Keynesian Historiography and the Anti-Semitism Question E. Roy Weintraub1 “By ‘anti-Semitism’, I understand, first, beliefs about Jews or Jewish projects that are both false and hostile, and secondly, the injurious things said to or about Jews or their projects, or done to them, in consequence of those beliefs.” (Julius 2010, 65) Historians’ treatment of John Maynard Keynes’s putative anti-Semitism raises complex historiographic issues. These differ from such questions as whether Carl Jung’s or Paul de Man’s standing as charismatic intellectual leaders of communities engaged in new ways of thinking and acting was associated in some way with their anti-Semitic writings2. In contrast, as Professor of Economics and Fellow, Center for the History of Political Economy, Duke University, Durham NC 27708-0097. In the several years of this paper’s development, I have received a large number of very useful comments and criticisms from various individuals. With memory’s failures and tricks, I recall only Duke’s Neil DeMarchi, Gianni Toniolo, Pedro Duarte, Bruce Caldwell, Kevin Hoover, Craufurd Goodwin, Malachi Hacohen, Julie Mell, Barbara Herrnstein Smith, and Frank Lentriccia, and virtual colleagues Roger Backhouse, Mary Morgan, Yann Giraud, and Tiago Mata. I am pleased to acknowledge the generosity of Lord Skidelsky in permitting me to quote from his correspondence with Don Patinkin. Two anonymous referees for HOPE were of great help at the end-stage of this paper’s progress, and I took their excellent suggestions, without assuming that they agreed with all my conclusions. Finally, I am pleased to acknowledge Maxine Borjon’s excellent assistance in preparing the manuscript. 1 For the Jung community, these matters were engaged in the conference, and conference volume, Lingering Shadows: Jungians, Freudians, and Anti-Semitism (Maidenbaum and Martin 1991); for the literary theory community, these issues were the subject of Responses: On Paul De Man’s Wartime Journalism (Hamacher et al. 1989). 2 Page 1 of 38 the charismatic intellectual leader of the “Keynesians”, Keynes has never3 been characterized as having created a system of thought that was anti-Semitic. Nevertheless the publication of Melvin W. Reder’s (2000) paper, “The Anti-Semitism of some Eminent Economists” opened up a related question, namely whether the term “ambivalent anti-Semitism” could be applied variously to John Maynard Keynes, Joseph Schumpeter, and Friedrich Hayek. That is, Reder argued that those three important economists expressed themselves in ways that today would be characterized as anti-Semitic. Although in their personal dealings each of these individuals had apparent positive regard for individual Jewish colleagues, and even friends (e.g. Keynes and Kahn), their utterances are characterized by what Reder called anti-Semitic stereotyping at least, and political anti-Semitic argumentation at worst. Reder used the neologism “ambivalent antiSemitism” to characterize Keynes’s views. I am not concerned here to appraise Reder’s argument about whether the label “antiSemitic”, whether “ambivalent” or not, is usefully attached to Keynes. I rather am concerned with the issue of how Keynesian historiography has dealt with the anti-Semitism question. That is, I am concerned with the role that Keynes’s attitudes and remarks about both individual Jews, and “the Jews”, has played out in Keynesian scholarship, and how the community of Keynes scholars has treated the allegation that Keynes was anti-Semitic. Recognizing the Keynes Anti-Semitism Problem To introduce the concerns of this paper, consider an exchange of letters between Robert Skidelsky, Keynes’s biographer then at work on Volume Two (Skidelsky 1992) of the eventual 3 But see the discussion of David Felix, below. Page 2 of 38 three volume work, and the economist Don Patinkin, who also had written extensively on Keynes’s General Theory. In a letter to Skidelsky dated 22 July 19874, Patinkin raised the following point: There is an observation that came to my mind when I reread his (Keynes’) ‘Economic Possibilities for our Grandchildren’ . . . which reminded me of a similar—though less explicit—sentence in Volume 1 of the Treatise [on Money] (page 11) about ‘the Semitic race is etc.’ These references probably reflect the genteel antiSemitism of the British upper middleclass. But his hitherto unpublished essay on Albert Einstein is a disgusting piece of coarse anti-Semitism of the street. (I once told Donald Moggridge that he should not have published it; but Moggridge said [that] Keynes could have destroyed it, but left it in his papers—so he meant it to be published. Maybe Moggridge was right.) . . . I think that this is a subject that you must also treat in your biography, and I hope that you will overcome any inhibitions that you might have on that score. In Volume 1 you made it very clear that in order to understand Keynes, one must also discuss his homosexualism [sic]. I think the same is true for his anti-Semitism. Patinkin appears to have worried about this matter, and after a few years he wrote again to Skidelsky (May 4, 1992)5, pointing to Keynes’s sentence “‘Perhaps it is not an accident that the race which did most to bring the promise of immortality into the heart and essence of our 4 5 Patinkin Papers, Box 66, file folder “Skidelsky”. Patinkin Papers, Box 61, file folder “Skidelsky” Page 3 of 38 religions has also done most for the principle of compound interest and particularly loves this most purposive of human institutions (JMK, IX, 330))’. That, to me, is an anti-Semitic remark.” As noted, Patinkin was upset by Keynes’s remarks on Einstein penned for the New Statesmen and Nation, 21 October 1933, which piece referred to Einstein as a “Jew boy” and which went on to say “Yet Albert and the blond beast make up the world between them. If either cast the other out, life is diminished in its force. When the barbarians destroyed the ancient race as witches . . .”6 Skidelsky replied7 to Patinkin on 5 June 1994: I would have thought that Keynes is simply saying that the world needs both the impersonal intellect and the community spirit, though the way he identifies these things with the Jews and the Nazis respectively, was part of the atmosphere of the early 1930s. Nowadays we would obviously see Nazism as a perversion of community feeling, not as its somewhat unbridled expression, but this was very early days. On June 20, 1994 Patinkin replied8 if your interpretation of Keynes’s New Statesmen article is correct, then it is really scandalous for by October 1933, the dictatorial and violently anti-Semitic nature of the Nazi regime was evident for all to see. After all, why had Einstein left Germany for England? Patinkin also must have queried Einstein’s biographer, physicist Abraham Pais, on Keynes’s Einstein remarks, for Pais replied (ibid.) to him on May 24, 1994 that those remarks “do not strike me as anti-Semitic. The use of `Jew Boy’ was very common in England that time, as you no doubt know.” 7 ibid. 8 ibid. 6 Page 4 of 38 Was that an expression of ‘community spirit’? So I think this article is even worse than Keynes’s morally insensitive preface to the German edition of the General Theory. Skidelsky’s reply9 on 11 July, 1994 was that I think you’ve got it out of perspective. To try to understand something is not to excuse it . . . [W]hether his understanding of the historical role of the Jews was defective is another matter. He thought about them in a stereotypical way, but it was very abstract. . . but, as I say, such theological fancies did not influence his personal conduct or reaction to the actual events in Germany. Nothing would be more sterile, in my view, than to start a “was Keynes anti-Semitic?” debate. There would probably be plenty of takers (there always are), but anything less important for the appraisal of his work can scarcely be imagined. Patinkin insisted on having the last word. On 18 August 1994 he wrote10 to Skidelsky I have little doubt that Keynes shared the anti-Semitic attitude of his upper middleclass English milieu as well as that turn-of-thecentury (and later!) Cambridge. . . but what should we do with the kind of expressions `Jew boy . . . [who] has had his bottom many times kicked, and expects it’ and similar ones in his unpublished piece on Einstein (JMK12, pages 382-84)? That’s anti-Semitism of the gutter. On the other hand, there were his close relations with 9 ibid. ibid. 10 Page 5 of 38 Richard Kahn and the warmth of his two concluding paragraphs in his essay on Melchior. . . . I certainly have no thought of starting a ‘was Keynes anti-Semitic’ debate. Skidelsky (2003) readdressed these matters when he revised his three volume work to produce a one volume abridged version of the biography. In many ways a stronger narrative emerged as the later materials could be woven into the earlier chapters. In that new volume, Skidelsky addressed the anti-Semitism issue via examination of Keynes’s essay “Economic Possibilities for Our Grandchildren” which essay had contained Keynes’s remark about Jews and the principle of compound interest. Skidelsky wrote: [There] are a few other references to Jews in Keynes’s writings which would now be construed as anti-semitic. In A Short View of Russia he had doubted whether communism ‘makes Jews less avaricious’. After a visit to Berlin in June 1926, he depicted Germany as under the ‘ugly thumbs’ of its ‘impure Jews’, who had ‘sublimated immortality into compound interest’. This was for a talk to The Memoir Club, published only posthumously; it was his most prejudiced utterance on the subject, but it falls a long way short of the murderously flip remakes which even someone like Dennis Robertson was capable of making.11 (373-374) Skidelsky went on to say that 11 In (Skidelsky 1992) we find a note from Robertson to Keynes (p. 664, note 60) from August 30, 1929: “I ran into the Prof. [Pigou] and Tom Gaunt on the way to Zermatt, and also made acquaintance with the latter’s attractive negroid wife and her overdressed mama. They are a curious party. How hard it seems not to murder Jews.” Page 6 of 38 [Such] stereotyping of Jews was common in Keynes’s circle, and the stereotypes were usually unfavourable. Keynes’s letters are mercifully free from personal abuse – not so Lydia’s, or those of some Bloomsberries. Individual Jews were exempted by the devices of exceptionalism or non-recognition of their Jewishness. Thus was decency reconciled to prejudice. But the occasion for decency did not often arise. Although Virginia Woolf married a Jew12, and Sraffa and Wittgenstein were half-Jewish13, there were very few Jews in Keynes’s world in the 1920s…meanwhile, stereotyping could flourish, and there was no need to mind manners…Keynes’s own stereotyping took place on the philosophical, not vulgar, plane. (374) Skidelsky characterized Keynes’s views as grounded in the idea that Jews embodied the spirit of capitalism, which was associated with an abstract love of money. He argued that Keynes distinguished between pure or religious or intellectual Jews and money loving Jews. In this discussion Skidelsky noted a letter of complaint to Keynes by University of California Professor Max Raden about the Economic Possibilities essay, where Raden had told Keynes that not only was immortality unimportant theologically for Jews, but that Jews were not especially concerned with the accumulation of money. In his reply to Raden “Keynes apologized for having been thinking along ‘purely conventional lines’ (ibid.). But he was reluctant to give up his 12 I note, in passing, that Leonard Woolf (1935), at the time of the intense anti-Semitic campaign being waged in Hitler’s Germany, took up the issue of English anti-Semitism quite directly in Quack, Quack. That volume’s “Appendix: A Note on Anti-Semitism” (195-201) provides a quite contrasting Bloomsbury view to that of Keynes. 13 According to Hayek, his second cousin, Wittgenstein was in fact three-quarters Jewish. Page 7 of 38 fancy: ‘I still think that the race has shown itself, not merely for accidental reasons, more than normally interested in the accumulation of usury.’ This correspondence took place in the autumn of 1933.” (374) Skidelsky concluded this discussion by remarking “Keynes anti-Semitism, if such it was, was little more than a theological fancy: expression, perhaps, of some unresolved conflict about his own Non-Conformist roots. There is no evidence that it influenced his personal conduct.” (374-375) This is somewhat misleading. One hundred and fifty pages earlier in that 2003 volume Skidelsky addressed Keynes’s dealings with Klotz, the French finance minister at the Versailles conference. Skidelsky quotes Keynes writing that Klotz was “‘A short, plump, heavymoustached Jew, well-groomed, well kept, but with an unsteady roving eye, and his shoulders were a little bent with instinctive depreciation.’14 Klotz represented, to Keynes, the other face of France’s grasping sterility – a view not uninfluenced by the anti-semitism which was normal to his class and generation.” (222) Skidelsky then proceeded to quote from the Melchior essay15: Never have I seen the equal of the onslaught with which the poor man [Klotz] was overwhelmed [by Lloyd George who] had always hated and despised him; and now saw in a twinkling that he could kill him. Women and children were starving, he cried, and here was M. Klotz prating of his ‘goold’. He leaned forward and with a gesture of his hands indicated the image of a hideous Jew clutching a money bag. Skidelsky’s reference for this quote is in error – it does not appear in the volume of Keynes’s Collected Works where Skidelsky places it, but rather it appears in Keynes’s biographical essay on Melchior, namely page 422 of Collected Works: Volume X (not XVI). 15 This essay was eventually published by Rupert Hart-Davis in 1949 as Two Memoirs. In the Collected Works, editor Moggridge states that “it was certainly read before January 1932, and probably in the summer of 1931” (CWX, 387) to the Memoir Club. 14 Page 8 of 38 His eyes flashed and the words came out with a contempt so violent that he seemed almost to be spitting at him…Everyone looked at Klotz… the poor man was bent over his seat, visibly cowering. (223-224) What this passage in Skidelsky’s one volume biography leaves out, with ellipses, is more than some unnecessary words. The penultimate sentence is actually the third from the last, and what is missing is Keynes’s sentence “The anti-Semitism, not far below the surface in such an assemblage as that one, was up in the heart of everyone.” (422) And the last ellipsis of the quoted passage replaced the words “with a momentary contempt and hatred” (ibid). These edits should disturb attentive readers since the missing sentence and phrase lends credence to the idea, denied later in the one volume biography, that such anti-Semitism did influence Keynes’s personal conduct at least in this instance. The point of course is not whether Keynes was an anti-Semite, but rather how material related to such an allegation was treated by, in this case, Keynes’s primary biographer. With respect to his earlier biographer, Roy Harrod’s (1951) authorized The Life of John Maynard Keynes set out the limits of the discussion in the early postwar period. The question of Keynes’s attitude to Jews is untouched, nor was there any mention of Keynes’s bisexuality16. In the 1960s, Sir Roy Harrod was my parent’s houseguest for extended periods in each of several years as he came over to the US to teach summer school at the University of Pennsylvania. One evening at dinner, in my presence, the conversation turned to the then new Michael Holroyd biography of Lytton Strachey, which book revealed in print for the first time Keynes’s homosexual life before Lydia. My father, a Post Keynesian and a homophobe, said that he for one did not believe it, and moreover Harrod’s own biography made no mention of this issue. Harrod replied that his own book “suggested” it in several passages of obscure prose (e.g. “They [Strachey and Keynes] had certain affinities … (Harrod 1951, 90), and “It was Keynes’s great intimacy with Duncan Grant … (ibid., 131)) but that no one looking at the photograph of Maynard and Duncan Grant (ibid. cit., facing page 130) gazing into each other’s eyes could have missed the message. My father of course was appalled. My mother, embarrassed, left the room. 16 Page 9 of 38 Skidelsky’s Volume 1 (1986), and (especially) Moggridge’s full biography of 1992 dealt with the issue of homosexuality in more detail. The latter’s discussion of Keynes’s references to Jews is however somewhat sketchy. And other than the brief discussion of the issue by Mark Blaug (1994) in a joint review of Moggridge’s and Skidelsky’s books17, I have found nothing whatsoever about anti-Semitism in any article or book review written about Keynes by the hundreds of historians of economics engaged with Keynes and his writings. Lydia One of the difficulties of dealing with the question of Keynes and anti-Semitism is that almost all of the discussions of which I’m aware are based on various writings that have been produced through Moggridge’s production of Keynes’s thirty volume Collected Works for the Royal Economic Society. A number of the letters in the collected works have also been used, as well as some unpublished writings, as for example the bit on Einstein. One source that has not been employed however is a collection of letters, specifically letters between Maynard and Lydia Lopakova, first as they were courting, and later following their marriage, which appeared after the publication of the various volumes of Keynes’s Collected Works. These letters, produced for a wider audience than historians of economics, were edited and published by Polly Hill and Richard Keynes, Maynard’s and Lydia’s niece and nephew respectively. They are a separate window into the kinds of questions that might emerge in a discussion of Keynes and antiSemitism. That is, these letters were never meant for public view, and are a unique entree into Blaug there wrote (op. cit., 1213) that “These two biographies tell us much about Keynes that we never knew before: his mild anti-semitism, so typical of educated people in the interwar years (Skidelsky 1992, pp. 238- 39; Moggridge 1992, pp. 609, 728); his insensitivity about Hitler and indeed indifference to the Nazi experience (Skidelsky 1992, pp. 86- 88, 581).” 17 Page 10 of 38 the unguarded thoughts and expressions of these two individuals. There is however one matter that needs to be faced immediately. These letters are a sample from a very large number of letters between Maynard and Lydia, currently deposited in the library of King’s College, Cambridge. The letters that appear in this volume have been edited as the editors say for clarity and to eliminate stylistic grotesqueries. It is not just spelling that has been changed though, and the editors are forthright in their introduction about the process they used to perform the editing task. What they do not discuss however is the presence of material in these letters that may have been expurgated. That is, if there was truly inflammatory material in the letters, the editors have not given us information about whether they suppressed such material. Thus any discussion of the letters’ employment of various anti-Semitic tropes and expressions comes up quickly against the possibility that if what appears here in the letters is representative, there is certainly more material there to examine. If what appears here is not representative, but is in fact a cleansed sampling, it would behoove scholars to examine the entire cache of letters more closely. Moreover, these letters from 1918 through 1925 were apparently to have formed but one volume of several. But that project never continued as Polly Hill’s ill health, and subsequent death in 2005, foreclosed the possibility. And of course the larger collection of Lydia Lopokova’s correspondence and papers has not been examined in print by historians of economics18. That said, the letters provide evidence for Skidelsky’s assertion, noted above, about Lydia’s letters “[not] being mercifully free from personal abuse [of Jews].” Two examples, from 18 Those letters do, however provide a major documentary source for a recent biography of Lopokova by the dance critic and historian Judith Mackrell titled Bloomsbury Ballerina: Lydia Lopokova, Imperial Dancer and Mrs. John Maynard Keynes (2008). That volume takes on the issue of Lopokova’s anti-Semitism directly (pp. 350-351). Page 11 of 38 the eleven that could be brought forward, will suffice (page references are to (Hill and Keynes 1989): L to M, 25 October, 1923. “Do you like to hear quotations? ‘Jew: A man who kills two birds with one stone and then wants the stone back.’” (115); L to M, 9 February 1925. “Being a versatile business woman, I went to the Alhambra, watched NicolaevaLegat programme, their last dance is a Jewish one, Legat was magnificently dressed in everyday clothes with a long coat and a nose of Jewish dimension, the hooky one, almost aquiline and isn’t, I did my best with hands and voice, but it is uninspiring to be in an empty theatre.” (286) Such remarks suggest that these stereotypes about Jews were, for Maynard and Lydia, common and acceptable in private conversation. There was no hesitancy about characterizing someone as a Jew, and thereby creating a particular set of reader responses based on shared presuppositions about Jews and Jewish characteristics. There is no evidence that the letter writers considered such reader expectations to be objectionable on any grounds. It is difficult to know how Maynard’s and Lydia’s personal behaviors might have been affected, but certainly the Jew as other, other than “us”, is readily apparent here and cannot be entirely masked in more public performances. This, of course, is not the kind of anti-Semitism which calls for Jews to be excluded from England or English institutions, sent off to Africa, placed in concentration camps, or murdered, yet it does suggest that Maynard and Lydia shared a mindset that “Jews were different from us”, even if Lydia was hardly a typical Englishwoman. Without delving into questions requiring explanation, it simply suffices for our argument to note these references and Page 12 of 38 also note how they have never explicitly appeared in any of the various discussions about Keynes, nor in any reference to Keynes and anti-Semitism that have appeared previously. Enter Reder, et al. As noted above, despite Patinkin’s (and Skidelsky’s) wish not to start a debate about whether Keynes was an anti-Semite, Mel Reder (2000) did just that. Reder went through, in detail, a number of “Items” that served to make his points about Keynes’s anti-Semitism. He used the “Jew boy” references, as well as those to the “very gritty Jewish type”. Following Moggridge (1992), he noted Keynes’s remark to Lydia in 1933 that “[I] made my usual conversation about the Jews in the Combination Room last night” prior to signing a petition “in their favor”. In his 1926 sketch of Einstein, he wrote that “If I lived there [in Berlin], I felt I might turn anti-Semite. For the poor Prussian is too slow and heavy on his legs for the other kind of Jews, the ones who are not imps, but serving devils, with small horns, pitch forks, and oily tails. It is not agreeable to see a civilisation so under the ugly thumbs of its impure Jews who have all the money and the power and the brains.” And finally Reder shows that such remarks did not end with World War II. In 1945 Keynes writes about the British left’s complaints about Bretton Woods that (Reder 2000, 838) “the doctrine of non-discrimination does not commit us to abjure Schactian methods, which their Jewish economic advisers (who, like so many Jews, are either Nazi or Communist at heart and have no notion of how the British Commonwealth was founded or is sustained) were hankering after.19” A HOPE referee of this paper asked whether “Keynes would have been so nasty about Schactian methods if he had known that Schacht was then a prisoner at Dachau?” 19 Page 13 of 38 In a follow-up to his 2000 paper, in a reply to Hamowy’s criticism of his argument about Hayek, Reder (2002) referred to a paper he had recently seen in a well-known Indian weekly. There World Bank economist Anand Chandavarkar (2000), who earlier wrote a well-received book on Keynes and India (1985), addressed Keynes’s possible anti-Semitism directly. This article by Chandavarkar is a detailed and historically focused piece on Keynes’s possible antiSemitism. Besides a thorough examination of the Collected Works, he reprinted a letter sent to him by Isaiah Berlin dated 18 April 1994, which letter concluded [S]o you are basically right. Keynes did suffer from the prejudices and tastes of his milieu. He greatly admired, e.g., Lord Samuel, who served in various liberal administrations but nevertheless [Keynes] could certainly bring himself to crack some joke about [Samuel as a Jew] in what might be thought doubtful taste – but it was no more than that. (1623) Chandavarkar reprised all of the comments that Keynes made about Jews, but he brought forth one additional piece of material that had not previously been noted. Specifically, he discussed the fact that Keynes was “the only non-Jewish member of a high powered advisory committee under the chairmanship of Herbert Samuel (at Versailles) which prepared the preliminary draft report for presentation of the Zionist case for a Jewish national home in Palestine, for the peace conference in Paris on February 23, 1919. The other members of the committee were [Jews] Lionel Abrahams of the India office and James de Rothschild.” (1622) Chandavarkar noted that this committee prepared the ground for the Balfour Declaration, and its work was favorably discussed in Chaim Weizmann’s autobiography. Chandavarkar concluded his piece saying “in retrospect, Keynes’s anti-Semitism will be seen more as a peripheral fringe of an inherently Page 14 of 38 compassionate personality, an unamiable foible rather than a fatal flaw of character, a blind-spot which never blurred the totality of his social and political vision.” (1623). Chandavarkar’s use of the word “will” is performative, not simply predictive. Kaun and Paulovicova I have located only two other published papers on this particular subject, each published in journals unfamiliar to historians of economics. In the July 2000 issue of Midstream, economist David E. Kaun published “The Anti-Semitism of John Maynard Keynes.” Kaun’s argument developed from his Marxian perspective, claiming that “Keynes’s failure to take Marx’ economics seriously” is possibly associated with Keynes anti-Semitism. Leaving to one side Kaun’s own objectives, his own discussion of Keynes’s “temperament and class” was based on the claim that “[Keynes’] belief [was] that one’s material condition was determined by character rather than the reverse” and that anti-Semitism was inextricably associated with Keynes’s class. Reviewing the material that Skidelsky had earlier developed, Kaun stated that “[Skidelsky’s] examples suggest more the complexity of the man than the absence of anti-Semitism.” Kaun went on to argue that: [A] component of Keynes’s anti-Semitism did, like that of Marx, focus on the alleged trait of money grubbing. But Keynes is guilty of a much wider set of biases. These extend beyond the casual use of anti-Semitic slang, to a visceral hostility as evidenced in his assumption of deep-seated Jewish ethnic and character flaws. The Page 15 of 38 thoughts of an anti-Semite were manifest at an early age. (Kaun 2000, 6) With that opening salvo, Kaun went somewhat beyond Skidelsky noting that, as early as a seventeen-year old at Eton, Keynes had penned “in the West it is the individual that is all important, in the East the mass…[the Jews, as Eastern people, possess] deep-rooted instincts that are antagonistic and therefore repulsive to Europeans [and as such] they can no more be assimilated to European civilization than cats can be made to love dogs.” (Skidelsky 1983, 92) Kaun commented that, some twenty-two years after Eton, “…Keynes lamented the condition of Europe, still torn between liberalism and radicalism. Bolshevik radicalism flowed, Keynes wrote, from a ‘besotted idealism and an intellectual error out of the peculiar temperaments of Slavs and Jews.’” Kaun reprised Skidelsky’s observation that Keynes grew up in a household with German nannies, and as a result the household was generally pro-German. However Kaun’s stringing together various quotes scattered throughout Keynes’s Collected Works, and Skidelsky’s biography, directed attention to Keynes’s repeated comments about Jews and money grubbing. Kaun thus linked Keynes in some ways to Marx even as Kaun attempted to use Keynes’s antiSemitic attitudes to explain Keynes’s distaste for Marx. Unless we talk about the psychological mechanism of “splitting”, and provide a way to employ it sensibly in this argument, Kaun’s discussion is incoherent since Marx was contemptuous of exactly those characteristics of Jews that Keynes wrote about. Apparently as part of her larger study of anti-Semitism, a young historian at the University of Alberta, Nina Paulovicova (2008), wrote an article “The Immoral Moral Scientist: John Maynard Keynes” which appeared in the graduate student journal Past Imperfect. She there Page 16 of 38 attempted to show that earlier discussions of this subject had been historically thin, failing to locate Keynes properly in the several worlds in which he operated, and in which anti-Semitism took on various meanings and expressions. She stressed that scholars needed to pay a “great deal of attention to the question of ‘Who was generally defined as an anti-Semite in Keynes’s own societal milieu?’ rather than ‘Which qualities of current forms of anti-Semitism can be traced in Keynes’s worldview?’” (40) Her conclusion stands in real contrast to that of Reder say: “Keynes simply appropriated anti-Semitic clichés as one facet of a modus operandi in political circles. However, seeing himself as ‘immoral’, i.e. critical of generally accepted norms of his time, he naturally stood out as the defender of those that the society put down – hence his public philosemitism and his sympathy for the women’s movement. Offering a new lesson [with respect to antiSemitism] based on the Keynes case seems to be pointless” (55). There is though one suggestive story recounted by David Landes20 (1994) in his memorial notice for Abba Lerner in the Proceedings of the Natural Academy of Sciences. There Landes wrote: In a country that was not unready to appoint to a professorship in Oxbridge on the basis of a single article, Lerner should have been professor many times over. But his achievements were counterbalanced in British eyes by religious origin, dress, and manners: Abba Lerner, Jew from Eastern Europe and then the brick and grit of the East End, bare feet in Although this story was first published by Landes, “the story was told” to him by David Colander, and it appears a bit later in (Colander and Landreth 1996). 20 Page 17 of 38 sandals (because, he said, his feet sweat), unpressed trousers hanging, shirt collar open, was a hippie before his time. In some things he could be difficult; in others he was too permissive. He had a disconcerting way of saying what he thought. The would-be genteel folk of academe could not see him twirling a sherry glass and making small talk in wood-paneled common rooms. The story is told, based on unpublished letters21, that Professor Lionel Robbins of LSE consulted Keynes in this regard when a post opened at the London School. Lerner was an unavoidable candidate. Keynes Brit-wittily replied by referring to Lerner's origin as from the Continent. Maybe, he wrote, if they found a job for Lerner as a cobbler during the day, they might wear him out and have him teach in the evening. Lerner did not get the job. He probably continued to pay for his particularities when he moved to the other side of the Atlantic. At any rate, he did not receive a post at a major university until very late in his career. (212-213) This story does no credit to Keynes. Unlike Richard Kahn, or Leonard Woolf, Abba Lerner was not the kind of Oxbridge Jew likely to share Keynes’s interests. Even after Lerner came to Cambridge on a postgraduate scholarship in 1934-5, and he became a “Keynesian”, Keynes was unsupportive of his career. 21 Colander states that the letter, from Keynes to Robbins, was dated May 2, 1935. Page 18 of 38 Nevertheless even with their limitations, Kaun’s and Paulovicova’s papers are singular in their scholarly discussions of Keynes and anti-Semitism. In the Keynes historiography there is nothing comparable to Anthony Julius’s (1995) T. S. Eliot, Anti-Semitism, and Literary Form which opened the T. S. Eliot historiographic/interpretive canon to important details of Eliot’s anti-Semitism. Other Histories With respect to discussions of these matters in books, there are several examinations of Keynes’s anti-Semitism. In Keynes and Population, John Toye (2000) examines all of Keynes’s writings and opinions on matters of population, and is thus well-prepared to explore the eugenicist and racialist Keynes. In his Chapter 4, “The Rapid Multiplication of the Unfit”, Toye explicitly takes up, in section 6, “With Prejudice to Some: Keynes’s Anti-Semitism” (149-156). After reviewing much of the material we have examined above, and placing it a wider frame of reference about categorization of “others”, Toye concludes (156) that Keynes’s 1943 arguments with Harry Dexter White and E. M. Bernstein and his accusation of American “talmudism” was “further evidence of a habit of prejudice that Keynes was never able to break with completely. It was a habit that stretched back over forty years, to a time well before the writing of ‘Population’”. In the 1990s, following his retirement as professor of development economics and economic history at Washington University St. Louis, David Felix began writing books about Keynes and his ideas. Felix’s interpretations of Keynes’s ideas are cranky and failed to engage the Keynesian historical community to any real extent. He regarded Keynes’s theory of Page 19 of 38 unemployment as resting on logical fallacies associated with false assumptions about the determination of the rate of interest. In the second of his books (1999), Keynes: A Critical Life Felix addressed the issue of anti-Semitism. In a remarkable passage (pp. 247-249), linking to some earlier remarks in his book, Felix argued: “The Shylockian passion for liquidity suggests another reason for Keynes’s clinging to his view of the Jews as a usurious race… Keynes is not quite so professional [as Marx in his anti-Semitism]. His theorizing undergoing metastasis, he has his Jew clinging to his “goold” and burying himself at the bottom of The General Theory of the Rate of Interest, and thus at the bottom of The General Theory. If the Jew is not absolutely necessary in the theoretical machinery, Keynes, perhaps signaling the weakness of his case, nevertheless finds him useful as an auxiliary in representing an excessive demand for liquidity and its depressive effects…The General Theory of the Rate of Interest is as mad as it seems…[D]id Keynes know that he was perpetrating nonsense, or rather, considering his marvelously operative brain, how could he not know?” For Felix, Keynes was a beaten and battered [sic] child (at the hand of John Neville Keynes) who acted out his sexual life in response to those paternal beatings. The extent of his anti-Semitism is discussed (227-232) but its roots are unexamined beyond the statement that it was a “very ordinary phenomenon among the English (and French, Germans, other Europeans, and Americans) of his time” (228). Page 20 of 38 More recently, there have been two other discussions of Keynes and anti-Semitism, by well-regarded historians in well-received books. In the first, Jerry Z. Muller’s (2010) Capitalism and the Jews, the discussion about Keynes is located in a long history of Western European and Christian thought that associated Jews and usury, via the mechanism of compound interest. Thus Keynes’s “speculative writings are redolent of the prejudicial association of Judaism with the features of capitalism from which he sought to distance himself, and eventually, his society” (61)22. In the second, Anthony Julius’s (2010) comprehensive Trials of the Diaspora: A History of Anti-Semitism in England considers Keynes to be an exemplar of particularly English views. Distinguishing among various “kinds” of anti-Semitism, he places Keynes in an intellectual tradition that created no new anti-Semitic alliances or political machinery, nor any large debates. “Anti-Semitism in England [in the modern period] tended to attach itself to more immediate, and less culturally fundamental issues – scandals, controversies, panic, fears, and the like – and then, mostly those with a foreign-policy character” (397). Going on in this vein, Julius’s Keynes “displayed a certain intrigued interest in Jews… [P]rone to amateur speculations about the distinctive nature of the Jewish mind…he was ready…to mock the Jewish race’s love for the principle of compound interest, or to doubt that communism makes Jews less avaricious…He had Jews pinned down, the object of his lazy, amused surveys, uninformed, dispassionate, and above all deriving from his own supreme self-confidence” (397).23 22 This same argument linking Jews and capitalism was made, in passing, by William Coleman (2002, 213-219) as he tracked some writings by and about economists primarily in the nineteenth century. 23 Keynes is, in Julius’s schema, an exemplar of the “normative anti-Semitism of English writers and intellectuals.” (414) Page 21 of 38 The Anti-Semitism Issue and the Post Keynesian Discussion List To look through another window on this discussion, I turned to the World Wide Web, and the PKT (Post Keynesian Thought) mail list. That web based discussion forum had been located at the University of Colorado, but is no longer is active24. That list, devoted to the exploration of Keynes’s ideas and Post Keynesian theory as especially guided by the Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, were rather muted with respect to the initial mention, on that list, of Reder’s article. John M. Legge, on February 20, 2001 noted: I think that that the social context [of anti-Semitism] was changed irrevocably by the Holocaust. Before then, you didn’t have to be off the planet to make a disparaging remark about Jews, individually or as a group….politically incorrect remarks about “others” were a normal part of conversation in Keynes’s day and unless one wants to condemn every generation before ours, we should accept that verbal disparagement and gas chambers are not part of some dreadful continuum but are different in kind. That response drew a response from Noemi Levy Orlick. “It’s very doubtful what you are saying, since persecutions against Jews have existed long before the Holocaust and in part were originated from those types of comments. Jewish people never have seen those comments as something normal. And anti-Semitism or any type of segregation should not be seen as “normal” at any other time.” 24 The list moderator, Ric Holt (Professor of Economics, Southern Oregon University) shut down the list in July 2004. The PKT-List Archive though is presently available at http://archives.econ.utah.edu/archives/pkt/index.htm Page 22 of 38 In a related follow-up, Clifford Poirot wrote “That Keynes may have held anti-Semitic views is a travesty, though a sad testament to the extent to which anti-Semitism and other forms of bigotry have often penetrated “polite” society. In a way, it does not surprise me any more than Marx’ virulent racism and chauvinism. The other issue is whether there is a connection between expressed anti-Semitism and one’s theory. It seems to me there is none in either Keynes’s or Hayek’s case.” Continuing this line, Legge replied “Keynes was a man of his time and used the language of his time. It is utterly illogical to single him out. When faced with a practical challenge of Nazi anti-Semitism, Keynes was vigorous in both easing the life of Jewish refugees and their access to Britain and ensuring that Britain offered Hitler no alternative to unconditional surrender.” Barkley Rosser, casting a somewhat wider net in the discussion, returned to Reder’s article with the observation that “It is not a simple matter, but in the case of Keynes, I fear that Reder is correct. Again, the point of his article was to use these examples to show a general set of widespread social attitudes and furthermore to discuss why those attitudes changed after World War II.25” And Colin Danby pointed out that “Keynes was as we know elitist; he also took an interest in eugenics. A staple of the elitism he grew up with is a notion of “blood” or “stock,” like breeding racehorses. There are remarks that suggest that he regarded workers as genetically different. So it is possible that race was part of Keynes’s social ontology, in which case it might not be totally irrelevant to his economics.” Matthew Forstater, one of the PKT List’s creators, responded (February 20, 2001) to several of the postings, noting The logical problem of excusing past discrimination based on the idea that everyone felt that way then, is that everyone did not feel Although as the earlier discussion about Keynes and “talmudism” demonstrates, Keynes’ negative comments about Jews did not abate at all after World War II. 25 Page 23 of 38 that way then. …It may be true that it took more courage to speak out then, but it is not true that “everyone felt that way” so it is ok. Once we start excusing these kinds of things, where does it end? It is also true however, that just because someone was wrong about one thing, they were not necessarily wrong about everything. So if Keynes was an anti-Semite, that in itself is not a refutation of The General Theory. After that comment, the discussion ended with no real engagement by any of the Post Keynesians. Conclusion Historiographically, within the last decade we have seen studies of the interconnection of the economics profession with the eugenics movement. The early twentieth century literature on immigration provides an entrée into economists’ eugenicist arguments, but these of course had some basis in nineteenth century ideas as David Levy and Sandra Peart (2005) have pointed out. And as Thomas Leonard (2005) has argued, the dark side of progressivism, and the institutionalist economics out of which the American economics profession developed, proffered a curious mélange of eugenicist propositions. The racism of many in the economics community in the late 1800s did not disappear either, as careful perusal of the 20th century AEA archives, and the papers of many eminent economists (e.g. Duke’s Joseph J. Spengler), can attest. The Review of Black Political Economy has made available to the economics profession large numbers of studies examining the racism of the economics profession both as a systematic Page 24 of 38 community problem and as individual failures. Moreover it is acceptable within the emergent literature in feminist economics (e.g. in the journal Feminist Economics) to reflect with scorn on the sexist biases of economists’ arguments. Indeed, those critical writings extend to the work of particular economists who are argued to have conscious gender biases. We have various studies on the narrowing of opportunity for women in the economics profession following the closing of colleges of home economics. But anti-Semitism seems to be a forbidden topic. Discussions of anti-Semitism have been particularistic, not systematic. The larger intellectual debate that developed around Jerome Karabel’s (2005) The Chosen, which detailed the anti-Semitic college admissions policies of Harvard, Yale, and Princeton over the course of the first two-thirds of the twentieth century, has passed unnoticed by historians of economics. The puzzle is that historians of economists understood, though remained silent about, the restrictions on admission of Jewish students as undergraduates to these important intellectual bastions, but they made no public, or seemingly even private, connection between the economics done, and the economists at, those very same institutions. It is as if anti-Semitism had stopped at the exit door of the Admissions Office. While mathematicians have examined their own institutional histories with openness and courage, and have studied in detail the effect on the American mathematics community of different attitudes among universities toward Jews in response to the European immigration of the 1930s and 1940s, there has been no similar examination by historians of economics. Perhaps that is a result of the paucity of institutional histories of economics departments in the twentieth century. Nevertheless, questions of anti-Semitism, and the role of the great American research universities of the East Coast in reproducing the American elites, has escaped the notice of historians of economics26. 26 The exception that “proves” the assertion is the rather extensive attention to the fact that antiPage 25 of 38 There are real contrasts in other words between the limited discussions about the antiSemitism of Keynes and the extensive examinations by the Jung community of Carl Jung’s antiSemitism, and by the literary theory community of de Man’s anti-Semitic 1930s wartime writings in Belgium. I have, in another context, referred to the Sherlock Holmes “Silver Blaze” story, with its remark about the failure of the dog to bark in the night. Why has this antiSemitism dog failed to bark in economics? It is difficult to create a compelling argument about why a logically and empirically possible event has not occurred. Nevertheless I believe that there are at least three27 (neither mutually exclusive nor exhaustive) possible answers to the question of why historians of economics concerned with Keynes, and members of the Keynesian community, have avoided addressing Keynes’s putative anti-Semitism. First, perhaps it is a matter of Keynes himself, namely that the allegation is simply inappropriate to associate with an economist of his importance. Second, perhaps there is something about economics that makes such questions inappropriate. And third, the allegation that any particular individual is anti-Semitic is simply too socially or politically dangerous for the rhetor who wishes to interrogate it. Let me take each of these up in turn. John Maynard Keynes plays a role in the history of economics second only perhaps to that of Adam Smith. Appeals to Keynes are as frequent as appeals to the invisible hand, and for both the appeals are often incoherent and contradictory. Nevertheless arrayed against Newton Semitism played a role in Harvard’s encouraging Paul Samuelson to leave Harvard to take up the offer from MIT. Harvard’s then Chairman Burbank will live on in the history of economics solely for that exercise in bigotry. 27 There is an obvious fourth argument as well. It might be the case that no Keynes scholar has been interested in looking at the topic because the topic appears prima facie uninteresting; after all the community is small, and time is short, and George Stigler once told the history of economics community that personalia should not concern scholars. Page 26 of 38 and Einstein, or Darwin, or Euclid and Gauss, or Galileo and Kepler, Keynes has some name recognition and authority. Denigrating, or appearing to denigrate, Keynes would be an act of lèse majesté, of debunking a heroic figure and sneering at the good and the true and the beautiful. It would be a sacrilege. The Keynes community achieved such a position quite deliberately, as Keynes’s disciples used the mythic Keynes to defeat those who had not learned from the master at Cambridge. They kept guard over the Keynes legacy by first controlling what could be known about him by protecting his papers and by contributing frequent historical recollections of his charisma and intellectual prowess. These moves were uniformly hagiographic and open hostility, and restricted access, was sometimes the Cambridge response to anti-Keynesians. The Robinson-Kahn treatment of D. H. Robertson comes immediately to mind, as does the creation of the U.K. Post Keynesian movement to preserve and promulgate the one true and original vision of Keynes’s work. A second line of argument about why the anti-Semitism allegation had so little purchase might be associated with the difference between economics and other fields of scholarly work. I have alluded to the major controversies that have arisen about the allegations of anti-Semitism in the historiography of both analytical psychology and post structuralist literary theory, associated with the writings and behavior of Carl Jung and Paul de Man. In each case at issue was the charismatic character of the intellectual leader, and whether the individual’s leadership was undermined by evidence of putative anti-Semitic public writing. In Jung’s case, the record seems clear that the Jung community addressed the matter with some courage, even though there was no emergent consensus on the issue of whether Jung’s anti-Semitism went beyond writing to actual cooperation with Nazi authorities in eliminating all Jews from positions in the Page 27 of 38 Psychoanalytic Society in the 1930s28. With de Man, the issue for scholars went to the concern with the basis of deconstructive readings of texts as a real or metaphorical response to de Man’s hiding (and thus potentially being unmasked by, or discovered in) his own history29 as a Nazi collaborator and author of anti-Semitic articles as a journalist in occupied Belgium. In both these cases the main arguments which the communities engaged concerned the individual’s work and its relation to the author’s putative anti-Semitism. In contrast, consider the case of Lev Semonovich Pontryagin (1908-1988), the eminent Soviet mathematician. Pontryagin was noted for his contributions to modern geometry, notably homology theory and cobordism. Later in his career he made very important contributions to optimal control theory, and became well-known to economists in the 1960s because that theory had immediate applicability to the theory of economic growth30. Yet in his later years, say from the 1960s, he gave expression, in public, to a virulent anti-Semitism which, given his position as an eminent Soviet mathematician, served to construct and then reinforce many prohibitions “Jung became the nominal editor of the Society’s journal, the Zentralblatt für Psychotherapie, which had been published in Germany. It was in this publication, in late 1933, that a manifesto appeared by Matthais Goering—with consent of Jung who had thought that it was to be published only as a special German edition—which called for a rallying by professional colleagues to the racial colors of Nazi Germany. To compound matters, appearing in that same issue of the journal was Jung’s essay “On the State of Psychotherapy Today,” in which he starkly reiterated the differences between German and Jewish psychologies that he had posited some years earlier. In addition, his article compared Jews unfavorably to `nomads and women’, and criticized Freud and Adler for stressing pathology while failing to appreciate the creative aspects of psychological life. . . This essay … became the principal theoretical document that Jung’s accusers offered as a demonstration of his anti-Semitism.” (Martin 1991, 7) 28 “In 1987 … a Belgian researcher Ortwin de Graef discovered a number of articles by Paul de Man written between 1940 and 1942 for the collaborationist newspapers Le Soir and Het Vlaamsche Land.” (Rajan 1991, 231) 29 30 There were 194 references to Pontryagin in JSTOR-Economics between 1960-1980. Page 28 of 38 against Jewish mathematicians31. His role in what later mathematicians called “intellectual genocide” against Jewish mathematicians and scientists is unarguable (Shifman 2005). Nevertheless, with all such material fully in view, Pontryagin’s mathematics itself remains unquestioned, indeed unquestionable. Whether or not Werner Heisenberg was a Nazi collaborator, his contributions to quantum mechanics are of lasting importance. It appears that in humanities scholarship the connection between one’s persona and one’s work remains important, and is thus worth an historian’s attention32. In mathematics and the natural sciences, such appears not to be the case. It is as if the created scientific work is appropriated by the relevant scientific community as a product alienated from its creator. The use of the passive voice and the mantle of impersonality that characterize a modern scientific publication render the author’s character nugatory. Economics, with its knowledge products being neither as personally grounded as they are in the humanities, nor as impersonally presented as they are in the natural sciences, is epistemically more confusing. Is Economics an art or science? Of course the recent literatures in science studies show us that such a question is ill-posed. “What are the community’s practices?” and “What are the rules?” are questions that are, at least, answerable in principle. And here we have some evidence to suggest that for economics the community’s practices are more like those found among mathematicians than among literary theorists. The historiography of Keynes’s anti-Semitism more nearly imitates those of physicists (e.g. whether or not Heisenberg had been His autobiography, published in Russian in the late 1970s, includes such sentences as “… Zionist circles carry out persistent attempts to present Einstein as the sole creator of the theory of relativity. This is unfair.” (Vershik 2005, 145n.) 32 Of course the New Criticism denied that historical/biographical information about the author was appropriately part of the interpretative process, but with respect to biography, and historical work on literary figures, the matter is quite different. And in any case, the views of the New Criticism are today mostly repudiated by literary scholars. 31 Page 29 of 38 a Nazi collaborator, his physics was a remarkable act of genius) than those of literary theorists (if literature has a moral dimension, Ezra Pound’s poetry, and T.S. Eliot’s, must be diminished in our estimation by his anti-Semitism). There is another issue, of greater complexity and weight, related to this last point. I have passed quickly over the argument by Felix that Keynes’s General Theory was an anti-Semitic work in the sense of its identifying capitalism’s faults with a Jewish Capitalism. The deeper issue is where did Keynes’ own ideas about “usury”, “Jews and compound interest”, “hoarding” and so on come from? The comments he was accustomed to make about Jews and money, witness his letter to Max Raden noted earlier in which he wrote ‘I still think that the race has shown itself, not merely for accidental reasons, more than normally interested in the accumulation of usury’, suggests that his beliefs were, in his mind, well-founded in evidence. It is very difficult to answer a question like “How could an intelligent historical personage believe something so stupid?” without falling into historiographic presentism. Nevertheless, it is important in this case to understand the rootedness of such an idea in both Keynes’ education and the Cambridge and economics communities, indeed the community of serious European intellectuals, in which he worked. In recent historical work, Julie Mell (2007, 12) reconsidered "Die Stellung der Juden im Mittelalter, betrachtet vom Standpunkt der allgemeinen Handelspolitik" (The Status of the Jews in the Middle Ages Considered from the Standpoint of Commercial Policy) … Wilhelm Roscher's 1875 essay [which] argued that the Jews had functioned in the middle ages as a commercial carrier and ‘tutor’ to the ‘younger nations.’" Roscher’s liberalism was inclusive, and thus for his time philosemitic. Mell (ibid., 13) however extends and deepens arguments originally presented in the 1940s by Toni Oelsner (1958-9), pointing out that: Page 30 of 38 [Oelsner] attacked the "special 'economic' function of the Jews" as mere folk-psychology, which when "deprived of [its] philo-Semitic and liberal guise could be turned into models for and instruments of the destructive Nazi 'Jewish science'" … Oelsner challenged assumptions which had played a decisive role in modern Jewish history. Jewish economic characteristics formed one of the key components of the political debates over the inclusion of the Jewish population in the modern European nation state from the seventeenth century on. The nineteenth-century German notions of a special affinity between Jews and commerce were notions shared by Jews and Christians, philosemites and antisemites, and used for apology and polemic. Nazi antisemitic imagery of bloodsucking Jewish capitalism was but the negative underside of widely held assumptions about Jewish economic difference -- and the awful conclusion to these debates.” As Oelsner and Mell argue the matter, the historical “evidence” of specifically Jewish connections to the rise of capitalism is simply not present. Such claims are in fact falsified by the evidence. Though well-meaning, Roscher’s desire to find a role for Jews in the new German economic system, by claiming that they had historically had such an important role, was founded on his misreading and misconstruction of the historical record. But Roscher’s place in economics, as leader of the German Historical School, meant that his views (as interpreted by Page 31 of 38 Sombert and Weber) on the history of the Jews and capitalism, usury and compound interest particularly, became canonical33. These were the tools with which Keynes made his arguments, these were the components of his integrated view of the Jews as “more than normally interested in the accumulation of usury.” It is in this sense, and this sense only, that Keynes might be said to have had a systematic misunderstanding of the connection between the Jews and capitalism/commerce. Only then to the extent that such unfounded beliefs might have shaped his economic arguments could it now be suggested that Keynes’ vision of modern capitalism was touched by anti-Semitic ideas. Third and finally, the issue of why anti-Semitism so little concerns historians of economics today may be associated with the volatile nature of the rhetoric associated with studies of anti-Semitism in the post War era. As emergent knowledge of the extent of the Holocaust made anti-Semitism (and eugenics) unpalatable for common consumption – antiJewish sentiment was the moral equivalent of mass murder – it likewise made impossible discussion of whether some prewar figure was or was not anti-Semitic. The Holocaust admitted no matters of degree. Moreover, the use made of “the Jewish question” in the early postwar period allied the “left” with the new state of Israel, and drew lines very clearly between fascists and those opposed to fascism. The community of anti-fascists was populated by Jews whose coreligionists were fascism’s victims, and those others who had “always” seen its evil, Communists The story of how these ideas “became” canonical, and thus became part of the mental equipment of economists and social scientists more generally, can be easily tracked as Mell has done. “I aim to show that the narrative was fashioned out of nineteenth-century discourses on Jews and commerce in response to the issues of Jewish emancipation and German capitalism and shaped in accord with German scholarly methods and theories. This public discourse moved into mainstream scholarship principally through the works of Wilhelm Roscher, Werner Sombart, and Max Weber. Through these scholars, the narrative was stamped with the organic folk model of the German Historical School, based upon the Historical School’s theory of economic stages, and shaped in relationship to the scholarly study of capitalism.” (Mell 2007, 15) 33 Page 32 of 38 for instance. But as the cold war took hold, and as many of the “premature anti-fascists” and “fellow travelers” seemed to have Jewish names, anti-Semitism reemerged from the background into which it had only temporarily disappeared. Following the end of the 1967 Yom Kippur War, with Israeli conquest and occupation of Palestinian lands, attacking Zionist (read Jewish) “imperialism’ became a fashionable activity and anti-Semitism, often in the guise of antiZionism, returned to its earlier place as a commonly accepted set of beliefs and opinions held by many well-educated non-Jews. It is troublesome that in the history of economics it is hardly possible to discuss such matters even in a larger economics community in which twenty seven of the first sixty two (to 2009) Noble Laureates were Jewish34. The silence is palpable; to speak of these matters offends against the community’s comfort. Without tenure, one might well consider writing on some other topic. As “social security” was once said to be the “third rail” of election politics in the US, so too discussions of anti-Semitism appear to have such electric power in historical scholarship today. When Reder’s article appeared, the Hayek community’s response gives some indication of the topic’s virulence. On the then functioning maillist Hayek-L, its moderator Greg Ransom wrote: Reder has some far more serious matters to clear up than any offhand or off-target remarks of anyone on the Hayek-L list. So does the HOPE editorial staff & its board. Reder's remarks were not offhand, and the decision on the part of HOPE & its editors to publish 34 This point is discussed in greater detail in the very recent paper by E. Glen Weyl (2011). Weyl’s exceptional introduction to Simon Kuznets’ writings on economics and the Jews should open a number of serious lines of inquiry, perhaps by economic historians as well as historians of economics, into some of the questions raised in this section. Page 33 of 38 Reder's article as it stood against the heated objection of one of his anonymous referees calls into question the judgment of those involved, and the scholarly standards and procedures used at that publication…Politicians love to get their enemies by pulling the "When did you last beat your wife" stunt. Academic journals and credible scholars shouldn't be in business of playing anything even close to this game. When the matter is one of whether or not to label someone an anti-semite, someone had better meet a very high level of scholarship, proof & care -- at least as high as the level of moral opprobrium which would go with the labeling. Reder & HOPE didn't come close to meeting this standard in my judgment.” (Ransom 2001) A demand that the HOPE Editor be fired came from a North Carolina legislator, prominent among letters sent to the President of Duke University and Duke University Press, while reports of disfavor attributed to members of the Hayek family in England35 were conveyed to HOPE by third parties. Indeed, it was this episode which led me to examine these issues in the first place. In the history of economics, matters are no easier to address when Keynes is the subject. In economics, a field which lays claim to have created the notion of the free marketplace of ideas, the historiographic issues herein addressed are worth considering. 35 Hayek’s best biographer, Bruce J. Caldwell, has a good discussion of this in his book, Hayek’s Challenge (Caldwell 2004, 145-146 n. 16) Page 34 of 38 References Blaug, M. (1994). "Recent Biographies of Keynes." Journal of Economic Literature 32(3): 12041215. Caldwell, B. (2004). Hayek's Challenge: An Intellectual Biography of F. A. Hayek. Chicago, University of Chicago Press. Chandavarkar, A. (2000). "Perspectives: Was Keynes Anti-Semitic?" Economic and Political Weekly May 6: 1619-1624. Colander, D. C. and H. Landreth, Eds. (1996). The coming of Keynesianism to America: conversations with the founders of Keynesian economics Brookfield, VT, Edward Elgar. Coleman, W. O. (2002). Economics and its Enemies: Two Centuries of Anti-Economics. New York, Palgrave Macmillan. Felix, D. (1999). Keynes: a Critical Life. Westport, CT, Greenwood Press. Forstater, M. (2001). PKT: Mail list. Hamacher, W., N. Hertz, et al., Eds. (1989a). Responses: On Paul de Man's Wartime Journalism. Lincoln, NB, University of Nebraska Press. Hamowy, R. (2002). "A Note on Hayek and Anti-Semtism." History of Political Economy 34(1): 257-262. Harrod, R. F. (1951). The Life of John Maynard Keynes. London, Macmillan. Hill, P. and R. Keynes, Eds. (1989). Lydia and Maynard: the Letters of John aynard Keynes and Lydia Lopokova. New York, Charles Scribner's Sons. Julius, A. (1995). T. S. Eliot, Anti-Semitism, and Literary Form. New York and Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. Page 35 of 38 Julius, A. (2010). Trails of the Diaspora: A History fo Anti-Semtism in England. Oxford and New York, Oxford University Press. Karabel, J. (2005). The Chosen: The Hidden History of Admission and Exclusion at Harvard, Yale, and Princeton. Boston and New York, Houghton Mifflin. Kaun, D. E. (2000). "The Anti-Semitism of John Maynard Keynes." Midstream 46(5): 1-9. Keynes, J. M. (1936). The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. New York, Harcourt Brace. Landes, D. (1994). "Abba Ptachya Lerner, 1903-1982." Biograpical Memoirs (National Academy of Sciences ): 207-230. Leonard, T. C. (2005). "Retrospectives: Eugenics and Economics in the Progressive Era." Journal of Economic Perspectives 19(4): 207-224. Laidler, D. (1999). Fabricating the Keynesian revolution : studies of the inter-war literature on money, the cycle, and unemployment. Cambridge [England] ; New York, Cambridge University Press. Mackrell, J. (2008). Bloomsbury Ballerina: Lydia Lopokova, Imperial Dancer and Mrs. John Maynard Keynes. London, Weidenfeld and Nicholson and Orion. Maidenbaum, A. and S. A. Martin, Eds. (1991). Lingering Shadows: Jungians, Freudians, and Anti-Semitism. Boston and London, Shambhala. Martin, S. A. (1991). Introduction. Lingering Shadows. A. Maidenbaum and S. A. Martin. Boston and London, Shambhala: 1-13. Mell, J. (2007). Chapter 2: The Economic Function of the Jews. In Religion and Economy in Pre-modern Europe: The Medieval Commercial Revolution and the Jews. Ph.D. Dissertation, Department of History, University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill. Page 36 of 38 Moggridge, D. E. (1992). Maynard Keynes: An Economist's Biography. London and New York, Routledge. Muller, J. Z. (2010). Capitalism and the Jews. Princeton, Princeton University Press. Oelsner, T. (1958-9). "Wilhelm Roscher’s Theory of the Economic and Social Position of the Jews in the Middle Ages: A Critical Examination." YIVO 12: 176-95. Paulovicova, N. (2007). "The Immoral Moral Scientist. John Maynard Keynes." Past Imperfect 13: 24-55. Peart, S. and D. M. Levy (2005). The "Vanity of the Philosopher": From Equality to Hierarchy in Post-Classical Economics. Ann Arbor, MI, University of Michigan Press. Poirot, C. (2001). PKT: Mail list. Pontryagin, L. S. (1979). "Soviet Anti-Semitism: Reply by Pontryagin." Science 205(4411): 1083-1084. Rajan, T. (1991). "Review: Allegories of Intertextuality: The Controversy over Paul de Man." Modern Philology 89(2): 231-246. Reder, M. W. (2000). "The Anti-Semitism of some Eminent Economists." History of Political Economy 32(4): 833-856. Reder, M. W. (2002). "Reply to Hamowy's Note on Hayek and Anti-Semitism." History of Political Economy 34(1): 263-274. Rosser, B. (2001). PKT: Mail list. Shifman, M., Ed. (2005). You Failed Your Math Test, Comrade Einstein. Singapore and London, World Scientific. Page 37 of 38 Skidelsky, R. (1986). John Maynard Keynes, Hopes Betrayed 1883-1920. New York, Viking Penguin Co. Toye, J. (2000). Keynes on Population. Oxford, Oxford University Press. Vershik, A. (2005). Science and Totalitarianism. You Failed Your Math Test, Comrade Einstein. M. Shifman. Singapore and London, World Scientific: 143-151. Weintraub, E. R. (2002). How Economics Became a Mathematical Science. Durham, NC, Duke University Press. Weyl, E. G. (2011). Introduction: Simon Kuznets, Cautious Empiricist of the Eastern European Jewish Diaspora. Jewish Economies Volume II: Development and Migration in America and Beyond - Simon Kuznets. E. G. Weyl and S. Lo. New Brunswich and London, Transactions Publishers: xv - lvii. Woolf, L. (1935). Quack, Quack. New York, Harcourt Brace. Page 38 of 38