Title: Land redistribution in Albania, its impact and the challenges of a postreform Edvin Zhllima 1, 2, 3, 5, Drini Imami 1, 2, 3, 4, 5 1. Development Solutions Associates 2. Faculty of Economics and Agribusiness, Agriculture University of Tirana 3. Department of Agricultural Economics and Engineering, University of Bologna 4. Institute of Advanced Studies, University of Bologna 5. Institute of Open Society (Grantee) Abstract In the early 1990s, Albania underwent the political, economic and social changes that took place also in the rest of Central Eastern Europe (CEE). Land reform was one of the main reforms affecting agriculture sector, economy and politics. Our paper is based on a study aiming to analyse the major institutional and structural results of the land reform in Albania. Our study found and re-identified the undesirable impact of the land reform of 1991, focusing on the Manez Municipality. On the structural side, the division of land created high fragmentation. On the institutional side the study found and re-identified many types of insecurity toward property rights. 1 Introduction In the early 1990s, Albania underwent the political, economic and social changes that took place also in the rest of Central Eastern Europe (CEE). Land reform was one of the main reforms affecting agriculture sector, economy and politics (about 2/3 of the population was leaving in rural areas, engaged primarily with agriculture). Land was transferred to the private agents (farmers - new owners), free of charge, equally per capita within each village. Land was spited in different plots, according to quality and location; consequently the average size was 1.2 Ha in the early 1990, and each farm consisted of 3-4 plots, resulting in high fragmentation. However, 15 – 20 % of agricultural land was redistributed to the “old owners” (pre collectivization owners) in line with the will of local residents. In some cases a mixed approach was used, respecting pre-collectivization boundaries. The land registration and titling in Albania was expected to immediately reduce the property right uncertainty of the Albanian farmers, encouraging investments and land transactions, contributing to the process of consolidation. 1 Our paper is based on a study aiming to analyse the major institutional and structural results of the land reform in Albania. The study focused mostly on reflecting the influence of the land reform on the emerging structure of agriculture production as well as in the land tenure insecurity created after the land reform. The main objectives of the paper are as follows: To reflect the structural impact of the land reform in agriculture; To find out the impact of the reform on the property rights (perceptions); To observe the agriculture land market performance in the context of tenure relations among farmers. The paper builds on a descriptive analysis of property rights evolution in Albania making use of literature review and an empirical conducted by the author in the Municipality of Manez. The paper is organized into six chapters. The next chapter provides a literature review of land reforms and the last land reform impact in Albania. Chapter three summarises the theory and the conceptual framework. Chapter four will describe the case study area. The fifth chapter describes the methodology used for the field research. The sixth chapter focuses on the land reform impact in the case study area. In the end are presented main conclusions and recommendations for further research. 2 Historical background of the land reforms in Albania After independence from Ottoman Empire, Albania had a highly unequal land structure dominated by Ciflig (large State ownership given temporarily to military and civil servants for merits). The remaining part was state and religious owned land and only a small share of land was designated as individual ownership. A market oriented land reform aiming at de-concentrating the agriculture land was initiated in 1932 by King Zogu I which failed to achieve this purpose. Between 1932 and 1945 the land inequality reduced because of the inheritance division process as well as due to the emerging land market pressure (Wheeler et al, 2003). After 1945, the Communist Party which came into power after WWII redistributed agriculture land to small owners and the landless. This redistribution was quickly followed by collectivization that was completed in 1976 with the establishment of large agricultural production cooperatives and state farms. Cooperatives was created 2 by a forced collectivisation process of family farms and State Farms were mainly created on formerly religious land, nationalized foreign agricultural enterprises, former big landowners or land made productive after continuing improvements. Different from other socialist countries in Central and Eastern Europe, the new constitution declared that the state or cooperatives were the sole owners of land except 3% of the land that remained privately owned, with a maximum surface of 1100 m2 per household (Wheeler et al, 2003). With the collapse of the communist regime in 1991, 80% of the agriculture land was to be distributed free of charge, to new owners in per capita terms based on the land surfaces of each village, strictly respecting the quality of the land and other indicators of its value. The remaining agriculture land was distributed according to pre-1945 boundaries. The process was accompanied by a registration and titling procedure (Giovarelli et al, 2001; Kodderitzsch, 1999) and by the creation of a unified system of immovable property, the Immovable Property Registration System (IPRS). The new owners were provided with initial land title that certifies the property right to land of family farm in the name of the household head. Data from Ministry of Agriculture tell that in 2007 has been accomplished the registration 87.5% of certificates distributed (MoAFCP, 2007). Table 1. Comparison among the land reforms in Albania Terms of land 1930 1946 1991 reforms Objective Reduction of the Distributing land to Distributing equally number of landless all rural residents in quantity and people quality land for all Surface affected 2.12 in % of agricultural land The rights given to Full rights new land owners transfer alienation 39.44 for Usufructs and 95.7 Full rights for Cooperatives Land Usufructs for State Farms till 1995 Land structure Big, medium and Medium and small Small farms emerged small farms farms Source: Guri, 2007 3 Table 1 (above) summarises the main features of the land reforms carried in Albania since 1930. It is obvious that the last land reform is the most egalitarian, most inclusive and radical in its objectives, area of implementation and its structural impact. The majority of scholars consider the distribution and privatization of land as a vital reform for the survival of the agricultural sector during the first transition years. National and international institutions assume that the individual ownership gave new incentives for farmers, boosting agricultural growth from which had collapsed in the early 1990 (WDR, 1997, MoAF, 2003). Despite the redistribution effect which was the first objective of land reform, there were also indirect and undesirable effects which mainly the structural fragmentation and the fuzzy land rights emerging after the distribution of land. A. The structural impact: On the structural side, the division of land created high fragmentation, with respect to the quality and distribution of land by families (See Table 1). As a result, the family farms are small (1.2 Ha), composed by many parcels (an average of 3-4 plots per farm), often allocated far from each other and from farm houses (from 1 to 10 km). Most studies in Albania conclude that fragmentation is one of the most negative phenomena of the reform (Lemel, 2000; MoAFCP, 2007 (a); Civici, 2003; Lusho et al, 1998). B. The Institutional impact. Despite the distribution of official titles, since in the beginning of the reform, scholars identified property rights insecurity in different areas in Albania. Lemel (1995) found two types of tenure insecurity: formal and subjective insecurity. By “formal” insecurity Lemel (2002) defined the insecurity coming from low availability of documentation, the registration discrepancies, inaccurate mapping, etc. Even after more than a decade since the beginning of the reform surveys carried in different parts of Albania still observe strong signs of formal insecurity on land rights (Mathijs, E., 2001; Stahl, et al 2007; MoAFCP 2007, B). By subjective insecurity is understood the owner’s perception on the insecurity of his/her property. Subjective property insecurity in Albania is affected by the unresolved issue of pre-collectivization owners, creating conflict inside rural communities (Lemel, 2000). In Albania are identified different types of subjective insecurity: 1. A direct type coming from the disputes residents among those having the land titles of the land reform and those having inherited land before 1945 (pre4 collectivization owners) in the villages (Lemel.H, 1998; Musabelliu et al, 2004; Wheeler et al, 2003) 2. An indirect type coming from Type A-The perception of people toward the changing patterns of policies regarding property rights. Such perception has implications on the nationally unresolved issues of restitution and compensation of the land owners of the period before 1945. The reform of 1991 did not take into consideration pre 1945 land owners but the pressure of ex-owners and the intervention of OSCE forced the government to approve a law for restitution, where possible, and compensation in financial or equivalent land terms in other cases. The process is still unsolved, generating still (perceived) property insecurity (OSCE, 2003: World Bank, 2006; IMF, 2006) Type B-The perception toward the institutions that manage the property titles and their transfer procedures (i.e. Immovable Property Right Offices, civil courts and notaries). This is relevant in the context of high levels of corruption (WB, 2007, CRSSD, 2007). C. The malfunctioning of the rural land market in Albania. The land consolidation has been seen from policy makers as a panacea for the low agricultural competitiveness in Albania and the land market as the main instrument of land consolidation (MoAFCP, 2007). Data and surveys show in the first decade after the beginning of the reform (Wheeler et al,2003; Lemel,2000; Moor et al, 1997, Kodderitzsch, 1999) until recently (WB, 2006; ARD, 2004; WB, 2007), a formal rural immovable property market scarcely developed in Albania1. Scholars found in Albania that property rights insecurity have a negative impact in land sale/buy decision (Lemel. 2000, Civici, 2003, Mathijsm, 2001, Stahl, et al 2007; Musabelliu et al, 2004) and in willingness to sell price levels (Guri, 2005:285) D. The environmental impact and the los of agricultural land. The legal and institutional failures in developing property laws after 1990 gave space to illegal occupation, abuse and irreversible alterations of agricultural land (USAID, 2004; Wheeler et al, 2003). The new Albanian farmers did not understand the legal 1 The Living Standards Measurement Survey (LSMS) 20051 gives some brief figures showing that 1.6 % of the interviewed farms sold land and 6.7% of farms bought land in the last 15 years. The IPRS database shows 32750 transactions of land per year which means, subtracting the lease, that less than 1.2% of total registered land in rural areas has been transferred per year (WB 2007). 5 obligations related to land reform2 (MoAFCP (c), 2007). Albanian farmers behaved similarly as their mates from other post-socialist countries, seeking to benefit from the ownership rights disregarding the associated obligations (Sikor, 2004). E. High number of land disputes and conflicts. There is a high incidence of land conflicts in rural Albania. Even recent surveys provides a large evidence of conflicts among villagers caused by overlapping land boundaries, clashes among the “post 1991” and “pre-1945” land titles, disputes on rights of passage, etc. (Stahl, et al, 2007, LSMS 2005, OSCE 2004). 3 Theoretical and conceptual framework Our research is based on New Institutional Economics (NIE) school which emphasis the role of property rights in providing certainty and improving the economic performance and efficiency (North, D., 1990). This school of thought accepts that free markets have transaction costs and assumes that property rights are the main force moving resources toward their optimal use (Pejovich, 1990). To maintain an environment with well defined property rights, NIE envisions the involvement of more actors than the state itself in the establishment of these rights. NIE considers more important the (informal) recognition of individuals or firms than the (formal/official) recognition by law (O’Driscoll et al, 2003). However NIE states that the State is a central actor in enforcing property rights and facilitating the transfer of resources to higher value uses (Davis et al, 1999). Barzel assumes that high transaction costs related to definition and transfer of the property rights, create a situation of non-complete property rights and impede people from finding the gains from their assets and the optimal distribution of property rights (Barzel 1997). Demsetz (1967) and Alchian (1973) show importance of transaction costs in situations of externalities created in the absence of rights, in shaping owner’s position in dealing with others by excluding and preventing them from interfering in his/her actions (Demsetz, 1967; Alchian et al, 1973). These concepts are reflected in Figure 1, in which the agricultural land market operates in the context of an efficient capital market as well as by an accessible market of 2 Although article 11 of Law 7501 maintains that those individuals that have land in ownership or in use are obligated to preserve and increase its productive capacity and to create systems of protection (Bockheim, 1998) 6 agricultural inputs and outputs. It also shows the direction of the impact by strata of interventions. Figure 1. Conceptual framework of the impact of property rights on agriculture development Source: Own contribution based on (Conning et al, 2006) The implication of institutions is very important. One of the basic arguments for scholars studying land property rights is that well defined property rights can reduce the risk perception future return on land use, creating incentives for short and long term investment (i.e. land productivity enhancement), land transfer (i.e. sale and rental) and crediting (Johnsen,1986). As a result, market incentives may flourish on both the supply and demand sides. 7 The efficient functioning of both the capital and land markets, in the context of property security, is assumed to facilitate the investments and reduce land fragmentation. Such changes can cause an increase of wealth for both buyers and sellers. Land buyers and users can increase production efficiency and turnover3. Secure property rights increases the land value and consolidation, therefore those who sell land have more financial leverage to shift to off-farm activities, while those that buy may benefit from the economies of scale. Land rights lead to the redistribution of land to its “best” use (Deininger, 2003 ; Swinnen, et al, 2006). According to some growth theories of structural change (envisioned by Lewis, W.A., 1954) the rural-urban migration could be facilitated at the meso-level (if urban areas can afford the smooth rural migration or the shift to off-farm activities is stimulated), and sustainable economic development could be generated in macro level. 4. Case study area description After reviewing carefully the literature on property rights security in Albania, a case study area was selected to investigate on land reform institutional impact in rural population of Albania. The field research was carried out in May 2007, in the Municipality of Manez, located in between the most developed urban centers in Albania such as Durres and Tirana, roughly 23 km from both of them and near to the sea (See Figure.2). Figure 2. Location of Manez Municipality in Albania 3 Data analysis of LSMS 2005 in Albania shows that 10% increase of land surface available to farms increase with 5% the agricultural production (WB, 2007 ) 8 Source: Albania Census Atlas, INSTAT 2004. Manez was selected because its rural community accepted the distribution of land according to the per capita principle, in line with the legal base of the reform. Another reason for choosing this area is its cooperative agricultural land status during the time of communism. This former status gives us a better opportunity to interpret the relations between ownership changes during the 20th century as it is based in former land titles which were collectivised in the communist regime. 5. Methodology of the study Most relevant studies on Albania try to identify or assess insecurity mostly through the assessment of title possession and the evaluation of the number of disputes. Since the survey made by Lemel (1998) on subjective insecurity, no research has dealt with insecurity perception of local agents. In this study we analyze the farmers’ perception on property rights or what is considered subjective insecurity. The study focuses on the same types of subjective insecurity provided in the literature review at Chapter 3. The levels of insecurity during the focus group procedure were rated through an interval from 1 to 5 where: 1-very strong, 2-strong, 3-not strong 4-weak and 5-very weak. Differently from the previous studies on land rights security in Albania, this study has applied a focus group method. The focus group method is used to elicit people’s feelings, beliefs, concerns and attitudes toward the land rights. It is a suitable instrument for acquiring the meaning behind facts and for giving insights into tendencies (IWOA, 2004; Kitzinger, 1994, Morgan, 1988, Krueger, 1988). The process of delineating the focus groups was based on different socio-economic indicators. The chosen focus groups represent different groups of interests regarding the land rights such as: (i) farmers that had land before 1946 (that potentially have land claims), (ii) farmers that became land owners with the reform of 1991, (iii) aldermen (official representatives and leaders of the local community) (iv) villagers that had done transactions of agricultural land in the last 3 years and (v) immigrants that moved to the chosen villages before and after 19914. 4 In 2001 immigrants counted for about 30% of the total local population, increasing the demand on land. The migrants came from vulnerable and mountainous areas of the Northeast part of the country or from areas that were selected for national strategic uses such as damns, lakes and mining activity. When the distribution of land began they profited from their share equally with the residents. 9 There were five focus groups were composed by six, seven or eight participants; a total of 38 people participated. . In addition, there we carried out 35 open interviews with other local residents, in order to better clarify, compare and verify issues that had come up during the focus groups. 6. The impact of the land reform 6.1 The structural impact of the land reform in Manez Manez inhabitants accepted the equal distribution and not other types of distribution, because the former owners were a minority, the biggest owners were not residing there, the land ownership perception was vague and the distribution of land gave higher surfaces in per capita terms compared with the land surface provided to the former owners if the land was distributed according to pre-1945 land boundaries. Further details of the land distribution procedure are given in the box below: Box 1. The “legal” distribution procedure of agricultural land Villages Land Distribution Commissions .— composed of 5-7 persons — were established to distribute land and certify property rights. After assessing the surface and the eligible population before 31 July 1991 they defined the surface per capita for each village. The land was allocated by quality and use, such as morphology, slope rate, infrastructure, inherited plants, and access to roads and distance from the village center. Pursuing such indicators, many villages divided the land into more than 4 different categories such as irrigated areas, planed areas, hilly areas, orchards and vineyard surfaces, etc. In order to be equidistant from houses, the parcels were divided in ribbon shapes and the divisions were developed in a radial fashion from the center of the village. Each resident benefited 0.35 Ha agriculture land from the land reform implemented in year 1991 in Manez, varying from village to village with respect to differences in population and available land. The newly created farms were small (1.2-1.3 Ha) (see Figure 3), composed by 4-5 plots on average (some of them, up to 8 different plots) with a maximum distance of 8 km from the house. Figure 3. Farm dimensions in the Manez Municipality 10 m ore than 3 ha Farm dimensions 2-3 ha 1.5-2 ha 1-1.5 ha 0.5-1 ha 0.1-0.5ha less than 0.1 ha 0 5 10 15 Share of agr. Holdings (%) 20 25 30 Source: Municipality statistics, 2006 During early transition most farms were “subsistence farms” because of lack of access to market, the high migration, limited financial resources and the limited off-farm opportunities. The farm structural change was accompanied with a reduction of the surface under irrigation because of the maltreating of the irrigation infrastructure (See Table 2). Approximately 25% of the land surface is left fallow as a result of low returns from agriculture activity, reduced land quality, limited irrigation and high migration. Table 2. The structural changes to agriculture in the first years of transition. Year 1990 Land distribution Year 1994 1 Number of units 1618 2354 ha Unit surface 1.4 ha 48 ha Plot surface 0.35ha 80% Land surface irrigated 49% Source: Manez municipality data Agriculture is the main economic activity for the poor population which represents 1/4 of the Manez population. However, the agriculture sector in Manez is loosing its importance and productivity has weakened slightly. The main couses mentioned in focus groups were fragmentation, long distance to market and the competitive pressure faced from the imported agricultural products. 11 6.2. The institutional impact -The subjective insecurity on land rights 6.2.1. The direct subjective insecurity The direct perception of insecurity are caused mainly from the disputes between the new land owners (those having land from the reform) and the villagers which shave inherited the same plots of land since the period before 1945-so called precollectivization land owners. In Manez Municipality there exists a general lower attention to indirect subjective insecurity of type A regarding the policies and the constitutional changes. The indirect insecurity of type B coming from the perceptions toward the main institutions which manage property rights is more emphasised and is mostly reported through the groups of pre-collectivisation owners, the “new” land owners (except youth and educated persons), the buyers and the aldermen (Table 3). Table 3: The perception of property right insecurity by groups of interest Subjective Pre- New land New Buyers and insecurity collectiv. owners. comers sellers toward PR land Strong Weak Strong Aldermen Interviews Strong Not strong Weak Weak owners Strong Direct Not strong buyers on Weak youth and for for sellers educated Indire Type ct A. Weak Weak Weak Weak Very weak for youth and educated Type Strong Not strong Not strong Strong Strong Not strong B. Source: Authors’ notes The focus groups organised with pre collectivisation owners placed property rights as root cause for agricultural inefficiencies and social conflicts. The existence of the precollectivization owners in the villages demonstrates direct subjective insecurity for the new owners. Discussions with them and the aldermen group revealed frustrating experiences of those possessing disputed land. 12 Most new owners were aware of their legal rights. Few of them, claimed that it is the right of former owners to seek their land, blaming the government for improper handling of this issue. However young farmers showed weaker awareness toward the former owners’ disputes. Discussants and representatives of public order explained disputes on land rise sporadically in the community bringing tension and refreshing the property rights issue. For those involved in land transactions, direct subjective insecurity was different between buyers and sellers. Buyers experienced doubts and preferred ancestral rights to reduce insecurity. Sellers declared that the formal rights were secure enough to assure the transaction of land. Their opinion was that the risk of not finalising the land transaction depended on the former owner’s willingness/ insistence to put pressure on one of the parties and block the arrangement. New comers, who “benefited” from the distribution of land or bought it from the local government, were less frequently showing direct subjective insecurity5. 6.2.2 The indirect subjective insecurity The indirect subjective insecurity of Type A which derives from the low credibility on reform accomplishment, was not strongly evident. The indirect perception of insecurity (Type B) is represented through the negative perceptions of focus groups members toward the administrative apparatus, which registers and enforces the land titles such as IPRS and the Civil Court. Majority of the participants in the discussions pointed blamed them for mismanagement, abuse, highly bureaucratic procedures, subjectivity and corruption, similar to different other surveys (WB, 2006) (CRSSD, 2005) (IDRA, 2007). Notaries have their share in the ongoing specific formal insecurity; reports show a low level of professionalism, ethical problems and legal violation conducted by notaries (OSCE, 2004). 6.3. The impact the subjective insecurity on the land market 6.3.1. The impact of direct subjective insecurity. 5 They were accused by other villagers for profiting from two distributions, one in the place of origin and the other in the place of residence. 13 The direct subjective insecurity was found to create low willingness to sell for some parcels which were subject to disputes with former land owners. Discussion with the group composed by the post-collectivization land owners and the aldermen brought up low willingness to sell land. In the group that had carried out land transactions, the insecurity impact was clearly divided in two types of statement. The buyers were more conscious of the former owners’ claims and started the transaction only if no serious dispute appeared. Potential buyers were more willing to buy (or perceived lower property right insecurity) on plots about which the pre-collectivization owners did not put pressure or “threaten” for any discretion or decision for transaction. Otherwise, former old owners, in some cases, obtained certain amount of money (5-10% of the value of transaction), against their commitment that they will recognize the new property transfer and rights. There exists also the risk that the price is reduced because the buyer takes the emotional costs of facing the claims of the pre-collectivisation owners. If the disputes are harsh and in the buyer is not from the village the transaction is frozen or blocked. It was a fact, expressed by notaries and the municipality that in the documents required for the transaction a certification from local government – proving that the land was not subject to conflict or a dispute over boundaries — was also needed. 6.3.2. Impact on land market of indirect subjective insecurity of type B. The indirect subjective insecurity of type A does not impact very much the land discretion. As for the type B on the side of land owners the errors in documents about the demarcation of land and the abusive orientation of the IPRO and notaries, in relation to documentation, negatively affected transactions. They were many respondents showing a fear of falsification of documents by notaries or IPRO personnel, or even the complete erasure of folders. All these problems arise not only before the transaction but also after the transaction is made. Interviews with the IPRO and experts of the notary and real estate agencies expressed the concern that if the alienation of rights is not registered in IPRO, this can break the chain of titles and make transactions valueless. 14 Table 4:The property right insecurity impact on transactions by groups of interest in the Municipality of Manez Subjective Pre- New land New Buyers and Alderm Interview insecurity collectiv. owners. comers sellers en s Weak Very Very weak Very Very weak weak toward land land transactions Indirect owners of Weak weak Type A Indirect of Strong Strong type B Direct Strong Strong Not Strong strong buyers Weak Strong Not strong buyers on Weak youth and for Strong Not Strong for Strong Strong for sellers educated Source: Author’s elaboration As theory states, a direct impact of property right insecurity is embodied in transaction costs. These costs exist in order to capture, transfer and enforce the property rights (Barzel, 1997).: The discussions with the focus groups and the interview revealed different types of costs such as High investigation and negotiation costs of potential sellers, because of numerous land disputes and the lack of transparency on ownership status. The interviews with real estate agents and the farmers who have experienced land transactions pointed that those which are not member of the community search for intermediaries/witnesses (relatives and friends) to do the investigations and negotiations which kept a percentage of the price (2-3% in most of the cases) 6. This happens because the buyers are aware of the conflicts that the purchased land can create, may affect the stability in their lives and their business in the community. One member of the group which made transaction expressed that: “When you come in Manez you don’t buy the home or land, but you buy the neighbour, which can be a bad one or good one”. 6 15 Another type of transaction costs are the high enforcement costs of property rights received. Interview with focus groups participants and villagers show that to register a transaction a villagers need to visit the IPRO an average of 15 times and the procedures can endure 6 months on average. The evidences from other surveys show that the official costs7 are duplicated by the bribes required from intermediaries or IPRO personnel, as well as distance costs8 (CRSSD, 2006:21). Conclusions The Albanian land reform remains one of the most radical reforms in the former communist countries of CEE with the highest level of de-collectivization and individual privatization, giving modest attention to former owner’s issue. The last land reform made changes to structural and institutional features that were identified as failures. Our study found and re-identified the undesirable impact of the land reform of 1991, focusing on the Manez Municipality. On the structural side, the division of land created high fragmentation in terms of average farm size and fragmentation within farm, which has direct impact on efficiency (economies of scale). and consequently,. On the institutional side the study found and re-identified many types of insecurity toward property rights. Similar to previous studies elsewhere, we found that in Manez Municipality exists a strong perception of direct subjective insecurity, resulting from the friction between the legal rights accepted by the majority of the local community and the ancestral rights which the former owners claim to have; as well as a strong perception of indirect subjective insecurity, which comes from the failures of the institutions that are responsible for property rights transfers and enforcement. The land rights insecurity has several important impacts: it reduces the willingness to sell or buy, it can reduce the returns from sales (a part is given to the claimers); it may also reduce the price of land, or in the worse case, it can cause an open ended conflict which can block or make difficult the transaction (and have other side effects). Farmers have difficulties in dealing with and excluding possible third parties (former 7 The normal procedure to complete an agricultural land transaction should last between 2 to 4 weeks and the cost of one exchange transaction is fixed at 70 Euro, from which 35 goes to the notary and 35 to the IPRS services. 8 The trip from the village to the IPRO costs 1.8 Euro. 16 owners, disputes and pressure of the community) from interfering in transactions and buyers have problems in capturing and enforcing the new land rights derived from the transaction. The overall transaction costs increase as the market suffers high pre-contractual and post-contractual costs. On one side the state can not fully secure, make transparent and manage the possession and exchange land rights. On the other hand, informal or community based self-enforcement and information diffusion, is only partially effective, given the heterogenic rural population. As a result of this insecurity the investigation, negotiation and enforcement costs are high and added to the contractual costs. Buyers are more oriented toward ancestral rights to reduce these costs, as a more secure attestation of the possession of property. Therefore, in the context of insecurity of property rights, state should enhance its central role in the land market. The state should “close the chapter” of clashes among ancestral rights and formal rights by permanently resolving the question of compensation and consequently bringing an end to the direct disputes of former owners. Also, formal rights have to be enforced by addressing the continuing legal, institutional and administrative inefficiencies. Consequently, the consolidation of property rights may decrease the land transaction costs, provide better incentives for land sale — for those who are ready to move out of agriculture — and facilitate the enlargement of market-oriented farms without destroying the social and economic equilibrium in rural areas. Resolving agriculture land property rights is a key step to promote agriculture growth, investments and efficiency in Albania, thus more attention from the policy-makers for this issue and more research can contribute to the future of the sector. 17 Bibliography Alchian, A., Demsetz.H. ,1973, “The property right paradigm”, The Journal of Economic History, Vol. 33, No. 1, pp. 16-27,The tasks of economic history, USA ARD, 2004, “Albanian registration organizational improvement project-Final report”, USAID, Albania. Auzins,A., 2004,” Institutional Arrangements: A Gate towards Sustainable Land Use”, Nordic Journal of Surveying and Real Estate Research Vol.1, pp.56-71, Sweden. Barzel, Y., 1997, “Economic analysis of property rights”, Second Edition in Political economy of institutions and decisions, Cambridge Press, UK. Bernstein,H., 2002, “Land reform:Taking a long(er) view”, Journal of agrarian Change, Vol.2, N0.4, pp.433-463, Blackwell Publishers LTD, USA. Bockheim,J., 1997, “Preparation of action plan and protection of land in Albania”, Land Tenure Center, Albanian series, Working Paper No 8, University of Wisconsin, USA. Center for Rural Studies and Sustainable Development (CRSSD), 2005, “Customer survey for the Immovable Property Registration System (IPRS)”, Tirana, Albania. Civici,A., 2003, “De-collectivization and reconstruction of the Albanian agriculture 1989-2002. A specific transition?” ENAM, Montpellier, France. Coase, R., 1960, “The problem of social cost”, Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 3, pp. 1-44, USA. Conning,J., Deb,P., 2006, “Impact evaluation for land property rights reforms”, City University of New York. USA available at: http://urban.hunter.cuny.edu/~conning/papers/Impact4Land.pdf, June 2007. Davis,K., Trebilcock,M., 1999, “What role do legal institutions play in development”, University of Toronto, Conference on Draft prepared for the International Monetary Fund’s Second Generation Reforms, available at: http://www.imf.org/External/Pubs/FT/seminar/1999/reforms/trebil.pdf, June 2007 18 Deininger, K., Feder, G., 1998, Land Institutions and Land Markets , Policy Research Working Paper 2014, The World Bank Development Research Group Rural Development, Washington, USA. Deininger,K., 2003, “Land policies for growth and poverty reduction”-A world Bank Policy Report, Washington DC, USA. Demsetz,H., 1967, Toward a theory of property rights, The American Economic Review, Vol. 57, No. 2, pp. 347-359, USA. FAO, 2002, “Land tenure and rural development”, Land tenure series No.2, Rome, Italy, available at: http://www.fao.org/sd/2003/IN0501_en.html , June 2007. Giovarelli,R., Bledsoe,D., 2001, “Land reform in Eastern Europe, Western CIS, Transcaucuses, Balkans, and EU Acesion countries”, RDI, Washington, USA. Guri,F., 2007, “Study of the land market in the Albanian coastal area (Case study of Durres-Kavaje area)-The importance of tourism and the land management policies”, PhD Thesis, UBT Tirana, Albania. Hurrelmann,A., 2006, “Understanding agricultural land markets: Insights from New Institutional economics and new economic sociology”, Humboldt University of Berlin, available at: http://www.isnie.org/ISNIE05/Papers05/hurrelmann.pdf, June 2007 IDRA, 2007, “Corruption in Albania: Perception and experience”, Survey 2006Summary and findings, Tirana, Albania, Available at: http://www.idra- al.org/pdf/en/Findings_Survey2006_Corruption_Perception_IDRA_web.pdf, June 2007. INSTAT, 2001, The Population of Albania, Durres, Albania. Johnsen, D. 1986, The formation and protection of property rights among the Southern Kwakiutl Indians. Journal of Legal Studies, 15, 41–67. Kodderitzsch.S, 1999, “Reforms in Albanian agriculture-Assessing a sector in transition”, World Bank Technical Report, Washington, USA. Kitzinger Jenny (1994), “The methodology of Focus Groups: the importance of interaction between research participants”, Sociology of Health and Illness, v.16, No1, pp: 103-121. 19 Krueger, Richard A. 1988, Focus groups: a practical guide for applied research., London: Sage, 1988. Lemel, H., 1998, “Rural land privatization and distribution in Albania: Evidence from the field”, Europe-Asia studies. Vol.50, No.1, University of Glasgow, UK. Lemel,H., 2000, “Rural property and economy in post-communist Albania”, New York- Oxford, USA. Lewis,W. A. (1954). ‘Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labor’, The Manchester School, Vol. 22, pp. 139–191. Mathijs, E., 2001, Micro-economic analysis of farm restructuring in Central and Eastern Europe-Case of Albania, EU PHARE-GTZ, Albania. Ministry of Agriculture and Food (MoAF), 2003, Annual Report, Tirana, Albania Ministry of Agriculture Food and Consumer Protection (MoAFCP), 2007, Internal report on land reform progress, unpublished, Tirana, Albania. Morgan. D., (1988), Focus groups as qualitative research, Newburry Park: Sage Publications: Qualitative research methods series. Musabelliu,B., Meco,M., Kercini,D., Vercuni,A., 2004, ““Land use policy-A survey on Albanian case”, Final Report, GTZ, Tirana, Albania. North,D., 1990, Institutions, institutional change and economic Performance, Cambridge, UK. OSCE, 2004, “Legal sector report for Albania”, Tirana Office, Albania, available at: http://www.osce.org/documents/pia/2004/02/2117_en.pdf , June 2007. O’Driscoll Jr, G., Hoskins, L., 2003, “Property rights- The key to economic development”, Policy Analysis No. 482, Cato Institute, USA. Pejovich,S., 1990, “The economics of Property rights: Toward a theory of comparative systems”, International Studies on Economics and Econometrics, Volume 22, Texas A&M University, Kluwer Academic Publisher, USA. 20 Stahl, J, Sikor, T. and Dorondel, S., 2007, “Transparency in Albanian and Romanian Land Administration”, Paper forthcoming in the next issue of Cahiers Options Méditerranéennes entitled "La question foncière dans les Balkans" available at:http://www.landcoalition.org/pdf/07_paper_transparency_land.pdf, December 2008. Swinnen,J., Vranken,L.,Stanley,V., 2006, “Emerging challenges of land rental markets-A review of available evidence for the Europe and Central Asia region”, World Bank, Washington DC, USA. Wheeler,R., Waite,M, 2003, “Albania country brief-Property rights and land market”, Land Tenure Center, University of Wisconsin, USA. World Bank, 2003, “Rural development strategy”, Tirana Office, Albania. World Bank, 2006, “Status of land reform and real property markets in Albania”, Tirana Office, Albania. World Bank, 2007, “Urban growth, migration and poverty reduction-A poverty assessment”, Report No. 40071- AL, Washington DC, USA. 21