwide that are estimated at $150 billion to $250 billion each year” (Stern 2006). Third, energy is a commodity, and so there is little to no product differentiation for newer, cleaner, and more technologically-advanced energy sources like solar and wind. Whereas pharmaceutical and high-tech companies have an incentive to invest heavily in R&D to invent new products, the energy sector will sell the same product — electrons — in 2100 that it sold in 1900. While there has been some very modest success selling “green power” to consumers, no serious expert believes that demand for green power will be anything more than negligible in determining future energy sources (Neuhoff, 2005: 19, EWEA, 2004). Cell phones, handheld digital devices, and laptops were all built on public investment, but they quickly became self-driven because they have high consumer demands for innovation. Niche markets of consumers want more sophisticated versions of these products, as proven by the 700,000 consumers who purchased the $600 iPhone in one weekend.14 By contrast, very few people are willing to pay more for low-carbon rather than for high carbon electricity. Fourth, in contrast to consumer electronics and pharmaceuticals, it is difficult for energy companies to capture their innovations through the patenting process. Pharmaceutical companies can invest roughly 15 percent of their revenue on R&D to develop new drugs because they can confidently patent specific drugs and benefit from a market monopoly for a certain number of years. By contrast, “it is far harder to define engineering patents in ways that cannot be circumvented over time, and renewable energy technologies consist of a large set of components and require the expertise of several companies to improve the system” (Neuhoff 2005, 14). One recent review of the literature finds that firms are often unable to capture the value of their investments because the knowledge and learnings from R&D “spills over” to benefit other firms, creating a free rider problem that acts as a disincentive to private investment in R&D by private firms (Nemet 2007: 5) Fifth, public investments in energy R&D are very low and have declined for 20 years, due to the declining cost of oil in 80s and 90s, the absence of an effective national lobby for clean energy, the "policy lock-in" of the pollution paradigm and regulation-centered approaches to energy, and other factors. Public investment in energy research and development in the United States dropped from an already modest $8 billion in 1980 to $3 billion in 2005 (in 2002 dollars). Fast Clean Cheap 12 Private venture capital during the same period dropped from $4 billion in 1980 to a paltry $1 billion in 2005 (Kammen 2006). This uncertainty is compounded by the volatility of public energy investment policy and tax incentives. Private investment is greatly driven by expectations about government action, whether regulation or investments, in the future. Past energy policy has created the perception among energy investors that “what the government giveth, the government taketh away” (Nemet, 2007). In wind, for example, the average duration for incentive programs over the past thirty years is merely 3.1 years, and overall energy R&D funding levels increased by a factor of three within five years and were cut in half over the next five years. As a result, there has been a decline in energy patents, which with the exception of nuclear fission, are well correlated with declining investments into R&D (Nemet 2007: 42). 2. Regulation-centered approaches to global warming will result in modest, not deep, reductions in carbon emissions. This is due to a combination of technical, economic, and political constraints. Technically, there simply does not yet exist the low cost, low carbon technologies that could be quickly brought to scale to replace carbon intensive energy sources. The environmentalist line that "we just need to scale up existing technologies" is only partly true.15 It is true that some strategies for reducing emissions, such as efficiency and conservation, can be scaled up immediately. But technologies like solar and carbon capture and storage are still far more expensive than coal and gas. Pricing carbon at $35 – 100/ton — whether through cap and trade or carbon taxes — can help us to get part of the way there. Carbon at those prices will drive investments into efficiency and conservation, and will create incentives for energy providers to build gas-fired rather than coal-fired plants. These measures could result in emissions reductions on the order of roughly 20 – 30 percent by mid-century — but only in the United States, not necessarily at a global level. To achieve major reductions on the order of 80 percent in the U.S., and 50 percent globally, we will need to replace coal and oil as energy sources almost entirely. And that will require dramatic technology breakthroughs to bring down the price of clean alternatives. Economically, the price of carbon dioxide would have to be set at exorbitant levels for today's clean energy alternatives to become cost-competitive with coal, gas and oil. The IPCC estimates that establishing a global carbon price of $184/ton16 — a figure five times higher than what most legislation being considered by the U.S. Senate would set it at — would still only result in a reduction of global carbon emissions by 20 – 38 percent by 2030. To reduce Fast Clean Cheap 13 greenhouse gases by 90 percent by 2050 in the United States through regulation alone, carbon would have to priced at around $300 dollars/ton between 2010 and 2030, and at a whopping $600 - 800/ton between 2030 and 2050. To gain a sense of the impact this would have on consumers, not to mention the economy as a whole, consider that carbon priced at $700/ton would increase the price of coalgenerated electricity in the U.S. two and a half times.17 Reducing carbon emissions by 80 percent worldwide through regulatory limits alone would require setting a very high price for carbon. For carbon capture and storage to become economically viable, carbon would have to be priced between $100 - 200/ton.18 For solar photovoltaic to become cost-competitive without other subsidies, carbon would have to be priced at over $800/ton, according to U.S. EIA (Table 1). Fast Clean Cheap 14 Table 1: Price Carbon Must Reach to Make Clean Energy Alternatives CostCompetitive with Coal in the United States. Carbon Pricing Scenarios, 2010 Coal (Pulverized) Solar Photvoltaic [1] Wind Solar Thermal [2] Fuel Cell Biomass [3] Geothermal Hydroelectric [4] Conventional Nuclear Advanced Nuclear Cents per kWh, 2010 [5] Price of Price above carbon to coal compete (cents/kWh) with coal [6] Price of CO2 necessary to compete with coal 4.84 0.00 $0.0 0 25.83 6.67 20.99 1.23 $807.3 $47.3 $219.97 $12.89 14.22 17.96 5.88 6.19 8.78 12.52 0.44 0.75 $337.7 $481.5 $16.9 $28.8 $92.01 $131.21 $4.61 $7.86 6.44 1.00 $38.5 $10.48 n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a [1] Central Station Generator [2] Central Station Generator [3] Integrated Gasification Combined Cycle [4] Conventional [5] EIA AEO 2007 Levelized Generation costs for 2010 [6] $100 per ton price on carbon results in price increase of $0.026 per kWh of coal electricity (Table created by authors based on EIA data 2007) Fast Clean Cheap 15 Politically, if action on global warming depends on voters and politicians accepting higher energy prices, there will be very few results. That's because voters consistently rank global warming dead last as a priority — and just as consistently rank rising gasoline and electricity prices as a top concern. Understandably, then, politicians care more about keeping energy prices low than they do about global warming. 3. Governments will set a low price for carbon, which will prevent clean energy technologies from becoming cost-competitive. Tradable pollution limits and a price for carbon could result in some emissions reductions — just not reductions approaching anything close to 80 percent in the U.S. or 50 percent worldwide. Recognizing that voters care more about the cost of energy than global warming, most policies under consideration in Congress would price carbon at around $25 – 55/ton. At that low price, private investment will flow toward the least expensive emissions reductions, such as burning methane from landfills, purchasing forest land for carbon sequestration, shifting from coal to natural gas, or retrofitting power plants and buildings so they operate more efficiently. It may also direct investments toward wind, though wind faces expansion obstacles from the lack of transmission lines between windy rural areas and cities. Firms seeking to comply with the law will work to get the most emissions reductions for the least amount of money. Thus, private investment will not, for the most part, flow toward technologies like solar energy and carbon capture and storage, which are currently more expensive but which need to receive major investment for costs to come down. This problem is consistent with past experience in Europe and the U.S. Europe implemented an emissions trading regime to fulfill its obligations under the Kyoto Protocol, with disappointing results. California’s experience demonstrates how rapidly political opposition to aggressive environmental regulations can gut them. And the American political experience shows conclusively that Americans, in particular, are unwilling to accept high energy costs. a. Lessons from Europe The European emissions trading scheme (ETS) is the largest multinational emissions trading system and it is a central piece of the European Union’s strategy to meet its Kyoto targets. It was designed to reduce emissions from large industrial and stationary sources and accounts for approximately 40 to 45 percent of the EU’s total carbon dioxide emissions, according to the EIA. Polluters are allowed to buy and sell permits according to their needs. The goal is to reduce total emissions by allocating a scarce number of permits whose rising Fast Clean Cheap 16 price will encourage firms to abate emissions rather than pay to pollute. The ETS requires individual country governments to set their own National Allocation Plan and give away permits to polluting industry. The ETS has not achieved its goal of significantly reducing the EU’s emissions because European governments issued too many permits to polluters. In 2006 more than 90 percent of the industrial plants covered by the EU's trading scheme were given a pollution allowance above their levels of emissions (Guardian 2007). The result was a collapse in the price for carbon, which reached a high of €30 per ton in April 2006 before plummeting to €10 per ton the following month. At that low price, few clean energy technologies will become cost competitive. Europe's challenges were the consequence not of technical errors but rather of reluctance on the part of government officials to raise energy costs to levels that might hurt domestic industries or slow economic growth. Already some European businesses, such as cement manufacturers, say that high energy prices have put them at a disadvantage relative to foreign competitors. This will continue to be a problem until the developing world prices its carbon. Therein lies another aspect of the Gordian Knot. Developed nations will be reluctant to price carbon too high, fearing a competitive disadvantage for domestic firms relative to firms who operate in countries that do not restrict greenhouse gas emissions. And even if developing nations like China and Brazil do one day set a price for carbon, they will face the same Gordian knot as developed nations. Investments will flow to areas that deliver the greatest emissions reductions for the dollar, which also happen to be some of the least promising in the long-term. b. Lessons from California California is regarded as a leader in environmental regulation and laws aimed at accelerating the adoption of clean energy technology. However, the implementation of these regulation-centered approaches has been mixed at best. California’s Renewable Portfolio Standard has so far failed to meet its targets. The state’s investor-owned utilities (IOUs) will likely not meet their 2010 target of 20 percent renewables, in part because the IOUs will in many cases find it cheaper to pay a penalty of 5 cents per kWh, which cannot exceed $25 million per utility per year — an amount that is, in one analyst's words, “a small price to pay relative to the cost of developing, building and operating renewables technologies [especially] since the annual revenues of the state’s three IOUs in 2006 were $35 billion (Nemet 2007: 212). California also demonstrates the Gordian Knot in the realm of ballot initiative politics. In July 2006, California voters indicated to pollsters their willingness to tax oil production to invest in clean energy alternatives.19 But just three months Fast Clean Cheap 17 later they voted against proposition 87 by a 10-point margin. Focus groups with swing voters in December 2006 revealed that even voters who strongly support clean energy and are concerned about global warming simply did not want to pay more for gasoline.20 The failure to properly enforce regulation-centered laws signals to business that the regulatory climate remains uncertain, and thus discourages firms from making large investments. Nemet points to the California mandate in 1990 that required that 10 percent of all vehicles sold in the state in 2003 be zero emissions. After automobile manufacturers sued California, the California Air Resources Board repealed the Zero Emissions Vehicles (ZEV) Mandate. Such actions, worries one analyst, “may be especially pernicious, in terms of creating incentives for innovation, because it suggests that policies can change not only due to the vagaries of political priorities, but also because potential innovators decide that lobbying and litigating to soften government imposed targets may be a more effective use of their resources than investing innovation to meet them” (Nemet 2007: 214-215). c. Lessons from National Politics. Voters today may be more anxious about energy prices than they have been in the last 25 years. When USA Today/Gallup asked how important gas prices are to someone’s vote for Congress in October of 2006, 90 percent of voters said it was at least moderately important, and 34 percent of respondents called gas prices “extremely important" (USA Today/Gallup 2006). Voters thus oppose efforts to increase the federal gas tax and elected officials can be expected to resist public policy initiatives that will result in increased gas prices. A CBS News/New York Times poll reported in April 2007 that 58 percent of Americans oppose an increase in the federal gas tax. In an April 2006 Gallup poll, 64 percent of Americans supported suspending all federal gasoline taxes. Gallup even found that 70 percent favored government price controls on fuel prices, one of the highest forms of government regulation. Americans specifically say they do not want to pay more for electricity or gasoline. When asked if the federal government should increase taxes on electricity or gasoline to encourage conservation, Americans overwhelmingly rejected the approach. A March 2006 ABC News/Washington Post Poll found that 81 percent of voters oppose increasing taxes on electricity, and 68 percent oppose increasing taxes on gasoline, to encourage conservation. Those numbers actually went up, despite expensive national and local media attention about global warming (the previous numbers were 79 and 67 percent respectively) (ABC News/Washington Post, 2006, 2007). Fast Clean Cheap 18 The lesson some have drawn from these experiences is that advocates must engage in public education efforts so that the voters care more about global warming than energy prices. However, there is no evidence that such a strategy is viable. Efforts to increase the public's concern with global warming as an issue have largely been unsuccessful. Public awareness reached a new high in the summer of 2006 with the publicity around Al Gore’s “An Inconvenient Truth.” The Pew Center for People and the Press21 conducted a telephone survey of 1,501 adults between June 14 and June 19, 2006, a period timed to coincide with the high point of the media’s interest in Gore’s movie. By far the most significant finding was that the movie had done virtually nothing to increase the saliency of global warming among voters. Pew researchers noted that “out of a list of 19 issues, Republicans rank global warming 19th and Democrats and Independents rank it 13th.”22 While 41% say global warming is a very serious problem, 33% see it as somewhat serious and roughly a quarter (24%) think it is either not too serious or not a problem at all. Consequently, the issue ranks as a relatively low public priority, well behind education, the economy, and the war in Iraq. By January 2007, global warming’s relative importance actually declined to 21st out of 21 issues for Republicans, 17th out of 21 issues for Democrats, and 19th out of 21 issues for independents.23 4. Setting a price for carbon is insufficient. Most energy experts do not believe a carbon price is enough. "Getting those new technologies on line will require more than price signals because no company on its own will invest in the necessary speculative and costly research and development concepts,” wrote Victor and Cullenward. "Ultimately, the belief that prices alone will solve the climate problem is rooted in the fiction that investors in large-scale and long-lived energy infrastructures sit on a fence waiting for higher carbon prices to tip their decisions. In fact, many factors stifle the implementation of novel low-carbon policies" (Victor and Cullenward 2007) It is for this reason that everyone from the Stern Review to the IPCC calls for major public investment. "[T]he presence of a range of other market failures and barriers mean that carbon pricing alone is not sufficient," the Stern Review concluded. "Technology policy, the second element of a climate change strategy, is vital to bring forward the range of low-carbon and high-efficiency technologies that will be needed to make deep emissions cuts." (Stern Review 2006: 308) Socolow and Pacala, who are frequently cited in justification for regulationcentric policies, agree. "But a price on CO2 emissions on its own may not be enough. Governments may need to stimulate the commercialization of low- Fast Clean Cheap 19 carbon technologies to increase the number of competitive options available in the future" (Socolow and Pacala 2006). This kind of public investment will both drive the early stage innovation and commercialization the private sector will by and large not engage in and draw in greater private investment to commercialize and bring those technologies to scale. MIT's John Deutsch writes, "Government support of innovation – both technology creation and technology demonstration – is desirable to encourage private investors to adopt new technology… Virtually every energy study recommends that the federal government mount technology research, development, and demonstration (R, D, & D) programs that require large and sustained budgetary support, of course, funded by the taxpayer." 5. Developing nations like China will not sacrifice their economic growth to reduce their emissions. High carbon prices would translate into dramatic increases in the price of energy and everything else that requires energy (which is to say, virtually everything). Given that increasing energy use and consumption are highly correlated with longer life spans and higher living standards in developing nations, a high carbon price would represent a major obstacle to economic development for poor countries. Environmental leaders insist that once the U.S. acts, so will China. They point to the fact that Chinese firms are earning billions selling emissions reductions to European firms, thus giving China a stake in the success of global emissions trading. Moreover, China is genuinely worried about global warming. Nevertheless, there is no reason to believe that if China does eventually set a price for carbon it will set it high enough price — at say $100 - $200/ton — for carbon capture and storage facilities to become cost-competitive. Doing so would dramatically slow the rapid climb that hundreds of millions of Chinese are making out of poverty. But even if the Chinese government were to set a high price for carbon as early as 2030, China will have already constructed hundreds of coal-fired power plants — few of which will be compatible with carbon capture and storage plans. In the end, the only way the Chinese government will be able to substantially reduce its emissions is if the price of clean energy and carbon capture technologies come down enough to get within striking distance of the price of fossil fuels — with or without a price for carbon. Fast Clean Cheap 20 6. Dramatic and rapid technological breakthroughs will not be primarily driven by the private sector. Private firms will play an important role in bringing new technologies to market — and carbon pricing will play an important role in making market conditions more amenable to clean energy technologies. However, private firms will not make the large, long-term investments in R&D and deployment, nor can they create the public infrastructure (e.g., new transmission lines) needed for the new energy economy. The energy sector is unlike the pharmaceutical, software, and computer sectors. Energy R&D requires far larger sums of investment capital than are required for other technologies, which helps explain why energy remains one of the least innovative sectors of the economy (coal and oil being very old fuel sources). Unlike those other industries, it is extremely difficult for energy firms to protect their patents against reverse engineering. And even pharmaceutical, software, computer and Internet industries all depended in their formative decades on large-scale government investments in education, infrastructure, and R&D. 7. There are not sufficient low cost clean energy alternatives. When people say that “we already have all the alternative energy technologies we need,” what they mean is that we have invented technologies that can produce energy without emitting carbon. This is true only insofar as these technologies exist, have been demonstrated in laboratory settings, and in the case of things like solar panels, have been deployed over a number of years at a relatively small scale. Other technologies, such as carbon capture and storage, are at an even earlier stage of development. What we have not yet succeeded in doing is producing clean energy technologies at costs low enough to deploy widely such that they might actually represent a real alternative to cheap, high-carbon conventional energy sources. "Many of the technologies needed are already available or close to commercialization," the International Energy Agency wrote in a major report last year. "But it will require substantial effort and investment by both the public and private sectors for them to be adopted by the market… Urgent action is needed to stimulate R&D, to demonstrate and deploy promising technologies, and to provide clear and predictable incentives for low carbon options and diverse energy sources" (Mandil/IEA 2006: 3) When we say “breakthrough” technologies, what we are referring to are breakthroughs in the performance of current clean energy technologies and the cost of deploying them. Without these breakthroughs, the costs of these technologies are too high, and their performance and return on investment too low, to justify private sector investment in their widespread deployment. This Fast Clean Cheap 21 will likely be the case even with the higher carbon prices that the many proposals currently being considered in the U.S. Congress would establish. Moreover, even dramatically improving the performance of clean energy alternatives and decreasing their price relative to conventional energy sources will not be sufficient, alone, to see them widely deployed. Clean energy alternatives like solar and wind will require significant improvement in the cost and performance of battery and other energy storage technologies and probably a new electricity grid as well, in order to be deployed at levels that might allow them to displace conventional energy sources on a large scale. Given the likelihood of low to non-existent prices for carbon in the developing world for many decades to come, the technology challenge will require that we very quickly drive the deployed price of low carbon alternative energy technologies not just down to levels at which they are competitive in energy economies with relatively high carbon prices, but down to levels wherein the real cost of those technologies are cost competitive with coal in developing economies with very low (or nonexistent) carbon prices. It is for this reason that we argue that, in the end, the most important objective of our efforts to address the climate crisis are to drive the real, deployed costs of clean energy technologies dramatically downward as quickly as possible. Fast Clean Cheap 22 III. Cutting the Knot: Towards an Investment-Centered Paradigm A. The Case for Public Investment There is a key difference between what government does well in terms of promoting technological innovation and what the private sector does well. The standard distinction is that government is the appropriate funder of basic research while the private sector is much better and much more efficient at commercializing new technologies. However, there is a vast chasm between basic research and commercialization where many promising technologies, particularly energy technologies, die. This is known as the "technology valley of death" (Grubb 2004). It represents critical early stage production and deployment stages of commercialization. At these stages the private energy sector has not, for a variety of reasons, done particularly well. There are also a number of reasons particular to energy technology that further increase risk. Energy patents are notoriously difficult to defend and easy to reverse engineer. Fearing "knowledge spillover" – innovations that can't be captured or monopolized by the companies doing the research — investors and firms avoid making big, long-term investments in emerging technologies. "Investors," wrote Stanford's David Victor and Danny Cullenward in September's Scientific American, "tend to focus on technologies that are nearing commercial application and potential profit.” Finally, the commodified nature of energy (one electron is as good as another) makes it difficult to develop new commercial products that can command a higher price. While Apple enthusiasts lined up to shell out $600 for an iPhone, very few consumers are willing to pay 2 to 3 times more for clean energy. These challenges and others have resulted in huge barriers to the widespread commercialization of new clean energy technologies by the private sector. And it is for this reason that the vast majority of energy experts, as well as the largescale reviews of the technology challenge as it relates to climate, such as the spring 2007 IPCC report, and the 2006 Stern Review, have called for exponential increases in public investment in research, development and deployment of clean energy technologies. The lack of investment is not a minor barrier – most energy experts view it as the primary barrier. "Probably the most significant barrier to ETI [Energy Technology Innovation] is inadequacy of funds, especially for R&D, in relation to the challenges that are faced by energy system" (Sims Gallagher et al. 2006: 221-222). Fast Clean Cheap 23 John Holdren, the current chairman of the American Association for the Advancement of Science, wrote, "Around the world, the energy sector’s ratio of RD&D investments to total revenues is well below that for any other high-tech sector of the economy… These investments will need to be boosted at least 2-3fold if the world is to meet the energy challenges it faces in the decades immediately ahead" (Holdren 2006: 20). Others say it should be much higher. "Using emissions scenarios from the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change and a previous framework for estimating the climate-related savings from energy R&D programs (Schock et al.., 1999), we calculate that U.S. energy R&D spending of $15 – 30 billion/year would be sufficient to stabilize CO2 at double pre-industrial levels [550 ppm]" (Kammen 2006a: 4) The efficacy of this kind of public investment is well-documented. In the roughly five years that the federal government guaranteed the market for microchips in the 1960’s, the price of a microchip came down from $1000 per chip to $20. A similar federal effort in the 1980’s saw similar improvements in price and performance. According to Stern and IPCC: "Extensive and prolonged public support and private markets were both instrumental in the development of all generating technologies. Military R&D, the US space programme and learning from other markets have also been crucial to the process of innovation in the energy sector" (Stern 2006: 361) "Government support through financial contributions, tax credits, standard setting and market creation is important for effective technology development, innovation and deployment" (IPCC 2007: 20) The dramatic price and performance improvements in wind technology occurred because Denmark guaranteed its market for wind energy in the 1980’s and 90’s. "Development of the Danish wind and Brazilian biofuels industries each required sustained government support over decades. The Danish subsidies totaled $1.3bn, and Danish wind companies now earn more than that each year (Carbon Trust, 2003). At current oil prices, Brazil may soon similarly recoup its investment in biofuel technology" (Grubb 2004: 26 – 27). And the Japanese government saw similar breakthroughs in the price of solar panels as result of its intervention in the solar market in the 1990’s. This is the kind of public investment that we desperately need to unleash the power of private sector investment and innovation. Without it, faith that the private sector will massively increase investment to deploy clean energy technologies is unfounded. Fast Clean Cheap 24 B. The Historical Precedent for an Investment-Centered Framework Large public investments into technology innovation and emerging industries are not new. Most of America’s largest industries have benefited from strategic public investment in their development: agriculture, aerospace, transport, biotechnology, and energy. Farm land was granted to early American frontier farmers, and agriculture has been publicly subsidized since the early 20th century. Before the Civil War, Abraham Lincoln was best known for his aggressive advocacy of publicly funded transit projects to allow for the flourishing of modernization and industry: canals, roads, and later, famously, railroads. Computer science, aerospace, and the highways were created and invested in after World War II out of competition with the Soviets and justified by national security concerns. And today’s highly mature energy markets are the result of decades of subsidies for coal mining and oil drilling. Government investments come in a variety of forms, from outright subsidization to contracting and procurement to various tax deductions, credits, and other mechanisms aimed at starting, finance, and otherwise supporting industries deemed important either to national wealth creation, national security, or both. The U.S. government invested directly in computer science scholarships and fellowships, prizes, R&D, and microchips. The private sector did not create, and could not have created, those high-tech markets. Many successful new technologies cannot become commercially viable without public investment in the form of government procurement. The Defense Department's procurement of microchips allowed the technology to penetrate the market and become cheap and powerful. It's not just microchip companies like Intel that benefited from these public investments. All high tech firms that depend on microchips, the Internet, and the computer sciences, from Dell to Google to Apple, only exist thanks to these "tech-push" strategies. At the same time, few believe that companies operating in the mature industry of consumer electronics and information technology, like Dell, Google or Apple should continue to receive large public investments. These established firms are able to finance their own innovation, often by developing and selling high end, cuttingedge technologies to niche markets that, over time, become less expensive. Personal computers and cell phones are often cited examples. Moreover, past great technological revolutions did not occur via regulatory fiat. The U.S. did not invent the Internet nor the personal computer by taxing or regulating typewriters. Nor did the transition to the petroleum economy occur because we taxed, regulated, or ran out of whale oil. Those revolutions happened because we invented alternatives that were vastly superior to what they replaced, and, in remarkably short order, a good deal cheaper. Adding scrubbers to smokestacks to deal with acid rain, and adding catalytic converters to vehicles, Fast Clean Cheap 25 are best understood as inexpensive technical fixes — not wholesale technological revolutions. In thinking about the history of U.S. technology policy we need to draw conclusions about policy design not just from its policy outcomes but also about the political preconditions, since if the past programs had lacked popular or elite support, they would never have been enacted. The first lesson is that public investments succeed when they gain and grow strong support from both elites and the public. Cold War military leaders, for instance, supported the expansion of airplane technology for security reasons, which also helped establish elite support for the space program. By the time President John F. Kennedy announced his intention to put a man on the moon and bring him safely back to home, which cost over $135 billion in 2006 numbers, there was already widespread public support for the aerospace industries, with both job creation and national security being strong drivers of that support. The second lesson is that these investment-centered policies succeeded politically because they spoke to core American values, such as ingenuity, creativity, perseverance, and competition. They were also urgent: the Manhattan project to build a nuclear bomb was a race against the Nazis, whereas aerospace, computers, and the Internet were motivated out a race with the Soviets. In the case of the Cold War space program, the U.S. was literally in a "space race" with the Soviets. The speed with which the U.S. built the railroads and the interstate highway system, invested in microchips, put a man on the moon, and built the Internet helped overcome bureaucratic obstacles to success. National security and economic development became justifications for policymakers and administrators to tunnel through various bureaucratic obstacles to success. Today Americans overwhelmingly view energy independence with equal urgency, viewing the situation in the Middle East and the price of oil as reasons to accelerate our transition to a clean energy future. The investment-centered framework for action on energy independence and global warming should speak to existing fear but also bridge to feelings of enthusiasm and excitement. The third lesson is that revolutionary new technologies are polymorphous — they have multiple benefits. ARPANET was created primarily for communication during the Cold War, but its development into the Internet clearly held many more benefits, eventually transforming practically every aspect of communication. Similarly successful public investment into clean energy has the potential to create widespread, unanticipated benefits: it can create jobs, increase national security through energy independence, reduce and stabilize energy prices by diversifying energy supplies, secure America's place in global innovation by taking part in the fast-growing clean energy technology Fast Clean Cheap 26 market, and help to mitigate the effects of global warming by reducing greenhouse gas emissions. C. Investment for Tech Innovation to Bring the Cost of Clean Energy Down Anyone who read the media coverage of the spring 2007 IPCC report would be forgiven for having thought that the U.N. had simply reiterated the longstanding consensus that global warming is happening and being caused by humans. In fact, the 2007 IPCC report went much further, calling not just for regulation but also for large public investments into clean energy. "Public benefits of RD&D investments are bigger than the benefits captured by the private sector," the IPCC report concluded, "justifying government support of RD&D." Similarly, the Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change, the influential report commissioned by the British government in October 2006, recommends that governments boost their clean-energy investments from current global levels of $34 billion (an amount that includes nuclear) to between $68 billion and $170 billion annually. Indeed, whether it’s the recommendations presented by the IPCC, the Stern Review, Scientific American, or top energy innovation experts, investment in technology is universally seen as a central element in overcoming ecological crisis. “Funding for energy research,” Scientific American said in its lead editorial in a special issue dedicated to clean energy, “must be accorded the privileged status usually reserved for health care and defense.” In the 2002 Science article by New York University physicist Martin Hoffert and 16 other leading energy experts that inspired the two of us to co-found the call for a "New Apollo Project" on energy, Hoffert et. al argued that, "although regulation can play a role, the fossil fuel greenhouse effect is an energy problem that cannot be simply regulated away." Advocates of the regulation-centered approach often claim that the technologies needed to deal with global warming already exist and just need to be scaled up. However, dramatic technological innovation in clean energy is needed for a different reason: to reduce the price of clean energy. Over the last ten years a consensus has emerged among energy policy experts seeking solutions to global warming that what’s needed are “disruptive” clean energy technologies that achieve “non-incremental” breakthroughs in price and performance (Christensen, 1997; Nemet 2007: 72, citing Hanemann and Farrell, 2006). New energy sources will not be able to compete with old energy sources until their production is increased to the point where the price declines to the levels of coal, natural gas, and oil. And for that to happen, a major investment will be needed in these new energy sources (Nemet 2007: 72) Fast Clean Cheap 27 Relying only on a high price for carbon without also making large public investments in strategic deployment, others warn, “is likely to result in distortions in other economic sectors and to increase the total costs of climate policy to society” (Grubb 2004, cited in Neuhoff, 2005: 18). In assessing various approaches to climate policy, one study concluded that “Investments in climate friendly technologies can reduce GDP losses to the U.S. by a factor of two or more" (Richels et al, 2007), a conclusion broadly echoed by the Stern Review, the IPCC, and other analysts (Stern 2006; IPCC 2007; Edmonds and Smith, 2006; Grubb 2004; Nemet 2007). Some have estimated that half of all economic growth is due to technological change (Jorgenson and Wilcoxen, 1990), while others credit technological improvements for nearly all economic growth (Victor 1999). Investments in clean energy technology are particularly promising because they both drive economic growth and avoid (or reduce the cost of) the most expensive impacts of climate change. Using an economic model aimed at calculating both the economic costs of climate change and the costs of mitigation, Yale economist William Nordhaus estimates that clean energy alternatives to dirty energy have a net value of roughly $17 trillion in 2005 dollars (Nordhaus, 2007). D. A Policy that Works Politically America's national culture today remains far more supportive of a politics and policy agenda grounded in accelerating the transition to a clean energy economy than one grounded in reducing pollution emissions. Poll data demonstrates strong public support for government research programs specifically. Though Americans do not support higher gasoline or electricity prices to change behavior, wide majorities also say they would be willing to pay higher gasoline and electricity prices if the money was sure to go to achieving energy independence and to clean energy.24 When both the benefits and costs of the policy initiatives are listed, the support for investment far exceeded the other options in the poll. The programs would benefit industry as well. In contrast to a regulationcentered approach that seeks to impose costs on businesses, the investmentcentered framework defines existing industries as potential allies rather than likely opponents. History provides a useful guide. Railroads were built by private firms but were entirely paid for by American taxpayers. The first Transcontinental Railroad, built in the 1860s, is widely considered by historians to be the greatest American technological feat of the nineteenth century. Nearly one hundred years later Congress passed and President Dwight D. Eisenhower signed the National Interstate and Defense Highways Act into law. Fast Clean Cheap 28 IV. Specific Recommendations The following specific recommendations are offered as a starting point for discussion. They are designed to drive home the scale of the problem and to initiate a dialogue about the best way to proceed. The choices of how much to invest, where to invest, and how to structure incentives for the private sector, are complicated and will take considerable thought. What is clear is that a new approach to the energy challenge is imperative at this point in time. A. Establish a carbon price consistent with what present technology can accomplish. There is much argument presently about what level of carbon reduction legislation under consideration in Congress should mandate. The grassroots climate movement demands 80% by 2050. Most legislative proposals in Congress undershoot that goal substantially. But with present technology, 80% reductions by 2050, if such a cap was actually enforced, would result in a price for carbon that would rise to between $600 and $800 per ton. This translates to more than doubling the real cost of energy, an outcome that is both politically unsustainable and economically devastating. For this reason, even Senators Barbara Boxer and Bernie Sanders’ cap and auction bill, the preferred vehicle of grassroots environmentalists and the Sierra Club, includes a safety valve provision that would lift the cap if the carbon price that it established became too expensive. By contrast, if clean energy technologies do see significant breakthroughs in price and performance, they will become cost competitive with conventional energy sources at much lower carbon prices. Either way, expending extraordinary political resources to establish caps over forty years that will either be unsustainable without technology breakthroughs or irrelevant with them doesn’t make a lot of sense. We’re better off establishing a carbon price in the shorter term that can capture the 20% emissions reductions that can be achieved through efficiency and shifting to cleaner conventional energy sources, and which can drive much deeper carbon emissions reductions if and when the price of alternative energy sources declines and their performance improves. B. Establish a dedicated source of public funding for clean energy investment that can rapidly drive down the deployed cost of clean energy technologies. Fast Clean Cheap 29 As noted above, whatever theoretical level a carbon cap is set at by Congress, there will almost certainly be a safety valve that will functionally limit how high the real price of carbon can rise. While we have no objection to setting caps that are more restrictive, as long as there is a safety valve the cap is largely irrelevant. What matters, then, is the maximum carbon price that the safety valve allows. When arguing for caps that mandate deeper reductions, environmentalists argue that the cost of complying with those caps will be much less than opponents suggest. Safety valves call the question on this debate. Given this framework, the cap is largely symbolic. The safety valve and the price and performance that clean energy technology can achieve will ultimately determine the level of reduction achieved. Given this framework, the key to achieving deep reductions is to drive the real price and performance of clean energy technology down as rapidly and as far as possible. As noted above, it is our contention that targeted public investment is the most likely path to this outcome. Carbon regulation is in fact the most likely source for this revenue stream. Whether through auctions or carbon taxes, federal carbon regulation has the potential to generate tens of billions of dollars annually for public clean energy investments. These investments should include dramatic increases in funding for basic research in the energy sciences, a ten year commitment to buy down the price of solar technology and battery and other energy storage technologies, and a commitment to build a smarter and more efficient electricity grid that can support energy generation that is both more distributed and, in many cases, more remote. C. Ramp Up: Invest $300 Billion In Research, Development, and Deployment Of Clean Energy Technologies. There is an emerging consensus among energy experts that investment in energy research, development, and deployment should be increased to $30 to $50 in the U.S., and $50 to $170 billion worldwide, per year.25 We are proposing a ten-year, $300 billion public investment into accelerating the transition to a clean energy economy. The goal of the program is to bring the price of clean energy down to the price of coal and natural gas in much of the world as quickly as possible. However, other values should also be built into the structure of the investment, such as labor, health, and other environmental standards. One econometric calculation using input-output models for various sectors of the economy found that an initial $300 billion public investment would trigger a $200 billion in private capital into similar investments. (Perryman 2003). This analysis is backed by various historical investment successes: just as past public investment efforts into the railroads, the highways, microchips, the Internet, computer sciences, and the medical biosciences triggered billions in private Fast Clean Cheap 30 investment, and paid for themselves many times over, so will these new investments into energy. This pattern remains apparent today in both biofuels and biosciences. The econometric analysis described above found that a $300 billion investment would pay for itself in 10 years both through energy savings, economic growth, job creation, profit taking, and thus additional revenue for the U.S. Treasury. The total value of clean energy sources to the global economy was recently estimated at $17 trillion (Nordhaus 2007). Paying for strategic national security, infrastructure, agricultural, and energy investments is traditionally done out of the general budget. The investments we are describing here can be paid for the same way, or alternatively, through revenues generated by auctioning emissions permits in a limited cap and trade system. D. Insulate federal clean energy investments from pork-barrel politics. There are many models for doing this, from the Pentagon's (Defense Advanced Research Projects Agency) DARPA, to the military base closing commission, to the creation of public corporations and industry boards. Some of the best thinking on this has been done by MIT's John Deutsch, who served as DOE Director of Energy Research under President Carter and left the experience concluding that what's needed is both more money for commercialization and new institutions, such as a public Energy Technology Corporation: Successful government action requires both more resources and a willingness to change the conventional approach to government’s support for energy technology commercialization… The ETC would select and manage technology demonstration projects without favoring particular fuels or supply over end use. [T]he ETC would be composed of independent individuals with experience and knowledge about future market needs, industry capability, and best use of indirect financial incentives – loans, loan guarantees, production tax credits, and guaranteed purchase – in order to run a project on as commercial a basis as possible. The ETC would not be subject to federal procurement rules, and if financed with a single appropriation, would be somewhat insulated from congressional and special interest pressure (Deutsch 2005: 16). E. Buy down the price of solar like we did with microchips There is no silver bullet when it comes to clean energy alternatives. For that reason, the Energy Technology Council must make investments in a wide range Fast Clean Cheap 31 of low to zero emissions technologies, including wind, geothermal, efficiency, carbon capture and storage, nuclear, solar, and advanced energy technologies. However, this does not mean that all clean energy sources are created equal. Solar has special potential, and merits special attention. Solar panels, like microchips, have their own kind of "Moore's Law": the price of solar comes down roughly 20 percent every time production capacity is doubled. Just as the Department of Defense guaranteed the nascent market for silicon microchips in the 1960s, bringing the price down from $1,000 to $20 per chip in just a few years, the Pentagon should do the same with silicon solar panels. Experts say that for a total cost of $50 to $200 billion, we could bring solar panels down to the price of natural gas or even goal. (Grubb 2004; Neuhoff 2005; van der Zwaan, 2004). It might be the best $200 billion ever spent by the U.S. military. One long-standing obstacle has been the sense among homeowners that they will not get the full value of their solar panel investment if they move before they pay off the panels. Solar installation firms have so far sought to allay this concern by pointing to evidence that home value increases with solar panels, and by offering to move the systems to new homes. The solution might be a Homeowners Power Act that would consist of a) a revolving fund that would pays the full cost for homeowners to install a home solar system, b) full net metering, allowing homeowners to sell power back to the grid at peak prices, and c) a mechanism for solar homeowners to pay the equivalent of their monthly electric bill back into the revolving fund. F. Play the Field: Make Strategic Investments in Key Energy Sectors and Technologies Energy policy experts emphasize that there are no silver bullets in energy. Indeed, meeting our present and future energy needs will require greater energy diversity. Experts emphasize the need for a "silver buckshot" approach that consists of investing in innovation, including deployment, of many new energy technologies (Grubb; Socolow and Pacala; Nemet 2007; Neuhoff; Edmonds 2007). Indeed, given the need to reconcile increased consumption with lower emissions, the effort must be to making many different kinds of investments into many different sources of energy. Anyone thus hoping to develop a new energy agenda must constantly grapple with complexity with an open mind to new technological possibilities, and its myriad of implications. Delving into each specific renewable technology is beyond the scope of this essay, but targeted investments in solar, wind, geothermal, and ocean energy, as well as efficiency mechanisms, carbon capture and storage, nuclear technology, and biofuels will be important and prudent steps for the near future. Additionally, the nation desperately needs an upgraded infrastructure of batteries and transmission lines Fast Clean Cheap 32 to deliver clean energy to the grid; those technologies should receive substantial public support as well. G. Create a framework for global carbon regulation tied to living standards. China, despite much criticism from environmentalists, has already done more to mitigate the environmental impacts of its development than has any developing nation in history. The establishment of nascent carbon prices in developing countries should be based upon benchmarks associated with improving living standards in those countries, the attainment of real reductions in carbon emissions in the developed world, and major progress in bringing down the costs of appropriate clean energy technologies. As economic development progresses, living standards improve, and the costs of clean energy technologies come down dramatically, modest carbon prices in the developing world will become both tenable and sufficient to drive the transition to low carbon alternatives. V. Conclusion The energy challenge has been framed thus far as a forced choice between poverty and environmental ruin. With a choice like that, it is no surprise that the world has failed to make real strides towards a cleaner energy future. Global warming and energy independence are new challenges that require new ways of thinking. The outmoded regulation-centered approach, which seeks to impose costs on polluters, is completely inadequate to deal with this new challenge. Instead, America should take the bold step of cutting the Gordian Knot by pouring public funds into new technologies. Unleashing the creativity of our greatest minds on this problem is likely to produce brilliant results not only for the environment, but for our economy, national security, and status in the world. Fast Clean Cheap 33 Bibliography Aitken, Donald W. "Transitioning to a Renewable Energy Future," International Solar Energy Society, 2003. Alic, John, David Mowery, Edward Rubin, "U.S. Technology and Innovation Policies: Lessons for Climate Change," Pew Center on Global Climate Change, November 2003. Anderson, Dennis. "Costs and Finance of Abating Carbon Emissions in the Energy Sector," Imperial College London, White Paper Prepared for the Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change, October 20, 2006. Blyth, William and Hamilton, Kirsty. "Aligning Climate and Energy Policy: Creating incentives to invest in low carbon technologies in the context of linked markets for fossil fuel, electricity and carbon," Chatham House White Paper prepared for the Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change, April 2006. John Deutsch, "What should the government do to encourage technical change in the energy sector?" Center for Energy and Environmental Policy Research, March 2005. Duke, Richard D. "Clean Energy Technology Buydowns: Economic Theory, Analytic Tools, and the Photovoltaics Case," Ph.D Dissertation, Princeton University, Woodrow Wilson School of Public and International Affairs Edmonds, JA, Wise, MA, Dooley, JJ, Kim, SH, Smith, SJ Runci, PJ, Clarke, LE Malone, EL, Stokes, GM. "Global Energy Technology Strategy: Addressing Climate Change," Global Energy Technology Strategy Program, May 2007. General Accounting Office, "Key challenges remain for developing and deploying advanced energy technologies to meet future needs," December 2006. Grubb, Michael “Technology Innovation and Climate Change Policy: An Overview of Issues and Options,” Keio Journal of Economics, 2004. Hoffert, Martin, Caldeira, Ken, Benford, Gregory, Criswell, David R., Green, Christopher, Herzog, Howard, Jain, Atul K., Kheshgi, Haroon S., Lackner, Klaus S., Lewis, John S., Lightfoot, H. Douglas, Manheimer, Wallace, Mankins, John C. Mauel, Michael E., Perkins, L. John, Schlesinger, Michael E., Volk, Tyler, Wigley, Tom M. L., "Advanced Technology Paths to Global Climate Stability: Energy for a Greenhouse Planet," Science, November 1, 2002. Holdren, John P. "The Energy Innovation Imperative," Innovations, Spring 2006. Fast Clean Cheap 34 Jaffe, Adam B. Richard G. Newell, and Robert N. Stavins, "A Tale of Two Market Failures: Technology and Environmental Policy," Resources for the Future, October 2004. Josefsson, Lars G. Vattenfall AB, "Statement given at the Ministerial Dialogue Meeting of the U.N. Commission on Sustainable Development," 2006-05-10 Mandil, Claude. "Foreward," Energy Technology Perspectives, International Energy Agency, 2006. The National Commission on Energy Policy, "Ending the Energy Stalemate: A Bipartisan Strategy to Meet America's Energy Challenges," December 2004. Karsten Neuhoff, "Large Scale Deployment of Renewables for Electricity Generation," Cambridge Working Papers in Economics #59, Cambridge – MIT, 2005. William Nordhaus, The Challenge of Global Warming: Economic Models and Environmental Policy, forthcoming book, 2008. Kammen, Daniel M. "Climate Change Technology Research: Do We Need a 'Manhattan Project' for the Environment?, Testimony before Congress, September 21, 2006. Kammen, Daniel, "The Rise of Renewable Energy," Scientific American, September 2006. Margolis, Robert M. and Daniel Kammen, "Underinvestment: The Energy Technology and R&D Policy Challenge," Science, July 30, 1999. Nemet, Gregory. "Policy and Innovation in Low-Carbon Energy Technologies," Ph.D Dissertation, Spring 2007. Richard Richels, Rutherford, Thomas, Blanford, Geoffrey, Clarke, Leon. "Managing the Transition to Climate Stabilization, AEI-Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies, January 2007 Sims Gallagher, Kelly, Holdren, John P., and Sagar, Ambuj D. "EnergyTechnology Innovation," Annual Review of Environment and Resources, August 25, 2006, pp. 193 – 237. Robert H. Socolow and Stephen W. Pacala. "A Plan to Keep Carbon in Check," Scientific American, September 2006. Fast Clean Cheap 35 Stern, Nicholas. The Stern Review: The Economics of Climate Change, UK Treasury, October 2006. Victor, David, and Cullenward, Danny. "Making Carbon Markets Work," Scientific American, September 24, 2007. United Nations Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, "Summary for Policymakers," April 30 to May 4, 2007. Notes Richard Smalley, "Future Global Energy Prosperity: The Terawatt Challenge," Material Research Society Bulletin, June 2005, p. 414, available at http:// cohesion.rice.edu/NaturalSciences/Smalley/emplibrary/120204%20MRS%20Bo ston.pdf. 2 Smalley, supra note 1, at 414. 3 Rob Collier, “A Warming World: China about to Pass U.S. as World’s Top Generator of Greenhouse Gases,” San Francisco Chronicle, May 5, 2007. 4 IEA, Energy Technology Perspectives, 2006 5 EIA, “International Energy Outlook 2007,” Chapter 7. 6 EIA, Annual Energy Outlook 2006; China will amount to 68.2% of the developing world and 42.6% of the world’s total emissions from coal. “International Energy Outlook 2007,” EIA, May 2007: Table A13. 7 Analysis done by Mark Clayton, "New coal plants bury Kyoto," Christian Science Monitor, December 23, 2004. 8 Richard Balzhiser, “The Chinese Energy Outlook,” National Academy of Engineering 28, no. 2 (summer 1998); Keith Bradsher and David Barboza, “Pollution from Chinese Coal Casts a Global Shadow,” New York Times, June 11, 2006. 9 “International Energy Outlook 2007,” EIA, May 2007: Table A10. China will amount to 68.2% of the developing world and 42.6% of the world’s total emissions from coal. “International Energy Outlook 2007,” EIA, May 2007: Table A13. 10 According to IEA, 2050 annual global emissions will be 58,022 million CO2 compared to 24,532 Mt CO2 in 2003. To calculate cumulative emissions during this period, we assume that the average annual increase between 2003 and 2050 is constant. 11 Assume BAU United States contributes 15% of global emissions in 2050, or 8,700 Mt CO2 (IEA) compared to 5,813 Mt CO2 in 2003 (EIA) 12 See Massachusetts v. EPA, 127 S. Ct. 1438, 1460 (2007). 13 Andy Revkin, "From Ozone Success, a Potential Climate Model," September 18, 2007. 1 Fast Clean Cheap 36 “Estimates put iPhone sales at over 700,000: Device sold out in most stores by Monday afternoon,” Seattle Post, July 2nd 15 See, for instance, David Hawkins, "Passionate But Confused," Grist.org, September 28, 2007. http://gristmill.grist.org/story/2007/9/28/11254/2676 16 United Nations Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, "Summary for Policymakers," April 30 – May 4, 2007, p. 9. 17 William Nordhaus, A Question of Balance: Weighing the Options on Global Warming Policies, (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press) 2008. 18 Scolow and Pacala 19 Katherine Hunt, "Prop. 87 divides Californians along party lines," San Francisco Chronicle, November 3, 2006. "According to the Field Poll released on Nov. 2, the No side has opened up a slim four percentage point lead at 44% to 40%, a reversal of the Oct. 4 poll when the Yes side was slightly favored, at 44% to 41%. In the Aug. 2 poll, Prop. 87 led by a five to three margin, with 52% in favor and only 31% against." 20 Focus Groups conducted by American Environics for Earthjustice, December 2006. 21 The Pew Center is funded by the same foundation that invests tens of millions annually into environmental causes. A 2001 New York Times article named Pew as the largest grant maker to environmental causes: $51 million in environmental causes in 2000 alone. Douglas Jehl, “Charity Is New Force in Environmental Fight,” New York Times, June 28, 2001. 22 Pew Research Center for People and the Press, “Partisanship Drives Opinion: Little Consensus on Global Warming,” July 12, 2006, accessible at www.peoplepress.org. 23 Pew Research Center for People and the Press, “Global Warming: A Divide on Causes and Solutions: Public Views Unchanged by Unusual Weather,” January 24, 2007. 24 An April 2007 CBS News/New York Times poll that showed 64 percent of Americans would be willing “to pay higher taxes on gasoline and other fuels if the money was used for research into renewable sources like solar and wind energy.” A Gallup poll taken at the same time found that when asked a battery of questions about what the government should do to address global warming, 65 percent of Americans said the government should be “starting a major research effort costing up to $30 billion per year to develop new sources of energy,” the highest scoring item in the battery. An August 2006 Los Angeles Times/Bloomberg poll asked Americans to identify the “best way for the US to reduce reliance on foreign oil.” A majority, 52 percent, cited “having the government invest in alternative energy sources, such as wind and solar power,” the top choice by a two-to-one margin. The highest levels of support in a March 2007 Gallup poll were for spending government money on the new energy sources. Proposals for “spending more government money on developing solar and wind power” was supported by 81 percent in 2007, up from 77 percent in 2006. Gallup found that “starting a major research effort costing up to $30 billion 14 Fast Clean Cheap 37 per year to develop new sources of energy” was supported by 65 percent of respondents, the largest level of support of the items tested. 25 While there is a strong consensus that public investment in energy R&D and deployment should increase, the amount recommended varies from a doubling or tripling (Holdren 2006) to a fourfold increase (Davis and Owens 2003; Schock et al 1999). Nemet (2007) argues that all of these estimates are too low, pointing out that one estimate of impacts of a fourfold increase (Schock et al. 1999) assumes a mean climate stabilization target at between 650 and 750 ppm CO2, and incorporates a 35 percent probability that no stabilization will be required, which would have CO2 levels reaching 1000 ppm by the end of the century. Nemet reconfigured the Schock et al. model to reach a target of 550-ppm atmospheric level of carbon, 100 ppm below what IPCC and Stern conclude would lead to drastic and irreversible consequences, and finds that the optimal R&D invesment would be between $11 and $32 billion annually in 2005 dollars, or roughly 5-10 times more than current energy R&D. That investment level would also act as “insurance” against electricity blackouts, oil price shocks, and air pollution (Nemet 2007: 54). This would be a large increase, but Nemet points out that such an increase would at 2.6% of total energy revenues, compared with pharmaceuticals, software, and computer industries, which invest 5 – 15 percent of their revenues annually (Nemet 2007: 58). Fast Clean Cheap 38