Lecture 2 (Chapter 2)

advertisement
Lecture 2 (Chapter 2)
Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage:
The Ricardian Model
The Concept of Comparative Advantage using a modern example
On Valentine’s Day the U.S. demand for roses is about 10 million.
Growing roses in the U.S. in the winter is difficult.
 Heated greenhouses should be used.
 The costs for energy, capital, and labor are substantial.
Resources for the production of roses could be used to produce other goods, say
computers.
Suppose that in U.S. 10 million roses can be produced with the same resources as 100
thousand computers. In Mexico 10 million roses can be produced with the same resources
as 30 thousand computers.
Production possibilities for a given amount of resources in each country
Roses (in millions)
Computers (in thousands)
U.S.
10
100
Mexico
10
30

Note that resources used in making 10 million roses in U.S are not necessarily equal
to the resources employed to make that many roses in Mexico. In this example
Mexico is relatively less productive in computer production compared to U.S.
Opportunity cost
 Note that the opportunity costs (the value of the next best option foregone) of
production in the two countries are different.
 The opportunity cost of rose production is defined as the number of computers that
must be given up to produce more roses.
Opportunity cost of producing 10 million roses
(in terms of thousands of computers not produced)

US
100
Mexico
30
Here the opportunity cost of rose production is lower in Mexico and for that we say
Mexico has comparative advantage in rose production. U.S. has comparative
advantage in computer production because the opportunity cost of computer
production is lower in U.S.
US
Mexico
Opportunity cost of 100 thousand computer
10
10*3.33
(in terms of millions of roses not produced)
Benefits from Trade
 If each country specializes in the production of the good with lower opportunity costs,
trade can be beneficial for both countries.
Hypothetical Changes in Production
Roses (in millions)
U.S.
-10
Mexico
+10
Total
0
Computers (in thousands)
+100
- 10
+ 70
The example in shows:
 If each country exports the goods in which it has comparative advantage (lower
opportunity costs), then all countries can in principle gain from trade.
 Once every country specializes in production of goods that has a comparative
advantage in, and then trades its excess supply, world production increases.
 The extra production is the result of better allocation of resources.
 This extra production can be divided between the trading countries allowing them
to achieve higher consumption levels.
Absolute Advantage versus Comparative Advantage
 If it takes the same amount of resources to produce 10 million roses in both
countries then we say US has absolute advantage in computer production because
it can produce more computers with the same resources or it takes less resources
to produce computers in US than in Mexico.
 If it takes fewer resources to produce 10 million roses or 30 thousand computers
in US then we say US has absolute advantage in both goods.
 However comparative advantage does not depend on absolute advantage. In the
example above US has comparative advantage in computer production regardless
of the amount of resources it uses for computer production (regardless of whether
the resources used to produce 10 million roses in US is larger the same or less
than that in Mexico).
What determines comparative advantage?
 Why relative productivities are different in the two countries? This could be
because of technological differences in the two countries or the quality of the
resources (or factors of production available) in the two countries (i.e., fertile
land and suitable weather in Agriculture, capital and skilled labor).
A Ricarian like Example
Consider two goods (say wine and cheese) produced using labor only and two countries
(Home, Foreign *)
 Define unit labor required a. This is hours of labor required to produce one unit
of output. This is represented with a for home and a* for the foreign country.
 Note that a=L/Q (hours per unit of Q) thus 1/a=Q/L or simply labor productivity
Unit Labor Requirement
(Hours of work required to produce)
In Home
Cheese (1 lb)
aLC = 1
Wine (1 gal)___________________
aLW = 2
In Foreign
a*LC = 6
a*LW = 3
In Home, in the 1 hr that it takes to produce 1 lb cheese how many gal of wine could have
been produced. The answer is .5 because it takes two hrs to produce 1 gal of wine. This is
the opportunity cost of cheese production (in terms of wine). For opportunity cost of wine
we ask how much cheese could have been produced in the 2 hrs that it takes to produce 1
gal of wine. The answer is 2.
Opportunity Cost (before trade)
In Home
Cheese (1 lb)
in terms of gal of Wine forgone
aLC /aLW = 0.5
In Foreign
a*LC/a*LW = 2
Wine (1 gal)
in terms of lb of Cheese forgone
aLW /aLC = 2
a*LW /a*LC = 0.5
In Home
one must give up .5 gal of wine to obtain 1 lb of cheese
Thus the OC of cheese is .5 gal of wine.
One must give up 2 lb of C to obtain 1 gal of W thus OC of W is 2 lb of C
In Foreign
must give up 2gal of wine to obtain 1lb of C, thus OC of C is 2gal of wine
The OC of wine is 0.5 lb of cheese

Here Home has absolute advantage in both goods because it takes fewer resources
to produce wine and cheese in Home country (MPL is higher in Home). That is:
aLC < aLC* and aLW < aLW* or MPLC > MPL*C and MPLW > MPL*W
But absolute advantage is irrelevant to trade. In the example Home has comparative
advantage in Cheese because its opportunity cost of Cheese production is lower (0.5< 2)
that is:
OC of Cheese in
Home
Foreign
aLC /aLW < aLC* /aLW*
–
–
Labor Productivity in Wine Relative to Cheese
Home
Foreign
=> MPLw/MPLc < MPLw*/MPLc*
or MPLc/MPLw > MPLc*/MPLw*
Opportunity cost of cheese is lower in home country because Home is
relatively more productive in cheese production (less productive in
wine production)
Home has a comparative advantage in cheese.

With two goods there is only one price ratio in each country
o Note that opportunity cost of wine and cheese are just reciprocal of each other
 Wine is relatively cheap in Home and wine is expensive.
 In Foreign cheese is relatively expensive and wine is cheap

Now trade and make money
Start with 1 gal of foreign wine, sell it in US mkt in exchange for 2
pounds of US cheese and then sell each pound of US cheese for 2 gallons
of foreign wine in foreign mkt and make 3 gallons of wine profit!
All in all, this condition is rather confusing. Suffice it to say, that it is quite possible,
indeed likely, that although Foreign may be less productive in producing both goods
relative to Home, it will nonetheless have a comparative advantage in the production of
one of the two goods.
If Home is twice as productive in wine production relative to Foreign but three times as
productive in Cheese, then Home's comparative advantage is in Cheese, the good in
which its productivity advantage is greatest. Similarly, Foreign's comparative advantage
good is wine, the good in which its productivity disadvantage is least. This implies that to
benefit from specialization and free trade, Home should specialize and trade the
good in which it is "most best" at producing, while Foreign should specialize and
trade the good in which it is "least worse" at producing.
The Ricardian Model
Assumptions
This is a model of two goods (say wine and cheese), two countries (Home and Foreign *),
and one factor of production labor. Wine and cheese are produced with labor only.
 Labor is homogeneous within every country
• mobile domestically and immobile internationally.
• supply of labor is fixed in each country (say at L and L*).

Technology is represented by ULR or constant marginal productivity of labor in
both countries.

Perfect competition prevails in all market
• There are no other costs involved (transportation costs, etc.)
This is a General Equilibrium Analysis: Now let us looking at the whole economy
 General Equilibrium v.s Partial Analysis
o PE is a study of a mkt for a commodity in isolation
 Increase in Supply of C leads to a decrease in Price of C
o GE incorporates impact on other goods (Wine) and “factors”, like L.

Production Possibilities
• The production possibility frontier (PPF) of an economy shows the maximum
amount of a good (say wine) that can be produced for any given amount of
another (say cheese), and vice versa.
•
The PPF of our economy is given by the following equation:
aLCQC + aLWQW = L
(1)
Note that opportunity cost, reflected by the slope of PPF, is constant in each country and
given by the ratio of ULR in the two sectors, that is aLC / aLW
Relative prices before trade:
 Denote with PC the dollar price of cheese and with PW the dollar price of wine.
Denote with WW the dollar wage in the wine industry and with WC the dollar wage in
the cheese industry.
– Under perfect competition price of each good is equal to its marginal cost: i.e.
PC = MCC
– MCC = WC aLC ,wage rate in Cheese industry x labor required to produce a
unit of wine that is aLC
– So PC= WC aLC
– Thus WC =PC / aLC or (WC = PC . MPLC)
That is the hourly wage in Cheese (Wine) industry is equal to the
value of what a worker can produce in an hour.
– If WW = WC that is if PW /aW = PC /aC or PW /PC = aW /aC
then both QC and QW will be produced
– In the absence of trade, both goods are produced, and therefore
PC / PW = aLC/aLW.
Or PC / PW = MPLw/MPLc
(optional)
– If WC > WW that is if PC /aC >PW /aW or PC /PW > aC /aW
then no Wine will be produced QW =0 and QC = L/aLC
i.e, when the relative price of cheese (PC/PW) exceeds its opportunity
cost (aLC / aLW), then the economy will specialize in the production
of cheese.
–
If WC < WW that is if PC /aC <PW /aW or PC /PW < aC /aW
then no Cheese will be produced QC =0 and QW = L/aLW
Home Equilibrium with No Trade
From our previous example, we have aLC = 1, aLW = 2 and L=120 in Home country.
Home:
QW
QC + 2QW = 120
Home
aLC/aLW = PC /PW = 0.5
60
A
U2
U1
L /aLC = 120/1= 120
QC
In absence of trade consumption in every country is constrained to its production. Before
trade Home country produces and consumes at point A where its production possibility
frontier is tangent the highest social indifference curve in autarky U1.
We will refer to point A as the “no-trade” or the “pre-trade” equilibrium for Home.
We are assuming that there are many firms in each of the wine and cheese industries, so
the firms act under perfect competition, i.e. taking the market prices for wine and cheese
as given. The idea that perfectly competitive markets lead to the highest level of wellbeing for consumers – as illustrated by the highest level of utility at point A – is an
example of the “invisible hand” that Adam Smith (1723-1790) wrote about in his famous
book The Wealth of Nations. Like an “invisible hand,” competitive markets lead firms to
produce the amount of goods that results in the highest level of well-being for consumers.
Foreign Equilibrium with No Trade
 In Foreign country we have: a*LC = 6 , a*LW = 3 and L* = 300 so the production
possibility frontier for foreign country is given by:
Foreign :
6Q*C + 3Q*W = 300
2Q*C + Q*W = 100
 Similarly the Foreign country produces and consumes at point a.
 Before trade prevailing prices in every country is equal its opportunity cost.
Foreign
QW
L*/a*LW =
100/1= 100
P*C/P*W = a*LC/a*LW = 2
a
U*1
50
QC
Case Study: Us Comparative Advantage in Wheat Production
The U.S. textile and apparel industry faces intense import competition, especially from
Asia and Latin America. Employment in this industry in the United States fell from about
1.5 million people in 1990 to less than 1 million in 1999. One example of this import
competition is the response of a U.S. fabric manufacturer, Burlington Industries, which
announced in January 1999 that it would reduce its production capacity by 25% due to
increased imports from Asia. Burlington closed seven plants and laid off 2,900 people,
about 17% of its domestic force. After the layoffs, Burlington Industries employed
17,400 persons in the United States. With 1999 sales of $1.6 billion, this means that its
sales per employee were $1.6 billion/17,400 = $92,000 per worker. This is exactly at the
average for all U.S. apparel producers, as shown in Table 2.2.
The textile industry is even more productive, with annual sales per employee of
$140,000. In comparison, the average worker in China produces $13,500 of sales per year
in the apparel industry, and $9,000 in the textile industry. Thus, a worker in the United
States produces 7 times more apparel sales than a worker in China and 16 times more
textile sales.
If the United States clearly has an absolute advantage in both of these industries,
why does it import so much of its textiles and apparel from Asia, including China? The
answer can be seen by comparing the productivities of cloth and textiles to those in other
industries, for example in the wheat industry.
Table 2.2: Apparel, Textiles and Wheat in the U.S. and China
China
Absolute
Advantage
Sale/Employees
$92,000
$140,000
Sale/Employees
$13,500
U.S./ China Ratio
7
Wheat
$9,000
16
Bushels/Hour
Bushels/Hour
U.S./ China Ratio
27.5
0.1
275
Comparative Advantage (Opportunity Cost of Wheat)
$/Bushels
$/Bushels
Apparel/(Wheat x1000)
92,000/27,500=3.34
13,500/100=135
Textile/(Wheat x1000)
140,000/27,500=5.1
9,000/100=90
United States
Apparel
Textile
Note: Data are for years around 1995.
The typical wheat farmer in California devotes only 1.35 hours per acre to
growing a crop of wheat, and an acre provides 37 bushels of wheat. This works out a
marginal product of 37/1.35 = 27.5 bushels per hour of labor. In comparison, the typical
wheat farmer in China obtains only one-tenth of a bushel per hour of labor, so the U.S.
farmer is 27.5/0.1 = 275 times more productive! The United States has an absolute
advantage in all of these industries, but it clearly has the comparative advantage in
wheat. Thus, it exports wheat to the China, while importing textiles and apparel, just as
predicted by the Ricardian model.
The Patterns of the International Trade
Post-Trade Equilibrium
 If countries specialize according to their comparative advantage, they all gain from
this specialization and trade.
 Since by assumption Home has CA in Cheese it will specialize in Cheese production
and exports its excess supply of Cheese to the world market and purchases (imports)
all the Wine it needs from the work market. Similarly Foreign country will specialize
in Wine production.
 World price ratio will be something between the pre-trade domestic price ratio of the
two countries Pc / Pw < (Pc / Pw) World < P*c / P*w
 Note that in Home before trade W=PC / aLC and W = PW /aLW. With trade PC↑ and
PW↓. That increases wages in the Cheese and reduces them in the wine industry. Thus
all the workers in Home move to Cheese. Home produces at point P and sells its
Cheese in world market at (Pc / Pw) World. This allows Home to achieve consumption
possibility frontier beyond its PPF.
 Recall the consumption possibility frontier states the maximum amount of
consumption of a good a country can obtain for any given amount of the other
commodity.

With trade Home can consume at point C along PC where its post trade CPF is just
tangent the highest social indifference curve.
Foreign
P
QW
100 P
QW
80
50
a
U*2
U*1
25 50
C
80
QC
35
0
60
P = (PC/PW)World
U2
60
c
20
Home
A
U1
40 50
120
P
QC
Terms of Trade and Relative Wage Rates (optional)
Demand determines terms of trade (TOT),
TOT = PX /PI
where PX = price of exports & PI = price of imports
The relative wage is linearly related to the terms of trade
TOT= PX /PI = PC /PW, for Home, where PC and PW, are world prices of C and W
- Home makes Cheese only so w= Pc / aLC
- Foreign makes Wine only so w* = Pw / aLW*
W/W* = (Pc / aLC)/(Pw / aLW*) = (aLW* /aLC)(Pc / Pw)= (aLW* /aLC) TOT
or
W/W* = (MPLC / MPL*W) TOT
- the higher the TOT the higher the home wages
- the higher the productivity in export industry (i.e., 1/aLC for home
country) the higher the wage rate.


Because there are technological differences between the two countries, trade in goods
does not make the wages equal across the two countries.
A country with absolute advantage in both goods will enjoy a higher wage after trade.
Solving for Wages Across Countries
Unit Labor Requirement
Home produces and exports cheese, so we can think of Home workers being paid
in terms of that good: their real wage is MPLC = 1 pound of cheese. We refer to this
payment as a “real” wage because it is measured in terms of a good that workers consume
and not in terms of money. The workers can then sell the cheese they earn on the world
market at the relative price of (Pc / Pw) World = 1. Thus, their real wage in terms of units of
wine is (Pc / Pw) WorldMPLC = (1) 1 = 1 gallons.
Summing up, the Home wage is:
MPLC = 1 pound of cheese
or
(Pc / Pw) WorldMPLC = 1 gallons of wine (0.5 without trade)
What happens to Foreign wages? Foreign produces and exports wine, and the real wage
is MPL*W = 1/3 gallons of wine. Because wine workers can sell the wine they earn for
cheese on the world market at the price of 1, their real wage in terms of units of cheese is
(Pw / Pc) WorldMPL*W = 1/3 pounds.
Thus, the Foreign wage is
(Pw / Pc) World MPL*W = 1/3 pound of cheese (0.167 without trade)
or
MPLW = 1/3 gallons of wine
Foreign workers earn less than Home workers as measured by their ability to purchase
either good.
Predictions of the Ricardian Model:


With free trade countries specialize (completely) in good(s) with lower opportunity
cost of production (or relatively higher labor productivity), export excess production
in those sectors and import the other goods.
Free trade increases the national (and the individual) welfare (consumption, income
or wage rates) in all trading countries. No one will be worse off.
But we do not see extreme specialization in the real world
 There are three main reasons:
1. In reality MPL is not constant as assumed in the model. That makes PPF
nonlinear. That is opportunity cost might be increasing. So a product with
comparative advantage before trade may lose its comparative advantage as
more of it is produced after trade. This is likely to happen when we have more
than one factor of production.
2. Countries sometimes protect industries from foreign competition.
3. It is costly to transport goods and services. In some cases transportation is
virtually impossible.
Example: Services such as haircuts and auto repair cannot be traded
internationally; introducing transport costs makes some goods nontraded.
Empirical Evidence
Can get an accurate prediction about actual international trade flows?
McDougall study using early Post WWII period data 1951






Comparing British and American Productivity and Trade
British Labor productivity was less than US in almost every sector (1/2US).
America had absolute advantage in almost everything
Yet the amt of British overall export was equal to that of US
U.S. productivity exceeded British in all 26 sectors by margin of 11 to 366%
US exports were larger than U.K exports only in industries where US productivity
advantage was larger than twice as much
U.S. exports goods in sector x if its cost of production is lower than UK:
W aX < w* a*X
or W/ W* < a*X / aX
That is U.S. exports x if: W/ W* < (1 / aX) / (1 / a*X) = (MPLX/MPL*X)
U.S.-UK relative wages < U.S-UK relative labor productivity in sector x
Since U.S.-UK relative wages: W/ W* = 2
U.S. exports in sectors in which U.S-UK relative labor productivity > 2
And UK exports in sectors in which U.S-UK relative labor productivity < 2
Question: Why the most productive firm in the most productive country does not
necessarily prevail in international competition?
Answer: Because there might be firms (in other industries) with even a stronger
productivity advantage than the firms in question driving wage rates (cost of production)
so high that the firm in question cannot compete internationally.
Significance of Ricardian Assumptions

Assumption of one homogeneous factor of production with constant productivity



o Makes everyone in society exactly the same in terms of skill & income. This
masks the fact that there are losers and winners from trade within any country.
o This assumption leads to extreme specialization with trade which is
unrealistic.
Technological differences are exogenous to the model
o Thus the model ignores the impact of international trade on the existing
technological differences. If trade facilitates technological improvements (in
the export sector) then the country receives two bonuses for its trade: once in
terms of higher income and welfare in the short run and second in terms of
higher growth and higher income in the long run. But if international trade
hinders or stifles technological progress in the import competing industry then
free trade may bring a short lived welfare gains at the expense of lower long
run growth.
o If physical of human capital explains technological difference, for instance,
then dynamic investment accumulation should be included in the model
before evaluating the merits of trade.
Labor is perfectly mobile between industries and perfectly immobile between
countries:
o There are actually large transition costs to specialization: 50 year old auto
worker has grave difficulties in finding a job in another sector say IT. The
model assumes he can and he will earn an income no less than the one he was
earning on his previous job (he is as productive as any existing worker in the
IT sector). The assumption masks the losses to import competing industries
and its factors of production.
Constant Returns to Scale
• Double labor double outputs?
• “Strategic” industries like airplane manufacture that face increasing
returns to Scale (learning by doing)
Conclusion and Summery
Two surprising conclusions:
A country may benefit from free trade even if it is less efficient than all other
countries in every industry.
It makes sense that one firm would be more successful than another firm in a local market
if it could produce its output more efficiently, that is at lower cost, than the second firm.
If the two firms produce identical products, then the less efficient firm is likely to be
driven out of business, generating losses. If we extend this example to an international
market then it would also make sense that a more efficient foreign firm would absorb
business from a less efficient domestic firm. Finally, suppose all firms in all industries
domestically were less efficient than all firms in all industries in the foreign countries. It
would then seem logically impossible for any domestic firms to succeed in competition in
the international market with the foreign firms. International competition would
seemingly have only negative effects upon the less efficient domestic firms and the
domestic country.
A domestic firm may lose out in international competition even if it is the lowest
cost producer in the world.
This result is a corollary of the previous point. As argued there, it seems reasonable to
think that a more efficient firm (i.e., one who produces at lower cost) would drive its less
efficient competitors out of business. The same would seem to follow if the two firms are
domestic and foreign and the two firms compete in international markets.
However, the Ricardian model of comparative advantage argues that a firm in one
country, even if it is the lowest cost producer in the world, may be forced out of business
once the country liberalizes trade with the rest of the world. Even more surprising,
despite the decline of this industry, the move to free trade can generate welfare
improvements for everybody in the country. In other words, losing production in a
highly efficient industry can be consistent with an improvement in welfare for
everyone. This contradicts the logic above which would suggest that more efficient
(lower cost) firms should always win.
It is important to note that this result does not imply that every decline of an efficient
industry will improve welfare. Instead, the model merely suggests that one should not
jump to the conclusion that the loss of an efficient industry will have negative effects for
the country as a whole.
Download