Thesis presented to obtain the degree of Master of Science in Human Ecology: Culture, Power and Sustainability May 13th, 2011 Salmon. Gender. Chiloé: Reflections on Sustainable Development. Supervisor: Dr. Susan Paulson Submitted by: Teresa-Laura-Maria Bornschlegl Human Ecology Division Department of Human Geography Faculty of Social Sciences Lund University 2|Page Table of Content: Abstract………………………………………………………………………………………..3 Acknowledgment……………………………………………………………………………...4 List of abbreviations……………………………………………………………………….......6 List of tables…………………………………………………………………………………...6 1 Introduction …………………………………………………………………………….7 2 Research design…………………………………………………………………………8 2. 1 Conceptual framework…………………………………………………………………....8 2. 2 Methods and blind spots……………………………………………………………..…..13 2. 3 Times and spaces……………………………………………………………………..….15 3 Findings on Gender and sustainable development……………………………16 3. 1 What is the (sustainability) issue in Chiloé?.................................................................16 3. 1. 1 The salmon boom……………………………………………………………………..16 3. 1. 2 Regarding social sustainability……………………………………………………......17 3. 1. 3 Regarding ecological sustainability…………………………………………...………19 3. 2 Livelihoods, and capitals…………………………………………………………….....20 3. 2. 1 Chiloé 1960 – 1990…………………………………………………………………...20 3. 2. 2 Chiloé 1990 – 2009………………………………………………………...…………24 3. 3 Social coalitions …………………………………………………………….………….31 3. 3. 1 Pro and contra salmon: social coalitions in Chiloé…………………..………………31 3. 3. 2 The matrix of social coalitions: participation and organization………………………32 3. 3. 3 … towards economic diversity and economic self-reliance? ………………………...34 3. 3. 4 …towards social inclusion and social justice?.............................................................35 3. 3. 5 … towards ecologically sound legal institutions? ………………………….………...36 4 Conclusion………………………………………………………………………………40 Bibliography …………………………………………………………………………...…….46 3|Page Abstract: This study discusses sustainable development with the help of a case study of the Chilean province Chiloé between 1960 and 2009 – main scene of the salmon industry that developed very rapidly in recent decades. Today, Chiloé faces the now common dilemma of ecological devastations and increasing income disparity, widely perceived as inevitable side-effects of development leading to local employment opportunities and national economic growth. Integrating gender into institutional analysis in the context of sustainable development, the study looks at implications of gender for the distribution of assets before and after the establishment of the salmon industry, the formation of social coalitions, the monitoring and control of legal institutions in Chiloé. The study aims to provide a more detailed picture of the territorial dynamics of Chiloé for potential policy recommendations towards a kind of development that would support social inclusion, ecological sustainability, and a stable economy. Keywords: salmon farming, gender, institutions, coalitions, sustainable development, Chiloé 4|Page Acknowledgement: First, and foremost, I’d like to thank my family (who is always there, and who taught me how to swim, and how to fish), Christine Ambrosi (who changed my life in many ways), Peter Robertson (who changed my life in many other ways), my two- handful- friends (from whom I am life-long learning), and the Japanese Karate Association (who gave me a direction). Tusen tack to Dr. Susan Paulson for having connected me to the world of sustainable development in general, and to Rimisp – Centro Latinoamericano para el Desarollo Rural - in detail. I owe Rimisp thanks not only for the financing of my research, but also for the access to the huge amounts of data accumulated during all the years of their on-going research on Chiloé. With Rimisp, I am grateful for having had the chance to be integrated into the marvellous research team within the Rural Territorial Dynamics Program (DTR) on Chiloé Island, Chile. Special thanks to Eduardo Ramírez, Felix Modrego, Rodrigo Yáñez, and, of course, JulieClaire Macé– my “gender-team”-colleague with whom I carried out a gender analysis within the project. Our report– published as a DTR working paper under the title: “Gender System Dynamics in Central Chiloé, or the Quadrature of the Cycles” - builds an analysis of some aspects of my thesis research, and contributes material and understanding to this thesis. Finally, thanks to all the people I encountered in Chiloé, for their patience, their trust, and their wisdom. They all taught me memorable lessons. 5|Page Dedicated to the wild fish. 6|Page List of abbreviation CONAMA Comisión Nacional del Medio Ambiente CEPAL Comisión Económica para América Latina EIR Environmental Impact Report FCR Feed Conversation Ratio NGO Non Governmental Organisation ProChile Dirección de Promoción de Exportaciones PRODEMU Fundación para la Promoción y el Desarrollo de la Mujer SEIA Sistema de Evaluación de Impacto Ambiental SERNAPESCA Servicio Nacional de Pesca SUBPESCA Subsecretaría de Pesca Rimisp Centro Latinoamericano para el Desarollo Rural List of tables: Table A: Women’s cultural capital per year, and differences between 1990 and 2009 Table B: Men’s cultural capital per year, and differences between 1990 and 2009 Table C: Differences in men and women’s cultural capital per year, and the change in differences between 1990 and 2009 Table D: Social and political participation of men and women in year 1990 and 2009 7|Page 1 Introduction “Because ´development´ is a word—like saying ´democracy´—we all think of something different” Former Director PRODEMU, Interview, 2010 Chile is often held as the example for succesfull development in Latin America: from the 1980s on, the country experienced a pronounced economic growth marked by a sustained increase in savings, investments and export sectors. However, this succesfull boom – commonly refered to as the “Chilean Miracle” - has a downside: the over-exploitation of natural resources, and rather harsh working conditions for the human labor force. Thus, the long-term prospect of this kind of development and therewith its role model raises questions. And while there is much research looking for explanations of what made the “Chilean Miracle” so succesful (Cypher, 2004), the overarching topic of my thesis consists in an assessement of what made it so unsuccesful in terms of ecologcial and social sustainability. My object of examination (under the microscope) is a case study of the development of the Chilean province Chiloé between 1960 and 2009 – the main scene of the salmon sector. The latter ranges amongst the most contributive parts to the “Chilean Miracle”, with a production growth of 1745 % within a time span of only ten years, generating annualy USD $ 2 billion, and the employment (direct and indirect) of 50,000 persons. Previous to the arrival of the salmon industry at site, the province Chiloé - an archipelago of more than 40 islands located in South Chile - was marked by a mostly subsistence economy based on small -scale agriculture, shellfish collection, forestry, wool-based crafting, complemented by temporal emigrations to northern and southern Chile and Argentina (Macé & Bornschlegl, 2010). Along with the establishment of the salmon industry, Chiloé experienced a growth in income and local employment opportunities, but also an increase in ecological devastations, energy use, and social disparity. 8|Page Thus, my main concern within that thesis is to analyse the recent historical development of Chiloé in the light of issues of social and ecological sustainability. My approach draws on institutional theory, placing the weight on the social process of institutions, that is, their interaction with different livelihood strategies of diverse actors. I set out to demonstrate if and how a gender analysis of such social process could enrich research of sustainable development. Thus, my research questions are: How does gender play out within the institutional analysis in terms of the distribution of assets before and after the establishment of the salmon industry? How within the formation of social coalitions, and the making and enforcement of legal institutions in Chiloé? The objective of my thesis consists primarily in painting a more accurate picture of Chiloé’s development in order to understand - as the inspector is looking at the dead body: what had happened exactly. The purpose is to present that picture in a way that will contributing to thought and policy on how a more sustainable development in Chiloé could be achieved, and how the research results could lead into some practical applications. 2 Research design “The theory decides what can be observed” Albert Einstein, 1926 2. 1 Conceptual framework The following sections define the main concepts that helped me to illuminate my research questions with a theoretical light: institutional theory (institutions, capitals, livelihoods of actors, and social coalitions), and gender – both seen as established theoretical tools in the context of sustainable development. There had been already a lot of academic debate about the meaning of “development” (Rostow, 1971; Cowen & Shalton, 1996), and the number of opinions about what “sustainable development” would mean are certainly not less plentiful (WCED, 1987; Ekins, 1993; Wackernagel & Rees, 1996; Dincer &Rosen, 2005). For the following thesis, I set the definition of a sustainable community by Bridger and Luloff (2001) as Archimedean point for 9|Page my understanding of sustainable development. Their ideal typical sustainable community is demarcated along five interrelated dimensions: “First, as is the case with standard economic development strategies, there is an emphasis on increasing local economic diversity. Second, virtually all definitions stress the importance of self-reliance, especially economic self-reliance. This is not to be confused with economic self-sufficiency. Self-reliance entails the creation of local markets, local production and processing of previously imported goods, greater cooperation among local economic entities, and the like. Selfreliant communities would still be linked to larger economic structures, but they would have vibrant local economies that would better protect them from the whims of capital than is currently the case. The third dimension centers around a reduction in energy use coupled to the careful management and recycling of waste products. Ideally, this means that the use of energy and material is in balance with the local ecosystem’s ability to absorb waste. The fourth dimension focuses on the protection and enhancement of biological and environmental diversity and wise stewardship of natural resources. Sustainable communities provide a balance between human needs and activities and those of other life forms. Finally, sustainable communities are committed to social justice. Sustainable communities provide for the housing and employment needs of all residents, and they do so without the kind of class and race-based spatial separation that is typical of many localities. As a result, they also ensure equality of access to public services. And perhaps most important, sustainable communities strive to create an empowered citizenry that can effectively participate in local decision-making”. (Bridger & Luloff, 2001: 462) Following institutional theory within sustainable development research (Ostrom et al, 2005; Berkes, 1989; Agrawal, 2001) I further assume that institutions are the means guiding the economic development (that is, the possible livelihood strategies of actors, or, the possible ways for human beings to make a living), preferably towards those stated five dimensions in order to meet the goal of social and ecological sustainability. By institutions I mean the set of established and embedded rules that structures social interactions and their particular enforcing characteristic (North, 1991; Hodgson, 2006). Those 10 | P a g e rules can be of legal or non-legal character: both types set an agenda of limited probabilities by constraining different options of an actor’s behaviours within a particular situation X to the chance of a certain possible response Y. Since human beings tend to align their actions with their assumptions about the probable actions of their social environment (hence actions are always “reactions”), institutions are mostly thought of as ways to reduce uncertainties resulting from collective action problems between asymmetrically informed actors (Ostrom, 1986; Hall, 1996). Institutions are not to conflate with “organizations” – the latter are structured organizational agencies composed of actors oriented towards rules. Defining institutions as rules, however, does not settle the matter entirely: to become a rule, legal or non-legal regulations also must be recognized and enacted implying a potential sanction in case of defection. Rules are not necessarily what is common in the sense of a majority behavior (or, “the average”), but what is normative. It is the potential sanction that distinguishes rules from mere repeated practices. Literal enforcement of rules is expensive in terms of transaction costs, and so in most contexts, enforcement is “assured” through legitimacy1. The occurrence of sustainability problems in the terms of those five dimensions can thus be attributed initially to malfunctioning on the level of institutions – there are either “bad” institutions; or “good” institutions are not sufficiently monitored or enforced. The possible livelihood strategies of actors would then be guided towards an unsustainable direction. Stating that is, however, not to say that there would be an ideal set of institutions for solving universally all sustainable problems across space and time (Ostrom et al, 2005). Livelihoods of actors in the context of sustainable development are to be understood in terms of their access to and disposition of capitals (Bebbington, 1999). In reference to Bourdieu (1985), I distinguish hereby between social, economic, cultural and symbolic capital, adding 1 It [legitimacy] is a process by which cultural accounts from a larger social frame-work in which a social entity is nested are construed to explain and support the existence of that social entity, whether that entity be a group, a structure of inequality, a position of authority, or a social practice. […]. In our view, then, the process of legitimation is a genuinely macro-micro process. (Berger et al, 1998). 11 | P a g e the notion of “natural capital” (Ekins, 1993). The latter equals the stock and flows of nonrenewable and renewable natural resources; economic capital corresponds to the financial means in terms of income and access to credit. Cultural capital equates the knowledge and education within a particular social system. Social capital refers to the network or social contacts an actor disposes of. Emphasis lies in the goal oriented dimension of social capital: returns are (and can be) expected from a contact. Social capital is not synonym to civic engagement and participation in social organizations or to conflate with “community”. Social capital does not equate with social coalitions (sometimes also termed within institutional theory: structured interorganizational cooperation). While being an important part of it, the formation of a social coalition involves all kind of capitals on the part of the actors (and the question remains under which circumstances it leads to that). A social coalition is the assemblage of different organizations, and depends hereby on the participation of actors in as well as on the communication between such entities. On the one hand, the negotiations and struggles taking place in the process of forming and advocating social coalitions are directed by institutions through e.g. the assurance of trust by reducing uncertainty and fulfilment of mutual expectations. On the other hand, social coalitions can influence the creation and enforcement of institutions. According to Elinor Ostrom (1986), the latter follow from: “(1) creating positions (e.g., member, convener, agent, etc.); (2) stating how participants enter or leave positions; (3) stating which actions participants in these positions are required, permitted, or forbidden to take; and (4) stating which outcome participants are required, permitted, or forbidden to affect.”(Ostrom, 1986: 18) The degree to which a social coalition determines such setting of an institutional agenda by negotiating/struggling with other actors/social coalitions depends on the strength of the aggregated value of the capitals brought by actors into the coalition. That is, the stronger social coalition the more influence on the creation and enforcement of institutions. The strength of the single actors, in turn, rests on the kind and the proportional composite of capitals the actor has access to or disposes of. We can think of capitals as different suits in a card game, the composite of capitals as the hand the actors got dealt out, and institutions as the rules according to which the card game takes place. 12 | P a g e However, all capitals discussed so far are not fix values in themselves (nor substitutable with each other). Their value is determined by the (temporally and spatially varying) symbolic capital - “commonly called prestige, reputation, renown, etc., which is the form in which the different forms of capital are perceived and recognized as legitimate” (Bourdieu, 1985: 274). In that sense, capitals are not only means for making a living in a purely material sense, but they also “give meaning” to the actor’s world (Sen, 1997). In sum, problems of ecological and/or social sustainability resulting from “bad” institutions, or a lack of enforcement of “good” institutions, can be delegated to the level of social coalitions, and so to the distribution of capitals, and which suit of capital is classified as trump. While the framework of institutional theory renders the concept of sustainable development therewith better operational through such classifications, it often remains a gender blind block (North, 1991; Hodgson, 2006; Ostrom et al, 2005). of sexes, but rather products of social relations embedded in spatial and temporal contexts2. In turn, in the context of sustainable development gender has sometimes been reduced to “women’s studies only”. Or: to “projects to help barefoot, poor women”, respectively. Such approaches as stirred by “ecofeminism” commonly hold that women inherent a closer relationship to “nature” – what means not only that the subjugation of women (by the patriarchy/capitalism/ect.) is linked to the subjugation of nature (will say: ecological degradation). Furthermore, women are said to be “naturally” better targets and vehicles for sustainable development projects (Shiva, 1989). That “synergism” found adaption by agencies such as the World Bank writing into their sustainable development programs the support (“empowering”) of women for overcoming poverty (through giving micro-credits), stimulating economic growth (through incorporation in the labor market), checking population growth (through education). That instru-mental, women- focused essentialism did not remain uncontested: critics (Jackson, 1993; Paulson, 2010) hold that “women” are not a single homogenous unitary category, that women’s relation to the environment cannot be understood in isolation from the ones of men, and that there aren’t, anyway, such things as “natural” qualities In order to understand men’s and women’s incentive towards sustainable development, a more systemic gender analysis would be needed. 2 On the question whether social construction or biological determination, I agree with Julia Serano (2007) saying: neither only the one, nor only the other. 13 | P a g e Accordingly, in this thesis, gender is embedded into institutional theory and conceptualized as “constitutive element of social relationships based on perceived differences between the sexes” and as “a primary way of signifying relationships of power” (Scott, 1986: 1076). That differences are perceived is to say that certain distinctions are deemed to be significant within a particular social system: differences do not exist in and of themselves. They are made differentiations: order from noise (Luhmann, 1984; von Förster, 2002). In this sense, gender structures perception, implying a normative dimension of how human beings are expected to behave appropriately according to their “gender category.” Gender means hence the assumptions as well as the performance of practices in everyday life that are largely patterned via and in terms of a distinction between the perceived different sexes (Acker, 1992). Gender is an organizing principle within social relations whose fulfilment in terms of gendered expectations varies through time and space. Gendering institutional theory then means recognizing that the position and accessing of capitals of each particular actor, the regularized leaving and entering of positions and the particular prescribed actions differ in terms of gender. Furthermore, gender is crucial in understanding how actors are created through social interactions with other actors through mutual behavioural expectation according to the respective cultural beliefs: women become women, men become men. Gender is happening at a micro – and macro level - and serves therefore as an analytic observable to understand legitimation processes of power. 2. 2 Methods and blind spots The following section is dedicated to a detailed description of the methods applied within my research, as well as their limitations and blind spots. In order to get an accurate picture of the situation in Chiloé in regard to sustainable development, I based my study on a triangulation of quantitative and qualitative methods as well as literature review. My main concerns were to disaggregate information by sex, to distinguish practices from discourse, and to avoid stereotyped categories (e.g. the category “housewife” precludes the actual activities of women) as far as possible. The first pillar of methods presents a two- week field work in August 2010 in Chiloé. During the field work, my colleague from Rimisp and I conducted 29 semi-structured interviews (17 men, 12 women) with local actors including current and former salmon workers, managerial 14 | P a g e level professionals in salmon industry, local government representatives, union leaders, farmers, artisans, historians, non-governmental organization representatives, and smallbusiness owners. Besides, we made a mixed-sex focus group of salmon industry union leaders composed of workers, and former salmon workers. For all interviews as well as for the focus groups, both my colleague and I remained always together for having two perspectives on the answers. In some interviews as well as in the focus group a local guide has been present to facilitate the interviews in cases of misunderstandings of local language/expressions. Both interviews and focus group have been tape recorded (authorized recording) in order to assure a backup of data. Additionally, some parts of the interviews have been transcribed by a native speaker. Furthermore, I had access to 9 transcriptions of interviews as well as a female focus group conducted during previous field work in Chiloé in 2009 by a research team of Rimisp on the subject of sustainable development and territorial dynamics. Interviewees were hereby union leaders, historians, local government officials, farmers, artisans, and professionals in salmon industry. Albeit interview questions had not been explicitly disaggregated by sex (that is, they did not ask specifically about men and women), they nevertheless provided gender related information. Second, I used the statistical analysis of data from a survey of 856 rural and urban households in Chiloé, administered in year 2009 by Rimisp and Woods Institute for the Environment, Stanford University. The survey was conducted according to the rules of statistical representativity. The survey allowed disaggregation of data of each survey question, the corresponding questions to each used data base will be cited in footnotes. Finally, I reviewed legal primary data including The General Law of Fishing and Aquaculture, as well as secondary literature on the salmon industry as published by e.g. The Universidad Austral de Chile and different NGOs (e.g. Rimisp, Fundación Terram) and on the history of Chiloé –as e.g. fundamental works of Rudolfo Urbina Burgos (1990), and Phillipe Grenier (1984). Each of the used methods shows shortcomings and blind spots – apart from the problem that there is always data missing. Disaggregating data by sex – whether within a statistical survey, 15 | P a g e interviews, or literature - reduces a diversity of realities and experiences to two purportedly homogenous blocks of material, and furthermore, to only two gender categories. Asking questions in interviews already directs the interviewed person in a certain direction. Furthermore, the answers given by the interviewed persons cannot be taken as unquestionable “truth”, but – as the common sense would suggest– are always subjective. And, of course, the interviewing person has an effect on the interviewed person – in this case, a gender-effect: since both my college and I range in the category “women”, answers might have been different if both of us would have been “men. Interviewed women perceived us sometimes as compañera de lucha, some men might have felt forced to say something positive about “women”. Within the focus group the limitation consists in the fact of having been a mixedsexed group. While discussion revealed interesting tensions in regard to gender relations, the persons present in the focus group may have expressed different opinions and information if given the opportunity to discuss the issues in single-sex groups. The blind spot in the survey presents the formulation of certain survey questions and categories within the survey (such as dueña de casa) that might preclude or hide information about actual practices and at the same time convey ideological meanings that influence empirical material. Furthermore, the administration of the survey to the jefe/a de hogar (head of household), who spoke as the “representative” of other household member might have biased answers within the survey expressing the experience of adult males more than other genders and generations. Finally, I am just a human being with my own perception, and equipped with a baggage of theoretical assumptions that “decides what can be observed” (Einstein, 1926) 2. 3 Times and spaces The spatial focus point of my research is concentrated on Chiloé, the second largest island in Chile. Chiloé is marked by three characteristics: infinite rain, infinite forests, and the infinite sea. Chiloé’s geography and climate is particularly favourable for aquaculture - disposing of large lakes with high oxygen levels and a suitable salinity of the ocean waters. However, this favourability is not to find all over Chiloé: Contrary to the inner sea on the east coast, the high seas of the west coast are not especially apt for salmon farming. 16 | P a g e The spatial choice of central Chiloé is therefore due to the fact that the socio-economic changes catalyzed by the establishment of the salmon industry are most profound in this territory relative to the rest of Chiloé (Modrego et al., 2008; Ramírez et al., 2009a). Central Chiloé comprises an area of 3.412 km2, six municipalities (Dalcahue, Castro, Curaco de Vélez, Quinchao, Chonchi, and Puqueldón), and a population of 79,000 people, of which approximately 48% resides in rural areas and 50% resides in the municipality of Castro, the functional centre of the territory (Modrego et al., 2008; Ramírez et al., 2009a; Macé & Bornschlegl, 2010). The temporal framework is divided into the periods 1960 – 1990 and 1990 - 2009. The beginning benchmark of the first period is the earthquake of 1960, while the year 1990 marks the consolidation of the salmon industry (initiated in 1978) and coincides with the governmental change in Chile. The second period is set from the consolidation of the salmon industry until year 2009aligning with previous research in territorial dynamics (Ramírez et al., 2009a; Ramírez et al., 2009b; Ramírez et al., 2010), and their most recent data set available. From 2007 onwards, the salmon industry experiences until recently a crisis in the salmon industry due to the ISA virus3 - however the latest development dynamics due to that crisis could not have been taken more specifically into account. By marking spatial and temporal limits within the framework, it is not to say that I do not see Chiloé as a part of longer global history. Nevertheless, the complexity of national and international contexts could not be considered explicitly within this study. 3 “Infectious salmon anemia (ISA) is one of the most important viral diseases of farmed Atlantic salmon.[…] Small changes in these viruses, analogous to the mutations that allow low pathogenicity avian influenza viruses to become highly pathogenic, may allow them to become more virulent. Recent evidence also suggests that some ISA viruses may cause illness in species other than Atlantic salmon. One isolate has been linked to illness among farmed Pacific coho salmon in Chile, and a highly virulent strain can cause disease in experimentally infected rainbow trout.” (Center for Food Security & Public Health, 2010, in: Macé & Bornschlegl, 2010). 17 | P a g e 3 Gender and sustainable development 3. 1 What is the (sustainability) issue in Chiloé? I think that in Chiloé there wasn’t any development of the salmon industry, but just the growth of the salmon industry [..] There wasn’t a development of the industry, a development that would have taken into account the environmental, social, labour conditions, the place where to include those, that was never really considered.4 Governmental officials, Interview, 2009 3. 1. 1 The salmon boom In order to define the problems of sustainability in Chiloé it is worth looking at the island’s history from 1960 onwards that is closely linked to the establishment of the Chilean salmon industry. Salmon – the third most important sector of Chile’s export industry5 - is not native to Chilean waters. Experiments in cultivating salmon in Chile could be dated back to the end of the 19th century, but they did not turn until the late 80s into the size of an industry. However- once off the starting blocks, salmon farming became a whiz kid in terms of economic growth: its production increased from 29 metric tons by 1990 up to 506 metric tons by 2002, pushing Chile worldwide in the rank of the second biggest producer of farmed (Montero, 2004). Chiloé is hereby not only the place where the story of industrial salmon ranching in Chile began, but forms part of the region De Los Lagos where still the lion’s share - about 80%- of Chilean salmon is produced. For Chiloé’s inhabitants, the establishment of the salmon industry meant a radical transformation. Within only 25 years Chiloé’s economy changed from one mainly based on substance agriculture into one lead by an export-oriented, highly concentrated, transnational industry – the globalized salmon cluster. Among the most manifest alterations for the local population in terms of livelihood strategies might count the development of the formal labor market. Whereas wage labor previously had “Es que yo creo que en Chiloé no hubo un desarrollo del salmón, sino que hubo un crecimiento de la industria […]No hubo un desarrollo de la industria, no hubo en el fondo un desarrollo tomando en cuenta las condiciones ambientales, sociales, laborales, el lugar donde están insertos, eso nunca se considero.” 5 C.f. ProChile foreign trade statistics: http://www.prochile.cl/servicios/estadisticas/exportaciones.php. 4 18 | P a g e been quasi non-existent in Chiloé, earning an income then became an essential pillar of Chilote livelihood strategies. The shift of the local livelihood strategies happened mostly on expense of the agricultural sector that got largely abandoned over time. Salmon farming turned into one of the main employers in Chiloé, generating not only direct occupations, but related business options like transport, services and fish meal production6. In sum, Chiloé experienced a rise in income and a reduction in poverty that surpassed the national average (Ramirez et al, 2009a), commonly linked to the salmon boom. However, it is not all roses. The economic ascension of the salmon industry entailed several social and ecological problems that will be classified in the following along the five lines of my chosen definition of sustainable development.7 3.1.2 Regarding social sustainability Regarding the social dimension of sustainable development, the main problems coalesce around aspects of local participation in the decision-making concerning Chiloé, an equitable distribution of opportunities and income, and economic diversity. First, the financial distribution in Chiloé is not really a fair sharing: the regional Gini-coefficient remains with 0.54 relatively high (Modrego et al, 2008). This income disparity cannot only be explained by the fact that non-salmon occupations aren’t that profitable. While the profit of the salmon industry increased over 540% between the years 1990 and 2000, the average salary within the salmon industry augmented only about 84% over time8 (Muñoz, 2004) Higher positions are generally held by people from outside Chiloé, whereas the productive infantry - operarios (salmon workers) – are mainly made up by the local population. The salary of operarios oscillates around Chile’s minimum wage of USD $ 334 per month.9 According to the Chiloé household survey, 63% of men and 71% of women By 2008, more than 45% of the economically active population of the communes of Chiloé central – except Castro where it is about one third – was employed within the aquaculture sector; 25% directly in the salmon industry (Macé & Bornschlegl, 2010). 7 Other issues of ecological sustainability in Chiloé that are, e.g. related to the forest management will not be considered within this study. 8 Observation made by Felipe Montiel within an international seminar held by CEPAL in the year 2002; in: Muñoz, 2004. 9 National minimum wage is 172.000 Chilean pesos per month, equivalent to approximately USD 334 monthly. http://www.lanacion.cl/senado-dio-luz-verde-a-salario-minimo-de-172-mil/noticias/201006-30/205317.html (Macé & Bornschlegl, 2010). 6 19 | P a g e working in the salmon industry earn a wage between USD $ 10 and USD $ 20 per day, or USD $ 200-400 per month (Macé & Bornschlegl, 2010; Rimisp & Stanford University, 2009). Operarios are furthermore subjected to unsecure working conditions and poor labour regulations: constant exposure to humidity and cold at the working place as well as the monotony of the work movements lead to chronic diseases as e.g. arthritis, lumbago and tendinitis. To this adds a high risk of working accidents of which some are fatal (Carrasco et al, 2000). Additionally, salmon workers experience an increase in precarious employment that can be best described as the “informalization of the formal”: while initially indefinite contracts were more common within the industry, over time the proportion of fixed-term or temporary contracts in both direct employment with salmon companies and subcontracts with secondary firms had been rising. Depending on available fish stocks, firms employ on a fixed-term basis, often with one to three-month contracts, after which workers are fired and usually rehired in one to six months. Short-term contracts entail that workers have no rights to benefits such as vacations or indemnity, and they have no guarantee of being rehired (Macé & Bornschlegl, 2010). Moreover, conflicts have been arising between the salmon industry and other economic sectors mainly linked to agriculture, artisan fishing and tourism. Their economic activities are bothered about the salmon industry through competition in labor force, use of marine areas, and landscape degradation. The dominance of the salmon industry inhibits therefore more economic diversity and economic self-reliance manifest in the creation of a local market and greater cooperation among local economic entities. Finally, the major part of the local population in Chiloé cannot be called an “empowered citizenry” (Young, 1990) effectively included in the decision- making process regarding the future and development of Chiloé. The local population is not consulted when it comes to questions whether public funds in Chiloé should be invested in a casino on site, or rather in a hospital. 3. 1. 3 Regarding ecological sustainability In terms of the ecological dimension I identify three major problems related to the salmon industry in Chiloé: energy use, waste management, and marine biodiversity. 20 | P a g e First, the Chilean production process of farmed salmon does not show a positive energy balance. The amount of feed necessary for to raise one kilo of salmon is made of approximately three to five kilo of other fish processed to fish meal and fish oil. While the gross feed conversation ratio (FCR) of salmon farming in Norway is 1.1 tons of feed per ton of salmon, the one in Chile is nearly 1.5: 1. Also Chilean on-farm energy use per ton of salmon is 85% higher than the one of Norway – what translate into the corresponding amount in global warming and acidifying emissions (Pelletier et al, 2009). Second, there is a problem with the waste generated by the production of farmed salmon. Litter from the salmon plants is polluting broad areas in Chiloé as there aren’t adequate landfills for depositing - in Castro alone there are counted 45 illegal landfills. Even more important is the contamination of the water: waste such as faeces and feed rests from the cultivated fish causes an augmentation of phosphorus (P) and nitrogen (N) in the water head within the salmon cages, the reduction of oxygen, an alteration of the pH value of the water and therefore eutrophication of marine areas and lakes. Sunken waste material changes furthermore the structure of the ground sediments (Pinto, 2007). Third, salmon farming also tend to endanger the biodiversity in Chiloé: when salmons escape from the cages, they compete for food with native species and risk spreading diseases. Even if there isn’t yet enough research done to allow the account of a direct causality, one can nevertheless state: the more escaped salmon the less native species exist (Soto & Moreno, 2001). The magnitude of all three problem dimensions depends, beside the topography and morphology of the water area, on the density of fish per cages, on the density of the cages within one area as well as on the quality of feed, the technology and the used material. The litmus test whether sustainable development in Chiloé with the salmon industry would not be anyway a contradiction in terms, remains undecided. A step towards sustainable development in Chiloé could mean to reduce the amount of fish per cages, and cages per area. According to Pelletier et al (2009) Chile’s salmon production could transform into the least environmental harmful in terms of energy use worldwide if the same FCR efficiency as Norway would be achieved. Yet, the scale of potential replacement of feed remains constrained by alternative product availability on global markets. 21 | P a g e 3. 2 Chiloé: Distribution of capitals & livelihood strategies In the mid-eighties Chiloé was known as an area of potatoes, of wheat, of oat, and the sectors of the island have been rather isolated from all those productive centres, commercial centres, the today’s concept of the mall did not exist”10 Artisan Fisher, Interview, 2009 Now that we have defined the problems within sustainable development in Chiloé, we can ask: what has gender to do with it? Hereby, it is worth looking first at the distribution of capitals in the context of the livelihood strategies of local people before and after the establishment of the salmon industry. 3. 2. 1 Chiloé 1960 – 1990 The livelihoods strategies of men and women within the period 1960 to 1990 of central Chiloé were embedded mainly in an agricultural-based economy directed largely towards subsistence. Export products included potatoes, timber, wool and, to some extent, grains. However, most of the production, including pigs, sheep and artisan fishing, was absorbed by internal consumption. As livelihood strategies within agriculture were tied to Chiloé’s climate, they varied according to the seasonal calendar. The production unit of the primarily rural population was based on the minifundio (small agricultural holding) which often has been seen as a barrier to agricultural development. From the early 60s onward, livelihood strategies started to include tourism as well as beginning fishing industries (artisanal fishing, shellfish canning industry, as well as the first salmon farms). All in all, Chiloé remained a national “problem child” until the 1980s, or, in the words of Urbina (1996): “Poor agriculture, poorly organized fishing despite the enormous potential, no industrial activity.”11 In a context of poverty, marginality and the minifundio, migration was one of the few ways to get access to economic capital in terms monetary income. From the turn of the century onwards, emigration from Chiloé was significant, fluctuating according to local work opportunities and the national economic situation. While emigration took a definitive as well 10 “Mitad de los ochenta se conocía mucho a Chiloé como una zona de papas, de trago, de avena, y los sectores isleños eran sectores más bien aislados de todos estos centros productivos, centros comerciales, no existía el concepto de mall que hay hoy día.” 11 “Pobre agricultura, pesca mal organizada a pesar del enorme potencial, nula actividad industrial.” 22 | P a g e as a temporal shape, especially the latter is interesting in regard to my study: like forestry and fishing, temporal migration has been chiefly men’s affair for Chilote residents.12 Chilote men left the archipelago normally in November after the potato harvest and stayed away until March. Destinations of their migrations were Argentina and mainland Chile, particularly the zone of Magallanes, Coyhaique-Aysén, Osorno, Llanquihue, where they worked as shearers, or the nitrate fields and mines of Northern Chile. Chilote workers were, albeit appreciated by their employees as “hard workers”, not paid majestically (Urbina, 1996). The income, if not spent otherwise during the trip home, was invested in the maintenance of their farms and fields. Men’s migration tended to leave Chiloé’s demography female-biased. For example, the census for Castro in the year 1960 indicates: 7,609 men and 10,653 women residents (Urbina, 1996). Numerous consulted residents stated that women’s business consisted mainly of “maintaining the house” which, if asked what activities that would have included, encompassed not less than: the education of children, looking after animals, tending the vegetable patch, cooking, and collecting shellfish and seaweed. Additionally, women also did all of the agricultural work labeled as “men’s” tasks: chopping wood, plowing, sowing, and harvesting - especially if the male labor force stayed away longer than expected. Furthermore, typically women were engaged in spinning, weaving, and artisan wool work.13 However, none of women’s livelihood strategies were remunerated in monetary terms. As described by a local government administrator in an interview, they were matriarcas sin recursos (matriarchs without resources), disposing of a large cultural capital, but depending on the economic capital that men brought home from migration. During the harvesting period of the year, both women and men were involved. While it was typically men’s work to sow, cut and scythe, women’s work was to collect and bale the yield within the threshing and to select potatoes from the potatoes harvest, managing both germplasm and nutrition resources. Bigger agricultural work was organized in form of the minga – a system of cooperation between neighbours exchanging labour force for labour 12 C.f. Mancilla & Rehbein, 2007. It is not clear to which date this activity can be dated back. While one interviewed anthropologist stated: “1975 empieza a desarrollarse la artesanía en lana, y la artesanía vegetal acá” a Chilote author said that already 120 years ago a market for wool and wool products existed in Dalcahue. 13 23 | P a g e force without any monetary payment. Within mingas the labour division between men and women and the correlated cultural capital remained the same as described above. In resume, the discursive norm states that while men’s livelihood strategies were centered in the external space - the outdoors, the forest, the sea - women’s space was indoors. However, whereas men stayed in their domain, women crossed those borders; as expressed by a local anthropologist in an interview: “Women develop all activities, they know [how to do] all the activities that men know, but men don’t know all the activities of women.”14 While the different sources allow an approximate assessment of cultural capital and economic capital in terms of gender, it is difficult to ascertain the social capital distribution of men and women within the social sphere during the period in question. We can infer from the general tendency within interviews where residents stated that women “participated little in community development” (Local historian, Interview, 2010)15 that they might have had less public social contacts as men. Considering the geography of rural Chiloé where distances between neighbors are often great, women might have remained quite isolated within the boundaries of their defined space, whereas men tended to have had more regular occasions to socialize: in bars, on migration – especially the latter was rather a group enterprise based largely on male kinship relations. Like social capital, it remains also problematic to assess exactly the natural capital distribution in gender terms, apart from the fact that land estates have rather belonged to men, while the sea was anyway common property. However, it is sure to say that people describe the distribution of all capitals as based on the belief of inherent qualities of each perceived sex. According to numerous consulted residents, women during the period in question are labeled as encargada de la casa (in charge of the house), and hogareña” (housewife); described as passive, albeit strong, with a special sense for tidiness. They are described in interviews as equipped with patience and with delicate “Las mujeres desarrollan todas las actividades, sí sabe todas las actividades que sabe el hombre, y el hombre no sabe todas las de la mujer.” 15 “Atrás lo veía una mujer pasiva, poco participativa en cuanto al desarrollo comunitario, poca participación.” 14 24 | P a g e hands required for “manipulating the cooking,” for grinding the flour, for spinning and weaving. Local actors also ascribe to the mother the responsibilities of transmitting knowledge of “traditional” Chiloéan culture. And, as it should be the concern of a woman to maintain the family, it is bad manners if she would waste resources on goods and alcohol outside the home. Men, on the contrary, according to descriptions of the époque in the literature16 and in interviews, waste money on alcohol, they are coarse, and they have strong hands to do hard physical labor in the field. Above all, men are viajeros (travellers): beyond generating income, migrations to mainland Chile fulfilled the function of “becoming a man.”17 Manhood was, furthermore, achieved through working – a man without work is a humiliated man.18 Chilote society during 1960-1990 is said to have been dominated by machismo and the jefe de hogar (head of household). As stated by multiple interviewees, women were “enclosed” in the house, obedient to the father and after marriage, to the husband. Nevertheless, it was not a standard machismo; it was a “matriarchal machismo”: interviewees stated that women supported macho attitudes by accepting them, and promoting them in ways such as educating children in tasks distributed by sex. Even more significant, it was a “machismo matriarchy:” women were, albeit indirectly, engaged in the decision-making, since even if the husband made the final decision, the consulted opinion of his wife was crucial. The idea of the matriarchy reverberated also in the attitudes in Chiloé towards single women with children. Rather than being rejected or marginalized, they were supported by the community. In sum, the matriarcado machista- as the Chiloéan society of that époque is labeled by literature and local informants – was a normative system that did not punish “strong” women who do “masculine” tasks; however the contrary did not hold true. “New” models of masculinity and femininity began to arrive to the territory through the Puerto Libre19 in the 1950s and through radio (and later television) from the 1960s onward. 16 Cf. Montiel, 2003; Urbina, 1996; Uribe, 2003. According to Maffesoli (2004), “El nomadismo no está determinado únicamente por la necesidad económica o la simple funcionalidad, es una especie de pulsión migratoria que incita al hombre a cambiar de lugar y de hábitos para alcanzar plenamente las diversas facetas de su personalidad, sólo accesible a través de la confrontación con lo extraño” in: Mancilla & Rehbein, 2007. 18 “Cuando un hombre no puede trabajar se siente muy humillado, se siente muy mal, pero sí siempre salimos delante de todas las cosas con eso” (Indigenous woman, Interview, 2010) 19 The Puerto Libre was a tax-free- trading area in Castro. E.g. it was cheaper to buy a car in Chiloé than on continental Chile. 17 25 | P a g e These models were absorbed by the youth, which was the most significant group within Chiloé’s demography during the 1970s: the “American way of life” seemed appealing to young men and women (Urbina, 1996). Lastly, the status of a man started to be defined more by economic capital than by personality and hard work.20 In terms of symbolic capital there already had been coming a shift of the trumps within in the card game of capitals. 3. 2. 2 Chiloé 1990 – 200921 Since the installation of the first salmon farm in Chiloé, a growing portion of the local labor force started to work in the salmon industry. The major reason mentioned by men and women interviewees on the question why they started work in the salmon industry, reflect the increased importance of economic capital in Chiloé: the salmon industry offered the opportunity to get a monetary income. Even if modest, the steady monthly wage opened access to credit and services, home loans, and consumer goods. The proximity of the salmon industry in Chiloé not only eliminated the need for men to migrate, but furthermore allowed women to also earn money without being forced to abandon their home-based labor. Since the salmon farms and processing plants are spread along the shores of Chiloé’s mainland and smaller islands, they opened up the occasion to work for money close to home even for remote rural populations. Particularly young men and women had been attracted by the option of monetary income since the beginning of the industry. As stated by several interviewees, still today natural capital such as land is not inherited by children until mature adulthood; therefore access to economic capital meant independence from the parents and a way of life the youth no longer felt committed to. The shift to salaried work has hereby often led to a gradual abandonment of agriculture due to the time-consuming, physical labor it entails, and the rather diminishing profit it generates. It was also stated by several interviewees that the prospect to meet colleagues at work motivated men and women to work in the salmon industry. This social dimension can be “Un hombre valía ahora mucho más por sus bienes materiales que por lo que representaba su persona. Entre los comerciantes importadores se podía reconocer lo que cada uno era capaz de presumir por la plata que tenía. (Urbina 1996) 21 The section “Chiloé 1990-2009” is mainly based on the writings of Julie Claire Macé within our DTR-report 2010. 20 26 | P a g e understood considering the already mentioned geographic isolation of Chiloé’s rural areas, and seemed to have been especially appealing for women. Whereas interviewees claim the entry into the salmon industry was “gender neutral”, they perceive a strong division of labor: men tend to be assigned towards tasks identified as “heavier”, and “harder” in the centros de cultivo (salmon cultivation centers)22, whereas women are given jobs identified as “delicate” or “detailed” in the plantas de proceso (processing plants).23 Women’s work within the plantas de proceso consists in assembly line de-scaling and cleaning salmon, extracting the spine and bones, packaging for export, and quality control.24 During the early stage of the salmon industry, women charged with the feeding of the salmon in the centros de cultivo, but those tasks have become mostly mechanized over time. According to a Manager of Cultivation Centre, men make up only 30% of labor in the plantas de proceso where they are assigned tasks such as filleting or removing heads, tails, and entrails, whereas 95% of the labor force within centros de cultivo is men (Macé & Bornschlegl, 2010). Men are working on the rafts and cages at the centros de cultivo, or working as buzo (diver) responsible for the repair and cleaning of the nets within the cages; men are operating machinery and navigating boats. They are also working in services related to the salmon industry such as construction, maintenance, transport, and security. Furthermore, high position such as managers and supervisors are generally held by men. And while none of the interviewed actors had ever seen a man doing women’s “delicate” task, women were said to occasionally also taking over some of men’s “heavier” tasks within plantas de proceso (Macé & Bornschlegl, 2010). 22 Centros de cultivos are located along the shoreline and their main function is to raise salmon and control its lifecycle: feeding, health and sanitation, etc. After approximately 10-13 months, salmon are “harvested” and transported to plantas de proceso (Pinto, 2007). 23 In plantas de proceso, salmon is converted into a value-added product. Harvested salmon are transported to the plants, where they are processed, which may include eviscerating, removing head and tail, fileting, deboning, washing, weighing and classification, freezing, removing scales, and packaging for shipment (Pinto, 2007). 24 The household survey data confirms that view showing that more women than men working in processing in 1990 and 2008 (Macé & Bornschlegl, 2010). . 27 | P a g e Interviewed managers, union organizers, and operarios alike agreed that there are no noteworthy income differences where men and women are accomplishing the same function. Nonetheless: different tasks are paid different amounts. The filleting of the salmon will be slightly better paid than other assembly line jobs, due to the necessary skill for performing a premium cut.25 Workers operating machinery, as supervisors, or as buzo will also earn a higher salary - as those tasks are said to be more complex or risky. Thus, while there is no explicit wage difference in gender terms, there is however an implicit once since the differently paid jobs are gendered. However, higher positions tend to be stuffed by “qualified” people from outside the island, while local labor force is employed mostly as low salaried operarios. Along with salmon industry shifted the cultural capital in Chiloé: First, we can observe that “new” knowledge and practices were introduced - not only in terms of higher valued skills related to formal academic education – what shall become the dominant cultural capital. Furthermore, new cultural capital got generated over the time through the creation of work experience: interviewees stated that an experienced operario will easier get hired than a nonexperienced one- though that kind of skill remains unpaid. The designation of tasks within the industry in gender terms helps hereby to assure the continuum of a newly created tradition. Second, interviewees as well as the household survey data tell that cultural capital related to agriculture decreases for both women and men over the period in question. However, that decrease of former cultural capital does not hold true for other “traditional” Chilote knowledge and practices - mainly such that can be translated into economic capital. Processed salmon is differently categories according to the quality. The category “premium”- a filet without fish skin and without fish bones - is the most expensive one. 25 28 | P a g e 1990 Change (+/-) 1990-2009 2009 Type of cultural knowledge Count % of total Count % of total Count change in % of total Wool-based crafts (spinning, knitting, weaving) 16.507 10,6 17.395 11,0 888 0,4 Wood-based crafts 2.425 1,6 1.709 1,1 -717 -0,5 Boat construction 651 0,4 203 0,1 -448 -0,3 Forest management 8.011 5,1 5.721 3,6 -2.290 -1,5 Land management 19.707 12,7 18.030 11,4 -1.677 -1,2 Small animal and livestock raising 19.652 12,6 17.726 11,2 -1.927 -1,4 Sea navigation 3.634 2,3 2.226 1,4 -1.408 -0,9 Diving 323 0,2 327 0,2 4 0,0 Shellfish collecting 18.232 11,7 17.499 11,1 -733 -0,6 Myths, tales, and stories of Chiloé 21.749 14,0 25.617 16,2 3.868 2,3 Chilote cuisine 22.140 14,2 26.169 16,6 4.029 2,4 Minga, religious festivals, dances 22.677 14,6 25.304 16,0 2.627 1,5 Total (N) 155.710 100 157.926 100 Table A: Women’s cultural capital per year, and differences between 1990 and 2009 Source: Rimisp – Latin American Center for Rural Development & Woods Institute for the Environment, Stanford University. (2009). Chiloé Household Survey; Macé & Bornschlegl, 2010. Survey responses reveal that the frequency of cultural capital related explicitly to Chilote identity – such as knitting/weaving, woodworking, forest management, local cuisine, navigation, local myths and history – increases over time among both men and women (See table A and B) (Macé & Bornschlegl, 2010). 29 | P a g e 1990 Change (+/-) 1990-2009 2009 Type of cultural knowledge Count % of total Count % of total Count change in % of total Wool-based crafts (spinning, knitting, weaving) 4.510 3,0 1.406 0,9 -3.105 -2,1 Wood-based crafts 6.809 4,6 7.447 4,9 639 0,3 Boat construction 2.182 1,5 1.956 1,3 -226 -0,2 Forest management 12.271 8,2 13.013 8,5 742 0,3 Land management 20.203 13,5 19.543 12,8 -660 -0,7 Small animal and livestock raising 20.111 13,5 19.078 12,5 -1.033 -1,0 Sea navigation 6.559 4,4 8.016 5,2 1.458 0,9 Diving 645 0,4 1.544 1,0 899 0,6 Shellfish collecting 17.504 11,7 16.904 11,1 -600 -0,7 Myths, tales, and stories of Chiloé 20.398 13,7 24.688 16,2 4.290 2,5 Chilote cuisine 15.622 10,5 14.718 9,6 -904 -0,8 Minga, religious festivals, dances 22.420 15,0 24.429 16,0 2.010 1,0 Total (N) 149.233 100 152.743 100 Table B: Men’s cultural capital per year, and differences between 1990 and 2009 Source: Rimisp – Latin American Center for Rural Development & Woods Institute for the Environment, Stanford University. (2009). Chiloé Household Survey; Macé & Bornschlegl, 2010. Interestingly, differences between men’s and women’s profiles increase for most of the cultural knowledge domains. Certainly, between 1990 and 2009, no change is observed in the fact that more men have knowledge in navigation and forest management, and more women know how to knit and cook. Nevertheless, these differences become much more pronounced over time. In the distribution of cultural capital still in 1990, men and women shared knowledge in many fields, minga and religious festivals, shellfish collecting, and land management. However, the distributional pattern in 2009 show that these domains of shared knowledge become more divided by gender over time. Thus, there is an increase in the differences between men and women’s types of knowledge for nearly every domain: cultural capital became highly gendered in comparison to the distributional patterns of the past (See table C). 30 | P a g e 1990 2009 Change in difference (+/-) 1990-2009 Type of cultural knowledge Difference (N men N women) Difference (N men N women) Count (N ) Wool-based crafts (spinning, knitting, weaving) 11.997 15.989 3.992 Wood-based crafts -4.383 -5.738 1.355 Boat construction -1.532 -1.753 222 Forest management -4.260 -7.292 3.032 Land management -496 -1.513 1.017 Small animal and livestock raising -459 -1.352 893 Sea navigation -2.925 -5.790 2.865 Diving -322 -1.217 895 Shellfish collecting 729 595 -133 Myths, tales, and stories of Chiloé 1.352 929 -422 Chilote cuisine 6.519 11.451 4.932 Minga, religious festivals, dances 258 875 617 Total (N) 35.232 54.494 % change in Total (1990 to 2009) Table C: Differences in men and women’s cultural capital per year, and the change in differences in 1990 and 2009 Source: Rimisp – Latin American Center for Rural Development & Woods Institute for the Environment, Stanford University. (2009). Chiloé Household Survey; Macé & Bornschlegl, 2010. 55% Also for the period 1990 -2009, the distribution of all different capitals is based on a gendered belief and perception of capabilities, and behaviors. For instance, within the context of the salmon industry, typical characteristics to describe women are: sensitive, productive, efficient, dedicated, responsible, rigorous, meticulous, and agile. Women are assigned tasks such as extracting the spine and bones, and to do the quality control because they have “fine delicate hands”, and “attention to detail”. Male workers generally are seen as strong, clumsy, brutish, with a tendency towards alcoholism and lateness, yet better able to take on risky, machine-based, or supervisory positions (Macé & Bornschlegl, 2010). 31 | P a g e Middle managers, the same people from the company, of course, they prefer for everything that has to do with handling, women. And everything that’s heavy work, one can say rough [work], less meticulous, men (Former salmon worker, Interview, 2010).26 Gender beliefs influence the hiring patterns: women come to be associated with certain jobs, and men with others, while on the supply side of labor, men and women adapt their behavior to fulfill these expectations. Nevertheless, the model of femininity remains focused around the house and the corresponding tasks as mother and wife. Albeit women started to work full-time in salaried occupations, domestic tasks such as cooking, cleaning, and raising children continues to typically fall on them. Besides, globally dominant trends can also be found in Chiloé: women preoccupied with wrinkles and weight; young girls dyeing their hair blonde to mimic women they see on television; and young men buying the latest hi-fi equipment to assure the echo of their masculinity (Macé & Bornschlegl, 2010). So, why is it important to look at the distribution of capitals in gender terms? What does it tell in regard to the identified sustainability problems? First, the distribution of capitals and livelihoods by gender in Chiloé generated an experience that provided the salmon industry with an already “trained” local labor force - nevertheless that experience mostly remained classified as “unskilled”, and therefore not worth to pay off. Due to Chiloé’s climate, historically, the population of the island was experienced in harsh working conditions. This could have come in handy in the salmon industry whose occupations at the base of the production process (where most Chilotes are employed) are generally described as tough work, mostly in a cold and humid environment. As men’s knowledge and practices were all about the sea, that might have found application in the cultivation centers. And while Chilote migrants were appreciated on the Argentinean and Chilean mainland for their “character” as tough workers without demanding much pay, the same holds true within the salmon industry: “Los mandos medios, la misma gente de la empresa, claro, ellos prefieren para todo lo que sea manipulación, mujeres. Y todo los que es trabajo pesado, brusco se puede decir, menos minuciosa, hombres.” 26 32 | P a g e Well, now one didn’t have to leave and people didn’t go to Argentina but instead worked here, of course some said, ‘Shoot, now we’re exploited on our own land, before we were exploited outside,’ some said, ‘now we’re exploited here’ (Local historian, Interview, 2010).27 This issue is even more crucial considering the case of women. The role that Chilote women fulfilled previously to the salmon industry provided them with knowledge and practices that facilitated the entry into the canning industry, and later the salmon industry. Since women were assigned to do the “fine work” like spinning and weaving, they disposed of the necessary training in fine motor skills required in the industry. The weaving leads to the “needlework” of removing fish bones, the quality selection of potatoes turns into the quality selection of salmon filets, the feeding of small animals in the yard provides the necessary sense for feeding fish in the cultivation centers. As we have seen, women were also well-accustomed to hard work in the pre-salmon-society, so they could stand the physically demanding working conditions in the industry. Furthermore, the plurality of tasks they confronted in daily life within Chilote society before the salmon industry may have made it possible for them to deal with the flexibility required by the industry in day-by-day work assignments: I think there was some legacy of women in the sense, say, in manual labor that her grandparents taught her, or in farm work, for example, with work, say, in cooking, work in developing products, I think that she already had experience. So, basically [the industry] replicated this experience (Local government administrator, Interview, 2010).28 Second, by consistently designating the same tasks to the same sex based on gender assumptions, the new industry “engendered” a new tradition. As stated by a cultivation center “Bueno ya no había que salir y la gente no se iba a Argentina sino que trabajaba aquí, claro que algunos decían chuta ahora somos explotados en nuestra propia tierra, antes eramos explotados afuera decían algunos, ahora somos explotados aquí mismo.” 28 “Yo creo que había una herencia un poco de la mujer en el sentido, digamos, por un trabajo manual que le enseñaban los abuelos o en el trabajo de la hacienda, por ejemplo, con el trabajo, digamos, de las comidas, con el trabajo de elaborar productos, yo creo que ya tenía una experiencia. Entonces, en el fondo replicó esa experiencia.” 27 33 | P a g e manager during an interview, the industry should put even more efforts in enforcing each sex’s “natural qualities”: […] specializing the sexes, helping them to strengthen, or giving them where women’s strengths are, which is the eye, the skill, land the mind. And the man, putting him a bit more in the more brutish work, where you can develop him more. I think we should continue in how the sexes are. 29 (Cultivation Center Manager, Interview, 2010) In this way, a new custom was created and with that custom experience – and again, experience that does not have to be paid. Indeed, no system of official certification documenting the work experience of operarios exists: even after several years in the industry: their work remains “unskilled” – and therefore without any regular “upgrading” of salary. This is even more important considering that some of the low-paid occupations like deboning are precisely the factors that add value to Chilean salmon in the international market. In sum, “cheap labor force” is one of the points commonly mentioned by the interviewed persons and by literature as a crucial explanatory factor for the success of the salmon industry (Carrasco et al, 2000; Montero, 2004; Díaz, 2003). The problem of low wages are hereby not only an essential point in terms of social sustainability, but also important for ecological sustainability. As Eduardo Silva (1996) points out: low labor prices are one the reasons that make the extension of old end-of-pipe- technology for firms more cost-competitive than the investment in improvements of the production processes in terms of less environmental harmful material and technology. In the next section, I will interrogate if the distribution of capitals affects also the formation of social coalitions, and how gender plays out in that regard. “[…]especializando los sexos, ayudándoles a fortalecer, o sea dándoles donde están las fortalezas de las mujeres, que es el ojo, la habilidad y la mente. Y al hombre poniéndolo un poco más en los trabajos más brutos, donde tú lo puedes desarrollar un poco más, o sea yo creo que seguiríamos como están los sexos.” 29 34 | P a g e 3. 3 Social coalitions When people notice that they are ignored, they just stop participating and that’s it […] 30 Work Union Leader, Interview, 2009 Nobody is wondering why those projects actually don’t work.31 Female Focus Group, 2009 What is needed is monitoring, because the laws do exist.32 Local Anthropologist, Interview, 2009 3.3. 1 Pro and contra salmon: social coalitions in Chiloé As stated in the theoretical framework, social coalitions of actors can influence the institutional framework to a degree that depends on the strength of the capitals accessed and mobilized by the corresponding actors forming the social coalition. The social coalition that largely defines the reality in and the development of Chiloé in terms of the institutional framework coalesces around the salmon industry, and encompasses the Chilean government (e.g. members of Parliament, Ministries, and administrative agencies), firms and investors linked to salmon production, and representatives of national media. (Ramírez et al, 2010).33 This social coalition is marked by organizational cooperation not only within entities on the public side as, e.g. Fundación Chile and ProChile as well as on the private side with the producers association SalmonChile, but also between private and public entities.34 The amalgam of this social coalition consists in shared interests such as economic growth, employment, foreign capital, and technological innovation. Those topics also serve as discursive base of legitimation for their operations and dominance acknowledged by parts of the local population in Chiloé. Albeit critical bodies exist such as social and environmental NGOs, local groups related to economic activities such as tourism, artisanal fishing, artisanal crafting, and some worker “Cuando la gente se da cuenta que no la consideras no participa nomás, entonces prefiere continuar con su vida diaria, que es el trabajo, el aislarse y el protegerse.” 31 “Nadie se cuestiona porque no funcionan estos proyectos.” 32 “Lo que se requiere es una fiscalización, porque están las leyes.” 33 Despite the ISA crisis the pro-salmon-coalition did not markedly lose strength (Ramirez et al., 2010). 34 This social coalition will be termed “pro-salmon-coalition” in the whole thesis, while the critic counterpart to the pro-salmon-coalition will be termed “counter-coalition”. 30 35 | P a g e unions, they did not succeed in forming a strong social coalition able to break the dominance of the pro-salmon alliance. Such counter- coalition could address the identified sustainability problems. In regard to economic diversity and self-reliance, that would mean to foster networks of alternative economic projects with local artisanal or agricultural products, artisanal fishing or with tourism. On a political level, a strong counter-coalition could potentially– via social inclusion- bring forward an ecologically sound and socially just legal framework. In the following, I will focus on the question what might have limited the impact of such counter- social coalition and on the gender component into that. Albeit I do not conflate participation in an organization with the automatic formation of social coalitions, I suggest that membership in organizations could serve as the first step and indicator of the forming of such. Therefore, I start by looking at the participation in organizations, including unions, social, political, and cultural organizations. 3. 3. 2 The matrix of social coalitions: participation in organizations35 The household survey (Rimisp & Stanford University, 2009) shows that the total number of men and women participating in political as well as non-political organizations increases between 1990 and 2009 (Macé & Bornschlegl, 2010). By 1990, the organizations ranked with the highest level of participation for both men and women are junta de vecinos in the first place, followed by sport clubs, and religious groups. By 2009 the order of highest participation for men stays the same, while the order of women’s participation changes to: first, junta de vecinos; second, religious groups, and third, educational groups (see table D). Contrary to widespread opinion of the interviewed actors, the household survey shows that men have a higher rate of participation in organizations than women. However, between 1990 and 2009 the number of female-dominated groups increases. For instance, groups such as housing committees, health association, religious and spiritual groups have a female majority (see table D). 35 The section 3.3.2 draws on parts originally written by Julie-Claire Macé within our DTR-report 2010. 36 | P a g e Table D: Social and political participation of men and women in year 1990 and 2009 Participation 1990 Participation 2009 Difference N men N women Men Women Count Total 1990 Count 6.983 5.899 12.881 1.084 Ethnic group 244 78 322 Political party 221 28 249 Housing committee 104 225 Religious or spiritual group 1.943 Union or trade association Cultural group or assoc. (folklore, etc.) Type of organization Neighborhood association (Junta de Vecinos) Men Women Count Count Total 2009 Difference N men N women 6.068 5.848 11.916 220 167 785 629 1.414 156 193 129 14 143 115 329 -121 230 595 825 -365 1.928 3.871 14 2.769 2.755 5.524 15 451 381 832 70 1.346 640 1.986 707 375 601 976 -227 679 528 1.207 152 Business association or other production group (tourism, etc.) Farmers' cooperative or association 25 106 131 -80 259 481 740 -223 586 480 1.066 106 535 521 1.056 13 Water or waste management group 112 35 147 77 2.142 1.370 3.512 771 43 73 116 -31 94 219 313 -125 74 163 237 -89 161 215 377 -54 3.860 804 4.664 3.057 5.817 1.228 7.045 4.588 219 1.178 1.397 -960 0 100 100 -100 0 31 31 -31 11 137 149 -126 259 741 1.000 -481 493 1.594 2.088 -1.101 95 44 139 51 583 715 1.298 -131 41 40 81 1 70 50 120 20 374 205 580 169 701 1.017 1.718 -316 16.009 13.039 29.048 7.009 22.873 18.657 41.530 9.297 Professional association (professors, veterans, academics, etc.) Artisan group Sporting club Mothers group (Centro de Madres) Youth group Education group (Parent-teacher association, etc.) Social action or charitable group Health association Other groups Total Source: Rimisp – Latin American Center for Rural Development & Woods Institute for the Environment, Stanford University. (2009). Chiloé Household Survey; Macé & Bornschlegl, 2010. The household survey data tells that organizations are becoming more polarized in their membership: differences between men and women’s participation become more pronounced over time. For instance, the participation in sporting groups is more male-dominated in 2009 than it has been in 1990. In general, women have stronger membership in organizations associated with the social and cultural realm, such as housing committees, and educationbased groups, while men participate more in sport clubs, councils, and work unions. That is, 37 | P a g e men and women’s work and social participation appear to be diverging over time into globally stereotype gender categories (see table D) (Macé & Bornschlegl, 2010). Within this development reverberate commonly hold gender beliefs about men and women: according to interviewees women are seen as having more commitment to the community and the communal, while men are said to generally lack interest and time to attend meetings since “they are working.” As a former director of PRODEMU observed, female-dominated groups would be also more sustainable through time fulfilling - beyond their official function- social purposes for their members. In other words, women “care” (Macé & Bornschlegl, 2010). Several interviewed actors perceive the participation of women in organizations and unions as new: women would have gained space, independence, and voice; they are “liberated” from the supremacy of men. Women are said to have expanded their roles as purely passive housewife by adopting new identities as workers and leaders. They are more active and confident: qualities that some attribute to the “Bachelet effect.” But despite the perception of women as innovadoras for the development and future of Chiloé, men are said to be taken more seriously than women in the public sphere: For example, it’s better that a man goes to a public office, they’ll give him a quicker answer maybe, and more specific, than if a woman goes, who doesn’t know how to move well within the public domain36 (Former PRODEMU director, Interview, 2010). Men are generally described by interviewees as less emotional and more rational than women – qualities that seem to make the better leader (Macé & Bornschlegl, 2010). Looking at participation in Chiloé not only in quantitative terms, but also in qualitative terms, the household survey reveals that while participation generally increases between 1990 and 2009, the quality of that participation diminishes over years.37 By 1990, 69% of all men, and “Por ejemplo es mejor que vaya un hombres a una oficina pública, le van dar una respuesta más rápida tal vez, y más concreta, que si va una mujer, que no sabe moverse bien en el ámbito público.” 37 This question was approached within the household survey 2009 by dividing the categories of participation into “high”, “medium”, and “low” (c.f. Macé & Yáñez, 2009). 36 38 | P a g e 61% of all women indicate that they would participate as actively involved members in their organization. By 2009, only 51% of all men and only 43% of all women remain committed members (Macé & Yáñez, 2009; Ramírez et al, 2010) – the latter is especially interesting in regard to the above mentioned perception about gained female space. But where does such participatory disenchantment stem from? 3. 3. 3 … towards economic diversity and self-reliance? While the system of economic “cooperativas” previous to the salmon industry is claimed to have worked rather well, interviewees perceive main problems on the level of economic organizations and participation in alternative development projects within the second time period of my research. First, several consulted actors stated that men and women in Chiloé would prefer to ask for charity rather than engaging actively in organizations themselves. This practice of asistencialismo (welfarism) is said to be complemented by a paternalismo (paternalism) on the part of governmental agencies such as the municipality. Instead of providing the necessary tools for “teaching how to fish”, the fish is simply given – what creates, wittingly or unwittingly- certain dependence. That is, no cultural capital in terms of knowledge and practices is generated. Paternalism is also said to be the reason why local men and women often are the lacking administrative and logistic skills necessary to lead an organization. Organizations fail because nobody knows “how to work together”, coordination is lacking and often the work load tends to fall on one single person. Second, interviewees mentioned the perceived ineffectiveness of encounters why men and women would be staying away from organizations: “We all should be furniture makers since this is the country of the round tables: round table for fishing, round table for agriculture, round table for tourism, round table for artisan crafters, round table for health; whatever problem, let’s just make a round table, but in the end, making round tables does not achieve anything; to 39 | P a g e be sure, it is an occasion of civil participation, but in the end, nothing concrete is achieved” 38 (Artisanal Fisher, Interview, 2009) Indeed, the household survey confirms that men and women in Chiloé perceive a loss in influence of their organization on the decision-making that determines the development of the community:39 while in 1990 79% of men and women considered the influence of their organization as strong, this amount decreases to 65% in year 2009. 3. 3. 4 … towards social inclusion and social justice? The perception of lacking influence can also account as reason for the lack of commitment on a political level. Decisions are perceived as being taken out of the reach of local influence, somewhere far away en los escritorios (at the desk) in Santiago, and even beyond- where the actual reality of Chiloé is unknown. Work unions remain weakened by the fact of the split production process into several sub-firms, as well as by the fear of getting on the “black lists” of the salmon industry– even if those might be not such common practice anymore. Local governmental bodies such as municipalities are criticized for being too bureaucratic, and being structured in a way that gives too much power to the mayor and not enough to organizations such as junta de vecinos. To this adds a perceived increase of the practice of clientelismo (clientelism) within governmental bodies – broad agreement within all consulted sources. A decreasing confidence in political actors - the household survey shows that 69% of both men and women don’t trust anymore in political actors - might be responsible for a general political apathy that translates in lower commitment to participation in organizations. This result is consistent with the broader tendency of political apathy in Chile, documented by several other studies (Klesner, 2007, Seligson, 1999). According to Carruthers (2001) “values of community, solidarity and participation have gone out of style, replaced by an unapologetic materialist consumerism”. On the practical side, the salmon industry means 38 Deberíamos ser todos mueblistas porque este es el país de las mesas, mesa de la pesca, mesa agrícola, mesa de turismo, mesa de los artesanos, […] mesas de la salud; […] hay un problema: mesa de trabajo y al final una mesa de trabajo no lleva a muchas cosas, entonces claro, es un momento de participación ciudadana, pero al final no te lleva a resultados concretos […]” 39 The measurement of perceived influence was approached through the following question: Do you think that your organization influences the decisions that affect the community (investments, policies, programs, services, strategies of development)? The respondents had to answer with a qualifications of a scale ranging from 1 (bad/low) to 7 (good/high) (¿Cuánto cree Ud. que esta organización influye en las decisiones que afectan a la comunidad? (inversiones, políticas, programas, servicios, estrategias de desarrollo, etc.).” 40 | P a g e hereby providing the income opportunity to buy the necessary accessories to fulfil models of masculinity and femininity. Interviewees stated that “new political actors” would be required with new ideas in order to motivate engaged participation. And even if de facto there still more men than women participating, however on the discursive level, participation in civil groups could become labelled as “a woman thing” – manhood does not seem to be achieved through civic engagement. This may lead not only to decreased engagement among men in future (if the trend continues), but also to “women’s things” not being taken seriously within a political realm, with the corresponding effect for a potential counter- coalition. The weakness of the counter-coalition reverberates in the creation and enforcement of the legal institutions respective to social and ecological sustainability. That will be illustrated in the following section by looking closer on the Chilean framework of environmental law – yet that is not to say other legal corpora would be less important. 3. 3. 5 …towards ecologically sound legal institutions? Until 1989 there did not exist any legal framework that would have controlled and monitored the operations of the salmon industry. In 1992, the environmental legacy with the General Environmental Framework Law and its main instrument – the environmental impact reports (EIR) – was introduced, passing as law in 1994. For understanding the issues of ecological sustainability in Chiloé, it is worth looking at the major legal devices regulating salmon farming40. According to the Chilean legislation, the use of water and coastal areas for aquaculture activities requires a governmental authorization. The General Law for Fishing and Aquaculture (La Ley General de Pesca y Acuicultura: Ley 18.892) regulates such authorized user right in form of given consents of the category “porción de agua y fondo” (portion of water and ground).41 40 It is also to mention that the salmon industry has established internal guidelines such as. e.g. Código- de- Buenas -Practicas (SalmonChile, 2003). 41 There are two different types of consents: The “aquaculture consent” which is the user right of a specific location of the marine territory for the specific purpose of aquaculture. The “aquaculture authorisation” grants the user right of a specific location of lakes, and rivers for the specific purpose of aquaculture (the breeding of young salmon) (SUBPESCA, 2003:57). 41 | P a g e For obtaining such consent, the applicant has to hand in a project report to the National Fishery Service (Servicio Nacional de Pesca, SERNAPESCA), subordinated to the Ministry of Economy, Promotion and Reconstruction. The project report must include information about the technical and geographical details of the planned cultivation. After a first verification by the SERNAPESCA, the application is passed to the Sub-secretariat of Fishery (Subsecretaría de Pesca, SUBPESCA), subordinated to the Ministry of National Defence the last instance for the final issuance of the consent. The criteria of verification for issuance is hereby assessed along the lines of the General Law for the Environment (Ley sobre Bases Generales del Medio Ambiente, Ley 19.300) as established by the Comisión Nacional del Medio Ambiente (CONAMA). Accordingly, each project is subject to an environmental evaluation in form of an environmental impact report (EIR) within the Regulations of the Evaluation System of Environmental Impact (Reglamento del Sistema de Evaluacion de Impacto Ambiental, SEIA). In the case of the salmon industry, the required EIR are either a Declaration of Environmental Impact (Declaración de Impacto Ambiental) or a Study of Environmental Impact (Estudio de Impacto Ambiental), depending on the size of the projects. Smaller projects, however, do not have to declare an EIR at all. The Environmental Regulation for Aquaculture (Reglamento Ambiental para la Acuicultura) holds that each cultivation centre must maintain its consigned area of cultivation in clean conditions. Once the consent is given to the applicant, the latter will register in the Registro Nacional de Acuicultura - administered by SERNAPESCA- and is then subjected to pay an annual patent tax, as regulated by the General Law of Fishing and Aquaculture. While those legal regulations mean a progress compared to the situation before 1990, there remain nevertheless several problems, respectively. First, the regulation of access to the consents was indirectly excluding the Chiloé’s local population not sufficiently equipped with the necessary cultural capital in jurisprudence, administration and logistics, and historically not used to the division of the sea into user rights - at least not in the beginning years. 42 | P a g e Second, the whole evaluation process from the application to the issuance of consent is based on the project report written by the applicant. Since the given information remains unchecked by a third party, essential issues such as e.g. the quantity of farmed fish and the size of the used area are never verified. According to Silva (1996) the EIR are administered by organizations that are themselves weak, and “in which the industry to be regulated is closely involved as collaborator and from which other social groups are essentially excluded” (Silva, 1996:3). Third, the monitoring of the legal framework simply does not work. Interviewees stated that there is no controlling body – an “authority- that could put the theoretically existing law into practice. The lack of coordination in regard to the question which organization would be actually in charge is reflected by the broad range of potential “candidates” as indicated by interviewed actors: SUBPESCA, CONAMA, or the municipalities. Apparently, responsibilities are not clearly set. However, there is a consistent lowest common denominator: all named agencies were said to lack personal and money to realize effective regular controls of the salmon industry. Matters are complicated by the geographical reality in terms of the huge and dispersed coastal territory that would need to be supervised. For instance, a Leader of a Work Union stated: And the other thing is the contamination, I mean, nobody controls the contamination; the CONAMA turns a blind eye because they don’t have enough people to go controlling centre X. And the marine authority does not have sufficiently staff on board for controlling the cultivation centres. 42 (Leader of Work Union, Interview, 2009) Minimal stuff in state agencies is hereby still the heritage of the free-market -policies by the dictator regime of Pinochet. Fourth, the patent pay, as established by Art.84 of the General Law for Fishing and Aquaculture is relative to the amount of hectare in terms of surface, not to the amount of actually used water in terms of volume. To put numbers into a perspective, the average monthly patent pay is only a third of the water bill of a Chilean household. By 2007, the “Y lo otro es la contaminación, o sea nadie tampoco supervisa la contaminación, la CONAMA hace vista gorda porque no tienen gente para ir a supervisar a centro x. A la autoridad marítima no le alcanza el personal embarcado para supervisar los centros de cultivo.” 42 43 | P a g e revenue of the salmon industry encompassed USD $ 2.200 million while the tax pay USD $ 1.68.868, that is 0, 0053% of its profit (Liberona & Furci, 2008). Finally, there is insufficient control in regard to the concentration of consents. As a locally based lawyer put it during an interview: So, that’s an industry without any control, nobody said that this should be an industry where nobody can have more than 40% of the consents […], because actually the mono-cultivations together with an economic concentration are disastrous [..]43 (Lawyer, Interview, 2009) Indeed, within 1992 and 1999 the numbers of companies shrink from 63 different companies to only 40 different companies, while the production per company increased from 790 to 5447 metric tons. The largest companies are hereby transnational corporations such as Marine Harvest Chile S.A, Invertec, Aguas Claras S.A (Montero, 2004) In sum, those findings confirm the view of Ostrom et al (2005) that ecological sustainability depends largely on the frequency of monitoring of institutions. Much of the legal Chilean environmental framework that regulates the salmon industry is still rather a “paper park” than de facto applied and enforced institution. However, I don’t agree with Ostrom et al (2005) in the point that successful resource management is independent of social coalitions - as it might be asked: who establishes the frequency of control if such is not related to social coalitions? Chile’s government – still oriented towards free-market policies- provides only limited funding to environmental agencies. And even though the environmental framework law ranges among the most progressive legal bodies respective to the inclusion of citizen participation, the latter remains largely the result of Chilean cúpulismo: non-participatory and centralist – “the law’s participatory mechanism tend to exclude precisely the groups most directly affected by proposed developments” (Carruthers, 2001). The practice of environmental law in Chile bears the traces of a dominant social coalition who sought to “Entonces esta es una industria que no la regularon, nadie dijo, esta es una industria donde nadie puede tener más del 40% de las concesiones […], porque efectivamente los monocultivos asociados a concentración económicas son nefastos [..].” 43 44 | P a g e inhibit any innovation in environmental policy fearing that it might curb economic growth (Silva, 1996). And as Chile’s environmental movement in a whole remains still without much resonance in a relatively weak civil society (Carruthers, 2001), also Chiloé is missing a counter-socialcoalition strong enough to enter as an interlocutor the institutional negotiations by imposing more enforcement. The main safeguard of the social coalition in favour of the salmon industry is their discursive sovereignty. The discursive accounts serve to explain and support the existence of the salmon industry (and generally the pro-salmon-coalition). In terms of legitimacy, the boot remains with the other foot - and yet there is strong gender component to it. Thus, salmon industry is commonly presented as the deliverer of modernity and employment rescuing Chiloé from backwardness. In the beginning years of the salmon industry, the discourse held that the families could now stay together: Chilote men could stay at home with their wife without the need to migrate. Then, the industry became credited for bringing the “liberation” of Chiloé’s women. And not only is this “liberation” presented as being without alternatives, it also goes along with well-known gender stereotypes. Simply put: no salmon industry, no washing machines. 4 Conclusion I think that there are very good intentions, there are competent people for developing those projects, those initiatives, those dreams I told you and that they can realize, but the means are lacking, the means to develop those activities […] 44 Municipality Official, Interview, 2009 Animadverting that the development in Chiloé is marked by major social and ecological problems coming along with the establishment of the salmon industry, I analysed the recent history of Chiloé in the light of issues of social and environmental sustainability within institutional theory. I hereby tried to find out if and how a gender analysis of such institutional process could enrich research and strengthen findings on sustainable development. “Yo encuentro que hay muy buenas intenciones, hay gente muy capacitada para desarrollar estos proyectos, estas iniciativas o estos sueños, que yo te contaba, y que lo pueden aplicar, pero falta eso el recurso, y el recurso para desarrollar la actividad […].” 44 45 | P a g e The results respective to my research questions of how gender plays out within the institutional analysis in terms of the distribution of assets before and after the establishment of the salmon industry, the formation of social coalitions, and the making and enforcement of legal institutions in Chiloé, are the following. I showed that the different capitals had been accessed and distributed in gendered ways in Chiloé before and after the arrival the salmon industry. Interestingly, the way gender organized the Chiloé society previously to the salmon industry facilitated the establishment of the latter. The pre-salmon gender division had “trained” Chilote women and men in skills and attitudes that were useful for the salmon industry. The latter thus disposed of an already experienced labor force by just taking over the previous gender division within the assignment of new tasks – yet classified as “unskilled”. Likewise, the “engendering” of a new tradition within the salmon industry via a gendered assignment of jobs assured the continuum of work experience that nevertheless remained financially unvalued for both men and (even more for) women. The establishment of the salmon industry changed gender models in so far as manhood was no longer “achieved” by migration to the Southern and Northern ends of Chile, but through activities such as sports, and more material oriented fullfilments of masculinity. The access to economic capital, however, did not change major expecations on being a woman, still including “female” duties as cooking, cleaning, and raising children. Greater economic capital in terms of higher positions within the salmon industry remains largely inaccessible for the local population in general, and for the female portion of it, in specific. The same accounts for the access to the “dominant” cultural capital (jurisprudence, management, and likewise) - whereas the commercialize-able parts of the former Chilote cultural capital get more gender pronounced. A social coalition that could advocate a more sustainable development of Chiloé still lacks the necessary strength in terms of capital composition. The goal of fostering of a strong social coalition of organizations in favor of ecological and social sustainability remains withdrawn by deficiencies in coordination/cooperation between organizations, and by additional deficiencies in a solid commitment within organizations. Also, in recent years, participation in organizations gets more distinct in gender terms - paired with typical gender assumption of “working men” and “caring women”. Whereas the number of female dominated groups increases, women remain less actively engaged in organizations 46 | P a g e than men. Despite the “Bachelet”-effect and the perception of women as innovadoras, women – assumed to be more emotional and less rational than men- tend to not be taken seriously in the public realm. This might be not only crucial within social coalitions regarding the increase of female dominated groups, but might also reverberate on their strength if commitment is getting discursively labeled as trivial “women’s thing”. The weakness (or non-existence) of a social coalition in favor of a more sustainable development is salient in regard to the potential legal mitigation of ecological problems whose main sticking point remains the practical application theoretical existing laws. Changes in the practice of environmental law are inhibited through the legitimation process of the salmon industry – presented by the corresponding socio-political forces as deliverer of modernity and employment. And, a related illustration of the noble deeds of the salmon industry is the representation of salmon work as responsible for the “liberation” of women (from barbaric traditions?) – which is, historically a quite common discursive pattern for legitimation purposes. In sum, regarding my research question of whether gender enriches institutional theory and research in the context of sustainable development, I can therefore say: it does – as it helps to paint a more accurate picture of the material and symbolic realities of the population within the territory in question necessary to understand what had happened, and probably also why it happened. By not considering gender relations within institutional theory, the probability of taking along snowsuits to a desert increases. However, gender could be taken into account in quite diverse ways – the usefulness of a concept is largely depending on its definition. Research and projects that operate with categories such as “housewife”, without ever questioning what empirical activities that category encompasses; essentialist approaches focused only on women; or the view of “poor” women that fit perfectly into any “liberation” discourse, might fail in terms of sustainable development. Nevertheless, the goal of a gendered institutional analysis is not to discover “green” gender relations as ultimate cause and vehicle towards sustainability. Likewise, taking into account gender should not mean ignoring other topics and issues. That would be just another form of being gender blind. 47 | P a g e Further research on sustainable development of Chiloé should focus in that sense on an exact examination of the practice of the environmental law framework, taking also into account the gender relations within the corresponding governmental agencies such as CONAMA, SUBPESCA, ect. Such study should also include an exact documentation of the cooperation/coordination/communication of the pro-salmon-coalition. Furthermore, a concise scrutinizing of the financial flows of the public and private sectors within Chiloé would be needed in order to evaluate potential strategies for alternative livelihoods. Both foci are even more important in regard to an assessment of the consequences of the actual ISA crisis of the salmon industry, spoken in gender terms. There is hope that the ways turning around the “Chilean miracle” lead towards a direction of social and ecological sustainability. Towards a sustainable “Chiloéan miracle” – redefining the role- model of what “successful” development means. Bibliography: Acker J. (1992). From Sex Roles to Gendered Institutions. Contemporary Sociology: A Journal of Reviews, 21(5). Acker J. (1990). Hierarchies, Jobs, Bodies: A Theory of Gendered Organizations. Gender and Society, 4(2). Agrawal, A.(2001). Common Property Institutions and Sustainable Governance of Resources. World Development. 29(10). Anderies, J. M. et al. (2007). Panaceas, Uncertainty, and the Robust Control Framework Sustainability Science. PNAS, 104. in AquaChile. (2007). Memoria Anual 2007. http://www.aquachile.com/web_aquachile/dinamicos/reportes/Memoria_Anual_AquaChile_2007.pdf Bachrach P., & Baratz, M. (1962). Two Faces of Power. The American Political Science Review, 56(4). Barrett, G., et al. (2005). Nadie es Profeta en su Tierra: Community, Civil Society, and Intervening Institutions in Rural Chile. Human Organization, 64(1). Barrett, G., et al. (2002). There are More Vets than Doctors in Chiloé: Social and Community Impact of the Globalization of Aquaculture in Chile. World Development, 30(11). Barrientos, S. (1997). The Hidden Ingredient: Female Labour in Chilean Fruit Exports. Bulletin of Latin American Research, 16(1). Barton, J.R. (2006). Sustainable fisheries management in the resource periphery: The cases of Chile and New Zealand. Asia Pacific Viewpoint, 47(3). 48 | P a g e Bebbington, A. (1999). Capitals and Capabilities: A Framework for Analyzing Peasant Viability, Rural Livelihoods and Poverty. World Development, 27(12). Beckwith, K. (2005). A Common Language of Gender? Politics & Gender, 1(1). Berdegué, J., & Schejtman, A. (2004). Rural Territorial Development. Rural Territorial Dynamics Program, Working Paper No. 4. Berger, J., Ridgeway, C., & Zelditch, M. (2002). Construction of Status and Referential Structures. Sociological Theory, 20(2). Berger, J., Cohen, B.P. & Zelditch, M. (1972). Status Characteristics and Social Interaction. American Sociological Review, 37(3). Berger, J., et al. (1998). The Legitimation and Delegitimaiton of Power and Prestige Order. American Sociological Review. 63(3). Berkes, F., et al. (1989 ). A comparative study of yield, investment and energy use in small-scale fisheries: Some considerations for resource planning. Fisheries Research. 7(3). Bourdieu, P. (1979). Les trois états du capital culturel. Actes de la recherche en sciences sociales, 30(1). Bourdieu, P. (1985). The Social Space and the Genesis of Groups. Theory and Society,14(6). Bourdieu, P. (1980). Le capital social. Actes de la recherche en sciences sociales, 31. Bridger, J. & Luloff, A.E. (2001). Building Sustainable Communitiy: Is Social Capital the Answer? Sociologicul Inquiry, 71(4). Camus, P. & Hajek, E.R. (1998). Historia Ambiental de Chile. Santiago: Andros Impresores. Caraway, T. L. (2009). Comparative Political Economy, Gender, and Labor Markets. Politics & Gender, 5(4). Caraway, T. L. (2006). Gendered Paths of Industrialization: A Cross-Regional Comparative Analysis. Studies in Comparative International Development, 41(1). Caraway, T. L. (2010). Gendering Comparative Politics. Perspectives on Politics, 8(1). Caraway, T. L. (2005). The Political Economy of Feminization: From "Cheap Labor" to Gendered Discourses of Work. Politics & Gender, 1(3). Carrasco, C. ,et al. (2000). Cultivando el Mar: para la Calidad de las Condiciones de Trabajo. Working Paper No. 13, Department of Research, International Labor Organization. Santiago: ILO. Carruthers, D. (2001). Environmental politics in Chile: Legacies of Dictatorship and Democracy. Third World Quarterly. 22 (3). Cypher, J.M. (2004). Is Chile a neoliberal success? http://dollarsandsense.org/archives/2004/0904cypher.html Dollars & Sense Magazine. 49 | P a g e Center for Food Security & Public Health, Iowa State University. (2010, March). Infectious Salmon Anemia: Hemorraghic Kidney Syndrome, Icterus Syndrome (Coho Salmon). Fact Sheet. http://www.cfsph.iastate.edu/Factsheets/pdfs/infectious_salmon_anemia.pdf Chappell, L. (2010). Comparative Gender and Institutions: Directions for Research. Perspectives on Politics, 8(1). Connell, R.W. (1985). Theorizing Gender. Sociology, 19(2). Colclough, G. (2005). Community or Social Capital: What is the difference? Sociological Inquiry, 75(4). Deutsch, S.M.G. (1991). Gender and Sociopolitical Change in Twentieth-Century Latin America. Hispanic American Historical Review, 71(2). Díaz Andrade, E. (2003) Globalización y multinacionales: Impactos en el trabajo de las mujeres. Hexagrama Consultoras Working Paper. Santiago, Chile. Díaz Andrade, E. (2003). Transnacionalización de la Industria Salmonera: Aspectos socio-laborales de un proceso en curso. Santiago: Oxfam & Hexagrama Consultoras. Díaz, E. & Espinoza, V. (2000). Proyecto: Propuesta de Política Pública con Enfoque de Género: Fiscalización de Condiciones de Higiene y Seguridad en Empresas Pesqueras de la Xa Región. Centro de Investigaciones Sociales, Universidad Arcis. Dirección del Trabajo. (2008). ENCLA 2008: Inequidades y Brechas de Género en el Empleo. Informe de Resultados. http://www.dt.gob.cl/1601/articles-97629_archivo_fuente.pdf Eggertsson, T. (1992). Analyzing institutional successes and failures: A millennium of common mountain pastures in Iceland. International Review of Law and Economics, 12(4). Eggertsson, T. (1990). The role of transaction costs and property rights in economic analysis. European Economic Review, 34. Ekins, P. (1993).”Limits to growth” and “sustainable development”: Grappling with Ecological Realities. Ecological Economics. 8(3). Eisenstein, H. (2005). A Dangerous Liaison? Feminism and Corporate Globalization. Science & Society, 69(3). Grenier, P. (1984). Chiloé et les chilotes, marginalité et dépendance en Patagonie chilienne: étude de géographie humaine. Aix-en-Provence: EDISUD. Hall, P. & Taylor, R. (1996). Political science and the three new institutionalisms. Political Studies, 44(4). Hodgson, G. (2006). What are Institutions? Journal of Economic Issues, 40(1). Hucke-Gaete, R., et al. (2008). Investicación para el desarrollo de área marina costera protegida Chiloé. Universidad Austral de Chile. INE. (2002). Population and Housing Census. http://www.ine.cl Jackson, C. (1993). Doing What Comes Naturally? Women and Environment in Development.World Development, 21(12) 50 | P a g e Joekes, S. (1999). Diminished Returns. Harvard International Review, 21(4). Kenney, S. (1996). New Research on Gendered Political Institutions. Political Research Quarterly, 49(2). Kenny, M. (2008). Gender, Institutions and Power: A Critical Review. Politics, 27(2). Klesner, J. (2007). Social Capital and Participation in Latin America. Latin American Research Review, 42(2) Liberona, F. & Furci, G. (2008). Concesiones acuícolas en Chile: La situación actual (APP 47). Santiago: Fundación Terram. Locke,C.& Okali, C. (1999). Analysing changing gender relations: methodological challenges for gender planning. Development in Practice, 9(3). Lovenduski, J. (1998). Gendering Research in Political Science. Annual Review of Political Science, 1(1). Luhmann, N. (1984). Soziale Systeme: Grundriß einer allgemeinen Theorie. Suhrkamp Verlag. Macé, JC. & Bornschlegl, T. (2010). “Gender System Dynamics in Central Chiloé, or the Quadrature of the Cycles”. Working Paper, Rural Territorial Dynamics Program, Rimisp – Latin American Center for Rural Development. Macé, JC & Yáñez, R. (2009). Participación política y capital social en Chiloé Central. Rural Territorial Dynamics Program, Unpublished Working Paper. Maffesoli, M. (2004). Nomadismo: Vagabundeos iniciativos. Fondo de Cultura Económica. México. Mancilla, M. & Rehbein, M. (2007). De viajes a retornos: Una aproximación al estudio del imaginario de la vida errante en el Chiloé de la primera mitad del siglo XX. Universidad Austral de Chile. Martin, P. (2004). Gender as Social Institution. Social Forces, 82(4). Modrego, F. et al. (2008). La heterogeneidad espacial del desarrollo económico en Chile: radiografía a los cambios en bienestar durante la década de los 90 por estimaciones en áreas pequeñas. Working Paper No. 9, Rural Territorial Dynamics Program, Rimisp – Latin American Center for Rural Development. Moe, T.M. (2005). Power and Political Institutions. Perspectives on politics, 3(2). Moghadam, V. M. (1998). Feminism and Development. Gender & History, 10(3). Montecino, S. (1993). Madres y Huachos: alegorías del mestizaje chileno. Santiago: Ediciones Cuarto Propio. Montero, C. et al. (2000). La industria del salmón en la X región: un cluster globalizado. Santiago: ECLAC. 51 | P a g e Montero, C. (2004). Formación y desarrollo de un cluster globalizado: el caso de la industria del salmón en Chile. Santiago de Chile: CEPAL Montiel Vera, D. (2003). Chiloé: Crónicas de un mundo insular. Dimar Ediciones. Muñoz, O. (2004). Desarrollo regional sustentable y Globalización. El caso de la industria del salmón y el ecosistema de Llanquihue-Chiloé (Chile). Santiago: FLASCO-Chile. North, D.C. (1970). Institutional Change and American Economic Growth: A First Step Towards a Theory of Institutional Innovation. Journal of Economic History, 30(1). North, D.C. (1991). Institutions. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(1). North, D.C. et al. (2004). Learning, Institutions, and Economic Performance. Perspectives on politics, 2(1). North, D.C. & Weingast, B. R. (2000). Introduction: Institutional Analysis and Economic History. Journal of Economic History, 60(2). Olson, M. (1993). Dictatorship, Democracy, and Development. American Political Science Review, 87(3). Ostrom, E.(1986). An agenda for the study of institutions. Public Choice, 48(1). Ostrom, E. (2008). Institutions and the Environment. Economic Affairs, 28(3). Ostrom, E., et al. (2005). Local Enforcement and Better Forests. World Development, 33(2). Paulson, S. (2010). Guía Metodológica y Marco Conceptual DTR- Género, Unpublished Working Paper, Rural Territorial Dynamics Program, Rimisp – Latin American Center for Rural Development. Pelletier, N., et al. (2009). Not all salmon are created equal: Life Cycle Assessment (LCA) of Global Salmon Farming Systems. Environment, Science, Technology, 43. Pinto, P. (2007). Salmonicultura Chilena: Entre el Éxito Comercial y la Insustentabilidad (RPP 23). Santiago: Fundación Terram. ProChile. (2010). Estadísticas de Comercio Exterior. http://www.prochile.cl/servicios/estadisticas/exportaciones.php Ramírez, E., et al. (2010). Chiloé Central: de la vulnerabilidad al desarrollo sostenible. Rural Territorial Dynamics Program, Unpublished Working Paper. Ramírez, E., et al (2009a). Dinámicas Territoriales en Chiloé Central: La Fuerza de las Coaliciones Extra Territoriales. Working Paper No. 54, Rural Territorial Dynamics Program, Rimisp – Latin American Center for Rural Development. Ramírez, E., et al. (2009b). Caracterización de los Actores de Chiloé Central, Working Paper No. 55, Rural Territorial Dynamics Program, Rimisp – Latin American Center for Rural Development. Ridgeway, C. & Correll, S. (2004). Unpacking the Gender System: A Theoretical Perspective on Gender Beliefs and Social Relations. Gender and Society, 18(4). 52 | P a g e Ridgeway, C. & Correll, S. (2000). Limiting Gender Inequality through Interaction: The End(s) of Gender. Contemporary Sociology, 29: 110-20. Rimisp – Latin American Center for Rural Development, & Woods Institute for the Environment Stanford University. (2009). Encuesta Dinámicas Territoriales en Chiloé, Household Survey. Rostow,W.W.(1971). Politics and the Stages of Growth. London: Cambridge University Press. Scott, J. W. (1986). Gender: A Useful Category of Historical Analysis. The American Historical Review, 91(5). Shiva, V. (1989). Staying Alive: Women, Ecology , and Development. London: Zed Books. Silva, E. (1996). Democracy, Market Economics, and Environmental Policy in Chile. Journal of Interamerican Studies and World Affairs.38(4). Seligson, M. (1999). Popular Support for Regional Economic Integration in Latin America. Journal of Latin American Studies, 31(1). Sen, A. (1997). Editorial: Human capital and human capability. World Development, 25(12). Sen, A. (2001). Population and Gender Equity. Journal of Public Health Policy, 22(2). Smiaroski, M.S. (1996). Women and Changes in the Chilean Economy: Some Questions. Gender and Development, 4(3). Soto, D.F.J. & Moreno, C. (2001). Escaped salmon in the inner seas, southern Chile: ecological and social conflicts. Ecological Applications. 11. facing United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. (2006). A Case Study of the Salmon Industry in Chile. New York: United Nations. Urbina Burgos, R. (1996). Castro, Castreños y Chilotes: 1960-1990. Valparaiso: Ediciones Universitarias de Valparaiso. Uribe Velásquez, M. (2003). Crónicas de Chiloé. (2nd ed.). Castro: Ediciones Aumen. Venegas, C. et al. (2007). Desarrollo Territorial Rural a partir de Servicios y Productos con Identidad Cultural. Chiloé: una reserva de Patrimonio Cultural. RIMISP - Centro Latinoamericano para el Desarrollo Rural. Santiago, Chile. Vidal, M. (2005). Las estructuras sociales de la economía popular y social en la provincia de Chiloé: un análisis a partir de los capitales tangibles e intangibles. Tesis de Magíster en Desarrollo Humano a escala local y regional, Universidad de La Frontera, Temuco, Chile. von Förster, H. (2002). Understanding Understanding. Essays on Cybernetics and Cognition. Berlin: Springer Verlag. Wackernagel, M. & W.E. Rees. (1996). Our Ecological Footprint. Gabriola Island, BC: New Society Publishers. Westermann, O., et al. (2005). Gender and Social Capital: The Importance of Gender Differences for the Maturity and Effectiveness of Natural Resource Management Groups. World Development, 33(11). 53 | P a g e Woolcock, M. (1998). Social Capital and Economic Development: Toward a Theoretical Synthesis and Policy Framework. Theory and Society, 27(2). Young, I. (1990). Justice and Politics of Difference. Princeton: The Princeton University Press. Zelditch, M. (2001). Processes of Legitimation: Recent Developments and New Directions. Social Psychology Quarterly, 64(1). Zelditch, M. & Ford, J. (1994). Uncertainty, Potential Power, and Nondecisions. Social Psychology Quarterly, 57(1)