Informal Institutions, State Reform, and Political Parties in East Central Europe Anna Grzymala-Busse Yale University Anna.busse@yale.edu Dept of Political Science 124 Prospect Street New Haven CT 06520 April 18, 2003 PRELIMINARY DRAFT: Please do not cite. 1 Why have the post-communist states diverged in their performance, despite similarities in formal reforms? While most work on post-communist reforms (political and economic) has tended to focus on formal institutions, an important source of variation in political performance has been ignored: informal institutions. As this paper argues, these informal rules interact with formal institutions and reforms in distinct and important ways. Whether they undermine or reinforce formal rules is a function of the competition among the political actors, and specifically, political parties in parliamentary systems. Introduction The formal institutions of post-communist democracy appear to have converged: all the post-communist states have functioning parliaments, electoral systems, and policymaking rules. Across the region, democratically-elected political parties have led the creation of new political institutions, holding in check the powers of presidents, the military, and other government actors. Parliamentary, proportional representation systems dominate, with mediadriven campaigns, secret and free ballots, and increasingly stable governing coalitions. After introducing and creating many of the institutions of the market and of democracy, these parties have recently focused public attention on the question of state reform, not least because the European Union has reviewed progress in these areas annually for each candidate country, highlighting administrative and democratic shortcomings. These reviews became a powerful spur to further reform, and so public administration reform, regional decentralization, and anti-corruption initiatives have all been introduced across the region (See Table 1.) As a result, the “parchment institutions” of the democratic state have been converging. Yet formal convergence belies differences on the ground: the state has expanded in size, but 2 not in capacity to provide public goods. Rates of employment in public administration have grown, but government effectiveness and the ability to control corruption have not increased1 (See Tables 2 and 3). By this metric, the Czech and Slovak Republics are among the surprising culprits, while Poland joins the more obvious success stories of Hungary and Slovenia. In both the Czech and Slovak republics, reform has been haphazardly implemented, with delays and scandals contributing to repeated accusations of deliberate sabotage of state effectiveness and transparency.2 What would account for the variation in state performance despite similar formal reforms? This paper argues that post-communist informal institutions—specifically, the ways in which they promote the discretionary and rent-seeking activities of political parties—explain this variation. Analyses of informal institutions initially argued that they either formalize as a function of the power of their beneficiaries, or eventually disappear.3 Informal institutions could thus be viewed as frequently transitory, marginal, and relatively easily expunged. Scholars of informal economic institutions, however, countered that informal institutions and practices not only persist, but coexist with formal institutions.4 Analyses of post-communist property 1 These Transparency International corruption rankings must be taken with a grain of salt, since they are provided by representatives of international companies who may themselves rely on these rankings in formulating their opinions. In their defense, the rankings are collated from several sources, and correlate strongly with other estimates of corruption. 2 See the scandals that broke out in the Czech press in 1996-8, and in Slovakia in 1998-9. 3 Knight, Jack. Institutitions and Social Conflict, Cambridge: CUP, 1992. de Soto, Hernando 1990 argues that such institutions disappear once formal overregulation is eliminated. 4 Portes, Alejandro, and Sassen-Koob, Saskia. “Making It Underground: Comparative Material on the Informal Sector in Western Market Economies,” American Journal of Sociology, 93 No. 1 (July 1987): 30-61. Portes, Alejandro, and Schauffler, Richard. “Competing Perspectives on the Latin American Informal Sector,” Population and Development Review vol 19, no 1, March 1993: 33-60. 3 relations thus emphasized informal elite networks and “recombinant” property as important aspects of economic reform and privatization.5 Nonetheless, the analogous role of informal political institutions has not been examined as thoroughly.6 Insofar as they have examined informal institutions in politics, scholars have emphasized their negative impact, and their corrosive effect on democracy. 7 The analysis presented here attempts both to examine the different types of informal institutions prevalent in politics, and to trace the variety of ways in which informal factors persist and influence the transformation of the post-communist state in the region. The paper proceeds as follows: Section 1 discusses informal institutions, and four distinct types of interaction with formal rules. Political competition determines the extent to which formal institutions can be undermined by informal rules. Section 2 demonstrates how these interactions occurred in four cases: Poland, Hungary, the Czech Republic, and Slovakia, and examines their impact on the state. Section 3 examines other potential explanations for the observed variation, which focus on broad regime legacies and the exigencies of nationbuilding. 1. The Role of Informal Institutions Informal institutions are consciously followed rules of political behavior. Much as formal institutions, they are rules that are widely recognized and taught as such. They are reflexive: actors need to know what they are. However, unlike formal institutions, they are not sanctioned or codified via legal recognition, legal enforcement, or official access to power/ 5 Bruszt and Stark 1997, Borocz, Borocz and Rona-Tas. Notable exceptions include Ganev 2001, Cirtautas 1997, Lewis and Gortat 1995. 7 See, for example, O’Donnell, Guillermo. “Another Institutionalization: Latin America and Elsewhere.” Kellogg Institute Working Paper Series, University of Notre Dame, # 222, March 1996. 6 4 policymaking.8 Examples include personal loyalties and networks, reputations, or discretionary distribution of resources. This definition has three implications. First, informal institutions are more than behavioral regularities, traditions, or unintentional byproducts 9 of formal institutions.10 Second, while they lack a formal enforcement mechanism, such as the state, they can be nonetheless enforced by informal means such as sanctions, ostracism, shunning, etc.11 Third, like formal institutions, informal institutions can be either weakly or strongly influential, and effectively or ineffectively enforced. Their informality does not presuppose either their extent or their impact. If formal institutions are viewed as coordination equilibria, norms, or rules,12 informal institutions are used in similar ways: as a source of information, to cut down on transaction costs, to redistribute resources, etc. Critically, however, informal institutions do not function independently of formal institutions. In the modern polity, most areas of political life are subject to formal rules of some sort, codified and enforced by the power of the state, even if these formal rules are not necessarily dense or effectively enforced. The nature of their linkage can vary, as we will see, but informal rules will either affect the functioning of formal institutions, or formal institutions will constrain the impact of informal ones. Thus, informal institutions can be very efficacious, but in most situations, theirs is an “impact without 8 This is not to say that the state and other formal actors cannot use informal institutions. Knight, Jack. Institutions and Social Conflict. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992, p. 172. This definition thus also runs counter to the arguments of József Böröcz, who argues that informality consists of avoiding or circumventing formal institutions. József Böröcz, “Informality Rules,”East European Politics and Societies, Vol 14, No 2, 2000: 348-380. 10 See also Helmke, Gretchen, and Levitsky, Steven. “Informal Institutions and Comparative Politics: A Research Agenda,” Manuscript, Harvard University, January 2003, and Lauth, Hans-Joachim. “Special Relationships: the different impact of informal institutions on different democratic institutions,” Paper presented at the Conferenc eon Informal Institutions and Politics in the Developing World, WCFIA, Harvard University, 56 April 2002. 11 Jack Knight 1992 and 2002 argues that the distinction between formal and informal institutions lies in the lack of third party enforcement of the latter. 12 Crawford, Sue E.S, and Ostrom, Elinor. “A Grammar of Institutions,” American Political Science Review, vol 89, # 3, September 1995: 582-600. 9 5 independence” from formal rules. This is not to argue that informal institutions are merely a “residual category” that explains politics only at the margins, or to ascribe greater explanatory power to either set of institutions. Nor should we assume a “parasitic”13 relationship, where informal institutions necessarily feed off, undermine, and weaken formal institutions.14 However, the interactions between informal and formal are critical for understanding how informal institutions can determine political outcomes despite the claims to superior authority and legitimate monopoly over both violence and resource extraction of formal institutions. There are several ways for informal and formal institutions to interact and coexist. Some informal institutions are formalized as a function of the distribution of power among those whom they would benefit (Knight 1990). Incumbents can formalize those unspoken “rules of the game” that favor them. Thus, many political parties, especially in nascent democracies, have changed the laws that govern political competition, constraining potential competition by increasing electoral thresholds and changing the mechanisms that translate votes into seats. They also passed the laws on their own financing, which allowed governing parties to strengthen their hand at the cost of the extra-parliamentary opposition, and obviated the need for financing by membership dues or local fundraising.15 Alternatively, informal rules substitute for weak formal institutions. Analyses of political economy, the state, and ethnic identity have shown that informal institutions persist and have a direct impact when formal institutions are either sparse or unconsolidated.16 Thus, informal institutions can formalize Lauth, Hans-Joachim. “’Special Relationships: The different impact of informal institutions on various democratic institutions,” Paper presented at the Conference on Informal Institutions and Politics in the Developing World, WCFIA, Harvard University, April 5-6, 2002. 14 József Böröcz, “Informality Rules,”East European Politics and Societies, Vol 14, No 2, 2000: 348-380 15 Mair 1995 demonstrated that parties in Western Europe have turned to the state as a survival strategy, and given its dominance by the parties, the state readily obliges with increased funding, staffing, etc. 16 Bates, Robert. States and Markets in Tropical Africa. Herbst, Jeffrey. States and Power in Africa: Comparative Lessons in Authority and Control. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2000. Laitin, David. Culture and Hegemony. 13 6 into legally codified structures or substitute for them. In both accounts, of formalization and of substitution, the relationship between formal and informal institutions is zero-sum: one functions in the absence or weakness of the other. However, there are other potential interactions between formal and informal institutions, which do not presuppose a zero-sum relationship or the necessary subsuming of one by the other. First, political actors can use informal institutions to exploit formal institutions, by mining legal loopholes and capitalizing on poor specifications of formal institutions. Where gaps in formal laws exist, informal rules guide decisionmaking in lieu of missing formal directives. Certain forms of clientelism and patronage that are not technically illegal, discretionary awarding of jobs and contracts, or discretionary implementing of policy fall into this category. For example, where no regulations provide the criteria for hiring new employees, personal loyalties or bias may determine hiring decisions. Similarly, using tax loopholes, lax incorporation requirements, subcontracting and subletting, earning an income in contexts unregulated by the state,17 are all forms of informal institutions that exploit the gaps in formal regulations.18 Second, informal institutions can also be used to subvert some formal rules. In contrast to exploitation, subversion consists of deliberate violation of formal strictures. It thus relies on existing formal institutions. Examples include covert party funding, contract re-negotiation or awarding in contradiction to formal stipulations regarding these. Subversion occurs more readily when formal regulation or monitoring is weak. With minimal enforcement, formal rules can be more freely broken. An excess of formal institutions—for example, when the formal rules are dense and contradictory—can also produce subversion, as informal solutions Portes, Alejandro, and Schauffler, Richard. “Competing Perspectives on the Latin American Informal Sector,” Population and Development Review vol 19, no 1, March 1993: 33-60. 18 József Böröcz, “Informality Rules,”East European Politics and Societies, Vol 14, No 2, 2000: 348-380 17 7 necessitate the breaking of formal rules.19 The incredibly dense regulatory body of Italian law, for example, regularly leads to the subversion of formal rules as the most efficient way to obtain personal or business goals. It becomes easier to pay a bribe than to continually run against conflicting regulations and laws.20 Third, informal institutions can be used to facilitate, or to supplement and enable, formal rules by providing information and expectations for strategic choices in the formal environment. Unlike either exploitation or subversion, facilitation reinforces formal institutions, if indirectly, by providing this informational wherewithal for the functioning of formal institutions. For example, when the creation of formal institutions is rapid and/or chaotic, extant rules and reputations may then provide the information that allows actors within formal institutions to make decisions in the absence of clear and readily available new data. Similarly, the informal rules and expectations—the “folkways”—of the Unites States Senate served to smooth its formal functioning and policymaking.21 These types of interactions can thus lower transaction costs engendered by formal institutions.22 Fourth, informal institutions can also reproduce formal institutions by creating popular expectations and incentives to comply with formal rules. While facilitating interactions augment formal rules by providing information to the actors, reproducing interactions reinforce formal rules more directly by changing the actors’ behavior. Informal rules can thus reinforce formal regulations, via informal sanctioning (truthful gossip), or reporting to formal authorities.23 Alternatively, informal institutions can inadvertently reify formal rules: for 19 De Soto, Hernando. The Other Path. Frei, Matt. Getting the Boot: Italy’s Unfinished Revolution. New York: Random House, 1995, p. 12. 21 Matthews, Donald. US Senators and Their World. New York: Vintage Books, 1960. 22 Pejovicz, Svetozar. “The Effects of the Interaction of Formal and Informal Institutions on Social Stability and Development” Journal of Markets and Morality, 2, #2, (Fall 1999): 164-181. 23 Ellickson, Robert. Order Without Law. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1991. 20 8 example, even as informal financing and mobilization techniques are used in electoral campaigns, they reinforce the notion that elections are the legitimate means of elite competition.24 As a result, formal rules can gain greater power to structure political behavior and decisionmaking. Two dimensions—the extent of the linkage, and whether it weakens or strengthens formal institutions—help to distinguish analytically between these four informal-formal interactions. First, interactions can be more or less dependent on dense and consolidated formal institutions. In subversion and reproduction, the impact of informal institutions is a direct function of existing formal rules. If there are no formal rules to break, or to reproduce, these interactions do not take place. Exploitation and facilitation, on the other hand, function even when the formal institutions are few and inchoate: profiting from loopholes and providing information do not rely as much on formal institutions for their impact, but on existing informal networks, experiences, and reputations. We can thus think of formal and informal interactions as tightly or loosely coupled. Second, informal institutions can either undermine or reinforce formal institutions: both exploitation and subversion undermine the rule-setting role of formal institutions, while reproduction and facilitation do not undermine the functioning of formal institutions, and can instead make formal rules more effective. This framework differs from fruitful distinctions based on the strength of formal institutions, and the compatibility between formal and informal rules.25 However, it may be more appropriate for the analysis of post-communist state institutions. For example, one reason to rely on the level of interaction, rather than on the See Kotkin, Stephen, and Sajos, Andras. Political Corruption: A Sceptic’s Handbook Budapest: CEU Press, 2002, for more of these ironies of new democracies. 25 Helmke and Levitsky 2003. 24 9 strength of formal institutions, is that the latter’s strength may be dependent on informal institutions, especially in a transitional setting.26 Figure 1. Types of interactions between formal and informal institutions Undermine FI Greater dependence on formal institutions Subversion Greater autonomy of formal institutions Exploitation Reinforce FI Reproduction Facilitation What are the constraints and opportunities for these interactions? Competition among the political actors determines the extent to which informal institutions can be used to undermine formal ones. Specifically, low alternation in power (turnover) and high concentration of power (fragmentation) in parliament both allowed political actors to build in formal advantages for themselves, and to subvert and exploit formal institutions with little fear of sanction or opposition.27 In East Central Europe, these new competitors consisted chiefly of political parties. Since policy demands were so huge, and the state itself so weak, parliamentary parties initially assumed much of the administrative work after 1989. The sheer volume of laws to be drafted, and the unresolved debates about powers and functions led to “overparliamentization” of policy, as parliaments expanded to fill the vacuum created by cabinet and state inadequacy.28 Their enormous role as the key lawmakers in constructing the institutions of market, polity, and administration meant that parliamentary parties could 26 Moreover, it may be unclear what the relevant aspects of formal institutional strength are: influence, density, or enforcement. Second, compatibility as an outcome may not necessarily indicate the mechanism of interaction that led to the outcome, whereas “undermine/ reinforce” refers to the processes of interaction. Another classification is found in Lauth 2002: formal-informal interactions can be a) complementary (coexistence and mutual reinforcement), substitutive (functionally equivalent), or conflicting (incompatible.) 27 Similarly, Mitchell Orenstein argues that lengthy incumbency delays policy learning, and perpetuates policy mistakes. See Out of the Red. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press, 2000. 28 Barbara Nunberg, ed. The State After Communism. Washington, DC: World Bank, 1999, p. 239-41. See also Attila Ágh, ed. The First Steps. Budapest: Hungarian Centre of Democracy Studies, 1994. 10 legislate for their own benefit. By creating new institutions, these parties could also build in statutory and informal privileges, “drawing up and then implementing the laws and proposals from which they benefit.”29 The greater the number of parties in parliament, and the higher their electoral uncertainty, the more likely they were monitor and sanction the actions of other parties as a way to gain electoral advantage for themselves. The greater the party turnover and fragmentation, the lower the likelihood any one party could build in benefits for itself and continue to exploit or subvert formal institutions. Well-established incumbents that can expect to be reelected and stay in office, on the other hand, can subvert and exploit formal rules with little fear of sanction or even publicity. If they could survive a regime collapse, as the communist parties did in Bulgaria, Romania, or Albania, they were even less constrained in their subversion or exploitation efforts. The converse scenarios are unlikely. A “cartel” of fragmented parties, which would Staff (and stuff) the public administration and monopolize state funding would require means (extensive party cooperation), and opportunities (lack of incentives for regulation of other parties) that rarely exist,30 and are even more scarce in consolidating party systems. Alternatively, a dominant party could give public access to state resources, reckoning that it would benefit more than other parties. However, there is little reason for a dominant party to be so magnanimous—it is more likely to accumulate resources and offices if it excludes others.31 Mair, Peter. “Political Parties, Popular Legitimacy, and Public Privilege.” West European Politics. July 1995: 40-57” pp. 54-5. 30 Koole 1996. 31 This is not to exclude the possibility that ideology can lead to self-sacrificing moves made by actors committed to ideals such as power-sharing and redistribution. See Pauline Jones Luong, Institutional Change and Political Continuity in Post-Soviet Central Asia. Cambridge: CUP, 2002. 29 11 Thus, competition constrains the degree to which informal institutions can undermine their formal counterparts. Whether we see interactions that are highly dependent on formal institutions is a function of the pacing of transformation: the faster the development of formal institutions, the more we would expect reliance on the informal provision of information and decision rules, since formal institutions have yet to consolidate. However, since the pace of institutional development is roughly similar across the region, we should not expect to see much differences in interactions that facilitate the functioning of formal institutions.32 Thus, the differences in the structures of party competition explain why parties differed in their use of informal institutions, and how these interacted with the formal structures and reforms of the state. The resulting constraints on the parties’ discretionary and rent-seeking activities explain the variation in state performance we observe in the region. 2. Party Competition and Institutional Interactions in East Central Europe Below, I examine how the configurations of party competition led to different formalinformal interactions, and how political parties both transformed and attempted to benefit from the state. Political parties exploited the formal institutions of the state by using particularist bases for decisionmaking in the absence of formal ones, subverted them by using covert channels of funding and financial support in contravention of formal laws, enabled the workings of formal institutions with informal reputations, and reinforced them with informal monitoring and sanctioning of each other. In all these cases, informal rules, such as personal loyalty, historical reputations, and discretionary decisionmaking, interacted with the formal institutions of the state and the economy. Party Competition 32 The real difference is with Western Europe, where the slower formal institutional development did not rely on informal facilitation, and was more able to constrain informal exploitation of formal rules. 12 In Slovakia and in the Czech Republic, the parliaments were dominated by the Movement for Democratic Slovakia (HZDS) and the Civic Democratic Party (ODS), respectively. These two parties ruled for most of the post-1989 period (until 1998 in both cases), with minimal opposition. As a result, these parties were relatively certain of their electoral performance, and expected that if they built in advantages, they would continue to benefit from them. Nor did other parties have the ability to monitor or publicize their transgressions, since these two parties limited access to both authority and information by the other parties. Power was initially far more dispersed in the highly fragmented Polish parliament, and in Hungary, where turnover rates and super-majority requirements offset any seat majorities. There, the fragmentation and turnover led to uncertainty regarding each of the parties’ electoral future. If one set of parties built in formal advantages, it could not be certain it would benefit from these advantages in the next electoral period. Moreover, no party had the wherewithal or the desire to allow any other to benefit exclusively. Given this electoral uncertainty, there was also a considerable incentive to publicize any transgressions by other parties, and use these to electoral advantage.33 Exploitation By exploiting formal loopholes, parties could informally extract resources from the state. State resources had the advantage of both stability and largesse, hard to find in a political environment lacking committed party members, private donors, or international support. Exploiting loopholes in formal regulations further meant that state enterprises funded governing political parties, and party loyalty would become a key criterion for employment in public administration. 33 For a detailed account of the process by which party competition configuration translated into formal constraints on rent-seeking, see Grzymala-Busse, Anna. “State Politicization and Party Competition in East Central Europe,” Comparative Political Studies. March 2003: forthcoming. 13 However, the extent to which parties were able to privilege themselves is a function of party competition: specifically, the informal mechanisms of mutual monitoring and constraint that occurred in the more fragmented parliaments. Where numerous parties faced electoral uncertainty, and each party could benefit from pointing out the errors and transgressions of the others, mutual suspicions and accusations (often publicized in the print media) served as a form of informal monitoring. Thus, in Poland and in Hungary, where government turnover was higher and no incumbent was re-elected, parties could exploit formal institutions far less than in the Czech Republic or Slovakia, where one party dominated politics for most of the transition period. (See Table 4) Turnover and fragmentation meant that each party faced considerable uncertainty about its electoral future, and thus all parties had incentives both to monitor each other’s performance, and to close loopholes that would unduly benefit ruling parties with state resources. Moreover, these parties repeatedly made public and sanctioned each other’s transgressions, in the newspapers, television interview programs, and in parliament itself—and where party votes were highly fragmented and fluid, gaining even a few voters via such appeals could mean the differences between governance, entering parliament or failing to clear the threshold. As a result, Polish and Hungarian electoral laws quickly eliminated financing by local government, by government-subsidized institutions, and by state enterprises.34 In contrast, the Czech and Slovak laws left considerable loopholes in this area. As a result, state firms and enterprises often funded national party activity, as did local government coffers. As early as January 1990, the rather vague Czechoslovak law on parties did little to address party finances, other than to stipulate that the Civic Forum, the Communist Party and its four satellites, and the Slovak counterpart of the Forum (Public Against Violence), could use their 34 See Grzymala-Busse 2003. 14 own funds.35 As Vacláv Klaus’s ODS arose from the Civic Forum, it “reluctantly allowed” state funding, but refused to expand the regulatory framework. Finally, when the opposition Social Democrats began to govern in 1998, state organs were no longer permitted to fund parties. However, since parties could be a joint owner of businesses, and local governments often owned these, funds could be easily funneled from local state offices to political parties, via informal networks of party members and allies. Since these gifts could remain anonymous until the 100,000 Kč ($30,000) threshold, parties could benefit greatly from these lax funding regulations.36 In mid-2000, parliament even voted to abolish the taxation of party donations. Gifts were limited, but loans were not, and parties did not need to provide information regarding the loans or their payment.37 As the scandals piled up,38 parties were now to name all donors, employees, wages paid, etc, but no enforcement mechanisms were put in to control this informal party financing.39 In Slovakia, as we will see below, even weak regulations were regularly broken, so that subversion rather than exploitation dominated. Employment in the state administration was similarly subject to informal exploitation of formal strictures. Given the delay in civil service laws, parties gained state resources by employing party loyalists in the state administration and then giving them discretion to further hire. Much as legal loopholes were exploited in the financing of political parties, so was the absence of formal regulations regarding the civil service or public administration employment. And, since the absence of regulations favored political appointments, civil 35 Since this allowed the communists to use their considerable assets, the newly democratic legislature did away with this privilege after the June 1990 elections, and forced the communist party to give up 95% of its assets to the state. Petroff, p. 8. 36 Vládní program boje proti korupci v Česke Republice. “Zpráva o korupci v České republic a možnostech účinného postupu proti tomut negativnímu společenskému jevu.” 17 February 1998. 37 “Rozhovor s Vojtĕchem Šimíčkem o financování politických stran,” Parlamentní Zpravodaj, 2000, #5. 38 See Appel, Hilary. “Corruption and the Collapse of the Czech Transition Miracle,” East European Politics and Society Fall 2001: 528-553. 39 Jednotka boji proti korupci, Ministry of Interior, Zpráva o korupci v ČR a o plnění harmonogramu opatření vládního programu boje proti korupci v ČR., 2001. 15 service laws were often delayed. As a result, state employment grew considerably after the fall of communism, far more than the architects of neo-liberal reforms and the concomitant slimming down of the state regulatory structures had expected. The differences, however, again lie in the constraints of party competition. With its steady rates of turnover, Hungary was relatively immune from the exploitation of formal structures by informal practices. From the start, the nascent political parties concerned themselves with ensuring that their relatively weak and uncertain positions would not be further imperiled. As a result, a civil service law, in place since 1 April 1992, effectively established the independence of the public administration system from political parties. It was followed up by a conflict of interest law in 1996, which forbade national government representatives from serving on the boards of directors and supervisory councils of companies with more than 10% of state stake.40 These heavily enforced laws eliminated potential loophole exploitation, and so very few political appointments were made in the executive structure.41 In Poland, the extreme fragmentation of the parliament also impeded the unhindered expansion of the public administration. The rapid turnover rates limited any accumulation of offices. Polish party coalitions were highly unstable, and the considerable conflict within the coalitions mean that even coalition partners tried to limit each others’ efforts. In Poland, after 1993, 10 new central offices were created, as were several funds and agencies.42 Polish parties also assigned their members to the supervisory boards (rady nadzorcze) of state corporations,43 but estimates of actual numbers placed by the parties in the public 40 Freedom House, Nations In Transit 2001. Washington DC: Freedom House, 2002, p. 204. Nunberg, Barbara. Ready for Europe: Public Administration Reform and European Union Accession in Central and Eastern Europe. World Bank Technical Paper No. 466. Washington, DC: World Bank, 2000, p. 274. 42 Wprost, 31 January 1999. 43 19 April 1997, Polityka. 41 16 administration fall below 20,000, or less than a tenth of the total public administration employment.44 Any transgressions were immediately publicized by other Polish parties (and subsequently stopped), and they did not lead to the accumulation of resources by parties over time. For example, after the 1997 elections, the ruling AWS openly spoke of exchanging 4,000 positions,45 but was immediately criticized for trying to establish a new “party nomenklatura.”46 Rather than continuing to allow exploitation, moreover, parties moved to close loopholes, by passing civil service laws in 1996 and in 2001. 47 The two laws illustrate the importance of party competition: the 1996 law built in a formal advantage for its communist successor authors: it specified that civil servants with more than 7 years of service were exempt from passing tests, and were to be favored in advancements. Needless to say, the only civil servants with this tenure were from the communist era. As a result, when the opposing AWS coalition entered office in 1997, it immediately announced it would change the law. The communist successor SLD then announced it would carefully monitor the creation of the new civil service legislation, repeatedly criticizing the novelization but keeping its meritocratic proposals when it re-entered office in 2001.48 In both the Czech Republic and in Slovakia, limited competition created limited incentives for closing formal loopholes. Two causal mechanisms underlie this correlation: first, the access of other parties to both authority and information was limited, all the more so as the governing parties entrenched themselves further in the bureaucracy. This was especially the case for opposition denounced by the governing parties as “illegitimate,” such as the 44 Polityka. 18 December 1999, Polityka. 46 22 January 2000, Polityka. 47 The extreme fragmentation, however, could also delay the implementation of formal constraints. Thus, while a civil service law was ready in 1992-3 in Poland, the fall of three different governments prevented its passing. 48 See Gazeta Wyborcza (cites from SLD file here) 45 17 Communists or the Republicans in the Czech Republic, and the Hungarian minority parties or the Christian Democrats in Slovakia. Second, given the electoral dominance of the ODS and HZDS, there were fewer marginal voters to capture via such public reports of their misdoings—and the governing parties were certain enough of future victories to continue to build in advantages for themselves without fear of subsequent electoral loss. As a result, the opposition had neither the access nor the incentives to close down the loopholes in formal regulations that favored the dominant parties. Thus, in neither country, no civil service laws were passed until 2002. In the Czech Republic, for example, the government approved a basic outline of the public administration code, and then shelved it.49 Even then, several political parties were vehemently opposed to civil service regulations, as “expensive and unnecessary.”50 Not surprisingly, in the absence of effective public employment regulations, an enormous amount of informal discretion was left: in one blatant example, in the 1996 Slovak regional reform, the HZDS instituted the “action fives,” groups of five political appointees whose job was to appoint or reappoint personnel to non-elected positions at district level. These boards “conducted a general, government-led purge of the ranks of district state administration based on explicit political criteria.”51 Similarly, when regional reform was considered, the HZDS government nominated eight regional plenipotentiaries in the fall of 1993, before the parliament approved any laws, or even the number of future regions. In other words, the HZDS knew all along that it wanted eight regions, and committed the government to this variant before laws were passed. 52 On 49 OECD, Issues and Developments in Public Management: Czech Republic-2000, p. 10. Both the ODS and the HZDS announced they would scrap the passed laws if elected into office in the 2002 elections in the two countries. 51 Krivý, Vladimír. “Slovakia’s Regions and the Struggle for Power,” in Szomolányi, Soňa and John Gould, eds. Slovakia: Problems of Democratic Consolidation. Bratislava: Friedrich Ebert Foundation, 1997, p. 116. 52 23 March 1994, Sme. 50 18 the night of 3-4 November, 1994, the HZDS also instituted what subsequently became known as the “night of long knives,” when almost all heads of oversight, monitoring, and administrative bodies were summarily exchanged for HZDS loyalists. Where parties could staff the administration with their own, both state employment and state structures expanded. In the Czech Republic, public employment more than tripled during 1989-2001, even despite the elimination of the regional governments in 1990. Slovakia also saw a similar increase, with the public employment more than tripling. Public employment did not multiply as much, “only” doubling since 1989. Part of the problem was that each ministry could hire its own employees, rather than relying on a pool of civil servants: and as a result, ministerial hiring became a favored way for political parties to reward its loyalists. The situation had become dire enough in the Czech Republic for the EU to conclude that “the occupying of positions in the state machinery according to party membership or on the basis of personal acquaintances is in contradiction with the requirements of the rule of law and with the interests of the public.”53 Moreover, in both the Czech and Slovak cases, top party leaders were direct members of supervisory boards of profitable enterprises,54 and “state agencies retained the ability to control the field by providing subsidies from state funds to select groups.”55 The HZDS moved to centralize power, and “rewarded its members and supporters in the organs of the state administration, especially on the regional and local level.” 56 Not PHARE and NVF, “An Analysis of Public Administration of the Czech Republic,” Summary Report, Prague, September 1998. 54 Mesežnikov, Grigorij. “The Open-Ended Formation of Slovakia’s Political Party System,” in Szomolányi, Soňa and John Gould, eds. Slovakia: Problems of Democratic Consolidation. Bratislava: Friedrich Ebert Foundation, 1997, p. 45. 55 Malová, Darina. “The Development of Interest Representation in Slovakia after 1989” in Szomolányi, Soňa and John Gould, eds. Slovakia: Problems of Democratic Consolidation. Bratislava: Friedrich Ebert Foundation, 1997, p. 100. 56 Mesežnikov 1997, p. 45. 53 19 surprisingly, a subsequent audit emphasized the need to eliminate many medium-level organizations, sections, committees, and divisions.57 This informal exploitation of loopholes in formal regulations had two effects: first, it made it possible for political parties to gain resources directly from the state. Thus, it enabled considerable rent-seeking, as state resources were awarded on a discretionary, rather than meritocratic or competitive basis. Second, it generated a feedback effect: parties that were powerful enough at the outset to privilege themselves, such as the HZDS and ODS, gained the material resources and clientelistic ties to gain an advantage in subsequent elections and could build in further loopholes for themselves, making it more difficult for other parties to compete and reverse this spiral. Since these parties created the laws that would then constrain their behavior, they could build in opportunities for further exploitation. For example, the Slovak Law on Political Parties and Movements formally allowed political formations to conduct business activity only in clearly defined areas. But in 1996, Slovak media revealed that the HZDS (which wrote the law) had founded businesses that deliberately participated in privatization projects in spheres not covered by the law. Subversion When political parties do not comply with formal reporting requirements, review or skew privatization decisions, award contracts in contravention of bidding rules, and so on, they subvert formal rules. Political parties did not stop at exploiting formal institutions: they also deliberately broke laws and operating procedures, and relied on faulty monitoring and enforcement mechanisms to escape punishment. Thus, favorable privatization privileges and deals drained resources out of the state treasury, rather than funding public goods. These deals “Audit súladu činností a financovania ústredných orgánov štátnej správy,” Slovak Government Information Service, August 2000, also available at http://www.vlada.gov.sk/INFOSERVIs/ DOKUment_UOSS_2000/audit_UOSS_2000_august.shtml 57 20 were concluded on the basis of individual and political networks, rather than on the basis of highest bids in the formal tenders, as in Slovakia during 1992-8. Subversion of formal rules also included the funneling of funds to party coffers from sources that were legally forbidden, such as anonymous donors. Unlike exploitation, subversion involves the explicit breaking and transgressing of formal regulations, rather than making use of its shortcomings. Like exploitation, however, it is more prevalent where dominant parties have gained access to state resources. Thus, the Czech Republic saw repeated scandals over party financing, and the tendency of the governing parties to break the few rules on the books: the main ruling party, the ODS, could not explain why a dead Hungarian and a resident of Mauritius were its main donors during 1995-6, why it concealed over 170 million Kč in Switzerland,58 or why it received 7.5 million Kč from Moravia Steel after the latter was allowed to lower its bid for Trinecke Železarne by 300 million Kč.59 Another coalition partner, the ODA received over 6 million, ostensibly from the TMC Company in the Virgin Islands, which turned out to be Philip Morris, the First Privatization Fund, and the Vitkovice steel mill. Both the ODA and the ODS received loans of 25 and 50 million, respectively, from Antonin Moravec, head of the Credit and Industry Bank, which they then repaid via favorable privatization deals.60 Parties thus deliberately broke formal privatization and financing regulations. In Slovakia, the dominant HZDS did not stop at exploiting legal loopholes, but went on a binge of unconstrained subversion as well. The second wave of voucher privatization, scheduled for 1993, never took place, but privatization nonetheless accelerated at beginning 58 Respekt, 1 December 1997. The ODS also claimed it had received over 2 million Kč from the American Committee for the Support of ODS, despite the latter’s denial it had ever paid the money. 60 Respekt, 16 February 1997. 59 21 of 1994, via direct sales in favor of the HZDS and its coalition partners.61 Moreover, HZDS often informed would-be participants in the privatization process that partnership with HZDStied companies was a “necessary precondition of the successful realization of their privatization projects.”62 The HZDS also used formalization to subvert earlier laws: a 1995 law gave tax breaks to the allies of the HZDS government who bought enterprises via direct privatization.63 Another law gave the state power over 74 key companies, and transferred power to administer privatization from the Ministry of Privatization to the National Privatization Fund, so that the state no longer had formal control over privatization decisions.64 Yet informal monitoring and checking among parties could curtail these practices. Initially, monitoring and reporting requirements were routinely ignored by Polish parties. Political parties and parliamentarians were to submit yearly statements regarding their economic activity and large donors, but these were not checked for either submission or accuracy. As a result, only two parties turned in declarations in the first year of the law.65 Yet the constant suspicions among the numerous and squabbling political parties and mutual accusations meant that informal practices would limit this subversion, and create incentives for the formalization of this monitoring. Thus, by 2001, a new Polish election law mandated Mikloš, Ivan. “Economic Transition and the Emergence of Clientelist Structures in Slovakia,” in Szomolányi, Soňa and John Gould, eds. Slovakia: Problems of Democratic Consolidation. Bratislava: Friedrich Ebert Foundation, 1997, p. 61. 62 Mesežnikov, Grigorij. “The Open-Ended Formation of Slovakia’s Political Party System,” in Szomolányi, Soňa and John Gould, eds. Slovakia: Problems of Democratic Consolidation. Bratislava: Friedrich Ebert Foundation, 1997, p. 38. 63 Mikloš, Ivan. “Economic Transition and the Emergence of Clientelist Structures in Slovakia,” in Szomolányi, Soňa and John Gould, eds. Slovakia: Problems of Democratic Consolidation. Bratislava: Friedrich Ebert Foundation, 1997, p. 77. 64 The NPF, a quasi-private joint stock company created to administer the privatization decisions of government and administer state properties, was fully under the personal discretion of the HZDS. Szomolányi, Soňa. “Identifying Slovakia’s Emerging Regime,” in Szomolányi, Soňa and John Gould, eds. Slovakia: Problems of Democratic Consolidation. Bratislava: Friedrich Ebert Foundation, 1997, p. 17. 65 22 January 2000, Polityka. These were the UW and ZChN. 61 22 full reporting and effective sanctions,66 since “all agree that to limit corruption it is necessary to publicize the sources of party financing.”67 As a result, the new law eliminated public fundraising, capped contributions, and stipulated that all campaign spending has to come from a public electoral fund set up by each party and monitored by an independent commission. The opportunities for such subversion were even more limited in Hungary, where the initial fragmentation and uncertainty prior to the communist exit made all the parties wary of any one benefiting disproportionately. Formal party funding was both generous and strictly regulated. According to the October 1989 law, parties receiving more than 1% of the vote were eligible for state funding. At the same time, the majority of the new law on parties was concerned with the methods of funding distribution, use, accounting, and limits on potential donations.68 Party funding reports were made public, and an independent monitoring agency, the Government Control Commission, was set up. Subsequently, in May 1991 professional accounting standards for parties were introduced, and repeatedly upheld.69 Similarly, privatization was far less subverted than in the former Czechoslovakia. As a result, despite the rise of foundations closely allied with the parties, and the ties of business with parties, party finances were more public, more stringently controlled, and allowed less rent-seeking, since “strong limits have developed upon party penetration into state and social life.”70 Both the mechanisms and constraints of subversion and exploitation were themselves informal. Where the political competition was limited, and both turnover and fragmentation rates were relatively low, parties were returned to office again and again, as in the Czech Parties not submitting a report, or those that did not pass the forensic accountants’ scrutiny, would not receive state funds for that electoral period. 67 19 May 2000, Rzeczpospolita. 68 As a result, some parties, like the MSZP, received only 24% of their funds from the state. The MDF received 60%, the FKGP 73%, while the others (Fidesz, KDNP, and SzDSz) received over 80% from the state. 69 Petroff, Wlodzimierz. “Finansowanie partii politycznych w postkomunistycznej Europie,” Kancelaria Sejmu, Biuro Studiów i Ekspertyz, June 1996, #95, p. 14. 70 Körösényi, p. 168. 66 23 Republic and Slovakia, such dominant parties could more readily build in advantages for themselves, confident they would be the beneficiaries. Thus, the powerful beneficiaries of informal institutions can formalize these practices, but in so doing, they may also undermine formal institutions and their development. Facilitation Informal practices facilitated formal institutions by decisionmaking rules for actors within formal institutions where the latter generated few formal guidelines. Unlike exploitation or subversion, facilitation is not a function of the configuration of party competition, but of the greater availability of information from existing informal rules at a time when formal institutions are being rapidly constructed, but have not yet become familiar or powerful enough to generate strong incentives. First, informal rules cut down on the costs of obtaining information—for example, before parties developed ideological reputations and practical experience, an informal “regime divide” structured the potential for formal coalitions and cooperation between parties with origins in the former opposition on the one hand, and the successors to the communist parties and their various satellites on the other.71 The more profound this divide (the result of communist party-society interactions and conflict), the less likely coalitions across these two camps, even when ideological proximity and other affinities would have dictated them. For example, the Polish communist successor party could only form coalitions with its former satellite. Its policy and ideology were far closer to the centrist Freedom Union, as both parties admitted, but its provenance made such a coalition impossible. In contrast, the Hungarian communist successor could govern with a former opposition party, chiefly because the regime Kitschelt, Herbert, Mansfeldová, Zdenka, Markowski, Radosław, and Tóka, Gábor. Post-Communist Party Systems. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999., Grzymala-Busse 2002. 71 24 divide was less stark. Coalitions thus formed not on the basis of ideological or numerical considerations, but of past conflict or cooperation.72 When it came to the state and its structures, governing coalitions in all four countries named representatives enterprise boards on the basis of informal power-sharing: if the head of a board was from one governing party, the vice chair was from the other. Positions were filled according to the political preferences of the governing coalition, and these in turn relied on extant personal alliances.73 With time, rather than a mid-way step to privatization, the supervisory boards became an end unto themselves, a lucrative and stable employment that was both a reward to party loyalists and a source of income to the party.74 Similarly, when governing parties were to appoint regional leaders in Poland, senior governing coalition partners named the voivode, and the juniors, the vice-voivode. These rules thus provided informational shortcuts for, and thus enabled the functioning of, formal institutions. Coalition-affinity and power-sharing rules thus facilitated formal institutions by making decisions within formal structures considerably more streamlined. Similarly, informal agreements facilitated formal arrangements when the question of staffing discretionary offices came up.75 Informal rules could thus provide information that was both useful to political parties on its own—and which greased the gears of the formal state machinery. Grzymala-Busse, Anna. “Coalition Formation and the Regime Divide,” Comparative Politics, October 2001. Wprost, 5 March 2000. 74 Parties could use these positions in two ways: use the moneys directly for various sponsoring and advertising, and to get foreign investors and others to contribute to the party in exchange for a permit to buy company shares. 75 Since these were intended to be named by political parties, this is not exploitation of the sort we see with personalistic hiring in the civil service in the absence of a civil service law. 72 73 25 Reproduction Informal institutions could also reproduce their formal counterparts, by monitoring and punishing the subversion and exploitation of formal institutions, and by reifying formal institutions. First, informal monitoring and sanctioning among the political parties could also reproduce formal institutions by limiting the amount of subversion and exploitation possible. Competition was thus not only a constraint on subversion and exploitation, but was also a mechanism of institutional reproduction. Where several parties competed for power, with no party getting re-elected, the greater electoral uncertainty meant that parties constantly watched each other’s hands, reporting any misdoings since that could be an electoral advantage, as argued above. The electoral uncertainty also meant that no party had either the incentive or the capacity to propose “winner-take-all” formal institutions, such as single member districts, funding based exclusively on number of seats, and so on, since it was unclear who would benefit. Parties also publicized each other’s shortcomings, thus informally sanctioning parties that sought rents from the state. Such constant monitoring limited the amount of subversion and exploitation of formal institutions. In contrast, where the informal monitoring and sanctioning were feeble, political parties could poorly specify the legislation on party financing so that local governments and state firms could contribute financially to the governing political parties. They could also exploit the lack of meritocratic laws regarding public hiring and staff the public administration with their loyalists, and break laws with less fear of adverse publicity or electoral punishment. Second, informal institutions reproduced formal institutions by expanding the latter’s sphere: several informal arrangements were formalized by political parties and leaders, only 26 to make them subject to formal oversight organizations, expanding the formal regulatory role of the state. For example, the creation of quasi-public agencies in Poland and in Hungary to take on privatization and other state roles allowed informal personal networks to carve out a sphere of activity that was formally codified and legitimated.76 At the same time, however, these were subject to the rulings of the Constitutional and other courts, reinforcing the latter’s regulatory role. Such patterns also show the acquiescence of local and national authorities to the proliferation and functioning of informal institutions: not only because they may be a way to gain discretionary benefits, but also because they offer shortcuts and strategic templates that allow formal institutions to function and to perform their codifying roles. Informal institutions may even reproduce formal institutions, both by limiting the undermining of formal rules, and by relying on the formal legitimation of informal gains.77 3. Alternative Explanations Two other alternative explanations seek to account for the role of informal institutions, and the peculiar divergence between Poland and Hungary on the one hand, and the Czech Republic and Slovakia on the other. The first one focuses on the existing supply of informal institutions in the legacies of the past, and the second emphasizes the potential demand for informal institutions in the processes of national and constitutional construction. Thus, relevant legacies of the past range from the kind of state that arose from the collapse of the communist-party state78 to the impact of tourism, which became a significant source of 76 These institutions first gained these funds in the 1980s, and were resurrected in the 1994-5, when branch ministries heavily pressured the center to create more extra-budgetary institutions.. Interview with Zyta Gilowska, by Elzbieta Misiak. 3 September 2001, available at http://www.platforma.org/new/wywiady/10.shtml. 77 See also Portes and Sassen-Koob, and Darden, Keith. “Graft and Governance: Corruption as an Informal Mechanism of State Control,” Manuscript, Yale University, August 2002. 78 Kitschelt et al 1999 27 unregulated, untaxed, and unregistered income in the 1980s.79 The more informal institutions were used in the past, the argument goes, the greater their impact after the collapse of communism. The communist parties’ response to the shortcomings and inefficiencies of their regime took the form of “accommodating” society through a degree of liberalization—the Polish and Hungarian states gained some independence from the party by the 1980s—or of increased authoritarianism, as in Czechoslovakia. This communist response, whether “patrimonial,” “accommodative,” or “authoritarian,”i could account for the observed variance. The more patrimonial or accommodative the communist regime, the looser the controls on the informal despoliation of the state, while the more constrained and authoritarian the communist state, the fewer such opportunities. However, the predictions of this explanation run counter to the empirical findings: the authoritarian regime in Czechoslovakia did not constrain the subsequent use of informal institutions—indeed, the informal undermining of formal institutions was considerably worse in the two successor republics. Moreover, the mechanisms that would sustain and adapt these informal institutions from one regime setting to another remain unclear. It is not clear from these accounts either which legacies would be deployed, or the mechanisms by which they were transmitted. As a result, this account does not specify clearly which informal solutions we would expect to see, or how they would continue to influence politics. Another set of scholars argues that informal institutions will be sustained only as long as there is external demand for them.80 Thus, where new nation-states are constructed, as in the case of the Czech Republic and Slovakia, we would expect greater demand for informal 79 Borocz 2000, p. 362. Pistor, Katharina. “The Evolution of Legal Institutions and Economic Regime Change,” Paper Prepared for the annual Bank Conference on Development Economic in Europe, Paris, France, 21-23 June, 1999. See also Barbara Geddes, The Politician’s Dilemma. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 1994. 80 28 facilitation and greater opportunity for informal exploitation, since the formal institutions had not consolidated enough for interactions dependent on formal institutions to take place. Yet subversion was the dominant interaction in these two countries, as existing formal rules were inherited, and new ones were constituted, only to be broken. This demand-driven approach tends to ignore both the persistence of informal institutions and their “stickiness,” as well as the possibility that informal institutions can so undermine formal institutions as to create their own demand. Thus, to complement these existing approaches to the study of informal institutions and their impact, a focus on the interaction of informal with formal institutions, and the results of these interactions, may be more helpful both in providing a mechanism for institutional retention, and for accounting for the persistence and change in these institutions. Conclusion If we examine the variation in state performance across East Central Europe, the imposition of formal institutions and constraints on state politicization does not coincide or precede the variation in the growth of state administration, political discretion in hiring or resource extraction, the control of corruption, or government effectiveness. Rather, the underlying patterns of party competition allowed and constrained a set of informal institutions to determine the shape of the state, and the ways in which it differed across the cases examined here. In short, in the post-communist context, formal institutions underwent a form of superficial isomorphism, resembling each other across countries and converging over time. Informal institutions, however, diverged in their function and importance. Parties used informal rules both to survive and to shape the state. These rules, derived from personal 29 networks, legal loopholes, and past patterns of conflict allowed the inchoate political parties to choose strategies and to consolidate their earlier gains. Yet informal institutions also limited how much parties could extract from the state, via informal monitoring and enforcement of formal rules. Thus informal institutions had two contradictory effects, both undermining and reinforcing the formal democratic structures. By subverting, exploiting, facilitating, and reproducing formal institutions, political parties have informally shaped the democratic development of the state, both reinforcing and undermining formal institutions. As a result, informal mechanisms do not simply hinder democratic accountability or the functioning of formal institutions,81 but function in considerably more nuanced ways, and can even enrich formal institutions considerably. Moreover, if the emergence of informal institutions can be seen as a function of conflict among actors competing for the benefits that flow from institutions,82 so is the moderation of the effects of informal institutions. Where fragmentation and turnover were high, parties faced considerable electoral uncertainty—and as a result, they both had incentives not to build in excessive advantages for incumbents (since it was unlikely they could benefit from them for long), and to monitor, report on, and sanction each other’s behavior (since they stood to gain a marginal electoral advantage this way.) These interactions between formal and informal institutions, and the informal mechanisms of their emergence and reproduction moderated each other’s impact.83 The result was the change over time we observe between the two groups of countries considered here. O’Donnell 1996. Knight 1992. 83 As Kathleen Thelen argues with respect to formal institutions, one important source of institutional change lies with the interaction of different institutional orders within society. Thelen, Kathleen. “Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Politics,” Annual Review of Political Science, 1999: 369-404. 81 82 30 Outside of this sample, there are cases that might call into question the analysis presented above. Slovenia, for example, has had the same party in power for most of its post-1991 independent existence, yet its rates of state politicization are the lowest in the region. However, the Slovene LDS’s hold on power was more tenuous than its time in office would suggest.84 Unlike the Slovak and Czech cases, coalitions were both unstable and differed from one term to next, with the 1996 election resulting in a deadlock.85 Subsequently, its coalition partner (SLS) extracted numerous power-sharing concessions from the LDS, and the government fell when the SLS went over into the opposition in April 2000. As a result, the LDS was constantly and consistently constrained in ways that neither the Czech ODS nor the Slovak HZDS were. The potential importance of informal institutions suggests two further venues for research. First, a comparison with the slower, more gradual institutional development in Western Europe may help us to isolate further the effects of pacing, and test the hypotheses provided here. Secondly, scholars and analysts examining the post-communist state (including international agents such as the European Union) would gain a more accurate image of state development, and the potential ways of addressing its shortcomings, by including informal institutions, as opposed to focusing chiefly on formal laws and regulations on the books. The party came under constant criticism, most notably from Janez Janša, leader of the SDS, the Social Democratic Party. 85 Coalition crises repeatedly occurred in 1993, 1994, 1996, and in 2000. In the 1996 election, the LDS got 25 seats, while the SLS+SKD post-electoral coalition got 29. 84 31 Table 1. Introduction of State Reforms Hungary Poland Slovenia Czech Rep Bulgaria Romania Slovakia Regional 1990 1998 ~ 2001 ~ 199687 1996/ 2002 Civil Service 1992 1996 1993 2002 1999 1999 2001 Anti-Corruption86 2001 1997 2001 1999 2001 1997 (unenforced) 2000 Table 2. Expansion of State Employment88 1989-2000 Change in 1989-2000 Change in State Employment State Employment as % of Total Employment -24.9% 1989: 7.5% Hungary 397,900 to 299,000 2000: 7.8% 201% 1989: 1.5% Poland 260,700 to 526,000 2000: 3.5% 210% 1989: 3.0% Slovenia 22, 895 to 48,000 2000: 5.3% 258% 1989: 1.5% Czech Rep 74,047 to 191,000 2000: 4.0% 300% 1989: 1.5% Slovakia 32,833 to 98,600 2000: 4.7% Table 3. Government Effectiveness and Control of Corruption Gov’t Effectiveness Control of Corruption Rankings 89 (-2.5 to 2.5 scale) Corruption (1-10 scale)91 90 1997/8 2000/1 (-2.5 to 2.5 scale) 199292 2002 .61 .60 .65 5.2 4.9 Hungary .67 .27 .43 5.2 4.8 Poland .57 .70 1.09 N/a 6.0 Slovenia .58 .31 5.2 3.7 Czech Rep .59 .57 .70 .23 5.2 3.7 Slovakia 86 Source: Monitoring the EU Accession Process: Coruption and Anti-corruption Policy. Budapest: Open Society Institute, 2002. 87 http://ro-gateway.ro/node/200156/editorial 88 Data unavailable for Bulgaria and Romania 89 Source: Kauffman, Kraay, and Zoido (2002): Governance Matters II Data Set, available from the World Bank. 90 Source: Kauffman, Kraay, and Zoido (2002): Governance Matters II Data Set, available from the World Bank 91 Source: Transparency International, and the Internet Center for Corruption Research, at http://www.gwdg.de/~uwvw/ 92 Estimate. 32 Table 4. Dispersion of Power in Parliament Hungary Poland Czech Republic Slovakia i Longest tenure of governing party in office, in months 48 48 89 Fragmentation 1st parliamentary term93 .71 .90 .55 Fragmentation 2nd parliamentary term .65 .75 .79 Fragmentation in 3rd parliamentary term .74 .67 .76/ .73 9094 .60 .69 .77 See Kitschelt, H., Mansfeldová, Z., Markowski, R., & Tóka. G. (1999) Post-Communist Party Systems Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. As measured by 1- Si 2, where Si is the seat share. The index measures the concentration of competitive strength among parties. A party system dominated by one party alone would have a fractioning index of 0, a twoparty system with an even split of seats an index of .5, and so on. See Rae, Douglas. The Political Consequences of Electoral Laws, New Haven: Yale University Press, 1971, and esp. p. 98. 94 The HZDS-led coalition was in office three times, for 9, 33, and 48 months, respectively. 93