The contribution of organic farming to rural development: an exploration of the socio-economic linkages of organic and non-organic farms in England Abstract Organic farming has experienced considerable growth in recent years. Proponents of organic farming point to the environmental and nutritional benefits of organic systems, although these are contested by some. More recently, it has been argued that organic farming can provide rural development benefits through enhanced employment and through closer connections with the local economy, reconnecting consumers with producers and stimulating positive economic multipliers. Against the background of claims made for the rural development potential of organic farming, this paper considers the generation and retention of income, purchasing patterns, and direct employment impacts of a large sample of organic and non-organic farmers in England. The paper reveals some important distinctions between the characteristics of organic and non-organic farms and farmers. It is argued that most of these differences do not stem directly from differences in farming systems but, rather, reflect considerable differences in the people who operate organic farms as well as the distinctive business configurations they frequently adopt. In confirmation of previous findings, organic farms are shown to employ more people, but the data reveal few differences between the local economic connections of organic and non-organic farms. In turn, this suggests that simply comparing organic and non-organic farm businesses is too blunt an approach. Instead, it is important to consider other factors such as the type of enterprises found on the farm and the marketing routes adopted by the business. It is argued that commentators need to adopt a more nuanced approach, recognising differences between farming systems, farm types, the configuration of farm businesses towards different marketing strategies and the inclinations of those who operate such businesses. This shifts the focus of the debate away from simplistic notions that equate organic production with local supply and assume a local economic benefit, towards a broader conception of the local agro-food economy in which some farms have strong local connections while others focus their efforts elsewhere and earn important export income for the local economy. Keywords organic farming; rural development; economic linkages; The contribution of organic farming to rural development: an exploration of the socio-economic linkages of organic and non-organic farms in England Introduction Organic farming in the UK has experienced considerable growth in the last two decades. Although the 4,639 registered organic farmers in England account for less than 1.6% of the farm population, the market for organic produce has grown from £100 million in 1993/94 to some £1.9 billion in 2006 (Soil Association, 2007). Interest in the organic sector stretches far beyond the apparent rapid growth and buoyancy of the market. Organic farming is frequently promoted on the basis of the multiple benefits it is argued to provide; healthier food, an improved farmed environment and, increasingly, a contribution to the rural economy (Soil Association, 2006; Smith and Marsden, 2004; Renting et al., 2003; Pretty, 2002). In nutritional terms, while there is some evidence that “a predominately organic diet reduces the amount of toxic chemical ingested, totally avoids GMOs, reduces the amount of food additives and colourings” (Cleeton, 2004, p. 62) as well as increasing the amount of vitamins, antioxidants and beneficial fatty acids (Soil Association, 2005), others have argued that “current scientific evidence does not show that organic food is any safer or more nutritious than conventionally produced food” (Krebs, 2003)1. To date, it is the environmental impacts of organic farming that have received most research attention and, while some still contest the environmental benefits of organic farming (e.g. Colman, 2000) there is a growing consensus that it does indeed offer certain environmental benefits over and above those of conventional agriculture (Sandhu et al., 2007; Petersen et al., 2006; Wood et al., 2006; Hole et al., 2005; Shepherd et al., 2003; Cobb et al., 1999). More recently, researchers have turned their 1 This debate has been reinvigorated with the widely publicised, ‘early’ results of an EU Sixth Framework project which indicates that organic fruit and vegetables contain 40% more antioxidants compared to non-organic foodstuffs. http://www.qlif.org/about/index.html attention to the role of organic farming in the rural economy and specifically, the potential for organic farming to contribute to rural development (e.g. Darnhofer 2005; Marsden et al 2002; Pugliese, 2001). In this context it is frequently argued that organic farming can promote employment in rural areas and thus contribute to rural development (Morison et al., 2005; Smith and Marsden, 2004; Midmore and Dirks, 2003; Hird, 1997) and that it can also make a broader contribution to rural development, for instance, through the provision of environmental services that underpin rural tourism. Despite these claims, it has been argued that research on the wider “social impacts of organic farming is very limited” (Morris et al., 2001). Significantly, Smith and Marsden (2004) have argued that considering organic farming as “a panacea for the problems of rural economic development … has to be seriously qualified by examining particular types of overall supply chain dynamics which are operating in particular types of organic sectors in different local, regional and national settings” (pp.355, emphasis in original). In parallel with the growth of, and interest in, the organic sector, ‘local food’ has also taken on increased economic, environmental and symbolic importance. Much of this is concerned with reducing environmental costs, particularly food miles, but also a desire to increase local economic multipliers and contribute to the (re)connection of farmers and consumers (e.g. Cranbrook, 2006; Ilbery and Maye, 2005; Pretty et al., 2005). It has also been suggested that patterns of increased local food purchases, rather than revealing a strong turn to quality and locally produced organic food, actually points to a politics of “defensive localism” (Winter, 2003). Although organic produce is not necessarily ‘local’ (even locally supplied organic boxes may not contain exclusively locally produced food), and local produce does not equate with organic, there is nevertheless a perceived close alliance between local food and organic food movements. For instance, although the majority of organic sales are via supermarkets, sales through direct routes, such as local box schemes, rose by 53% between 2005 and 2006 (Soil Association, 2007). Combining a greater degree of localness in food sourcing with increased organic production would lead to considerable savings associated with the reduction of environmental externalities (Pretty et al., 2005). Whereas the economic and social benefits of reducing negative externalities and increasing positive externalities have long been recognised, the renewed research focus on the ‘local economy’ and interactions, clusters and networks within it (Winter and Rushbrook, 2003) may point to a role for organic farming and local food in developing and sustaining local economies. Certainly writers such as van der Ploeg et al (2000) have suggested that the operators of farm businesses have particular advantages to bring to the process of rural development, while Renting et al (2003) have demonstrated aggregate benefits in terms of additional Net Value Added stemming from a number of “short food supply chains” (including organics and direct sales) and Smithers et al (2008) point to the benefits of retaining a greater proportion of farming and food expenditure within the local economy. Similarly, in discussing the multiple rationales associated with the promotion of “locally sourced organically produced food” Seyfang (2006) argues that such food supply chains can, amongst other things, favour new “socially embedded economies of place” and “make a significant contribution to rural development” (p. 386) by giving farmers greater control of their market and retaining a greater proportion of food spend in the local economy. The assumed localised nature of organic food and associated social and economic benefits are not uncontested. For instance, Clarke et al (2008 p. 220) have recently commented on the “supposedly localised nature of organic food” and called for more critical and reflexive accounts of what it is organic food networks can do for us. Against the background of claims concerning the rural development potential of farmers generally and organic farming in particular, this paper considers the generation and retention of income, purchasing patterns, and direct employment impacts of a large sample of organic and non-organic farmers in England. If, as some of the authors quoted above suggest, organic farmers can play a role in engendering rural development by stimulating employment and helping retain money in the local economy, it is important to understand the socio-economic links between such farms and the local economy. Building on a methodology developed by Harrison (1993) and modified by Errington and Courtney (2000) this paper presents spatialised data on the socioeconomic linkages associated with different types of farming and also evidence of social embeddedness of the principal farmer2. In doing so, the paper seeks to contribute to the debate outlined above concerning the extent to which organic farming and organic farmers are embedded in, and contribute to, the development of the local economy. Rural economies, rural development and organic farming3 For most purposes the term ‘rural economy’ is a shorthand way of considering a range of ‘economies’ rather than discussing a discrete, unified and homogenous economy (Winter and Rushbrook, 2003). These various economies may share similar characteristics but may also be quite different in terms of economic linkages with the wider economy and reliance on different sectors, for instance. The shift in rural policy towards more of a territorial focus and the growing policy emphasis on regional and local sustainable economic development is associated with the development of research addressing interactions within ‘local’ economies. For example, writers such as Courtney and colleagues (2007; 2000) have considered economic linkages between businesses and localities. Analysis of purchase and sales links provides a method of exploring the extent to which farms (or indeed, any business) of different types are connected to local economies. There are a number of ways of approaching the concept of economic connectivity. Earlier studies of economic linkages (e.g. Curran and Blackburn, 1994) focused on the proportions of sales and purchases by businesses within certain localities, whereas Harrison (1993) extended the approach to include the monetary 2 Clearly, the majority of farms are operated by families rather than ‘a farmer’. Nevertheless, within the constraints imposed by the methodology adopted for the research (a postal survey) the questionnaire was directed at the main decision maker/principal farmer. 3 For the purposes of this research, the definition of organic farming was based on certified compliance although it is recognised that organic farming can be much more than this. Equally, by defining organic farming, remaining farms have been classified as non-organic although in reality non-organic farms exist on a spectrum of farming systems, some of which are ‘near-organic’. values of sales and purchases. Harrison’s methodology, which involved examining sets of farm accounts and tracing the location of input suppliers from receipts, as well as identifying the location of output sales, was particularly labour intensive and benefited from being able access to the accounts of a small (52) sample of businesses participating in the annual Farm Business Survey. In reflecting on her methodology, Harrison raised the issue of defining those with the greatest value of local inputs or outputs as being those with the strongest local economic links, arguing that frequency and number of transactions may also be a useful indicator of economic linkage. Another method that has been used to measure the direct, indirect and induced impacts of linkages on rural economies are input-output models. For instance, John’s and Leat (1987) examined rural development in the Grampian region of Scotland, while Midmore (1988) analysed Welsh land based industries. This technique, developed by Leontief in the 1930s, is based on the notion that production of output needs inputs (Armstrong and Taylor, 2000). Multipliers are derived from an input-output (I-O) analysis that identifies backward linkages in terms of a change in the deliveries of final demand on aggregate gross output, incomes and employment (Midmore 1993). However, the lowest spatial level of analysis associated with I-O models tends to be at a regional scale rather than a local scale. Therefore this approach may need reshaping to reflect the needs of a more local, rural focus as opposed to a larger area analysis (Robison, 1996). Furthermore, there is a high cost associated with collecting data for the transactions matrices that I-O modelling relies upon (Armstrong and Taylor, 2000). To focus on a sub-regional level, Courtney et al. (2007) employed a social accounting matrix (SAM) model to estimate the strength of local employment and output multipliers. Such a method enables first round multiplier effects to be calculated as well as identifying the linkages between a town and its hinterland. (Courtney et al., 2007; Courtney et al., 2006; Courtney and Errington, 2000; Errington and Courtney, 2000) have further developed this approach, initially focusing on the first round of economic transactions in order to establish the linkages between small towns and their local economics and subsequently using social accounting matrices to estimate local employment and output multipliers (Courtney et al., 2007). Highlighting economic linkages in this manner reflects a concern with a spatialised understanding of economic multipliers and leakages. If income is ‘leaking’ out of a local economy it reduces the amount of money circulating in the area and therefore potentially available for salaries, purchases, etc. Other things being equal, the lower the leakages from the local economy, the higher the associated multiplier effects are. This notion is captured by the New Economic Foundation’s (NEF) ‘leaky bucket’ analogy and its interest in strengthening local economies by “plugging the leaks” (Sacks, 2002). Moreover, the NEF have developed a multiplier tool (LM3 – Local Multiplier 3), which is based on a Keynesian multiplier model. LM3 incorporates three rounds: the first measures a source of income, the second determines of how much of income is spent locally, and the third determines how much of this spent income is re-spent within a defined geographic area (Sacks 2002). Thatcher and Sharp (2008) however caution that LM3 methodology may be too simplistic and is reliant on assumptions, estimation patterns and sampling.4 Indeed, some of these criticisms may also be aimed towards other Keynesian type multipliers (Armstrong and Taylor, 2000). The renewed focus on the local economy however, extends beyond traditional concerns with economic multipliers and has witnessed a resurgence of interest in the importance of clusters, networks and the embeddedness of businesses and entrepreneurs (Winter, 2003; Winter and Rushbrook, 2003; Murdoch , 2000). Drawing on these concepts, economic behaviour is no longer viewed simply in narrow economic terms. Rather, the behaviour of individual businesses is viewed as being linked with the associational capacities of those controlling it. Entrepreneurial skill is not seen as being 4 Thatcher and Sharp (2008) do acknowledge that Sacks (2002, p.19) originally conceived LM3 as a “quick and simple” tool for communities, businesses and local authorities to calculate local multiplier effects, rather than a sophisticated measure. held by an isolated individual but is located within networks of association or ‘clusters’ of other people with whom business operators can trust, collaborate and share knowledge with. Consequently, the transaction costs of the business are lowered. Such interest in social relations inevitability brings the concept of community into play. Community is a frequently ill-defined term referring to notions of settled populations with “a wide variety of kinship, social and political links plus a cultural awareness or identification with the local geographical area” (Curran and Blackburn, 1994, p.18). That said, the observation that the connections between people, and the collective actions of people who share some bonds are important is one that is hard to ignore. The concept of embeddedness (Granovetter, 1985) points to the recognition that economic interactions are also related to non-economic connections (including non-business connections). Individuals are not free of social relationships. They are embedded in a community and linked to others through networks of association (professional and/or social): “in other words, economic connections are embedded in social, political and cultural relations and structures. Indeed, strong political and social links are seen as especially critical for models of industrial development that have a strong local component” (Curran and Blackburn, 1994, p. 93). In such a situation, bonds of trust and friendship will develop and it is argued that these relationships can lower transaction costs. So, embeddedness may aid economic efficiency. In these terms then, if, as its proponents frequently claim, organic farming has a role to play in rural development, it could be expected to be associated with certain ‘traditional’ economic indicators such as employment but also perhaps closer economic and social connections to a locality. Thus, the strengthening of local ties may be seen as being a prerequisite for the formation of a stronger rural economy with the benefits of local enterprise cascading into the rest of the rural economy. This takes the study of endogenous development beyond the consideration of economic multipliers alone to consider the importance of a whole range of interactions and transactions which may strengthen the local economy (Courtney and Errington, 2000). Research interest in rural economies is closely connected with policy concerns regarding ‘rural development’, although as van der Ploeg and colleagues concede: “Any critical discussion of these issues must begin with the acknowledgement that, as yet, we have no comprehensive definition of rural development” (van der Ploeg et al., 2000, p. 391). For instance, Sotte argues that rural development “means providing non agricultural functions and employment in rural areas, fostering exchanges between sectors and territories, and thus breaking both isolation and mono-functional agricultural specialisation” (Sotte, 2002, p.12). Errington on the other hand, adopts a definition less overtly antagonistic towards agriculture, arguing that rural development involves “premeditated changes in human activity which seek to use resources within the rural arena to increase human well-being” (Errington, 2002, p. 11). In this sense, rural development is about more than promoting employment and generating income. That said, for many commentators employment remains an unambiguous and easily measurable indicator of rural development success. Jobs protected or created within a rural area provide the foundation on which viable communities can be based, as they in turn supply the economic multipliers that support other businesses and services. According to Midmore and Dirks (2003) employment is a central concern in rural development: “the approximate measure of rural community well-being is and should still be employment, because although the emerging paradigm of rural development suggests this should no longer be the end of policy, it is certainly one of the most important means by which further ends should be achieved” (Midmore and Dirks, 2003, p.3). Whilst we accept Errington’s notion that rural development is (or should be) concerned with bringing about broad based improvements in human well-being, within the confines of this paper we concentre largely on the economic aspects of rural development notably employment and purchases and sales in the local economy. We comment on some of the wider aspects of rural development elsewhere (e.g. Reed, Butler and Lobley, 2008). Given the long term trend of falling farm employment, at first glance it might appear that there is only limited room for farming to play a role in rural development. For instance, it is the non-farming sectors that tend to generate most employment in rural areas of the UK. Nevertheless, van der Ploeg et al (2000) argue that farm businesses have particular advantages in being involved in the process of rural development as long-term residents with the self-interest to run viable businesses and thus support vibrant economies. In addition it is suggested that farm businesses offer the opportunity to realise new enterprises in a step-wise manner. Farmers and their household members are able to ‘toe-dip’ into new opportunities, minimising business risks. While it is true that farming provides a resource base from which to experiment with new economic activities, equally, it could be argued that many existing farmers are in a poor position to respond quickly to market signals. Despite powerful driving forces evidence suggests that recent agricultural restructuring has been confined to a relatively few farms and that a distinct group of ‘resistors’ are particularly unwilling to quickly re-configure their resources and realign their businesses (Lobley and Potter, 2004). Despite the long term trend of falling farm employment, research on the employment impact of organic farming typically indicates a positive effect. Padel and Lampkin (1994) for example, estimate additional labour requirements in the range of 10-25% and Hird (1997) reports a similar effect, although the employment impact is sensitive to enterprise type. For example, Bowler (1992) found the employment impact to be positively associated with horticultural and vegetable production, while research in Germany suggests that on organic arable farms employment is 60% higher, but that no significant differences exist for livestock farms (Kohne and Kohn, 1998, quoted in Centre for Rural Economics Research, 2002). According to Midmore (1994), the impact on employment is positive for most outputs under organic production. However, pasture and forage crops are less likely to create employment with only half the quantity used compared to conventional production methods. Other production systems that have a considerably lower employment multiplier include the production of organic cattle, which uses 34% less than conventional production systems. Only organic milk production has a significantly greater employment multiplier than conventional production at 2.96 compared to 2.29. Morrison et al (2005) argue that while the number of jobs per farm varies according to farm type and size, organic farming generates a substantial employment dividend in rural areas as organic farms in the UK employ 2.52 Full Time Equivalents5 (FTEs) per farm compared to 1.24 FTE per conventional farm. Furthermore, it is suggested that a 20% expansion of organic farmland could create an additional 73,200 FTE jobs in the UK. Although there is empirical evidence to support the notion that certain types of organic farming can contribute to rural development through a positive employment effect, previous research suggests that the additional employment created by organic conversion is largely confined to part-time and casual labour (Centre for Rural Economics Research, 2002; Morris et al., 2001) and while for some, part-time employment may offer flexibility around other work and family commitments, casual employment by its very nature offers little job security. Indeed, there is some debate “whether job increases within organic farming represent sustainable full-time employment” (Morris et al., 2001). Moreover, technological change and greater labour efficiency over time could threaten the much-quoted organic jobs dividend (Haring et al., 2001; Offermann and Nieberg, 2000). Equally, the increasing freedom of movement of labour means that migrant labour is often employed in agriculture which, in turn, means that the rural development impact of agricultural employment in a given area may be reduced if migrant workers send a proportion of their wages back to their home country. Clearly, the local economic impact of a farm (whether it is organic or not) goes beyond employment. Bateman et al. (1993) also calculated the output and income multipliers6 for different agricultural crops and livestock (cereals, pasture and forage, other crops, milk, cattle, sheep and other livestock) for Welsh agriculture. Generally, the output multipliers suggested that for most 5 Morison et al. (2005) assume one part-time job is the equivalent of 0.5 FTE. Their survey suggested that a casual worker on average is employed for 41.6 days. Therefore, using 240 working days, which excludes weekends and holidays, equates to one FTE. By deduction, one full time employee will equate to one FTE. 6 These are derived from Input-Output model of Welsh agriculture at the regional level. outputs there were only marginal positive or negative differences between the organic and non-organic farming systems. Income multipliers, on the other hand, suggested that pasture and forage crops produce substantial more income than conventional agriculture with the former recording a multiplier of 4.26 compared to 1.88. Only sheep and cereals produced less income from organic production compared to conventional production. As a result of this analysis, Midmore (1994) concluded, “conversion to organic farming does have the potential to generate considerably wider social and economic impacts than simply on the farms involved” (Midmore, 1994, p. 368). Although this appears to be a widely shared belief, few researchers (notwithstanding the work of Midmore et al) have collected any quantitative empirical evidence. Exploring socio-economic linkages Our approach to exploring socio-economic linkages and the consequent potential contribution that organic farming can make to rural development has been informed by the literature reviewed above. Given the importance ascribed to employment impacts and the retention of food and farming spending in local economies in the literature, these are the main means employed here to explore the rural development potential of organic farming. That said, rural development clearly encompasses a broader range of factors and we also consider the extent to which farmers are socially embedded in their local communities. We therefore do not provide a fully comprehensive analysis of all aspects of rural development but concentrate on a number of social and economic indicators of rural development potential that are discussed in the literature but for which there is limited quantitative empirical evidence. In order to explore the socio-economic linkages of organic and non-organic farms a self-completion postal questionnaire was designed to capture a range of information about farm business characteristics, patterns of sales and purchases (the value and location of transactions), diversification activities, respondent demographic characteristics, embeddedness and participation in the local community and the extent to which formal and informal networks play an important role in the farm business (see Lobley et al., 2005 for full details). The choice of the postal survey approach offered the benefit of being able to conduct a large scale survey with limited resources. The trade-off was that there were limitations to the depth and complexity of information that could be collected and for this reason it was decided, in terms of economic impacts, to limit our approach to first round transactions in the economy. As such our approach owes much to the methodology employed by Harrison (1993) and by Courtney and Errington (Courtney et al., 2007; Courtney et al., 2006; Courtney and Errington, 2000; Errington and Courtney, 2000). However, in contrast to these more conventional economic studies, our hybrid approach also involved the collection of data on social connections and emdeddedness (informed by Curran and Blakburn, 1994 and Granovetter, 1985) and thus forms an initial attempt to consider a wider range of social and economic interactions which Courtney and Errington (2000) have suggested may strengthen the local economy. The sample was drawn by Defra’s census branch and was stratified to reflect a mix of ‘mature’ and well established businesses in some parts of England and more recently developed businesses in other areas, as well as reflecting a good mix of main farm types. The total sample comprised 1684 farm businesses in England, of which 684 were registered organic. The postal survey ran from early March to mid-May 2004 and achieved an overall response rate of 43%, although this varied from a 44% (302) response rate for organic farms to 35% (353) for non-organic farms. Respondents to the postal survey managed an agricultural area of 98,000 ha, of which 44,000 ha were in the hands of the operators of organic farms. This represents approximately 20% of the organically farmed area of England in 2004. Mean farm size was 155 ha (median = 68 ha), although organic farms in the survey were smaller on average. Data on the distribution of organic farms by size and type is not readily available from Defra so it is not possible to compare the farm size and type characteristics of the sample with the national organic population. However, a recent survey by the Organic Farmers and Growers (2004) and data from Soil Association registration lists provides some basis for comparison. As Table 1 illustrates, on this basis the farm survey has captured a relatively representative cross-section of organic farms of different sizes although it appears that larger organic farms are slightly over-represented. Similarly, Table 2 indicates that the survey achieved a good cross section of the main farm types. Turning to the respondents themselves, a range of personal and demographic data points to some significant differences between the people who operate organic farms and their conventional counterparts. For example, the mean age of organic farmers in the sample is 50 compared to 56 for non-organic farmers7. There are far fewer organic farmers aged 65 or over and a greater proportion of young (<45) organic farmers compared to their non-organic counterparts. Perhaps partly as a result of the markedly different age structure of organic farmers, they are also significantly more likely to have achieved a higher education qualification compared to non-organic farmers (51% and 30% respectively). It is well known that many farmers succeed to and eventually inherit their farm, while many also ‘inherit’ the occupation of farming but farm away from the core family farm. In the current sample, three quarters of respondents operated established family farms8 and managed 90% of the total farmed area captured by the survey (of this, 52% was in non-organic production and 38% in organic production). Family occupancy of the current farm or local farmland was often long term, with 22% of the sample tracing their family’s occupancy of the farm to 1900 or earlier. The operators of organic farms however, were less likely to have such long farming connections in the area and 44% were the first generation of their family to farm the current farm compared to 37% of non-organic farmers. In other words, organic farmers were more likely to be new entrants to farming of any kind. Consequently, it is not surprising to 7 This is statistically significant using an independent samples t-test. 8 Established family farms are defined as those operated by at least the second generation of the family to farm, either operating the original family farm or farming in the immediate area of the first family farm. discover that organic farmers are also more likely to have previously worked outside of farming (60% compared to 48% of non-organic farmers9). A further dimension of the emerging distinctive socio-economic profile of organic farmers is revealed through a series of proxy indicators measuring the degree to which respondents can be said to be embedded in their locality. The questionnaire employed three proxy measures of embeddedness: distance from place of birth, distance from majority of close family and distance from majority of close friends. Analysis of this data revealed a consistent picture indicating that, on the basis of these measures, the operators of organic farms are less embedded in their local community than their non-organic counterparts. For example, 49% were born either on their current farm or within ten miles compared to 64% of non-organic farmers. Similarly, 28% described most of their close family as living over 100 miles away compared to 18% of non-organic farmers. A similar proportion of organic and nonorganic farmers reported that most of their close friends live within 10 miles of their farm, although in relative terms organic farmers were more likely to have most of their close friends living at least 100 miles away. These results are also consistent with the emerging picture of at least a significant proportion of organic farmers being new entrants who had previously worked outside of agriculture and who have frequently moved a considerable distance from the roots of their kinship networks. The results do not mean that organic farmers are less involved in social networks but rather that they may be embedded in networks which are less ‘local’ and perhaps less geographical (e.g. virtual/mediated networks). The profile of organic farmers presented here supports the earlier findings reviewed by Rigby et al (2001) indicating that organic farmers are frequently better educated, younger, more likely to come from an urban background and to have less farming experience. 9 The association between organic status and having previously worked outside of farming is statistically significant using Chi Square test of independence. The farm business The distinctiveness of organic farmers is also reflected in the characteristics and organisation of their businesses. The CRER evaluation of the Organic Farming Scheme (CRER 2002) noted the tendency for organic farms to diversify, but did not make comparisons between organic and non-organic farms. The results of the present survey indicate that organic farms are more likely to have diversified into a range of additional activities (see Table 3), although compared to their non-organic counterparts they are significantly less likely to have diversified into the provision of agricultural services (9.6% compared to 18.4% of non-organic farms). Organic farmers, on the other hand, are more likely to have established trading and on-farm processing enterprises, providing the opportunity to capture added value and to develop closer connections with customers. Twenty-one per cent of organic farms in the sample operate a trading enterprise compared to just 5% of non-organic farms. The tendency for organic farms to have diversified into trading and/or processing activities is further revealed by analysis of the ‘routes to market’ employed by organic and non-organic farms in the sample. Direct and local marketing is a much more common feature on organic farms with 39% involved in one or more direct marketing route such as, farm shops, box scheme, farmers’ market, supply of local shops, compared to just 13% of nonorganic farms. Marketing channels are important because of the implications for local economic impacts. Whilst local marketing may help retain local household incomes in an area, the opportunity cost of this is the potential injection of income into the local economy provided through export earnings (i.e. food sales beyond the ‘local’ area). Economic linkages10: Farm business purchases Analysis of purchasing links provides a method of exploring the extent to which farms (or indeed, any business) of different types are connected to local 10 It should be noted that for the remainder of this paper, the category of ‘Other’ in the farm type classification, while capturing an important aspect of rural society, has been excluded on the basis that they did not necessarily represent farm businesses since many did not include any commercial agricultural functions. economies. In measuring economic connectivity (both in terms of purchases and sales) data was collected on the proportion (by value) of sales/purchases made by a business locally, regionally, nationally, internationally and also the actual value (totals and means) of these economic transactions. Consequently, it is possible to distinguish between businesses that are ‘highly connected’ in terms of the proportion of their sales and purchases made locally, but which nevertheless make a relatively small impact due to low sales and purchase values, and business which may be associated with a greater local impact even though their business is orientated towards more distant markets. A total of 470 respondents (246 organic and 224 non-organic) supplied details of the value of business related11 purchases made in the most recent year for which information was available. Together these respondents spent over £64m in purchases for their businesses. This clearly represents a significant injection of money into the economy although, following the economic linkage concept, it is important to understand where that money was spent and whether agricultural and related businesses purchases represent a source of leakage from local economies or an injection of spending that will be associated with local multiplier effects. A smaller number of respondents (443) supplied spatial estimates of where they made their purchases12. Analysis of the farm size and type characteristics of those who answered these questions revealed no statistically significant differences in terms of farm size and type between the main sample of 655 and the smaller number of farmers returning spatial data. Consequently we have not reported separately on the farm size and type characteristics of the latter groups. These respondents spent over £55m on purchases and it is this smaller group on which the subsequent analysis is based. At an aggregate level, 28% of purchases (by value) were made very locally (within 10 miles) and a total of 68% were made either very 11 Household purchases were excluded. Labour values were captured separately through salary rates. 12 As with most self-completion questionnaires, the response rate for individual questions varied according, in part, to the complexity of the information requested. It is therefore not surprising that fewer respondents completed this question or the equivalent question on business sales. locally or within the rest of the county. There are no directly comparable studies with which to contrast these results with, although Harrison (1993) found that 40% of the value of input transactions were made within the smaller radius of 10km (approximately 6 miles). There are a number of possible explanations for the differences between the two findings including the changing nature of agricultural supply networks since 1989 (the harvest year that formed the basis of Harrison’s study) and geographic differences: the present study includes upland areas where the nature of the terrain probably means that local services are often some distance away from the farm. Looking at purchases in more detail, Figure 1 presents data for non-organic farm businesses only. Non-organic respondents were responsible for purchases of approximately £30m, of which 26% were made very locally (within 10 miles of the farm), while a total of 64% were made either very locally or within the county. The average (mean) value of purchases in the county was slightly larger than those at the very local level (£54,672 and £38,529 respectively). That only 11% of all purchases by value were made in the national economy appears to point to limited leakages. Purchases in the national economy were also considerably smaller on average: the mean value of national purchases was £16,312 compared to £55,077 for purchases made within the county. Figure 2 presents the same data but for organic farm businesses. The organic businesses supplying spatial data recorded £25m of purchases. The lower value of total purchases compared to non-organic farms may partly be a reflection of the purchasing requirements of organic farm systems. However, it is apparent from Figure 3 that the mean values for local, county and national sales are not greatly different and neither is the proportion of purchases sourced very locally (within 10 miles) or within the county: On average organic farms made purchases of £32,110 within 10 miles of the farm compared to £38,529 for non-organic farms. Measuring economic connectivity in terms of the proportion of all purchases made within 10 miles reveals very little difference between organic and non-organic farms (29% and 26% respectively) although if the concept of local is stretched to the county boundary then the difference becomes larger; 72% compared to 64% for nonorganic farms. Although the total value of purchases made by non-organic farms is greater, the size of the non-organic sample is also larger. When mean purchases per farm are considered, again there is little apparent difference between organic and non-organic farms. Looking in more detail at different farm types revealed variation both within the organic farming sector and between organic and non-organic farms. In terms of their purchasing behaviour (i.e. the relative location of purchases) most types of organic farm, with the exception of arable farms, purchase a high proportion of inputs and services locally (within 10 miles of the farm). On the other hand, while organic horticulture farms source a significant proportion (42%) of their inputs very locally compared to non-organic horticulture farms (24%), organic lowland livestock and pig and poultry farms are less well connected in this sense compared to their non-organic counterparts (see Table 4). Extending coverage to purchases within the county reveals that organic dairy farms source 74% of purchases within the county. Organic lowland livestock producers make an even larger proportion (86%) of their purchases within the county although in that case the absolute sums involved are much lower than the equivalent spending of their non-organic counterparts (see Table 5). Labour use on organic and non-organic farms One of the most common claims made for organic farming in a rural development context relates to employment creation. At the most basic level, employment is necessary in order to earn income to purchase goods and services and also brings with it a range of less tangible benefits such as social contact and a feeling of self worth. While employment is not the only goal of rural development, it can be seen as a principal means of meeting several objectives. The farms in the sample employed a total of 3,071 people, of which organic farm businesses accounted for 60%. On average organic farm businesses employed 6.4 people per farm compared to 4.8 people on nonorganic farms. One implication is immediately clear; organic farms ‘punch above their weight’ in employment provision. They account for less than half the sample but more than half of all employment recorded and despite operating smaller farms (in terms of area) organic farms employ more people per farm. However, while absolute numbers of people employed may be taken as an indicator of rural development impacts at the farm level, it obscures differences in terms of full-time labour, part-time, causal and seasonal employees. In particular, 55% of labour on non-organic farms is provided by full-time, 22% by part-time and 23% casual/seasonal workers compared to 44%, 21% and 35% respectively on organic farms. Given the differences in the composition of the total labour force within the survey, a more meaningful comparison is to standardise labour into Full Time Equivalents (FTEs)13. In these terms the surveyed farm businesses employ 2,016 FTEs, of which 1,125 (56%) are found on non-organic farms. In terms of salaried non-family as opposed to family labour, on average organic farms provide work for more FTEs (59% of all non-family FTEs in the sample compared to 41% for non-organic farms) and this employment effect is even more marked when considering FTEs per ha. These differences are at least partly explained by differences between farm types, with some organic farms employing significantly more labour in FTE terms than comparable (in terms of farm type) non-organic farms. For example, organic arable, horticulture, mixed and pig and poultry farms all employ more FTEs than their non-organic counterparts. In particular, the role of organic horticultural farms complicates the picture, supporting fewer employed non-family FTEs but significantly more family FTE labour (see Table 6). Overall, organic horticultural farms generate higher levels of FTEs/ha than their non-organic counterparts and given the significance of horticulture within the organic sample14, this is likely to impact on the aggregate mean figures for employment on organic farms. A further explanation relates to the very different business model adopted by some 13 The calculation of FTEs was based on the definition from Errington and Gasson (1996) where: full-time = 1 worker, part-time = 0.5 of a worker, casual = 0.33 of a worker and seasonal = 0.125 of a worker). 14 There were three times more horticultural farms in the organic sample compared to the non-organic sample. organic businesses. As the earlier analysis indicated, organic farmers are more likely to be involved in diversification, on-farm processing and direct sales, all of which could be expected to have an employment impact. Indeed, 27% of organic farmers report increasing employment following conversion, employing on average an additional 1.73 FTE labour units. Overall, the employment of more non-family FTEs in organic farm businesses indicates that, in this sense, they are more likely to support the local economy rather than just their own farming family. These findings support earlier studies that examined employed labour requirements on organic farms. For example, Padel and Lampkin (1994) estimated that increases in labour normally range between 10 and 25 per cent higher than conventional farms, with similar findings reported by Hird (1997). Labour requirements depend, of course, on the type and mix of enterprises that make up the farm holding. As a general rule, the more diverse the enterprise mix is the higher the labour requirements will be, as the benefits of specialisation and economies of scale are lost (Centre for Rural Economics Research, 2002). Some of this diversity is illustrated when employed labour use on different organic farm types is considered. Comparing the results of the survey reported here with that of Morrison and colleagues (2005) demonstrates that, with the exception of horticultural farms, most FTE labour requirements between the two surveys are remarkably similar, although the values of Morrison et al. tend to be greater. For example, Morrison et al. report 2.74 FTEs labour use for arable farms compared to 2.19 in the current paper; 1.63 FTEs for livestock farms compared to 1.55 FTEs; and 2.84 FTEs for mixed farms against 2.17 in this research. Establishing the number of jobs supported by organic and non-organic farms is one thing but it is also important to identify rates of pay for family and nonfamily employees. Together, the organic and non-organic farm businesses in the survey have an annual salary bill of approximately £23m. The salary per FTE is approximately £1,400 lower for organic farms, although this is largely accounted for by low family ‘wages’ as non-family labour is paid at a marginally higher rate. However, the data on the salaries of family labour must be treated with some caution, particularly where this represents a farmer and spouse as many farmers do not pay themselves a wage that is easily comparable with salaried workers either within farming or beyond. Farm Business Sales Turning to farm sales, as an indication of the ability of farms to generate value in the economy at the aggregate level, the 468 respondents supplying sales data generated sales of £88.9m. Mean sales per farm were higher for nonorganic businesses at £231,624 compared to £152,862 for organic farm businesses, with this difference being significant in a statistical sense. 15 In both instances though, the wide range of farm sizes, between the extremes of micro businesses to some very large businesses skews the mean figure towards the largest business and as such the respective median values of £77,170 and £48,293 give a more accurate picture. Given the differences in the farm size structure of the organic and non-organic samples comparing the values of sales generated per hectare provides a more robust basis for comparison. On this basis, organic farm businesses generate sales of substantially greater value per hectare compared to non-organic farms, £2,837 ha-1 and £1,857 ha-1. However, when the median figures are considered this difference reduces considerably to £722 ha-1 for organic farms and £650 ha-1 for non-organic. This suggests that only a few organic farms manage to create a greater sales value per hectare whereas most perform at a similar level to their conventional counterparts. Again, a slightly smaller number of respondents (430) supplied information on the spatial destination of sales, recording sales totalling £76m or an average of £177,349 per farm. In terms of the spatial distribution of sales, 33% took place locally (this compares to 33% within 10 km in Harrison’s study), 30% within the rest of the county and just 13% in the national economy. Considering sales from organic and non-organic farms, 37% of all sales by value (£34.4m) were associated with organic farms. Figures 3 and 4 present data on the spatial economic connectivity of sales behaviour for organic and 15 This is statistically significant using an independent samples t-test. non-organic businesses. A first point to note is that while the mean values and absolute values of sales differ, in terms of their very local and county level connectedness the two sub-samples differ very little. Indeed, 56% of the value of sales from non-organic farms were either made within ten miles of the farm or within the county compared to 57% for organic farms. Organic farms however, are slightly less locally orientated than their non-organic counterparts with the value of local sales accounting for only 20% of the total sales made by organic farms compared to 27% for non-organic farms. On the basis of this measure, organic farms are no more connected to their local economy than non-organic farms and the value of their sales is less. One interpretation of these results is that organic farming does not lead to a benefit to rural economies over and above that of conventional agriculture. Despite the increasing importance of the ‘local food’ market and the greater use of local and direct sales routes by organic farmers, a lower proportion of their sales are located in the local area. One explanation may relate to the definition of local16 although an alternative explanation is that treating both organic and non-organic farms homogenous groups obscures important distinctions which may be revealed by exploring differences associated with farm type classifications or indeed alternative methods of categorising farm businesses. Further analysis indicated substantial differences in terms of economic connectivity between organic and non-organic farms that are ostensibly of the same type. As with purchases, there are considerable differences between different types of organic farm. For instance, organic horticultural farm businesses appear highly connected to their local economy with 67% of sales (by value) taking place locally (within a radius of 10 miles) and with mean local sales of close to £37k per farm (see Tables 6 and 7). Non-organic horticultural farms on the other hand made only 33% of sales locally with a significantly lower mean value of £5k per farm. Non-organic horticultural farms in the sample are much more focused on regional and national sales, which account 16 Farmers may be travelling further than ten miles to participate in farmers’ markets for instance. for 48% of sales.17 Within the organic sector there are marked differences between different types of farm. For instance, 59% of arable and dairy farm sales take place outside of the county, compared to 35% for all organic farms. This greater focus of organic dairy and arable farms on regional and national markets both in terms of sales behaviour and the value of sales represents an important injection of ‘export income’ back into the local economy. It also clearly indicates that the 'organicness' of the farming system is not necessarily a marker of the localness of a farm’s marketing strategy. Discussion and Conclusions Recent years have seen the concept of the localness of food production and purchase become increasingly important as a means of addressing food miles issues, contributing to the (re)connection of farmers and local consumers, and retaining income in the local economy (e.g. Smithers 2008; Pretty et al 2005). At the same time, the role of organic farming has been explored in the context of its potential to provide a means of securing wider rural development benefits due to the employment dividend associated with organic production and the assumed closer linkages between organic farms and the local economy (e.g. Seyfang, 2006; Midmore and Dirks, 2003; Renting et al 2003). The analysis presented in this paper has certainly revealed and confirmed some important distinctions between the characteristics of organic and nonorganic farms and farmers. Arguably, most of these differences do not stem directly from differences in farming systems but, rather, reflect considerable differences in the people who operate organic farms, as well as the distinctive business configurations they frequently adopt (e.g. in terms of the incidence and type of diversification, routes to market, etc). The analysis presented in this paper has confirmed that the people who operate organic farms are typically younger and more highly educated than their non-organic counterparts and a significant proportion have entered 17 This should be interpreted with caution, as there were only eight non-organic horticultural farms. agriculture as an entirely new ‘career’. It is reasonable to assume that this distinctive group of organic farmers brings with it different skills and aptitudes and possibly also a different attitude to operating a farm business. They certainly appear more willing and/or able to diversify their farm businesses and to do so in a different manner to their non-organic counterparts. These characteristics alone may be considered to provide evidence that organic farming, or more precisely, organic farmers can have a wider role to play in rural development, perhaps by demonstrating that alternative food business can be developed by new entrants and thus encouraging others to enter the sector, or by contributing their skills and experience to cooperative endeavours. In terms of the proxy measures employed in this research, organic farmers are less well socially embedded in their local communities than non-organic farmers but given that many have made a positive choice to enter organic farming after another career it is perhaps not surprising that they now find themselves living at some distance from most of their close family and friends. In confirmation of previous findings (e.g. Morrison et al 2005; Offermann and Nieberg, 2000), organic farms in the survey employed more people. Importantly, from a rural development perspective, the present survey has demonstrated that not only do organic farms generate more employment but they also employ a greater proportion of non-family FTEs. Such businesses are therefore not simply providing employment for their extended family but also for others who live and/or work in rural areas. There is also some evidence that salary levels for non-family labour on organic farms are higher, although this requires further investigation. However, despite the distinctive profile of organic farmers and despite quite radical differences in farming systems, the analysis presented here also clearly reveals that, at an aggregate level, the economic connectivity of organic and non-organic farms is not dissimilar. Although the non-organic sample generated greater sales in total and spent more on purchased inputs, the mean sales figures and proportion of sales according to distance from the farm differed only marginally compared to organic farms. In turn, this suggests that in terms of patterns of sales and purchases there are no appreciable differences in the rural development potential of organic and non-organic farms. Such a conclusion is, however, overly simplistic. The data presented in this paper clearly demonstrate that simply comparing organic and non-organic farm businesses is too blunt an approach. Treating organic farms (and nonorganic farms) as homogenous sectors does not help in identifying rural development potential. Indeed, we have seen that by combining organic status and farm type it is possible to identify those organic businesses that have particularly strong local economic connections, both compared to their non-organic counterparts and other organic farms. Organic horticultural farm businesses emerge from this analysis as being amongst the most likely to operate short, local supply chains. Their marketing orientation is distinctly more local both compared to non-organic horticultural businesses and other organic farms, suggesting that it is not organic status or farm type alone or in combination that is the most useful indicator of a farm’s local economic connectivity and rural development potential, but a combination of these factors as well as the way in which the business configures it’s marketing routes. As this paper has shown, organic farming and local supply are by no means synonymous with each other. Consequently, it is important for policy makers and researchers to adopt a more nuanced approach, recognising differences between farming systems, farm types, the configuration of farm businesses towards different marketing strategies and the inclinations of those who operate such businesses. This then shifts the debate away from simple notions that equate organic production with local supply and assume a local economic benefit, towards a broader understanding of the local agro-food economy in which some farms (which may or may not be organic) have strong local connections while others focus their efforts elsewhere and earn important export income for the local economy. Acknowledgements We are grateful to Defra for funding the research on which this paper is based. References Armstrong, H. and Taylor, J. 2000 Regional economics and policy (3rd Edition), Blackwell, Oxford, 437pp. Bateman, D. I, Hughes, G. O., Lampkin, N. H., Midmore, P. and Ray, C. 1993. Pluriactivity and the Rural Economy in Less Favoured Areas of Wales. Report for the ESRC. Department of Economics and Agricultural Economics, University of Wales, Aberystwyth. Bowler, I. 1992. Sustainable agriculture as an alternative path of farm business development. In: Bowler, I., Bryant, C., and Nellis, M. (Eds) Contemporary Rural Systems in Transition, Volume 1. CABI, Wallingford. 296pp. Centre for Rural Economics Research, 2002. Economic evaluation of the organic farming scheme: final report to DEFRA. Department of Land Economy, Cambridge University, Cambridge, 122pp. Clarke, N., Cloke, P. Barnett, C. and Malpass, A. 2008. The spaces and ethics of organic food. Journal of Rural Studies, 24 (3), 219-230. Cleeton, J. 2004. Organic food in relation to Nutrition and health. Coronary and Diabetic Care in the UK 2004, 58-63. Cobb, D., Feber, R., Hopkins, A., Stockdale, L., O’Riordan, T., Clements, B., Firbank, L., Goulding, K., Jarvis, S. and Macdonald, D. 1999. Integrating the environmental and economic consequences of converting to organic agriculture: evidence from a case study. Land Use Policy, 16, (4), 207-221. Colman, D. R. 2000. Comparative economics of farming systems. In: P. Tinker (end), Shades of green - a review of UK farming systems. Royal Agricultural Society of England, Stoneleigh, 42-58. Courtney & Errington (2000) The Role of Small Towns in the Local Economy and some Implications for Development Policy. Local Economy, 15 (4), 280301. Courtney, P., Hill, G. and Roberts, D. 2006. The role of natural heritage in rural development: An analysis of economic linkages in Scotland. Journal of Rural Studies, 22, (4), 469-484. Courtney, P., Mayfield, L., Tranter, R., Jones, P. and Errington, A. 2007. Small towns as ‘sub-poles’ in English rural development: Investigating rural–urban linkages using sub-regional social accounting matrices. Geoforum, 38 (6), 1219-1232. Cranbrook, C. 2006. The Real Choice: How local foods can survive the supermarket onslaught. CPRE, London. 24pp. Curran, J., and Blackburn, R. 1994. Small Firms and Local Economic Networks. London, Chapman. 224pp. Darnhofer, I. 2005. Organic Farming and Rural Development: Some Evidence from Austria. Sociologia Ruralis, 45 (4), 308–323. Errington, A. and Gasson, R. 1996. The Increasing Flexibility of the Farm Horticultural Workforce in England and Wales. Journal of Rural Studies, 12 (2), 127-141. Errington, A. 2002. Developing tools for rural development: a multidisciplinary research agenda. In: Arzeni, A., Espostri, R. and Sotte, F. (Eds) European Policy Experiments with Rural development, EAAE, Kiel.19-41. Errington, A. and Courtney, P. 2000. Tracing the "Economic Footprint" of market towns: A Methodological Contribution to Rural Policy Analysis. Agricultural Economics Society Annual Conference, Manchester. Granovetter, M. 1985. Economic action and social structure: the problem of embeddedness. American Journal of Sociology 91, 481-510. Häring, A., Dabbert, S., Offermann, F. and Nieberg, H. 2001. Benefits of Organic Farming for Society. Paper presented at The European Conference – Organic Food and Farming - Towards Partnership and Action in Europe, Copenhagen, Denmark. Harrison, L., 1993. The impact of the agricultural industry on the rural economy – tracking the spatial distribution of farm inputs and outputs. Journal of Rural Studies 9, 81–88. Hird, V. 1997. Double Yield. SAFE Alliance, London. Hole, D. G., Perkins, A. J., Wilson, J. D., Alexander, I. H., Grice, P. V., and Evans, A. D. 2005. Does organic farming benefit biodiversity? Biological Conservation, 122, 113-130. Ilbery, B. and Maye, D., 2005. Food supply chains and sustainability: evidence from specialist food producers in the Scottish/English borders. Land Use Policy 22, 331-344. Köhnem M. and Köhn, O. 1998. Betriebsumstellung auf ökologischen Landbau – Auswirkungen der EU-Förderung in den neuen Bundesländern. Berichte der Landwirtschaft 76, 329-365. Quoted in Centre for Rural Economics Research, 2002. Economic evaluation of the organic farming scheme: final report to DEFRA. Department of Land Economy, Cambridge University, Cambridge, 122pp. Johns, P.M. and Leat, P.M.K., 1987. The application of modified grit input– output procedures to rural development analysis in Grampian Region. Journal of Agricultural Economics 38, 243–256. Krebs, J. 2003. Is Organic food better for you? Speech to Cheltenham Science Festival, 4 June 2003. Lobley, M. and Potter, C. 2004. Agricultural change and restructuring: recent evidence from a survey of agricultural households in England. Journal of Rural Studies 20 (4), 499-510. Lobley, M., Reed, M. and Butler, A. with Courtney, P. and Warren, M. 2005. The Impact of Organic Farming on the Rural Economy in England. Final Report to DEFRA. CRR Research Report No. 11, Exeter, 132pp. Marsden, T., Banks, J. and Bristow, G. 2002. The social management of rural nature: understanding agrarian-based rural development. Environment and Planning A, 34, 809-25. Midmore, P., 1988. The impact of agricultural policy on the Welsh economy: an input–output approach. Unpublished PhD thesis. University College of Wales, Aberystwyth. Midmore, P. 1993. Input-Output Forecasting of Regional Agricultural Policy Impacts. Journal of Agricultural Economics, 44 (2), 284-300. Midmore, P. 1994. Input-Output Modelling of Organic Farming and the Rural Economy of England and Wales. In: Lampkin, N. and Padel, S. (Eds.), The Economics of Organic Farming. An International Perspective. Wallingford, C. A. B. International, pp.361-369. Midmore, P. and Dirks, J. 2003. The development and use of 'rapid assessment methods' in ex-Ante and ex-Post evaluations of policy initiatives in the rural economy. Agricultural Economics Society Annual Conference, Seale Hayne Campus, Plymouth University. Morison J., Hine, R. and Pretty, J. 2005. Survey and analysis of Labour on Organic Farms in the UK and Republic of Ireland, International Journal of Agricultural Sustainability, 3 (1), 24-43. Morris, C., Hopkins, A. and Winter, M. 2001. Comparison of the social, economic and environmental effects of organic, ICM and conventional Farming. Cheltenham, Countryside Agency. Murdoch, J., Marsden, T. and banks, J. 2000. Quality, nature, and embeddedness: some theoretical considerations in the context of the food sector. Economic Geography, 76(2), 107-125. Offermann, F. and H. Nieberg 2000. Economic performance of organic farms in Europe. University of Hohenhiem, Hohenhiem. Padel, S. and Lampkin, N. 1994. Conversion to Organic Farming: An Overview. In Lampkin N. and Padel S. (Eds), The Economics of Organic Farming: An International Perspective. CAB International, Wallingford, pp. 295-313. Petersen, S. Axelsen, J. A., Tybirk, K., Aude, E. and Vestergaard, P. 2006. Effects of organic farming on field boundary vegetation in Denmark Agriculture, Ecosystems & Environment, 13 (1-4), 302-306. Pretty, J. 2002. Agri-culture: Reconnecting People, Land and Nature. Earthscan, London. 261pp. Pretty, J., Ball, A., Lang, T. and Morison, J. 2005. Farm costs and food miles: An assessment of the full cost of the UK weekly food basket. Food Policy, 30, 1-19. Pugliese, P. 2001. Organic farming and sustainable rural development. A multifaceted and promising convergence. Sociologia Ruralis, 41(1), 112-131. Reed, M., Butler, A., and Lobley, M. 2008. Growing Sustainable Communities: Understanding the Social-Economic Footprints of Organic Family Farms in Farnworth, C.,(ed) Creating Food Futures. Gower, London. (In press). Renting, H., Marsden, T. and Banks, J. 2003. Understanding alternative food networks: exploring the role of short food supply chains in rural development. Environment and Planning A, 35, 393-411. Rigby, D., Young, T. and Burton, M. 2001. The development of and prospects for organic farming in the UK. Food Policy, 26, 599-613. Robison, M. H. 1997. Community input-output models for rural area analysis with an example from central Idaho. The Annals of Regional Science, 31, 325351. Sacks, J. 2002. The money trail: measuring your impact on the local economy using LM3. New Economics Foundation, London. Sandhu, H. S., Wratten, S. D., Cullen, R. and Case, B. 2007. The future of farming: The value of ecosystem services in conventional and organic arable land. An experimental approach. Ecological Economics, In Press, Corrected Proof. Seyfang, G. 2006. Ecological citizenship and sustainable consumption: Examining local organic food networks. Journal of Rural Studies, 22 (4) 383-395. Shepherd, M., Pearce, B., Cormack, B., Philipps, L., Cuttle, S., Bhogal, A., Costigan, P., Unwin, R., 2003. An Assessment of the Environmental Impacts of Organic Farming. Defra, London. Smith, E. and Marsden, T. 2004. Exploring the ‘limits to growth’ in UK organics: beyond the statistical image. Journal of Rural Studies, 20 (3), 345357. Smithers, J., Larmarche, J. and Joseph, A. 2008. Unpacking the terms of engagement with local food at the Farmers’ Market: Insights from Ontario, Journal of Rural Studies, 24 (3), 337-350. Soil Association, 2007. Organics market report 2007. The Soil Association, Bristol. Soil Association, 2006. Organics market report 2006. The Soil Association, Bristol. Soil Association, 2005. New research proves organic milk is higher in vitamins and antioxidants than non-organic milk. Press Release. The Soil Association, Bristol. Sotte, F. 2002. Introduction. In: Arzeni, A., Espostri, R. and Sotte, F. (Eds) European Policy Experiments with Rural development, EAAE, Kiel. 9-16. Thatcher, J. and Sharp, L. 2008. Measuring the local economic impact of National Health Service procurement in the UK: an evaluation of the Cornwall Food Programme and LM3. Local Environment, 13, 3, 253–270. van der Ploeg, J., Renting, H., Brunori, G., Knickel, K., Mannion, J., Marsden, T., de Roest, K., Sevilla-Guzmán, E. and Ventura, F. 2000. Rural development: from practices and policies towards theory. Sociologia Ruralis, 40(4), 391-40. Winter, M. 2003. Embeddedness, the new food economy and defensive localism. Journal of Rural Studies, 19, 23-32. Winter, M. and Rushbrook, L. 2003. Literature review of the English rural economy. Centre for Rural Research, Exeter, pp. 71. Winter, M. and Rushbrook, L. 2003. Literature review of the English rural economy. Research report prepared for Defra. Centre for Rural Research, University of Exeter, Exeter. Wood, R., Lenzen, M., Dey, C. and Lundie, S. 2006 A comparative study of some environmental impacts of conventional and organic farming in Australia. Agricultural Systems, 89, (2-3), 324-348. Table 1: Farm size distribution: farm survey data compared to OF&G and SA data Farm Type OF&G 2004a Farm survey respondents Soil Association b Organic Non-organic All farms Organic Organic Less than 20 ha 21.6 27.4 24.7 19.0 29.1 Between 20 - 49 ha 17.6 14.3 15.8 20.2 22.1 Between 50- 99 ha 23.6 19.0 21.2 23.4 20.8 Between 100 - 199 ha 17.9 17.9 17.9 20.3 13.9 200 ha or Over 19.3 21.4 20.4 17.1 14.1 Total 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% N= 302 353 655 n/a n/a Source: Farm survey; Soil Association 2003; Organic Farmers and Growers 2004 a Analysis of data from the OF&G 2004 survey. b Analysis of data taken from the Soil Association registration list 2003. Table 2: Farm type distribution: farm survey data and DEFRA June sample data compared Farm Type Farm survey respondents DEFRA Organic Non-organic All farms All farms Arable cropping 7.6 19.8 14.2 22.3 Horticulture 9.3 2.8 5.8 3.8 Dairy 10.3 9.6 9.9 7.4 Lowland cattle and sheep 14.6 15.0 14.8 16.9 Pigs and Poultry 4.6 1.1 2.7 4.5 LFA cattle and sheep 12.6 13.6 13.1 12.1 Mixed 34.4 18.4 25.8 5.9 Other farm type 6.6 19.5 13.6 27.1 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 302 353 655 N= Source: Farm Survey, DEFRA June sample 2003 Table 3: Diversification activities: organic and non-organic farmers compared Diversification % of organic % of non-organic % of all farms respondents respondents Agricultural Services* 9.6 18.4 14.4 Accommodation 15.4 15.3 15.3 Recreation/Leisure 7.6 8.8 8.2 Trading Enterprises* 21.2 5.4 12.7 Processing* 15.8 3.5 9.6 Equine Services 7.0 9.9 5.0 Unconventional Crops 6.0 4.2 7.8 Unconventional Livestock 9.9 5.9 9.6 Any diversification* 56.3 46.5 50.8 Multiple diversification* 23.2 15.3 18.9 N= 302 353 655 Source: Farm Survey * The association between organic/non-organic status and this diversification type is significant using Chi Square test. Table 4: Farm business purchases Farm Type % of Purchases by value Non-organic N Local County Regional National Imported Arable 61 31 34 25 9 1 Horticulture 8 24 17 21 21 16 Dairy 27 44 29 19 7 0 Lowland Cattle and Sheep 33 51 23 17 8 1 LFA Cattle and Sheep 34 45 40 13 2 0 Mixed 56 30 42 18 11 0 Pigs and Poultry 3 57 25 5 13 0 All non-organic farms 222 38 34 19 9 1 Organic N Local County Regional National Imported Arable 16 29 35 23 13 1 Horticulture 23 42 17 17 21 3 Dairy 26 41 33 15 11 1 Lowland Cattle and Sheep 34 46 40 8 6 0 LFA Cattle and Sheep 33 42 39 10 5 0 Mixed 86 41 33 14 12 0 Pigs and Poultry 21 43 22 23 12 0 All organic farms 239 41 32 15 11 1 All Farms 461 40 33 17 10 1 Source: Farm Survey Table 5: The spatial distribution of farm business purchases by farm type and organic/non-organic status Farm Type Total Value of Purchases (£,000) Non-organic N Local County Regional National Imported Arable 59 3230 3899 2592 1221 274 Horticulture 7 294 391 471 544 399 Dairy 25 1164 1002 717 367 29 Lowland Cattle and Sheep 33 447 1683 300 288 9 LFA Cattle and Sheep 30 347 799 137 69 0 Mixed 51 2347 3518 2446 846 52 Pigs and Poultry 2 148 26 10 41 0 All Non-organic Farms 207 7975 11317 6673 3377 763 Organic N Local County Regional National Imported Arable 16 486 1440 726 286 30 Horticulture 23 416 587 426 433 80 Dairy 25 1238 1056 579 422 50 Lowland Cattle and Sheep 30 373 221 97 113 6 LFA Cattle and Sheep 31 694 428 173 79 6 Mixed 80 3882 6777 1242 1332 35 Pigs and Poultry 21 168 350 546 416 0 All Organic Farms 226 7257 10859 3788 3080 207 All Farms 433 15232 22176 10462 6457 970 Source: Farm Survey Table 6: Labour use by FTE ha-1 by farm type FTE ha-1 Farm Type Non-organic N Family* Employed** All FTE ha-1* Arable 59 0.011 0.005 0.017 Horticulture 8 0.287 0.446 0.733 Dairy 34 0.035 0.012 0.048 Lowland Cattle and Sheep 45 0.046 0.010 0.056 LFA Cattle and Sheep 39 0.038 0.014 0.052 Mixed 61 0.030 0.014 0.044 Pigs and Poultry 4 0.278 0.016 0.294 All Non-organic Farms 250 0.043 0.025 0.067 Organic* N Family* Employed** All FTE ha-1* Arable 22 0.010 0.010 0.020 Horticulture 25 0.473 0.319 0.792 Dairy 30 0.021 0.010 0.031 Lowland Cattle and Sheep 42 0.031 0.006 0.037 LFA Cattle and Sheep 38 0.025 0.004 0.029 Mixed 99 0.045 0.015 0.060 Pigs and Poultry 14 0.233 0.152 0.385 All Organic Farms 270 0.084 0.046 0.130 All Farms 520 0.064 0.036 0.100 Source: Farm Survey * Means between organic and non-organic farm types are significant (t-test, p <0.001). ** Means between organic and non-organic farm types are significant (t-test, p <0.1). Table 7: The spatial distribution of farm business sales by farm type and organic/non-organic status Farm Type Mean Value of Sales (£’000) Non-organic N Local County Regional National Exported Arable 59 115 81 46 35 3 Horticulture 7 5 24 178 484 2 Dairy 23 51 55 90 17 0 Lowland Cattle and Sheep 33 10 53 19 10 0 LFA Cattle and Sheep 32 7 29 8 0 0 Mixed 46 54 75 62 46 4 Pigs and Poultry 2 66 7 62 0 0 All Non-organic Farms 202 11182 12350 9862 8323 390 Organic N Local County Regional National Exported Arable 16 18 152 83 27 2 Horticulture 25 37 20 64 28 0 Dairy 26 29 33 78 35 0 Lowland Cattle and Sheep 30 6 5 9 5 0 LFA Cattle and Sheep 31 12 16 7 10 0 Mixed 80 45 99 47 28 0 Pigs and Poultry 20 26 17 19 20 0 All Organic Farms 228 29 56 42 22 0 All Farms 430 42 58 45 31 1 Table 8: Farm business sales Farm Type % of Sales (by value) Non-organic N Local County Regional National Imported Arable 61 27 37 24 12 1 Horticulture 8 33 3 15 48 3 Dairy 26 34 26 30 10 0 Lowland Cattle and Sheep 33 38 20 33 9 0 LFA Cattle and Sheep 35 33 42 24 1 0 Mixed 52 24 35 24 15 1 Pigs and Poultry 3 38 5 33 23 0 All non-organic farms 218 30 32 26 12 1 Organic N Local County Regional National Imported Arable 16 16 25 28 28 2 Horticulture 25 67 14 16 2 0 Dairy 27 18 23 39 20 0 Lowland Cattle and Sheep 32 47 27 15 12 0 LFA Cattle and Sheep 32 31 41 12 15 0 Mixed 86 33 32 20 14 0 Pigs and Poultry 20 49 22 17 12 0 All organic farms 238 37 28 20 14 0 All Farms 456 34 30 23 13 0 Figure 1: Purchases by non-organic farm businesses Figure 2: Purchases by organic farm businesses Figure 3: Sales by non-organic farm businesses Figure 4: Sales by organic farm businesses