Identity Diversity in Family Firms: Concept and Implications Dr. Alain Praet Hogeschool-Universiteit Brussel, Faculty of Economics & Management Research Centre for Entrepreneurship Stormstraat 2, 1000 BRUSSELS, Belgium Tel: +32- (0) 2 609 82 50; Fax : +32 (0) 2 217 64 64 alain.praet@hubrussel.be Abstract Based on Akerlof and Kranton (2000, 2005), I introduce the concept of identity, a person’s sense of self, as a novel way to approach the concept of familiness. As such it extends the classical economic theory that depicts utility as a fixed function of income and effort to a utility function that is situation-dependent. A person’s identity is determined by the perceptions of how one should behave according to the social category one belongs to. Accordingly, I view the family firm as a combination of different groups that may have different identities. These groups include family members as well as other stakeholders such as the employees. As a result, family firms exhibit varying degrees of diversity in identities. Therefore, I suggest a categorization of family firms based on the diversity of identities and performance measures that fit each of these different categories. Key words: Identity, Diversity of family firms Introduction Despite many efforts, research up till now has failed to demonstrate a clear relationship between ‘familiness’ and performance (Rutherford, Kuratko & Holt, 2008). On one hand, this follows from the difficulty of measuring familiness and the different ways of operationalizing this. On the other hand, many different performance measures have been used, including accounting-based measures and self-reported performance measures. However, both approaches entail difficulties since families may pursue noneocnomic goals (Gomez-Mejia, HaynesNunez-Nickel, Jacobson & Moyano-Fuentes, 2007;. Zellweger & Astrachan, 2008), which implies that traditional profit measures become less relevant as performance benchmarks. Using self-reported measures on the other hand assumes that the perception of performance is homogeneous within the firm which is reflected upon in a fair way by the respondent. Standard economic theory is unable to explain these problems and the behavior that accompanies it. However, the validity of this approach has been criticized and recent research emphasizes the diversity of family firms. Westhead and Howorth (2007) identify six types of private family firms dependent on the dominance of the family in ownership and management. Accordingly, the objectives of the family firm will vary between purely financial objectives and family objectives. Although this kind of approach provides interesting insights, it does not take into account the role and the impact of people that play a role in the family firm as a stakeholder or as an individual that influences family behavior. Howorth, Westhead, Rose & Hamilton (2010) state that the role of invisible members such as women is under-researched although they contribute to family dynamics. In order to include these different elements into a unifying theory on family firms, I apply Akerlof and Kranton’s (2005) idea that the identity, a person’s self-image, has an impact on the decisions they take, on family firms. As such it extends the classical economic theory that depicts utility as a fixed function of income and effort to a utility function that is situation-dependent. A person’s identity is determined by the perceptions of how one should behave according to the social category one belongs to. Accordingly, I view the family firm as a combination of different groups that may have different identities. These groups include family members as well as other stakeholders such as the employees. As a result, family firms exhibit varying degrees of diversity in identities. Therefore, I suggest a categorization of family firms based on the diversity of identities and performance measures that fit each of these different categories. Identity and the family firm Traditional economic theory has used utility functions and posits that people will act as to maximize their utility. However, this traditional approach has failed to explain concepts from sociology and psychology, such as altruism and nepotism, that have been proven to be important concepts in family firms. According to Akerlof & Kranton (2000, 2005), introducing identity into the utility function of an individual and extending the standard economic analyses, allows the explanation of these concepts. Identity is used to describe a person’s social category but is also defined as a person’s sense of self. As such it departs from the assumption in traditional economics that the utility functions are not situation dependent. Falck, Heblich & Luedemann argue that this concept of identity depends on a person’s socialization. They find that entrepreneurial intentions result from parental influence but also from peer influence. In their conception, utility functions change because norms of appropriate and inappropriate behavior differ across space and time. Since the same person belongs to different social categories, for example man/woman, worker/manager, shareholder/non-shareholder or family member/non-family member, that person’s behavior will depend on the specific circumstances. This leads to the following specification of the utility function (Akerlof & Kranton, 2000): Uj = Uj (aj,a-j,Ij) where utility for person j depends on j’s identity Ij as well as on j’s own actions aj and others actions a -j. A person’s identity can then be modeled as (Akerlof & Kranton, 2000) Ij = Ij (aj,a-j;cj ,j ,P) where a person’s identity depends on j’s assigned social categories cj, the extent to which j’s own given characteristics match the ideal of j’s assigned category, indicated by the prescriptions for that specific category P, and the extent to which j’s own and other’s actions correspond to the prescribed behavior indicated by P. This concept of identity allows the distinction between family firms and non-family firms in the first place. Although one’s family is a relevant social category for everyone, family firms distinguish themselves from non-family firms in that the family becomes a relevant social category in the working environment. This implies that in professional situations, family will be relevant and the expectations from the family will impact the family member’s behavior. As a result, family members may take actions that are hard to explain by traditional economic theory but make sense from an identity point of view. A typical example concerns the existence of altruism (Schulze, Lubatkin & Dino, 2003). Although altruistic behavior may impose costs on the organization, family members may be willing to incur these costs although they lead to a decreased utility. Since the family constitutes an important element in the identity of some family members, they are willing to incur costs to avoid loss in identity. Although this cost will lower the utility of the individual family member, they will still engage in this activity when the cost to preserve the identity is smaller than the loss in utility that would follow if no action is undertaken. This will be the case if the incurred loss is smaller than the expected loss in utility by non-altruistic behavior due to the loss in identity when family as a social category is very relevant. This view thus would provide an alternative explanation for the finding that in some cases family members are willing to provide human, social and financial capital to the firm (Danes et al., 2009). On the other hand, given that family as a social category will be relevant to the family members involved in the firm, does not mean that the perception of the appropriate behavior will be the same for all family members. Family firms are often plagued by substantial conflict. Kellermans & Eddleston (2004) stress that although conflict is often perceived to have negative effects, it can also be beneficial under certain circumstances .They distinguish between task conflict, process conflict and the moderating role of relationship conflict. They posit that altruism will also play a role an diminish the relationship conflict in family firms. Dependent on the expectation of what is appropriate, family members will behave differently in similar situations and they will have different expectations with respect to the preferred outcome in terms of financial or non-economic goals. An example here is transmitting the firm to the next generation, which is a crucial element in defining the family firm and has received a lot of attention in previous research. From an identity point of view, the next generation in the family could have a completely different view and expectations about the firm. Whereas the founders that started the firm might be tempted to consider the firm and its well-being as a crucial element of their identity, even at the expense of their family life, this could be different for the following generations. For the next generations, the firm and its continuance may still be important but at the same time they may not exhibit the same willingness to sacrifice their personal life. Generational involvement is also expected to have an impact on the relationship between task and process conflict on one hand and performance on the other hand (Kellermans & Eddleston, 2004). As a result, the transition of the family firm to the next generation which has been shown to have an impact on performance (Molly, Laveren & Deloof, 2010), may in fact reflect a shift in identity in which later generations have different preferences. Identity and work incentives Although it is straightforward that family members are the ones most likely to include the family in their identity, other stakeholders as well may consider the family as an important element. A first category of stakeholders that play an important role are the employees, including the top management team. Applying identity to organizations, this leads to the following utility function for a worker (Akerlof & Kranton, 2005) U(y,e;c) = ln y – e + I c – t c e*(c) - e Where U denotes the worker’s utility, y is her income, e is her actual effort, c is her social category, Ic is her identity utility from being in category c and t c e*(c) - e is the disutility from diverging from the ideal effort level for category c, denoted e*(c). Akerlof & Kranton (2005) show in their theoretical model that a worker, dependent on whether he feels like an insider or outsider, will engage in more or less effort. This has important implications since identity and monetary incentives could be substitutes. When a family succeeds in attracting workers that feel like insiders, in this case as people that consider the founding family as a relevant social category to their identity function, wages could be lower and effort could still be high. In the same vein, hiring a family member CEO or hiring an external CEO is in this case not the relevant issue but rather whether he identifies himself as an insider with the same identity who wants to act in the best interest of the family. As a result, the agency conflict, which is traditionally described as the conflict between the management and the owners, will disappear if the CEO feels like an insider. In the latter case, he will behave as a steward for the interests of the shareholders. Nevertheless, the choice between a family member and an external as CEO not only has direct implications but also indirect ones. This follows since one has to take into account that actions from others, the other employees, are also relevant. When the family decides to appoint a family member as CEO since this reinforces their identity and the associated utility, employees may have the feeling that the selection process was unfair. Appointing a family member that has insufficient legitimacy towards the employees could create a loss in identity for the other employees. As a result, they could adjust their behavior and react with potentially adverse effects for the firm as a whole. Familiness and performance From the previous it has become clear that identity concerns and the relevance of the family in the identity will be quite different for the different stakeholders within the firm. Even within the group of family members identity concerns may be quite. As a result, family firms will be characterized by differing levels of diversity with respect to their identity. Although this approach shows similarities to the literature of organizational identity (eg Zellweger et al., 2010) or corporate culture, it is still different. The approach used here views corporate culture as the division of stakeholders into different groups where each group differs in the extent to which they identify with the family where each group has its own prescribed behavior and will adopt different goals. As a result, different groups within family firms may have different views on performance. So performance evaluation within family firms would be more appropriate when the identity of the stakeholders in the firm and their preferences are revealed. Failing to take this into account would lead to a misspecification in the relationship between familiness and performance. Familiness, which has its roots in the resource based view and has been described extensively by Frank, Lueger, Nosé & Suchy (2010), would thus depend on the diversity of the family identity. Identity and firm classification Based on the previous, I suggest a novel approach to defining and classifying family firms. As can be made up from figure 1, I suggest that firms would be classified based on the two following dimensions: family firm identity and influence. As described, family firm identity would be measured dependent on the importance of the family in an individual’s identity. The second dimension I consider is the influence a particular member or group of members could exercise. This goes further than simply considering the level of ownership or the involvement in the management as is done in the components approach. Even stakeholders that have no ownership, for example workers, spouses of the family members, a non-active founder, could be quite influential in the family firm. Figure 1: An identity framework for family firms Family identity Family group 2 Workers group 2 TMT Workers group 1 Family group 1 Influence Central in each of these two dimensions is thus the perception by the different stakeholders involved. An approach to imply this empirically could be with the technique of multidimensional scaling where all stakeholders are mapped based on their perceptions. An example of a possible configuration can be found in figure 1. It shows that the firm is characterized by two groups of workers and family members that differ significantly in influence and relevance of the family to their identity. As a result, performance will have quite a different meaning to them and the use of a self-reported measure by for example the top manager (TMT) would give an inaccurate view. Family firms could thus be characterized based on the diversity of the family identity of the different stakeholders. Using this identity approach also allows new insight into the concept of familiness (Habbershon & Williams, 1999). When diversity within the family firm is small, a family identity can be built, which is hypothesized to be an important dimension in familiness (Zellweger, Eddleston & Kellermans, 2010). On the other hand, when the family firm is characterized by a large degree of heterogeneity in family members’ identity, familiness may be created if control over the firm’s resources is concentrated in the hands of a few people. As a result of this identity approach, the essence element (Chrisman, Chua & Sharma, 2005), which entails greater effort by family members, can thus be viewed as a consequence of identity rather than a separate dimension. Implications and conclusion This paper has adopted the view that family firms could be classified based on two different dimensions: influence and identity. Identity, a person’s sense of self, will play an important role in explaining the behavior of stakeholders within a family firm and extends as such the traditional economic theory. Adopting the view that the identity of stakeholders in the family firm plays a determinant role has many implications for family business research. First of all, instead of focusing on easily observable variables such as gender, family or non-family management or generation, it would be more relevant to use a classification based on identities. The traditional variables are typically included in empirical research but may be poor proxies for the real identities that lie behind them. Secondly, from the point of view of the family members, realizing that the family may have different meanings to different family members will have important consequences. With respect to the issue of succession, it has become clear that differences in identity may lead to conflict between the different generations. Allowing family members in the family firm, is also an important issue to consider since this may improve family identity on one hand, but harm the identity, and the associated effort of the other workers on the other hand. So clear rules with respect to those issues would be necessary in order to guarantee the long term well being of the firm. Evidently, this paper is one particular approach to classifying family firms which may benefit from other theoretical lenses as well. Still it seems a promising avenue to explain the relationship between family firm types and performance. References Akerlof, G.A., and R.E. Kranton (2005). Identitiy and the Economics of Organizations. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115 (3), 715-753 Akerlof, G.A., and R.E. Kranton (2005). Identitiy and the Economics of Organizations. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19 (1), 9-32 Chrisman, J.J., Chua, J.H., Pearson, A.W. & Barnett, T. (2010). Family involvement, family influence , and family-centered non-economic goals in small firms. Entrepreneurship Theory & Practice, forthcoming Chrisman, J.J., Chua, J.H. & Sharma, P. (2005). Trends and directions in the development of a strategic management theory of the family firm. Entrepreneurship, Theory & Practice, 29, 555-575 Falck, O., Heblich, S. & Luedemann, E. Identity and entrepreneurship: Do school peers shape entrepreneurial intentions? Small Business Economics, forthcoming Frank, H., Lueger, M., Nosé, L. & Suchy, D. (2010). The concept of “familiness”. Literature review and systems theory-based reflections. Journal of Family Business Strategy, 1, 119-130 Gomez-Mejia, L. R., Haynes, K. T., Nunez-Nickel, M., Jacobson, K. J. L., & MoyanoFuentes, J. (2007). Socioemotional wealth and business risks in family-controlled firms: Evidence from Spanish olive oil mills. Administrative Science Quarterly, 52, 106-137. Habbershon, T.G., & Williams, M. (1999). A resource-based framework for assessing the strategic advantage of family firms. Family Business Review,12, 1-25 Howorth, C., Westhead, P., Rose, M. & Hamilton, E. (2010). Family firm diversity and development: an introduction. International Small Business Journal, 28 (5), 437-451 Kellermans, F.W. & Eddleston, K.A. (2004). Feuding families: when conflict does a family firm good. Entrepreneurship, Theory & Practice, 28, 209-228 Molly, V., Laveren, E. & Deloof, M. (2010). Family business succession and its impact on financial structure and performance. Family Business Review, 23 (2), 131-147 Rutherford, M.W., Kuratko, D.F., & Holt D.T. (2008). Examining the link between ‘familiness’ and performance: can the F-PEC untangle the family business theory jungle? Entrepreneurship, Theory & Practice, 32, 1089-1109 Schulze, W. S., Lubatkin, M. H., & Dino, R. N. (2003). Toward a theory of agency and altruism in family firms. Journal of Business Venturing, 18, 473-490. Westhead, P. & Howorth, C. (2007) ‘Types of private family firms: an exploratory conceptual and empirical analysis. Entrepreneurship and Regional Development, 19, 405-431 Zellweger, T.M., & Astrachan, J.H., 2008. On the emotional value of owning a firm. Family Busines Review, 21(3), 347-363 Zellweger, T.M., Eddleston, K.A. & Kellermans, F.W. (2010). Exploring the concept of familiness: introducing family firm identity. Journal of Family Business Strategy, 1, 5463