Democratic Innovation and Gradual Institutional Change – The Case of Better Reykjavik Magnus E. Jonsson Doktorand statskunskap Örebro universitet NOOS 2015 5-6 Februari Malmö/Lund TIDIGT UTKAST VÄNLIGEN CITERA INTE DENNA VERSION 1 Abstract Democratic innovations have a tendency to be short-lived, and/or ad-hoc islands of participation with little or none formal connection to the policy and decision-making process. The participatory online platform for creating citizen initiatives Better Reykjavik (Betri Reykjavik) and the participatory online budget process Better Neighborhoods (Betri Hverfi) in Reykjavik, Iceland, are, however, two exceptions. The Better Reykjavik platform was born out of the financial and political crisis in 2008 by a non-profit grass-root organization and has since the local elections in 2010 been connected to the policy and decision-making process in City Hall. While research on democratic innovations is focusing on the institutionalization of participatory and deliberative practices, there exists few, or none, links to the existing frameworks in the tradition of ‘new institutionalism’. This study is departing from a comprehensive institutional framework focusing on the interrelationship between the characteristics of the political context, the characteristics of the political institutions and the dominant change-agents. By applying such a broad approach, the article aims to answers the questions on how the implementation of Better Reykjavik and Better Neighborhoods occurred, and how we can understand the implementation in relation to the institutional framework. This study is based on two rounds of interviews (N=8) with key stakeholders in both the Better Reykjavik and the Better Neighborhoods projects and secondary literature about Icelandic civic and party culture. The analysis shows that when the Icelandic political system was hit by an exogenous chock (the financial crisis), a ‘window of opportunity’ opened up. Due to the weak party institutions in Iceland and the contemporary ‘discourse’, the ‘dominant change actor’ (the political party the Best Party) could invoked a range of participatory tools that became implemented and (normatively) institutionalized. KEYWORDS: Political participation, institutional change, ICT, democratic innovations, 2 Introduction Democratic innovations have a tendency to be short-lived, and/or ad-hoc islands of participation with little or none formal connection to the policy and decision-making process (Gießel & Joas 2013; Geissel & Newton 2012; Grönlund, Bächtiger & Setälä 2014; Saward 2000; Smith 2009; Åström, Granberg & Khakee 2011). So far, most democratic innovations have been considered to be alien to the representative repertoire and therefore applied only as experiments within the framework of representative democracy. Often democratic innovations are initiated by one administration just to be dissolved by the next administration, created adhoc to deal with a specific issue, or, most often, as experiments in local governments. Some innovations do, however, live on, and among these we find the participatory budgeting in Porte Allegre and the Bundestag e-petition system. Some innovations thus become more or less institutionalized. This article will focus on two examples of the latter; Better Reykjavik and Better Neighborhood. The umbrella term ‘democratic innovation’ has recently received a lot of scholarly attention. The concept have been discussed in the literature since the early 2000’s (Saward 2000) but has, arguably, flourished in the later part of the 2000’s and early 2010’s (e.g. Smith 2009; Geissel & Newton 2012; Grönlund et al 2014). There is no single agreed-upon definition to the concept, but I will argue that it is suitable to apply Kenneth Newton’s (2012) general description of democratic innovations as “the successful implementation of a new idea that is intended to change the structures or processes of democratic government and politics by improving them” (p. 4). The main reason why Newton’s definition is suitable is the focus on implementation and institutional change. Most other definitions focus more on the connection between government and citizens, but do to a large extent leave the need for actual implementation aside. While the literature on citizen participation and deliberative democracy to a large extent has been focusing on non-institutionalized forms of politics, democratic innovations is more clearly leaning towards the creation and functions of institutions. Despite the focus on institutions, the connection to the literature on ‘new institutionalism’ is rather weak. One reason to this de-linking might be that, as noticed above, democratic innovations, so far, has tended to be short-lived and not fully implemented within the governmental structure. With the current wave, in which democratic innovations has started to leave the experimental stage and are implemented and applied in real political events, there is a need to consult the 3 institutionalism literature to better understand the processes that leads to the sustainable implementation of democratic innovations. The case of democratic innovations in Reykjavik in Iceland started with the launch of the participatory online platform Shadow City (Skuggaborg), which later turned into ‘Better Reykjavik’ (Betri Reykjavik) in the mist of the financial and political crisis that hit Iceland in the fall of 2008. Iceland was, up until then, considered to be a grand example of how to successfully transform an economy mainly based on the fishing industry to an economy based on financial products. Only a few years before the collapse, scholars and politicians had unison praised the de-regulation of financial markets, the liberalization of financial regulations and the growing financial industry. And Iceland was indeed a success story with low unemployment and strong economic growth with averaging 3-4% annually since the mid1990s. The world was witnessing was the “miracle on Iceland” (Gissurarsson 2004). In a few days in September 2008, however, the miracle turned into a financial and political nightmare. The collapse of the three major banks created not only a situation of economic crisis for individual citizens, companies and government agencies, but also a deep and broad sense of frustration and antipathy against the established political and financial system. In January 2009, thousands of citizens gathered in what has been labeled as the ‘pots-and-pansrevolution’ (Hardarson & Kristinsson 2011), ending with the toppling of the government and the election of the first Social Democratic government in the history of Iceland. The legitimacy of the political system was eroding and in an opinion poll in 2011, only one in ten Icelanders expressed ‘great trust’ in parliament (survey cited in Gylfason 2012). As a response to the crisis and the protests, the Icelandic political establishment turned their attention to a number of solutions, whom all had a common focus: the deepening of citizen participation. Among these solutions we find the online crowdsourcing of the new constitution (Gylfason 2012, Landemore 2014, Castells 2012, Åström et al 2013), the two referendums in 2010 and 2011 on foreign debt which are “the only known direct democratic votes on sovereign debt resettlement in history” (Curtis, Jupille & Leblang 2014), and on local level in the capital Reykjavik the rise of the citizen initiative system called Better Reykjavik (Åström et al 2013). Some scholars argue that this supposedly ‘participatory turn’ on national level has not endured. On the contrary, politics on national level has started to find its way back to ‘politics as usual’ (Bergmann 2014). Yet, the development on local level in the capital Reykjavik has been steady towards more participatory politics, and the most interesting part is therefore not the participatory response to the crisis in itself, but the ongoing day-to-day work that has put 4 participatory institutions in the heart of local government. Before the local elections in 2010, the city of Reykjavik had no digital platform for citizen participation, and now, after the 2014 local elections, there are two digital platforms (Better Reykjavik and Better Neighborhoods) and also a formalized committee for issues concerning citizen participation and democracy (Committee for Democracy and Administration). This development and implementation of democratic innovations are rather rare. Usually, democratic innovations are introduced with an experimental approach and platforms and processes can therefore fairly easy be invoked in times of systemic stress, and then later discarded when the issue or problem has blown over or, for the time being, been solved. To discard such innovations can often be done without much resistance from the administration, nor the citizens, since they are not a part of the institutional framework. But what happens if democratic innovations, on the contrary, is initially introduced and framed as being an additional and continual part of the institutional framework? And what role does the characteristics of the political context, the characteristics of the institution, and the type of dominant change-agent have in the implementation of such innovations? And what are the driving forces for developing the democratic innovations, once they are in place? This article aims to answers those questions. The article is structured as follows: firstly, a discussion on the theoretical background and previous research will be conducted. Secondly, the choice of method and data will be discussed, and the research questions presented. Thirdly, a short description of politics in Iceland will follow. Fourthly, the data will be presented and discussed. The article will end with a discussion on how to understand the implementation of the democratic innovations and what type of institutional change that has been occurring in Reykjavik. Since this is an early draft, there will be sections that are not finalized at this stage, and I therefore appreciate all possible feedback at this stage. Democratic Innovations and Political Institutions The roots of the literature on democratic innovations are found in the traditions of participatory and deliberative democracy. Founded on the theoretical and empirical finding in these two fields, the concept of democratic innovations is bridging the traditional separation in the fields by “indicate how deliberation (as realized through a combination of inclusiveness, considered judgment and publicity) might be embedded in participatory 5 institutions that have significant decision-making powers (realise popular control)” (Smith 2009, p. 197). The tradition within both participatory democracy and deliberative democracy is either purely theoretical or focusing on politics outside the established institutions. The same patterns can be found in the literature on online deliberation, where there has been more focus on deliberation per se, than on the connection between public deliberation and the policymaking process (Jonsson & Åström 2014). It has thus, for a long time, been a lot of focus on deliberation and participation per se and outside the political institutions, and less, or no, focus on the relationship between deliberation, participation and institutions in action. In recent years, however, a more holistic ‘systemic perspective’ has been discussed in the literature (Mansbridge et al 2012; Warren 2012). The systemic perspective acknowledges that the democratic innovations has begun to move from the drawing to become real world political institutions and applied ad hoc in political events. When analyzing, and understanding, democratic innovations as parts of a democratic system and with different functions in the system, the role of political institutions become vital. Understanding Gradual Institutional Change Institutions do matter in the study of politics. Over the last three decades, the development of institutional theory has been vast and it is now common to label at least three main perspectives as the ‘new institutionalism’: rational choice institutionalism (RI), historical institutionalism (HI) and sociological institutionalism (SI). More recently an additional approach, discursive institutionalism (DI) has been discussed in the literature. In this section, I will present and discuss these four forms of institutionalism, and also present the theoretical framework that will be applied in this study. Since the institutional perspective in political science is both wide and deep, it is impossible to cover the whole history of the approach in a few sentences. It is, however, important to present and discuss the core ideas with each approach, since the model I will apply in this article borrows elements from three of the main approaches; historical, sociological and discursive institutionalism. The model I will apply in this article - Mahoney and Thelens framework of gradual institutional change - borrow elements from all three of the main approaches (historical, sociological and rational institutionalism). 6 In this paper, I will apply a modified version of Mahoney and Thelen’s (2010) framework of gradual institutional change. The framework is mainly based on insights from historical institutionalism1, and consists of three core independent variables; characteristics of political context, characteristics of political institutions, and dominant change-agents. To briefly present what these three variables consists of; the characteristics of political context focuses on veto possibilities among the actors; the characteristics of institutions focuses on the level of discretion in interpretation/enforcement afforded to the actors; and the dominant changeagent are divided into four categories: insurrectionists, symbionts, subversives and opportunists (p. 18-29). These three variables are interconnected through what Mahoney and Thelen call ‘links’. Through these links, the dependent variable, modes of institutional change, is affected. Four modes of institutional change is presented; displacement (the removal of existing rules and introduction of new ones), layering (the introduction of new rules on the top of or alongside existing ones), drift (the changed impact of existing rules due to shifts in the environment), and conversion (the changed enactment of existing rules due to their strategic redeployment) (2010, p. 15-16) Figure 1. Framework for Explaining Modes of Institutional Change Characteristics of Political context III Type of dominant Change-agent II Type of Institutional Change Characteristics Of Institution I Note: Adopted from Mahoney, James & Thelen, Kathleen (2010). 1 The authors are, however, specific to argue that ”our propositions can be explored with equal profit by sociological and rational-choice institutionalists” (p. 32). Thus, my addition of insights from DI and SI should be understood as an attempt to empirically test and, possibly, develop the framework. 7 This model is, however, not complete but needs to be developed and broaden. The conceptualization of ‘political context’ and ‘institutions’ are too narrow. There is a need to include the insights from Schmidt (2010) that: “The institutions of discursive institutionalism, however, are not the external rule-following structures of the three older institutionalisms that serve primarily as constraints on actors, whether as rationalist incentives, historical paths, or cultural frames. They are instead simultaneously constraining structures and enabling constructs of meaning, which are internal to ‘sentient’ (thinking and speaking) agents whose ‘background ideational abilities’ explain how they create and maintain institutions at the same time that their ‘foreground discursive abilities’ enable them to communicate critically about those institutions, to change (or maintain) them (Schmidt, 2008).” (p. 4). There is, thus, more than the veto possibilities and possibilities to discretion that is vital to endogenous change. Democratic Innovations: Design and Functions The design of democratic platforms has been scrutinized in the literature (Rose & Sæbø 2010). Departing from Dalton, Scarrow and Cain (2003) categorization, it is possible to distinguish three models of transformative reforms: representative democracy (reforms that seeks to improve electoral processes with electoral adjustments), direct democracy (reforms that seeks to bypass, or complement, the processes of representative democracy, e.g. referendums) and, advocacy democracy (reforms that seeks to allow citizens participate in policy deliberation and formation, yet leaves the final decisions to the elites) (2010, p. 126). While most current democratic innovations are advocacy reforms, the innovations in Reykjavik are mixed. While BR is a typical example of an advocacy reform, BN is a hybrid case that ought to be labeled semi-direct. Method, Data and Research Questions The study is based on interview data (N=8) with key stakeholders connected to the Better Reykjavik and the Better Neighborhoods in 2014, interview data from an initial round of interviews in 2012, and three workshops in which Better Reykjavik and Better Neighborhoods 8 has been the topic. Secondary, and complementary, data is taken from previous studies on the political culture and party structure of Iceland and Reykjavik. The interviews were conducted with a semi-structured approach. A common template questionnaire was used in all interviews, and a battery of follow-up questions was also applied. Since the interviewees had different relationships to the project, the questions had to be customized to their position and knowledge about the project. One of key features with a semi-structured approach is flexibility (Bryman 2008). This study would, of course, have possible to conduct by quantitative measures, such as a sensus survey among politicians and civil servants in Reykjavik. The reason why I choose semistructured interviews over a survey is connected to the fact that there exist little, or no, research combining the insights from applied democratic innovations and institutional theory. And, there are no previous studies on the case of Reykjavik. I therefore lack both previous research and knowledge about the case. From these grounds, I concluded that qualitative approach, using semi-structured interviews would be good to get as much information as possible out of the respondents, so that they would not be too narrowed into my frame. The article is based on one set of primary data and complemented by another set of secondary data in form of previous research. The primary data consists of interviews with key stakeholders. The interview data is gathered from an initial round of interviews in 2012, three workshops in which Better Reykjavik and Better Neighborhoods has been the topic, and a second round of deep interviews that were conducted in Reykjavik during one week in October 2014 by the author. The deep interviews lasted 50 – 70 minutes and were taped digitally and later transcribed into text. All interviews are anonymized and are in the text referred to as [Interviewee 1; Interviewee 2; and so on]. The secondary data is mainly gathered from the work of Kristjánsson (1996; 2004) and Kristinsson (2001) about party politics, and Bergmann (2014) about Icelandic political culture. The study aims to answers three research questions. The first question concerns the description of the implementation of the platforms. The second question concerns the institutional change, and how we can understand it. The third question aims to understand the driving forces for development within the government, and connect that to further research. 1) How did the BR and BN become implemented? [descriptive] 2) How can we understand the institutional change in Reykjavik? [analytic] 9 What role did the characteristics of the political context have? What role did the characteristics of the institution have? What type of dominant change-agent became essential? 3) What are the driving forces for developing the democratic innovations, once they are in place? [analytic] Characteristics of the Political Context in Iceland and Reykjavik To begin with, Iceland is a very small state with only 320,000 citizens. It is also very concentrated with 120,000 living in Reykjavik, and a total of 250,000 living within Reykjavik metropolitan area. It is thus a sparsely populated country outside the city area, with only smaller towns on the coasts. The size of the population matters to the understanding of Iceland, since much of the political history is characterized by strong local elites often connected to the fishing industry and politics. In this section I will, very briefly, present the history of Iceland with focus on the modern and contemporary history. I will then continue by presenting some previous research on the party structure in Iceland, and also some previous research on political culture. A few words on the general history The history and the use of history in politics are also of interest when painting the picture of the Icelandic context. As the first settlers came in 874 CE, the nation is rather young. The modern history is commonly referred to be starting in 1904 when Iceland was granted home rule, while still being under the Danish Crown. After the globally turbulent time of the Second World War, the citizens of Iceland were offered to have a referendum on independence from Denmark. The participation rate was high (98,6%) and the results can hardly be discussed: 99,5% voted for independence and 0,5% (or 377 citizens) voted against independence. On the 17th of June 1944, Icelanders celebrated its independence and Iceland was declared a republic. The Financial Crisis and the Local Election in 2010 10 In a few days in September 2008 Iceland turned into a financial and political chaos. The collapse of the three major banks created not only a situation of economic crisis for individual citizens, companies and government agencies, but also a deep and broad sense of frustration and antipathy against the established political and financial system. In January 2009, thousands of citizens gathered in what has been labeled as the ‘pots-and-pans-revolution’ (Hardarson & Kristinsson 2011), ending with the toppling of the government and the election of the first Social Democratic government in the history of Iceland. The legitimacy of the political system was eroding and in an opinion poll in 2011, only one in ten Icelanders expressed ‘great trust’ in parliament (survey cited in Gylfason 2012). As a response to the crisis and the protests, the Icelandic political establishment turned their attention to a number of solutions, whom all had a common focus: the deepening of citizen participation. Among these solutions we find the online crowdsourcing of the new constitution (Gylfason, Landemore, Castells, Jonsson et al), the two referendums in 2010 and 2011 on foreign debt which are “the only known direct democratic votes on sovereign debt resettlement in history” (Curtis, Jupille & Leblang 2014), and on local level in the capital Reykjavik the rise of the citizen initiative system called Better Reykjavik (Åström et al 2013). At the local level in Reykjavik, a parallel process started. In the Reykjavik City Elections, held in May 2010, the newly established political party, Best Party (Besti flokkurinn), that “started as a parody of the old parties” (Hardarson, & Kristinsson, 2011) and with a party leader that labeled himself ‘anarcho-surrealist’ (Gnarr 2014, p ix), received 34,7 per cent of the votes. With the two traditionally strongest parties, the Independence Party (Sjálfstæðisflokkurinn) and the Social Democratic Alliance (Samfylkingin) at 33,6 per cent and 19,1 per cent respectively, the Best Party was the winners. The Best Party then formed a coalition government with the Social Democratic Alliance. In the spring of 2014, the most recent local elections were held, this time without the Best Party that dissolved itself (due to its political beliefs that politics should not be an occupation). Sprung out of the Best Party, however, is Bright Furture (Björt framtíð)2, that got 15,6% of the votes, and could together with the Social Democratic Alliance (31,9%), the Left-Greens (8,3%) and the Pirate Party (5,9%) create a new coalition that is now in majority in Reykjavik. Despite the deviation from other European municipalities when it comes to the embracement of democratic innovations, Reykjavik is following the trend among industrialized democracies in terms of decline in electoral participation. In the period from 2 Björt framtíð is also, since 2013, represented in the national parliament. 11 1950 to 2005, the average rate was 87.7 percent, with lowest point at 81,9 percent. In the 2006 elections, the rate dropped to 78,7 percent, and with the 2010 elections to 73,4 percent (Eyþórsson & Kowalczyk 2013, p. 3). This trend seems to be steady, with the 2014 electoral participation rates at 66 percent. Characteristics of Political Institutions in Iceland Iceland is a representative democracy with a multiparty system. In this section I will present and discuss the party system in Iceland. The Party System There is a modern tradition that the Independence Party (Sjálfstæðisflokkurinn) and the Progressive Party (Framsóknarflokkurinn) rules in coalition. The rule of these parties was, however, broken in the aftermath of the financial and political crisis in 2009, when the Social Democratic Alliance became the biggest party. The rule of the Social Democrats did, however, become short, and in the 2013 national elections, the Independence Party and the Progressive party once again took office. Despite the central position of the political parties, and then especially the Independence Party and the Progressive Party that has been power holding parties for decades, the political parties in Iceland can be described as ”internally fragmented” and that they lack a ”clear ideological dividing lines between the parties” (Kristjánsson 1998, p. 154). Kristjánsson (2004) also notes “that the Icelandic version of ‘parliamentary government’ did not include any notion of rule by organized political parties. In nineteenth-century Iceland, ‘democracy’ implied direct national self-rule of the people, by the people and for the people.” (p. 163). In the 1970s, the political parties in Iceland were in crisis. There was a strong societal pressure on the parties and one major reform from that period is that the parties now have primaries. The reform was initiated to open up the democratic process by letting citizens vote for which candidates that should run. From the perspective of the political parties, the reform backfired in some sense, since it has led to that “individual politicians often perceive an antiparty position as beneficial to their political success, increasing their popularity among potential participants in an open primary by taking a stand for ‘the people’ and ‘democracy’ against the dictates of ‘the party bosses’” (Kristjánsson 1998, p. 158). 12 This had ended up in the conclusion that “[i]ncreasingly Icelandic political parties resemble umbrella organizations for individual politicians rather than highly disciplined organizations” (Kristjánsson 1998, p. 163). Even more importantly for this study is that “[p]arty representation at the local level in Iceland has always been weak” (Eyþórsson & Kowalczyk 2013, p 2). Yet in Reykjavik and the other bigger municipalities, ”the national parties have held almost all of the seats for decades.” The national politics thus “seem to have been well represented in Iceland’s largest municipalities, but to a much lesser extent in the smaller ones.” (ibid. 2). Dominant Change Agents and the Links to Institutional Change In this section, I will present and discuss the development and implementation of BR and BN in Reykjavik, departing from the interview data. The first part will focus on the implementation of BR and BN in local government. The second part will focus on the institutional barriers that have been identified in the literature as being obstacles to implement new institutions. The Implementation of Better Reykjavik and Better Neighborhoods Better Reykjavik (BR) and Better Neighborhoods (BN) are two different platforms that can be seen as two complementing channels for ICT-based political participation (in short two democratic innovations), in the City of Reykjavik. In this section I will focus on the initial shortly present both platforms and highlight their differences and similarities and how they are thought to complement each other. Better Reykjavik BR started out as a participatory online platform called Shadow City (Skuggaborg) by the non-profit organization (Citizens’ Foundation) in 2010. The main initial idea with the platform was to fill the gap between citizens and politicians and create an around the clock online channel for citizen participation [Interviewee 2]. It was then used as a platform for the political campaigns of the parties in the 2010 Reykjavik local elections. All political parties was invited to create an own page on the platform and collect ideas from the citizens and 13 initiate discussions. The platform was widely used, and it “was all over the news, and all the links and ideas that were being discussed in the society, left and right. We had tens of thousands of people interacting over a period of two weeks” [Interviewee 2]. BR, thus, became a hype. The design of BR is similar to a e-petition system, yet it differs in two aspects; it allows discussions both for and against the idea, and it is based on ‘votes’ rather than signatures. It is also important to call it an ‘initiative’ or ‘priority’ system rather than a ‘petition system’ according to the developers, since it does not deal with petitions, but with the priorities of the citizens. The system thus provides any registered citizen3 to post a new idea. When the idea is posted, it is open for every citizen to vote for or against the idea, and also to discuss the idea with other citizens. The platform is also integrated with some of the biggest social media platforms, so that participants can share and comment on the idea from their social media platform. After the elections, the newly formed coalition between the Best Party and the Social Democrats choose, in cooperation with the Citizens’ Foundation, to reconstruct and implement the platform in the local municipal system under the name Better Reykjavik, since the name Shadow City had negative connotations [Interviewee 5]. The decision to take in the platform was processed in a steering group consisting of politicians from the majority and civil servants. In line with Icelandic political culture, the minority did not participate in these meetings, following the ‘winner-takes-it-all’ mentality of ruling in the municipality [Interviewee 8]. The most pressing issue was how to implement the platform into the municipal body. Since Icelandic municipalities are obliged to communicate answers to citizens coming in with questions, suggestions or complaints, the implementation of a platform such as BR would increase the amount of work drastically. It was therefore vital to find an alternative way for the city to connect to BR. The solution that was decided upon was that the city would go into an agreement with the NGO, letting the NGO run the platform and deliver only some of the suggestions and ideas to the departments in city hall. “Originally we had the idea that we going to have a cooperation agreement between us, and that were our biggest mistake not to make that.” [Interviewee 2]. But days turned into weeks, and weeks turned into months, and then more than one year had passed. The contract was still being handled within the 3 There is no age limit to BR. School children as well as retired citizens can participate. 14 administration and in the end, the NGO and the City “settled down with something that looked like a contractor agreement” [Interviewee 2]. The institutional arrangement is rather unique. Each month, a project manager4 goes to the BR platform and collects the five most popular ideas for each department. These ideas are then presented and discussed within each department. The ideas are then handled as any other formal errand within the departments. When the decision is taken (implement or discard), a message is sent from the department to the project manager, whom communicate the result to the citizen whom initiated the idea. An idea, or priority, is thus not takin into consideration due to a set limit of votes or likes, but is taken into consideration in relation to the relative popularity to other ideas. The consequences of such a design is that a very popular idea can be discarded since that department already have filled their quota, while the opposite, i.e. that a very unpopular idea might be taken into the department since there is no competition that month to a particular department. Thus far, however, there exists no case in which a very popular idea has been discarded, while the opposite has happened a lot and almost become a problem, since civil servants at the departments must take on a formal process to an errand with maybe less than three votes [Interviewee 4]. Better Neighborhoods One year later, in 2011, the BN project started as a complementary process to BR with focus on the improvement of neighborhoods. While BR is characterized by bottom-up participation with little structure, BN is a formally structured process with four (?) stages. The first stage is taken in October each year when the mayor holds a press conference and thereby officially opens the collection of ideas from the citizens in each neighborhood in Reykjavik. This collection phase is open for all citizens residing in the designated neighborhood to participate, and the platform on which these ideas are collected, is open for one month. The second stage is that all ideas and suggestions are scrutinized by a local committee and the local committee than selects the best ideas for elections. In the third stage, the selected ideas presented for the citizens in the neighborhoods and every citizen have a possibility to participate and elect ideas within the framework of the budget (at 300 000 000 million ISK per year, equals approx. 1,944,800 Euro). Citizens then design their own list of priorities within the framework of the budget and then ‘vote’ on this list of things that should be done. 4 The job as a ’Project Manager’ was created with the implementation of BR. In the first two years, 2010-2012, the position was half-time. Since 2013, the position is a full-time employment. 15 Since the beginning in 2011, there have been three elections within BN. Electoral participation has been 6%, 7%, and 8%. These low rates of participation have been met with mixed responses. While some civil servants and the NGO consider it to be at the same level as other similar processes in other states [Interviewee 1; Interviewee 2], mainly politicians consider it to be a problem with such low figures [Interviewee 3]. One of the ideas expressed is that in the coming years have one or two bigger projects instead of a large number of smaller projects [Interviewee 1; Interviewee 2]. Institutional change To sum up, the change that has been occurring in Reykjavik is that the two platforms BR and BN has been implemented into the system and that the Committee for Administration and Democracy has been created. Figure 1 below illustrates this development. Figure 1. Institutional Change in the City of Reykjavik 2010-2014. 16 Institutional Barriers in Reykjavik To change or add an institutional feature to be more participatory or citizens-oriented into the established representative framework often meet resistance in some form. From a normative political point of view this is understandable, since the representative model is built upon a rationalistic ideal in which the experts (i.e. politicians and civil servants) should rule on their mandate of the citizens, for the common good. When participatory features is involved into the policy making process, the idea of rationality becomes threatened and also the idea of representation, so the argument goes. In this part, I will focus on the interview data specifically dealing with these questions. There are four main issues that will be dealt with ’is BR and BN a threat to actors in the institutions’, ‘struggles within administration’, ‘legal barriers’ and ‘perception of public opinion’. Is BR and BN a Threat to Actors in the Institutions? Since the institutional structure in representative democracies are based upon political parties, there is often a resistance among political parties to embrace participation coming from outside the party system. Following the basic argument in Arnstein’s (1969) ‘ladder of citizen participation’, participation can range from ‘manipulation’ of the citizens to ‘citizens control’, the reason for established actors (political parties and civil servants) to see new innovations as a threat is highly depending on what rung such new innovation ends up. Departing from the description above, it can be argued that the party system in Iceland is rather weak and vulnerable, lacking a strong foundation in mass-movements. They would therefore, assumedly, see platforms such as BR and BN as a threat, since they cannot control what happens on these platforms. Somewhat surprisingly, none of the interviewees considered BR or BN as a threat to either the administration, nor to the political parties. When answering the question, all of the respondents have different answers, yet they all lean in the same direction. Struggles within administration After the local elections in 2010, and the entrance of the new coalition, one of the first actions was to negotiate and formalize a link between Better Reykjavik and the administration. According to the interview data, the implementation of the BR platform can be said to have 17 been a “smooth sailing” [Interviewee 1]. There haven’t been any major struggles within the administration, and BR has been seen as a positive innovation. Yet, there has been some tension within the administration, concerning epistemic issues such as expert knowledge versus collective knowledge; increased workload for some branches, and how to view the suggestions coming in via the system. In this section I will present and discuss these issues. A first, and general answer, to the question “has there been any struggles within the administration concerning BR and BN?” was; “no, not really” [Interviewee 1; Interviewee 4; Interview 8]. On the contrary, there seems be a general unitedness among civil servants that BR and BN are good ideas that everyone seems to support. This is similar to the results of the previous round of focus-group interviews conducted in 2012 (Åström et al 2013). Legal barriers In the interview with a representative from the NGO, the BR had great support from both the political majority and the bureaucracy. Yet, “there was some invisible bureaucratic obstacles, that were sort of in the system” [Interviewee 2] that hindered the implementation of the platform. When looking closer into these ‘invisible bureaucratic obstacles’, it becomes obvious that the current regulative framework is important to the problems. The framework in Reykjavik states that every formal question, idea or suggestion that comes into City Hall should be processed and answered by the department in question. Perception of Public Opinion There seems to be a general feeling among the stakeholders that citizens are becoming dissatisfied with various parts of BR and BN. The transparency of the system once the idea is brought into the departments are one of these issues. One description that occurs in one way or another in at least half of the interviews is that citizens are becoming more and more skeptical to the process of BR, due to the lack of transparency of the process. If a citizen creates a suggestion and aggregate a lot of support for the issue, the issue is taken in to the responsible department and then, maybe half a year later, the citizen get a mail back from the department saying that the suggestion was “accepted” or “declined” [Interviewee 2; Interviewee 3; Interviewee 8]. This creates a problem, since the citizens cannot follow the discussion on why or how the decision was taken. The minority politician argues that citizens have been starting to ask the question: “is it not in the end the 18 politicians and the people in the administration that have the last saying? Are we just being fooled?” and continues, “That is pretty much the feeling that you get.” [Interviewee 3] Another theme that many of the interviewees comes back to is that citizens seems to mix up BR and BN, and also think that both platforms deal with small things like playgrounds and benches in downtown areas [Interviewee 1;2;3;4;5]. Since no thorough evaluation has yet been done on BR or BN, the interpretations among politicians and civil servants differs. The Type of Institutional Change in Reykjavik Following the modified model originally developed by Mahoney and Thelen, there are three independent variables that are supposed to explain change in the dependent variable. Departing from the presentation and discussions on the interview data above, it is possible to see some general patterns in the case of institutional change in Reykjavik. First of all, the political context in which BR is developed and implemented is rather extreme. While the established political system is shaking, a platform for participation created in the public sphere becomes one of the central arenas for discussing politics during the local elections in 2010. Since it didn’t exist any digital platform for citizen participation before the elections, and no official platform after the elections (i.e. the new coalition did not create a new, own, platform, but did stick with the one already in place), there are strong reasons to assume that if BR had not been created at that moment in time, there would not have been a platform in place at all in the city of Reykjavik. In the earliest stages, BR had a solid function in the political system: it was a bottom-up platform for new ideas and discussions. Secondly, the political parties in Iceland are rather weak, and therefore more open for change. The electoral reform with primaries in the 1970’s opened up for a modern political culture in which the individual politician can actually benefit from distancing him/herself from the party organization. It is therefore not that difficult to understand that the political parties do not see BR and BN as a threat, but as a complement to ‘politics as usual’. Another dimension is the fact that both civil servants and politicians perceive the public opinion as regarding both BR and BN to deal with ‘small’ questions such as a playground or benches in downtown Reykjavik. Since no survey data is available, it is not possible to determine whether this is true or false, yet, that does not really matter in this context since what are important is how civil servants and politicians perceive the public opinion, and not 19 what the actual public opinion is. If politicians and civil servants perceive that the public thinks that the platforms are about small things, then it is totally rational to not see as a threat. To take the parallel to national level in Iceland makes the picture more clear: in the case of the new constitution, the democratic innovation (crowdsourcing) was a real threat to whole established political system, and the whole process challenged the legitimacy of the established actors (the political parties, the experts and the economic elite). In that case, the whole process was blown off, despite the fact that it ended up in a national referendum. Thirdly, the dominant change-actors ought to explain a lot of the institutional change in this case. The emergence of the ‘Best Party’ and the persistent work to implement BR and BN into the institutional arrangement, of course, explains the initial phase of the implementation process. If the Best Party wouldn’t have become the biggest party in the 2010’s elections, BR would, most probably, not have been implemented. To understand the persistence of the innovations, and the will to development among key stakeholders, there is a need to see how the three independent variables interact with each other. If the Best Party, being a newcomer with barely any ‘institutional capital’ or experience from the political world, would have forced BR and BN into a rigid and inflexible organization, in a political context that still had confidence in the ruling of established political parties, both BR and BN, I’ll argue, would have been dissolved by the new majority. This did, however, not happen. It is therefore reasonable to interpret the survival of the BR and BN as a token that there has been a gradual (however small) change within the institutions. Returning to the analytical framework, it is probably most appropriate to interpret the type of change as a combination of layering (i.e. the introduction of new rules on top or alongside existing rules), and a form of conversion (i.e. the changed enactment of existing rules due to their strategic redeployment). Since both BR and BN has been added to the institutional arrangement and thus not replacing any existing institution, and due to the fact that few practices, policies or laws have been changed in (e.g. how to handle citizen suggestions, or how the departments should communicate the discussions to the public), I argue that it is reasonable to argue for such a type of institutional change. One of the most worn-out citations in research dealing with political change in some form is probably Victor Hugo’s “nothing is more powerful than an idea whose time has come”. In almost all cases, the quote, I argue, is a misfit since it most I applied in a strong normative manner, thus that the author wants the time to be right. Yet, usually the analysis shows that the time for the idea has not come. In the case of Reykjavik, however, it seems to be the case 20 that the idea of citizen participation did strike at exactly the right moment and that the two forms of institutions, that Roland (2004) has called ‘slow-moving’ and ‘fast-moving’ institutions, crossed paths with a particularly good timing. Conclusions This study set out to explain the institutional changes and the implementation of democratic innovations in Reykjavik. The analysis shows that when the Icelandic political system was hit by an exogenous chock (the financial crisis), a ‘window of opportunity’ opened up. Due to the weak party institutions in Iceland and the contemporary ‘discourse’, the ‘dominant change actor’ (the political party the Best Party) could invoked a range of participatory tools that became implemented and (normatively) institutionalized. References Arnstein, S. R., 1969. A Ladder of Citizen Participation. JAIP, 35(4), pp. 216-224. Bergmann, Eirikur. 2014. Iceland and the International Financial Crisis – Boom, Bust and Recovery. Palgrave Macmillan, Hampshire, UK. Bryman, Alan. 2008. Social Research Methods. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Castells, Manuel. 2012. Networks of outrage and hope: Social movements in the Internet Age. Cambridge, UK: Polity Press. Curtis, K. Amber; Jupille, Joseph & Leblang, David. 2014. Iceland on the Rocks: The Mass Political Economy of Sovereign Debt Resettlement. International Organization, 68, pp 721-740 Dalton, Russell J; Scarrow, Susan E. & Cain, Bruce E. 2010. Advanced Democracies And The New Politics. Journal of Democracy Volume 15, Number 1, January 2004. Eyþórsson, Grétar Þór & Kowalczyk, Marcin. 2013. Explaining the low voter turnout in Iceland’s 2010 local government elections. Samtíð 1 (2013), 2. http://dx.doi.org/10.12742/ samtid.2013.2 Geissel, Brigitte & Newton, Kenneth (eds.). 2012. Evaluating Democratic Innovations – Curing the democratic malaise? Routledge, Oxon, UK. Geißel, Brigitte & Joas, Mark. 2013. Participatory Democratic Innovations in Europe – Improving the Quality of Democracy? Barabara Budrich Publishers, Leverkusen Opladen, Germany. 21 Gissurarsson, H. 2004. Miracle on Iceland. The Wall Street Journal Online, 29th January 2004. Website: http://courses.wcupa.edu/rbove/eco343/040compecon/Scand/Iceland/040129prosper.htm (Accessed: 2014-09-17). Gnarr, Jón. 2014. Gnarr – How I Became the Mayor of a Large City in Iceland and Changed the World. Melville House, New York, USA. Grönlund, Kimmo; Bächtiger, André & Setälä, Maija (eds.). 2014. Deliberative mini-publics – Involving citizens in the democratic process. ECPR Studies in European Political Science. Gylfason, T. 2012. From Collapse to Constitution: The Case of Iceland. Cesifo Working Paper, No. 3770. Munich: Cesifo. Hardarson, Ó., & Kristinsson, G. H. (2011). Iceland. European Journal of Political Research, 50(7-8): 1002-1003. Kristjánsson, Svanur. 1998. Electoral Politics and Governance: Transforming of the Party System in Iceland, 1970-96. In, Pennings, Paul & Lane, Jan-Erik (Eds.). 1998. Comparing party system change. Routledge. London, UK. Kristjánsson, Svanur. 2004. Iceland: Searching for Democracy along Three Dimensions of Citizen Control. Scandinavian Political Studies, 27(2): 153-174. Landemore, Hélène. 2014. Inclusive Constitution-Making: The Icelandic Experiment. The Journal of Political Philosophy. Mahoney, James & Thelen, Kathleen. 2010. A Theory of Gradual Institutional Change, in Mahoney, James & Thelen, Kathleen (eds.). 2010. Explaining Institutional Change – Ambiguity, Agency and Power. Cambridge University Press Mansbridge, Jane; Bohman, James; Chambers, Simone; Christiano, Thomas; Fung, Archon; Parkinson, John; Thompson, Dennis F. & Warren, Mark E. 2012. A Systemic Approach to Deliberative Democracy, in Parkinson, John & Mansbridge, Jane (eds.) Deliberative Systems. Cambridge University Press, New York, USA. Pappas, Takis S. & O'Malley, Eoin. 2014. Civil Compliance and ''Political Luddism'': Explaining Variance in Social Unrest During Crisis in Ireland and Greece. American Behavioral Scientist published online 23 May 2014. Roland, Gerard. 2004. Understanding Institutional Change: Fast-Moving and Slow-Moving Institutions. Studies in Comparative International Development, Winter 2004. Rose, Jeremy & Sæbø, Øystein. 2010. Designing Deliberation Systems. The Information Society, 26:3, 228-240 Saward, Micheal (ed.). 2000. Democratic Innovation – Deliberation, representation and association. Routledge/ECPR Studies in European Political Science. London, UK. Schmidt, Vivien A. 2010. Taking ideas and discourse seriously: explaining change through discursive institutionalismas the fourth ‘new institutionalism’. European Political Science Review (2010), 2:1, 1–25 & European Consortium for Political Research. 22 Warren, Mark E. 2012. When, Where and Why Do We Need Deliberation,Voting, and Other Means of Organizing Democracy? A Problem-Based Approach to Democratic Systems. Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, August 30 - September 2, 2012. Åström, Joachim; Granberg, Mikael & Khakee, Abdul. 2011. Apple Pie – Spinach Metaphor: Shall Edemocracy Make Participatory Planning More Wholesome? Planning Practice and Research, 26:5, 571-586. Åström, Joachim; Hinsberg, Hille; Jonsson, Magnus E. & Karlsson, Martin. 2013. Crisis, Innovation and e-Participation: Towards a Framework for Comparative Research, in Wimmer, Maria A.; Tambouris, Efthimios & Macintosh, Ann. (eds.) Electronic Participation - 5th IFIP WG 8.5 International Conference, ePart 2013, Koblenz, Germany, September 17-19, 2013. Proceedings. Springer 23