Supplementary electronic Appendix: Introduction of EC-IAM Environment Canada’s integrated assessment model (EC-IAM), which is based on the MERGE model (Manne and Richels, 1995, and 2005), combines an economic activity based economy-energyemission sub-model with a climate science based climate sub-model into an integrated assessment model system for climate policy analysis. Economy-energy-emission Sub-model Economy-energy-emission sub-model is the core model. It can run standalone or in combination with climate sub-model. In the economy-energy-emission submodel, the “Negishi Method” is utilized to approach the decentralized multi-region intertemporal equilibrium solution by transferring it into a global social planning problem (Negishi, 1960). The objective function (NWEL) is a global utility function, which is a sum of regional discounted utilities (U(Crt,Trt) weighted by Negishi weights (NWTr )1. πππΈπΏ = ∑π ∑π‘ ππππ ∗ ππ·πΉππ‘ ∗ logβ‘(π(πΆππ‘, πππ‘ )) (1) The Negishi welfare weight for region r is updated iteratively according to the weights of regional monetary utility value in overall global value. UDFrt is the utility discount factor for region r at period t. U(Crt, Trt) is represented by a constant elasticity of substitution (CES) function between consumption (Crt) and passenger transportation (Trt). The optimal solution involves the maximization of the above global utility function subject to a number of constraints including regional budget, economic production, energy supply and passenger transportation technologies and /or climate equations of constraints. Economic activity in each region is represented by a top-down putty-clay macro production function where price responsive inputs, such as labour, capital and energy are introduced through a nested CES technology. Different regions are linked through international trade flows. This regional aggregate production (Yrt) satisfies the competitive demand for regional consumption (Crt), investment (Irt), transportation cost (TCrt), energy cost (ECrt), abatement costs (ACrt) (for non-CO2 GHG abatement) and net exports (ππππrt). πππ‘ = πΆππ‘ + πΌππ‘ + πΈπΆππ‘ + ππΆππ‘ + π΄πΆππ‘ + ππππππ‘ (2) For the macro production, all inputs (i.e., labour, capital, electric and non-electric energy) and outputs, as well as consumption, passenger transportation and utility are vintaged as old and new. Old vintages are determined by the amount of last period minus depreciation. New vintage output is represented by an economy-wide nested CES production function of new vintages of capital (KNrt), labour (LNrt), electric energy (ENrt) and non-electric energy (NNrt) as follows: 1 For debate on the equity issue of Negishi weight, see Stanton, E.A. (2011). π 1 π½ 1−π½ πΌ 1−πΌ )π ππππ‘ = π΄ππ‘ [πππ‘ (πΎπππ‘ πΏπππ‘ + (1 − πππ‘ )(πΈπππ‘ ππππ‘ ) ] ⁄π (3) New vintage utility is represented by a CES utility function of new vintages of consumption and passenger transportation as follows, ππππ‘ = π΅ππ‘ [πππ‘ πΆπ πΏ + (1 − πππ‘ )ππ πΏ ]1/πΏ (4) There are limited goods that are tradable. These include macro goods, oil, gas and emission permits wherever applicable. Heckscher-Ohlin paradigm is assumed to govern the international trade (i.e., tradable goods are homogeneous, rather than region-specific). For each tradable good i and each projection period t, there is a balance-of-trade constraint (NTXirt) that, at a global level net exports or imports for all regions must sum up to zero. ∑rNTXirt = 0 (5) New vintaged capital is formed by investment of last period and new vintaged labour and labour supply is exogenously determined. Energy supply is represented both by bottom up electric and non-electric technologies (vintage as well as non-vintage), while transportation supply is captured by bottom up vehicle modes. Major electric technologies are vintaged. A list of available technologies is provided in Appendix table A. Electric Energy and non-electric technologies compete to supply electric energy and non-electric energy demand by the macro production. Vehicle modes or technologies compete to supply the demand for transportation by regional consumers. Exogenous Levelized costs and heat rate (if applicable) are assumed for those electricity technologies including renewable and backstop technologies, non-electric technologies and passenger transportation technologies. The choices of those technologies are determined endogenously by cost minimizing actions of agents subject to various energy supply constraints and/or with the climate policies taken into consideration. The energy supply includes the following blocks of equations or constraints: 1) Hotelling equations describing the supply and evolution of exhaustible resources: oil, natural gas and uranium. There are two major costs associated with exhaustible resources. One is the extraction cost, that is, the cost of removing the fuel resources from the earth. Another is the resource exploration or discovery cost: the cost of converting undiscovered resources into proved resources for extraction. The extraction costs rise with the fraction of accumulated extraction over aggregate endowment. The discovery costs rise with cumulative reserve additions as a fraction of undiscovered resources. Extractions of resources are constrained by the proven reserves. Reserve additions are constrained by undiscovered resources. 2) Accounting identities linking the energy submodel and the macroeconomic model, flow variables with stock variables, and component variables to aggregate variables: Demands for electric energy and non-electric energy in the economic submodel equals the sum of supplies of electric technologies and non-electric technologies respectively in the energy submodel. Total energy cost in the economic 2 model equals the sum of supply costs of electricity associated with electric technologies and nonelectric energy associated with non-eclectic technologies. Energy supplies must be balanced with energy consumptions. 3) Various energy constraints based on experts’ knowledge: (1) Expansion constraints and / or contraction constraints are set up for those energy technologies subject to expansion limits and /or decline limits. (2) Market share constraints are set up for some electric technologies such as coal fired or gas fired technologies or intermittent electric technologies of wind and low cost solar, and some non-electric technologies. (3) Capacity constraints are set up for some electric technologies such as hydro, nuclear, and wind and some non-electric technologies, such as bio fuels and synthetic fuels. Energy related GHG emissions are directly related to the use of energy such as coal, oil and gas in the energy production or conversion, or in the macro production and passenger transportation. Non-energy related GHG emissions and abatement costs are set exogenously. Climate submodel The climate submodel is a reduced aggregate description of the climate system from GHG emissions to GHG concentration to radiative forcing and to temperature change over the preindustrial level in 1750 (IPCC, 2001; IPCC 2007; Manne and Richels, 2005). The global emissions of each GHG gas is the sum of regional energy related emissions endogenously determined by the demand and supply of energy and non-energy emissions (exogenous) less abatement.2 This provides the link between the climate submodel and the macroeconomic submodel & the energy submodel. The total stock of GHG gases is determined by a distributed lag process to account for the inertia of the climate system represented by the decay or lifetime of GHG gases and the accumulation of current emissions. Concentration of GHG gases in the atmosphere is determined by the total stock of GHG gases proportionally. In turn, the radiative forcing of GHG gases is determined by the concentration of GHG gases, namely, following IPCC; ο§ Radiative forcing of CO2 is proportional to the logarithm of CO2 concentration. ο§ Radiative forcing of CH4 or N2O is proportional to the square root of CH4 or N2O concentration. ο§ Radiative forcing of F-gas is proportional to the F-gas concentration. ο§ Total radiative forcing of GHG gases is the sum of radiative forcing of various GHG gases. 2 For non-energy GHG emission and their abatement cost-potential, EC-IAM is based on the estimates provided by the Energy Modeling Form Study 21. 3 In the end, the eventual equilibrium temperature is proportional to the aggregate radiative forcing. The actual temperature increase from pre-industrial levels is determined by a lagged response to the equilibrium temperature. As in MERGE (Manne and Richels 1995, and 2005), there are a number of energy and technology supply constraints some of which are based on expert knowledge and some are driven by resource constraints. In addition, accounting identities linking supply and demand, flow variables and stock variables, and component variables and aggregate variables must be met. GHG emissions are tightly linked to economic and energy activities. Energy-related GHG emissions are directly related to the use of energy such as coal, oil and natural gas in energy production or conversion, or in macro production. Non-energy related GHG emissions and abatement potentials are set exogenously using information from various sources such as the US EPA (2006) and those obtained from Energy Modeling Forum Study 21. Climate submodel The climate submodel is a reduced form climate system model that links GHG emissions from the economy-energy-emission submodel to GHG concentration, to radiative forcing and finally to temperature change over the preindustrial level in 1750 (IPCC, 2001; IPCC 2007; Manne and Richels, 2005). The global emissions level of each GHG gas is the sum of regional emissions less abatement. The total stock of GHG gases is determined by a distributed lag process to account for the inertia of the climate system represented by the decay or lifetime of GHG gases and the accumulation of current emissions. Concentration of GHG gases in the atmosphere is determined by the total stock of GHG gases proportionally. Following IPCC guidelines, the radiative forcing of GHG gases is determined by the concentration of GHG gases as follows: ο§ ο§ Radiative forcing of CO2 is proportional to the logarithm of CO2 concentration. Radiative forcing of CH4 or N2O is proportional to the square root of CH4 or N2O concentration. ο§ Radiative forcing of F-gas is proportional to the F-gas concentration. ο§ Total radiative forcing of GHG gases is the sum of radiative forcing of various GHG gases. In the end, the eventual equilibrium temperature is proportional to the aggregate radiative forcing. The actual temperature increase from pre-industrial levels is determined by a lagged response to the equilibrium temperature. Currently, there are 11 regions in the model (Table A) The technology assumptions are presented in Table B. The GDP growth rate and technology cost change parameters used in model calibration are presented in Tables C and D. 4 Table A: Regions in the model Region code OECD EMRE ROW Definition Group Australia and New Zealand Canada I I Greater European Union I Japan United States Brazil China India Middle income Rest of World (include Indonesia, South Korea, Thailand, Malaysia, other high-income Asia, Low-income Eastern Europe, Turkey, Mexico, Argentina, Chile, Uruguay, Other highincome ROW, South Africa) Russia I I II II II Low income and oil exporting Rest of World ( include HighIncome oil-exporting countries, Mid- and Low-income oilexporting countries, Other low-income Latin America, Other Former Soviet Union, Other low-income Latin America, Other Middle East/North Africa, Other Sub-Saharan Africa) 5 II III III Table B : Various technologies of the model Electric Technology Vintaged Hydro-electric power No Nuclear power Yes Coal-fired electric power without CCS Yes Oil-fired electric power without CCS Yes Gas-fired electric power without CCS Yes Coal-fired electric power with CCS, Yes Gas-fired electric power with CCS, Wind generated electric power Yes Yes Solar generated electric power Biomass fired electric power Yes Yes Other renewable generation (geothermal , waste, and other renewable generation) No Liquid fuel supply technologies Refined oil Biomass-based liquids Coal-based synthetic liquids Non-electric energy Technologies Coal for end use Gas for end use Liquid for end use Backstop fuel for end use Passenger transportation Technologies Internal combustion engine vehicle Compressed natural gas vehicle Plug-in hybrid electric vehicle Full electric vehicle Backstop (e.g. H2) vehicle 6 Table C: Expected Annual Average Economic Growth in Starting decade 2011-2020 Region GDP Grow Rate Brazil 3.5% Canada 2.4% India 7.1% Russia 3.5% United States 2.8% Europe 2.0% Japan 1.4% Australia, New Zealand 3.0% China 6.6% Middle income countries 3.2% Low income and oil exporting countries 4.6% Table D: Average cost change from 2010 to 2050 (%) Technologies OECD EMRE ROW Coal-fired electric power without CCS -14 -14 -14 Gas-fired electric power without CCS -10 -10 -10 Oil-fired electric power without CCS -10 -10 -10 Coal-fired electric power with CCS -33 -42 -49 Nuclear power (generation II and III) -3 -7 -10 Nuclear power (generation IV) -33 -33 -33 Solar generated electric power (back stop) -47 -54 -54 Solar generated electric power (intermittent) -34 -36 -38 Wind generated electric power -52 -54 -43 Biomass fired electric power -39 -41 -32 References EPA (2006), Global Mitigation of Non-CO2 Greenhouse Gases, http://www.epa.gov/nonco2/econ-inv/international.html 7 IPCC (2001), IPCC Third Assessment Report: Climate Change http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/publications_and_data_reports.shtml#1. 2001 (TAR), IPCC (2007), IPCC Fourth Assessment Report: Climate Change http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/publications_and_data_reports.shtml#1. 2007 (AR4), Manne, A. and R. Richels (2005), “Merge: An Integrated Assessment Model for Global Climate Change”, In Richard Loudon, Jean-Philippe Waaub, and George Zaccour (eds), Energy and Environment, pages 175-189. Springer US. Manne, A., Mendelson, R., and R. Richels (1995), “MERGE: A Model for Evaluating Regional and Global Effects of GHG Reduction Policies”, Energy Policy, 23(1), 17-34. Negishi, T. (1960), “Welfare Economics and Existence of Equilibrium for a Competitive Economy”, Metroeconomics 12, 92-97. 8