*Conference draft: Please do not cite* Privileging Biological or Residential Relationships: Family Policy on Obligations to Children in 12 Countries Daniel R. Meyer University of Wisconsin–Madison School of Social Work Institute for Research on Poverty drmeyer1@wisc.edu Christine Skinner University of York Department of Social Policy and Social Work christine.skinner@york.ac.uk Jacqueline Davidson University of York Social Policy Research Unit DRAFT August 2012 We thank Deborah Johnson for assistance with the manuscript and Emily Warren and Vanessa Rios Salas for research assistance. Meyer, Skinner & Davidson | 1 *Conference draft: Please do not cite* ABSTRACT Children’s domestic living arrangements have become increasingly complex over the last several decades in developed countries, with increasing numbers of children born to parents who do not live together, and, even among those born to parents who do live together, increasing numbers are experiencing their parents separating and one or both re-partnering. Children may live with a variety of adults including biological parents, married step-parents, cohabiting stepparents, and, perhaps, other adults who have no biological relationship to the child but do take on aspects of the parental role. In countries with generous and well-developed welfare states, these demographic changes may have few consequences for the economic well-being of children. But in other countries, these demographic changes raise complex questions about who has financial responsibility for the children. In this paper, we identify six common family transitions that children may experience and conceptualize how different potential child support (child maintenance) schemes might deal with these transitions. We then investigate how the child support policies in place in the mid-2000s in several countries handle these family transitions, and use the results of this analysis to categorize countries into the five potential child support schemes. Finally, we compare the categorization of child support schemes with the level of family complexity in each country to see if countries with the highest levels of complexity tend to organize responsibility differently. Meyer, Skinner & Davidson | 2 *Conference draft: Please do not cite* Children’s domestic living arrangements have become increasingly complex over the last several decades in developed countries, with increasing numbers of children born to parents who do not live together, and, even among those born to parents who do live together, increasing numbers are experiencing their parents separating and one or both re-partnering. Yet, the rates of these types of complexity and instability are not uniformly high across countries, sometimes varying substantially across countries that are similar in other ways. To examine these trends and document the differences between countries, Andersson (2002) attempts to provide comparable and systematic data across a range of sixteen developed countries.1 Andersson (2002) found substantial variation in the proportion of children born outside of residential unions (that is, whose parents were not cohabiting or married). It varied from 3% of births or less in five of the countries he studied, including Finland, to more than 1718% in the United States (17%) and the German Democratic Republic (GDR; because he is tracking children’s lives over time, he uses data prior to German reunification). Of these children born outside of unions, it is relatively common for them to experience their mother beginning a new residential partnership (either cohabitation or marriage), often fairly quickly. In seven of nine countries for which there is data, more than half of these children experienced their mother partnering (which may be re-partnering) by the time they were nine years of age (Andersson 2002). But even though this is a common experience, there is substantial variation in proportions, from 32% in Poland to 87% in the GDR. Family instability and complexity is not just an issue for children born outside of unions. For those born in an unmarried cohabiting relationship, by the time they were nine, one-quarter These “countries” include separate data for Austria, Czech Republic, Finland, Flanders, France, GDR, Hungary, Italy, Latvia, Lithuania, Norway, Poland, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden, USA, and West Germany. 1 Meyer, Skinner & Davidson | 3 *Conference draft: Please do not cite* or more had experienced the dissolution of their parents’ relationship in twelve of fourteen countries, and, among these countries, Hungary (48%), Latvia (58%), and the United States (64%) have very high rates. In contrast, rates of dissolution in Italy are estimated to be quite low (7%). While the rate of dissolution is lower for children born in marriage, more than one in ten marital children has experienced dissolution by age nine in twelve of the sixteen countries with data (Andersson 2002). The high rates of dissolution are followed in many countries by high rates of re-partnering; within three years of parental separation (either marital or nonmarital) more than one-third of children experienced their residential parent being in a union again in Norway, United States, Germany, Hungary, Czech Republic, and Slovenia. The conclusions from these data are clear: first, the degree of family instability varies substantially across countries. This has also been documented in other studies, examining different countries and different indicators of children’s experiences (e.g., Chapple 2009; Iacovou & Skew 2010; Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development [OECD] 2011). Second, regardless of the circumstances of a child’s birth, a large proportion of children will experience some time living apart from one of their biological parents, and many of these will experience time living with one of their parent’s new partners. Family instability raises questions about who has financial responsibility for children. When children live with their biological parents, it is clear that both parents have financial responsibility for the children. When children live with only one biological parent, countries have developed a variety of child support (child maintenance) policies that outline whether the resident parent, the nonresident parent, some other adult, or some combination has financial responsibility for them (Corden 1999; Meyer, Skinner & Davidson 2011; Skinner & Davidson 2009). However, as can be seen in the data on family complexity, children may go on to live Meyer, Skinner & Davidson | 4 *Conference draft: Please do not cite* with a variety of adults including biological parents, married step-parents, cohabiting stepparents, and, perhaps, other adults who have no biological relationship to the child but do take on aspects of the parental role. These family transitions raise complex questions about who has financial responsibility for the children. In this paper, we identify six common family transitions that children may experience and conceptualize how different potential child support schemes might deal with these transitions. We then investigate how the child support policies in place in the mid-2000s in several countries handle these family transitions, and use the results of this analysis to categorize countries into the five potential child support schemes. Finally, we compare the categorization of child support schemes with the level of family complexity in each country to see if countries with the highest levels of complexity tend to organize responsibility differently. I. Conceptual Overview of Biological and Residential Responsibility Schemes An important distinction in classifying family policy across countries is whether financial responsibility for children resides primarily in private relationships or in the state, and a substantial amount has been written on this topic (e.g., Cunningham-Burley & Jamieson 2003; Eekelaar 1991; Esping-Anderson 2009). One key distinction is between residual welfare states (in which individual families have primary financial responsibility, with the state playing a role only when parents are not able to provide) and those countries in which financial provision for children is seen more as society’s responsibility as a whole. Another broad distinction is whether policy allows for defamilialization, that is, the extent to which the state provides social rights to a minimum income standard that means individuals do not need to rely on the family (Hantrais 2004). The literature on the role of parents versus the state and the family versus the state is Meyer, Skinner & Davidson | 5 *Conference draft: Please do not cite* fairly well developed, but it is not our focus here. Instead, we are interested in the private sphere, in identifying which adults are responsible, given family changes. We begin our categorization of child support schemes of assigning responsibility for children by outlining common family transitions. Distinctions between schemes are easiest to see when family transitions occur because different types of transitions change responsibilities in some schemes and not others. In the top panel of Table 1 we introduce notation and identify a base case and six transitions. The base case is simple: a focal child lives with one parent (the resident parent, R) and the other parent is living elsewhere (the nonresident parent, N), and neither of these parents is living with a partner or has had children with another partner. There are then six main family transitions of interest that could occur from this base case. The transitions are differentiated by which parent gains a new partner — the nonresident parent gains a new partner (NNP) in T1 and the resident parent gains a new partner (RNP) in T4. The transitions are further separated by whether the new partnership includes an “old” child (the child of the new partner, the stepchild of the focal child’s parent) in T2 and T5 or a “new” child (a biological child of the focal child’s parent and the new partner) in T3 and T6. There are other potential transitions that we could include, including the addition of new children without a new resident partner, or the dissolution of the relationship with a new partner, or combinations of these transitions; we ignore these because the issues are closely related to other cases we cover. In the base case, and after each of these transitions, children live with one parent (R) and the other parent (N) lives elsewhere; in some of these cases children also live with another adult, their parent’s new partner (RNP). Which of these adults should have financial responsibility for the child? Countries assign responsibilities differently, as seen in their child support schemes. One key division is between biological responsibility and residential responsibility. Under an Meyer, Skinner & Davidson | 6 *Conference draft: Please do not cite* extreme biological scheme determining parentage is critical. A child’s two biological parents always retain financial responsibility, regardless of their family transitions.2 Thus, in the base case, the resident parent, R, would have obvious responsibility and the nonresident parent, N, would also be responsible, with the obligations paid as child support under whatever rules or guidelines are in place. If either or both parents re-partner and live with new children (either biological, or the children of the new partner), it would not matter: biological parents have full responsibility. This is the first of our five schemes (A-E) defined in Table 1 as “A: Biology Absolute.” The bottom panel of Table 1 shows that no transition affects N’s obligation to his/her biological child. In contrast, in an extreme residential scheme, financial responsibility for a child would end if a parent/adult stopped living with a child (or financial responsibility would never start if the parents never lived together following the birth of the child). Because no parent has financial responsibilities for nonresidential children, no child support system is required. Only resident parents would be responsible for the child until/unless the resident parent re-partners, in which case the new partner would also have responsibility for all children and stepchildren with whom he/she lives.3 No developed country that we are aware of has this type of extreme residential scheme, so we do not consider it here. We do, however, consider a scheme, “B: Residence Primary,” in which residence is more important than biology in some instances. In this scheme, a country requires a nonresident parent to be financially responsible in the simple base case, consistent with a principle in which two separated biological parents should be financially responsible for any child (as long as they 2 For simplicity, we ignore adoption, essentially assuming that adoptive parents can be treated as biological parents in later family transitions. 3 If a child lived with both parents after they split (joint custody/joint residence or equal shared care), each parent would have full responsibility for the child whenever the child was residing with him/her, and no responsibility when the child was not. Meyer, Skinner & Davidson | 7 *Conference draft: Please do not cite* do not have other obligations). But in scheme B, any other residential transition could change who is responsible for a child, with residence being more important than biology. First consider any type of transition that involves the resident parent living with a new partner, whether they have new children or not (T4-T6). In this case, the focal child becomes their joint financial responsibility because of their joint residence and the nonresident parent’s child support responsibility is lessened or ends. Alternatively, consider the division of responsibilities when it is the nonresident parent who re-partners (T1-T3). If the nonresident parent lives with a new partner, he/she has obligations to the new partner, as well as to any children living in their home (whether step or biological children), so the child support obligation to the original focal child is lessened (or perhaps eliminated). In these ways, residence trumps biological responsibilities. Thus the bottom panel shows that the financial obligation of N is lowered under any transition. Note that in this scheme (and in others described below), we group together the elimination of financial responsibilities with the lowering of financial responsibilities. We do this for both pragmatic and conceptual reasons. Pragmatically, the data we will use to categorize countries are not always clear on whether child support is lowered or eliminated. Moreover, in many cases elimination of responsibility is merely the extreme case of lowering the obligation. For example, often N’s ability to pay support matters; N’s responsibility after a transition might be eliminated if there was deemed to be no ability to pay, a small amount if there was a small ability to pay, etcetera. The third scheme we consider, “C: Biology Primary,” is similar to scheme A (Biology Absolute) in that biological relationships primarily define responsibilities. However, in this scheme more recognition is given to financial responsibility for residential biological children than biological children who lived elsewhere. In this scheme, if the nonresident parent re- Meyer, Skinner & Davidson | 8 *Conference draft: Please do not cite* partners but no children are involved (T1), or if the nonresident parent re-partners and has only stepchildren (T2), this does not affect the responsibility for the focal child, since biological relationships are primary. However, if the nonresident parent has a new biological child with whom he/she lives (T3), this would lessen the responsibility to a previous biological child (the focal child), since biology and residence together trump a child who has only biology. Because biology is primary in this scheme, N’s responsibilities to biological children are unaffected by R’s transitions (T4-T6). In an adaptation of this scheme, “D: Biology Modified,” responsibility for biological children is still quite important, but responsibility for adult partners as well as for children is incorporated. The key difference between schemes C and D occurs when the nonresident parent takes a new partner, but no children are involved (T1). If a country wants to ensure that a nonresident parent fulfills obligations to a new partner, it could lower (or eliminate) the responsibility for the focal child whenever there is a new residential partner. In this scheme, though, there is no new responsibility for resident stepchildren (T2); they remain the responsibility of their biological parents. Nor does N have a change in responsibility for R’s transitions, since, for example, there is no responsibility for stepchildren (N’s biological child is RNP’s stepchild, and biological ties remain). Finally, there could be a Biology Pragmatic scheme (E). This scheme is like the modified biological scheme (D), but it also considers responsibilities to stepchildren. Typically N’s responsibility to a residential stepchild (T2) would be enough to lessen responsibility to a biological nonresident child. However, this scheme has what could be considered a fundamental inconsistency. If a nonresident parent’s stepchildren can lower the obligation to his/her biological child, then that can be seen as one having some responsibility to stepchildren. But if Meyer, Skinner & Davidson | 9 *Conference draft: Please do not cite* this is the case, then a resident parent’s new partner (RNP) should have some responsibility for the focal child (the RNP’s stepchild), and this new adult with responsibility could lower the obligation of N. In the countries with this type of scheme, however, this change does not occur. From the description of the child support schemes in these countries, which we will describe below, this is because the lowering of the obligation to focal child in response to a transition involving stepchildren is seen as merely reflecting the fact that more children in N’s home mean he has less ability to pay child support to the focal child, rather than reflecting a general principle that adults have financial responsibility for stepchildren. For this reason, we term this scheme “Biology Pragmatic” — biological relationships are the foundation of child support obligations, but these obligations are tempered by a nonresident parent’s available resources, and stepchildren matter in the calculation of available resources. These are not the only conceptual schemes that are possible. We have already mentioned what could be called a “Residence Absolute” scheme, in which responsibilities follow residence only, and biology leads to no obligations. But other combinations are possible as well; for example, if an RNP had substantial resources and was willing to provide for the focal child, a country could essentially assign responsibility to RNP and lower N’s obligation. We have focused on the five schemes we outline because they are conceptually distinct and are represented by countries in our data. We now turn to our analysis of what countries actually do in practice. II. Data and Approach This paper uses data gathered on the child support schemes in 2006 in 12 countries — Austria, Australia, Canada, Denmark, Finland, Germany, the Netherlands, New Zealand, Meyer, Skinner & Davidson | 10 *Conference draft: Please do not cite* Norway, Sweden, the United Kingdom, and the United States.4 The data were gathered to assist the U.K. government in evaluating changes to its child support policy (Skinner, Bradshaw & Davidson 2007). An expert national informant was identified in each country and asked to describe relevant policy, an approach often used in comparative research on tax and benefit systems (see, for example, Bradshaw et al. 1996; Bradshaw & Finch 2002; Corden 1999; or Eardley, Bradshaw, Ditch, Gough, & Whiteford 1996). In federalist countries, informants selected a single jurisdiction’s policies to describe; thus the Canadian data are from Ontario and the U.S. data are from Wisconsin. The expert informants, primarily academics who conduct policy research, were each sent a questionnaire focused on a variety of aspects of child support policy; it was structured to allow some scope for discursive responses. Questions were asked about how child support amounts were assigned, followed by several specific questions covering the nonresident and resident parents’ family situations. For example, country experts were asked: Is the obligation affected by whether the nonresident parent has a new partner with whom he/she lives? How does it affect the obligation? Does a new partner’s own child (the nonresident parent’s stepchild) matter to the obligation? How? Is the obligation affected by whether the parent with care has a new partner? How is the obligation affected? Does a new partner’s own child (the parent with care’s stepchild) matter to the obligation? How? Informants also responded to several vignettes in order to elicit child support policy responses to common scenarios, including the re-partnering of the parents. 4 Data were also gathered from Belgium and France. However, both these countries have a discretion-oriented judicial system, so questions were often answered “it depends on the judge;” as a result, we do not incorporate these countries into our analysis. Meyer, Skinner & Davidson | 11 *Conference draft: Please do not cite* Our approach is relatively straightforward. We take responses within each country to the series of questions about whether different family situations are considered in the setting of child support obligations. We then confirm our understanding of the scheme by examining responses to the vignette in which experts described what would happen to obligations in a series of example cases that included family transitions. The focus of this work is not on the precise calculation of the amount of the obligation, but on whether the amount is varied depending on family circumstances. Thus, we categorize countries based on whether obligations are lower in complex family circumstances, rather than the actual amount of the difference. Our approach is obviously limited by the accuracy of the experts’ information. Moreover, some countries have changed policies since these data were collected; however, no more recent systematic policy review exists and this analysis serves to elucidate the potential range of different responses of child support schemes to complex family forms. III. Results Table 2 shows the results for each transition, and Table 3 shows the categorization into schemes. In every country, in the base case, an N has financial obligations to his/her children. We focus therefore on whether the obligation changes when transitions occur. As shown in the first row of Table 2, in Australia, R’s transitions (T4-T6) are irrelevant to the obligations of N. An NNP (T1) would not change the obligation, nor would it matter if that NP brings a stepchild into the N’s home (T2). All of these policies are consistent with the notion that one has an obligation to a biological child that is not modified by residence. However, if the N and the NP have a child together (T3), this is a new obligation of the N, which then lessens the obligations to previous children. Thus, because only the N’s new biological children matter to the obligation, Meyer, Skinner & Davidson | 12 *Conference draft: Please do not cite* Table 3 shows this as a clear case of the Biology Primary scheme (C). Denmark, Norway, and the United Kingdom are all similar to Australia in the results of family transitions, so they are also categorized as Biology Primary schemes.5 The Norway case has an unusual feature (at the time of the study). The obligation is calculated after considering the income of the N and an amount set aside for own expenses. Because NPs are typically seen as potential earners, the amount set aside for an individual living with a partner is less than the amount set aside for an individual living alone. This means that in certain cases, the obligation to a nonresident child could actually increase if an N began living with an NP. Austria, Finland, and Germany are similar to Australia in that a new resident biological child (T3) lowers the obligation to the focal child, and obligations are not changed based on the R’s transitions (T4-T6). These countries differ from the first set of countries in that the addition of a new spouse of the N (T1) can lower the obligation, because the N is essentially financially responsible for a new spouse. Thus, Table 3 shows this as a Biology Modified scheme (D). The United States, as exemplified by Wisconsin, is the only country studied that does not change the obligation to the focal child in response to family transitions, as shown in Table 2. Thus, Table 3 shows the United States characterized as a Biology Absolute scheme (A). In Wisconsin, as in every state in the United States, the R’s living situation is irrelevant to the N’s obligation. Similar to several other U.S. states, no adjustment is made when Ns re-partner. In a few states, adjustments are made when Ns have new biological children (Brito 2005; Caspar 2006; Venohr & Griffith 2005), but in Wisconsin there is no adjustment; biological obligations are not modified by residence. 5 We have categorized countries according to the responses of experts as to common cases, but our categorization may not hold for all cases. For example, the Danish expert did note that it is possible for an NP to lower the obligation to focal child, but because this would only occur after delinquency and after a full court review, and then is not guaranteed, we do not consider it the typical case here. Meyer, Skinner & Davidson | 13 *Conference draft: Please do not cite* The Netherlands and Sweden can be characterized as Residence Primary schemes (B). In both these countries, an R’s transitions (T4-T6) can mean changes to the obligation to the focal child. This type of adjustment occurs because obligations are determined based on the economic resources of both parents, and economic resources include the potential to draw on those resources. Thus, if an R adds an NP who has low or no earnings, the R’s needs have increased with the additional person in the home. If the obligation were recalculated, the N would now be a little better off compared to the R than before; this can result in an increased child support obligation. Correspondingly, if the RNP has moderate income, R is now better off compared to N than before, so N’s obligation could decrease. In terms of the Ns’ transitions, adding any new person into the home (T1-T3) increases needs and can result in the N having a lower obligation. Thus, these are countries in which residence is quite important, and can (at least in principle) lower biological obligations. Finally, Canada and New Zealand are categorized as Biology Pragmatic schemes (E). In these countries, an N’s transitions (T1-T3) can lower the obligation, using the same general logic as the Netherlands and Sweden. However, in these countries, the R’s resources and needs transitions do not generally enter the calculation of the amount owed, so the R’s transitions (T4T6) do not change obligations. Countries do vary by the transitions under which residence can modify biologically based obligations, and by whether family transitions of adults matter, or only when transitions include children. Special conditions can matter as well: for example, in Ontario (Canada), the N’s transitions can all result in a lower obligation to the focal child, but only if the transitions create undue economic hardship. Thus, Ontario can be seen as operating two different schemes: for lower-income Ns, residence is important; in contrast, for parents who both Meyer, Skinner & Davidson | 14 *Conference draft: Please do not cite* have moderate incomes, residence is unimportant, and the system resembles the extreme biological scheme of Wisconsin/United States. IV. Discussion Our analysis has shown that there is diversity in approaches across countries, although most of the countries are more focused on biology than residence. One country (United States) follows a scheme that emphasizes biological responsibility alone, and seven countries follow a scheme that we characterize as primarily privileging biology, but allowing it to be modified by residence in some circumstances. Two countries we consider Biology Pragmatic schemes (Canada and New Zealand), and two countries we consider as following a Resident Primary scheme (see Table 3). The rates of family instability and transition differ across countries. Child support policy could be linked to the level of family instability in a country. That is, if a country experiences a high level of family transition, one might imagine that their policy would be particularly likely to take this into account. On the other hand, if a country has high rates of family transition, policymakers might be particularly reluctant to take into account these changes because the magnitude of changes would make the workload high for those charged with assessing obligations and monitoring and enforcing their payment. We are able to provide some suggestive data on this issue in Table 4a and Table 4b. Table 4a shows demographic indicators from the six countries in which Andersson (2002) provided data on the rate of family changes in four key areas. Table 4b shows point-in-time measures of children’s living situations in ten countries. Together, these enable us to explore whether it is the countries with the most change/most instability that factor in residence to their scheme regarding obligations for children. The table shows substantial diversity on each Meyer, Skinner & Davidson | 15 *Conference draft: Please do not cite* indicator. In Table 4a, the United States stands out with the highest rate in three of the four indicators of family transitions, sometimes substantially higher than the second-highest country. Norway shows the highest rate of partnering for children born to lone mothers. Table 4b, shows that the United States has by far the highest rate of children living in a sole-parent family, and Denmark is second highest; the United States also has the highest rate of living in a step-family, and Finland is second highest. Interestingly, the United States, Norway, and Denmark, the countries with the highest rates of residential transitions and of single parenthood, are those with the least modifications for residence — the United States as the example of the Biology Absolute scheme and Norway and Denmark as Biology Primary schemes. There are several competing explanations for this suggested relationship. As suggested, this could be pragmatic: if the child support system in a country with high rates of transitions were to adjust child support obligations in response to residential transitions, changes to obligations would need to occur fairly often. Or perhaps this is motivated by a desire to protect children financially from transitions of their parents, or perhaps, especially in the U.S. case, the lack of responsiveness of policy may be an intentional effort to dampen family instability. All explanations are consistent with the observed relationship; further research would be useful. This research has described parents in terms of residential relationships, rather than focusing on gender. We have done this because custody laws in developed countries are generally gender-neutral. If, however, mothers are much more likely to be resident parents than fathers, a country that had strong gendered roles for parents might be more likely to think of the categories as based on fathers and mothers, rather than nonresident and resident parents. Describing a country’s rules in terms of nonresident fathers and resident mothers can provide Meyer, Skinner & Davidson | 16 *Conference draft: Please do not cite* additional insight. For example, in both Norway and Austria a nonresident father’s obligation to a focal child can change if he has a new wife, but the effect can be in opposite directions. In Norway, the new wife is essentially assumed to be an economic contributor to the household, so the nonresident father is better off and he may be able to afford more child support. In Austria, in contrast, a nonresident father is essentially taking on a new dependent when he marries, and thus he is allowed a higher amount for his needs, and his obligations to his child could go down. This contrast potentially highlights differences in gender roles and perhaps gender equality mechanisms in countries. More explicit consideration of the role of gender within and across countries could yield important further insights. We have highlighted here differences across these countries — differences in their child support policy schemes, and differences in their level of family instability and transitions. However, the level of transitions seems to be increasing in countries where there is comparable over-time data (Chapple 2009); while there is some debate over the extensiveness of the second demographic transition, the level of family complexity does not appear to be lessening (OECD International Futures Programme 2011). Family policies developed in periods of relative stability may need to be re-examined to see if they are still appropriate in contemporary circumstances. Meyer, Skinner & Davidson | 17 *Conference draft: Please do not cite* References Andersson, G. 2002. “Children’s experience of family disruption and family formation: Evidence from 16 FFS countries.” Demographic Research 7: 343–364. Bradshaw, J. & N. Finch. 2002. A comparison of child benefit packages in 22 countries. Department for Work and Pensions Research Report No. 174, Corporate Document Services, Leeds. Bradshaw, J., S. Kennedy, M. Kilkey, S. Hutton, A. Corden, T. Eardley, H. Holmes, & J. Neale. 1996. The employment of lone parents: A comparison of policy in 20 countries. The Family and Parenthood: Policy and Practice, Family Policy Studies Centre, London. Brito, T. 2005. “Legal issues, complicated families, and child support policy.” Report to the Wisconsin Department of Workforce Development. Madison, WI: Institute for Research on Poverty. Caspar, E. 2006. “A review of child support guideline policies for multiple family obligations: Five case studies.” Report to the Wisconsin Department of Workforce Development. Madison, WI: Institute for Research on Poverty. Chapple, S. 2009. “Child well-being and sole-parent family structure in the OECD: An analysis.” OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Paper No. 82. Corden, A. 1999. Making child maintenance regimes work. Family Policy Studies Centre, London. Meyer, Skinner & Davidson | 18 *Conference draft: Please do not cite* Cunningham-Burley, S. and L. Jamieson (eds.). 2003. Families and the state: Changing relationships. Basingstoke: Palgrave. Eardley, T., J. Bradshaw, J. Ditch, I. Gough, & P. Whiteford. 1996. Social assistance in OECD countries: Country reports. Department of Social Security Research Report No. 47, HMSO, London. Eekelaar, J. 1991. “Parental responsibility: State of nature or nature of the state.” Journal of Social Welfare and Family Law 13(1):37–50. Esping- Anderson, G. 2009. Incomplete revolution: Adapting welfare states to women? New roles. Oxford: Polity Press. Hantrais, L. 2004. Family policy matters: Responding to family change in Europe. Bristol: The Policy Press. Iacovou, M. & A. Skew. 2010. Household structure in the EU. ISER Working Paper No. 201010, Colchester: Institute for Social & Economic Research. Meyer, D. R., C. Skinner & J. Davidson. 2011. “Complex families and equality in child support obligations: A Comparative policy analysis.” Children and Youth Services Review 33: 1804–1812. OECD. 2011. Doing better for families. Paris: OECD Publishing. OECD International Futures Programme. 2011. The future of families to 2030: A synthesis report. Paris: OECD Publishing. Meyer, Skinner & Davidson | 19 *Conference draft: Please do not cite* Skinner, C., J. Bradshaw, & J. Davidson. 2007. Child support policy: An international perspective. Department for Work and Pensions Research Report No. 405, Corporate Document Services, Leeds. Skinner, C. & J. Davidson. 2009. “Recent trends in child maintenance schemes in 14 countries.” International Journal of Law, Policy and the Family 23(1): 25–52. Venohr, J., C. Venohr & T. E. Griffith. 2005. “Child support guidelines: Issues and reviews.” Family Court Review 43(3): 415–428. Meyer, Skinner & Davidson | 20 *Conference draft: Please do not cite* Table 1: Family Transitions and the Assignment of Financial Obligations for Children in Five Schemes Living Arrangements: Base Case and Six Transitions (T1-T6) Base: Child lives with resident parent (R); not with nonresident parent (N); neither parent has a new partner T1. Nonresident parent (N) adds new partner (NNP), no children involved T2. Nonresident parent (N) had new partner (NNP), adds resident stepchild (new partner’s child) T3. Nonresident parent (N) had new partner (NNP), adds new biological child together T4. Resident parent (R) adds new partner (RNP), no children involved T5. Resident parent (R) had new partner (RNP), adds resident stepchild (new partner’s child) T6. Resident parent (R) had new partner (RNP), adds new biological child together Five Schemes for Assigning Financial Obligations Scheme Description A. Biology Absolute N and R always have obligation to focal child B. Residence Primary Financial obligations primarily linked to residence C. Biology Primary Financial obligations primarily biological, but biology and residence together is a higher claim than biology alone D. Biology Modified Financial obligations primarily biological, biology and residence together is a higher claim than biology alone; residential partnerships also exert a higher claim than biology alone E. Biology Pragmatic Any residential relationship of N exerts a higher claim than a nonresidential biological claim After a Transition, Does the Nonresident Parent’s Obligation Decline?* Scheme T1 T2 T3 T4 T5 T6 A. Biology Absolute No No No No No No B. Residence Primary Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes C. Biology Primary No No Yes No No No D. Biology Modified Yes No Yes No No No E. Biology Pragmatic Yes Yes Yes No No No *In some cases the obligation declines to zero (i.e., is eliminated). Meyer, Skinner & Davidson | 21 *Conference draft: Please do not cite* Table 2: Policy in 12 Countries: After a Transition, Does the Nonresident Parent’s Obligation Decline? Country T1: N adds new partner, no children T2: N had new partner, adds resident stepchild T3: N had new partner, adds resident biological child T4: R adds new partner T5: R had new partner, adds stepchild T6: R had new partner, adds new resident biological child Australia No No(a) Yes No No No Austria Yes, if 1 No Yes No No No Canada Yes if 2 Yes if 2 Yes if 2 No No No Denmark No(b) No Yes No No No Finland Yes if 1 No Yes No No No Germany Netherlands New Zealand Norway Sweden United Kingdom United States Yes if 1 Yes if 3 and 4 Yes No(c) Yes if 3 and 4 No No Yes if 3 and 4 Yes No Yes if 3 and 4 No Yes Yes if 3 Yes Yes if 3 Yes Yes No Yes if 3 and 4 No No Yes if 5 No No Yes if 3 and 4 No No Yes No No Yes if 3 and 4 No No Yes No No No No No No No Coding of Conditions: 1 if married; 2 if undue hardship; 3 if N has low income; 4 if new partner has low income; 5 if new partner has high income and R relies on it. (a) If a court ordered N to assume financial responsibility for the stepchild, this would lower the obligation to focal child. (b) If N was delinquent and asked for a full review; in the review, the amount of protected income would increase because N has a new partner; if this is more than the income the partner brings, the obligation to focal child could be lowered. (c) New partner decreases the amount set aside for his expenses so could in principle increase his obligation. Meyer, Skinner & Davidson | 22 *Conference draft: Please do not cite* Table 3: Categorization of Countries’ Child Support Schemes A: Biology B: Residence C: Biology Absolute Primary Primary United States Netherlands Australia Sweden Denmark Norway United Kingdom D: Biology Modified Austria Finland Germany E: Biology Pragmatic Canada New Zealand Meyer, Skinner & Davidson | 23 *Conference draft: Please do not cite* Table 4a: Child Support Scheme and Degree of Family Transitions Scheme % births Of births to lone Of those born in a Of those who experience to lone mothers, % ever union, % ever out parental separation, % ever in mother in union by age 3 of union by age 15 union within 6 years D: Biology Modified 10 44 26 47 Austria D: Biology Modified 3 39 20 45 Finland D: Biology Modified 6 32 29 50 Germany* C: Biology Primary 7 54 21 57 Norway B: Residence Primary 5 29 30 51 Sweden A: Biology Absolute 17 37 40 67 United States Notes: Rates taken from Andersson (2002), Tables 2, 3, 4, and 7, period of data varies. * For Germany, we use the rates for “West Germany.” Table 4b: Child Support Scheme and Cross-Sectional Measures of Children’s Living Situations Scheme Austria Canada Denmark Finland Germany Netherlands Norway Sweden United Kingdom* United States D: Biology Modified E: Biology Pragmatic C: Biology Primary D: Biology Modified D: Biology Modified B: Residence Primary C: Biology Primary B: Residence Primary C: Biology Primary A: Biology Absolute % children living in % children living in sole-parent family step-family 14 8 18 11 19 12 16 13 15 9 12 7 16 10 14 12 16 12 24 14 Notes: Rates are taken from Chapple 2009, and cover 2005–2006. * For United Kingdom, we use the rates for England. Meyer, Skinner & Davidson | 24