Interactions between Institutional Rules and Norms in Natural Resource Governance Authors: Arun Agrawal*, Daniel G. Brown*, Gautam Rao*, Rick Riolo†, Derek Robinson* *School of Natural Resources and Environment, University of Michigan, 440 Church Street, Ann Arbor, MI 48109-1041; and †Center for the Study of Complex Systems, University of Michigan, 321A West Hall, 1085 S. University Ave., Ann Arbor, MI 48109-1107 Edited by: Much of the literature on common property has focused on how different kinds of institutions shape the incentives of users who rely on harvesting subsistence related products from a common-pool resource system for their daily need. With the recognition that variations in institutional forms and arrangements matter to resourcerelated outcomes, the explosion of writings on the commons has advanced existing knowledge about how institutions can be designed to improve sustainable resource governance, the relationship of users to each other in relation to resources, and institutional processes themselves. A significant puzzle that has occupied this scholarship is the nature of the differences between formally designed and introduced institutions, and more spontaneously created informal networks, and how such differences have a bearing on resource governance outcomes. This paper focuses directly on this question with the help of an agent-based model built around the interactions of villagers with forests based on the information they derive from their social interactions with their neighbors (an informal network with two-way flows of information) and an externally imposed institution that strictly enforces announced limits on forest product extraction. The paper investigates how changes in the relative dependence of users on information from formal institutions versus informal networks affect user behavior, harvesting levels, and forest-related outcomes. Literature review. Our focus is on the relationship between institutions, information, and resource-user behavior. A number of existing definitions of institutions highlight these interactions.1 These definitions suggest that institutions shape outcomes by structuring the formal rules and informal norms that affect behavior. Faced with the choice of adhering to rules or norms, individuals opt among various combinations of the two by selecting the combination that maximizes their utility given desires for higher incomes, lower risks, and/or sustainable performance. Thus, effective formal institutions achieve desirable outcomes by recognizing the existing preferences and networks, and influencing incentives for a sufficient number of individuals and households, such that desirable aggregate behavior is achieved and/or norms are shifted towards behaviors that yield desirable outcomes. Where resource governance is concerned, formal institutions produce their effects on outcomes through the information signals they provide to their constituents in relation to use, management, and governance of resources (Fig. 1). When reliably communicated, such information, together with knowledge about the nature of rule enforcement, sanctions, and adjudication, shapes user incentives and behavior, affecting resource outcomes. Monitor Inf ormation agent-based modeling | common pool resource | fuelwood extraction | institutional governance | norms Institutions play a particularly important role in influencing local resource use and outcomes for renewable resources such as forests, pastures, irrigation and drinking water, and coastal fisheries. However, the signals and sanctions issued by institutions interact with the social networks that create norms of behavior in communities. This interaction and various combinations of institutional effectiveness, frequency of signaling, network structure, and resource-user’s preferences give rise to an important question for governance theory and the practice of natural resource governance: How are user behaviors and resource-related outcomes affected by rules imposed by formal resource governance institutions in the context of established informal networks that shape user behaviors through norms? We distinguish between rules and norms by focusing on information flow and signaling among actors in a natural resource governance situation. (develop this point further – about one way vs two way, refer to some recent work on informal vs formal…). We distinguish the oneway flow of information about resource conditions and acceptable behaviors issued by formal institutions to households from two-way flows of information about resource-extraction behavior disseminated among households in a social network. We used an agent-based model to investigate how household preferences for resource extraction and complying by rules, together with the structure of the network over which information is conveyed among households, affect resource-user harvesting levels and subsequent forest-related outcomes. Institutions Rules Agents - Interactions - Form Expectations Social Interactions Take Actions Outcomes (Forest Resource) Norms Fig. 1. Conceptual model of the flow of information between institutions, individual agents, and social networks. The flow of information back to institutions occurs through different pathways for formal institutions and informal networks. Formal institutions monitor the state of the resource and results of previous aggregate behaviors and make subsequent judgments and policy decisions based on those outcomes. Usually these decisions are made more infrequently than the resource-use decisions of the constituents influenced by those policies <citation>. These operational differences have been shown to produce lags in the system that create large-scale inefficiencies <citation> and increase the risk of individuals’ collectively exhausting common pool resources (Hardin 1968). In contrast to aggregate level assessments by formal institutions, informal networks 1 “institutions are the formal and informal rules of the game in a society (North 1990);” they are “complexes of norms and behavior that persist over time by serving socially valued purposes (Uphoff and Buck 2006);” and they are “humanly crafted mechanisms that structure, mediate, and attenuate social outcomes (Ostrom 1990).” 1 are generally more localized, interact at a higher frequency, and interact by observation of behaviors and actions carried out by nearby (socially and spatially) constituents <citation>. Recognizing that variations in institutional forms and arrangements matter to resource-related outcomes, literature on common-property resources has advanced existing knowledge about how institutions can be designed to improve sustainable resource governance, the relationship of users to each other in relation to resources, and institutional processes themselves. A significant puzzle that has occupied this scholarship is how the differences between formally designed and introduced institutions and the different structures of informal social interactions influence resource government outcomes. This paper focuses directly on this question using an agent-based model built to represent the interactions of villagers with forests based on the information they derive from rules imposed by a formal institution to limit fuelwood extraction and norms that are derived through social interaction with their neighbors. Methods Forest Use and Management in Himachal Pradesh, India. Over the last century, forests in Himachal Pradesh, India, have been distributed to the landless, have been the sites of extensive road construction and infrastructure development, and have served as important commercial resources by providing resin for turpentine (Pinus roxburghii), raw materials for paper and pulp – including bamboo (Bambusa bambos) and bhabhar grass (Euloliopsis binata) – and wood packing cases for Himachal Pradesh's important fruit industry. In 2001, over 90 percent of the state’s 6 million inhabitants lived in 16,000 rural villages (DOP 1997), most of which have relied on forest resources to provide fuelwood for cooking and heating. The overwhelming demand for forest resources is further exacerbated by the low-energy density of fuelwood and the inefficient cooking devices with which it is used (Prasad and Verhaart, 1982). While the legally defined forests cover 66.5% of the 55,673 km2 area of Himachal Pradesh, only 8976 km2 or 24% of the lands legally defined as forest have crown density above 40% (FDHP 2001). In this context of high population density and competing uses, a number of different institutional mechanisms are in evidence to secure the formal participation of local residents in forest management in Himachal Pradesh. In the context of this trade-off that households face between abiding by formal institutional rules related to forest management and forest sustainability versus meeting subsistence requirements and adhering to norms emerging from social interactions, we used an agentbased model to study the effectiveness of formal institutional rules under varying conditions of household preferences and network interactions. Agent-based modeling. Agent-based modeling (ABM) is an approach to representing the properties, behaviors, decision-making strategies, and actions of interacting components in a dynamic system that is composed of actors and their environment. ABMs can be run to evaluate the aggregate system-level implications of individual behaviors, and the diversity and interactions thereof. Because ABMs derive systemlevel outcomes from component interactions, the approach can represent and model non-linear dynamics, positive and negative feedbacks, heterogeneity, learning and evolutionary decision-making strategies (i.e. adaptation), and a range of other analytically intractable processes (Holland 1995, PNAS-99 2002). Furthermore, the ABM approach can be used as a framework to integrate various sources of data, theories, and conceptual models (Janssen and Ostrom 2006; Robinson et al. 2007) and has replicated experimental commons dilemma results (Deadman et al. 2000). Model Description. We developed an ABM to test the implications of assumptions about how different combinations of rules from formal institutions and norms derived from social interactions affect the sustainability of a forest resource near a small village. The model represents a hypothetical place, but uses several parameter values derived from data and literature on Himachal Pradesh in India. Our model is composed of three types of agents that represent the two key actors (i.e. households and formal institutions) and the resource being utilized. We model agent behaviors and interactions over time using discrete montly time steps. At each step, household agents are confronted with a decision problem – how much resource to extract. The resource being extracted is fuelwood, which is obtained from local forests and constitutes the primary energy used for cooking in India (ABE 1985, Misra et al. 1988, Bhatt and Sachan 2004). Household agent decision making is represented using an approach framed as bounded rationality (Simon <citation>). A utility function is used to represent agents’ preferences over "consumption" bundles. A household’s utility is a function of its desire for three goods (consumption, leisure, and adherence to rules and norms) over a bounded set of resource extraction levels. The extraction level that maximizes a household’s utility is the level of resource depletion carried out by the household. To determine the optimum extraction level for each time step, household agents randomly select 10 different discrete levels2 of resource extraction from a continuous range, and chose the selected level that maximizes the following utility function: c l nr u C L ( n r) 1 where u is the utility for a household, C is the level of consumption, L is the amount of leisure, n is a function of the average extraction level of neighbors in the previous step and an associated preference weight for abiding by norms, r is a function of the extraction rule signaled by the formal institution and an associated preference weight (see appendix), and αc, αl, and αnr are the weights applied to consumption, leisure and institutional adherence3, respectively. The utility a household derives from consumption is a decreasingreturn function of subsistence requirements, resource extraction levels, and the weight households place on consumption versus leisure and institutional adherence. Because markets for fuelwood are essentially non-existent in the locations we studied (Heltberg et al. 2002), agents face a trade-off between time spent extracting fuelwood and time spent in leisure. However, extraction time increases exponentially as the resource is depleted (Kumar and Hotchkiss 1988, Baland et al. 2004). The rate of increase in extraction time is a function of the initial and remaining size of the forest, proportion of forest branches, village population, average biomass per m2, and average head-load carried by an adult. The formal-institution agent represents a branch of the Indian government that manages the forest resources and aims to maintain both the ecological quality of the forest and its ability to function as a common pool resource for fuelwood harvest. The formal-institution agent determines the sustainable per capita harvest for a given timeperiod by dividing the net growth of the forest by the population size and weighting it for each household based on its size and estimated fuelwood requirements. It then informs each household of its allowable (sustainable) extraction level. 2 A second extraction level selection method was used and is described in the Appendix. Results were qualitatively similar and therefore not reported. 3 Institutional adherence refers to the degree to which household behavior matches the signals about expected extraction levels coming from both the institutional rules and the social norms. 2 Forest Resource. The forest resource is represented by an agent as a closed-canopy maturing mixed pine and oak forest. We introduce some variability around the mean growth rate of 2.7% per year (0.01% per month) to incorporate stochastic climatic conditions. The villagers use forest fodder and lop off branches for fuelwood. Observations of aboveground biomass and carbon allocated to individual tree components (e.g. stem, bark, branches, and foliage) vary widely. Jenkins et al. (2003) demonstrated that a range of 7-30% of biomass for softwood species and 15-95% for hardwood species is allocated to branches, which is the biomass of use to villagers for fuelwood. For our model, we divided the above-ground biomass and carbon values in half to estimate the amount found in branches. The fraction of the initial forest resource remaining after some period of resource extraction was the primary outcome of interest in our analyses. We used this value as an indicator of the sustainability of various household preferences and network structures, and of the influences of rules and norms on sustainability. Agent Interaction. At the beginning of a model run, an agent forms an interaction network with its eight neighbors. Based on a probability parameter p, the agent may swap each member in its current network with one randomly selected from within the community at large. The agent computes the average extraction level of the other agents in its network from the previous time step. The dissemination of information among household agents provides an indication to each agent of how much resource other agents are using, information that is then factored into their own decision making (n in equation 1). When p is 0 the interaction network of an agent is its eight adjacent neighbors, and when p is 1 the agent has a social network based on eight neighbors drawn randomly from the community. Increasing levels of p mean that more of the interaction network is drawn at random, as opposed to being selected from the spatial neighborhood of the agent. When p is low, neighbors who are adjacent share information in both directions; increasing p results in agents who are not adjacent sharing information only in one direction. Household agents also interact with the formal-institutional agent. This interaction is unidirectional in that the institutional agent sends each household a signal indicating the prescribed level of resource extraction that is deemed sustainable (r in equation 1). When r is nonzero, the household agent derives increasing utility from matching the sustainable harvest level. The household agent experiences a direct trade-off between matching formal rules and informal norms defining expected resource extraction levels Computational Experiments We conducted four sets of computational experiments. Each experiment was conducted by comparing among model runs with alternative parameter settings. The experiments were defined to explore how (a) the relative weights on rules and norms, (b) various levels of preference for consumption, (c) network structure and (d) the proportion of the population with a high level of attention to rules all affected resource outcomes. The model was run thirty times for each combination of parameter values, and the average and variance of resource remaining were computed. This metric best captures our concern with the sustainability of resource extraction.4 Each model run was composed of 625 household agents and was run for 600 time steps (i.e. 50 years). Initialization of a model run involved creating and placing household agents on a grid (25 x 25), with one household agent per cell. Households varied in size, with an average size of 4.75 based on rural household survey data (Misra et al. 1988). After all households were created, they established a social network that remained stable for the entire model run. In each time step (i.e. month), the resource grows and the formal institution calculates the sustainable extraction for the following year. Households asynchronously, and in a different order each time step, choose how much resource to extract. Experiment 1: Weight on rules versus norms. In this experiment we tested the effects of altering the weight agents place on adherence to rules over norms. We performed this experiment to test whether the amount of forest remaining would increase as the population placed greater emphasis on adhering to rules set by the formal institution. Increasing the importance of rules in our model can be interpreted as an increasingly good reputation of the formal institution among the population of agents, or increasingly strict enforcement or sanction that make rule non-compliance more costly to the agents. We set up a series of cases where the weight the on rules (wr) of all agents was varied from 0.0 (no attention to rules, complete attention to norms) to 1.0 (complete attention to rules, no attention to norms). For this experiment, agents were each given preference weights of c=l=nr=0.33 (Equation 1) and social networks composed of their eight immediate neighbors (p=0). Experiment 2: Varying preferences for consumption. In the second experiment, we evaluated how important the weight on consumption was compared to the institutional rules and social norms on the resource outcome. A second group of ‘high consumer’ agents was added to the group included in the Experiment 1, where their weight on consumption was twice that placed on leisure and institutional adherence (c=0.5;l=nr=0.25). We varied the proportion of the population composed of high consumers from 25% to 100%, and included the variations on wr used in the Experiment 1. The landscape was divided into two sections with one population on each side of a single shared boundary. Experiment 3: Network Structure. In the Experiments 1 and 2, interaction among agents was constrained to the immediate neighbors of each household. For this experiment, we added network connections that extended beyond immediate neighbors. The objective was to examine how different social network structures affected the dissemination of information and the formation of norms that, along with institutional rules, influence aggregate fuelwood extraction behavior. We implemented this experiment by varying the parameter (p). Experiment 4: Heterogeneity in weight on rules. In Experiments 1 and 2 all households within a model run were given the same value for the wr. To evaluate the degree to which a small number of agents with a high wr might be able to influence norms sufficiently to yield desirable resource outcomes, we created two groups with different levels of wr. ‘Rule adherents’ weight rules much higher than norms (wr=0.9), while ‘Norm adherents’ have the opposite weights (wr=0.1). In this experiment, we varied the relative proportion of rule adherents (0 to 1) and the network structure parameter (p, from 0 to 1). Like Experiment 1, household agents’ preference weights were c=l=nb=0.33. 4 Other metrics such as the distribution of agent consumption levels, and XXXX were also examined, and were found to correlate strongly with the amount of forest remaining at the end of the simulation. 3 Experiment 1: Weight on rules versus norms. Altering the level of rule adherence (wr) among agents in the different model runs resulted in a non-linear response on the amount of forest remaining (0% line in Fig. 2). At very low values of wr much of the forest was consumed. However, at low to medium levels (i.e. 0.2 to 0.4) households dramatically altered their extraction behavior, which led to much higher levels of forest resources remaining. Experiment 2: Varying preferences for consumption. When we recreated Experiment 1 but with a population of agents that had a greater preference for consumption, we found that, not only did it take a much higher weight on rule adherence over norms (wr) to achieve nearly the same level of remaining forest, but the effect was damped both in the rate at which it altered agent behavior and the amount of forest remaining (100% line in Fig. 2). Including a mix of agents from the two subpopulations (i.e. agents with high versus moderate preference for consumption) produced moderate responses of forest remaining to varying levels of wr (Fig. 2). For all proportions of agents preferring higher levels of consumption, low values of wr resulted in the lowest levels of forest remaining. Increasing the proportion decreased the amount of forest remaining and altered the non-linear response to wr. As the proportion of agents with higher weight on consumption increased, agents needed to place increasing weight on rules (higher wr) before improvements in forest resources were realized. % Consumerists Fig. 2. Results from Experiments 1 and 2 show the effect on forest remaining of changing the weight placed on rules and the relative number of acquisitive agents. Error bars represent 95% C.I. Experiment 3: Network Structure. By altering the way information on agents’ behaviors is propagated through social networks, we measured how changes in network structure affected the interaction between weight on rules (wr) and the number of agents with higher preference for consumption (Fig. 3). In particular, for wr values of 0.2 to 0.4, increasing p non-linearly reduced the amount of forest remaining with respect to the proportion of agents with a high preference for consumption. Strong declines in forest remaining when 25% of agent populations had high preference for consumption suggests that as social mixing increases, a smaller number of agents preferring consumption are required to create a high-consumption norm. Additionally, when values of wr were less than or equal to 0.1 or greater than or equal to 0.5, the network structure had little effect on forest remaining. In these cases the strong influence of wr overwhelmed the effects of preference heterogeneity. There is no further effect of increasing p to produce a completely mixed network (p=1.0), which means that a small number of long-range interactions in the network can have a large effect on propagation of information – consistent with findings network theory (<citation>). 200% 200% a. WR1=WR2=0.2 150% b. WR1=WR2=0.3 150% p = 0.0 p = 0.5 p = 1.0 100% % Forest Remaining Results 100% 50% 50% 0% 0% 0% 25% 50% 75% 0% 100% 200% 25% 50% 75% 100% 200% d. WR1=WR2=0.5 c. WR1=WR2=0.4 150% 150% 100% 100% 50% 50% 0% 0% 0% 25% 50% 75% 100% 0% 25% 50% 75% 100% % Consumerists Fig. 3. Results from Experiment 3 illustrate the Effect on forest remaining of network structure (p), weight placed on rules (wR1=wR2) and the relative number of consumerists. Error bars represent 95% confidence intervals. (a) wR1 = wR2 = 0.2 (b) wR1 = wR2 = 0.3 (c) wR1 = wR2 = 0.4 (d) wR1 = wR2 = 0.5. Experiment 4: Heterogeneity in weight on rules. When we increased the proportion of rule adherents in the population the model produced a near-linear increase in forest remaining outcomes. As we altered the network parameter p from a highly clustered network (p = 0) to a perfectly mixed network (p = 1), the amount of forest remaining increased, for all proportions of rule adherents less than one. At moderate levels of social mixing (p = 0.25), strong non-linearity in relative outcomes of forest remaining were evident (Fig. 4). In particular, small numbers of rule adherents made large differences when household networks had a small number of distant non-adjacent connections. The effect of additional rule adherents tapered off strikingly beyond 20%. These results were achieved despite rule adherents not having a special place in the network (such as a higher degree of connections). This is consistent with the explanation for the effect of social mixing advanced above. Fig. 4. Results from Experiment 4 illustrate the effect on forest remaining of relative number of rule adherents and network structure. Error bars represent 95% C.I. 4 Discussion Formal resource-management institutions have a number mechanisms at their disposal by which they can affect the outcomes of collective resource use and encourage more sustainable levels of use. These include communication of rules and their rationales and the nature of rule enforcement, sanctions, and adjudication. Because these activities are carried out in the context of systems of social interaction through information networks that generate norms for behavior, understanding the effects on resource outcomes of the choices a formal institution makes can be challenging. Although we can make no claims on quantitative magnitude of these effects in specific cases, our model reveals, qualitatively, the effects that social interactions and norm formation can have on the effectiveness of an institution’s activities. The results of our Experiment 1 suggest that, when households in a community have a homogenous level of preference for adhering to the rules pronounced by a formal institution the goal of which is to maintain sustainable harvesting levels, the level of resource use decreases and remaining resource amount increases, non-linearly with increases in that preference. This non-linearity is governed by the process of norm formation in the community, which we modeled through households seeking to match the level of extraction of their neighbor. Low levels of preference for adhering to rules in our model might be interpreted as representing low levels of (a) trust in the institution, (b) communication from the institution, (c) enforcement of rules, or (d) sanctions for violating rules. In such cases, decision making of households is more strongly influenced by the behavior of their neighbors and by the utility households derive by balancing consumption and leisure. Small increases in preference for rule adherence achieve little to decrease consumption, until a tipping point in that preference is reached, such that the norms of the community are influenced by the rules issued by the institution. Resource-management institutions governing commonpool resources, therefore, should seek levels of investment in communication, enforcement, sanctions, and/or adjudication that are sufficient to influence the norms of a community and tip the behavior toward those desired by the institution. Good news is that once there is sufficient interest in rule adherence to affect the process of norm formation, little additional effort may be required to achieve a level of resource use that is consistent with the goals of the institution. Our initial experiment was predicated on two key assumptions. The first was a homogeneous population, in terms of the importance households place on various contributors to their utility (i.e., consumption, leisure, and adherence to rules and norms) and the relative importance of adherence to norms versus rules. The second assumption was that there were no long-range ties within the social network. In Experiment 2, we relaxed the first assumption to form two groups, one group with balanced preferences for consumption, leisure, and adherence to rules and norms and a second with greater preference for consumption, and found that as the number of agents preferring consumption increased, the effectiveness of institutional rules decreased essentially linearly. This decreased effectiveness was evidenced by a decline in the amount of resources remaining, regardless of the level of interest in following rules versus norms. Additionally, the level of interest in following rules (wr) required to achieve a tipping point, where norms shifted towards more sustainable behavior, was higher (Fig. 2). Some understanding of the diversity and types of preferences in a community is, therefore, necessary for institutions to identify a level effort that is likely to be successful. The results of Experiment 3, which evaluated the importance of longrange ties in the social network that structures the formation of social norms, indicate that, at moderate levels of rule adherence (0.2<wr<0.5), the presence of long-range ties results in a non-linear relationship between the number of households preferring consumption and forest condition. At these moderate levels of weight on rules, a reasonably small number of households with greater preference for consumption and produce a relatively large decline in the forest outcome, as these preferences have a greater influence on norms throughout the community because the social network has greater connectedness. This effect of network structure enhances the sensitivity of the response of resource outcomes to rule adherence at just the levels of rule adherence of most interest to the institution, i.e., in the range of effort levels near the tipping point from little influence on outcome to greater influence. The results of Experiment 3 indicate that a small group of households with a preference for consumption can reduce the effectiveness of efforts by an institution to reduce resource consumption, through the influence on norms. It might also be possible that a small group of households with a strong interest in adhering to the rules of the institution, over norms, can have a strong positive influence on the community to adhere to the rules. The results of Experiment 4 indicate that (a) as the number of such rule adherents increases, the amount of resource remaining also increases and (b) as that social network includes more long-range ties, a smaller number of rule adherents is needed to achieve a high-level of resource remaining. Although a formal institution may have little influence on the structure of the social network itself, these results suggest that resource-management institutions can might be able to use the process of norm formation to enhance the effectiveness of their rules by enhancing the commitment of a fraction of the community to adhering to rules. Such commitments might be secured through greater participation in the institution within the community. Conclusions References Adhikari, B., S. D. Falco, and J.C. Lovett (2004). "Household characteristics and forest dependency: evidence from common property forest management in Nepal." Ecological Economics 48(2): 245-257. Advisory Board on Energy (ABE) (1985). Government of India: Towards a Perspective on Energy Demand and Supply in India in 2004/2005. Government of India Press, Nasik. Baland, J. M., P. Bardhan, S. Das, D. Mookherjee, and R. Sarkar (2004). "The Environmental Impact of Poverty: Evidence from Firewood Collection in Rural Nepal,’." Commons in an Age of Global Transition: Challenges, Risks, and Opportunities. The Tenth Conference of the International Association for the Study of Common Property, August: 913. Bembridge, T. J. and J. E. Tarlton (1990). "Woodfuel in Ciskei: A Headload Study." South African Forestry Journal 154: 88-93. Bhatt, B. P. and M. S. Sachan (2004). "Firewood consumption along an altitudinal gradient in mountain villages of India." Biomass and Bioenergy 27: 69-75. Birdsey, R. A. (1992). Carbon storage and accumulation in United States forest ecosystems. Radnor, PA, Program manager, Global Change Research, Northeastern Forest Experiment Station. 5 Collier, N. (2000). Repast: An extensible framework for agent simulation. Swarmfest 2000, Logan, Utah. Deadman, P. J., E. Schlager, and R. Gimblett (2000). "Simulating Common Pool Resource Management Experiments with Adaptive Agents Employing Alternate Communication Routines." Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation 3(2). Heltberg, R., T. C. Arndt, and N.U. Sekhar. (2000). "Fuelwood Consumption and Forest Degradation: A Household Model for Domestic Energy Substitution in Rural India." Land Economics 76(2): 213-232. Holland, J. H. (1995). Hidden order : how adaptation builds complexity. Reading, Mass., Addison-Wesley. Irfanullah, S. (2002). "Gujars in the Pakistani Hindu Kush-Himalayas: Conflicts and Dilemmas about Lifestyles and Forest Use." Nomadic Peoples 6(2): 99-110. Janssen, M. A. and E. Ostrom (2006). "Empirically Based, Agent-based models." Ecology and Society 11(2): 37. Jenkins, J. C., D. C. Chojnacky, et al. (2003). "National-Scale Biomass Estimators for United States Tree Species." Forest Science 49(1): 12-35. Kumar, S. K. and D. Hotchkiss (1988). Consequences of Deforestation for Women's Time Allocation, Agricultural Production, and Nutrition in Hill Areas of Nepal, Int Food Policy Res Inst. Misra, N. M., A. K. Mahendra, and M.Y. Ansari (1988). "Pilot survey of fuel consumption in rural areas - V." Indian Forester 114(2): 57-62. Mosler, H. J. and W. M. Brucks (2003). "Integrating commons dilemma findings in a general dynamic model of cooperative behavior in resource crises." European Journal of Social Psychology 33(1): 119-133. North (1990) Ostrom (1990) PNAS-99 (2002). Special Issue on ABM, Joe Sackler Colloqium, Irvine CA. Robinson, D. T., D. G. Brown, et al. (2007). "Comparison of empirical methods for building agent-based models in land use science." Journal of Land Use Science 2(1): 31-55. Uphoff and Buck, (2006) 6 Supporting documentation Fuelwood collection. Fuelwood and community forests are perceived as a free common pool resource for use by local households. Therefore, markets for fuelwood are non-existent in the study region and instead the cost of fuelwood is a function of collection or gathering time, which is typical for fuelwood and minor forest products in rural areas in India (Heltberg, Arndt et al. 2000). However, as households extract fuelwood resources they degrade the forest from the edge inward and are forced to spend more effort and time in subsequent fuelwood collections (Kumar and Hotchkiss 1988; Baland, Bardhan et al. 2004). We use a simplified approach to model time spent collecting fuelwood and assume that when fuelwood is abundant, a minimum of 2 hrs is required to make a single fuelwood gathering trip. However, gathering time increases exponentially as the resource is depleted (Fig. S1). The rate of increase in gathering time is a function of the initial and remaining size of the forest, proportion of the forest in branches, the population of the village, and average biomass per square meter. The average head-load carried by an adult individual in a single trip approximates 30 kg (Bembridge and Tarlton 1990, Irfanullah 2002, Adhikari et al. 2004). Since households must make several trips to satisfy their subsistence cooking requirements, we calculate the overall time allocated to fuelwood collection per month using the following equation: Gm Min xcmax d have g l where Gm is the gathering time per month, x is the extraction level of the household, cmax is the maximum consumption level of the household, have is the average head load per trip, d is the average density of oak and pine (600 kg·m-3), g is the gathering time for a single trip, and l is the total labor endowment that each household has. Fig. S1: Time spent for a single trip gathering fuelwood based on the available resource level. Average head-load carried by an adult - (i.e. 30 kg, Bembridge and Tarlton 1990, Irfanullah 2002, Adhikari et al. 2004) Fuelwood demands are particularly high in India due to the low energy density of fuelwood and the inefficient cooking devices with which it is used (Prasad and Verhaart, 1982). Fuelwood energy requirements for cooking range from 6-32 MJ per capita per day (Ravindranath and Ramakrishna 1997, Nayak et al. 1993). While the specific density, moisture, and calorific value of forest species vary, a general conversion factor (1 kg = 19.89 MJ – ABE 1985) can be used to calculate the corresponding range of per capita fuelwood requirements, 0.3-1.61 kg (6-32 MJ). The National Council of Applied Economic Research and the state calculated consumption values of 1.31 and 1.97 kg/capita/day, respectively (Pandey 2002). Similar measurements have been found at other areas of India (Nayak et al. 1993, Bhatt et al., Reddy 1981, Bhatt and Sachan 2004). Household Utility. In our model, household utility is a function of its desire for three goods (consumption, leisure, and adherence to institutional pressures) and a bounded set of resource extraction levels. The extraction level that maximizes a household’s utility is the level of resource depletion carried out by the household. To determine the 7 optimum extraction level for each time step, household agents randomly select 10 different levels of resource extraction and chose the level that maximizes the following utility function: ui C c l L ( n b) nb where ui is the utility for household i, c is the level of consumption, l is the amount of leisure, n is the influence of informal institutions, b is the influence of formal institutions on sustainability of the resource, and αc, αl, and αnb are the weights applied to consumption, leisure and institutional influence, respectively. The three overarching preference weights sum to one and ensure diminishing returns on consumption, leisure, and matching formal (i.e. sustainable) and informal (i.e. social norms) extraction level beliefs. The consumption component of a household’s utility is a decreasing function of their subsistence cooking requirements, a stochastic set of possible extraction levels, and the weight the household places on consumption versus leisure and institutional influence. Fig. S2: Consumption curves for different consumption preference weights (i.e. alpha values) and extraction levels. The subsistence cooking requirements for each household are calculated as a function of household size and per capita energy requirements: h e S i i c d where Si is the subsistence wood requirement (m3) for household i, hi is the size of household i, e is the per capita energy requirement for cooking per month (240 MJ), c is the energy content of wood (16 MJ, World Bank 2004), and d is the average density of oak and pine (600 kg·m-3). Since markets for fuelwood are largely non-existent in the locations we studied, the chief expense incurred by agents in fuelwood extraction is time - invariably, the cost of the leisure time that agents forsake to extract the resource. The leisure component is calculated based on the gathering time for fuelwood collection, the available amount of time devoted to labor, and the weight the household places on leisure versus consumption and institutional influence. The function takes the following form: L 1 Gm l 8 where L is the result of the leisure component ranged 0-1. A value of 0 for leisure means that the household spends no time in leisure, a value of 1 means the household spends all of its time in leisure. Gm is the time spent gathering fuelwood per month and l is the total labor endowment, which we set to 5 hrs per day per household. The last factor in the household agent’s utility function represents the type and level of adherence to institutional influence. Each household faces a trade-off regarding whether to match its extraction level to the network of households with which it shares information (i.e. social norms) or to match institution rules that define a sustainable level of extraction. We represent the outcome of matching social norms using the following equation: N nf 2 ( 1 x nnet ) where N is the value placed on social norms, nf is a ratio defining the households adherence to social norms versus institutional rules, x is the extraction level, and nnet is the mean extraction level of the eight household social network that the household gathers information from. Similarly, the outcome of matching institutional rules is calculated as follows: ( 1 nf ) [ 1 ( x sus)] 2 F where F is the value placed on institutional rules and sus is the sustainable extraction level recommended to the household by the institution. Both the social norm and institutional rule values are added together and weighted by the household’s preference for abiding by institutional influences versus its preference for consumption and leisure. (i.e. the preference weights placed on sustainability and social norms sum to one, following Mosler and Brucks 2003). ABM We created the ABM using the RePast simulation libraries (Collier 2000). Increasing levels of p mean that more of the interaction network is drawn at random, as opposed to being selected from the spatial neighborhood of the agent. The parameter is operationalized by having an agent draw a random number between 0-1 for each of the eight neighbors, and if that random number is smaller than p then the connection to that neighbor is swapped with a randomly selected household in the landscape. Forest The forest grows on average at a rate of 2.7% per year (0.14 kg · m-2· yr-1, Birdsey 1992). 9