1 « New Perspectives on the Study of Chinese Culture and Society » Princeton University (March 24th-26th, 2003) Towards a Social Approach of the Economic History? Christian Lamouroux (EHESS, Paris) Let me begin by recalling a recent experience, supported by the CCK Foundation to which I express my gratitude for inviting me here to-day. In 1998, I applied for a research program of 3 years: the title of the program is « Water Control and Social Organization in Northern China ». Northern China here refers to villages in Shaanxi and Shanxi where we have collected data related to the management of water by associated villages. Unsurprisingly, the steles and manuscripts collected during the 3 years give a definition of the identity of every association — among them some are more one thousand years old —, provide rules for the building and the maintenance of the canals and for controling the distribution and the use of water, or simply stand as a public marker of the decisions made for solving the unavoidable conflicts among users1. However, only field surveys shed precise light on the other aspect of collective management: the social power, including the symbolic dimension, encapsulated in the control of a resource as critical as water. Thanks to the field surveys, which provided us the different elements necessary for writing history, we have also discovered the basic social mechanisms on which the hierarchy of these local societies is still set up to-day. We would have been unable to shed light on the social function of the very scattered written texts we found had we not been able to put them back in the micro-level local contexts, sometimes just to achieve basic understanding of the highly specific vocabulary used: steles or regular copies of manuscripts give rules for using the irrigation canals (Jingyang, Hongtong-Jiexiu), or define the control exerted by rotation by each community on the drinking water (Huozhou) or for the protection of the statue of a deity reputed to provide rain water and other benefits (Pucheng). In all cases, they constitute official legitimization of the social power of the local gentry and their families, and they are regularly used as tools for the reassumption of the links between rural associations (committees of elders or community leaders or of a temple) and the xian administrative and political level, especially when they are originally the product of xian-level decisions taken to solve conflicts. Our results would never have been obtained without the collective research undertaken in the same spots by Chinese and French scholars, mainly historians and anthropologists. During the fieldwork inquiries, nobody understood the full complexity of the field, so, whatever the various specializations and intellectual backgrounds, we had to confront our questions, our doubts and our analyses in order to make hypotheses that then determined the research agenda for everyone. Even if this was the ideal process, difficult to realize every time, everybody was conscious that this is the only proper way to develop our research and collect material. Can the experience I have gained in the process be useful for my future research? At the very least, I have become strongly convinced of two realities: first, in China where written texts play such a central role, a pluridisciplinary approach is the only way to examine texts from different viewpoints in order to avoid to being manipulated by them. Second, fieldwork provides the best conditions for that approach. More precisely, the permanent to and fro motion between texts and field makes it possible to understand the social properties of the research objects in their local context — for us, the social impact of the canals’ digging, 1 Four books, published by Zhonghua shuju, are forthcoming: the two first volumes are devoted to two spots in Shaanxi (i.e., Jingyang-Sanyuan and Pucheng), and will appear before 2003 March. The other manuscripts, devoted to Shanxi spots (i.e., Hongtong, Jiexiu and Huozhou) have just been completed for edition process. 2 maintenance and management, or of the cults and their rituals —, and the integration of that social reality in a legacy, which the texts can transform into a local history. Since we are invited here for a discussion on some new perspectives, I will now ask, as a Song historian, which are the historical topics worth approaching through a combination of written sources and fieldwork, understood from the sociologists’ and anthropologists’ viewpoint as a space of social action and performance. If I try to define the common topic of our field surveys in Northern China, i.e., the federative link between every written text and the field, it was obviously the management of water by collective bodies, or the collective management of a natural resource (Jingyang, Hongtong-Jiexiu), or of the lack of such a resource (Pucheng, Huozhou). So, viewed from the pluridisciplinary approach, two aspects emerge from this topic: the social control of material resources; the making of the community itself, through the definition of the control rules. So it seems that the social or economic realities that a group can see as possible study objects largely depends on its own pluridiciplinary capacities. After those remarks drawn from my own experience, I will turn now to a more concrete discussion. Unfortunately, the Song historian has no Dunhuang manuscripts to read and, except for the Song huiyao, which is a textual reconstruction, and epigraphy, the firsthand sources he can use are very limited, especially if compared to the huge Ming and, above all, Qing archives. If we turn to archeology, some people are disappointed by the priority too often given to the sites where the material findings are supposed to be the most prestigious (imperial or aristocratic tombs), and so by the neglect of everyday life sites, like popular housing or workshops, even if, for instance, some prospecting and findings in Jiangxi on the ceramic furnaces shed clear light on the organisation of private ceramic producers on the eve of the spectacular growth of the Jingdezhen nationwide production. So it should hardly be surprising that the texts written by Song scholars are the only first-hand sources used by Song historians. The incomplete and one-sided viewpoint is not the worst consequence of using only Song texts: the problem would be the same with any written source, and the sinologist is trained to ask the appropriate questions of this kind of material. The main trouble with these texts is of course their silence on critical questions. Since I am interested in economic matters, I would like to elaborate on that point. Just like political history, which was reduced to an evolutionist history of the State and then died, economic history is in a sorry state due to its basic conception on «progress» and its frequent use of concepts unsuitable for premodern societies. In Chinese studies, the problem is complicated by the fact that the concepts were imported from a different intellectual tradition, and I view this fact as the direct origin of some approaches like «sprouts of capitalism», «slow economic development» or «backwardness». How to get out of this dead end? Li Bozhong’s work is obviously a development of the economic theories of Wu Chengming, applied to the local history of Jiangnan. Two main ideas emerge from his two books2: the economic process is viewed from local perspective; since the first book is devoted to the Tang dynasty and the second one to the Ming-Qing period, Li’s study puts no emphasis on a continuous, evolutionist process, but firmly links each economic process under study to its social backgrounds. This approach results in a convincing demonstration of the economic adaptability of the Yangzi delta region, based on the combination of intensive rice culture and commercial cropping, a combination which made it possible to support a huge demographic 2 Li Bozhong, Tangdai Jiangnan nongye de fazhan, Peking, Nongye chubanshe, 1990; Agricultural Development in Jiangnan, 1620-1850, Houndmills, Macmillan Press, 1998. 3 growth for a thousand years. So Li concludes on the following point: we cannot view this adaptative process as stagnation on the pretext that the social and economic organization never became commercial capitalism and then an industrial revolution. As he mischievously adds, every attempt at «modernisation and industrialisation» of rural Jiangnan, that is to say every attempt to break the special linkage between production and commercialisation as it was produced by the historical process, has had only one consequence: economic and social decline. The Jiangnan markets are here analysed as a central part of the social relationships of the region, and they strongly contributed to the longue durée transformation of those relationships. It seems to me that some prerequisites of Li’s research offer new methodological approaches to economic history. The economic process can be analysed from two perspectives: its emergence in the local context, and the feedback of the local society and the State on this process, a reaction studied through the making of central policies and regional or local management. Li’s study of the regional process focuses on some research topics common to different disciplines and makes good use of all of them. Here are some examples of these different topics: sociology of demographic attitudes, which uses demographic growth as an index of the relationship between social actors and not simply as an economic constraint; sociological and economic approach to the environment, which emphasises the cultural choices and the social and economic adaptations generated by the use of natural resources, like water, wood or minerals; institutional history, which makes an analysis of the fiscal policy as a factor in regional economic choices. In short, I am quite convinced by the richness of the approach, which is clearly the result of a challenge: to give up general explanation in terms of economic mechanisms supposed to be universal, i.e., the building of nationwide, interregional or local economic markets, with general financial tools like money or credit. In fact, Li’s study takes the sources available into consideration without neglecting their silent part. Is this silence only a consequence of ideological neglect about economical matters? I don’t think so. The fact is that economic activity was mainly viewed by the actors from social and institutional perspectives, and we have to understand why and how this view can have also supported the economic goals of local people who were always aware of the importance of economic organization in their search to strengthen local influence, i.e., their power and their wealth. So Li has also opened a path to a history of the reproduction and transformation of economic ideas, a history the writing of which depends also on fieldwork, since we need to make it clear the concrete perceptions of separate interest, private or collective, and the public good, the Chinese way of distinguishing between micro and macroeconomy, which was the basis of the development of the «political economy» in XVIIIth century England and France. Consequently, it is a path that should make possible new comparative perspectives. However, I would like to put special emphasis here on the pluridiciplinary conditions of this approach. Considering the kinds of sources available, I believe it is now possible to approach the history of economic organization in pre-modern China in terms of its own patterns. Roughly speaking, this pattern can be defined as follow: a multiplicity of economic choices resulting in the connection of different material cultures; the tension between the official and merchant networks, due to the complicity and rivalry of these two nationwide networks; the necessity for these two networks in search of efficiency to rely on the support of an omnipresent figure on the administrative and economic Chinese stage, the middleman. If we agree with this starting point, we have to take three aspects into simultaneous consideration: a history of collective economic organization at the local level which is a part of the social and cultural identity and is in consequence connected to other identity factors like religious patterns and material culture; a sociology of the local groups according to their level of action and interest, 4 i.e., the analysis of the different attitudes and strategies of the local administration, local merchants and rural producers towards regional differences with respect to resources, production of goods, manpower and funding; a social anthropology of economic action in order to shed light on peasant, merchant and official ideas of material production, I mean the mental way of transforming a project for the production of some item into an economic action, which means a clear distinction between production and profit. The necessary prerequisites for so ambitious a program are: a division of labor between disciplines, as historians, geographers and archeologists, sociologists and anthropologists would all have a precise role to play; the presence on every field survey of local scholars or specialists whose help makes it possible to choose the right places and the right people, to collect material and written documentation and so, to view history from local perspective. Without any doubt, these field surveys are only a part of the research program, their scale and intensity should be different according to the research orientation adopted and the questions raised, but I can mention some of their advantages. Considering regional economic history, how can we avoid mentioning Skinner’s work? The influence of his ideas over the last thirty years is due to the organic linkage he made, thanks to central place theory, between the three levels of economic activities: the productive activity of rural families, exchange systems built by regional entities differentiated by economic pattern, and a stability of the empire wide economic territory. I am convinced that fieldwork cooperation may give us a chance to put our feet back on the path opened by Skinner in Sichuan a half century ago: to approach the actors’ views on exchange, to understand the organisation of production, exchange and consumption of goods. We may raise simultaneously and precisely questions about economic mechanisms and the social conditions of their reproduction or transformation at various levels. To do so, just as Skinner did, we have to choose a survey space, I mean places and scales. Every place is patterned by history: this is the process of the making of its identity and of territorial hierarchies (this is the point emphasised by the traditional geographical encyclopedia everyone uses). These hierarchies are of course still often present and observable: we are in a city, or in a xian environment, or at the village level, where the collective groups were and are acting everyday. So any enterprise, private or collective, collective or public, has to deal with these hierarchies to transform the scale of its economic action: it is obvious when we are dealing with hydraulic systems, but it is true of any collective undertaking. Since we are interested in subcontracting systems based on a complex division of labor, which makes a distinction between production and economic profit, we have to choose one or two particular kinds of production. It is the only way to make a clear distinction between the scale activity of the entrepreneur and the direct purpose of the producer activity. Of course, here is one of the central parts of the program, and one of the main points to be studied by the anthropologists: which cultural environment is required to undertake an action in order to reach a goal fixed in advance, such as a work or a trade? How to make a deal, to bargain and to exchange a product for money3? Everybody is convinced that local rules exist to do this, so the key for acting on things is nothing but the good choice of the right man: that is my point, when I mention the omnipresent figure of the middleman, whether he serves the administration or a private entrepreneur. Field survey implies making a choice of sites and drawing up questions. How to choose a site? What is the kind of queries useful for specialists of social and economic history? And what are the goals to be reached through these queries? There is of course no single answer, and not 3 The institution named al-muqāwala, one of the Arab equivalents of our « undertaking », was set up as an answer to theses questions, after Hélène Vérin (Entrepreneurs, entreprise — histoire d’une idée, Paris, PUF, 1982, p. 20). 5 I shall simply mention my answers, derived from the fact that I am interested with other young colleagues in the social and economic organisation of the production and the commercialisation of silk and ceramics. Just as we did during the fieldwork on hydraulics, several basic criteria have to be kept in mind: the sites selected are still in activity, and they mobilize their legacy in order to enhance the value of their production; so their past is viewed as a long and prestigious history, and it is consequently quite easy to find some local scholars or technicians who are proud of this legacy and ready to make inquiries at the village level where they may find valuable material and written sources. Of course, there is almost no chance of finding pre-Qing written sources, but local epigraphy and archeology certainly may shed light on place locations, economic organizations, and above all provide objects and signs that a patient study by the specialists of techniques can transform into valuable information. Last but not least, anthropology helps to study vocabulary, ways of thinking, cultural clashes between contemporary organisations and «traditional» ones, including continuity and rupture. So fieldwork implies a « regressive » approach. That means it is necessary to ask historians of different periods, whose sole competence is to be able to read and to interpret texts in the political, social and intellectual context familiar to them, to work together. This is the way to analyse the organisation and the transformation of the production, stocking and circulation of goods, of distribution and consumption patterns, and the image produced by the society of its own economic activities: which activities were viewed as more necessary than others? How did the society make a choice? What kind of hierarchy did the society produce? How did those hierarchies change? In a society organized by hierarchical status what was the meaning of «undertaking»? This program is certainly ambitious, even quite utopian, but discussions among different specialists to-day should be very useful for a definition of common goals, just when the tools — Geographical Information Systems, including cartography systems, computerization and the making of huge data bases — are urging us to be more ambitious and utopian.