The Process of Power-Sharing How Constitutions Were Established in Afghanistan and Iraq after US Intervention Anne van den Heuvel Student Number 0318698 Utrecht University 17 March 2009 Thesis submitted to the Board of Examiners in partial fulfillment of the requirements of the degree of Master in Arts in Conflict Studies and Human Rights Supervisor: Chris van der Borgh Date of Submission: 12 March 2009 Word Count: 17,507 (excl. Bibliography) Trajectory: 30 ECTS: Compulsory Courses 15 ECTS: Research/Thesis and Internship Report 15 ECTS: Internship (12+ weeks) at International Crisis Group UN Advocacy Team New York, USA Additional: Internship (12 weeks) at MoFA of the Netherlands, Permanent Representation to the European Union Department Middle East/Northern Africa Brussels, Belgium Table of Contents Introduction 2 Chapter 1: Power-Sharing Theory and Horowitz’ Notion of “Process” 5 1.1 Theories on Power-Sharing and Current Scholarly Debate 5 1.1.1 Consociationalism and Centripetalism 5 1.1.2 The Current Scholarly Debate on Power-Sharing 7 1.1.3 Power-Sharing Theory and the Case Studies Afghanistan and Iraq 9 1.1.4 Conclusion on Consociationalism and Centripetalism 10 1.2 The Constitutional Process and Power-Sharing 11 1.2.1 Definition and Relevance of Process 11 1.2.2 Process in Existing Power-Sharing Theory 12 1.3 Analyzing Constitutional Processes Chapter 2: Afghanistan 13 14 2.1 Overview Interim Period 14 2.2 Outcome: The Constitution 15 2.3 Local Actors and Groups 16 2.4 The Constitutional Process 18 2.4.1 Decision-making During Bonn 18 2.4.2 US Role/Warlords 19 2.4.3 Centre-Periphery Relationship 21 2.4.4 UN/International Community 21 2.4.5 Hamid Karzai 22 2.5 Findings Chapter 3: Iraq 24 25 3.1 Overview Interim Period 25 3.2 Outcome: The Constitution 26 3.3 Local Actors and Groups 27 3.4 The Constitutional Process 28 3.4.1 US Role and Iraqi Ownership 28 3.4.2 UN/International Community 31 3.4.3 Exclusion of Sunni Arabs/De-Ba’athification 32 3.4.4 Ethnicization of Politics 34 2.5 Findings 35 Conclusion 36 Bibliography 39 Introduction Afghanistan and Iraq were invaded by coalitions led by the United States (US) within a time frame of eighteen months. In the period after the invasion and the toppling of the ruling parties, new constitutions that included power-sharing arrangements were established in both countries. Power-sharing is a crucial part of peace agreements and new constitutions in many contemporary post-conflict situations. For groups to agree on sharing power can provide an alternative for the violent power struggle that took place during conflict. Power-sharing agreements have both succeeded and failed but, after researching power-sharing arrangements in 191 countries and in-depth research of ten post-conflict societies, Pippa Norris of Harvard University concludes, “power-sharing is one of the most promising avenues towards lasting peace settlements and sustainable democracy” (Norris 2008:223). There are different areas in which power-sharing can be applied; at the executive and government level, but also in the legislature and in judicial and economic sectors. In each case where power-sharing is applied, these areas are in- or excluded in a more- or less comprehensive way. In this thesis the focus is on political power-sharing arrangements. “Political arrangements” refers to regulations regarding the executive and government levels that include institutional and constitutional rules such as the type of electoral system, the type of executive (presidential or parliamentary) and the division of power between central government and regions (Papagianni 2007:25, Norris 2008:23). A detailed definition of power-sharing depends on the theory of power-sharing advocated. A general, broad definition is based on common elements from political power-sharing theories and is given by Pippa Norris and Timothy Sisk, an oftencited scholar on power-sharing in post-conflict societies. Sisk defines political power-sharing systems as “practices and institutions that result in broad-based governing coalitions generally inclusive of most, if not all, major groups” (Sisk 1999:vii, 4). The definition used in this thesis is put forward by Pippa Norris, who defines political power-sharing as “formal institutional rules which give multiple political elites a stake in the decision-making process” (Norris 2008:23). In order to institutionalize and implement political power-sharing arrangements, questions on which groups will get a stake in power, on how it will be decided how much power a group gets and on who is to answer these first two questions have to be answered (Papagianni 2008:49). Power-sharing theory deals with these puzzles. There are two main theories in power-sharing literature, known as consociationalism and centripetalism. Both include guidelines and explanations on how to share political power and on what type of powersharing arrangements works best. The scholarly debate evolves around the critiques of these theories and focuses on the questions “what can be done” (criticizing practical use of centripetalism) versus “what should be done” (criticizing theoretical foundations of consociationalism). The power-sharing arrangements that were adopted in Afghanistan and Iraq differ significantly and correspond for a large part with the two different theories. At the same time, the countries show important structural similarities which “provide the constraints that narrow the options” for power-sharing (Horowitz 2008:1247); In both countries the 2 establishment of new power-sharing arrangements was caused in the same way, namely after US-led military intervention as part of the “War on Terror” and the toppling of governing regimes. Another similarity is that the US and its coalition partners had a special and important role in the period after the invasion when the countries had to be rebuild; not only as a mediator with great leverage, but also as an invader with an own agenda. Finally, the two interventions started less then 18 months after one another and the interim period - the period between the invasion and the adoption of the new constitution - was in both countries of similar duration, around three years. The fact that Afghanistan and Iraq show important structural similarities but adopted very different power-sharing arrangements that largely reflect different power-sharing theories, raises questions about how these differences can be explained. Donald Horowitz, a prominent scholar on power-sharing, recently argued that power-sharing arrangements are the outcome of negotiations that take place during constitutional processes that precede the adoption of the power-sharing arrangements (Horowitz 2008:1226, 1230). The structural similarities and different types of power-sharing arrangements in Afghanistan and Iraq, combined with Horowitz’ notion that power-sharing arrangements are the outcome of constitutional processes, leads to the following research question: “How can differences in power-sharing arrangements in Afghanistan and Iraq be explained by Horowitz’ notion of constitutional process?” The answer to this question will provide insight in the particular composition of power-sharing arrangements in Afghanistan and Iraq. Instead of focusing on what works best, as most power-sharing literature does, the focus in this research is on how to explain the particular composition of - and differences between – power-sharing arrangements. The answer to this question will apply to the case studies Afghanistan and Iraq, and results will not necessarily be similar in other cases. This research is qualitative; the goal is not to come up with a blueprint that lists factors that influence the outcomes of constitutional processes in any case. Even though there are structural similarities, there are numerous differences as well. Afghanistan and Iraq are selected because the specific similarities between the countries (the reason why power-sharing arrangements are established, the duration of the interim period and whether an external power plays a large role) are according to power-sharing literature decisive elements for the eventual success of political power-sharing (for example, Papagianni 2007:29, Schneckener 2002:217, Sisk 1999:xiv). In Afghanistan and Iraq, powersharing arrangements are defined in and legalized by adopting them as part of the constitution. For that reason, in this thesis the term constitution refers to the adopted power-sharing arrangements. The constitutional process is the period that precedes the adoption of a new constitution during which the new constitution is made. The constitutional process will be defined in more detail in chapter 1. In both countries the constitutional process took place during the interim period, which is the period between the toppling of the respective regimes and the adoption of a new constitution. In order to answer the research question I will address the following issues in this thesis: The first chapter deals with the theoretical context of power-sharing and Horowitz’ notion of process. First of all 3 existing power-sharing theories, and why they are not used to answer the research question will be discussed. Secondly, Horowitz’ notion of process as a framework to explain differences in power-sharing arrangements will be defined and the way in which the constitutional process will be researched in this thesis will be explained. In the second and third chapter, the constitutional processes and power-sharing arrangements in Afghanistan and Iraq will be described and analyzed. In the conclusion, findings will be presented, the research question will be answered and options for further research will be given. 4 Chapter 1: Power-Sharing Theory and Horowitz’ Notion of “Process” As noted in the introduction, the power-sharing arrangements in Afghanistan and Iraq differ significantly. The purpose of this chapter is to explain why in this research an analysis of the constitutional process is chosen to explain these differences, and how this analysis will be done. In his recent article “Conciliatory Institutions and Constitutional Processes in Post-Conflict States” (Horowitz: 2008), Donald Horowitz argued the constitutional process is a crucial part of power-sharing arrangements. To understand the context in which Horowitz came up with the notion of process, in the first part of this chapter existing power-sharing theories and the current scholarly debate will be discussed, and their meaning for the power-sharing arrangements in Afghanistan and Iraq will be explained. In the second part the definition and use of the constitutional process with regard to power-sharing will be elaborated upon. Attention will be given to what process is and how it relates to the current power-sharing debate. Finally, an explanation of how to analyze the constitutional processes of Afghanistan and Iraq will be discussed in the third paragraph. 1.1 Theories on Power-Sharing and Current Scholarly Debate Within power-sharing literature, two main schools of thought have evolved around two theories, the first introduced by Arend Lijphart, the second by Donald Horowitz. Both theories will be introduced, followed by a discussion on the current scholarly debate on power-sharing. Whether and how current power-sharing theory can explain the differences between the constitutions in Afghanistan and Iraq will explained in the last section of this paragraph. 1.1.1 Consociatonalism and Centripetalism Consociationalism: Arend Lijphart The dominating approach among scholars and practitioners on power-sharing is introduced by Arend Lijphart in 1969, and is known as “consociationalism”. Lijphart’s theory was groundbreaking because it provided both an alternative to majoritarian rule and an answer to the question how to implement democracy in deeply divided societies (Sisk 1999:5, Norris 2008:23). Consociationalism highlights protection of groups, especially minorities, who often are victims in conflict. Consociationalism is based upon the idea that in a post-conflict climate where trust between parties is minimal, all significant parties must be secured of participation in government. Consociationalism relies on three principles: First of all, all major parties are represented in government on basis of proportional representation (Lijphart 2004:103). Because all parties are guaranteed representation in government, political parties are formed before elections take place, often along groupboundary lines (Sisk 1999:5). The second principle is the mutual veto. The veto-right protects every party of being politically outvoted by a majority (Lijphart 2004:97,107). As a consequence of the mutual veto, decision-making is based on consensus and thus a grand coalition, in which all parties participate, is required. Another consequence of the mutual veto and the decision-making based on consensus is that 5 executive power in a consociational electoral system often lies within the parliament (Horowitz 2008:1216). The last principle is segmental group autonomy, often through federalism. The underlying idea is that minorities can rule “over itself in the area of the minorities exclusive concern” (Lijphart 1977a:41, in Sisk 1999:37), meaning that only in areas of common concern decision-making will take place by consensus at the national level. Autonomy can be given through territorial or non-territorial federalism ‘Schneckener 2002:205, Norris 2008:25). Although Lijphart emphasizes that there is “no single consociational blueprint” (Lijphart 1982:175), these three principles are to be found in a consociational approach. Centripetalism: Donald Horowitz The other main theory on power-sharing is introduced by Donald Horowitz is known as ‘centripetalism’ and was established as a critique on and an alternative to consociationalism (Norris 2008:28). Horowitz’ main argument is that power-sharing should provide incentives for cooperation between moderates. An essential feature of centripetalism is intergroup cooperation as a prerequisite for electoral success, which means that leaders have to gain support from other groups in order to be elected (Sisk 1999:41). The underlying idea is that in order to receive votes from other groups, parties have to moderate their views by finding common ground between their own and the other group(s) and show that they are willing to compromise. This will lead to informal cross-boundary coalitions between groups that are formed before elections take place. According to Horowitz, the commitments of one party to another make the centripetal approach superior to the consociationalist approach (Horowitz 2008:1219). In order to make sure leaders need to reach out to other groups, incentives for moderates, such as electoral rules and institutions fostering political cooperation, are an important factor in centripetalism (Horowitz 2008:1218-). An example of an electoral rule is the use of the alternative vote, whereby voters need to vote for their second preference as well. The alternative vote is usually given to the group that offers most compromises after first voting for the ‘own’ group. This electoral rule helps to form cross-boundary coalitions and forms an incentive for parties to reach out to other parties in order to get the second votes (Sisk 1999:43). Most power-sharing agreements characterized by centripetalist ideas have a presidential system as opposed to a parliament, because a strong moderate president can serve a “nation-building role” and is able to push legislation through a divided parliament (Sisk 1999:43). Centripetalism is not opposed majority rule, but tries to create a moderate ruling majority that is willing to compromise and reach out to other groups Horowitz argues that as a consequence of intergroup cooperation across group boundaries, political parties will evolve along lines different then the group differences by which society was divided during conflict and that therefore centripetalism will lead to stable governments. 6 1.1.2 The Current Scholarly Debate on Power-Sharing Consociationalism and Centripetalism: Analyzing Similarities and Differences Consociationalism and centripetalism have similarities; both focus on avoiding exclusion (Horowitz 2008:1215), both accept existence of group boundaries and try to manage their effects (Horowitz 2008:1219) and both promote broad inclusive governing coalitions, although they differ about how and when these coalitions are formed (Sisk 1999:7). These similarities are mostly a consequence of the fact that any power-sharing theory has to deal with in- and exclusion of groups in the political process. The differences between centripetalism and consociationalism, such as the electoral system or electoral rules like the alternative vote or mutual veto, can be seen as a consequence of the fact that the two theories rest on fundamental different ideas about social identities (Sisk 1999:13). This can be clarified by looking at the difference regarding timing of coalition-formation and elections. In the centripetal approach, coalitions are to be formed before elections, whereas in the consociationalist approach parties form coalitions after elections (Sisk 1999:45). The formation of unofficial coalitions that include members of multiple groups before elections take place shows that the centripetal approach is based on the structuralist idea that identities are fluid and can be (re)constructed (Norris 2008:28). This (partial) reconstruction of identity makes it possible that people vote for another party then their own. A definition of “coalition” according to the centripetalist approach could be “one large political party, with the goal of forming a majority in government, that consists of members from multiple (ethnic/religious/social/territorial) groups”. It is hard to find empirical examples of centripetalist systems. Although many US’ citizens identify themselves with their ethnic group, political parties are not organized along ethnic lines - a characteristic of centripetalism. Ethnicity does not make someone Democrat or Republican and thus there are Democrats and Republicans within each ethnic group. Consequently, politics in the US are not divided along ethnic lines. Still, the US is not a centripetalist system as it does not have the electoral rules that require a certain number of votes from groups other then their own in order to get elected; in the US the majority wins, no matter where the votes come from. Horowitz cites the 1978 constitution of Sri Lanka as an example of a centripetalist system that used special electoral rules that required votes from different groups in order to be elected (Horowitz 1993, in Sisk 1999:43). Still this is not a very good example, as this system did not stop Sri Lanka from further conflict. The guaranteed government participation and post-election formation of coalitions, essentials of the consociationalist theory, show the roots of this approach lie in the primordialist idea; social identities are fixed and hard to change; therefore people will not vote for any group but their own. Because identities are not easily reconstructed and people from one group will not compromise with other groups on issues that they perceive as crucial, each group needs to be assured of government participation in order to include all major groups in the process. A definition of coalition according to the consociationalist approach could be “multiple political parties (often formed along ethnic/religious/social/territorial group boundaries) that work together in order to form a majority in government”. The political system in the Netherlands, on 7 which Lijphart based his approach, was founded on the consociationalist idea; Dutch society was strongly divided along religious lines and each religious group was assured of political representation in government, resulting in a multi-party democracy (Lijphart 1975). Centripetalism and Consociationalism: Critiques There are three main criticisms on consociationalism. The main critique on Lijphart’s theory is that consociationalism rewards extremists’ views; since every party is granted participation at the executive level, there is no incentive to moderate views and granted participation instead encourages more populist, extreme views by party leaders in order to let other groups look ‘bad’ and the own group best (Sisk 1999:41). Consociationalism, critics say, freezes wartime balances because political parties are formed along group boundary lines that reaffirm cleavages that played a role during conflict (Papagianni 2007:3031). This can obstruct long-term transformation of society because groups that participated in the conflict become competing political parties and are not stimulated to develop a relationship of trust and cooperation; groups do not build common identities different from wartime identities. The following critiques are based on this main critique. Another critique is that consociationalism is undemocratic (Papagianni 2007:29), because parties know they will be represented in government before elections take place. Guaranteed representation also means participation in conflict is rewarded since not participating in the conflict can mean no representation in government. Since leaders know they will be part of the government, they are less accountable in relation to their constituencies since their representation is already assured (Papagianni 2007:23, Sisk 1999:39). The third critique is based on the effects on the mutual veto. The veto can have the consequence that decision-making is slow and the chance for a political deadlock (when parties cannot agree with each other and one continues using its veto rights to block decision-making) is significant, which has for example happened in Bosnia after Dayton. The veto can also cause can create unwillingness of majorities to participate in a consociationalist system since they loose a lot of power to minorities, who in a majority system would not have been large enough to block decision-making by themselves (Horowitz 2008:1219). Critiques on consociationalism evolve around questions on long-term issues and theoretical disagreements about identity formation. Critics agree that consociationalism might be easier to implement (for example, Horowitz 2008:1223) but argue that implementing this theory will impede long-term peace and stability because groups do not transform along lines that were different form the group boundaries in conflict. Critiques on centripetalism evolve around two points. The most heard critique is that centripetalism is hard or impossible to implement in a deeply divided society. To demand from parties that have been fighting each other to interact and compromise during the very first stage of the constitutional process proves hard to implement in practice; voters are often unwilling to vote for any party but their own when conflict 8 recently ended, when differences between groups are perceived big and when trust between groups is minimal. As a consequence, there are very few empirical examples of centripetalism, especially when it comes to post-conflict societies (Sisk 1999:44). Horowitz agrees partly on this critique by noting; “warfare may be hard to end except on at least some consociational terms” (Horowitz 2008:1223). Favorable conditions for implementing power-sharing are often absent due to the adverse environments on the ground, a characteristic of most post-conflict societies (Schneckener 2002:218). Another critique is focused on the vulnerable position of minorities. In a centripetalist system minorities are not assured participation in government, and even though leaders need their support in order to be elected, it is not guaranteed that once a leader from a large group that includes majorities and minorities is elected, minorities will get the share of power they deserve (Sisk 1999:5,44). The critiques on centripetalism evolve around questions on short-term issues, in particular practical obstacles. Critical authors are often not explicitly “against” the centripetal idea, but argue that centripetalists fail to come up with a way to implement this theory in practice. 1.1.3 Power-Sharing Theory and the Case Studies Afghanistan and Iraq In this paragraph consociationalism and centripetalism will be used to explain the differences in powersharing agreements in Afghanistan and Iraq. When comparing power-sharing theories with the cases, Afghanistan shows important similarities with centripetalism, whereas power-sharing arrangements in Iraq show mainly consociationalist characteristics. This is clearly reflected in the governing and electoral system adopted in each country; Afghanistan adopted a majoritarian system with an alternative vote for presidential elections, Iraq has a parliament formed on basis of proportional representation with compensatory seats for minority parties (Norris 2008:29). To use consociationalism and centripetalism to explain differences in the constitutions of Afghanistan and Iraq would look like this: Afghani constitution-makers largely based power-sharing arrangements on “what should be done”, as they adopted a system that is hard to implement in a postconflict society with deep cleavages and minimal trust between groups. Iraqi constitution-makers based power-sharing arrangements on “what can be done”, as they adopted a system that impedes long-term stability since in this system it is likely that groups do not build common identities along lines that are different from the group boundaries in conflict. This answer is not satisfactory for three reasons. First of all, the answer merely explains which theory is easier to implement – not why differences exist. Secondly, power-sharing arrangements are not (only) based on power-sharing theory; if this was the case constitution-makers could choose the theory they think would be most successful and write the constitution accordingly, which in post-conflict societies does not happen. An observation by Donald Horowitz, which is reflected in the cases of Afghanistan and Iraq, is relevant at his point. Horowitz notes that in practice, contemporary post-conflict power-sharing agreements contain elements from both theories or implement only parts of either theory; there are no current post-conflict examples of one theory implemented as a whole (Horowitz 2008:1226). This is in line with Arend Lijphart’s observation that there 9 is no blueprint for a power-sharing agreement (Lijphart 1982:175). Because the power-sharing agreements of Afghanistan and Iraq are for a large part but not completely reflected in the two theories, conclusive answers on differences between the two constitutions can not be provided by centripetalism or consociationalism. As Horowitz notes, “partial innovations and hybrid outcomes may well be at the root of the inability to form conclusive judgments about contending prescriptions for inter-ethnic accommodation” (Horowitz 2008:1226). Finally, to explain why power-sharing arrangements are the way are (and thus why one is different from the other) would require a step-by-step analysis about how they were created. Powersharing theory does not pay attention to this; it takes the already adopted power-sharing agreement as a starting point for analysis and debate. 1.1.4 Conclusion on Consociationalism and Centripetalism This paragraph provided an insight in power-sharing theory and showed that the scholarly debate focuses on two power-sharing theories and their gaps and possible solutions, thereby trying to find an answer to the question that Timothy Sisk poses, “Which approach manages conflict best – one that essentially sees ethnic groups as building blocks of national politics in multi ethnic states [consociationalism], or one that purposefully encourages the formation of political blocs across group lines [centripetalism]” (Sisk 1999:13). Three conclusions on the main theories and current power-sharing debate can be made. First of all, consociationalism and centripetalism are used as the two corner stones for the scholarly debate. Most scholars favor one theory and make recommendations for improvement, while criticizing the “other” theory. Scholars use power-sharing arrangements as a starting point for debate by looking at what factors are in- or excluded, what went wrong and what succeeded after adoption and how failure or success can be explained by looking at the constitution or the post-adoption implementation process. Secondly, similarities between the two theories are consequences of the fact that all power-sharing theory has to deal with the inand exclusion of groups, which leads to assumptions about social identity formation. Thirdly, the scholarly debate showed that critiques on consociationalism focus on the theoretical question “what should be done” and argue the ideological fundaments and long-term durability of this theory is questionable. The critics on centripetalism focus on the practical question “what can be done” and argue that the proposed arrangements of centripetalism are, in practice, hard or impossible to implement in a post-conflict society. As for the case studies, power-sharing theory cannot explain the differences in the power-sharing arrangements in Afghanistan and Iraq in a satisfactory way because of three reasons. First of all, conclusive answers cannot be found using the two theories since neither the Afghan nor the Iraqi arrangements fully reflect those theories. Secondly, power-sharing literature bases analysis of power-sharing agreements on the content of the actual agreement and the post-adoption period; the question how differences in the agreement itself can be explained remains unanswered. Finally, even though power-sharing theory leads to interesting insight in what power-sharing constitutions “should look like” in theory or “can look like” in practice, the debate is stuck as it poses theoretical obstacles versus practical implications, which only leads to conclusions on which approach is easier to implement, not in how differences can be explained. For 10 these reasons, current power-sharing theory is not used to explain differences in power-sharing agreements in Afghanistan and Iraq. In the next paragraph another way of looking at power-sharing constitutions, and its possible use for explaining differences, will be introduced. 1.2 The Constitutional Process and Power-Sharing In this paragraph an alternative way of explaining differences in power-sharing arrangements, namely through analyzing the constitutional process, will be discussed. First the definition and relevance of “process” will be explained, secondly how process is addressed in current power-sharing theory, and finally how it can be used in this research as a framework to explain the differences in the constitutions in Iraq and Afghanistan. 1.2.1 Definition and Relevance of Process One of the conclusions drawn when explaining differences in power-sharing arrangements in Afghanistan and Iraq by using consociationalism and centripetalism was that power-sharing theory is never the same as practice and that therefore power-sharing theory alone is not sufficient to explain differences in powersharing agreements. The following statement by Donald Horowitz is related to that observation and addresses the relevance of process. Horowitz writes: [If partial innovations and hybrid outcomes are at the root of the inability to form conclusive judgments about power-sharing theory,] “constitutional processes and their impact on the adoptability of contending designs are the neglected elements in debates about measures to promote interethnic cooperation” (Horowitz 2008:1226). In other words, processes preceding power-sharing arrangements are crucial for power-sharing theory because any issue regarding powersharing has to be decided upon during this process before it can be adopted as part of the constitution. According to Horowitz, power-sharing agreements are a combination of the process leading up to the power-sharing agreement and the institutional arrangements eventually adopted. Focusing exclusively on institutional arrangements (the adopted power-sharing arrangements), as most power-sharing literature does, would be neglecting the dynamics of the process in which power-sharing agreements are adopted (Horowitz 2008:1225-1231). Therefore, in order explain why power-sharing arrangements are different from each other, studying the process that led to those arrangements can prove relevant. The definition of process according to the Compact English Oxford Dictionary is: “a series of actions or steps towards a particular end”. A constitutional process can be defined as a series of actions or steps towards a constitution, or more specifically towards political power-sharing arrangements. Power-sharing arrangements consist of a number of political arrangements, which were defined as “regulations regarding the executive and government levels” in the introduction of this research. Therefore the “actions or steps” towards political power-sharing arrangements are the regulations regarding government and executive levels - all these regulations together form the power-sharing arrangement. The groups or individuals that have decision-making power during the constitutional process decide upon these regulations, and therefore these groups or individuals can play a crucial role during the constitutional process. 11 1.2.2 Process in Existing Power-Sharing Theory In power-sharing literature Donald Horowitz is the only author who, only recently, paid attention to processes preceding power-sharing arrangements (Horowitz: 2008). Horowitz noted that coherence and developments during constitutional processes are adversaries, as one thing is “traded” for another during negotiations with the result of a “bargained” outcome. Further on he explains that the process of constitution-making is often not done with the goal of ending conflict or implementing the centripetal or consociationalist approach, but with the goal of meeting time and cost limitations and getting the parties to agree upon terms: “Constitution-making is not typically as much a deliberative process as it is a negotiating process” (Horowitz 2008:1230). The outcome of a negotiating process is likely to differ significantly from what would be the best system according to power-sharing theories or from what would be most effective for long-term political stability, because stakes in power-sharing arrangements will depend on the role a group or elite played in negotiations, as opposed to what would be best for long-term stability. Other power-sharing scholars do pay some attention to process or constitution-making but do not analyze the process itself. There is a body of literature on “democratic constitution-making” that focuses on constitution-making and which describes prerequisites that would lead to democratically adopted, durable constitutions. The problem is that in severely divided societies these ideas are hard to implement, as this literature prescribes a “deeply participatory process” in situations when feeling towards other groups are adverse, and “transparency”, which is often impossible or counter-productive during negotiations (Horowitz 2008:1231-2). The power-sharing scholars Norris, Sisk and Schneckener acknowledge that the way in which power-sharing agreements are brokered influences the likelihood of success. They argue that power-sharing constitutions that are imposed by third parties seem less likely to survive and provide durable peace settlements (Norris 2008:30) and agreements should be indigenously arrived at, not as a result of too-heavy external pressure (Sisk 1999:xiv). The role of third parties should be limited to the role of assistant (Schneckener 2002:216). These conclusions are based on research that is focusing on what is wrong with the final arrangements, not on analyzing the process itself. Applying these conclusions and recommendations to the case studies of Afghanistan and Iraq does not explain the differences in the power-sharing arrangements, but does show the common obstacles both countries faced at the start of the constitutional process: whereas theory on democratic constitution-making prescribes an inclusive, transparent process and scholars on power-sharing argue that the role of external parties should be minimal and that arrangements should be indigenously arrived at, in Afghanistan and Iraq the constitutional process took place because of external intervention and external parties continued to play an influential role during the interim period. By analyzing the constitutional process it will become clear how these “obstacles” were dealt with. 1.3 Analyzing Constitutional Processes In this paragraph will be explained how the information acquired in this chapter will be used for analyzing constitutional processes in Afghanistan and Iraq in the following chapters. The purpose of this chapter was 12 to find a theoretical framework in which differences in power-sharing arrangements in Afghanistan and Iraq can be explained. In the first paragraph existing power-sharing theories were discussed and used to explain the differences between the power-sharing arrangements in Afghanistan and Iraq. As discussed in paragraph 1.1.4, differences could be explained on grounds of practical versus theoretical preferences of the constitution-makers, but the question why the arrangements were different remained unanswered. In the second part of this chapter it was argued that differences between power-sharing agreements can be explained by analyzing the constitutional process. The constitutional process is no central element in the current power-sharing debate, but all issues regarding political power-sharing have to be decided upon during this process. As a result of Horowitz’ division between process and institutions, the assumption was made that analyzing the constitutional process could be relevant in order to understand the composition of power-sharing arrangements and why they differ. The definition of the constitutional process is the first step in how to analyze constitutional processes in the next chapters. “Constitutional process” was defined as a series of regulations regarding the executive and government levels that together form a constitution or power-sharing agreement. As discussed in paragraph 1.2.1, the individuals and groups that are in the position to decide upon those regulations have decisive influence on the content of power-sharing arrangements: they decided who was involved in writing the constitution, it was some of them that were in the position to change it and that could decided who was involved. Therefore those individuals and groups will be the main objects of study when analyzing constitutional processes. In the next two chapters the constitutional processes in Afghanistan and Iraq will be analyzed by discussing the role of the most influential internal actors and groups in relation to factors that shaped the political situation in the interim period. In Afghanistan these factors were: the goals of the US, the political dynamics between centre and periphery, decision-making during the Bonn Conference, the role of the international community and the role of Hamid Karzai. In Iraq, these factors were: the role of the US and Iraqi ownership, the role of the UN and international community, the exclusion of the Sunni Arabs and the ethnicization of Iraqi politics. While discussing these factors, the focus will be on which groups and actors were involved, what the (trends in) relations between them looked like, who exercised power and how, and what their influence was on the process and the power-sharing arrangements eventually adopted. This analysis will result in an overview of the constitutional process that led to the power-sharing arrangements. 13 Chapter 2: Afghanistan In this chapter and in chapter 3, the constitutional processes of Afghanistan and Iraq will be analyzed with the goal of explaining differences between their power-sharing arrangements. In order to clarify the context in which the constitutional process took place, the first paragraphs are descriptive and include a timeline of the interim period, an overview of the power-sharing arrangement that was eventually adopted and an introduction of the local groups involved. In the fourth paragraph, the constitutional process will be analyzed. Finally, the findings of this chapter will be presented in the last paragraph. 2.1 Overview Interim Period On 7 October 2001, troops from the US and the United Kingdom (UK) invaded Afghanistan as part of ‘Operation Enduring Freedom’. The invasion was a response to a series of suicide attacks by Al Qaeda on the United States that took place on 11 September 2001. The ruling party in Afghanistan since 1996, the Taliban, had provided a safe haven for Al Qaeda, an Islamic extremist movement. Following the invasion, the Taliban fled the capital Kabul on 12 November. After nearly three decades of conflict, government institutions had to be build up from scratch (Fukuyama 2006:3). Afghanistan was one of the poorest and weakest governed countries worldwide and had not had a strong central government for decades (ICG 27/11/01). Therefore, after the toppling of the Taliban there were two main issues that needed to be addressed in the political arena: the establishment of a transitional government that would govern the country until elections could take place, and the drafting of a new constitution on basis of which elections could be held. These issues were addressed under United Nations (UN) auspices during the Bonn Conference, which started in the end of November 2001. Lakhdar Brahimi, the UN Special Representative of the Secretary General (SRSG) for Afghanistan, chaired the talks. Nine days after the start of the Conference the Bonn Agreement was established (Rubin 2004:6). The Bonn Agreement included a timeline for a new constitution and elections, and prescribed the way the country would be governed until a permanent government could be elected. The Afghan Interim Authority (AIA), appointed in Bonn, would govern the country for six months after Bonn (ICG 16/05/02:web). Hamid Karzai, a former deputy foreign minister who had been living in exile in Pakistan before the US-invasion, was appointed chairman. After six months an Afghan Transitional Administration (ATA) and an Interim President would replace the AIA. Members of the ATA and the interim president would be elected through an Emergency Loya Jirga (ELJ), a traditional Afghan decisionmaking process. The ATA and Interim President would govern the country until a new government was elected (elections required an adopted constitution that defined electoral systems and state structures). The constitutional process was partly linked to the timeline of the political process. Participants in Bonn adopted a transitional constitution that would be in place until a new constitution was adopted. After the ELJ took place, the constitutional process had to start. The Interim President, assisted by the UN, had to appoint a “Drafting Commission” and a “Constitutional Commission” that were tasked with drafting the 14 constitution and with public education and consultations on the draft, and a “Review Commission” that had to review the draft (ICG 12/06/03:13-15). The draft from the Review Commission was presented to the interim president before it was made public, and the final draft had to be presented to a Constitutional Loya Jirga (CLJ), which had to debate and approve the constitution (ICG 16/05/02:1). The maximum period between the ELJ and the CLJ was 18 months. The constitution was adopted on 24 January 2004. The timelines of the political and constitutional process formed the basis of the interim period. An overview of the interim period and the political and constitutional processes is displayed in figure 1. Figure 1: Overview Interim Period Afghanistan Political process Afghan Interim Authority (AIA) Emergency Loya Jirga (ELJ) Timeline Constitutional process Bonn Agreement Transitional Constitution Nov-Dec 2001 December 2001 June 2002 Afghan Transitional Administration (ATA)* Drafting Commission/ Constitutional Commission/ Review Commission Final Draft after review by Karzai Constitutional Loya Jirga (CLJ) Oct. ’02Sept. ‘03 November 2003 December 2003 Permanent Constitution January 2004 * The ATA governed the country until a permanent government was elected on the basis of the permanent constitution. Presidential elections took place in October 2004. 2.2 Outcome: The Constitution “No meaningful power-sharing is envisaged either within the national government or between central and provincial governments” (ICG 12/12/03:11) After the constitutional process, the Constitutional Loya Jirga approved the draft constitution on 4 January 2004. It was officially signed and promulgated by Interim President Karzai on 26 January 2004. The outcome of the constitution will shortly be discussed in this chapter, with a focus on the type of powersharing system, regulations regarding the executive and government levels constitutional arrangements, the basic type of electoral system, type of presidential or parliamentary executive and division of power between central government and regions. The goal of this paragraph is to explain where the constitutional process led to regarding power-sharing arrangements. 15 The electoral system adopted is a majoritarian presidential system with a single vote. The executive consists of a President who is elected through the alternative vote system, and two Vice Presidents (Norris 2008:29-30, Rubin 2004:5). The President is commander-in-chief of the armed forces and appoints, with approval of the Lower House, the judges of the Supreme Court, ministers, the attorney general and the director of the Central Bank. The constitution prescribed a National Assembly in the form of a bicameral parliament with a Lower House (Wolesi Jirga) and an Upper House (Meshrano Jirga). The National Assembly lacked effective power to constrain the President. In December 2003, International Crisis Group wrote on the proposed constitution that “given the level of political fragmentation in Afghanistan and the limited prospect any party will emerge from parliamentary elections with a strong majority, a near complete absence of mechanisms through which to share power and the lacks of checks on the executive are likely to destabilize” (ICG 12/12/03:5). The constitution laid out a highly centralized administration with considerable decision-making in the presidency and executive, checked by weak legislature (Norris 2008:29-30, Rubin 2004:5). As for minorities, regulations for representation of specific groups were not included in the constitution, and the constitution banned the formation of political parties based on ethnic, regional, linguistic or regional affiliation, or connected to armed organizations. With a focus on central institutions, little attention was devoted to administrative structures at the sub-national level, and the constitution did not address centre-province relations (ICG 12/12/05:5). Although the power-sharing arrangements in Afghanistan correspond for a large part with the centripetalist approach discussed in the first chapter, it lacks comprehensive power-sharing mechanisms (such as electoral rules that provide protection to minorities and that include incentives for moderates). Therefore, the power-sharing system adopted in Afghanistan has more characteristics of a majoritarian system, in which the majority rules without being constitutionally constrained by electoral regulations, then a centripetalist system. 2.3 Local Actors and Groups There are many different ways in which a population can be divided in groups. In this paragraph, the actors and groups that played an influential role during the interim period in Afghanistan will be introduced. The main ethnic groups in Afghanistan are the Pashtun, the Tajik, the Hazara and the Uzbek. Afghanistan is a fractured nation and each of these ethnic groups consists of numerous factions and subgroups. The groups described below do not consist solely of the ethnic groups or sub-groups described; they overlap. The Pashtun community is the largest ethnic group in Afghanistan, although it is unclear whether they form a majority. Estimates vary between 38% (according to the Independent Loya Jirga commission) and 60-70% (according to Pashtun records) (Rubin 2004:11, ICG 16/05/02:9-10). Since its foundation in 1747, Afghanistan is mostly ruled by (factions of) Pashtuns (Simonsen 2004:709). During the Taliban rule 16 the Pashtuns did not clearly oppose the regime and were therefore labelled as “supporters of the Taliban” by the Northern Alliance (ICG 16/05/02:4). The Northern Alliance (NA) (original name Islamic United Front for the Salvation of Afghanistan) is an organization founded on common opposition during the Taliban regime that consists of mainly three ethnic groups. The NA mobilized themselves years before the US-invasion in 2001. The NA was a strong ally of the US and backed by the US/UK-led coalition they re-took Kabul in November 2001 (Rubin 2004). Its composition is dominated by three ethnic groups; the Tajiks (27% of the population), the Hazara (9%) and the Uzbeks (8%) (CIA World Factbook). The Panshiri are a sub-faction of the Tajiks that played an influential role in the constitutional process, mainly because of the fact that they took over key positions immediately after the Taliban had been forced to flee Kabul, which proved to be a strong negotiation position in Bonn. The Rome Group is a group that participated in Bonn but that did not have any political or military organization on the ground before the invasion. The group consists mostly of exiles, among which was former king Muhammed Zahir Shah. Zahir Shah, originally a Pashtun, was the last King of Afghanistan in 1933. He was overthrown by a coup in 1973 and had lived in Rome ever since. The Rome Group played an important role in drafting the transitional constitution (Rubin 2004:6, ICG 16/05/02:12). The Taliban was the ruling party in Afghanistan between 1996 and October 2001. The Taliban is an ultraconservative Islamic extremist faction, and provided refuge for al-Qaeda. The Taliban was originally from Pashtun areas. After the US-led invasion, many fled to the Pakistan border area. Neither the Taliban nor al-Qaeda was party to the Bonn-Agreement (Rubin 2006:180). During the three decades of conflict before 2001, and especially under the rule of the Taliban, many local military leaders or warlords such as the mujahidin militia unofficially controlled small parts of the country, mainly through military means. The last local group that played a large role in the constitutional process is the Loya Jirga. The Loyal Jirga is not an established group but a gathering of hundreds Afghan representatives drawn from, for example, settled and nomadic population, refugees and diasporas, civil society organizations and intellectuals. Loya Jirgas are a traditional form of community decision-making, used in Afghanistan at key moments in its history. There are no established rules or procedures, and there is no protocol for the (s)election of its membership (ICG 16/05/02:7). Loya Jirgas have been involved with the drafting of each of Afghanistan’s former constitutions and have assisted during key national decisions. During the interim period after the US-invasion, two Loya Jirgas were held; one to elect a transitional administration, the Emergency Loya Jirga (ELJ), and one to debate and adopt the constitution, the Constitutional Loya Jirga (CLJ). The Emergency Loya Jirga consisted of 1,500 delegates, the Constitutional Loya Jirga of a little over 500. The Loya Jirgas during the interim period were meant to legitimize the process of establishing a representative government (Rubin 2004:7, Dobbins 2003:132). 17 2.4 The Constitutional Process In this paragraph the constitutional process in Afghanistan will be analyzed, as explained in paragraph 1.3, by looking at the role of the most influential internal actors and groups. While discussing the role of the most influential actors and groups, the focus will be on the (trends in) inter-group relations, who exercised most power and how, and what their influence was on the power-sharing arrangements eventually adopted. The role of local actors and groups will be explained by discussing the following factors, which shaped the constitutional process in Iraq: The goals of the US, political dynamics between centre and periphery, decision-making during the Bonn Conference, the role of the international community, and the role of Hamid Karzai on constitution-making. 2.4.1 Decision-making During Bonn Government institutions and a constitutional process had to be built from scratch. The first decisions on these issues were made during the Bonn Conference. Several decisions made in Bonn influenced the constitutional process. First of all, even though the establishment of a “fully representative government” was the main goal of the political process laid out in the Bonn Agreement, the Afghan signatories to the agreement were not representative of the Afghan people. Only four Afghan groups, all of who supported the invasion, participated: the NA and the Rome Group, and two smaller ad-hoc groups based in Pakistan and Iran (Rubin 2006:184, Dobbins 2003:130). This meant that the Tajiks, Hazaras and Uzbeks were overrepresented, while the Pashtuns, although in a way represented by the Rome Group, were underrepresented. Members of the Taliban and numerous local leaders were excluded from the talks. SRSG Lakhdar Brahimi, who led the talks, was aware of the uneven representation and stressed that an inclusive constitutional process was a priority. The establishment of Loya Jirga’s was meant to increase the legitimacy of the constitutional process and make the governing institutions representative of the population (Rubin 2006:180, Starr 2006:118). Before the ELJ convened, there were several problems with the selection of representatives regarding electoral districts and population numbers, public information, intimidation and keeping out commanders of local militias (ICG 16/05/02:10, Rubin 2004:10). In 1963, electoral districts were drawn, according to non-Pashtuns in favour of the Pashtuns; the districts that were mainly populated by Pashtuns were drawn smaller, so that a one-representative-per-district situation, the Pashtuns would be over-represented (ICG 16/05/02:9). Public information structures were absent, and widespread intimidation marred selection of candidates for Emergency Loya Jirga. When the ELJ convened in June 2002 to elect a head of state and to approve structure and key personnel of a transitional administration that would take over from the AIA, delegates complained that they did not vote on the new structure and key personnel, and that the new administration was not significantly more representative then the AIA (Rubin 2004:9, ICG 16/05/02:web). During negotiations regarding the governing institutions that would be put in place after Bonn, the Rome Group made an important compromise with the Tajik/Panshiris (ICG 16/05/02:12). The 18 Tajik/Panshiri faction had a strong negotiation position at the Bonn Conference because they had started placing its own candidates in key posts after the Taliban forces had fled, and they controlled the intelligence service (Rubin 2004:8). In exchange for granting the Tajik/Panshiris the three most powerful ministerial posts in the Afghan Interim Administration (Defence, Interior, Foreign Affairs), the Tajik/Panshiris would allow the exiled former king Zahir Shah of the Rome Group to return to Afghanistan. The six-month mandate of the AIA gave the Tajik/Panshiris considerable time to consolidate power (ICG 16/05/01:12, Dobbins 2003:130). As a consequence, similar to the critiques on the participants of the Bonn Conference, he AIA was criticized for not being representative of the Afghan population (Starr 2006:118). Thirdly, in Bonn was decided that the “basic law”, the constitution that was implemented by King Shah in 1964, functioned as a basis for the interim constitution (Bonn:Art.II.1), and many elements were copied in the eventually adopted constitution - even though this constitution had, at the time, not been able to establish a stable government (Rubin 2004:8,10). In other words, both major groups, the Rome Group and the NA, took advantage of their powerful positions in Bonn. A fourth element is the “political party law” that was included in the Interim Constitution (ICG 12/06/03:27-28). This law made it hard for new political parties to enter the political field because it outlawed any political party that was based on ethnicity, whereas the political parties already existed - and that were included in the political process - were often based on ethnicity. In other words, Afghan politics were already ethnicized before the “political party law”, and the political parties law limited the chances for moderates to enter the political arena (ICG 12/12/03:5, ICG 12/06/03:28). With regard to power-sharing, decisions taken during the Bonn Conference were made by a group not representative of the population, with an emphasis on exiles. In particular the Panshiri faction, who took over government buildings after the Taliban had fled, had a powerful position in Bonn, which resulted in an over-representation in the interim administration. The political party law made it hard for any party to enter the political arena after the Bonn Agreement. 2.4.2 US Role/Warlords Removing the Taliban regime, capturing Al Qaeda leaders and a cessation of terrorist activities in Afghanistan were the objectives of the US at the time of the invasion (Fukuyama 2006:12, ICG 27/11/01). The invasion of Afghanistan was executed in a short time; there was less then a month between the attacks on 11 September and the start of the invasion. The US did not have an outline or plan for the post-invasion period, as the planning document for post-intervention reconstruction that was established under President Clinton, ‘Complex Contingency Operations’, was not renewed nor replaced (Presidential Decision Directive 56, in: Dobbins 2003:138). After the invasion, the US had the leading role in military reorganization and focused on counter-terrorism. The role of the US regarding the political process was limited; on 1 October 2001, President Bush announced that the US supported a UN-coordinated political transition and reconstruction program (Rubin 2004:6, Fukuyama 2006:13). During the first two years after 19 the intervention - almost the whole constitutional process - the US did not take on any peacekeeping or political responsibilities (Dobbins 2003:133). Although the US did not play a direct role in the political process, they did influence the political process, mainly in three ways. First of all, the US was responsible for “pentagon-created warlords” (ICG 15/03/02:4). In order to win support for the counter-terrorism objectives, the US sponsored local militias, who used this income to mobilize patronage networks into armed groups and to take control over land and illegal economic gains. Due to the collapsed state infrastructure the power vacuum created by departure of the Taliban was filled by expanding power of these warlords, instead of the Transitional Administration - while support of these leaders for the ATA was crucial in order to centralize the state and implement policies effectively (ICG 30/07/02:8). Thus, the goals of the counter-terrorism agenda of the US enhanced the influence of the local militias and undermined the legitimacy of the ATA (Starr 2006:113, Dobbins 2003:144). Secondly, the US influenced the political process through their position on expansion of the International Security Assistance Force (ISAF), an international assistance force established by the UN Security Council (and taken over by NATO in 2003) that was mandated with providing security so that the political process would not be hindered. Establishment of ISAF had been decided upon at the Bonn Conference. The mandate of ISAF was Kabul-focused. Although there was a growing call from the AIA and ATA for a broader mandate outside Kabul, before October 2003 the US vetoed ISAF expansion several times in the UN Security Council because of possible ISAF-interference with US counter-terrorism efforts. Consequently, there was no multinational presence in the rest of the country until October 2003, which was almost at the end of the constitutional process (Dobbins 2003:135-137). Thirdly, on the ground a (perceived) US influence regarding the electoral system and other constitutional issues became prevalent during the constitutional process. Since Karzai was both the interim head of state involved with the constitution-making process, and as widely known the favoured candidate of the US for future Afghan president, the perception that the constitution would only serve the interests of Karzai, the US and rest of the international community became prevalent – even more so because there was a lack of transparency during the constitution-making process (Shah 2004:4). Karzai was increasingly seen as a puppet of the US, which undermined his legitimacy (ICG 16/05/02:15). The fact that Karzai appointed two Afghans who had US-citizenship in the cabinet of the AIA, strengthened this view. With regard to power-sharing, the main problem regarding US decision-making is that the US did not take the political situation and constitutional process into consideration, as it was not part of their agenda or mandate. During most of the constitutional process, US-policies regarding security and counter-terrorism did influence political developments, but political developments in Afghanistan did not influence US policy. As part of its counter-terrorism efforts, the US sponsored warlords that undermined the legitimacy of the government and the attention for the constitutional process outside Kabul. ISAF could not provide security or enhance visibility outside Kabul because its mandate was limited, and the US blocked expansion for the main time of the interim period. It was in the second half of 2003 that the US took on 20 more responsibilities regarding the political process through a major policy shift in Washington, but the influence of this shift on the constitutional process, which was almost at its end, is debatable. 2.4.3 Centre-Periphery Relationship During the constitutional process, the gap between the capital and the rest of the country widened. Although the interim constitution prescribed a centralized system, away from the capital the influence of the central government was minimal and showed an increasing gap between grass roots realities and constitutional rules (Rubin 2004:8). Local leaders filled the power gap and increased in popularity. There are several explanations for this. Two important ones are named in the last paragraph; the increase in power and of local militias that were sponsored by the US, and the mandate of ISAF that was limited to Kabul. Another argument is that the interim constitution is responsible for the gap between cities and provinces, since it prescribed a very centralized form of governing – something hard to realize in a fractured nation like Afghanistan that had not had a strong government for decades (ICG 15/02/02:8). The interim constitution did not only include political centralization, it also stated that armed groups had to come under control of the AIA and ATA - an extremely difficult process in itself, complicated by US counter-terrorism efforts. With regard to power-sharing, the increasing gap between centre and periphery meant that national politics and the constitutional process became something capital-oriented, instead of a national process. Since the population outside the capital did not see any government influence or changes made by the government, the notions power-sharing and constitution became something obsolete for the population that did not live in the capital, especially because the power vacuum was filled by local militia with their own laws and regulations. 2.4.4 UN/International Community Even though the UN had the lead in the political process, its influence after Bonn was small and it had more an advisory role then anything else since it had a limited presence with a mandate focused on the capital. During the constitutional process there was a very modest presence of the international community; a small ISAF/NATO force and a UN mission that was not capable of effectively leading the transitional political process. The initial decision to deploy ISAF forces only in Kabul was hard to change at a later stage since the US blocked expansion efforts until the end of the constitutional process was near, even though in the rest of the international community the idea that ISAF presence should be expanded was widely supported. The idea behind expansion was that ISAF presence throughout the country could make Afghans hesitant to resort to force (like it did in Kabul), and could in that way provide political space to for transitional administration (ICG 15/03/02:3). During the interim period the international community stayed neutral and did not undertake much action towards groups that were undermining the political process (ICG 30/07/02:16), as the focus was 21 more on security then on a legitimate political process (Starr 2006:108). External players did play a role in the reconstruction process and had mandates focused on different areas of reconstruction. However, during the interim period the international community was operating without having a coherent strategy (Rubin 2006:176). This influenced the political process as support for it was heavily dependent on efforts beyond Karzai’s scope such as demobilizing militias and eradicating drugs trade (Rubin 2004:6). With regard to power-sharing, the international community did not have enough leverage to significantly influence the constitutional process. The UN was criticized for not playing a large enough role, and the international community did not influence US-counter terrorism activities. The effect of several external countries taking part in the reconstruction efforts was minimal for the political process, as the lack of central government and, for example, the demobilization of militias were negatively influenced by each other’s lack of performance. 2.4.5 Hamid Karzai and Drafting the Constitution Through the constitutional process, Hamid Karzai has been chair of the AIA and Interim President. In these positions, had considerable influence on the constitutional process. Two examples of his influence are his role regarding the constitution commissions and his role in debate whether or not to include a Prime Minister in the new government, and whether to adopt a parliamentary or presidential system. The constitution-making process included different Constitutional Commissions (as to be seen in figure 1). The drafting commission was tasked with preparing the first draft, the Constitutional Commission with finalizing the draft and holding public consultations (that were aimed at increasing the legitimacy of the draft), and the review commission to prepare to final draft before it was presented to Karzai. Hamid Karzai appointed all three commissions without existence of any criteria regarding its members and without a public document that listed responsibilities and obligations (ICG 12/06/03:13). As a result, members of the ATA, in particular of the Panshiri-faction, dominated the commissions (ICG 12/06/03:16). Another example of his influence becomes clear when looking at Karzai’s role regarding the type of electoral system. In April 2003, the Drafting Commission completed initial draft of the constitution that reflected, like the interim constitution, many elements of the 1964-constitution (Rubin 2004:10). The draft proposal included a semi-presidential system, with a directly elected Pashtun president and a non-Pashtun prime minister in order to keep ethnic balance. In this version, executive power would be shared between the Prime Minister and the President. The Constitution Review Commission, inaugurated by Karzai through a Presidential Decree, reviewed the text (Shah 2004:2). The final draft was presented to President Karzai on 3 September. One month later, on 3 November 2003, the draft was made public (Shah 2004:3, Rubin 2004:10). There were important differences between the versions of the Drafting Commission and the version that was published after Karzai reviewed and changed it (ICG 12/12/03:3). The main difference was that in Karzai’s draft there was no longer a Prime Minister. A vice president, who would only have executive power in case the president would die, replaced the post of Prime Minister (Rubin 2004:12). 22 During the Constitutional Loya Jirga in December 2003 there were different opinions regarding the changes to be made in the proposed constitution regarding power-sharing. The Northern Alliance was the main opposition group to the proposed draft. The NA and a number of smaller groups campaigned for a greater check on presidential powers through a parliamentary system and a prime minister (Shah 2004:7). The Tajik/Panshiris advocated for power-sharing at the central level, and the Uzbeks and Hazaras wanted recognition of their identities and mechanisms for local self-government (Rubin 2004:11). The main argument of the group opposing the draft was that with a strong president the risk for ethnic dictatorship would be enlarged, and that a parliamentary system would lead to coalition governments that would be more inclusive and thus more stable (Rubin 2004:12). Karzai and his supporters, mostly but not only Pashtuns, argued that a strong president was needed because of the absence of political accommodation between parties and since the ethnic divide had widened; too much power-sharing, as with a parliamentary system, would obstruct state-building and efficient decision-making. Moreover, for Pashtuns the choice for a presidential system with a Pashtun president was seen as the preferable outcome, especially because they say the outcome of the Bonn Agreement as a “compromise”: since Pashtuns formed a majority of the population, they would relatively lose the most in a power-sharing system as opposed to a majoritarian system, something that already had happened in Bonn (Rubin 2004:12). According to Karzai, a parliament would be a “fragmented body controlled by warlords”; participation in parliament would provide warlords with funds that could be used for more support, which would make an even more divided political culture in a time when Afghanistan needed a strong government (Rubin 2004:13, Shah 2004:7-8). Because of the support of the majority of the Pashtuns for a strongly centralized state with a strong President, Karzai’s supporters formed a majority in the CLJ (Shah 2007:7). Another issue of disagreement was the appointment of cabinet positions holding dual citizenship, which had been the case in the ATA for the Interior Minister and the Finance Minister. During the public consultations, a strong disagreement was expressed and a ban on minister with dual citizenship was requested. However, Karzai and the international community were against the ban. Eventually it was decided that if the President appointed a Minister with dual citizenship, the Lower House (Wolesi Jirga) had to vote on it, which had not much meaning as that was the was the case for any minister (Rubin 2004:13). During the CLJ, changes and compromises were made regarding differences but when it came to power-sharing arrangements, the final draft that was approved did not significantly differ from Karzai’s draft. Hamid Karzai had a big influence with regard to power-sharing. His decisive role in appointing members of the constitutional commissions shows his influential role in steering constitution-making, but even more crucial were the changes that he made after reviewing the final draft that was presented to him by the final (review) commission. Karzai’s preferences were clearly reflected in the constitution that was finally adopted, especially with regard to the type of executive and division of powers. Two factors contributed by 23 the powerful role Karzai played; first of all, he was the favoured candidate by the US, and his aims for strong Presidential powers did not raise objections from the US-side. Secondly, Karzai was from Pashtun origin, the largest ethnic group in Afghanistan. Because of strong Pashtun support during the CLJ, the proposed constitution was eventually adopted. 2.5 Findings The purpose of this chapter was to analyze the constitutional process by looking at the role of different local actors and groups during the interim period. Their role had been discussed by looking into decisions made during the Bonn Conference, the role of the US and the international community, the role of Hamid Karzai and the increasing gap between centre and periphery were discussed. At the end of each paragraph a short summary on how the issue related to- or influenced power-sharing was given. Although all factors discussed are interrelated, the most distinct characteristic of the constitution, the (unusual) strong position of the president, was mostly influenced and made possible because of two factors. First of all, the support of the president’s ethnic group, the Pashtuns, was crucial - they formed a majority in Afghanistan and wanted to consolidate power. Secondly, the US and the international community favoured Karzai for president and did not object to strong presidential powers. The fact that a centralized system was adopted in the end and the fact that the constitution did not address centre-province relations can be seen as a consequence of the increasing gap between centre and periphery. This increasing gap can be explained by the limited mandate of ISAF and the increasing power of US-sponsored warlords as opposed to the central government. In short, the outcome of the constitutional process was a set of power-sharing arrangements that were favoured by the groups and actors that played the most influential role during the interim period. These local actors and groups could play such a powerful role because they were empowered during the constitutional process by being included from the beginning (for example the Panshiri faction) and by support from the international community (such as Karzai). 24 Chapter 3: Iraq This chapter has the same purpose and set-up as the previous chapter; to analyze the constitutional processes of Iraq with the goal of explaining differences between the power-sharing arrangements in Afghanistan and Iraq. In order to clarify the context in which the constitutional process took place, the first paragraphs are descriptive and include a timeline of the interim period, an overview of the power-sharing arrangement eventually adopted and an introduction of the local groups involved. In the fourth paragraph, the constitutional process will be analyzed. Finally, the findings of this chapter will be presented in the last paragraph. 3.1 Overview Interim Period On 20 March 2003, US-led coalition forces invaded Iraq as a consequence of Iraq’s alleged possession of weapons of mass destruction that, according to the US, posed a threat to the western world. The objective of the invasion was to turn Iraq into a democracy, which was seen as start of a much larger goal; to transform politics in the Middle East (Fukuyama 2006:3). On 9 April Baghdad fell when the ruling Ba’ath party was toppled and Iraqi President Saddam Hussein fled. After the invasion, Iraq was occupied and governed by the “Coalition Provisional Authority” (CPA) that was led by the US. Even though the CPA appointed an Iraqi Interim Governing Council (IGC) in July 2003, it kept all decision-making power and was actively governing Iraq until June 2004. The first steps regarding an Iraqi political and constitutional process were taken in the November Agreement of 2003 between the CPA and the IGC. This agreement included a timeline regarding the transfer of sovereignty from the CPA to an Iraqi Interim Government in June 2004 (ICG 22/12/04:4). Prior to this date a transitional constitution, which would take effect when the Interim Government was established, had to be drafted and adopted by the IGC. The transitional constitution laid out further steps towards a permanent constitution After the November Agreement the constitutional process consisted of two parts; firstly the drafting and adopting of a transitional constitution, secondly the drafting of a permanent constitution. The transitional constitution, named Transitional Administrative Taw (TAL), was adopted by the IGC and would take effect in June 2004, when sovereignty was handed over to an Interim Iraqi Government (ICG:08/04/04). The TAL would function as the constitution until a permanent constitution would be adopted. The next step was the establishment of a permanent constitution. The TAL prescribed that a democratically elected Transitional National Assembly (TNA) would draft the permanent constitution. The TNA was elected in January 2005 and had to submit a draft constitution by 15 August 2005. The draft would be adopted through a referendum no later then 15 October 2005. In regard to the political process, it was decided in the November Agreement that power would be handed over to the Iraqi Interim Government by 30 June 2004. The TAL set out a timeline for the political process after June 2004. Elections for a Transitional National Assembly (TNA) were to be held no later then January 2005. Apart from drafting a permanent constitution, the main task of the TNA was to appoint 25 a transitional government. In April 2005 this transitional government was appointed and took over from the Interim Government. The transitional government would rule the country until elections for a permanent parliamentary assembly and government under the new constitution were held (ICG 22/12/04:7). The constitution was adopted through a referendum on 15 October 2005. The November Agreement and the TAL set out the timelines for the constitutional and political process in the interim period. An overview of the interim period and the political and constitutional processes is displayed in figure 2. Political process Figure 2: Overview Interim Period Iraq Central Provisional Authority (CPA) Interim Governing Council (IGC) Iraqi Interim Government Transitional Government* Timeline Constitutional process November Agreement Central Provisional Authority (CPA) April 2003 July 2003 November 2003 Transitional Admin. Law (TAL) Transitional National Assembly (TNA), through elections June 2004 January 2005 Permanent Constitution April 2005 October 2005 * The transitional government governed the country until a permanent government was elected on basis of the permanent constitution. Presidential elections took place in December 2005. 3.2 Outcome: The Constitution “A sectarian document that both marginalized and alienated the Sunni Arab community” (ICG 27/02/06) When the constitution was adopted on 15 October 2005, Iraq became an Islamic federal democracy. The electoral system adopted is was a parliamentary system with proportional representation plus compensatory seats for minority parties, with a Prime Minister as head of a multiparty coalition government. Executive power was divided between the Prime Minister and an indirectly elected three-person Presidential Council. A high level of decentralization with four levels of government characterized the constitution: the central government in Baghdad, and the regional, provincial and local administrations. The powers of the central government were reduced to defence, foreign policy, and fiscal and customs policy - the rest was deferred to the regional or local levels (ICG 16/09/05:i-ii). Three crucial issues for Sunni Arabs were rejected in the constitution. First of all, the draft included (a high degree of) federalism, a notion Arab Sunni’s rejected. Secondly, the de-Ba’athification 26 process was not eliminated, and finally, the national Arab identity was denied by the words in which it was put in the constitution (“its Arab people are part of the Arab nation”, ICG 26/09/05:6-9). Apart from these provisions, the constitution did not show consensus, since all major issues were left out or vaguely described (Norris 2008:29-30). Many crucial issues were not decided upon but were either deferred to the permanent National Assembly (that still had to be elected), or they were tackled in a vague way (ICG 26/09/05:1). Examples of issues that were deferred are: a specific definition of federalism and the exact division of powers between the centre and regions, details on how the regions will be formed - except for the Kurdish region and details on the procedures of key institutions (such as the presidential deputies, the supreme judicial council, the Federal Supreme Court) (ICG 26/09/05:6, Brown 13/12/05). A last minute compromise to get the Sunni Arabs on board included a provision that the constitution could be amended in the first six months of 2006, which decreased the legitimacy of the constitution. The Iraqi constitution included many consociational characteristics, with proportional representation, compensatory seats for minority parties and a multiparty system with a mixed type of executive. However, the Ba’ath party was outlawed and thus not represented, since many crucial issues were deferred, and since a major group was largely excluded from the constitution-making process, the constitution is a weak document (ICG 27/02/06:2). 3.3 Local Actors and Groups Iraq is a multi-ethnic and multi-religious society. The main ethnic groups are 75-80% Arabs, 25-20% Kurds and 5% other and the main religious groups are 97% Muslims (of which 60-65% Shia Arabs and 32-37% Sunni Arabs) and 3% Christian or other (CIA World Factbook). The main groups that played a political role during the interim period are Shia’s, Arab Sunni’s and Kurds – although these groups are no homogeneous communities but rather groups whose many factions follow different leaders (ICG 26/09/08:5). The Arab Shia’s (also called Shiite) are the largest community in Iraq. Several different factions from within the Shia community formed a political alliance, the United Iraqi Alliance (UIA). The UIA was led by Grand Ayatollah Ali al-Sistani. Al-Sistani was a moderate highly respected Shia cleric with a large following. He commented often on the political and constitutional process and was able to influence the political situation since he was be able to mobilize large crowds (27/04/04:4). The UIA won a majority of votes in the TNA elections (Phillips 2005:9). Shia’s legitimized their strong role in the constitutional process because they formed the largest group in Iraq (Brown 11/05:2). The Arab Sunni’s (“Arab” because the majority of Kurds is Sunni as well) were the most powerful community under Saddam Hussein’s regime, and were most affected by the invasion of the US and the toppling of the ruling Ba’ath party. Although the Ba’ath party was originally a party in which all religious denominations could participate, in practice Sunni Arabs dominated the party. There are three factions within the Arab Sunni group; the rejectionists (who want to restore power as under Saddam Hussein’s 27 regime), the Wahhabists and Salafists (who want a holy war against to US) and the moderates (who are tired of the insurgency and want minority rights and decentralized self-rule) (Phillips 2005:9). The Kurds is an ethno-linguistic community spread out over several Middle Eastern countries. In Iraq, the Kurds have a long history of repression by the state and, for decades, their main objective has been autonomy. David Phillips explains how the Kurds’ objective influenced their stance on the new Iraqi government and on the constitution. Phillips writes that the Kurds were “seeking enough concessions form Iraqi Arabs to justify their participation in an Iraqi state while, at the same time, building a system to become independent if opportunity arises” (Phillips 2005:11). This position influenced negotiations regarding power-sharing significantly; Kurds proved to only be prepared to postpone their main goal if their concerns were addressed (ICG 13/11/03:13-14). These concerns included secularism and the creation of a federal Iraqi state called Iraqi Kurdistan with Kirkuk as capital. 3.4 The Constitutional Process In this paragraph the constitutional process in Iraq will be analyzed in the same way as Afghanistan in the last chapter. When discussing the role of the most influential internal actors and groups, the focus will be on (trends in) inter-group relations, who exercised most power and how, and what their influence was on the power-sharing arrangements eventually adopted. The role of local actors and groups will be explained by discussing the following factors, which shaped the constitutional process in Iraq: the role of the US and Iraqi ownership, the role of the UN and international community, the exclusion of the Sunni Arabs and the ethnicization of Iraqi politics. 3.4.1 US Role and Iraqi Ownership The US role is larger then “a factor”; the US had complete governing authority through the Coalition Provisional Authority for thirteen months after the invasion. During this period, the US role was not an influence to the political process; it was the process. For power-sharing, this meant that the US decided which groups to in- or exclude in the political and constitutional process. The two main documents guiding the political and constitutional process during the interim period, the November Agreement and the TAL, were both put forward or heavily influenced by the US. Since the US played such an influential role in Iraq, its influence regarding power-sharing will be analyzed during two different stages; when the US was governing Iraq, and the role of the US when sovereignty was handed back to the Iraqis. The United States: Governing Iraq The post-invasion goal of the US was to turn Iraq into a model-nation for the region: a democratic, secular nation upholding free-market principles (ICG 22/12/04:28). Even though planning started a year before the invasion, the US post-war planning office that would coordinate reconstruction efforts was established less then two months before the invasion (Fukuyama 2006:11). This office, called the Office of Reconstruction and Humanitarian Assistance (ORHA), had prepared a blueprint for the governance of Iraq that was loosely 28 based on a document called the “Final Report on the Transition to Democracy in Iraq”, a document prepared in November 2002 by a group of 32 Iraqi exiles that lived in the US; the majority of this group came from two Kurdish parties and one Shia party (ICG 13/11/03:3). Quickly after the invasion, the Coalition Provision Authority (CPA) superseded ORHA. The CPA functioned as a temporary government and all executive, legislative and judicial issues fell under its authority (ICG 27/08/03:10). In June 2003, attacks and protests against the US opposition increased and the Interim Governing Council was established in order to give Iraqis a role in the transitional process. The US selected the members of the IGC and selected thirteen Shia’s, five Sunni Arabs, five Kurds and two representatives from smaller groups. These ethnic groups did not form unified political entities and many IGC-members were former exiles and pre-war opposition groups with small constituencies and limited legitimacy. Several Baghdad-based political parties and grass roots organizations complained to be excluded from participating in the IGC (ICG 25/08/03:14). It turned out that the IGC was more a symbolic Iraqi representation then anything else; it did not increase Iraqi participation in or legitimization of the political process, it had no bureaucracy of its own, its authority was vague and it did not have access to the existing administration. The political role of the IGC is largely dismissed, as it did not have governing authority. However, it did have an influence on the constitutional process and left a mark on power-sharing arrangements – which became clear in the November Agreement, in which they were assigned an important role. Due to rising insurgency, a gradual loss of control over large parts of the country and a growing call from Iraqi’s and the international community to transfer power to the Iraqi people in the first six month of the occupation, the CPA changed its initial approach and decided to speed up the handover of sovereignty. In a plan known as the November Agreement the US unexpectedly announced that the CPA would be dissolved by July 2004. The Agreement included a timetable that included a transitional constitution, the handing over sovereignty to a transitional Iraqi government and the drafting of a permanent constitution, on basis of which democratic elections could be held. The Interim Governing Council was meant to write the transitional constitution (TAL) and elect the transitional government. The IGC had to present a program outlining steps regarding the constitutional process to the UN Security Council by 15 December 2003 (ICG 27/04/04:2-4). Grand Ayatollah Al-Sistani, who led the UIA and was not part of the IGC, organized several protests regarding the proposals in the November Agreement and TAL. According to the TAL the draft for the permanent constitution would be written by the IGC, and an interim government would be appointed by the IGC. This would give the IGC, a non-representative body selected by the US, a too powerful role (ICG 27/04/04:24-26). Al-Sistani demanded national elections for an interim government that would draft the permanent constitution. After consultations with the UN it was decided that the IGC would appoint a commission that would write the TAL and elect a temporary interim government before June 2004. National elections for a transitional government, which would be tasked with writing the permanent constitution, would be held in January 2005 (ICG 27/10/04:2). In this way, sovereignty would be 29 transferred to the Iraqis as soon as possible and a democratically elected government would draft the permanent constitution. A committee of ten Iraqis selected by the IGC drafted the transitional constitution and in March 2004, the IGC signed the Transitional Administrative Law (TAL), which would function as a transitional constitution after sovereignty was handed over to the Interim Government. The TAL included a bill of rights and provisions to govern the transitional period. The TAL would take effect upon US handover of power until a permanent constitution was adopted. An interesting provision was that all laws that would be in force on 30 June 2004 would remain in effect, including all laws issued by the CPA. Another interesting paragraph included provisions on an autonomous Kurdish region, a highly divisive issue in Iraqi politics, clearly against Arab Sunni interests. Disproportionate representation of Kurds and Shia’s in the IGC was clear when looking at the content of the TAL. In the end of June 2004, sovereignty was passed to Iraqi Interim Government through UNSC resolution 1546. United States post-CPA: Iraqi Sovereignty? On 28 June 2004, the US (CPA) transferred sovereignty to the interim government. After formally handing over sovereignty and dissolving the CPA, the US remained a powerful political player in the Iraqi landscape because all the laws it had adopted were still in place and because the US kept full authority over security operations and its troop strength remained undiminished (Fukuyama 2006:7). Because of the earlier transfer of “sovereignty” to the IGC that turned out to be symbolic, because the IGC selected members of the interim government, and because the US remained an influential player after June 2004, the term “sovereignty” was disputed had lost credibility, especially for the groups that were not included in the process (ICG 22/12/04:5). The constitution-making process provided an opportunity to include all groups and gain new legitimacy. However, with insurgency and anti-US sentiments on the rise in Iraq and decrease of support for the war among the US population, the Bush administration chose to sacrifice inclusiveness for the sake of deadlines (ICG 26/09/05:1). As explained by a US Official: “The one thing going for us is that the political process is moving along. If we manage to hold elections that are reasonably free and fair, the problem of legitimacy basically will be solved” (Interview ICG with US Analyst, Washington DC October 2004, in: ICG 22/12/04:13). Another reason for the US to “rush” the process was that a major US troop rotation was planned right after elections were scheduled to take place in December 2005; if elections would be postponed the newly arrived troops immediately had to deal with elections, which was not preferred by the US (IGC 08/06/05:9). In the very last stage of the constitution-drafting process, the US focus on sticking to timelines changed. The notion that inclusiveness as opposed to timelines was the pretext for stability was adopted when it turned out the Sunni Arabs would not support the proposed draft in he very last weeks before the referendum. In the last weeks before the referendum on the constitution US Ambassador Zalmay Khalilzad started intensive efforts to bring the Sunni Arabs back into the process. 30 With regard to power-sharing, the role of the US in Iraq is immense. There are two main factors. First of all, the US created the IGC, and through the IGC had a big influence on the content of the TAL. Even though the governing authority of the IGC was minimal, they did have an influence on the constitutional process because they selected a six-month interim government, and they selected the authors of the TAL. The unexpected quick transfer for sovereignty announced in the November agreement caused a rushed political and constitutional process preceding the transfer. Secondly, the US administration's determination to stick to the by them established timelines in the November Agreement and TAL, even though actual Iraqi empowerment and legitimization of institutions was far behind, has emptied symbolic dates and developments of their meaning (ICG 22/12/04:4). As a consequence, legitimacy of the newly established institutions was disputed since the transitional constitution and the interim government were established by the IGC under heavy US influence. The notion “sovereignty” lost its meaning as the Iraqi perception that the US would do whatever it wanted with or without Iraqi representation or government. US goals and methods changed towards the end of this process (inclusiveness over timeline), but the question is whether that was too late. As International Crisis Group wrote in April 2004, “The history of post-Saddam Iraq is one of successive, short-lived attempts by the US to mould a political reality into its liking” (ICG 27/04/04:i). 3.4.2 UN/International Community The UN and rest of the international community have not been able to influence the constitutional process significantly. This is mainly due to two factors: First of all, the US had veto power in the UN Security Council (UNSC). During the constitutional process, the US was resistant to internationalizing the political process in Iraq and it blocked any serious effort by other countries to expand the political or peacekeeping role of the UN in Iraq (ICG 27/03/04:1). Secondly, in the cases where the UN or international community did play a role, it was mostly in an advisory or subordinate capacity (ICG 25/08/03:20). This can be seen when looking at resolutions adopted by the Security Council. In 2003, for example, three resolutions on the political situation in Iraq were passed. The first two (resp. UNSC resolutions 1483 and 1500) lacked substance: they welcomed new institutions and even established a UN Assistance Mission in Iraq (UNAMI), but were vague on the exact political responsibilities of the UN or international community (Phillips 2005:12). The third resolution (UNSC resolution 1511, adopted in October 2003) included stronger language regarding the political situation: it requested from the IGC a precise timetable and program for a constitution to be drafted and elections to be held. This plan had to be presented to the Security Council by 15 December 2003. However, whether this is to be called influence from the international community is debatable, as this resolution was drafted by the US (ICG 13/11/03:19). The times when the UN did play a role, was when the US reached a deadlock. This happened after the 15 November Agreement in 2003, when the discussion on how to elect a Transitional National Assembly was at a dead end. The Grand Ayatollah al-Sistani insisted on elections, while according to the 31 US elections would be too difficult and time-consuming to implement. Lakhdar Brahimi, UN Special Envoy for Iraq, was requested to look into possibilities and come up with a plan. The “Brahimi Plan” concluded that elections were necessary but unrealistic to be held within a short time, was translated into the new policy that an appointed Interim Iraqi government would take over from the CPA in June 2004 and would rule for six months. After six months elections would be organized for the Transitional National Assembly, which would draft the constitution (ICG 27/04/04:4). Overall, the UN and international community have been willing to offer help and have assisted; but during the interim period the US was unwilling to accept it. With regard to power-sharing, the UN and the international community only played a role when the US “permitted” it during the constitutional process. The UN did influence the constitutional process with the Brahimi Plan, which had the result of elections taking place before a permanent constitution would be drafted. Since Sunni’ Arabs boycotted the TNA elections, which will be addressed in the next paragraph, the real influence of the UN on power-sharing arrangements remains limited. 3.4.3 Exclusion of Sunni Arabs/De-Ba’athification “At each stage of the transitional process, the US and its Iraqi allies decided against wider inclusion in the political process (of former Ba’ath members), although alternatives existed which could have created a political space for dialogue. As a consequence of this alienation, Sunni’s and Ba’athists rejected the 2005 constitution” (Papagianni 2008:44-45) The Sunni Arabs, some of who supported the Ba’ath regime, but by many seen as one group that as a whole supported Saddam Hussein, were excluded from political and constitutional processes at several stages. Between May and November 2003, the CPA outlawed Saddam Hussein’s Ba’ath party, dissolved the Iraqi national security and intelligence forces and installed a Supreme National De-Ba’athification Commission to root out Ba’ath-member from the ministries. As a consequence, thousands experienced Sunni Arab employees, who might not have committed crimes under Saddam Hussein’s regime, were excluded from the political process and thousands of professionals (for example doctors and teachers) could not exercise their profession any longer (ICG 28/08/03:2). Additionally, the disbanding of the security forces left a large group of people jobless and took away any indigenous security sector. In April 2004, when support for insurgency increased, the US changed their policy and brought several senior former Ba’athists back in the security forces, and in June 2004 the De-Ba’athification Commission was dissolved, although it continued to exist and it was eventually outlawed in the constitution (CFR Website). Secondly, on 30 January 2005 elections for a Transitional National Assembly took place. Most Sunni Arabs boycotted these elections out of fear for violence. As a result, seats in the TNA for the three biggest groups were divided as follows: the United Iraqi Alliance (Ayatollah al-Sistani’s party) won 140 32 out of 275 votes, the Kurdish Coalition List (coalition of two main Kurdish parties) won 75 out of 275 votes and Sunni Arabs parties won 17 out of 275 votes. Consequently, the Sunni Arabs played a downsized role in the transitional government that was formed in April 2005; they received five out of thirty-six ministries. A Shia Prime Minister (Ibrahim al-Jaafari) and a Kurdish President (Jalal Talabani) led the transitional government. Since the Kurdish and Shia parties had a relative strong position in the TNA, sticking to deadlines became favourable for those groups as they were in a strong position regarding what to in- and exclude in the constitution (ICG 08/06/05:1-2). Because meeting deadlines was prioritized over inclusiveness, the constitution-making process became a new stake in the political battle instead of an instrument to solve it (ICG 26/09/05:4). Thirdly, Sunni Arabs were marginalized and excluded during the constitutional process in 2005. Although the US initially insisted on including representatives from all groups, the US did not protest when Sunni Arabs were progressively marginalized during this the process in order to meet the time table for the new constitution that had been established in the Transitional Administration Law (TAL). The TNA appointed a 55-member Constitutional Committee consisting solely of TNA members (ICG 08/06/05:2); there were only two Sunni Arabs included. Grand Ayatolla Al-Sistani and US Secretary of State Condoleezza Rice urged to include more Sunni Arabs in the constitution-drafting process, but the process to select those individuals, how many should be added, and their status vis-à-vis elected committee members was time consuming (ICG 08/06/05:4). Less then six weeks before the draft had to be finalized, fifteen Sunni Arab leaders were added to the Committee. After this date the constitutional negotiations moved from the Constitutional Committee to an informal leadership of Shia and Kurds, where the Arab Sunni drafters were only invited after the Shia and the Kurds worked out the basic terms of the agreement behind closed doors (ICG 26/09/05:3). Consensus could not be reached and Arab Sunni’s eventually withdrew from the negotiations (ICG 26/09/05:1). The Constitutional Committee handed in a draft constitution to the TNA in the end of August, after less then 3 months of constitution writing, which was accepted without a vote. This was followed by US-led mediation to include the Sunni Arab community back into the political process. In a last-minute deal the Sunni Arabs agreed to participate in both the constitutional referendum in October and the national elections in December of 2005. In exchange, a mechanism to review and amend the constitution in the first six months of 2006 was added to the draft (Economist 27/10/05). When the constitution was approved through a referendum in October 2005 it exposed ethnic voting trends: Shia and Kurdish areas almost unanimously approved the draft while Sunni areas rejected it with overwhelming majorities (Brown 11/05:1). With regard to power-sharing, the exclusion from the Sunni Arabs had major implications for powersharing because the Shia and Kurds could express their preferences during the constitutional process, while Sunni Arabs could not. As International Crisis Group wrote in wrote in 2006, “no single issue proved more polarizing in post-war Iraq than the 2005 drafting of the country’s permanent constitution” (ICG 19/12/06:3). There was no substantial political dialogue between Sunni Arabs and other key political elites 33 during the transition from 2003 until the adoption of the constitution in 2005 and former Ba’athists were excluded from the political process, which meant that the former governing structures were completely neglected in the political process. 3.4.4 Ethnicization of Politics Iraqis increasingly grouped themselves along ethnic lines during the interim period. A main reason for this development is that the US selected Iraqi representatives along ethnic lines, which increased the perceptions on importance of group differences and boundaries. The ethnicization of politics started with the selection of the IGC. Its members were chosen as to mirror Iraq’s sectarian and ethnic groups. This was the first time in the history of Iraq that political representation was explicitly apportioned according to ethnic quotas. Even though the number representatives should or is likely to correspond with the size of their constituency, the fact that this became a decisive factor for selection had the effect that the role of ethnic identity increased in Iraq (ICG 22/12/04:ii). Before the invasion Iraqi political society had not defined itself in terms of religious or ethnic affiliation. The decision to take ethnicity and religion as a parameter for representation reflects how the US - not the Iraqi people - viewed Iraqi society and politics (ICG 25/08/03:13-16). Unrest between groups is likely to be exacerbated as its people increasingly organize along these divisive lines (ICG 25/08/03:16). The IGC and interim government consisted for a large part of parties that were founded in exile that, upon their arrival in Iraq in April 2003, had no recent experience with authentic political life, Saddam Hussein’s regime having suppressed it and the CPA having failed to provide for it. The IGC and interim and government have proved unable to bring about the important compromises needed to heal the deepening rifts - they have accentuated differences by their brand of identity politics and promotion of a political system in which positions are allotted according to communal (ethnic or confessional) identities. During the interim period, Sunni, Shia and Kurdish identities were transformed into the primary markers of political group formation, superseding a national identity or interest (ICG 19/12/06:3). As a consequence, Sunni’s increasingly felt that they were equated with Ba’athists (ICG 25/08/03:16). With regard to power-sharing, the fact that group formation in the political arena was increasingly dominated and marked by religion and ethnicity, deepened gaps between groups and led to a polarized view on society and other groups. The US played a role in group/boundary formation, as they started to select Iraqis that could participate in the constitutional process on basis of ethnicity or religion. The Shia’s and Kurds used this polarized climate, in which Sunni Arabs were increasingly identified with Saddam Hussein’s regime, to win more support. Since Kurds and Shiites, who formed a majority in the transitional government, were satisfied with the status quo, they did not push for a redraw of group boundaries. 34 3.5 Findings The purpose of this chapter was to analyze the constitutional process in Iraq by discussing the role of actors and groups during the interim period. Their role has been discussed by looking into the role of the US and the international community, the exclusion of Sunni Arabs and the ethnicization of politics. At the end of each paragraph a short summary on how the issue related to- or influenced power-sharing was given. As was the case for Afghanistan, factors turned out to be inter-related; one influenced the other. However, the main characteristics of the constitution, namely the high level of decentralization and the vagueness or absence of provisions that are perceived crucial by (one of) the parties, can be explained in the following ways when looking at the groups and actors that influenced the constitutional process. First of all, the high level of decentralisation was a consequence of the over-representation of Kurds, who wanted to be as autonomous as possible and the exclusion of Sunni Arabs, who have been the most nationalistic group in Iraq that was opposed decentralization. The Sunni Arabs were first excluded by the US through a process of de-centralization. Later, this was taken over by Shia’s and Kurds, as they wanted to profit as much as possible from their newly gained decision-making power. The fact that many issues were still undefined, postponed, or vague, showed deep rifts between groups; the constitution was not a consensual one, as most divisive issues were simply left out (ICG 26/09/05:6). The deepening gap between groups was a consequence of the ethnicization of politics, a development started by the US in the very first stage of the interim period through selection processes based on ethnicity or religion. Again, groups that saw their power increase through this, the Kurds and the Shia, held on to their new positions; the increase of their power gave them a vested interest in resisting further change. 35 Conclusion In this conclusion, findings of this research will be summarized and the research question will be answered. To conclude this thesis, a few suggestions for further research will be given. After presenting the research question in the introduction, the decision to use Horowitz’ notion of process to explain differences in power-sharing arrangements was explained in the first chapter by exploring current power-sharing literature and its ability to explain the different arrangements. The conclusion was that current power-sharing theory would not be used to explain why power-sharing arrangements differ for three reasons. First of all, power-sharing literature bases analysis of power-sharing agreements on the content of the actual agreement and the post-adoption period; the question how differences in the agreement itself can be explained remains unanswered. Secondly, consociationalism and centripetalism are never fully reflected in power-sharing agreements. Conclusive answers on these theories derived from empirical evidence are therefore impossible. Thirdly, the power-sharing debate is polarized and paralyzed between centripetalists and consociationalists because critiques regarding practical obstacles and theoretical objections only explain which theory is easier to implement, not why agreements are different. Because power-sharing theory is never fully implemented in practice, and because taking powersharing agreements as a start for analysis fails to explain differences in power-sharing agreements, Donald Horowitz’ notion that “constitutional processes and their impact on the adoptability of contending designs are the neglected elements in debates about measures to promote interethnic cooperation” was interesting. During constitutional processes all regulations, which together form power-sharing arrangements, have to be decided upon. Analyzing these processes might explain why power-sharing agreements “are the way they are” – and why one is different from the other. At the end of the first chapter, a framework to analyze the constitutional processes in Afghanistan and Iraq in order to answer the research question was presented. Since the groups and actors that eventually have to share power by agreeing upon a constitution have to decide upon all the regulations that together form the power-sharing arrangements, the constitutional process would be analyzed by focusing on these groups and actors. After researching the interim periods in Afghanistan and Iraq, the key factors that shaped the power-sharing arrangements were identified, and the role of groups in relation to these factors was explained. In the second and third chapter, the constitutional processes in Afghanistan and Iraq were analyzed. In Afghanistan, the counter-terrorism agenda of the US, the decision-making during Bonn regarding interim governments, the limited role of the international community, the influential role of Hamid Karzai and the deteriorating relationship between the central government and regions shaped the constitutional process. In Iraq, the occupation and authoritative role of the US, the limited role of the UN, the gradual exclusion of the Sunni Arabs and the increased ethnicization of politics were the main issues that influenced powersharing arrangements. These are the main issues that decided and shaped power-sharing arrangements in 36 each country because they influenced inter-group relations and the distribution of power and influence per group. When looking at these factors and the (trends in) inter-group relations, which groups and actors exercised most power and how, and what the influence of particular groups and actors was on the powersharing arrangements eventually adopted, there are two main similarities between Afghanistan and Iraq. These similarities reflect the conclusions of this thesis and the answer to the research question: “How can differences in power-sharing arrangements in Afghanistan and Iraq be explained by Horowitz’ notion of constitutional process?” First of all, in both Afghanistan and Iraq, the local groups or actors that were empowered directly after the invasion, were the groups most involved with setting the agenda for the constitutional process, and they maintained their powerful positions throughout the interim period. In Afghanistan, the Panshiri faction, who was able to take a powerful position in the Interim Administration, continued to play a powerful role, and Hamid Karzai, initially appointed as chairman of the AIA, had crucial decision-making power regarding the new constitution. In Iraq, the Kurds and Shia’s gained strong positions in the beginning of the interim period, positions that they secured by gradually excluding Sunni Arabs and taking a lead in the constitutional process. On the contrary, groups that were excluded or under-represented from initial talks or interim administrations continuously did not play a significant role in the political and constitutional process or were even excluded from it. In Afghanistan, the political party law made it hard for groups to establish themselves as new political parties, and the US-sponsoring of local militia caused more distance between the groups that were already part of the political process and the groups that were not. In Iraq, Sunni Arab’s, who were under-represented from the start, were gradually more excluded through a process of de-Ba’athification and ethnicization. Secondly, external parties involved, in this research mainly the US and the UN, had powerful roles when it came to empowering groups; they initiated and led talks about the new political and constitutional processes and decided who would be represented, and the groups they selected continued to play an influential role in the constitutional process in both countries. In Afghanistan, the groups that participated in the Bonn Conference turned out to be the most influential groups during the constitutional process, and in Iraq the groups that had the largest representation in the IGC proved to play the most influential during the interim period. In short, this research showed that empowering groups and actors in the very first stage of the interim period is crucial and decisive for the type of power-sharing arrangements that were adopted in Afghanistan and Iraq, and the difference in power-sharing arrangements can be explained by looking at the interests of the groups that were first empowered in the interim period, and the interests of the external parties that contributed to their empowerment. This conclusion confirms Horowitz’ notion that constitutional processes are negotiating processes and thus include winners and losers based upon the amount of power they exercised during the constitutional 37 process. Moreover, this research adds another detail to Horowitz notion; in the cases of Afghanistan and Iraq the “winners” of the processes (the ones who were in the position to shape power-sharing arrangements to their likings) were in both case studies the individuals or groups that were empowered in the very first stage of the constitutional process. In both Afghanistan and Iraq, the type of power-sharing arrangements that were adopted were the ones that consolidated the influential positions of the groups that were in power during the interim period in the most effective way. In Afghanistan President Karzai would be most benefitted by a majoritarian, centralized system with strong presidential power, and as a member of the largest ethnic group and with support of the international community he had the power to establish such a system. In Iraq, there was no strong majority, and because Arab Sunni’s were largely excluded from the process, the Shia’s and Kurds had relatively strong positions that they wanted to consolidate, which worked best in a parliamentary system. The conclusion that group empowerment in the first stage of the interim period is a decisive factor in constitutional process raises questions about the importance of the constitutional process in power-sharing literature. As discussed in the first chapter, similarities between the consociationalism and centripetalism are based on the dilemma inherent to power-sharing; who to in- and exclude in the process. When powersharing arrangements are (re)defined, which was the case in Afghanistan and Iraq when a new constitution had to be adopted, it is likely that some groups will have to “hand in” power, whereas other groups can use this as an opportunity to increase their power. Consociationalism and centripetalism are based on different social identity theories that deal with in- and exclusion of groups. Each theory presents ways to minimize the exclusion of groups, which nevertheless remains problematic in both consociationalist and centripetalist systems. The problem of “who to include” could be explained by looking at the interests of the groups first empowered in the interim period; in this research those groups or individuals proved to play the most decisive roles regarding power-sharing arrangements and who to in- and exclude. However, any assumption or conclusion on the importance of constitutional process for powersharing literature is premature, and more research on this topic is required. Suggestions for further research are thus whether the conclusions of this research correspond with other cases in which the constitutional processes was brought about by foreign intervention, and on an even broader level: whether in other postconflict cases the first groups put in power during a transitional or interim government will remain in power by shaping the power-sharing arrangements as to consolidate their power during and after the constitutional process. Researching constitutional processes of other cases will show whether Donald Horowitz’ division between institutions and process deserves permanent attention in the political power-sharing debate. 38 Bibliography Bercovitch, J. (eds.) (2002) Studies in International Mediation: Essays In Honor of Jeffrey Z. Rubin. London: Palgrave Macmillan Bonn Agreement. Retrieved via http://www.afghangovernment.com/AfghanAgreementBonn.htm (20/12/08) Brown, N.J. (2005) Is Political Consensus Possible in Iraq? Washington DC: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace Brown, N. (2005). Interview Council Foreign Relations, retrieved via http://www.cfr.org/publication/9414/brown.html (10/12/08) CIA World Factbook. Retrieved via https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/ (15/12/08) Crocker, C.A, Fen Osler Hampson and Pamela Aall (eds) (2004) Taming Intractable Conflict: Mediation in the Hardest Cases. Washington DC: United Institute of Peace Dobbins, J. (eds.) (2003) America’s Role in Nation-Building From Germany to Iraq. Santa Monica: RAND Final Report for Post-Invasion US Governance of Iraq: http://www.iraqfoundation.org/studies/2002 dec/10_draft.html Fukuyama, F. (eds) (2006) Nation-building: Beyond Afghanistan and Iraq. Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press Hartzell, C., and M. Hoddie (2003) “Institutionalizing Peace: Power Sharing and Post-Civil War Conflict Management” American Journal of Political Science 47-2:318-332. Horowitz, D. (2008) “Conciliatory Institutions and Constitutional Processes on Post-Conflict States” William and Mary Law Review 49:1213-1248 Lijphart, A. (1975) The Politics of Accommodation: Pluralism and Democracy in the Netherlands. Berkeley: University Press Lijphart, A. (1982) “Consociation: The Model and its Applications in Divided Societies” in Desmond Rea, ed., Political Cooperation in Divided Societies London: Macmillan 166-186 Lijphart, A. (2004) “Constitutional Design for Divided Societies” Journal of Democracy 15-2:96109 Mukherjee, B. (2006) “Why Political Power-Sharing Agreements lead to Enduring Peaceful Resolution of Some Civil Wars, But Not Others?” International Studies Quarterly 50:479-504 Norris, P. (2008) Driving Democracy: Do Power-Sharing Institutions Work? New York: Cambridge University Press. Oxford Online Dictionary, http://www.askoxford.com, 29/01/09 Papagianni, K. (2007) “Power-Sharing: A Conflict Resolution Tool?” Centre for Humanitarian Dialogue Background Paper, African Mediator’s Retreat:23-33. 39 Papagianni, K. (2008) “Power Sharing, Transitional Governments and the Role of Mediation” Centre for Humanitarian Dialogue Background Paper, The OSLO Forum Network of Mediators:42-54. Rubin, B.R. (2004) “Crafting a Constitution for Afghanistan” Journal of Democracy 15-3:5-19 Schneckener, U. (2002) “Making Power-Sharing Work: Lessons from on Preventing Deadly Conflict” Journal of Peace Research 39-2:203-228 Shah, B. (2004) The Constitutional Process in Afghanistan. Institute for Strategic Studies, Islamabad. Retrieved via http://www.issi.org.pk/journal/2004_files/no_1/article/4a.htm Simonsen, S.G. (2004) “Ethnicising Afghanistan?: Inclusion and Exclusion in Post-Bonn Institution Building” Third World Quarterly 25-4:707-729 Sisk, T.D. (1999) Power Sharing and International Mediation in Ethnic Conflicts New York: Carnegie Cooperation Sisk, T.D. (2003) Power Sharing: Knowledge Base Essay. Retrieved via http://www.beyondintractability.org/essay/power_sharing/ Stedman, J.S., D. Rothchild, E.M. Cousens (2002) Ending Civil Wars. The Implementation of Peace Agreements Reports International Crisis Group: On Afghanistan: Securing Afghanistan: The Need for More International Action, Asia Briefing N°13, 15 March 2002 The Loya Jirga: One Small Step Forward?, Asia Briefing N°17, 16 May 2002 Afghanistan: Judicial Reform and Transitional Justice, Asia Report N°45, 28 January 2003 Disarmament and Reintegration in Afghanistan, Asia Report N°65, 30 September 2003 Elections and Security in Afghanistan, Asia Briefing N°31, 30 March 2004 Afghanistan: From Presidential to Parliamentary Elections, Asia Report N°88, 23 November 2004 Afghanistan: Getting Disarmament Back on Track, Asia Briefing N°35, 23 February 2005 Political Parties in Afghanistan, Asia Briefing N°39, 2 June 2005 Afghanistan Elections: Endgame or New Beginning?, Asia Report N°101, 21 July 2005 Afghanistan’s New Legislature: Making Democracy Work, Asia Report N°116, 15 May 2006 On Iraq: Iraq after the Surge II: The Need for a New Political Strategy, Middle East Report N°75, 30 April 2008. Iraq and the Kurds: Resolving the Kirkuk Crisis, Middle East Report N°64, 19 April 2007. After Baker-Hamilton: What to Do in Iraq, Middle East Report N°60, 19 December 2006. 40 Iraq and the Kurds: The Brewing Battle over Kirkuk, Middle East Report N°56, 18 July 2006. Unmaking Iraq: A Constitutional Process Gone Awry, Middle East Briefing N°19, 26 September 2005. Iraq: Don’t Rush the Constitution, Middle East Report N°42, 8 June 2005. 41