Neg Uniqueness Coop Now Fed respecting states The US is trying to better involve states in ocean policy Heimes 10 (Rita S., “Ocean Management & Planning in the United States: From Competition to Cooperation”, Annuaire de Droit Maritime et Océanique, Forthcoming, http://mhk.pnnl.gov/sites/default/files/publications/Heimes_2010.pdf) Since the United States began in earnest to regulate ocean uses to prevent environmental degradation, while at the same time encouraging exploitation of its natural resources for human food and energy consumption, it has generated multiple federal laws and regulations managed by a plethora of administrative agencies, departments and executive offices. It has also tried, through the Coastal Zone Management Act, to take into consideration the concerns and ideas of the coastal states upon whom much of the negative impacts of ocean exploitation fall. Through the National Ocean Council and, eventually, coastal and marine spatial planning efforts conducted throughout the nation by regional bodies, the US has an opportunity to streamline its ocean-related regulatory processes, coordinate decisions for the benefit of commerce and ecosystems alike, and involve state and local interests in a fully integrated and meaningful way. The Federal Government is respecting state’s rights—Colorado proves Scot Kersgaard November 16, 2012 <The Colorado Independent, Coffman backs move to force feds to respect states’ rights on marijuana, http://www.coloradoindependent.com/126376/coffman-backsmove-to-force-feds-to-respect-states-rights-on-marijuana> Today I am proud to join with colleagues from both sides of the aisle on the ‘Respect States’ and Citizens’ Rights Act’ to protect states’ rights and immediately resolve any conflict with the federal government,” said Rep. DeGette in a press release. “In Colorado we’ve witnessed the aggressive policies of the federal government in their treatment of legal medicinal marijuana providers. My constituents have spoken and I don’t want the federal government denying money to Colorado or taking other punitive steps that would undermine the will of our citizens.” Coffman said in the release that while he opposed the legalization of marijuana, he feels an obligation to support the will of voters, who in his district supported the measure. “I voted against Amendment 64 and I strongly oppose the legalization of marijuana, but I also have an obligation to respect the will of the voters, given the passage of this initiative, and so I feel obligated to support this legislation,” he said in the release. “Residents of Colorado and Washington have made it clear that the public is ahead of the federal government in terms of marijuana legalization,” said Oregon Rep. Earl Blumenauer in the release issued by DeGette. “It’s time for Congress to pass legislation – such as the ‘Respect States’ and Citizens’ Rights Act’ – that allows states to implement their own laws in this area without fear of federal interference.” Oregon voters shot down a measure that would have legalized marijuana in that state. More from DeGette’s press release: “The federal government’s failure to develop a reasonable approach towards the varying state marijuana use laws has made this legislation necessary,” said Rep. Sam Farr (CA-17). “From increased raids on legal dispensaries to denying defendants in court the right to present evidence of their legal marijuana use, the federal government has chosen to trample on state rights rather than work with them as a partner to address this issue.” Polis today sent a letter to Attorney General Eric Holder and Drug Enforcement Administration Administrator Michele Leonhart asking that they take no action against people whose activities related to marijuana are in compliance with state law. In addition to Polis, the letter was signed by: Steve Cohen, D-TN; DeGette, Ed Perlmutter D-CD-7; Barney Frank D-MA; Earl Blumenauer,D-OR; Jerrold Nadler, D-NY; Jan Schakowsky, D-IL; Sam Farr, D-CA; Jim Moran, D-VA; Chellie Pingree, D-ME; Adam Smith, D-WA; Barbara Lee, D-CA; Dennis Kucinich, D-OH; Raúl Grijalva, D-AZ; Robert C. Scott, D-VA; and John Conyers, D-MI. Current system good Cooperative Federalism now, States acted first Glicksman ’06 (Robert, professor at George Washington University law school, From Cooperative to Inoperative Federalism: The Perverse Mutation of Environmental Law and Policy, GW law, http://scholarship.law.gwu.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1653&context=faculty_publications, accessed: 7/12/14 GA) Both the federal government and the states have ample authority to take actions that are designed to protect human health and the environment from the adverse effects of industrial and developmental activity. The federal government may rely upon its authority to regulate interstate and foreign commerce49 to restrict pollution-generating activities, for example,50 and it may rely upon its power to “make all needful Rules and Regulations respecting” property that it owns51 to manage the federal public lands and resources and protect them from damage caused by activities on adjacent private land.52 Beginning in the nineteenth century, the federal government frequently resorted to its authority under the Property Clause by enacting statutes that authorized federal agencies such as the National Forest Service53 and the National Park Service. It was the state and local governments that first took the initiative in restricting polluting and land development activities with the potential to harm the environment. Common law litigation sounding in causes of action such as nuisance, trespass, negligence, and strict liability provided one forum in which those injured by pollution. Power is balanced in the status quo – federally mandated coastal policy systems create complex local/state management systems that give states adequate control. Knight 2000 (Maurice, Senior Policy Advisor Coastal Resources Center, University of Rhode Island, “The United States Experience in Decentralized Coastal Management: Lessons for Indonesia”, http://www.crc.uri.edu/download/TR-00_05-E_The_US_Experience.pdf) 1.2 National Program Throughout the IST, the participants were involved in discussions concentrated on the importance of the National Coastal Zone Management Act of 1972 (CZMA) in setting a national coastal management agenda in the United States. The CZMA resulted in states, local governments and stakeholders focusing their attention, efforts and financial resources on coastal zone management. Especially emphasized was the way the national law was designed to encourage states, local governments, Indian tribes and the general public to exercise their full right and authority in appropriately managing and developing coastal resources. This includes clarifying the specific roles of different levels of government, ensuring minimum standards of performance through voluntary certification of programs and guaranteeing opportunities for public participation. Certification of all state and local coastal zone management (CZM) programs is a pivotal feature of the Integrated United States program. The requirements for voluntary certification of state and local programs under the CZMA can be broadly categorized as processes related to information and definitions, institutions and organization, procedures and planning. By setting out the process and elements that must be included in each of these broad categories, the United States national government ensures an orderly and effective approach to decentralization of coastal management. In addition, the United States federal government lays out incentive structures that provide enough encouragement for all states to voluntarily enter the national certification programs. These incentives are financial and jurisdictional (in terms of federal, state and local consistency with approved coastal plans). 2.4 State and Local Response to the CZMA Through Integrated Coastal Management Programs The coastal zone of United States and territories generally includes lands and waters from the territorial limit of three nautical miles to sea, to some inland boundary which may correspond to political boundaries (e.g., the inland boundary of all coastal counties), administrative boundaries (e.g., the nearest roadway), functional boundary (e.g., important ecosystem boundary) or some combination of these. This CZMA requires only that the coastal zone boundary be defined and allows state and local governments to decide on the appropriate method according to local conditions. Many states use a tiered approach for defining the coastal zone, usually two tiered. The first tier includes the area with the 'most direct interaction with the coast' or the 'zone of primary influence'. Tier two includes the rest of the coastal zone considered to have indirect interaction with the coastal zone. Permitting in Tier one usually requires that any proposed development use be designated as a 'coastal dependent use' before being considered appropriate for near coastal zone. Tier two would then consider for permitted use those developments that are less dependent on being located immediately adjacent to the shore. Meetings between IST participants and the Coastal Commission of Rhode Island, a smaller state than most others, revealed a three tiered approach. These include a "zone of primary influence, a second zone delineated by the inland borders of the coastal counties and a third that includes the entire state in the coastal zone". Florida and Hawaii also designate the entire state as coastal zone except for federal lands and Indian Tribal lands. Under the CZMA, the management structure for receiving national certification is not determined. Approaches range from complete direct state control of all designated coastal lands and waters, to regional agreements among various agencies for to co-management. Generally, states do not manage their coastal zones as one contiguous, all encompassing unit. Usually, coastal zone management authority is divided among various state and local authorities to which a considerable amount of coastal management review and permitting authority is delegated. In some states these local units are county or municipal governments, others are special management area commissions that manage areas that cross political boundaries (e.g., dividing the state into regional zones which may be individually managed). However, in all cases, a lead agency retains oversight of these local programs through some mechanism. There is widespread use of state-local administrative relationships in United States coastal states and territories. Usually local county or municipal (city or township) authorities create local coastal zone management programs with technical help from the state level. Once these local programs are approved, some degree of permitting and enforcement authority is delegated to the local level with continued but loose oversight from the state lead agency. States Control Now Generic States are pushing for more coastal management now, and have significant power over their waters Rachael E. Salcido in 2008 Associate Professor of Law, University of the Pacific, McGeorge School of Law, Offshore Federalism and Ocean Industrialization, Tulane Law Review 82 Tul. L. Rev. 1355 After initial recognition of the environmental impacts of offshore development, coastal states and local governments prompted the next phase of offshore federalism by seeking to increase their respective roles. Spurred by national interest that culminated in the adoption of the CZMA, coastal states began more concerted coastal planning guided by the CZMA and now constitute a significant source of coastal regulation. n179 In the 1990s, following the federal government's extension from a three-to twelve-mile territorial sea, coastal states began agitating once more, and ultimately unsuccessfully, for additional offshore management jurisdiction. n180 [*1387] Recently, to address the pollution from increasing populations and to restore marine ecosystems, many coastal states have also undertaken alternatives to the traditional rules-based laws used to manage oceans. Some states have initiated a form of ocean zoning in addition to zoning inland. States have delineated spatial areas offshore within state jurisdiction to manage the oceans for particular preservation and restoration goals: one example is California's Marine Life Protection Act. n181 The purpose of the Act is to review the adequacy of existing marine protected areas and to determine the need for new marine protected areas. n182 The most controversial aspect is the designation of new areas as off-limits to extractive activities. n183 Further, funding for implementation was an early issue that halted implementation and is projected to remain a salient issue moving forward. n184 Similar state efforts and coastal state and regional coalitions indicate an increasing awareness of the challenges of sustainable coastal management across jurisdictional boundaries. n185 As discussed further in Part IV, these approaches hold important promise for ecosystem-based management. Unfortunately, federal funding for increased coastal management has waned over time, and funding for these initiatives is becoming a significant impediment to their progress. n186 Certainly, these financial issues do emphasize the need for shared revenues where the environmental impacts of coastal and offshore developments can be mitigated by rents, royalties, and other types of development payments made by private users of public resources. n187 Yet it does not explain the continued narrow focus on [*1388] boundaries and revenues that currently dominates the debate over legal reform. In status quo US states control resources- good for the economy Kolawole 2013 (Simon, “A Federalism Ruined By Allocations [opinion]”, This Day (Lagos), October 13, 2013, Lexis Nexis) What is federalism? You are never going to get one definition. Not that it cannot be neatly defined but, in practice, there are hardly any two forms of federalism that are the same. I have done extensive studies on federalism in the US, Canada, Mexico, Germany, Australia, UAE and Brazil, among others, and I find it interesting that every country seems to have evolved a system that suits its history and purposes. While some political scientists will want federalism described simply as "weak centre, strong units" (compared to the unitary system of "strong centre, weak units"), the consistent feature is that power is shared between the centre and the federating units. Federalism is mostly two-tiered, but countries such as Nigeria, India and Brazil have introduced a third tier called local governments or municipalities over the years. In terms of ownership of natural resources, federal systems do not have a standard format. In the UAE and US, for instance, every federating unit controls its resources. This is "resource control" at work. In Canada, however, there is a deliberate policy to achieve "balance" or "equalisation" through the sharing of a percentage of the petrodollars with non-oil-producing provinces. In Nigeria, we apply principles such as "need", "land mass" and "population" to achieve a federal government is totally in charge of the oil, much like Nigeria. All the states receive 20 per cent as transfers (federal allocations). Mexican municipalities (called councils in Nigeria) where oil production and shipping activities take place receive an extra 3.17% as "compensation" (13% "derivation" in Nigeria). similar objective. Meanwhile, in Mexico, the But I am not here today to propose what variant of federal system is best for Nigeria. I honestly cannot be bothered. I worry more about the leadership rather than the systems. My concern, and many Nigerians have been expressing this worry for ages, is our variant of federalism which is based on federal allocations. This is stunting our development. We run an economic system where all the tiers of government shamelessly live on "federation salaries". If these "salaries" are delayed or short-paid in any month, there is immediate repercussion for the economy. Nigeria's most important meeting every month is that of the Federation Account Allocation Committee (FAAC). Without FAAC, we are nothing. Take away the oil money and you have a country that is headless and we can run a federalism where the units are economically strong, with or without amendments to the constitution. How can the states become less dependent on going in no particular direction. The conversation we ought to be having today is how FAAC? How can federal allocations become mere "pocket money"? How can a state like Rivers or Delta get N20 billion from FAAC but generate N100 billion internally? How can we change our mentality from allocation and consumption to production and development? For me, that is the real deal as we seek to make Nigeria a better country and reduce the political and economic tension in the land. States have the control of the ocean now – both inside and outside the three mile line Burger 11, Burger, Micheal. "Consistency Conflicts and Federalism Choice: Marine Spatial Planning Beyond the States’ Territorial Seas." Environmental Law Institute 7.41 (2011): 2-5. Pace Law. Pace University Law School, July 2011. Web. 11 July 2014. CS Jurisdiction.over.tidal.waters.in.the.United.States.is.clearly. divided.between.the.federal. government. and.the.states .. The.Submerged.Lands.Act.(SLA)13.gives.states.jurisdiction. from.the.mean.hightide.line.out.to.three.nautical.miles,14. and. grants.coastal.states. “title.to. and.ownership.of.the. lands.beneath.navigable.waters.within.the.boundaries.of. the.respective.states,.and.the.natural.resources.within.such. lands. and.waters .”15.The.federal.government.does.retain. some.power.within.the.states’.territorial.seas—including. the.power.to.regulate. “commerce,”. “navigation,”. “power. generation,”. and. “national. defense”16—but. it. does. not. have.the.rights.to.“management,.administration,.leasing,. use.and.development.of.the.lands.and.natural.resources .”17. Beyond.the.states’.territorial.seas,.the.federal.government. claims.jurisdiction.out.to.200.nautical.miles,.the.boundary. of.the U .S . Exclusive Economic Zone (EEZ) . 18.Under.the. still-unratified.United.Nations.Convention.on.the.Law.of. the.Sea.III,.signatories.have.extensive.rights.over.natural. resources.within.their.EEZs,.including.the.right.to.develop. renewable.energy.resources . 19 Iõ achieve a balance, the CZMA does two things. First, it provides states fhnding to develop coastal management programs (CMPs) that then approved and made enforce able to the Nationa1 Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration (NOAA).N Second, the CZMA provides for “consistency review. Consisting review allows the states to deny or restrict activities both within and outside the coastal woe if the result for “coastal effects” would be inconsistent with die enforceable policies of a state’s CMP.” Coastal effects are broadly defined, including any reasonably forseeable effect on any coastal use or resource resulting from a federal agency activity or federal license or permit activity,”” aid the effects test” transcends any memoir oljurisdllctiona1 boundaries, including the boundary marking federal land located within a state’s coastal zonez the landward boundary between the coastal woe and upland areas,’ and the three-mile line between the state’s territorial sea and kderal Viewed through a & federalism lense, consistency review is che CZMA’s most unique and important feature, constituting a “limited waiver of coral supremacy and authority”0 char is highly unusual, if not entirely unique, in environmental law. The limitations on that waiver exist at both the CMP ami consistency review stages, and they arc critical. as they check state authority both within and beyond the three-mile line. At the CMP stage. the CZMA requires stares co consider the “national interest,” and to give “priority consideration . . . to coastal-dependent uses and orderly processes for siting major facilities related to national defense, energy. fisheries development, recreation, ports and transportation.”‘ The CZMA also gives the Secretary of Commerce authority to periodically evaluate CMPs and to review claims that a given state has failed to account fix the national interest.’3 Ar che consistency review stage. the CZMA allows either 6dcral agencies or the Secretary of Commerce to override individual adverse consistency deter minations when certain conditions are met.44 The next part uses the RI O..SAMP as a case study to detail how these CZMA provisions will determine the force state MSP is able to exert on siting renewable energy facilities in federal waters. Aquaculture States have jurisdiction over aquaculture up to three miles off the coast—California proves Naylor and Leonard 10 (Rosamond L. and George H. , Times Colonists “Aquaculture viable if planned responsibly; U.S. bill aims to set standards to ensure environment is respected”, Times Colonist (Victoria, British Columbia), February 21, 2010 Sunday Final Edition, LexisNexis) While our appetite for seafood continues to grow, most of us know little about where our fish comes from or now it was produced. In California, more than half of our seafood comes from aquaculture, often imported from fish farms in other countries. Just as most chickens, pigs and cows are raised in tightly confined, intensive operations, so too are many farm-raised fish. But raising fish in tight quarters carries some serious risks. Disease and parasites can be transmitted from farmed to wild fish. Effluents, antibiotics and other chemicals can be discharged into surrounding waters. Non-native farmed fish can escape into wild fish habitat. And a reliance on wild-caught fish in aquaculture feed can deplete food supplies for other marine life. These environmental impacts have been evident in many countries with intensive marine fish farming. In Chile, where industry expansion was prioritized over environmental protection, salmon aquaculture has collapsed, causing a major blow to what had been one of Chile’s leading exports. Tens of thousands of people are now jobless in southern Chile, where the salmon farming industry once boomed. If aquaculture is to play a responsible role in the future of seafood, we must ensure that the “blue revolution” in ocean fish farming does not cause harm to the oceans and the marine life they support. In December, California Rep. Lois Capps introduced the National Sustainable Offshore Aquaculture Act, a bill that addresses the potential threats of poorly regulated fish farming in U.S. ocean waters. Her bill shares many of the features of a California state law, the Sustainable Oceans Act, which was signed by Goy. Arnold Schwarzenegger in 2006. That legislation regulates fish farming in state waters, which extend three miles off the California coast. At present, all aquaculture operations in California and the U.S. are located just a few miles offshore. If the U.S. follows California’s lead, we might be able to reward innovation and responsibility in aquaculture and at the same time prevent the kind of boom-and-bust development that happened in Chile. Unlike previous attempts to legislate fish farming at the national level, the Capps bill would ensure that U.S. aquaculture in federal waters, which extend from three to 200 miles offshore, establishes as a priority the protection of wild fish and functional ecosystems. It would ensure that industry expansion occurs only under the oversight of strong, performance-based environmental, socioeconomic and liability standards. The bill also would pre-empt ecologically risky, piecemeal regulation of ocean fish farming in different regions of the U.S. Indeed, regulation efforts are already underway in many states, with no consistent standards to govern the industry’s environmental or social performance. Previous federal bills introduced in 2005 and 2007 were fundamentally flawed -- and ultimately did not pass -- because they put the goal of aquaculture expansion far above that of environment protection. Now, for the first time, a bill has been introduced that would demonstrably protect marine ecosystems, fishing communities and seafood consumers from the risks of poorly regulated open-ocean aquaculture. The Obama administration is currently developing a national policy to guide aquaculture development. It would do well to embrace the vision for a sciencebased and precautionary approach to ensure a responsible future for ocean fish farming. Rosamond L. Naylor is director of the program on food security and the environment at Stanford University. George H. Leonard is director of the aquaculture program at the Ocean Conservancy Santa Cruz, Calif. They wrote this article for the Los Angeles Times. Court rulings Court rulings have allowed states to control ocean development through environmental regulations Rachael E. Salcido in 2008 Associate Professor of Law, University of the Pacific, McGeorge School of Law, Offshore Federalism and Ocean Industrialization, Tulane Law Review 82 Tul. L. Rev. 1355 The most important public lands case for offshore federalism insights is California Coastal Commission v. Granite Rock Co. n308 The Supreme Court held that state regulation of minerals development was not preempted merely because the federal government also regulated minerals development pursuant to its Property Clause power. n309 The California Coastal Act prohibits development in the state's coastal zone [*1404] without a California Coastal Commission permit. n310 Granite Rock Company, a mining company, entered federal public lands in the coastal zone open to prospecting pursuant to the Mining Act of 1872 and obtained unpatented mining claims in the Los Padres National Forest. n311 Granite Rock sought an injunction and declaratory relief exempting it from the Coastal Commission permit requirement. n312 The Court found that state regulation was not expressly preempted. n313 Moreover, after conducting the preemption analysis employed by modern courts - where the court examines whether the provision is either expressly or impliedly preempted - the Supreme Court determined that neither the National Forest Management Act, the FLPMA, nor the CZMA (which defined "coastal zone" to exclude federal public lands) preempts state environmental regulations. n314 The majority decision embraced the Coastal Commission's assertion that it would impose environmental regulations, not land-use controls, through its permitting requirements. n315 The decision was viewed as a significant CZMA victory for states n316 and has been severely criticized by those favoring federal supremacy. n317 CZMA The Coastal Zone Management act has given states authority over their coasts for the past three decades Russell 2004 (Robert H., J.D., Harvard Law School. Mr. Russell teaches environmental law in the graduate program at Tufts University, and has taught energy regulation, environmental law and policy, and property law at other universities and law schools in the Boston area. He also consults with nonprofit organizations and government agencies on environmental matters., “COASTAL WIND ENERGY GENERATION: CONFLICT AND CAPACITIE: SYMPOSIUM ARTICLE: Neither Out Far Nor in Deep: The Prospects for Utility-Scale Wind Power in the Coastal Zone”, 2004 Boston College Law School, Boston College Environmental Affairs Law Review, Lexis Nexis) II. COASTAL MANAGEMENT: A REGULATORY COLLAGE Expansive near-shore wind development is likely to attract controversy and opposition. n59 But whether the outcry is loud or muted, the controversy will be examined through the lens of the nation's coastal zone management program. The coastal zone program is the primary means by which federal, state, and local agencies and political units attempt to balance and harmonize intensive and contradictory patterns of use along the expansive American shore. To fully appreciate the challenges wind power faces, it is necessary to consider the values, policy objectives, and legal framework of this unusual program. n60 A. The Fault Line of Coastal Policy Over the centuries, the American coastline has become a conflict waiting to happen. From colonial times, public trust concepts have accorded to private citizens the right to engage in a variety of commercial activities along the coast and in coastal waters. n61 During that early period, the states generally took the lead in regulating offshore fishing. n62 Not long after, the federal government developed an interest in maintaining shoreline integrity. n63 American federalism, augmented by a long tradition of local land use control, continues to ensure that coastal oversight is a relatively decentralized, and therefore complex, task. In the twentieth century, particularly in recent decades, the potential for conflict has been realized. The 1990 U.S. population living in coastal counties stood at more than 133 million. That population is increasing nearly fifteen percent faster than in inland areas. n64 By 2025, [*233] nearly three-quarters of the nation is expected to live along the coast n65--even though its 672 coastal counties account for only fourteen percent of the total land area of the contiguous states. n66 New understanding of the enormous biological productivity of the coastal ocean--the area stretching 200 nautical miles from the shoreline to the far edge of the Exclusive Economic Zone n67-has served to intensify the conflict. Today, the coastal ocean is a vital and unique ecological resource. It also is the source of fossil fuel and mineral wealth, and significant recreational opportunities. n68 Offshore wind power is one of the most recent arrivals in a complicated, congested, and contentious arena. At the most general level, the challenges that confront wind development arise from the two faces of federalism: (1) state exercise of power to defend territorial waters from locally undesirable coastal uses; n69 and (2) a persistent federal aversion to addressing or even identifying the most pressing of the myriad demands for coordination that test coastal management. n70 B. The CZMA: A Harbinger of Devolution The Coastal Zone Management Act (CZMA) n71 establishes the structure whereby competing demands and conflicts along the coast and in state waters are mediated among federal, state, and local agencies. n72 [*234] When it was enacted more than thirty years ago, the CZMA presaged a shift in regulatory authority from the federal government to the states--a trend that has accelerated over the past two decades. n73 The Act and state programs it promotes mark a period of intensifying and sometimes incompatible public and private interest in coastal resources, both on land and in water. Unlike other legislation affecting the coast and ocean, n74 the CZMA is designed to be general and integrative in its application. Unlike many other major environmental laws, it openly embraces a devolutionary federalism. n75 It encourages states to take charge of their own coastal problems, often with little federal oversight and even less interference. The CZMA, in fact, remains one of the few major examples of a federal statute that envisions a fully cooperative relationship among the levels of government. It is said to be both the federal government's "first major experiment with an integrated environmental program," n76 and "the oldest national-level coastal management program in the [*235] world . . . ." n77 And, from a state perspective, the CZMA appears to have weathered relatively well. n78 But for others, particularly those seeking to site utility-scale wind farms near populated shorelines, the early signs point to choppy waters ahead. 1. The General Approach The Coastal Zone Management Act addresses a wide spectrum of potentially conflicting activities and uses, yet it does this in an indirect manner. n79 Rather than attempting to command specific substantive results, Congress established a procedural matrix that, in its view, would achieve those results in practice. n80 Its central premise is that effective coastal management can arise from comprehensive state-level planning, provided background authority is properly allocated among federal, state, and local officials. The CZMA is intended to further the protection and development of each state's coastal zone, n81 including the coastal zone's "natural, [*236] commercial, recreational, ecological, industrial and esthetic resources . . . ." n82 Each one of these goals is broad and vague. In the aggregate, they serve to sharpen conflict among uses and users. n83 Reflecting the breadth and flexibility of these findings is the "great flexibility" n84 of the Act itself. States enjoy enormous leeway in crafting customized coastal zone plans. These plans can and do address a diverse range of issues. n85 Like coastal ecology itself, those issues may vary widely from jurisdiction to jurisdiction. n86 The CZMA's focus on process means that each coastal management program tends to operate like a "black box"--it can generate decisions, while failing to enunciate the clear principles and performance standards that many believe are a necessary prerequisite to coherent coastalzone management over the long term. n87 It is ironic that, at the time of its passage, the CZMA's main legislative competitor was a more comprehensive national land-use bill that would have subsumed coastal protection. Many in the environmental community favored this broader approach because the program would have been under the control of the Department of the Interior rather than the Department of Commerce, and because it promised a stronger federal hand in state decisionmaking. n88 But an influential [*237] commission n89 that had been clearing the path for national shoreline legislation concluded that coastal management should be largely the responsibility of the individual states. The result was a separate measure--the CZMA-guided by the principle of "cooperative federalism." n90 The more comprehensive initiative notwithstanding, coastal policy has remained a matter of state and local supervision for the past three decades. Like land-use planning and zoning, n91 it has been driven by distrust of centralized federal direction. n92 2. The Planning Process The cooperative coastal zone management blueprint is not difficult to read. The CZMA program is voluntary, yet it has attracted almost unanimous participation. This has been achieved by offering participating states two benefits: money and a conditional power to block federal decisionmaking. n93 To receive them, states must submit--then implement and maintain--a qualifying coastal management plan. Funding has never been generous. For all CZMA programs combined, it has averaged about $ 40 million a year, or a mere $ 1.2 million for each participating jurisdiction. n94 As a result, the second inducement, socalled [*238] "consistency review," n95 has come to serve as the more effective carrot. n96 Once a state's plan has been approved, federal coastal officials periodically review its implementation. n97 Enforcement, however, is limited. Funds may be withheld only if implementation has failed, and then only after a process that can take more than three years to complete. n98 States, of course, may update their approved coastal zone management plans to meet new challenges, but they are under no obligation to do so. Federal authorities may not manipulate or withhold grants or other funding as a means of pressuring a state to revise its coastal plan. n99 The CZMA gives States the authority to reject federal ocean policy- consistency review Russell 2004 (Robert H., J.D., Harvard Law School. Mr. Russell teaches environmental law in the graduate program at Tufts University, and has taught energy regulation, environmental law and policy, and property law at other universities and law schools in the Boston area. He also consults with nonprofit organizations and government agencies on environmental matters., “COASTAL WIND ENERGY GENERATION: CONFLICT AND CAPACITIE: SYMPOSIUM ARTICLE: Neither Out Far Nor in Deep: The Prospects for Utility-Scale Wind Power in the Coastal Zone”, 2004 Boston College Law School, Boston College Environmental Affairs Law Review, Lexis Nexis) C. (In) Consistency The most unusual feature of the CZMA and the one that has drawn the most attention from courts and commentators is consistency review, its single, clear enforcement mechanism. n134 In brief, consistency review permits a state whose coastal zone is affected by a federal or federally-permitted project n135 to file an objection, and thereby either halt the project or force its modification--if the project is found to be incompatible with an enforceable component of that state's federally-approved coastal zone management plan. n136 Consistency has attracted wide commentary. n137 Whether it hands states "veto" power over activities that may harm the coastal zone, or [*247] whether its effects are more subtle and less predictable, is a matter of continuing discussion. n138 Nonetheless, when adopted in 1972, the consistency provision represented "a significant innovation." n139 More than three decades later, it continues to carry symbolic, and potentially real, force. n140 Indeed, responding to a 1984 Supreme Court decision limiting its scope, n141 Congress in 1990 amended the CZMA to allow states to review the coastal impact of federal actions in federal waters. n142 Consistency is important here because it gives states the power to reject an offshore n143 wind power facility, even one to be built outside the state's three-mile territorial limit. Although disagreement continues regarding the scope of the power and its overall utility, n144 in state hands consistency review operates like a one-way ratchet. If a state does not want to encourage offshore wind, or wants to discourage a particular proposal, consistency review potentially serves to deflect both the developer's request for federal approvals and a federal government--or at least a federal agency--that is supportive of renewable energy. n145 On [*248] the other hand, if state policy seeks to encourage near-shore wind, consistency review is irrelevant; it cannot be used to force a federal agency to license a project. As for the federal agency itself, consistency is not an option. The ratchet turns only one way. Thus, the CZMA is more than simply non-preemptive; it engages in a form of reverse preemption. n146 Of course, if a project is opposed by both state and federal officials, the mechanism is not relevant. Energy Generic States are taking clean energy initiatives despite a lack of federal support Marsden 2013 (William, Postmedia News, “America's revolution threatens Canada”, The Leader-Post (Regina, Saskatchewan), August 3, 2013 Saturday, Lexis Nexis) California is planning a $9.5-billion U.S. high-speed train connection that's expected to take hundreds of thousands of commuters off the highways. In Rhode Island, the U.S. Bureau of Ocean Management put 93,000 hectares of continental shelf up for lease for wind turbines that could produce enough to power upwards of a million homes. In the greater scope of America's fossil fuel appetite, these clean energy initiatives could be mistaken as insignificant. Yet they carry all the signs of a quiet revolution gradually emerging across the nation. They are slowly reshaping the energy landscape in spite of a federal government that remains gridlocked over climate change legislation. "What we have seen regarding energy policy is that almost all Americans regardless of their political orientation are decidedly for clean energy future for America," said Edward Maibach, a professor at George Mason University who tracks public opinion on climate change. His data have given U.S. President Barack Obama and his closest advisers the confidence to go bold on clean energy, and dismiss projects such as Keystone XL as old economics. States lead in the context of energy policy GRUNWALD 2006 (MICHAEL, Wire Services, “Warming up to inconvenient facts; If climate change is real, what are we willing to do about it?”, The Record (Bergen County, NJ), July 30, 2006 Sunday, Lexis Nexis) Scott thinks waste reduction and energy efficiency are good for business as well as the Earth. He eventually wants his company to generate zero waste and use only renewable energy, and he wants his 60,000 suppliers to follow suit. That could drive the climate debate faster than years of congressional bloviation. And other sectors of corporate America are paying attention to climate as well. The storm-battered insurance and reinsurance industries are redlining vulnerable coastal areas. U.S. farmers are embracing no-till agriculture in growing numbers. Even some energy firms are trying to move "Beyond Petroleum," as the BP Global ads say; Entergy Corp. recently joined 12 states in suing the Bush administration over its refusal to regulate carbon emissions. States are leading the battle against greenhouse gases, filing lawsuits against the Bush administration's fuel-efficiency and clean-air efforts as well. California, for example, has proposed strict fuel-efficiency standards for cars sold in the state, and Republican Gov. Arnold Schwarzenegger wants to reduce the state's greenhouse emissions 80 percent by 2050. As the recent heat wave stoked brownout fears, he also announced a statewide conservation push, pleading with Californians to use less energy. Ultimately, conservation will have to play a big role in any emissions cuts; Vice President Cheney has mocked it as a virtuous but ludicrous energy strategy, yet the collective impact of individual actions could be huge. Fisheries Congress has given jurisdiction to the states for fisheries management, the aff undermines this jurisdiction Englebrecht ’02 (Erin, professor of law at Evansville, Can Aquaculture Continue to Circumvent the Regulatory Net of the MagnusonStevens Fishery Conservation and Management Act, Emory Law Journal, http://heinonline.org/HOL/Page?collection=journals&handle=hein.journals/emlj51&type=Text&id=1224, accessed: 7/12/14 GA) Congress enacted the EFH Provision in response to increasing threats to the nation's fisheries posed by the "continuing loss of marine, estuarine, and other aquatic habitats"176 and explicitly referenced coastal habitat in state boundaries.177 Congress directed that fishing activities be subject to enforce- able regulations to specifically protect the essential "spawning" and "breeding" habitat of the nation's fishery species. Such habitat is almost exclusively found in estuarine and coastal areas, which are entirely within the states' territorial seas. It is thus Congress's unequivocal intent that all fishing activities adversely affecting all designated EFH, whether in the federal or state zone, are subject to the substantive mandates of the 1996 EFH Provision Congress placed jurisdiction over fisheries to the states Englebrecht, 2002, Englebrecht, Erin, lawyer Ph.D from Emory. "Can Aquaculture Continue to Circumvent the Regulatory Net of the Magnuson-Stevens Fishery Conservation and Management Act." Emory Law Journal 3rd ser. 51 (2002): 1187-224. Hein Online. Web. 11 July 2014. CS Congress enacted the EFH Provision in response to increasing threats to the nation’s fisheries posed by the ‘continuing loss of marine, estuarine, and other aquatic habitats’ and explicitly referenced coastal habitat in state boundaries. mCongress directed that fishing activities be subject to enforce-able regulations to specifically protect the essential “spawning and ‘breeding” habitat of the nation’s fishery species. Such habitat is almost exclusively found in esluanne and coastal areas, which are entirely within the states’ territorial seas. h is thus Congress’s unequivocal intent that all fishing activities adversely affecting all designated EFH, whether in the federal or statc zone, are subject to the substantive mandates of the 1996 EFH Provision. Accordingly, if NMFS were to classify aquaculture as fishing,’ then aquaculture activities within state boundaries would be subject to enforceable conservation measures. Again, Congress’s enactment of the 1996 EFH Provision elevated the significance of NMFS’ determination for how to c1assi1y aquaculture. Nonetheless, NMFS’ policies on aquaculture with regard to the Magnuson-Stevens Act are not in conformance with the mandates of the 1996 EFH Provision. Empirically fish management has operated under a cooperative federalist model – states are given the majority of control over fisher management in accordance with federal law – this is distinct from direct federal management of fisheries such as the plan. Barstow in 1999(Erik T., University of Maine School of Law, Class of 1998, “AMERICAN LOBSTER FISHERY MANAGEMENT UNDER THE ATLANTIC COASTAL FISHERIES COOPERATIVE MANAGEMENT ACT: AN ATTEMPT AT COOPERATIVE FISHERY JURISDICTION,” OCEAN AND COASTAL LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 4:113) The 1996 Magnuson Act amendments post-date the decision to withdraw the Lobster FMP, and therefore, were in no way implicated in the initial determination. The amendments are, nevertheless, important in considering the underlying shift to cooperative management. It is quite likely that passage of the ACFCMA in 1993, and the lobster fishery situation as a whole, served as an impetus for the 1996 Magnuson Act Amendments. This conjecture is based upon the emphasis in the 1996 amendments on federal and state cooperative fishery management. This emphasis is particularly evident in the expanded authority of the states to regulate fishing activities outside of the traditional state waters. On the other hand, the 1996 Amendments have further complicated the transition to ASMFC management of the lobster fishery by requiring the regional councils to promulgate pro-active management measures for overfished fisheries. This particular aspect of the 1996 Amendments is addressed at greater length in Part N.A. State authority to regulate fishing vessels outside the boundaries of the state was the subject of substantial change. Section 1856(a)(3) of the Magnuson Act, was modified significantly and now articulates in the positive a state's authority to regulate vessels outside of its boundaries given specific circumstances.27 The first set of circumstances requires, as with the pre-Amendment version, that the vessel be registered under the laws of the state.' Furthermore, one of two additional requirements must be met: Either (1) no fishery management plan or pertinent Federal regulations exist with regards to the fishery in which the vessel is engaging; or, (2) the laws and/or regulations of the state must be consistent with the federal FMP or regulations applicable to the fishery in which the vessel is operating. 9 The 1996 Amendments provided a second significant expansion of potential state authority over a fishery that extends into federal waters. States may now regulate fishing vessels outside the boundaries of the state when the management plan, for the fishery in which the vessel is operating, "delegates management of the fishery to a State and the State's laws and regulations are consistent with such fishery management plan. '30 While not specifically addressed in the provision, presumably the FMP could simply delegate management authority to various states without providing an underlying framework of a specific management plan. No standards for measuring consistency of state laws and regulations would exist in such a situation. 31 If the Secretary determines certain state measures are inconsistent with the relevant FMP,th e Secretary must notify the state and the appropriate Council and then provide the state with the opportunity to correct the inconsistency.32 Failure by the state to correct such inconsistencies would result in suspension of the state's authority until corrective measures were taken and approved by the Secretary and the Council.33 Essential to the analysis under either section 1856(a)(3)(A) or (B), is the concept of "consistency" of state regulations. Any state regulation which either regulates vessels, licensed under its law, or which is an exercise of authority delegated to the state by a federal FMP, must be consistent with any existing FMP for the targeted fishery. Congressional hearings shed light on the primary intent underlying this requirement and the extent to which states may regulate consistently with existing federal regulations. A colloquy between Senator Snowe of Maine and Senator Stevens of Alaska, the author of the amendment, is particularly interesting as Senator Snowe specifically mentioned Maine's efforts in the area of lobster management. Senator Snow, after delineating several of Maine's specific lobster regulations, questioned whether Maine's regulations, that were more stringent than the regulations promulgated pursuant to the federal lobster management plan, would continue to be considered "consistent" with the Lobster FMP, under the intent of the amendment's author. 4 Senator Stevens responded affirmatively, stating that his amendment would protect "the existing authority of States to impose more stringent regulations which are not inconsistent with a management plan on its vessel in the Federal zone."3' Senator Stevens continued by noting that more stringent state regulations which were considered to be consistent prior to the amendment would continue to be considered consistent.36 Thus, a state may, consistent with the Congressional intent underlying the amendment, impose more stringent regulations over federal waters pursuant to authority vested by the amendment than are imposed by the federal regulations. These two changes to state jurisdiction under the Maguuson Act reflect the underlying movement towards cooperative federal-state jurisdiction. Indeed, they evidence support for a return of fishery management authority to the states as exemplified by the lobster fishery scenario. The amended Act, however, provides for such delegation to the state to be executed within the parameters of the Magnuson Act. A federal FMP can delegate management authority to a state, but require certain minimum standards by providing for them within the framework of the FMR In this manner the federal government may provide goals and guidelines for management of a particular fishery while leaving the specific methods to state and even local determination. An interesting question is whether this approach would have been an effective alternative for lobster fishery management rather than withdrawal of the FMP in favor of ASMFC management. Lobster stock rebuilding programs started at the federal level have failed – this resulted in a transition to state control over fishery management. Barstow in 1999(Erik T., University of Maine School of Law, Class of 1998, “AMERICAN LOBSTER FISHERY MANAGEMENT UNDER THE ATLANTIC COASTAL FISHERIES COOPERATIVE MANAGEMENT ACT: AN ATTEMPT AT COOPERATIVE FISHERY JURISDICTION,” OCEAN AND COASTAL LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 4:113) Central to proposed Amendment Five, and of greatest significance, was the comprehensive stockrebuilding program. This provision of the proposed Amendment is also central to the topic of this Comment, as the program sought to better recognize the regionalized needs and problems of the lobster fishery, and attempted to induce cooperation among the various states and the federally created NEFMC. Proposed Amendment Five would have created a framework process to institute a lobster stock rebuilding program in the EEZ with the intent that the several states would introduce similar measures in state waters. 75 Implementing regulations recognized four regions: Area 1 was to be the near shore EEZ waters of the Gulf of Maine; Area 2 would be the near shore EEZ waters of Southern New England; Area 3 was the offshore waters in the EEZ; and, Area 4 would be the near shore EEZ waters of the middle Atlantic. 76 This regional approach to conservation and management was intended to better address the specific needs of each area and respond to the various environmental and economic forces unique to each region. Tailor-made management programs for each area would, it was hoped, foster stronger regional support.'" The stock rebuilding framework also created Effort Management Teams (EMT).'78 The EMTs were a unique, and somewhat ingenious, mechanism to ensure regional input into lobster fishery management. An EMT was created for each of the four regions noted above and charged with the responsibility of making recommendations for stock rebuilding to the NEFMC. 179 EMTs were to consist of a common, core group of NMFS, state, and NMFC representatives "0 in an attempt to encourage action and compliance by including all interested players in the lobster fishery. Furthermore, each EMT was required to "consult with lobster fishermen operating within each Management area.., with the intent of reaching consensus regarding the specific measures to be applied in each area.''. A deadline of January 20, 1995 was set for the submission of the EMT recommendations to the NEFMC. s2 The Council was required to adopt or modify the recommendations and then submit to the Secretary corresponding management measures in compliance with the Lobster FMP objectives by July 20, 1995.83 Failure of the NEFMC to meet this deadline would allow the Secretary of Commerce to determine whether a secretarial amendment to the FMP was needed. " While the various EMTs submitted their recommendations by the set deadline, the NEFMC failed to meet the July 20th deadline due to the unwillingness of state directors from Maine, New Hampshire, Rhode Island, and Connecticut to implement measures in support of a Council amendment.185 The NMFS had previously indicated to the NEFMC that its support of an amendment implementing stock rebuilding measures, such as proposed Amendment Five, was predicated on state participation in the administration of the amendment and implementation of complimentary state programs.'86 The failure of the states to reach consensus on complimentary programs, and the resulting lack of support of the NMFS sounded the death knell for Amendment Five. The failure of Amendment Five is of great significance in most part due to what it attempted to reach; a system of co-operative management between the federal agencies, the NEFMC, and the relevant state parties. Amendment Five would have required the states to rely on the federally created NEFMC for its directives and for the implementation of local recommendations, a relationship not without antagonism. Furthermore, a lack of initiative for agreement and consequences for failure, as between the states, was reflected in the inability of Maine, New Hampshire, Rhode Island, and Connecticut to adopt measures in support of the NEFMC Amendment. The model of fishery management based on power centered with the federal government and siphoned down to a state and local level had failed for the lobster fishery. It became apparent that a paradigm of management was necessary wherein the states, holding a vested interest in the lobster fishery, more directly wielded regulatory and jurisdictional power. Monitoring Coastal states have the jurisdiction to develop ocean management programs Heimes 10 (Rita S., “Ocean Management & Planning in the United States: From Competition to Cooperation”, Annuaire de Droit Maritime et Océanique, Forthcoming, http://mhk.pnnl.gov/sites/default/files/publications/Heimes_2010.pdf) Many coastal states have coastal management programs that prepare Coastal Management Plans, administer federal grants under the CZMA, and coordinate policies with federal agencies. These programs have varying degrees of responsibility and authority, and are housed within different governmental departments depending on the state.72 Through these programs and targeted state legislation, states have been engaging in various forms of “marine zoning” and area planning efforts for over twenty years,73 and the idea of ocean zoning is hardly novel.74 In the second half of this decade, however, some states’ leading efforts to comprehensively map and zone in three dimensions their ocean waters, including in some instances overlapping federal waters, have set a precedent for other coastal states and even the federal government to follow. This article describes only three such programs as leaders in state-level coastal and marine spatial planning. States have the right to develop ocean monitoring systems—Massachusetts proves Heimes 10 (Rita S., “Ocean Management & Planning in the United States: From Competition to Cooperation”, Annuaire de Droit Maritime et Océanique, Forthcoming, http://mhk.pnnl.gov/sites/default/files/publications/Heimes_2010.pdf) The Massachusetts Ocean Management Plan represents a model ocean planning process on at least three levels: It was developed in a relatively short period of time with involvement from multiple stakeholders; it is backed with the hefty authority of a powerful cabinet-level position representing many key state agencies; and its scientific basis was supported initially, and will continue to be informed in the future, pursuant to a major grant from a private foundation that coordinated many participants. In 2003, the Massachusetts governor appointed a task force to investigate ocean use, trends and governance mechanisms, and propose changes in legislation and ocean administration.114 Following its report, Waves of Change, 115 the Massachusetts legislature passed the Massachusetts Ocean Act of 2008.116 The statute directed that the Secretary of the Executive Office of Energy and Environmental Affairs (EEA) develop an integrated ocean management plan.117 The Act was signed on 28 May, 2008; the final report was due by 31 December, 2009.118 To assist the Secretary of EEA with developing the plan, the Ocean Act created an ocean advisory commission comprised of state legislators; directors of the coastal zone management, environmental protection, and marine resources commissions; and several other members of the public appointed by the governor, including one representing commercial fishing interests and one with knowledge of offshore renewable energy development.119 The Ocean Act also established “an ocean science advisory council to assist the secretary in creating a baseline assessment and obtaining any other scientific information necessary for the development of an ocean management plan.”120 In parallel with these official and regulatory developments, a powerful coalition of organizations joined together to form the Massachusetts Ocean Partnership (MOP).121 This independent “public-private partnership” was funded by the Gordon and motivated scientists, policymakers, lawyers, fishermen and environmental Betty Moore Foundation through 2011 “to convene diverse stakeholders and develop a Five Year Strategic Plan to advance Ecosystem-based Marine Spatial Planning” in Massachusetts.122 The MOP worked closely with the EEA in preparing and publicly vetting the Ocean Management Plan. The partnership between EEA and MOP proved effective during plan development and continues during plan implementation. While EEA was responsible for development of the plan pursuant to the legislative mandate of the Oceans Act (including management of the plan development process and drafting of the plan itself), MOP funding and staff provided EEA with necessary support. For example, MOP funding helped EEA maximize the public involvement goal (videos of workshop presentations were made available on-line). Additionally, MOP funded important policy analyses (e.g., a review of other ocean management efforts from around the world to identify a potential frameworks for Massachusetts) and development of derived data products (e.g., transformation of raw Vessel Monitoring Systems data), and continues to help EEA address identified priority science needs (e.g., characterizing spatial patterns of recreational activity in Massachusetts waters).123 States have the ability to make ocean monitoring programs—California proves COCMP No Date (Coastal Ocean Currents Monitoring Program, http://www.cocmp.org/) History: In 2005, the California State Coastal Conservancy and the State Water Resources Control Board invested $21 million from the infrastructure to map ocean surface currents. The California Coastal Ocean Currents Monitoring Program (COCMP) uses a suite of technologies, high-frequency radar in particular, to track ocean surface currents in near real-time. The 54 land-based stations now span the California coastline, voter-approved Propositions 40 and 50 funds to build providing anyone with access to the Internet the ability to track past and near real-time movement of California’s coastal waters, including any floating pollutants. COCMP is an investment by the State of California to better manage our ocean and coastal resources, and to ensure a healthy ocean environment for current and future generations. Pollution/Conservation States have authority over issues of pollution- 2011 EPA ruling proves US Official News 2013 (US Official News, “Kentucky: Attorney General Conway Announces Bipartisan Brief Opposing CrossState Air Pollution Regulations”, November 16, 2013 Saturday, Lexis Nexis) Department of Commonwealth, The State of Kentucky has issued the following news release: Attorney General Conway announced today that Kentucky has joined eight other states in a major brief filed in the United States Supreme Court opposing the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency’s new rule on cross-state air pollution. The amicus brief argues that EPA exceeded its authority under the federal Clean Air Act when the agency promulgated a rule in 2011 announcing new air pollution cuts and imposing federal implementation plans on states. The brief argues the CAA requires the EPA to give states an opportunity to decide how to meet new air pollution standards. The brief was signed by a bipartisan group of attorneys general representing the states of West Virginia, Arizona, Arkansas, Kentucky, Missouri, Montana, North Dakota, South Dakota and Wyoming. It was filed in support of 15 other states, as well as industry groups and labor organizations, who sued EPA on this issue in 2011. In August 2012, the U.S. Court of Appeals for the D.C. Circuit struck down the regulation, saying that it "exceeds the agency’s statutory authority." The Supreme Court agreed to review the rule earlier this year. "Other state attorneys general and I are urging the nation’s highest court to uphold the appellate court decision and leave important questions about how states should meet new air pollution standards at the state level, as clearly spelled out in the Clean Air Act," General Conway said. According to the court of appeals’ opinion, "EPA’s rule defines emissions reduction responsibilities for 28 upwind States based on those States’ contributions to downwind States’ air quality problems. The Rule limits emissions from upwind States’ coal- and natural gas-fired power plants, among other sources. Those power plants generate the majority of electricity used in the United States." The court of appeals’ opinion held that EPA crossed the Clean Air Act’s "federalism bar" when EPA attempted to take away the states’ right to decide how to make cuts in air pollution within their borders. As the court explained, "a State may decide to impose different emissions limits on individual coal-burning power plants, natural gas-burning power plants, and other sources of air pollution, such as factories, refineries, incinerators, and agricultural activities." The parties to the case will present oral arguments before the Supreme Court in December. A decision is expected by next June. Three Miles The states control three miles of sea off of their shoreline Resources Agency of California 95 (The Resources Agency of California, “California’s Ocean Resources: An Agenda for the Future”, July 1995, http://resources.ca.gov/ocean/html/chapt_3.html) Debate over who controls and manages the waters and resources found offshore the United States began in the late 1700's and continues to this day. Issues in this debate include key federal and State relationships which must be better understood for effective management of California's ocean resources. ¶ Soon after the founding of the United States, the newly formed federal government asserted sovereignty over a territorial sea extending three miles from the coast. Moreover, the coastal states asserted the ability to develop ocean resources out to three miles. Over the past 45 years, however, a number of events have occurred which drastically modified management of the offshore area. In 1947, the United States Supreme Court upset what had appeared to be settled law and determined that the United States, rather than coastal states, had paramount rights over the nation's coastal waters and resources [United States v. California, 332 U.S. 19 (1947)]. This decision was surprising to coastal states, and set the stage for a debate resulting in the enactment of the Submerged Lands Act of 1953 (granting coastal states ownership of the lands and resources out to three nautical miles from shore). Also enacted was the Outer Continental Shelf Lands Act of 1953, establishing federal jurisdiction over the resources beyond three nautical miles from shore and creating a legal process for developing those resources.¶ In the early 1970's, Congress recognized that activities beyond states' control and jurisdiction could significantly affect coastal states. Congress enacted the Coastal Zone Management Act (CZMA; 16 U.S.C. 1451 et seq.) in 1972, providing a crucial link between coastal states and federal activities, or federally permitted activities, which occur just beyond state waters. As an incentive for states to develop management plans for their coastal resources, the Congress granted states the ability to review, and in some circumstances stop, federally permitted activities which "affect" the resources of the coastal zone, if those activities are not consistent with the federally approved state coastal program. However, the CZMA allows the U.S. Department of Commerce to override a state's objection to a federal permit activity if the Secretary for Commerce finds that the objection is not supported by the approved coastal management program, or the activity is otherwise required in the interests of national security.¶ The states control three mile off of the coastline Marine Conservation Institute ND (Marine Conservation Institute, “Economic Importance”, ND, http://easybib.com/cite/eval?url=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.marineconservation.org%2Fmedia%2Fshining_sea%2Ftheme_economics.htm) The majority of the US population lives near the coast, not just because the ocean is beautiful but because the ocean is a major hub of economic activity. The sea provides us with food and livelihoods along every coast of the United States and its territories. Commercial, recreational, and subsistence fisheries bring in many millions of pounds of fish -and dollars- each year to coastal communities. People also use the ocean and shoreline for boating, sightseeing, vacationing, and other recreational activities.¶ Despite the development of planes, trains, and automobiles, shipping is still the major means for transporting goods internationally, and many cities rely on their ports as a major source of revenue. The ocean is also valued for the natural resources that lie beneath the ocean floor. In the Gulf of Mexico alone there exists billions of dollars' worth of oil and natural gas.¶ ¶ Exclusive Economic Zone (EEZ)¶ As on land, the sea is crossed by boundary lines drawn by people for exploration and use of resources. Generally speaking, the water stretching 12 nautical miles directly off the shoreline is considered sovereign territory of the adjoining country, except that foreign ships (military and civilian) are allowed to pass through it. The first 3 miles off the coast are state waters, meaning that each US state manages and controls use within their own region.¶ Beyond the territorial sea, is the area where countries have the right to manage and control marine affairs and resources, such as fishing, mineral extraction and oil drilling. This area of ocean, extending 200 nautical miles from a country’s coast, is called the Exclusive Economic Zone (EEZ).¶ ¶ Exclusive economic zone (EEZ) is an area of sea up to 200 nautical miles from a country’s coast.¶ ¶ The USA has jurisdiction over quite a lot of the world’s ocean. For example, the US EEZ surrounding the islands of Guam and the Northern Marianas, roughly 5,600 miles from the West Coast of the USA, is home to the Mariana Trench—the deepest place in the ocean. The US EEZ also contains water surrounding America Samoa in the Southern Hemisphere, portions of the Arctic Sea, waters off the Virgin Islands and the Puerto Rico Trench in the Caribbean Sea. In total, the USA has jurisdiction over more of the ocean than land. In fact, the USA has jurisdiction over more ocean than any other country, an area of 4,382,646 square miles (territorial waters plus EEZ). Link Aquaculture Aquaculture is being regulated by states now- even open ocean aquaculture is a state interest because of spillover effects Rachael E. Salcido in 2008 Associate Professor of Law, University of the Pacific, McGeorge School of Law, Offshore Federalism and Ocean Industrialization, Tulane Law Review 82 Tul. L. Rev. 1355 The newest ocean development projects promise an expanded range of benefits, many of which have no historical precedent. One example is located offshore of California, where the Grace Mariculture Project is underway. n22 The project uses a retired oil rig, Platform Grace, located 10.5 miles off the coast of Ventura, to cultivate and rear marine organisms (primarily fish) for human consumption. n23 Aquaculture projects such as this are generally being promoted to reduce the pressure on natural stocks of fish and to fill the widening gap between supply and demand of fish as a source of protein for human diets. n24 Ocean aquaculture proponents advocate use of offshore areas as a way to avoid near-shore conflicts and significant coastal development. n25 As explained by the Grace Mariculture Project, "by moving operations to an offshore environment, the Grace Mariculture [*1362] Project is the next step in the research and development of sustainable aquaculture." n26 But this "next step" is not necessarily benign. Several environmental concerns about the advent of open-ocean aquaculture - sea farming occurring far from shore - have impeded economic development of aquaculture in the United States and provide fuel for additional state-federal conflicts. n27 These concerns include escape of reared fish, the spread of disease, and concentration of fish wastes. n28 In light of these unresolved scientific questions about the environmental impacts of open-ocean aquaculture, some legislators representing state interests have threatened to impose an openocean aquaculture moratorium, much like the moratorium prohibiting oil drilling in regions offshore California and Florida. n29 Furthermore, states have begun to move ahead with comprehensive statutes to address environmental concerns, which may provide additional constraints on offshore aquaculture developments to the extent that any projects utilizing federal offshore areas will necessarily need to pass through state-governed offshore areas. n30 CZMA The federal government must comply with the CZMA and consult states when operating in their waters SALCIDO 2010 (Rachael E. Salcido 2010. Professor Rachael Salcido is a scholar of environmental and natural resources law, with particular expertise in ocean and coastal law and ecosystem restoration. Her articles have appeared in prominent law journals and she is an active member of the Rocky Mountain Mineral Law Foundation. Law Applicable on the Outer Continental Shelf and in the Exclusive Economic Zone Source: The American Journal of Comparative Law, Vol. 58, Supplement: Welcoming the World: U. S. National Reports to the XVIIIth International Congress of Comparative Law pp. 407-435) A second incentive for state participation in CZMA planning is known as the "consistency requirement." The federal government must seek a consistency determination from the state coastal management agency when authorizing activities if it is reasonably foreseeable that the activity "will affect any natural resources, land uses, or water uses" in the coastal zone of a state.31 The CZMA pro vides that federal agency activities shall be carried out "consistent to the maximum extent practicable with the enforceable policies" of the state's plan.32 The consistency requirement also applies when a pri vate party or other non-federal actor seeks approval from a federal agency for an activity.33 Finally, outer continental shelf plans for exploration, development, or production of oil and gas are also subject to a consistency determination. This appears both in provisions of the CZMA34 as well as in OCSLA,35 which specifically regulates outer continental shelf oil and gas development. In this manner states have some influence over activities beyond their immediate offshore boundaries. Tension between the federal government and states has been greatest in the context of oil and gas development offshore,36 but emerging uses of the submerged lands and waters of the EEZ have spurred new con flicts between state and federal actors. Energy The federal government must consult the states and they have the power to reject renewable energy projects Griset 2011 (Todd J., practices law with Preti Flaherty's Energy and Telecommunications Group from the Augusta, Maine office. His clients include renewable and other energy developers, industrial and forest products manufacturers and commercial entities, “HARNESSING THE OCEAN'S POWER: OPPORTUNITIES IN RENEWABLE OCEAN ENERGY RESOURCES”, Marine Law Institute, University of Maine School of Law, Ocean and Coastal Law Journal, Lexis Nexis) C. States' Roles In addition to this complex web of federal regulation, states retain considerable authority regarding offshore renewable energy projects in their adjacent waters. Each state has broad discretion to regulate such projects; the resulting lack of uniformity of state regulation adds yet another layer of regulatory risk to projects. Reflecting federalism-- the balance between states' rights and federal rights-- the federal Coastal Zone Management Act (CZMA) n124 requires applicants for federal licenses or permits affecting a state's costal zone to obtain a state certification that a proposed project is consistent with that state's coastal zone management program. n125 If a state refuses to issue such a consistency certification, the Secretary of Commerce may overrule the state and authorize the issuance of a permit only if the Secretary concludes after a notice and comment period that the proposed activities are either consistent with the objectives of the [*416] CZMA, or are "otherwise necessary in the interest of national security." n126 Thus, the CMZA provides states with a powerful tool in deciding whether to allow the development of offshore renewable energy projects. Furthermore, electricity generated by an offshore project--even one sited in federal waters--must generally be transmitted to shore for distribution and consumption. In practical terms, this requires crossing state-jurisdictional coastal zones. n127 This creates a significant role for states in reviewing and permitting the transmission cables needed to carry the power produced at sea to consumers on land, both in leasing subsurface rights for laying cable and in reviewing the utility aspects of the proposed transmission infrastructure. Even where a state's authority is limited to reviewing the onshore transmission development associated with an offshore energy project, in practice, states' evaluations of these transmission aspects are often informed by the to the fate of the project. n128 States may also affect the fate of projects through their regulation of utility activities. Through the exercise of their rights to regulate utilities and establish utility retail rates, states generally have jurisdiction to approve power purchase agreements between offshore energy project developers and utilities. Securing approval of such power purchase agreements is a critical step in any project's successful development, as developers are generally reluctant to understanding that the transmission and generation components are each integral incur the major capital costs required to develop an offshore project without the certainty of an offtake agreement for the power to be produced. n129 While such state review is generally conducted by public utilities commissions or their analogues, experience has shown that issues beyond utility ratemaking, such as aesthetics or environmental considerations, often end up being raised in these utility forums. For example, the Massachusetts Department of Public Utilities heard extensive testimony on such issues in the context of its review of the proposed power purchase agreement between the utility provider National Grid and Cape Wind. n130 Because of [*417] the power reserved to states, such issues may play a large role in the ultimate success of renewable ocean energy projects. This state regulatory role rests on top of the multiple layers of federal regulation described above, adding another layer of regulatory complexity. Federal Ocean Policy State consultation over federal ocean development is key- it balances state and federal interests Rachael E. Salcido in 2008 Associate Professor of Law, University of the Pacific, McGeorge School of Law, Offshore Federalism and Ocean Industrialization, Tulane Law Review 82 Tul. L. Rev. 1355 Unlike other federal laws adopted during this time that directly prescribed certain state obligations, the approach of the CZMA was to foster cooperation between federal, state, and local governments by purely voluntary means. n148 Congress recognized the concurrent interests of states and the federal government in the coastal zone and sought a governance mechanism that would capitalize on this interdependence. n149 The CZMA acknowledged that states have [*1382] jurisdiction over the shoreline out to three miles offshore, allowing them to manage sensitive coastal areas such as estuaries, wetlands, and coastal development that are integral to marine ecosystem sustainability. n150 The CZMA encouraged state creation of coastal management plans (CMP) by offering two important incentives: (1) matching grants to support state coastal planning and management and (2) a consultation role in shaping development projects in federally managed areas based on the state's coastal management plan. n151 In adopting this voluntary approach, based on financial incentives and a consultation role in federal project developments, the CZMA created the current cooperative federalism framework. n152 As NOAA recently characterized the consultation aspect of the CZMA, "these "consistency' requirements provide an avenue for states to participate in or influence management of ocean resources under federal jurisdiction." n153 The consistency determination is the heart of conflict resolution in the CZMA. A federal project must be consistent with enforceable policies of a federally approved state CMP, developed and implemented by the coastal state. n154 By statute, state CMPs must incorporate specified objectives, such as consideration of national interests. n155 Almost all coastal states have approved coastal zone [*1383] management plans and receive funding from the federal government to implement them. n156 From an environmental standpoint, there are at least two shortcomings of the current consistency process. From the start, environmental considerations inherent in particular offshore or coastal projects have not been altogether fleshed out prior to state consistency findings. n157 States and environmental groups have often complained that environmental impact assessments are not complete by the time the state must determine whether a reviewed project application is consistent with the enforceable policies of a state's CMP. n158 Second, the federal government encouraged state planning for areas under state jurisdiction but did not undertake similar planning for offshore areas. n159 There is no comprehensive EEZ plan discussing the feasibility or desirability of particular developments in federal waters. Importantly, as noted, the consistency determination is a vital component of the CZMA, and anything that detracts from its full and effective implementation necessarily erodes the "cooperative federalism" aim of the statute. But if consistency determinations are not meaningful because they are compromised by a lack of needed information (either environmental impacts or future development plans), these policy goals are also undermined. This contradiction is inherent in the stated goals of the CZMA, which initially set out to "protect, preserve and develop" the coastal zone but which was frequently amended, and now includes (in addition to encouraging state-federal coordination, protection, and restoration) the following: Priority consideration being given to coastal-dependent uses and orderly processes for siting major facilities related to national defense, energy, fisheries development, recreation, ports and transportation, and the location, to the maximum extent practicable, of new commercial [*1384] and industrial developments in or adjacent to areas where such development already exists. Increased federal action in ocean policy causes state backlash and power struggles. Juda 2006 (Lawrence, Department of Marine Affairs, University of Rhode Island, “The Report of the U.S. Commission on Ocean Policy: State Perspectives”, Coastal Management, Jan-Mar2006, Vol. 34 Issue 1, p1-16. 16p, EBSCOHost, Date Accessed: 10 July 2014) Regional Approaches to Ocean Governance A notable recommendation made by the US. Commission on Ocean Policy calls for the creation of Regional Ocean Councils (ROCs) as a device to overcome the jurisdictional administrative, and financial limitations of individual states in their approach to ocean governance. The response of the governors to this recommendation generally indicated recognition of the need for regional cooperation, but expressed very significant wariness and even some outright opposition to the creation of such councils. A number of governors viewed the creation of ROCs as a potential challenge to the role of individual states or as a threat that could undermine existing regional mechanisms. Governor Murkowski of Alaska asked for major changes in the Commission's recommendations concerning ROCs, warning that it "would be unacceptable for any council or board to reduce the state's authority for management of our jurisdictional waters or lands" and indicated that he would be prepared to “protect the state's sovereign interests”. Florida maintained that ROCs were not needed to improve interstate and regional cooperation and was concerned that, if created, ROCs might seek to impose federal or regional requirements on individual states that would preempt state or local governance. Michigan expressed cautious support for the creation of ROCs but warned that it was the states that would have to retain authority over water use and management of coastal resources. Several states expressed concern over the potential duplication of roles that might occur should ROCs formed and pointed to existing regional mechanisms such as Regional Fisheries Management Councils (RFMCs) and regional environmental efforts such as the Gulf of Maine Program, the Chesapeake Bay Program, the Gulf of Mexico Program, and the National Estuary Program. What exactly would be the nature and role of the proposed new ROCs? Would the ROC process be mandatory or recommendatory? What authority would the ROCs have? How would the ROCs relate to the RFMCs and other extant regional organizations? Who would be represented on the ROCs? Such questions and the comments of the states demonstrated fears that but another layer of bureaucracy was being established, that ROCs would interfere with on-going regional efforts, and that they would place new, additional demands on the states. It is apparent that efforts to establish the envisaged ROCs will require further and careful consideration of their nature, roles, and relationships to on-going regional programs. Fisheries Federal fishery regulation pre-empts state regulatory efforts. Glicksman in 2006(Robert, George Washington University Law School, “From Cooperative to Inoperative Federalism: The Perverse Mutation of Environmental Law and Policy,” 41 Wake Forest L. Rev. 719) EPA is not the only federal agency whose organic statutes and implementing regulation have had preemptive effect. In one case, for example, the D.C. Circuit concluded in affirming the district court’s denial of a preliminary injunction that a rail carrier was substantially likely to succeed in its argument that regulations issued by the Department of Transportation under the Federal Rail Carrier Safety Act358 preempted more stringent regulations adopted by the District of Columbia that restricted the transportation of hazardous materials by rail near the U.S. Capitol Building.359 Some state and local efforts to minimize the dangers posed by nuclear waste also have fallen by the wayside based on the preemptive effect of the Atomic Energy Act.360 The courts have found that legislation governing management of the federal lands preempts some state and local environmental regulation. The Eighth Circuit, for example, held that the General Mining Law preempted a county ordinance prohibiting the issuance of new permits for surface metal extraction in the national forests.361 In another case, the court held that the Magnuson Fishery Conservation and Management Act362 preempted state regulations that prohibited the use of gill nets to take rockfish in federal waters.363 Fishery management is a proving ground for federalism – it has empirically been devolved to state regulation in cooperation with federal entities. Barstow in 1999(Erik T., University of Maine School of Law, Class of 1998, “AMERICAN LOBSTER FISHERY MANAGEMENT UNDER THE ATLANTIC COASTAL FISHERIES COOPERATIVE MANAGEMENT ACT: AN ATTEMPT AT COOPERATIVE FISHERY JURISDICTION,” OCEAN AND COASTAL LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 4:113) Fishery management has become a proving ground of this regulatory reform and the call for return of power to the states. In 1996 the Atlantic lobster fishery became the target of this emerging federalism. Lobster fishery management, it is contended, is a prime example of a federal regulatory scheme that is better suited to state management. As a result, in late March 1996, the National Marine Fisheries Service (NMFS) an-nounced its intention to withdraw approval of the federal Fishery Management Plan for the American Lobster Fishery (Lobster FMP) and implementing regulations.3 Conservation and management of the lobster fishery, proposed the NMFS, could be managed by the states through the Atlantic States Marine Fishery Commission (ASMFC).4 The NMFS called upon the ASMFC to further develop its lobster coastal management plan (CMP) and to develop regulations under the authority of the Atlantic Coastal Fisheries Cooperative Management Act (ACFCMA).5 Federal regulation over fisheries creates tension between the federal and state government – could be construed as a constitutionality issue. Barstow in 1999(Erik T., University of Maine School of Law, Class of 1998, “AMERICAN LOBSTER FISHERY MANAGEMENT UNDER THE ATLANTIC COASTAL FISHERIES COOPERATIVE MANAGEMENT ACT: AN ATTEMPT AT COOPERATIVE FISHERY JURISDICTION,” OCEAN AND COASTAL LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 4:113) The second issue that grows from this balance of power inherent in the cooperative jurisdiction of the ACFCMA pertains to the Secretary of Commerce's powers. Under the ACFCMA the Secretary has enlarged powers in the state waters of the ASMFC states. The ACFCMA grants the Secretary of Commerce authority to take action within state waters which is likely to raise concerns of state sovereignty. The most significant power invested in the Secretary is the ability to impose a moratorium on fishing in the targeted fishery in the waters of a state that is deemed out of compliance with the ASMFC.245 Violation of a moratorium placed on a fishery in a state's territorial sea may lead to federal civil and/or criminal penalties.2' Obviously, the imposition of a moratorium by the federal government on state waters, at the very least, gives rise to adversarial posturing between the penalized state and the federal government that is the antithesis of the cooperative environment that the ACFCMA seeks to promote. Furthermore, it is likely to create tension between the penalized state and the other ASMFC states that, as is discussed in the following paragraph, must determine non-compliance. Both levels of animosity would likely inhibit future development of management and conservation measures. Additionally, and perhaps more interesting from a legal standpoint, is the potential implication of the Tenth Amendment. State control over and responsibility for fishery management in state waters is well established.247 A Secretarial moratorium on state waters arguably is a federal impingement of state sovereignty and rights as guaranteed by the Tenth Amendment to the United States Constitution.248 In a situation where a Secretarial imposed moratorium were to take place pursuant to the lobster management plan developed by the ASMFC, it is probable, absent quick remedial efforts by the state, that such a moratorium would be challenged on Tenth Amendment grounds. Congress has historically been able to exercise broad regulatory power over fishery management pursuant to the Commerce Clause, which would weigh in favor of constitutionality. Furthermore, coupling Commerce Clause power with the contingent nature of the Secretarial authority under the ACFCMA provides greater support for the Act in the face of a Tenth Amendment challenge. The Secretary exercises the authority to impose the moratorium, but only upon the finding of state non-compliance by the Commission.249 The Secretary of Commerce does not determine whether or not a state has failed to implement an ASMFC management plan, this is done by the Commission. Thus, ASMFC states monitor the efforts of partner states and report non-compliance to the Secretary in order to seek responsive action." Only after receiving notification from the Commission can the Secretary review the determination of non-compliance"1 and then impose a moratorium if necessary."2 Finally, the states, acting through the Commission, can withdraw the determination of non-compliance upon finding that the offending state has taken remedial measures, and notify the Secretary of such withdrawal. z3 While the punitive measures are indeed imposed by the federal government, via the Secretary of Commerce, the ability to do so is contingent upon action by the Commission, comprising fellow states entered into under a voluntary interstate compact. While not dispositive of the constitutional issue of the Tenth Amendment, it certainly would impact a court's analysis of the issue. Analysis of the Tenth Amendment implications in the ACFCMA could constitute a complete article in and of itself and is well beyond the scope of this Comment. 4 It suffices, for purposes of this Comment, to identify the issue and acknowledge it is a constitutional challenge likely to be resolved only in a court of law. Certainly, should the matter arise in the context of litigation, the outcome will have a profound effect on future attempts for state and federal cooperative jurisdiction in fishery management and conservation. Liquid Natural Gas States are regulating liquid natural gas facilities now- federal regulations violate state rights Rachael E. Salcido in 2008 Associate Professor of Law, University of the Pacific, McGeorge School of Law, Offshore Federalism and Ocean Industrialization, Tulane Law Review 82 Tul. L. Rev. 1355 The development of Liquefied Natural Gas (LNG) terminals is also making headlines as controversial in coastal areas. For example, the Broadwater LNG Project is a proposed floating storage and regasification unit, which will sit in the Long Island Sound. n51 The proposed site will be nine miles from the nearest Long Island shoreline and eleven miles from the nearest Connecticut shoreline. n52 However, due to state and citizen resistance, the Broadwater project may ultimately lead to litigation. n53 LNG has become an increasingly sought fuel for domestic uses such as heating and cooking. n54 Imports of LNG [*1366] had previously occurred at only a handful of sites nationally, and now the federal government is stepping up efforts to facilitate increased supply. n55 These efforts have led to "stalemates" over LNG facility siting, where state and local agencies have sought to block new terminals on or adjacent to the shoreline. n56 The EPA of 2005, as discussed further in Part IV.C, sought to move past this impasse, but efforts thus far have not succeeded, and state and local governing bodies have begun to adopt additional measures in hopes of preventing LNG development in their jurisdictions. n57 While the feds have authority on LNG stations- states still must be consulted and get input on project selection Rachael E. Salcido in 2008 Associate Professor of Law, University of the Pacific, McGeorge School of Law, Offshore Federalism and Ocean Industrialization, Tulane Law Review 82 Tul. L. Rev. 1355 Congress took a significant step toward increasing LNG distribution by preempting state jurisdiction over the siting of LNG facilities. n232 The amendments define "LNG terminal" to include "all natural gas facilities located onshore or in State waters." n233 Congress provided for exclusive authority to approve LNG siting offshore or in the coastal zone by the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission: "The Commission shall have the exclusive authority to approve or deny an application for the siting, construction, expansion, or operation of an LNG terminal." n234 However, the EPA of 2005 also provided that states still play a role in approvals through the CZMA consistency provisions, the Clean Water Act, and the Clean Air Act. n235 Therefore, although states cannot block the federal government from choosing a site along its coastline for a LNG terminal, they will have an opportunity to weigh in on whether the project is consistent with enforceable policies of their CMP and will have an opportunity to shape the project details through permitting of the facility for water quality and air quality impacts. n236 Monitoring/Management Offshore Wind Power Federal action in offshore wind meets strong local opposition – Cape Wind Project proves. Powell 2012 (Timothy H., J.D. Candidate, Boston University School of Law, 2013, “Revisiting Federalism Concerns in the Offshore Wind Energy Industry in Light of Continued Local Opposition to the Cape Wind Project”, Boston University Law Review. Dec2012, Vol. 92 Issue 6, p2023-2053. 31p., Academic Search Complete, Date AccessedL 12 July 2014) A. The Problem: Failure in the Current Federal-State Balance of Powers Interest in developing offshore wind energy projects in the United States has increased dramatically in the last few years.'5" Yet the complex and changing regulatory scheme, coupled with the high cost and delay associated with private litigation from citizen groups challenging every step of the approval process, will likely discourage future development of wind energy projects in the United States without reform. The problem can be traced to a failure in the current federal-state balance of powers: a disconnect between the federal approval process and the inherently local nature of offshore wind energy. Both the opposition by the Wampanoag Tribe and the overruling of the FAA's approval further illustrate this disconnect between the interests of the federal government on the one hand, and state and local interests on the other hand. In both instances the federal government has pursued a hard line in favor of the Cape Wind project. The DOI fully approved the project despite a warning from the Advisory Council on Historic Preservation that the project would have significant adverse effects on historic properties. The FAA similarly issued a Determination of No Hazard presumably based only on a cursory application of its regulations, and possibly under political pressure from the Obama Administration. In both instances more localized entities Native American tribes, local citizen groups, towns, and even state agencies - have expended considerable resources to express their various views in opposition to the Cape Wind project.'^' To date, the overruling of the FAA's approval is the only legal victory on the part of the project's opposition.'^^ But whatever the merits of the opposition's legal claims, the process has demonstrated the inefficiency of the current regulatory scheme. The decision of whether the Cape Wind project should go forward has now dragged on more than a decade. The saga has been an incredible waste of resources and time, as the federal government attempts to fit a square peg in a round hole, with local opposition mounting complaints with all levels federal and state agencies and courts to confuse and delay the process. There must be a more effective way to efficiently and optimally allocate the harvesting of coastal wind energy throughout the United States. Offshore wind power requires transmission of power and placement of wind on state – controlled territory- federal regulations undermine state sovereignty Rachael E. Salcido in 2008 Associate Professor of Law, University of the Pacific, McGeorge School of Law, Offshore Federalism and Ocean Industrialization, Tulane Law Review 82 Tul. L. Rev. 1355 A second example of a potential new offshore development with significant human benefits is the Cape Wind offshore wind farm proposed for Nantucket Sound, Massachusetts. The project is currently in the permitting stage and construction of wind turbines is [*1363] projected for 2010. n31 The project is anticipated to occupy twenty-four square miles in federal waters offshore Massachusetts and consist of 130 3.6-megawatt wind turbines. n32 The Minerals Management Service (MMS), within the Department of the Interior (DOI), is creating a regulatory process to facilitate leasing of the area for the project to move forward. n33 One of the purported benefits of the project is an increase in renewable energy. n34 Yet it has become clear that potential federalism issues are raised in the generation of offshore wind energy. Like aquaculture developments, the resource developed offshore must be transmitted across state areas to reach consumers onshore, thus triggering state regulation of submerged lands. n35 Furthermore, the acceptance of the potential impacts to state interests has already generated litigation. n36 While the use of wind as an alternative energy source to fossil fuels has environmental advantages, the impacts on the marine and coastal resources - including bird and marine life mortalities and [*1364] destruction of marine habitat - are certainly not insignificant. n37 Thus, a citizen group, publicly endorsed by some state officials antagonistic to the federal project, sued to prevent continued project progress. n38 In Alliance To Protect Nantucket Sound, Inc. v. U.S. Department of the Army, a residents' association (Alliance) challenged the approval of an offshore data tower that was proposed to test the feasibility of the wind farm in an area of Nantucket Sound. n39 The specific area, Horseshoe Shoals, is located on the OCS in an area subject to federal jurisdiction. n40 Alliance argued that the Corps did not have authority under section 10 of the Rivers and Harbors Act to issue a permit for the data tower. n41 Alliance also argued that Cape Wind Associates did not have the requisite property interests necessary to obtain a permit pursuant to Corps regulations. n42 The court found that OCSLA (as amended in 1978), which authorized the Corps to prevent obstructions to navigation, also extended the Corps' jurisdiction to all artificial islands and all installations for exploring, developing, or producing resources, or other installations of devices. n43 The jurisdiction was not limited just to structures extracting minerals. n44 Alliance also argued that the National Environmental Policy Act (NEPA) required that the federal government publish a finding of no significant impact because the proposed action was one "without precedent." n45 One of the main criticisms of the proposal was the impact to scenic values. n46 Opponents contended that in the future, if the project were approved, windmills would sit in the center of the sound, destroying the aesthetic appeal and natural beauty of the sound. n47 [*1365] Appellants argue that the data tower proposal is "without precedent" because Nantucket Sound is a pristine, undeveloped area and because "there is no precedent for permitting a privatelyowned structure for wind energy, or even related research, on OCS lands." n48 However, because a similar data tower was permitted in state waters offshore of Martha's Vineyard, the court rejected the Alliance's claims and agreed with the Corps that the data tower was not without precedent. n49 However, as will be discussed in Part IV.C, Congress has not addressed these environmental or federalism concerns because Congress encouraged additional wind energy development offshore with various provisions of the EPA of 2005. n50 Off Shore wind cannot be implemented without destroying States’ authority over their coasts Russell 2004 (Robert H., J.D., Harvard Law School. Mr. Russell teaches environmental law in the graduate program at Tufts University, and has taught energy regulation, environmental law and policy, and property law at other universities and law schools in the Boston area. He also consults with nonprofit organizations and government agencies on environmental matters., “COASTAL WIND ENERGY GENERATION: CONFLICT AND CAPACITIE: SYMPOSIUM ARTICLE: Neither Out Far Nor in Deep: The Prospects for Utility-Scale Wind Power in the Coastal Zone”, 2004 Boston College Law School, Boston College Environmental Affairs Law Review, Lexis Nexis) A key feature of this process is the generality that is allowed, and indeed expected of, n100 state coastal zone management plans. n101 This is enhanced by the significant discretion the CZMA accords states to freely interpret those plans when specific conflicts arise. Typically, the burden is on a project developer to demonstrate that its activities conform to the coastal zone plan. n102 But it is seldom possible to ensure conformity [*239] based on review of the plan document itself. To apply coastal program standards, more process--particularly interaction with state agency staff--is required. n103 But if that miscarries or fails, essentially no enforcement mechanism exists to set matters aright. The federal government exercises only limited control over how states conduct their review, and neither the CZMA nor the typical state coastal zone program makes provision for aggrieved private citizens to seek judicial relief from private developers, local governments, or the state itself. n104 Although coastal zone programs vary in their priorities as well as their effectiveness, they all tend to operate in a zone of discretion lying between the federal government and shoreline municipalities. n105 For wind energy, the most potentially accommodating areas of the overall statutory design are provisions for federal aid to the states, and the requirement that, to be approved, a plan must consider the "national interest," including "the siting of . . . energy facilities which are of greater than local significance." n106 But each offers less than it appears. Federal aid would seem to be a way to stimulate the state innovation that will be needed in many cases to accommodate wind power. But, beyond a modest baseline, the prospects are poor, given the historically low level of federal support for coastal zone management and renewable energy development. n107 Moreover, when federal agencies comment on a proposed state plan or an amendment to an existing one, the CZMA has been read to assume that a state's program addresses the national interest, including interest in energy security. n108 Even if conditions change later, the plan as written remains in effect--largely, if not wholly, immune from attack. [*240] From the perspective of wind power development, the manner in which coastal plans are created, approved, implemented, and administered creates significant regulatory uncertainty. n109 The plans themselves typically do not offer specific guidelines or even basic guidance--for example, guidance to help identify areas in which offshore wind generation might be favorably considered. Instead, plans elaborate upon the broad array of principles enunciated in the CZMA. Typically, they demand a complex balancing of related but often conflicting standards, while suggesting few criteria that would aid in discerning priorities among them. Finally, as will be discussed, the sheer generality of the program document makes it easier for an individual state to argue that a federally-permitted project is inconsistent with some aspect of its plan, thus blocking the siting of the project. n110 Although the CZMA's one undisputed effect has been to encourage states to view the coastal zone as a unified ecological area, this new understanding has not always inspired new modes of action. 3. Program Structure a. Basic Design State coastal zone programs vary widely in scope, n111 as well as structure. n112 Some, like North Carolina's and California's, are comprehensive and centralized. n113 A single state agency implements the program, although some authority may be delegated to municipalities. n114 [*241] The majority, however, are "networked" among the potentially numerous state and local agencies that share some say over coastal affairs. Often, a single state agency coordinates all or most of the others. The Massachusetts, Maine, New Hampshire, Virginia, Florida, and Texas coastal zone programs are of the networked variety. n115 Through executive orders, policy directives, or memoranda of understanding, networked coastal programs attempt to amalgamate and shape the preexisting activities and agendas of parallel agencies. n116 b. Spillover Effects For the development of offshore wind power, the structure of the state coastal zone management system creates a potentially serious boundary, or spillover, problem. Wind energy provides significant benefits well beyond the borders of a given jurisdiction--for example, by addressing climate change and global security issues. But a relatively small percentage of those benefits are captured locally. Moreover, in at least some cases, the local benefits of wind energy will not outweigh the locally perceived detriment to coastal "character," aesthetics, other environmental values, and other uses of coastal resources. n117 Although this spillover, or externality, problem is not unique to wind development, n118 it presents itself here in an unusual posture, n119 given the continuing debate over the nature and significance of the local impacts of wind, and the equity issues that a shoreline headcount cannot adequately resolve. n120 [*242] c. Massachusetts: A Case in Point To understand why state territorial waters might be an unfriendly environment for wind development, it may be useful to examine a specific, representative coastal zone management program. The Massachusetts program has received high marks, n121 and, like the majority, is a networked program. In addition, the state has a fairly typical range of environmental statutes, including those that address environmental impacts, the siting of power plants, ocean protection, and public trust resources. The commonwealth's coastal program is based on at least seven memoranda of understanding between the Massachusetts Office of Coastal Zone Management and the other state agencies that exercise supervisory authority over use and development of the coastline. n122 These include the state Energy Facilities Siting Board, the Executive Office of Transportation and Construction, the Massachusetts Environmental [*243] Policy Act Office, the Department of Agricultural Resources, and the Department of Conservation and Recreation. n123 State law does not provide the public with the means to challenge action or inaction by coastal officials, or to require the coastal office to enforce its agreements with other agencies--although two review processes might help. First, in many cases (especially those involving sizable coastal incursions), a factual record detailing environmental harms and benefits must be developed, largely through the commonwealth's environmental impact review process. n124 Second, the Energy Facilities Siting Board has the authority, but not the obligation, to facilitate the siting of for power generation projects by waiving local and state permitting requirements. n125 Nonetheless, the Massachusetts regulatory system poses a number of challenges to offshore wind development. The first is its sheer complexity. n126 Multiple sets of regulations address similar activities in similar language, yet they do so in seemingly uncoordinated and sometimes inconsistent ways. n127 As a result, wind development may be diverted to [*244] federal waters, if any shallow enough can be found. n128 The second challenge is the generality of the standards. n129 They demand a great deal of interpretation, which increases transaction costs. Third, the coastal zone itself is a "generalized" space, creating further uncertainty. Most, if not all, of the values that its varied resources support may require assessment each time a significant project triggers the commonwealth's coastal protection apparatus. Although the process this necessitates may be adept at identifying discrete interests and values, it may be far less effective in translating those findings into specific conditions that apply to designated activities in specified locations. Fourth, a high degree of generality may be favored as a way to conserve agency resources, if not ocean resources. The more precise a given policy or decision, the clearer it acts as directive or precedent. Agencies may seek to avoid such precision, since one of its by-products is the assignment of priority to values and uses--and in consequence intensifying the demand for hands-on, and often controversial, resource management. [*245] Finally, the commonwealth's coastal program appears to be ambivalent about whether wind power should be encouraged or not. n130 Some coastal zone management provisions seem to treat the resource as a potentially water-dependent activity that should be favored. Others lean in the opposite direction. n131 This adds to the regulatory uncertainty. Whether wind generation will be sited off the Massachusetts coast remains an open question. But the regulatory pathway that will determine the fate of each proposal has more twists than necessary. n132 This does not mean the Massachusetts program is particularly weak. In fact, survey results tabulated in Appendix A suggest that the commonwealth is considerably farther along than most other eastern seaboard states in reconsidering its coastal program in light of the evident potential for utility-scale wind power in or near state waters. n133 But the bottom line is the same: near-shore wind power's potential is being dissipated by a decentralized system ill-suited to this new regulatory challenge. One unintended consequence is that developers will propose more massive projects, on the assumption that the ensuing negotiation will demand broader concessions, and that--given a basic lack of structure-the negotiation will impose additional costs that can be offset only by the extra revenue generated by more or larger turbines. Yet, this dynamic could easily heighten regulatory scrutiny, with the consequence that the entire project ultimately is [*246] rejected. That outcome, however, is not consistent with existing policy in any coastal state. Offshore Development Even projects in federal waters cause federalist disputes- states retain control over coastal environments Rachael E. Salcido in 2008 Associate Professor of Law, University of the Pacific, McGeorge School of Law, Offshore Federalism and Ocean Industrialization, Tulane Law Review 82 Tul. L. Rev. 1355 A significant distinction between environmental federalism and offshore federalism must be considered from the outset. First, in examining environmental federalism, the environmental ills to be regulated are often (though not always) unrelated to lands owned by the federal government. n105 The history of offshore federalism, however, is based on an initial dispute over ownership of offshore areas. n106 Conflicts between the state and federal government occur most frequently with development that is proposed for areas under federal jurisdiction - as is the case with much offshore oil drilling and, today, with the development of open-ocean aquaculture and wind farms. n107 When one discusses development on the OCS, a significant distinction can be made from other federalism disputes in that the federal government is managing areas completely outside the boundaries of any of the states. n108 This makes the OCSLA-CZMA framework and the "cooperative federalism" approach to coastal and ocean management all the more unique when discerning appropriate structures for local, state, and federal regulation of coastal and ocean development because distinctive incentives and regulatory propensities can be identified. n109 Oil and Nat Gas Federalism requires consultation with states and incorporation of their suggestions before initiating offshore development of oil and natural gas Rachael E. Salcido in 2008 Associate Professor of Law, University of the Pacific, McGeorge School of Law, Offshore Federalism and Ocean Industrialization, Tulane Law Review 82 Tul. L. Rev. 1355 In addition to developments related to the CZMA, Congress also amended OCSLA in 1978 to incorporate additional provisions relating to environmental protection. n162 OCSLA relies on five-year plans prepared by the DOI that identify particular offshore areas to be leased for oil and gas exploration. n163 In making the decision of which areas to offer for lease, the Secretary of the Interior must consider, among many other factors such as energy needs, the environmental information available and alternative possible uses for the area. n164 The Secretary of the Interior must plan, "to the maximum extent practicable," to achieve a balance between potential benefits in terms of a discovery of oil or gas and the environmental damage or adverse impact on the coastal zone. n165 Coastal states play a formal role in this planning process as the amendments in 1978 provided that the Secretary of the Interior shall solicit and consider comments from coastal states, submit proposed plans to the governors of affected states prior to publication for wider comments, and accept comments from states and local governments after publication. n166 After the DOI [*1385] develops the five-year plans, the MMS conducts lease sales where companies submit initial bonus bids to obtain the right to explore a certain area for oil and/or gas. n167 States again have a formal opportunity under OCSLA to make recommendations "regarding the size, timing, or location of a proposed lease sale." n168 States must approve Outer Continental Shelf development and states don’t like oil or natural gas plans WALLS 93 (MARGARET A., Fellow in the Energy and Natural Resources Division of Resources for the Future, “Federalism and Offshore Oil Leasing Resources”, NATURAL RESOURCES JOURNAL, Vol 33, http://lawlibrary.unm.edu/nrj/33/3/10_walls_federalism.pdf, accessed 7/11/14) Typically, the current OCS development process follows the following sequence of events. The Secretary of Interior releases the five-year leasing plan. State governors, local officials, and the general public, as well as other federal agencies and Congress, comment on the plan. Once the plan is adopted, MMS publishes in the Federal Register a call for information and a notice of intent to prepare an environmental impact statement (EIS). A draft EIS is prepared and released to the public for comments to be received within 60 days. Public hearings are also held within this 60-day period. A final EIS is then prepared and a proposed notice of sale is announced by MMS. This proposed notice is sent to the governors of affected states, who then have 60 days to submit comments on the size, timing, and location of the proposed sale. A final notice of sale is then prepared, taking the governors' concerns into account. The sale is held no less than 30 days after the final notice of sale. The length of the process from adoption of the five-year plan to the actual sale can take two to three years. After a tract has been leased, all exploration, development, and production plans must be submitted to MMS, other federal agencies, the governor of the affected state, the state agency responsible for management of the coastal zone, and any other relevant state and local agencies. The state agencies have a maximum of six months to determine if the plan is consistent with the state's coastal zone management program. If the plan is deemed inconsistent, the lessee must submit a new plan or appeal to the Secretary of Commerce. All OCS activities, such as drilling and construction of platforms or pipelines, require MMS permits. Any of these activities that affect a state's coastal zone must meet with state approval. The requirements embodied in the CZMA and the OCSLAA, the two main pieces of legislation that affect the OCS leasing and development process, have led to a much greater role for state and local governments. They have also led to increased costs for OCS activities and added many months and, in some cases, years of delays to the development process. The main problem with the Acts is that they have not addressed the issue that is really at the heart of the OCS debate: the coastal states bear most of the costs of OCS development and get very few of the benefits. Coastal states live with the risk of oil spills, air pollution from offshore activities, and the perceived unsightliness of platforms, rigs, and other facilities. These impacts lead to costs in the form of decreased property values, reduced recreation and tourism, health and visibility impacts, and aesthetic losses. Several studies have attempted to identify, and in some cases quantify, these costs. Oil spills clearly cause losses by damaging beaches and killing wildlife and vegetation; some studies have attempted to estimate the magnitude of these losses.16 Fewer studies have looked at the non-spill related impacts of OCS development-i.e., property value, recreation and tourism, and aesthetic impacts that result simply from the ongoing operation of platforms, drilling rigs and ships, and supporting onshore facilities. The Dornbusch and Company study, sponsored by the Minerals Management Service, undertook such an effort, estimating the impacts on recreation in Ventura and Santa Barbara counties in California from operation of platforms and onshore processing facilities there. The study found that consumer surplus was reduced by four percent in Ventura county as a result of three existing platforms and an onshore facility and would be lowered by three percent in Santa Barbara county if two proposed platforms and an onshore facility in the north county area (a less-populated region'of the county) were built.17 These costs were due purely to the visual impact of the platforms and processing facilities and were not related to the possibility of spills."' The federal government must get state approval for drilling in the outer continental shelf Ryan 2011 (Erin, Teaches environmental and natural resources law, property and land use, water law, negotiation, and federalism at Lewis and Clark Law School, Federalism and the Tug of War Within, Oxford University Press, http://books.google.com/books?id=FEVpAgAAQBAJ&pg=PA296&lpg=PA296&dq=federalism+ocs+drilling &source=bl&ots=3DV4BqNxjR&sig=fUe8ige_7T0753O9B26Z1PIhFU&hl=en&sa=X&ei=S1HAU7ejHLSJ8gH_mYGIBQ&ved=0CE8Q6AEwBQ#v=onepage&q=fede ralism%20ocs%20drilling&f=false, accessed 7/11/14) In another example of state-empowered exceptions bargaining, the Coastal Zone Management Act (CZMA) invites states to participate in the protection of coastal zones in which both the federal and state governments have significant interests. When a state elects to participate by creating a federally approved management plan. approval authority for federal activities within the zone shifts to the states.15° For this reason, the Department of Interior often must receive stare approval before issuing federal leases for offshore drilling on the outer continental shelf (OCS).’1 OTEC The federal government needs State approval for OTEC plants Cornell Law School No Date (Legal Information Institute, 42 U.S. Code § 9115 - Adjacent coastal States, http://www.law.cornell.edu/uscode/text/42/9115, accessed 7/11/14) (a) Designation of adjacent coastal State (1) The Administrator, in issuing notice of application pursuant to section 9112 (d) of this title, shall designate as an “adjacent coastal State” any coastal State which (A) would be directly connected by electric transmission cable or pipeline to an ocean thermal energy conversion facility as proposed in an application, or (B) in whose waters any part of such proposed ocean thermal energy conversion facility would be located, or (C) in whose waters an ocean thermal energy conversion plantship would be operated as proposed in an application. (2) The Administrator shall, upon request of a State, designate such State as an “adjacent coastal State” if he determines (A) that there is a risk of damage to the coastal environment of such State equal to or greater than the risk posed to a State required to be designated as an “adjacent coastal State” by paragraph (1) of this subsection or (B) that the thermal plume of the proposed ocean thermal energy conversion facility or plantship is likely to impinge on so as to degrade the thermal gradient at possible locations for ocean thermal energy conversion facilities which could reasonably be expected to be directly connected by electric transmission cable or pipeline to such State. This paragraph shall apply only with respect to requests made by a State not later than the 14th day after the date of publication of notice of application for a proposed ocean thermal energy conversion facility in the Federal Register in accordance with section 9112 (d) of this title. The Administrator shall make any designation required by this paragraph not later than the 45th day after the date he receives such a request from a State. (b) State coastal zone management program (1) Not later than 5 days after the designation of an adjacent coastal State pursuant to this section, the Administrator shall transmit a complete copy of the application to the Governor of such State. The Administrator shall not issue a license without consultation with the Governor of each adjacent coastal State which has an approved coastal zone management program in good standing pursuant to the Coastal Zone Management Act of 1972 (16 U.S.C. 1451 et seq.). If the Governor of such a State has not transmitted his approval or disapproval to the Administrator by the 45th day after public hearings on the application are concluded pursuant to section 9112 (g) of this title, such approval shall be conclusively presumed. If the Governor of such a State notifies the Administrator that an application which the Governor would otherwise approve pursuant to this paragraph is inconsistent in some respect with the State’s coastal zone management program, the Administrator shall condition the license granted so as to make it consistent with such State program. (2) Any adjacent coastal State which does not have an approved coastal zone management program in good standing, and any other interested State, shall have the opportunity to make its views known to, and to have them given full consideration by, the Administrator regarding the location, construction, and operation of an ocean thermal energy conversion facility or plantship. (c) Agreements and compacts between States The consent of Congress is given to 2 or more States to negotiate and enter into agreements or compacts, not in conflict with any law or treaty of the United States, (1) to apply for a license for the ownership, construction, and operation of an ocean thermal energy conversion facility or plantship or for the transfer of such a license, and (2) to establish such agencies, joint or otherwise, as are deemed necessary or appropriate for implementing and carrying out the provisions of any such agreement or compact. Such agreement or compact shall be binding and obligatory upon any State or other party thereto without further approval by the Congress. Federal Lands Even policy over federally controlled lands can generate state-federal conflict over resources Rachael E. Salcido in 2008 Associate Professor of Law, University of the Pacific, McGeorge School of Law, Offshore Federalism and Ocean Industrialization, Tulane Law Review 82 Tul. L. Rev. 1355 The potential for intergovernmental conflict also exists in offshore areas. A state might designate an area open to commercial fishing while the federal government designates an adjacent ocean area protected as a "no-take marine reserve" or similar conservation-oriented designation. At the boundary line, species protected within federal areas lose such status and can be captured, frustrating federal efforts at conservation. This scenario is not just speculative. When the federal government designated areas of the Northern Hawaiian Islands as a marine reserve, state officials expressed concern about the impact [*1401] on adjacent state management objectives, including management of commercial fishing. n285 Hawaiian officials were reluctant to provide similar protection to state areas, and fortunately an informal resolution of the conflict, including federal subsidies to fishermen to obtain stakeholder buy-in, avoided any legal conflict where the supremacy of federal objectives would make conflicting state objectives recede. n286 Internal links States Challenge Federal Gov Generic The states will oppose the federal government—they oppose regulatory frameworks Rabe, 2011 <Barry Rabe, University of Michigan, “Contested Federalism and American Climate Policy”, http://closup.umich.edu/people/barry-rabe/publications/PubliusContested_Federalism.pdf> Lacking precise intergovernmental dividing lines, scholars have searched for criteria to explain why the policy approaches of various levels of American government shift over time and frequently diverge. Many have defined and examined patterns whereby states (either a single state or a subset of them) tend to take the lead in policy innovation, sometimes fostering considerable sub-national diffusion of policy that may (or may not) trigger some form of federal response (Volden, Ting, and Carpenter 2008). States are often found taking early action to gain a competitive advantage over their neighbors, most commonly through attempts to accelerate or diversify economic development (Oates and Schwab 1988). Such steps are often thought to coincide with state aversion to those governmental functions that could impose heavy costs on a state and its taxpayers such as regulatory or redistributive programs (Peterson 1995). Questions of federal engagement often follow, whether to build on early state efforts through policy learning, erase them in the name of national uniformity, or jump in amid a seeming absence of state involvement (Posner 2010). Application of this work to the arena of environmental protection regularly raises issues of negative externalities and whether states attempt to advance their own economic well-being by generating environmental contaminants that drift or flow to other jurisdictions where they cause ecological or human health damage (Lowry 1997). This has fostered considerable analysis of strategies to either reconcile cross-jurisdictional conflicts (such as interstate litigation for alleged damages or creation of interstate compacts to unite neighboring states on common environmental concerns) or sort out federal and state responsibilities to minimize cross-state contaminant transfer (such as federal preemption of a policy area). Externalities are rarely easy to measure with precision, however, and efforts to establish clear dividing lines between what constitutes a federal as opposed to a state area of responsibility have proven elusive at best. Analysis that focused on intergovernmental relations was initially dismissed by scholars as irrelevant to climate change, given the predominant thinking that theories of international relations and regime formation were far more applicable. But the American case over recent decades, as well as emerging lessons from other federal systems, suggest that an intergovernmental perspective can be applied with considerable rigor to climate policy (Burke and Ferguson 2010). As we shall see, climate change policy options pose classic questions of economic development versus cost imposition. Just as no two states are likely to face the same risks from accelerating climate change, no two will likely frame such policy options in identical fashion or have comparable capacity to formulate policy. In turn, any federal responses will vary depending upon issue saliency at a given juncture as well as political factors that shape policy development, including public opinion and partisan control of the legislative and executive branches. At the same time, climate change might not seem to impose classic externality issues, as GHG emissions from any jurisdiction contribute to total global concentrations rather than move directly from one locale to another. But inherent in the combustion of fossil fuels that produce carbon dioxide, the dominant GHG, is a host of related environmental concerns, such as the release of conventional air contaminants. Alongside the likelihood of varied short- and long-term impacts from climate change on different states and regions (and hence different incentives to promote emissions reductions), the externality factor remains inexact but nonetheless present and contributing to intergovernmental policy considerations. Environment Cooperative federalism is the most effective solution for environmental management—state coastal management systems prove Duff no date (THE COASTAL ZONE MANAGEMENT ACT: REVERSE PRE-EMPTION OR CONTRACTUAL FEDERALISM ? by John A. Duff 6 Ocean & Coastal L.J. 109 2001) All along the coasts of the United States, as the lands give way to the sea, another transition takes place as well. Federal law washes over state law until at last, miles out to sea, federal law rules exclusively. The dynamic natural environment contributes to the fact that land-based activities affect the seas, and vice versa. As a result, federal law may not adequately protect federal interests and state laws may be insufficient to protect a state's coastal zone from activities that take place in distant federal waters. How can government fashion a system that serves both federal and state interests? The answer: cooperation through a partnership contract arrangement, an option that has been employed since 1972. In an era of increasing battles over the proper roles of federal and state power, the Coastal Zone Management Act' (CZMA) stands as a useful example of a vehicle that mutually benefits the federal and state governing authorities and the areas they govern. The CZMA achieves this result under a theory as close to contract as federalism. The CZMA provides federal funds to states to manage their coastal areas in accordance with a set of federal guidelines. The CZMA does not mandate state participation, but, rather, makes the states an offer. The benefits of this cooperative or contractual federalism relationship can be seen in the number of states that have accepted the offer and have adopted state coastal management programs, which serve the dual purpose of protecting not only the coasts of the individual states, but the entire nation's coastal zone.2 One aspect of the CZMA, the consistency provision, allows states a voice in activities that are outside of the state territory, but which may affect the state's coastal zone. Critics of the CZMA argue that the federal government bargained badly in constructing the contractual nature of the relationship and that the CZMA, or at least certain features of the coopera- tive federalism relationship, including the consistency provision, ought to be abolished. In his article, The Federal Consistency Requirements of the Coastal Zone Management Act: It's 7ime to Repeal This Fundamentally Flawed Legislation, 3 Bruce Kuhse makes an impassioned plea to eradicate what he characterizes as a costly, burdensome, and ill-conceived instrument in the form of the consistency provision, due to what he claims are its reverse pre-emption effects on federal activity and authority. This brief article is designed to address some of the arguments made by Mr. Kuhse, to provide the reader with a different perspective on the CZMA federal- state relationship, and to posit the argument that the consistency provision is not a cession of federal authority, but, rather, even in its limited strength, a persuasive material element which attracts states to participate in the system. The Federal Interest in State Coastal Waters Since the beginning of the Republic, the federal government has exercised a range of authorities over activities in the nation's coastal waters. The federal courts have plenary jurisdiction over admiralty and maritime matters.4 The Commerce Clause of the Constitution5 creates a navigation servitude which encumbers all navigable waters of the United States.6 Moreover, a host of federal statutes govern the maintenance and protection of the condition and capacity of the nations's coastal waters.7 Even in those circumstances where neither an express constitutional provision nor a federal statute conveys federal authority, the U.S. Supreme Court has recognized that rarest ofjudicial legal authority, federal common law, as a means of recognizing a federal interest in the nation's waters.' At the same time, there can be no doubt that the federal government recognizes substantial sovereign rights of each state related to their dry land, submerg- ed lands, and coastal waters. The Submerged Lands Act9 articulates the recognition of a state's title and right to coastal submerged land areas and also expressly reserves certain federal authorities deemed paramount.' ° While those water-borne paramount rights allow the federal government to pre-empt conflicting state law, that pre-emption authority decreases or disappears as the sea gives way to the shore. Given this regime of concurrent jurisdiction over coastal waters where federal law may reign supreme and the coastal land where state sovereignty constitutes greater strength, the question arises as to the best means of establishing a system that protects the entire nation's coastal zone, including both wet and dry areas. That question was answered by Congress in 1972 when the CZMA became law." Based upon recommendation of the Stratton Commission and with the knowledge that federal authority in the coastal zone dissipated at the water's edge, Congress enacted a law designed to persuade, rather than mandate, the states to protect the resources of the coastal zone.'I At the outset of the CZMA, Congress states that there is a "national interest in the effective management, beneficial use, protection, and development of the coastal zone."' 3 By its very nature, the CZMA is contractual. The states need not enter into the partnership offered by the federal government. 4 Nor does the federal government have to enter into a relationship with a state if it deems the state's coastal management plan to be deficient. 5 The considerations exchanged in the contract are cash from the federal government to the state government in exchange for a state program designed to protect coastal zone in accordance with federal guidelines. Simply put, the effect of the contract is that the states get money and the federal government gets a national system of coastal management programs that meets its basic objectives. The Bargaining Chip-Giving the States a Voice in Federal Activities and Federal Territory A significant bargaining chip in the CZMA contract or partnership is the federal consistency provision. 16 In addition to the funding provided by the federal government, a state is effectively given a voice in federal activities via the consistency provision. Some commentators contend that the contractual nature of this cooperative federalism relationship, particu- larly the consistency provision, effectively produces a "reverse pre- emption" system whereby a state can effectively block the federal government from exercising its authority. In his article advocating the abolition of the consistency provision, Mr. Kuhse characterizes the measure as an ill-conceived cession of authority from the federal to the state government. The effect, contends Kuhse, amounts to a reverse pre-emption scenario, i.e., rather than the federal government having the power to pre- empt state law, the state has authority to block what would otherwise be an allowable federal activity. Kuhse's recounting of circumstances where states have used the consistency provision as a means of influencing or impeding federal activity is constructed to illustrate the threat that this "negative pre-emption" poses not merely to the proposed activity at issue, but to the very nature of federal authority itself. One reading Mr. Kuhse's argument might be led to believe that a federal government activity or a permitting decision related to an activity that takes place outside state jurisdiction may be derailed by the whim of a state by the mere utterance of the term "inconsistent." But in those circumstances where the federal activity may impact the state's coastal zone, the state must do more than merely object; it must articulate some rational basis for doing so. In fact, in 1984, the U.S. Supreme Court ruled against a state for failure to state a consistency objection within the meaning of the CZMA. This decision led to a congressional strengthening of the state's consistency scope. 17 While there is no doubt that the states have effectively blocked some types of activity from occurring,"s they have done so not in opposition to federal authority, but with the full understanding of the federal government and pursuant to a provision of afederal law which has been revisited and re-authorized by Congress numerous times over the last quarter century.19 In some instances, the consistency provision has proven to be a NEPA-like tool that fosters sound and informed decision-making. "When the EPA wanted to designate an ocean dumping site, it consulted Louisiana: The 30-day comment period on EPA's Final EIS closed on January 11, 1999. Only one comment letter, from the State of Louisiana, Department of Culture, Recreation and Tourism, Office of Cultural Development, was received on the Final EIS. The Louisiana Office of Cultural Development found the document to be thorough and well written, and concurred with the evaluation that there would be no effect on significant cultural resources, and as such, had no objections to the proposal. EPA's NEPA review included coordination with the State of Louisiana underrequirements of the Coastal Zone Management Act. The State of Louisiana concurred with EPA's determination that final designation of the Atchafalaya River Bar Channel ODMDS is consistent, to the maximum extent practicable, with the Louisiana Coastal Resources Program. This final rulemaking document fills the same role as the Record of Decision required under regulations promulgated by the Council on Environmen- tal Quality for agencies subject to NEPA." Id 114 OCEAN AND COASTAL LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 6:109 Who's Trumping Whom? In issues of pre-emption, courts often characterize the exercise of a superior federal power as a right to "trump," or override, a state law or decision. Kuhse's notion of inverse pre-emption paints a picture of the federal government giving away this trump card to the states when it comes to matters that may affect the coastal zone of the nation. However, a more accurate card-playing portrayal of the federal-state partnership might be a picture of the federal government dealing a wild card to each state in exchange for each state anteing up with a coastal zone management program that enriches the dealer by effecting his objectives. And while each state may play that wild card from time to time in the form of a consistency objection, it is obvious that even that wild card may be trumped by any number of cards that the federal government retains. The Trump Cards That Remain in the Federal Government's Hand While the state may hold a wild card in the form of an "inconsistency" claim, there remain a number of trump cards in the federal government's hand. Exclusion The CZMA expressly excludes federal lands from being considered part of a state's coastal zone.21 As a result, activity on federal lands within the borders of a state's coastal zone have a trump card characteristic to them. Mr. Kuhse indicates that the exclusion provision is weakened by the fact that a state may "claim inconsistency" for activity that takes place in an excluded area that might have an impact beyond the excluded area and in the state coastal zone.22 He is correct, but that does not render the exclusion provision meaningless.23 Presidential Exemptions for Federal Activities Another trump card exists even where a state plays its wild card in the form of a consistency objection to a federal activity. The President may "exempt from compliance those elements of the federal agency activity... found . . . to be inconsistent with an approved State program, if the President determines that the activity is in the paramount interest of the United States." Secretary Override for Federal Permitting Decisions The fact that the consistency provision can be trumped by the Secretary of Commerce is illustrated by the numerous instances in which the Secretary, contrary to a state claim of inconsistency, has ruled that a federal permit issuance was in fact "consistent" under the terms of the CZMA. The fact that the federal government continues to play the game and raise the stakes suggests that it is willing to leave its own contribution, vis- avis the consistency provision, intact. In light of its growing reliance on states to develop more extensive coastal management programs with increasing responsibilities, it is unlikely that the federal government wishes to eliminate its allowance for states to have a voice in federal activities and permitting decisions that may affect their coasts Conclusion When the notion of reverse pre-emption, as posited by Mr. Kuhse, is considered in the context of the CZMA, it is important to remember that the federal government cannot be absolutely bound by the states in any real ongoing way. In the CZMA contractual federalism card game, the federal government convened the game, wrote the rules, holds a number of trump cards, and has the ability to end the game when it wishes. The consistency provision that gives states a voice that they would otherwise not have does not threaten federal authority. In its worst manifestation it amounts to nothing more than a wild card that might be played by the state. The fact that on some occasions the federal government allows the state's wild card to go untrumped does not mean that the federal government is powerless. Rather in those circumstances, it may be better characterized that the federal government allows a state to benefit from the bargain struck in the CZMA federal-state contract partnership. There is likely no doubt that in some of the situations Mr. Kuhse cites, certain individuals have borne a greater burden than may have been anticipated. However, a distinction should be drawn between the limited situations in which these arguable inequities occur and the overall nature of contractual federalism embodied in the CZMA regime. There may be remedies to addressing the seemingly unfair circumstances that may result under a state's claim of "inconsis- tency.' 30 But a balancing of the bargaining chips seems to indicate that states might drop out of the bargain if one of the biggest chips is taken out Approval Decisions on conditions for the Rhode Island coastal nonpoint program. NOAA and EPA conditionally approved the Rhode Island coastal nonpoint program on September 27, 1997. NOAA and EPA have drafted approval decisions describing how Rhode Island has satisfied the conditions placed on its program and therefore has a fully approved coastal nonpoint program." ld. 30. A recent Supreme Court decision indicates that the U.S. federal government may have to increase its financial contribution to the CZMA process in the form of payments back to prospective federal permittees whose development proposals have been thwarted by, among other things, state CZMA consistency objections. See Mobil Oil Exploration & Producing Southeast, Inc. v. U.S., 120 S. Ct. 2423 (2000). 118 OCEAN AND COASTAL LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 6:109 of the pot. And in light of recent efforts of Congress to raise the stakes in the game, by requiring, for example that states implement non-point source pollution control management systems, it seems even more inequitable for the federal government to reduce its contribution to the partnership. While the 106' Congress struggled to construct budgets to fund federal programs, it became clear that the legislative and executive branches agreed that the CZMA ought to continue to receive substantial federal financial support to assist states in administering their respective coastal management pro- grams. 3 1 The Federal Government can’t correctly implement environmental policy and states will challenge it Adler ’98 (Johnathan, political scientist, Environmental policymakers are increasingly turning to the states for solutions to today’s environmental problems, Environmental Forum, http://home.earthlink.net/~jhadler/federalism.html, accessed: 7/11/14 GA) Today, however, the consensus in favor of a centralized, national approach to environmental policy is disintegrating. Environmental analysts, government officials, and activists across the environmental spectrum are calling for greater local control in environmental policy and are looking to places other than Washington, D.C., for solutions to environmental problems.1 State officials are particularly aggressive. In 1994, several state environmental agency heads formed the Environmental Council of the States (ECOS) to lobby for greater state flexibility. "State environmental leaders could no longer stand by and let EPA take the lead," explains Mary Gade, Director of the Illinois Environmental Protection Agency. "States were quite simply ‘Fed up.’"2 The reason for the disintegrating consensus is straightforward: the basic policy framework enacted in the 1970s does not serve America well in the 1990s. Costs have escalated to the point where Americans now spend well over $150 billion complying with environmental regulations, and the results are dwindling. Some laws, such as Superfund and the Endangered Species Act, are outright failures, at time exacerbating the environmental problems they were meant to solve. As regulatory commands piled up bureaucratic controls, the system has neared a breaking point. In the words of law professor Richard Stewart of New York University, "The system has grown to the point where it amounts to nothing less than a massive effort at Soviet-style planning of the economy to achieve environmental goals."3 Of particular concern is the ability of a national, centralized regulatory structure to address environmental problems that are largely local and regional in nature. The EPA’s Scientific Advisory Board concluded in 1990 that most remaining environmental problems "are site-specific, varying from area to area and requiring tailored controls at the regional, state, or local level for effective mitigation." Yet current programs fail to allow state and local governments sufficient flexibility in tailoring their programs to local needs. According to the United States Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations, "Federal rules and procedures governing decision-making for protecting the environment often are complex, conflicting, difficult to apply, adversarial, costly, inflexible and uncertain."4 State and local officials increasingly complain that federal laws and regulations force them to implement environmental programs that make little sense in their part of the country, diverting resources from more pressing concerns. As a Columbus, Ohio, health official said a few years ago, "The new rules coming out of Washington are taking money from decent programs and making me waste them on less important problems."5 State environmental agencies must follow federal dictates governing minute details of regulatory programs that are not simply for pollution control purposes. Federal regulations require states to provide for the requisite amount of public participation and opportunities for litigation by citizens and even ensure that permitting programs meet EPA’s standards for environmental justice. Whereas the Clean Water Act speaks of preserving and protecting the states’ primary role in pollution control, "under the present scheme of the Act, the states generally have a choice between acquiescing to federal proscriptions or ultimately facing the prospect of federal exemption," notes environmental attorney Mark Pifher of Colorado Springs, Colorado.6 In this context, it should be no surprise that many analysts are calling for a return of substantial policymaking authority to state and local governments. In 1995, for instance, the National Academy of Public Administration (NAPA) concluded that "EPA and Congress need to hand more responsibility and decision-making authority over to the states."7 ECOS calls for "the long overdue transfer of power in the state-federal partnership."8 David Schoenbrod, an attorney formerly with the Natural Resources Defense Council, argues that the historical preference for federal regulation is misguided. "The popular desire for a clean environment can be realized with far more common sense by returning control of local government," Schoenbrod says.9 NAPA, ECOS, and Schoenbrod are but three voices in a growing chorus calling for a new environmental federalism that would return greater environmental policymaking responsibility to the states. Federal environmental policies are vulnerable to challenge Adler, 2004 < Jonathan H. Adler, 2004 “Judicial Federalism and the Future of Federal Environmental Regulation” Case Research Paper Series in Legal Studies Working Paper 04-6 April 2004 > The expansive reach of federal environmental regulation places it in the middle of the federalism debate.4 Environmental regulation arguably represents the most ambitious and farreaching assertion of federal regulatory authority. The very premise of much environmental regulation is that ubiquitous ecological interconnections require broad, if not all-encompassing, federal regulation.5 This premise is contrary to that of a federal government of limited and enumerated power that underlies the constitutional structure of federalism.6 Due to theirexpansive scope, environmental statutes are particularly vulnerable to challenge on federalism grounds, a fact noted with great concern by Justice Stevens, among others.7 Some even suggest that the revival of federalism has “the potential to undo the foundation of modern environmental law.”8 At a fundamental level, the foundational principles of the Supreme Court’s federalism revival – that the Constitution creates a federal government of defined and strictly limited powers and that state sovereignty remains a judicially enforceable limit on federal power – are in direct conflict with the organizing principle of contemporary environmental law. The existing statutory framework is based upon the presumption that most environmental problems require broad assertion of federal power. Even though federal environmental regulation adopts a “cooperative federalism” model, it is a model in which the federal government sets environmental priorities, imposes far-reaching restrictions on potentially environmentally destructive behavior, and provides general direction for state efforts. Insofar as federalism is a judicially enforced constraint on the authority of the federal government, it could have a significant impact on federal environmental regulation. Yet while federalism may limit federal regulatory authority, it need not undermine the cause of environmental protection. Other issues prove States not afraid to challenge the federal government—domestic spy program and gun-control prove Ulbricht 14 (Adam, “Nullification movement grows as states challenge federal power”, http://watchdog.org/125992/nullificationfederal-government/) The battle for power between states and the federal government has been raging since the ink was still wet on the freshly signed U.S. Constitution. The struggle continues as state governments look to take back power they claim is rightfully theirs through a process called nullification. STATES’ RIGHTS: Nullification bills are challenging federal power all around the country. Although the application of the concept has started to take off more recently, the idea itself dates back to the late 1790s, when Thomas Jefferson and James Madison penned the Kentucky and Virginia Resolutions, opposing theAlien and Sedition Acts. Today, a number of nullification bills have popped up in states across the country that addressing a wide range of issues. Multiple states, including Washington, Arizona, New Hampshire and Tennessee, have introduced legislation that bar state workers from cooperating with the National Security Administration’s domestic spy program. Some bills, such as HB1533 in New Hampshire, even make it a Class-A misdemeanor if state employees are caught violating the proposed law. In other states, such as Montana and Missouri, nullification bills have either been passed or introduced that refuse to recognize gun-control requirements made by the federal government. In 2009, Montana passed the Firearms Freedom Act, which prohibited federal regulations of guns manufactured within the state’s borders. A federal appeals court struck down the act in August, citing the commerce clause. A host of states are challenging President Obama’s signature legislative achievement, the Affordable Care Act. Indiana just introduced HB1406, which resists the enforcement of ACA guidelines. The Hoosier State joins South Carolina, Oklahomaand Georgia in doing so. So, why all the recent outrage from the states? That question is debatable. Geoffrey Skelley, a political analyst with the Center for Politics at the University of Virginia, says major legislation, such as the ACA, often creates tension and “strident disagreement.” Skelley said he believes it’s actually “healthy” because it “forces us to have conversations about these issues.” Still, others, such as Michael Maharrey of the Tenth Amendment Center, say it’s the federal government overstepping its bounds. “We have an unlimited federal government today,” said Maharrey. “We seem to let the federal government decide what its own powers are.” States will challenge the federal government over environmental policy—offshore wind farms prove Schroeder 10 (Erica, J.D., University of California, Berkeley, School of Law, 2010, Yale School of Forestry & Environmental Studies, 2004; B.A., Yale University, 2003 California Law Review Vol 98 Issue 5, Turning Offshore Wind On, http://scholarship.law.berkeley.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1069&context=californialawreview) Ultimately, the CZMA, with its focus on decentralized, state control over coastal-zone management, leaves the federal government and offshore wind proponents with minimal recourse in their struggle to develop offshore wind projects. The CZMA allows states near-complete control over their coastal zones through their CZMPs, with almost no role for the federal government in promoting offshore wind energy (or any kind of renewable energy). Because electricity transmission lines must necessarily run through slates' coastal zones to reach consumers, states therefore have significant control over offshore wind projects. Through federal consistency review, their direct control can even extend into federal waters; though states have not often employed this process, the Secretary of Commerce has seemed willing to give them some deference when they do. Given a policy of such strong local control, and the absence of a firm federal mandate for offshore wind power development, local interests have been able to stall both federal and state permitting processes, often through litigation. Proponents of offshore wind have little federal support, and no guaranteed source of state support, on which to rely. Cape Wind presents a compelling and frustrating illustration of this problem. States not afraid to challenge the federal government over controversial issues— health care and abortion laws prove McAllister 14 (Stephen R., law professor at the University of Kansas School of Law and solicitor general of Kansas “When States Object to Federal Law”, http://www.csg.org/pubs/capitolideas/2013_may_june/federalism.aspx) In recent years, states with some frequency have disagreed with and objected to a variety of federal laws. Sometimes the objectionable federal law has been in the form of federal statute. Sometimes the federal law is constitutional law, in the form of U.S. Supreme Court decisions interpreting the scope of the federal government’s power and federal constitutional rights. Prominent examples in recent years include state objections to the federal health care law, in particular the individual mandate that requires people to purchase health insurance, and the federal government’s decision not to exempt certain employers with religious objections from mandatory contraceptive coverage as part of employee health plans. Other prominent examples include state-sponsored personhood amendments or laws that would declare life to begin at conception, an objection to the current abortion jurisprudence under federal law. Oceans key Generic There is balance between state and federal over ocean policy now - Expanding federal government control collapses federalism Weilkinson 12, Weilkinson, Laura titrust partner in the Washington, DC office of Weil, Gotshal & Manges with a practice focusing on mergers and acquisitions. "First U.S. National Ocean Policy Established – Congress Just Needs to Support It." The George Washington Journal of Energy Environmental Law. The George Washington Journal of Energy Environmental Law, 13 Nov. 2012. Web. 11 July 2014. CS For reasons that have to do with federalism principles and a historically piecemeal approach to ocean management, no regulatory entity oversees U.S. ocean waters as a whole.[4] Coastal states exercise exclusive control over the first three miles of coastal waters, and the federal government has sovereignty over the expansive Exclusive Economic Zone, which extends two hundred miles offshore.[5] Overall management of ocean and coastal waters is divided among numerous federal, state, and local agencies, operating under different, overlapping, and sometimes conflicting regulatory regimes and objectives.[6] As a result, each activity or threat to ocean health is typically considered in isolation; the coordinated management of cumulative impacts is rare and difficult to achieve.[7] The National Ocean Policy is the first federal ocean program to espouse principles of ecosystem-based management (“EBM”). EBM is an integrated approach to managing ocean resources that considers the entire ecosystem and the cumulative impacts of human activities and environmental changes.[8] This holistic approach is crucial to preserving our failing ocean ecosystems. To implement EBM, the National Policy calls for the creation of Regional Planning Bodies to engage in comprehensive coastal and marine spatial planning of the Large Marine Ecosystems bordering U.S. coasts.[9] Coastal and Marine Spatial Plans will take into account ecosystem-wide effects, identify vulnerable areas, prioritize ocean uses, and designate regions for suitable uses and activities.[10] The National Ocean Policy has been controversial among some congressional and industry circles because it seems to expand federal authority over a historically state-dominated field and threatens to saddle commercial development with more environmental priorities and protection.[11] More recently, states and regional partnerships have taken initiatives to implement the National Ocean Policy, but ocean programs are still underfunded by Congress.[12] William Ruckelshaus, co-chairman of the Joint Ocean Commission Initiative, said in a statement, “We cannot let partisan politics threaten our ability to adequately manage ocean resources to improve ocean health and support numerous businesses and jobs around the country.”[13] Oceans are a key area in federalism- must maintain proper balance between state and federal control Rachael E. Salcido in 2008 Associate Professor of Law, University of the Pacific, McGeorge School of Law, Offshore Federalism and Ocean Industrialization, Tulane Law Review 82 Tul. L. Rev. 1355 Full scale industrialization of the oceans is now upon us. Ready or not, government agencies are considering and processing proposals for increasing commercial use of the oceans for energy generation, mining, seawater desalination, and fish farming, creating a modern ocean industrial revolution. n1 Though some ocean uses have well- [*1357] established legal authorizations, the regulation of new ocean uses and development projects is just emerging. This Article evaluates the offshore federalism framework that may be used - despite its many known flaws - to facilitate ocean and coastal development in the twentyfirst century. Ocean governance is at a crossroads, and contemporary discourse on oceans law and policy is characterized by of a formal property system for managing competing ocean uses argue that "all these new uses share a common problem and raise a common concern - policy regarding their use in U.S. waters is being formulated piecemeal, many ideas for change. In addressing the growing number of industrial uses of ocean resources, advocates and they are all developing economically in the absence of a coherent and publicly-vetted policy framework." n2 Laws designed to accommodate certain uses are being stretched to apply in factual scenarios not previously contemplated: no overarching institution or institutional framework manages or coordinates all activities, it is evident that all potential ocean uses cannot be accommodated, and, perhaps most importantly, marine environment health continues to decline. n3 Despite these problems, recent efforts at legal reform continue to perpetuate the same failed approaches to addressing the enduring controversies over exploitation of ocean resources. While "old issues never quite die in the [*1358] management of the Outer Continental Shelf, and new issues constantly emerge," the regulatory response remains consistently inadequate. n4 Any meaningful attempt at ocean governance reform must confront - and if possible, resolve - the long-standing conflict between coastal states and the federal government. This conflict continues both to define and complicate ocean governance reform. n5 At its center is a geographic boundary that, in an ecological sense, is purely arbitrary: coastal states have jurisdiction over the shoreline up to three miles seaward, and beyond this boundary, the federal government regulates an expansive Exclusive Economic Zone (EEZ) internationally recognized to extend 200 miles from the shore. n6 Intergovernmental relations with respect to this boundary are dictated in large part by the Coastal Zone Management Act (CZMA), n7 which creates a "cooperative federalism" approach to offshore management n8 and the Outer Continental Shelf Lands Act (OCSLA). n9 Both statutes were amended recently by the Energy Policy Act of 2005 (EPA of 2005), n10 a flawed legislative response to the continuing conflicts over onshore and offshore energy development. Altogether, coastal and Outer Continental Shelf (OCS) development remains a contentious, politically charged battle between coastal states, the federal government, environmentalists, and private entrepreneurs. This tension has long been recognized (particularly due to highly publicized conflicts over offshore oil drilling), but it is now at a critical point because it limits the ability to ensure the sustainable development of [*1359] ocean resources - a vital policy goal that is compelled by both economic and ecological considerations - as industrialization of the oceans accelerates. n11 Ocean Federalism Bad- Env Management State-federal conflict over ocean policy ensures continued environmental degradation- must have a consistent framework for policy Rachael E. Salcido in 2008 Associate Professor of Law, University of the Pacific, McGeorge School of Law, Offshore Federalism and Ocean Industrialization, Tulane Law Review 82 Tul. L. Rev. 1355 The relationship between the coastal states and the federal government - the two main regulators of marine resources on the outer [*1371] continental shelf - is of increasing importance for several reasons. First, we are utilizing marine ecosystems and resources now more than ever before. Human activities once only possible in shallow waters are increasingly being carried out farther offshore in federally controlled areas, which lie beyond the three-mile boundary demarcating areas of state control. Near-shore activities continue, including historical ocean uses such as shipping commerce, oil and gas exploration, and commercial and recreational fishing. Lawmakers are also approving new mineral extraction operations, n83 aquaculture and mariculture developments, n84 wind and wave energy production projects, n85 and marine research for medical and pharmaceutical applications farther offshore in areas previously frequented only by fishermen or shipping barges. n86 This proliferation of ocean users contributes to concern about [*1372] the failing health of the marine environment n87 and heightens concern about leasing offshore areas without sufficient environmental safeguards directed toward individual activities or their potential cumulative impacts. n88 Second, as the population of coastal states is expected to increase steadily, land-based pollution and pollution originating from offshore activities will continue to burden the marine ecosystem. Land-based pollution is a grave threat to the health of the estuarine and coastal environment and has a significant impact on the entire marine ecosystem. n89 The United States Commission on Ocean Policy [*1373] (USCOP) estimated that over fifty percent of the American population lives on coastal lands, representing less than twenty-five percent of the total land base. n90 In response to the report prepared by USCOP, the Bush Administration created the Ocean Action Plan (OAP) which acknowledges that it "expects that by 2025, approximately 75 percent of Americans will live in coastal areas." n91 This fact alone heightens concern about the increased use of coastal and ocean resources and calls into question the viability of restoring key coastal ecosystems that are already overtaxed by human activity. The direct dependence on coastal and ocean ecosystems is growing as increasing numbers of people are moving to the coastal zone. But while increasing activities in the ocean carries one set of risks, this intensified use of the coastal zone also threatens additional land-based pollution and erosion. n92 These circumstances underscore the need for coordinated land-ocean management between coastal states and the federal government. Finally, the sustainable development of the oceans is an indispensable element in achieving the goal of lasting economic prosperity. The oceans are severely impacted by human activities, and efforts to reduce land-based pollution as well as a myriad of other adverse marine impacts are far outpaced by increasing demands on marine resources - particularly ocean fish as a source of food. n93 While leadership on these management issues is desperately needed, more problematic in this regard is the fact that the development tail is currently wagging the ocean governance dog. For example, the OAP proposes to intensify ocean use and to rely more on privatization of ocean space to achieve efficiency of ocean use. n94 The Bush [*1374] Administration recognizes a difficulty in reconciling conservation with increased productive use. n95 Yet in contrast to the approvals of proposals for additional ocean uses and development, the Bush Administration has been slow to advance a conservation agenda or to implement existing laws that are protective of the marine environment. n96 Nor has Congress embraced recommendations directed toward conservation and ocean health restoration (and recently has been slow to embrace most other types of environmental reform). n97 This has in turn led to more significant actions by coastal states, both in state legislative activity and in the lobbying of congressional representatives for extraordinary measures such as offshore drilling and open-ocean aquaculture moratoria through appropriations limitations. n98 Thus, the fact that coastal states and the federal government continue to clash over development and conservation on the OCS presents one with a rather depressing picture: imagine a boat being rowed with opposing oars, destined to circle but moving forward only miraculously by the current or a strong wind. State independence key to fed States’ ability to protect their independence is key to successful federalism Weingast 2006 Barry R. Weingast, Senior Fellow, Hoover Institution, and Ward C. Krebs Family Professor, Department of Political Science, Stanford University, “Second Generation Fiscal Federalism: Implications for Decentralized Democratic Governance and Economic Development”, June 2006, http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1153440, accessed 7/12/14) Decentralization differs in federal versus unitary systems, the most important of which is constitutional: the decentralization of authority in federal states has a constitutional basis, often supported by explicit institutions, whereas decentralization in unitary states is legislative or by decree. Per condition F5, this means that decentralization in unitary states remains at the discretion of the central government. And what is given may be taken back. We should not overdraw this distinction, however. Constitutions are mere parchment, and many constitutional are honored in the breach or simply ignored.17 Some constitutionally federal systems, such as the Soviet Union or Mexico prior to the early 1990s, are highly centralized in which subnational governments function as administrative units of the national government. Similarly, constitutionally unitary states, such as modern China, have devolved power in sufficient ways that maintaining the system is no longer at the discretion of the central government. What matters, therefore, is not simply whether decentralization is constitutionally mandated, but what mechanisms subnational governments have at their disposal to protect their independence. A classic constitutional mechanism is the explicit representation of states in a national Senate, as in Argentina, Germany, and the United States. This gives states a forum within which to pursue their collective interest and, potentially, to defend these interests against encroachments by the center.18 As Riker (1964) observed, absent mechanisms to protect the subnational government autonomy, the central government has a tendency to “overawe” the states and make the system more centralized. This has happened in both India and Mexico, and appears to be happening in contemporary Russia. Similarly, a center that is too weak cannot prevent encroachments on the common whole, such as internal trade barriers or subnational governments forcing the center to bail out their deficits. Russia during the mid-1990s exhibited some of these qualities, as did Argentina in the late 1980s and early 00s. New plans key Despite recent changes in structure, there is still no set institutional frameworkfuture policy will set the tone for federal-state cooperation Rachael E. Salcido in 2008 Associate Professor of Law, University of the Pacific, McGeorge School of Law, Offshore Federalism and Ocean Industrialization, Tulane Law Review 82 Tul. L. Rev. 1355 Congress essentially turned OCSLA into a multiple-use statute, authorizing the MMS to lease areas on the EEZ for aquaculture, oil drilling, alternative energy projects and reusing already-placed oil platforms for "alternate uses" without providing any hierarchy of uses or suggestions for a desirable mix of uses. n244 The MMS is drafting regulations to implement these provisions, is developing a Renewable Energy and Alternate Use Program, and recently published an Environmental Impact Statement (EIS) pursuant to the National Environmental Policy Act. n245 In the EIS, the MMS only considered the next five to seven years as a time frame. n246 The potential projects it has contemplated approving "include, but are not limited to, offshore wind, wave, ocean current, and solar energy capture technologies." n247 Further, alternative uses of previously sited oil platforms include "offshore aquaculture, research, education, recreation, support for other offshore operations and facilities, and telecommunications." n248 While Congress did not initiate a planning process for overall EEZ development, it authorized the MMS to move ahead with offshore developments. n249 As already indicated in the EIS that the MMS has prepared, the immediate plan is for facilitation of projects that industry has indicated they are interested in at this time, which provides a rationale for limiting the focus of the EIS to the next five-to seven-year time frame. n250 Looking forward, statutes governing additional aspects of offshore development are being developed that are likely to supplement these OCSLA provisions or to replace them for particular uses. n251 However, the ideas being exchanged by policymakers [*1396] frequently model OCSLA by using leasing provisions to obtain competitive bids, bonuses, and rental payments, in addition to some form of royalties on profits. n252 Although the National Offshore Aquaculture Act of 2005, drafted and promoted in large part by NOAA, has yet to be adopted by Congress, it is likely that some form of new aquaculture legislation will soon come to bear on open-ocean fish farming. n253 The Bush Administration vowed to increase aquaculture five-fold, in part to balance the trade deficit in farmed fish and to provide a local source of fish currently demanded by the American marketplace. n254 Some of the elements of the National Offshore Aquaculture Act of 2005 reflect lessons learned under OCSLA, such as the need to require bonds for clean-up and removal of offshore structures. Congress also amended the CZMA in anticipation of aquaculture. n255 Development conflicts continue, and progress is hampered by states and the federal government often acting alone rather than in tandem. The interest in offshore development and recent attention to the need for legislative reform present an important opportunity to engage in structuring an institutional framework for sustainable development offshore. Federalism disputes are coming now- must be consistent in application of power Rachael E. Salcido in 2008 Associate Professor of Law, University of the Pacific, McGeorge School of Law, Offshore Federalism and Ocean Industrialization, Tulane Law Review 82 Tul. L. Rev. 1355 In a recent article on the emergence of additional offshore uses, Professor John A. Duff urged that we extend our lessons from public lands management to offshore management. n257 Professor Duff specifically looked to the Federal Lands Policy and Management Act (FLPMA), adopted by Congress in 1976, to distill important policy goals such as retention of public lands, conservation, and multiple-use sustained yield management principles. n258 One aspect of public lands management that is a potential source of ways to improve offshore management is the resolution of federalism conflicts. Several cases involving natural resource management conflicts on the public lands illustrate the inevitability of the unfolding ocean federalism disputes. These cases often involve wildlife or conservation objectives or plans for natural resource development. n259 Two constitutional provisions, the Property Clause n260 and the Supremacy Clause, n261 are often at issue in these federalism disputes on public lands. n262 In addition to the Property Clause, constitutional provisions such as the Commerce Clause, the Navigational Servitude (implicit in the Commerce Clause), n263 and the [*1398] so-called War Power n264 also sustain the legality of federal activities outside of federally owned lands and have been tested thoroughly in the context of onshore water regulation and development. n265 These constitutional provisions have generally been applied to support federal government actions beyond the boundaries of federal property. n266 But in designing our model of federalism, the Founders enabled potential activities of multiple sovereign powers within the United States. n267 This framework's design creates a tension with states at physical borders, particularly in the modern environmental law and natural resources context where a transition to ecosystem management is sought. n268 New court rulings will affect state power for years to come Gaylord ’13 (Scott, associate professor of law at Elon University School of Law, States Need to Keep Federal Power From Overstepping, New York Times, http://www.nytimes.com/roomfordebate/2013/07/16/state-politics-vs-the-federal-government/states-need-more-controlover-the-federal-government, accessed: 7/10/14 GA) As the old saying goes, all politics are local. State and federal governments affect our daily lives in numerous ways. Yet, in our federal system, there is supposed to be a balance between federal and state power. As James Madison envisioned it in Federalist No. 51, “the power surrendered by the people” would be “divided between two distinct governments,” creating a balance of power that would enable the “different governments [to] control each other.” Under the United States Constitution, the federal government has broad authority in specific enumerated areas, but its power is not unlimited. State government plays a critical role in all those areas that are not left exclusively to the federal government. As a result, state politics are extraordinarily important because states are charged with protecting the welfare, safety and health of their citizens (which is one reason why roughly 95 percent of criminal court cases are handled in state courts). At least since the New Deal, however, the balance of power has shifted decisively in favor of federal politics. The expansion of administrative agencies and other federal programs have encroached on state sovereignty, often with little or no resistance from the states themselves. Fortunately, governors and state attorneys general have begun to challenge overstepping by the federal government. But the winds of change are blowing in states across the country. Governors and state attorneys general have begun to challenge what they view as the federal government’s overstepping its constitutionally prescribed role. In 2010, more than 20 states filed suit against the federal government claiming that the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act exceeded Congress’s power. In addition, state attorneys general have successfully challenged various actions by the Environmental Protection Agency and other federal agencies, using state politics to protect the vertical separation of powers. Moreover, recent Supreme Court decisions provide a glimmer of hope to those championing state sovereignty. In National Federation of Independent Business (N.F.I.B.) v. Sebelius, a majority of the court determined that the individual mandate under the health care act exceeded Congress’s commerce clause power. In Shelby County v. Holder, the court held that Congress unconstitutionally infringed on state sovereignty by using an outdated formula under the Voting Rights Act to decide which states had to get federal approval before changing their voting laws. In United States v. Windsor, the court emphasized that the Defense of Marriage Act was unconstitutional in part because the regulation of domestic relations has always been left to the exclusive province of the states. Yet even in these cases, federal supremacy lurks in the background, ready to limit the reach of state political power. According to the court, Congress had ample taxing power to enact the individual mandate; Congress can propose a new formula under Section Four of the Voting Rights Act; and state control over domestic relations remains subject to the federal Constitution. As evidenced by the court’s 5-4 decisions in N.F.I.B., Shelby County and Windsor, the Supreme Court has been the last arbiter of the balance between state and federal power, and that balance is dictated by the narrowest of margins. Consequently, federal politics, including the next Supreme Court appointment, may determine the scope of state sovereignty for years to come. Impact Modeling Generic US federalism modeled now Tarr 05 Chair of the Department of Political Science at Rutgers University [G. Alan Tarr “United States of America” appearing in John Kincaid and G. Alan Tarr, editors Constituional Origins, structure and change in federal democracies” McGill Queen’s University Press, Montreal and Kingston: 2005 pg 382] The United States of America is the world's oldest, continuing, modern federal democracy. Indeed, the framers of the United States Constitution are widely regarded as the inventors of modern federalism, as distinct from ancient forms of federalism, especially confederalism. The US Constitution has been influential as a model of federal democracy, and key principles of the Constitution - such as federalism, the separation of powers, an independent judiciary, and individual rights - have gained acceptance worldwide. Americans believe that the nation's success owes much to the brilliance of the Constiution's drafters. Yet neither the Constitution, nor the federal polity it created, has remained static. Amendments adopted after the Civil War (186 1 -65) altered the federal-state balance, and the authorization of a federal income tax in the Sixteenth Amendment (1913) greatly augmented the fiscal power of the federal government. The Constitution has also both influenced and been influenced by political and social developments, including the transformation of the United States from a few states hugging the Atlantic Coast to a continental nation and also from a country recently liberated from colonial rule to an economic and military superpower. Environment Federalism in the US is modeled globally—especially in the context of environmental policy Sovacool 08 (Benjamin, Research Fellow in the Energy Governance Program at the Centre on Asia and Globalization, Adjunct Assistance Professor at the Virginia PI and University in Blacksburg VA Wrote a book, PhD in Science and Technology, Stanford Environmental Law Journal, June, 27 Stan. Envtl. L.J. 397) Third, other countries continue to model American-style federalism. Germany, the Republic of Austria, Russian Federation, Spain, India, and Nigeria have all based parts of their government structure on American federalism, choosing to decentralize power by adopting constitutions that are more federalist than the ones that they have replaced. n24 The "American experience with ... federalism," writes John Kincaid, "may have useful implications for an emerging federalist revolution worldwide." n25 Mikhail Gorbachev even stated that "the phenomenon of federalism affects the interests of the entire global community." n26 Given such trends, it seems likely that other countries may model American environmental federalism. If this is the case, ensuring that the United States government addresses renewable energy and climate policy at the proper scale becomes even more important for the signal it sends to the world. Solve conflict US federalism is modeled globally—promotes peace and innovation Mallat 3 (Chibli, Ph.D., University of London, “Federalism in the Middle East and Europe” CASE WESTERN RESERVE JOURNAL OF INTERNATIONAL LAW, Winter 2003, p. 3, http://content.lib.utah.edu/utils/getfile/collection/utlawrev/id/570/filename/14805.pdf) Federalism is the quintessential American invention. I have had occasion to dwell on it recently in a work which was published in English as a long series of newspaper articles which accompanied the 2000 presidential campaign in America, and appeared in book shape in Arabic in August 200I. It dwells on what makes America successful, its achievements, but also its limitations, and concludes that the excellence of law is one of the two distinctive features of pride for the American model — the other being science. While this rooting in law is not particularly new to an American audience, what one may not perceive as strongly from within the US is how much the world has been Americanized in terms of law. Laurence Tribe, in Constitutional Choices,4 summarized what he calls the underlying political ideas of the American system into a list of six categories: representative republicanism, federalism, separation of powers, equality before the law, individual autonomy and procedural fairness. America has shared many of these traits with other democracies for a long time, but two constitutional features stand out on a world level as typically American — federalism and the Supreme Court. The American people deserve credit for both inventions which brought new dimensions to democracy and the rule of law for the rest of the planet. Perhaps America does not know it, but the world has been a consistently better place wherever her two home-grown intellectual products have found anchor. In contrast, and as further illustration to this point, federalism and the protection of law by an independent supreme court appear as the two missing ingredients for a peaceful and creative future in the many countries and regions that do not know them. US federalism is modeled worldwide—solves conflict Calabresi ’95 (Steven G., Assistant Prof – Northwestern U., Michigan Law Review, "A Government of Limited and Enumerated Powers": In Defense of United States v. Lopez”, JSTOR) First, the rules of constitutional federalism should be enforced because federalism is a good thing, and it is the best and most important structural feature of the U.S. Constitution. Second, the political branches cannot be relied upon to enforce constitutional federalism, notwithstanding the contrary writings of Professor Jesse Choper. Third, the Supreme Court is institutionally competent to enforce constitutional federalism. Fourth, the Court is at least as qualified to act in this area as it is in the Fourteenth Amendment area. And, fifth, the doctrine of stare [*831] decisis does not pose a barrier to the creation of any new, prospectively applicable Commerce Clause case law. The conventional wisdom is that Lopez is nothing more than a flash in the pan. 232 Elite opinion holds that the future of American constitutional law will involve the continuing elaboration of the Court's national codes on matters like abortion regulation, pornography, rules on holiday displays, and rules on how the states should conduct their own criminal investigations and trials. Public choice theory suggests many reasons why it is likely that the Court will continue to pick on the states and give Congress a free ride. But, it would be a very good thing for this country if the Court decided to surprise us and continued on its way down the Lopez path. Those of us who comment on the Court's work, whether in the law reviews or in the newspapers, should encourage the Court to follow the path on which it has now embarked. The country and the world would be a better place if it did. We have seen that a desire for both international and devolutionary federalism has swept across the world in recent years. To a is due to global fascination with and emulation of our own American federalism success story. The global trend toward federalism is an enormously positive development that greatly increases the likelihood of future peace, free trade, economic growth, respect for social and cultural diversity, and protection of individual human rights. It depends for its success on the willingness of sovereign nations to strike federalism deals in the belief that those deals will be kept. 233 The U.S. Supreme Court can do its part to encourage the future striking of such deals by enforcing vigorously our own American federalism deal. Lopez could be a first step in that process, if only the Justices and the legal academy significant extent, this would wake up to the importance of what is at stake. Democracy Federalism k2 Demo Federalism is key to global democracy Wright, 97 (Robin, a contributing correspondent of The Washington Quarterly, covers the patterns of democratization and other global issues for the Los Angeles Times, Washington Quarterly, Summer) The most dynamic political trend promoting democracy worldwide in the 1990s is devolution, the transfer of power beyond capitals and traditional elites in ways that are in turn redefining democracy's scope and application. It is now the frontline of democratization in Latin America, Central Europe, Africa, and Asia. The most radical experiment in Latin America is Bolivia's new "popular participation" program, which is devolving power and resources long concentrated in three urban centers to 311 municipalities. The project effectively expedites democracy. Towns and villages no longer have to appeal to regional or national authorities for everything from electricity to school desks. The goal is for communities to provide services and handle problems according to local needs and priorities as a check against the abuse of power at the national level. Before the transition to democracy began in the 1980s, Bolivia witnessed 189 coups in 162 years. For the first time, popular participation has included the country's majority -- the 65 percent indigenous population that has long been excluded by descendants of Spanish colonials. Many of Bolivia's Aymara and Quechua Indians, whose civilizations date back millennia, are getting their first taste of modern power. In Africa, Mali's first democratic government contends decentralization works because it forces engagement. The West African state, which is twice the size of Texas, has shifted control of key administrative and financial functions, including education, health, and development, to more than 500 rural and urban communities. Each locality fixes tax rates and allocates revenues. To allow local direction and limit corruption, each area also negotiates directly with foreign aid groups. Devolution also helps block democracy's undoing by dispersing power beyond the reach of armies or strongmen -- a recent problem among Mali's neighbors. Democratic progress in Niger and Gambia has been reversed by military intervention, while Nigeria's army stepped in to void results of the oil-rich state's first democratic elections. Former dictators have won democratic elections in Benin and Burkino Faso. And irregularities have marred elections in Mauritania, Guinea-Bissau, and Equatorial Guinea. Devolution can also provide a mechanism to ease ethnic or sectarian disparities. Ethiopia boasts one of Africa's most radical experiments in devolution in an attempt to prevent further dismemberment. Differences among its 80 ethnic groups -- which use a dozen major languages and three alphabets -- have spawned a host of conflicts during both monarchial and communist rule. (Eritrea broke away in 1993.) As part of its still-tentative transition to democracy, Ethiopia has introduced a new constitution that divides 55 million people into nine ethnic-based states. It also bestows major powers of self-administration and even the right to secede. The motive for transferring power is not always altruistic. Devolution often also represents an attempt to transfer the onus of solutions beyond central governments no longer able to provide services or answers. In reaction to the strong centralization of communism, democratic Poland is moving in the opposite direction as the state devolves power to gaminas, local communities of various sizes run by councils now locally elected. Warsaw has several gaminas, whereas a rural gamina may include several villages. Among all the units of government, gaminas now have the highest public support. n15 In 1996, the state began to transfer control of education to gaminas, which are now allocated about 10 percent of national revenues. Gaminas also collect local taxes, although income varies widely depending on local resources. But the combination of local and state funds is often insufficient to pay for schools and other services the federal government once provided. As a result, some communities have actually appealed to Warsaw to reassume responsibility for schools. Devolution is also not without basic conceptual problems. In many places, shortcomings include poorly educated or inexperienced new officials, including some who can barely read or who know virtually nothing about budgets and managing a municipality. Initial projects have often been flashy rather than thoughtful infrastructure schemes. Local areas are also not immune to corruption, which in Bolivia led to installation of "vigilance committees" to oversee its mayors. Yet as in many places, the government in La Paz contends devolution is still the best mechanism for both the initial democratization process and subsequent stabilization. Devolution shares problems as well as power. It introduces a wider array of players to shoulder the burdens as well as to have a stake in the outcome. And by embracing men and women in the most remote rural corners of countries, devolution also prevents or defuses the flashpoints behind competition and strife. US leadership on federalism is essential to democracy worldwide David Broder, Washington Post, June 24, 2001, “Lessons On Freedom.” Broder was a pulitzer prize recipient and reciepient of 16 honory degrees, earned a bachelor’s degree in liberal arts from the University of Chicago in 1947 and continued his studies there, receiving a master’s degree in political science in 1951. Even more persistent were the questions about the role the United States would play, under this new administration, in supporting democratic movements around the world. It is sobering to be reminded how often, during the long decades of the Cold War, this country backed (and in some cases, created) undemocratic regimes, simply because we thought military rulers and other autocrats were more reliable allies against communism. The week of the Salzburg Seminar coincided with President Bush's first tour of Europe. He was a target of jokes and ridicule for many of the fellows as the week began. But the coverage of his meetings and, especially, his major address in Poland on his vision of Europe's future and America's role in it, earned him grudging respect, even though it remains uncertain how high a priority human rights and promotion of democracy will have in the Bush foreign policy. Another great lesson for an American reporter is that the struggle to maintain the legitimacy of representative government in the eyes of the public is a worldwide battle. Election turnouts are dropping in almost all the established democracies, so much so that seminar participants seriously discussed the advisability of compulsory voting, before most of them rejected it as smacking too much of authoritarian regimes. Political parties -- which most of us have regarded as essential agents of democracy -are in decline everywhere. They are viewed by more and more of the national publics as being tied to special interests or locked in increasingly irrelevant or petty rivalries -- anything but effective instruments for tackling current challenges. One large but unresolved question throughout the week: Can you organize and sustain representative government without strong parties? The single most impressive visitor to the seminar was Vaira Vike-Freiberga, the president of Latvia, a woman of Thatcherite determination when it comes to pressing for her country's admission to NATO, but a democrat who has gone through exile four times in her quest for freedom. She is a member of no party, chosen unanimously by a parliament of eight parties, and bolstered by her popular support. But how many such leaders are there? Meantime, even as democracy is tested everywhere from Venezuela to Romania to the Philippines, a new and perhaps tougher accountability examination awaits in the supranational organizations. The European Union has operated so far with a strong council, where each nation has a veto, and a weak parliament, with majority rule. But with its membership seemingly certain to expand, the age-old dilemma of democracy -- majority rule vs. minority and individual rights -- is bound to come to the fore. The principle of federalism will be vital to its success. And, once again, the United States has important lessons to teach. But only if we can keep democracy strong and vital in our own country. Impacts That outweighs war Rummel, 97 ( Prof of Political Science at University of Hawaii, “Democracy, Power, and Democide” http://www.hawaii.edu/powerkills/SOD.CHAP17.HTM) Our century is noted for its absolute and bloody wars. World War I saw nine-million people killed in battle, an incredi ble record that was far surpassed within a few decades by the 15 million battle deaths of World War II. Even the number killed in twentieth century revolutions and civil wars have set historical records. In total, this century's battle killed in all its international and domestic wars, revolutions, and violent conflicts is so far about 35,654,000. Yet, even more unbelievable than these vast numbers killed in war during the lifetime of some still living, and largely unknown, is this shocking fact. This century's total killed by absolutist governments already far exceeds that for all wars, domestic and international. Indeed, this number already approximates the number that might be killed in a nuclear war. Table 1 provides the relevant totals and classifies these by type of government (following Freedom House's definitions) and war. By government killed is meant any direct or indirect killing by government officials, or government acquiescence in the killing by others, of more than 1,000 people, except execution for what are conventionally considered criminal acts (murder, rape, spying, treason, and the like). This killing is apart from the pursuit of any ongoing military action or campaign, or as part of any conflict event. For example, the Jews that Hitler slaughtered during World War II would be counted, since their merciless and systematic killing was unrelated to and actually conflicted with Hitler's pursuit of the war. The totals in the Table are based on a nation-by-nation assessment and are absolute minimal figures that may under estimate the true total by ten percent or more. Moreover, these figures do not even include the 1921-1922 and 1958-1961 famines in the Soviet Union and China causing about 4 million and 27 million dead, respectably. The former famine was mainly due to the imposition of a command agricultural economy, forced requisitions of food by the Soviets, and the liquidation campaigns of the Cheka; the latter was wholly caused by Mao's agriculturally destructive Great Leap Forward and collectivization. However, Table 1 does include the Soviet government's planned and administered starvation of the Ukraine begun in 1932 as a way of breaking peasant opposition to collectivization and destroying Ukrainian nationalism. As many as ten million may have been starved to death or succumbed to famine related diseases; I estimate eight million died. Had these people all been shot, the Soviet government's moral responsibility could be no greater. The Table lists 831 thousand people killed by free -- democratic -- governments, which should startle most readers. This figure involves the French massacres in Algeria before and during the Algerian war (36,000 killed, at a minimum), and those killed by the Soviets after being forcibly repatriated to them by the Allied Democracies during and after World War II. It is outrageous that in line with and even often surpassing in zeal the letter of the Yalta Agreement signed by Stalin, Churchill, and Roosevelt, the Allied Democracies, particularly Great Britain and the United States, turned over to Soviet authorities more than 2,250,000 Soviet citizens, prisoners of war, and Russian exiles (who were not Soviet citizens) found in the Allied zones of occupation in Europe. Most of these people were terrified of the consequences of repatriation and refused to cooperate in their repatriation; often whole families preferred suicide. Of those the Allied Democracies repatriation, an estimated 795,000 were executed, or died in slave-labor camps or in transit to them. If a government is to be held responsible for those prisoners who die in freight cars or in their camps from privation, surely those democratic governments that turned helpless people over to totalitarian rulers with foreknowledge of their peril, also should be held responsible. Concerning now the overall mortality statistics shown in the table, it is sad that hundreds of thousands of people can be killed by governments with hardly an international murmur, while a war killing several thousand people can cause an immediate world outcry and global reaction. Simply contrast the international focus on the relatively minor Falkland Islands War of Britain and Argentina with the widescale lack of interest in Burundi's killing or acquiescence in such killing of about 100,000 Hutu in 1972, of Indonesia slaughtering a likely 600,000 "communists" in 1965, and of Pakistan, in an initially well planned massacre, eventually killing from one to three million Bengalis in 1971. A most noteworthy and still sensitive example of this double standard is the Vietnam War. The international community was outraged at the American attempt to militarily prevent North Vietnam from taking over South Vietnam and ultimately Laos and Cambodia. "Stop the killing" was the cry, and eventually, the pressure of foreign and domestic opposition forced an American withdrawal. The overall number killed in the Vietnam War on all sides was about 1,216,000 people. With the United States subsequently refusing them even modest military aid, South Vietnam was militarily defeated by the North and completely swallowed; and Cambodia was taken over by the communist Khmer Rouge, who in trying to recreate a primitive communist agricultural society slaughtered from one to three million Cambodians. If we take a middle two-million as the best estimate, then in four years the government of this small nation of seven million alone killed 64 percent more people than died in the ten-year Vietnam War. Overall, the best estimate of those killed after the Vietnam War by the victorious communists in Vietnam, Laos, and Cambodia is 2,270,000. Now totaling almost twice as many as died in the Vietnam War, this communist killing still continues. To view this double standard from another perspective, both World Wars cost twenty-four million battle deaths. But from 1918 to 1953, the Soviet government executed, slaughtered, starved, beat or tortured to death, or otherwise killed 39,500,000 of its own people (my best estimate among figures ranging from a minimum of twenty million killed by Stalin to a total over the whole communist period of eighty-three million). For China under Mao Tse-tung, the communist government eliminated, as an average figure between estimates, 45,000,000 Chinese. The number killed for just these two nations is about 84,500,000 human beings, or a lethality of 252 percent more than both World Wars together. Yet, have the world community and intellectuals generally shown anything like the same horror, the same outrage, the same out pouring of anti-killing literature, over these Soviet and Chinese megakillings as has been directed at the much less deadly World Wars? As can be seen from Table 1, communist governments are overall almost four times more lethal to their citizens than non-communist ones, and in per capita terms nearly twice as lethal (even considering the huge populations of the USSR and China). However, as large as the per capita killed is for communist governments, it is nearly the same as for other non-free governments. This is due to the massacres and widescale killing in the very small country of East Timor, where since 1975 Indonesia has eliminated (aside from the guerrilla war and associated violence) an estimated 100 thousand Timorese out of a population of 600 thousand. Omitting this country alone would reduce the average killed by noncommunist, nonfree governments to 397 per the more freedom in a nation, the fewer people killed by government. Freedom acts to brake the use of a governing elite's power over life and death to pursue their policies and ensure their rule. This principle appeared to be violated in two aforementioned special cases. 10,000, or significantly less than the 477 per 10,000 for communist countries. In any case, we can still see from the table that One was the French government carrying out mass killing in the colony of Algeria, where compared to Frenchmen the Algerians were second class citizens, without the right to vote in French elections. In the other case the Allied Democracies acted during and just after wartime, under strict secrecy, to turn over foreigners to a communist government. These foreigners, of course, had no rights as citizens that would protect them in the democracies. In no case have I found a democratic government carrying out massacres, genocide, and mass executions of its own citizens; nor have I found a case where such a government's policies have knowingly Absolutism is not only many times deadlier than war, but itself is the major factor causing war and other forms of violent conflict. It is a major cause of militarism. Indeed, absolutism, not war, is mankind's deadliest scourge of all. and directly resulted in the large scale deaths of its people though privation, torture, beatings, and the like. Democratization solves nuclear war Muravchik, 2k1 (Joshua, resident scholar The American Enterprise Institute, July 11-14, http://www.npec-web.org/syllabi/muravchik.htm) The greatest impetus for world peace -- and perforce of nuclear peace -- is the spread of democracy. In a famous article, and subsequent book, Francis Fukuyama argued that democracy's extension was leading to "the end of history." By this he meant the conclusion of man's quest for the right social order, but he also meant the "diminution of the likelihood of large-scale conflict between states." (1) Fukuyama's phrase was intentionally provocative, even tongue-in-cheek, but he was pointing to two down-to-earth historical observations: that democracies are more peaceful than other kinds of government and that the world is growing more democratic. Neither point has gone unchallenged. Only a few decades ago, as distinguished an observer of international relations as George Kennan made a claim quite contrary to the first of these assertions. Democracies, he said, were slow to anger, but once aroused "a democracy . . . . fights in anger . . . . to the bitter end." (2) Kennan's view was strongly influenced by the policy of "unconditional surrender" pursued in World War II. But subsequent experience, such as the negotiated settlements America sought in Korea and Vietnam proved him wrong. Democracies are not only slow to anger but also quick to compromise. And to forgive. Notwithstanding the insistence on unconditional surrender, America treated Japan and that part of Germany that it occupied with extraordinary generosity. In recent years a burgeoning literature has discussed the peacefulness of democracies. Indeed the proposition that democracies do not go to war with one another has been described by one political scientist as being "as close as anything we have to an empirical law in international relations." (3) Some of those who find enthusiasm for democracy off-putting have challenged this proposition, but their challenges have only served as empirical tests that have confirmed its robustness. For example, the academic Paul Gottfried and the columnist-turned-politician Patrick J. Buchanan have both instanced democratic England's declaration of war against democratic Finland during World War II. (4) In fact, after much procrastination, England did accede to the pressure of its Soviet ally to declare war against Finland which was allied with Germany. But the declaration was purely formal: no fighting ensued between England and Finland. That Freedom House could count 120 freely elected governments by early 2001 (out of a total of 192 independent states) bespeaks a vast transformation in human governance within the span of 225 years. In 1775, the number of democracies was zero. In 1776, the birth of the United States of America brought the total up to one. Since then, democracy has spread at an accelerating pace, most of the growth having occurred within the twentieth century, with greatest momentum since 1974. That this momentum has slackened somewhat since its pinnacle in 1989, destined to be remembered as one of the most revolutionary years in all history, was inevitable. So many peoples were swept up in the democratic tide that there was certain to be some backsliding. Most countries' democratic evolution has included some fits and starts rather than a smooth progression. So it must be for the world as a whole. Nonetheless, the overall trend remains powerful and clear. Despite the backsliding, the number and proportion of democracies stands higher today than ever before. This progress offers a source of hope for enduring nuclear peace. The danger of nuclear war was radically reduced almost overnight when Russia abandoned Communism and turned to democracy. For other ominous corners of the world, we may be in a kind of race between the emergence or growth of nuclear arsenals and the advent of democratization. If this is so, the greatest cause for worry may rest with the Moslem Middle East where nuclear arsenals do not yet exist but where the prospects for democracy may be still more remote. Surely this is an exception that proves the rule. CONTINUES… FREEDOM! Fed key to Freedom States are necessary to individual freedom, the Constitution leaves all reasonable law making to the States Hawkins ’13 (Dustin, law professor at The University of Pennsylvania law school, Federalism: Case for Reinvigorating State's Rights, US conservatives, http://usconservatives.about.com/od/conservativepolitics101/a/The-Conservative-Case-For-Returning-Government-Power-ToThe-States.htm, accessed: 7/10/14 GA) There is an ongoing battle over the proper size and role of the federal government, especially as it relates to conflicts with state governments over legislative authority. Conservatives believe that state and local governments should be empowered to handle local issues such as healthcare, education, immigration, and many other social and economic laws. There is little question that the current role of the federal government far exceeds anything ever imagined by the founders and has clearly taken over many roles originally designated to individual states. The founding fathers, through the U.S. Constitution, sought to limit the possibility of a strong centralized government and in fact gave the federal government a very limited list of responsibilities. Simplified, the founders thought that the federal government should handle issues that it would be difficult or unreasonable for states to handle such as the maintenance of military and defense operations, negotiating with foreign countries, creating currency, and regulating commerce with foreign countries. Ideally, individual states would then handle all most matters that they reasonably could. The founders even went further in the U.S. Constitution’s Bill of Rights to prevent the federal government from grabbing too much power. One of the clear benefits of a weaker federal government and stronger state governments is that the needs of each individual state are more easily managed. Alaska, Iowa, Rhode Island, and Florida are all very different states with very different needs, populations, and values. A law that may make sense in New York might make little sense in Alabama. For example: Some states have determined it is necessary to prohibit the use of fireworks due to an environment that is highly susceptible to wild fires. Other states have no such problems and have laws that allow fireworks. It would not be valuable for the federal government to make one standardized law for all states prohibiting fireworks when only a handful of states need such a law in place. State control also empowers states to make tough decisions for their own well-being rather than hope that the federal government will see the states’ problem as a priority. A strong state government also empowers citizens in two ways. First, state governments are far more responsive to the needs of the residents of their state. If important issues are not addressed, then voters can hold elections and vote in people they feel are better suited to handle the problems. However, if an issue is only important to one state and the federal government has authority over that issue, then they have little influence to get the change they seek as they are but a small part of a larger electorate. Second, empowered state governments also allow individuals to choose the state that best fit their own personal values. Families and individuals are able to choose states that either have no or low income taxes, or states with higher ones. They can opt for states with weak or strong guns laws, with restrictions on marriage or without them, and so on. Some people may prefer to live in a state that offers a wide range of government programs and services, others may not. But just as the free market allows individuals to pick and choose products or services they like, so to can they choose a state that best fits their lifestyle. An over-reaching federal government limits this option. Federalism protects freedom Calabresi 95 (Steven G., Asscociate professor at Northwestern University of Law, “A Government of Limited and Enumerated Powers: In Defense of the United States v Lopez”, December 1995, Jstor) Because it often may be unclear what bundles of public goods are desirable at what cost, competition among jurisdictions holds out the potential for a market mechanism that can provide an empirical answer to the most important questions of governance.69 This argument has built into it two crucial assumptions: first, that the policies adopted by the states do not generate significant externalities, a point I come back to; and second, that there be free movement of capital and labor across state borders with no important residency requirements of any kind. Obviously, a right of exit is crucial to any competition among jurisdictions because it is that right that allows market discipline of those jurisdictions that provide less desirable bundles of public goods.70 Without a right of exit, a situation of jurisdictional monopoly prevails like that which exists under all uni- tary national governments. Jurisdictional monopoly is conducive not only to a low-quality bundle of public goods; at the extreme, it could be said also to lead to the denial of fundamental individual liberties. Jurisdictional competition, then, is also beneficial because it leads to the protection of liberty. If I dislike the laws of my home state enough and feel tyrannized by them enough, I always can preserve my freedom by moving to a different state with less tyrannous laws. Some may think this liberty argument for federalism is just another form of the argument already made that federalism leads to competition in the provision of public goods. And, of course, if one wrongly believes that fundamental private liberties are "provided" by government as a public good, then these two points indeed do collapse into each other. In fact, however, it turns out that fundamental private liber- ties are actually antecedent to government,71 and, therefore, the protection of those liberties through jurisdictional competition is a great and additional benefit of federalism. Impact Protecting freedom is a priori – it cannot be sacrificed for anything Petro in 74 (Sylvester Petro, professor of law at Wake Forest, Spring 1974, Toledo Law Review, p. 480) However, one may still insist on echoing Ernest Hemingway – "I believe in only one thing: liberty." And it is it is unacceptable to say that the invasion of one aspect of freedom is of no import because there have been invasions of so many other aspects. That road leads to chaos, tyranny, despotism, and the end of all human aspiration. Ask Solzhenstyn, Ask Milovan Djilas. In sum, if one believes in freedom as a supreme value and proper ordering principle for any society aiming to maximize spiritual and material welfare, then every invasion of freedom must be emphatically identified and resisted with undying spirit. always well to bear in mind David Hume's observation: "It is seldom that liberty of any kind is lost all at once." Thus, Violence/Conflict Federalism prevents violence and war Calabresi, 1995,Steven Law Prof @ NWU, December, 94 Mich. L. Rev. 752. Small state federalism is a big part of what keeps the peace in countries like the United States and Switzerland. It is a big part of the reason why we do not have a Bosnia or a Northern Ireland or a Basque country or a Chechnya or a Corsica or a Quebec problem. American federalism in the end is not a trivial matter or a quaint historical anachronism. American-style it prevents violence and war. It prevents religious warfare, it prevents secessionist warfare, and it prevents racial warfare. It is part of the reason why democratic majoritarianism in the United States has not produced violence or secession for 130 years, unlike the situation for example, in England, France, Germany, Russia, Czechoslovakia, Yugoslavia, Cyprus, or Spain. There is nothing in the U.S. Constitution that is more important or that has done more to promote peace, prosperity, and freedom than the federal structure of that great document. There is nothing in the federalism is a thriving and vital institutional arrangement - partly planned by the Framers, partly the accident of history - and U.S. Constitution that should absorb more completely the attention of the U.S. Supreme Court. Federalism is key to preventing violence, secessions, and rebellions—prefer empirical studies Lawoti, 09- Professor of Political Science at Western Michigan University (Mahendra, “Federalism for Nepal”, Telegraph Nepal, 3/18, http://www.telegraphnepal.com/backup/telegraph/news_det.php?news_id=5041)//MC Cross-national studies covering over 100 countries have shown that federalism minimizes violent conflicts whereas unitary structures are more apt to exacerbate ethnic conflicts. Frank S. Cohen (1997) analyzed ethnic conflicts and inter-governmental organizations over nine 5-year –periods (1945-1948 and 19851989) among 223 ethnic groups in 100 countries. He found that federalism generates increases in the incidence of protests (low-level ethnic conflicts) but stifles the development of rebellions (high-level conflicts). Increased access to institutional power provided by federalism leads to more low-level conflicts because local groups mobilize at the regional level to make demands on the regional governments. The perceptions that conflicts occur in federal structure is not entirely incorrect. But the conflicts are low-level and manageable ones. Often, these are desirable conflicts because they are expressions of disadvantaged groups and people for equality and justice, and part of a process that consolidates democracy. In addition, they also let off steam so that the protests do not turn into rebellions. As the demands at the regional levels are addressed, frustrations do not build up. It checks abrupt and severe outburst. That is why high levels of conflicts are found less in federal countries. On the other hand, Cohen found high levels of conflicts in unitary structures and centralized politics. According to Cohen (1997:624): Federalism moderates politics by expanding the opportunity for victory. The increase in opportunities for political gain comes from the fragmentation/dispersion of policy-making the compartmentalizing character of federalism also assures cultural distinctiveness by offering dissatisfied ethnic minorities proximity to public affairs. Such close contact provides a feeling of both control and security that an ethnic group gains regarding its own affairs. In general, such power… institutional proximity expands the opportunities for political participation, socialization, and consequently, democratic consolidation. Saidmeman, Lanoue, Campenini, and Stanton’s (2002: 118) findings also support Cohen’s analysis that federalism influences peace and violent dissent differently. They used Minority at Risk Phase III dataset and investigated 1264 ethnic groups. According to Saideman et al. (2002:118-120): Federalism reduces the level of ethnic violence. In a federal structure, groups at the local level can influence many of the issues that matter dearly to them- education, law enforcement, and the like. Moreover, federal arrangements reduce the chances that any group will realize its greatest nightmare: having its culture, political and educational institutions destroyed by a hostile national majority. These broad empirical studies support the earlier claims of Lijphart, Gurr, and Horowitz that power sharing and autonomy granting institutions can foster peaceful accommodation and prevent violent conflicts among different groups in culturally plural societies. Lijphart (1977:88), in his award winning book Democracy in Plural Societies, argues that "Clear boundaries between the segments of a plural society have the advantage of limiting mutual contacts and consequently of limiting the chances of ever-present potential antagonisms to erupt into actual hostility". This is not to argue for isolated or closed polities, which is almost impossible in a progressively globalizing world. The case is that when quite distinct and self-differentiating cultures come into contact, antagonism between them may increase. Compared to federal structure, unitary structure may bring distinct cultural groups into intense contact more rapidly because more group members may stay within their regions of traditional settlements under federal arrangements whereas unitary structure may foster population movement. Federalism reduces conflicts because it provides autonomy to groups. Disputants within federal structures or any mechanisms that provide autonomy are better able to work out agreements on more specific issues that surface repeatedly in the programs of communal movement (Gurr 1993:298-299). Autonomy agreements have helped dampen rebellions by Basques in Spain, the Moros in the Philippines, the Miskitos in Nicaragua, the people of Bangladesh’s Chittagong Hill Tracts and the affairs of Ethiopia, among others (Gurr 1993:3190) The Indian experiences are also illustrative. Ghosh (1998) argues that India state manged many its violent ethnic conflicts by creating new states (Such as Andhra Pradesh, Gujurat, Punjab, Harayana, Arunachal Pradesh, Goa, Himachal Pradesh, Meghalaya, Mizoram and Nagaland) and autonomous councils (Such as Darjeeling Gorkha Hill Council, Bodoland The basic idea, was to devolve powers to make the ethnic/linguistic groups feel that their identity was being respected by the state. By providing autonomy, federalism also undermines militant appeals. Because effective autonomy provides resources and institutions through which groups can make significant progress toward their objectives, many ethnic activities and supporters of ethnic movements are engaged through such arrangements. Thus it builds long-term support for peaceful solutions and undermines appeals to militant action (Gurr 1993:303). Autonomous Council, and Jharkhand Area autonomous Council, Leh Autonomous Hill Development Council). according to Ghosh (1998:61), Policies of regional devolution in France, Spain and Italy, on the other hand, demonstrate that establishing self-managing autonomous regions can be politically and economically less burdensome for central states than keeping resistant peoples in line by force: autonomy arrangements have transformed destructive conflicts in these societies into positive interregional competition". Federalism for Nepal Federalism is essential in plural countries like Nepal because it provides cultural autonomy to different cultural groups within a country. By allowing ethnic groups to govern themselves in cultural and developmental matters, it lessens their conflicts with the central state. Many of the conflicts of the identity movements are in cultural issues like religion, language, education and so on. Once regional governments are established, either the contesting parties from their own governments at the regional level, and decides in those matters, and/or influence the outcome because their proportional presence at the regional level is more than in the national level. Thus, many ethnic and linguistic groups can effectively put more pressure to the regional governments. Under unitary system, numerous regionally concentrated groups have not been able to put pressure on the central government because their conflicts will be regionally focussed. Hence, many of the conflicts will decrease in intensity and strength at the central level. The bureaucracy will also increasingly reflect the regional composition because the regional governments would population and voice are small at the central context. Even if they are not, their nature will become different. Some of the hire local people in the administration. Bureaucrats with knowledge of local languages and specific local problems will be able to provide relatively more efficient administration. This will also reduce conflicts. Inclusion of more ethnic members into regional politics and administration will ensure more public politics directed toward regional needs, instead of irrelevant policies directed by the center. This will contribute to reducing conflicts arising out of mal-distribution of resources. If minorities want some form of autonomy to protect and promote their culture, develop their people and regions, and self-determine their future, they are likely to struggle for it unless some autonomy is provided. The struggle might take different form in different periods due to varying circumstances. Even if unfavorable circumstances may lead to non-actions during some periods, favorable conditions for mobilizations in other periods may lead to more activities, perhaps in violent ways. The growth of ethnic movements in Nepal after 1990 is an example. Thus, to address the conflicts arising out of issues of identity and cultural rights that are inherent human aspirations, autonomy is essential. Granting of federalism would in all likelihood bring an end to ethnic insurgencies like the Khambuwan Mukti Morcha because it meets their major demand. It will also prevent the possibilities of other ethnic insurgencies with demand for Territorial federalism can work for the benefit of large ethnic groups concentrated regionally but may not be able to address problems of the numerous low populated ethnic groups or groups that are not federalism. concentrated because they may not form majorities anywhere. For these groups, non-territorial federalism, as in Belgium, Austria etc. may address their needs. In non-territorial federalism, members of ethnic groups have rights to decide about their culture, education, language and so on by electing councils who have jurisdiction over cultural, social and developmental realms. The problems of the dalit and small ethnic groups can be addressed through non-territorial federalism. Federalism and its critics in Nepal The dominant group in Nepal often argues against federalism by raising the fear of secession. I have argued elsewhere that this fear is misplaced. In demanding only a few of the rights that mainly deal with cultural and social issues, the minority groups acknowledge that advantages of staying within the existing nation-state. On the other hand, devolution helps to avert separatism because granting of devolution meets substantial demand of the minorities. However, power has to be devolved in ways that make the state and minorities perceive benefit form it. Large numbers of ethnic groups with small population further minimize the secessionist possibilities in Nepal, if any. The lack of resources and difficult topography of settlement in may cases make the creation and sustenance of smaller independent nations difficult, more so when the groups are in a state of under development. On the other hand, experience elsewhere demonstrates that absence of autonomy may lead to secessionist movements. Federalism was considered "slippery" in the 60s in Sri Lanka when the Tamils demanded autonomy. Today, autonomy does not satisfy the demands of federalism, in fact, may contribute in keeping a country together by satisfying communities have power over themselves, there is less need to secede; hence, a federal structure can keep different communities united within a nation-state framework. Where cultural autonomy has not been provided, many countries have seceded or are undergoing civil war or violent ethnic conflicts. Many in Nepal ignorantly argue that a small country like Nepal does the movement that arouse out of its denial (Stepan 1999). Hence not need a federal structure. However, federal countries like Belgium, Switzerland, Israel, Papua New Guinea, Holland and Austria have less population than Nepal. This belies the widespread fallacy that ‘small’ country like Nepal does not require federalism. The difficult geographic terrain and the problems of transportation and communication, on the other hand, make Nepal effectively larger than its area and population indicates. The perception that Nepal is a small country is due to its sandwiched position between the world’s two most populous countries. In terms of real and effective population, geography and cultural diversity, Nepal is not a small country. In fact, it is the 40th populous country among 227 countries in the world as of 2002 (US Census Bureau 2002). Federalism in not only in the interests if the marginalized groups, however. It is also in the interests of the dominant community because it lessens the underlying reasons for conflicts. Conflicts are more costly to the privilege sections of the society; hence as a toll for lessening the conflicts, federalism can serve the interests of the dominant community as well. Excerpts from the book "Nepal Tomorrow: Voices and visions" edited by D.B. Gurung. Secessionism causes global wars Gottlieb, 93 (Gidon, Director of the Middle East Peace Project and Visiting Fellow at Council on Foreign Relations, Nation Against State, 127-7) Self-determination unleashed and unchecked by balancing principles constitutes a menace to the society of states. There is simply no way in which all the hundreds of peoples who aspire to sovereign independence can be granted a state of their own without loosening fearful anarchy and disorder on a planetary scale. The proliferation of territorial entities poses exponentially greater problems for the control of weapons of mass destruction and multiplies situations in which external intervention could threaten the peace. It increases problems for the management of all global issues, including terrorism, AIDS, the environment and population growth. It creates conditions in which domestic strife in remote territories can drag powerful neighbors into local hostilities, creating ever widening circles of conflict. Events in the aftermath of the breakup of the Soviet Union drove this point home. Like Russian dolls, ever smaller ethnic groups dwelling in larger units emerged to secede and to demand independence. Goergia, for example, has to contend with the claims of South Ossetians and Abkhazians for independence, just as the Russian federation is confronted with the separatism of Tartaristan. An international system made up of several hundred independent terriatorial states cannot be the basis for global security and prosperity. Countries adopt decentralization for a laundry list of reasons—protects countries against external conflict, achieves economies of scale, and are easier to mange Brancati 5 (Dawn, Harvard University Institute for Quantitative Political Science, “Decentralization: Fueling the Fire or Dampening the Flames of Ethnic Conflict and Secessionism”, http://www.nyu.edu/gsas/dept/politics/seminars/brancati_f05_paper.pdf) Many countries, moreover, have adopted decentralization for reasons other than the need to manage ethnic conflict and secessionism. Some countries, like the United States and Canada, have adopted decentralized systems of government in order to unite different territories into a single country protect themselves against external military threats (Hamilton, Madison and .Jay, 1987; Hiker, 1964), and achieve economies of scale (Hamilton, Madison and Jay. 1987: Alesina and Spolare, 1997; Bolton and Roland, 1997). Some countries also have decentralized systems of government because they are large and cannot be easily managed from a single central government located far away from most of its constituents (Panizza, 1999; Treisman. 2002). Other countries, like Nigeria and South Africa. have decentralized systems of government because they are former colonies of the United Kingdom. The United Kingdom used decentralization to maintain control over its colonies - many of which have continued to use decentralization after gaining independence because decentralization entrenched regional elites, who were unwilling to relinquish power once their colonies gained independence (Young, 1994; Elerbst, 2000). Other colonial powers, including France and Spain, did not use this system of government to maintain control over their colonies, even though their colonies were very diverse ethnically and religiously. Econ General Federalism is key to the economy Katz, Vice Pres and Dir-Metropolitan Policy Program, 12 (Bruce, February 06, “Remaking Federalism to Remake the American Economy”, Campaign 2012 Papers, No. 3, LL) To achieve these twin goals, the U.S. needs to restructure the economy from one focused inward and characterized by excessive consumption and debt, to one globally engaged and driven by production and innovation. It must do so while contending with a new cadre of global competitors that aim to best the United States in the next industrial revolution and while leveraging the distinctive assets and advantages of different parts of the country, particularly the major cities and metropolitan areas that are the engines of national prosperity. This is the tallest of economic orders and it is well beyond the scope of exclusive federal solutions, the traditional focus of presidential candidates in both political parties. Rather, the next President must look beyond Washington and enlist states and metropolitan areas as active co-partners in the restructuring of the national economy. Remaking the economy, in essence, requires a remaking of federalism so that governments at all levels “collaborate to compete” and work closely with each other and the private and civic sectors to burnish American competitiveness in the new global economic order. The time for remaking federalism could not be more propitious. With Washington mired in partisan gridlock, the states and metropolitan areas are once again playing their traditional roles as “laboratories of democracy” and centers of economic and policy innovation. An enormous opportunity exists for the next president to mobilize these federalist partners in a focused campaign for national economic renewal. Given global competition, the next president should adopt a vision of collaborative federalism in which: the federal government leads where it must and sets a robust platform for productive and innovative growth via a few transformative investments and interventions; states and metropolitan areas innovate where they should to design and implement bottom-up economic strategies that fully align with their distinctive competitive assets and advantages; and a refreshed set of federalist institutions maximize results by accelerating the replication of innovations across the federal, state and metropolitan levels. Competitiveness Federalism encourages economic competitiveness- finds the best policies Feld, Zimmermann, and Döring 2004 (Lars P., Full Professor of Economics, particularly Economic Policy at the Uni versity of Freiburg, Horst, Thomas, Professor at Humbolt University of Berlin, “Federalism, decentralization, and economic growth”, Marburger volkswirtschaftliche Beiträge 2004,30, http://www.econstor.eu/handle/10419/29883, accessed 7/12/14) 2.2 Federalism and decentralization as a growth-generating process Because of the regionally differentiating effects of growth processes, the question must be more precisely, how federalism actually influences economic development: Which impact on regional development processes should be ascribed to the fiscal federalism and in particular to fiscal competition? Usually economists evaluate competition positively as the main force creating a high variability and quality of product supply and the possibility that individuals can pursue their preferences. Tiebout’s metaphor (1956) of voting by feet thus implies that competition has positive effects that mainly develop in a dynamic economy. A decentralized experimentation of new governmental solutions for economic problems occurs such that new solutions are adapted by competing jurisdictions. Competition between jurisdictions thus becomes a discovery process which enhances the prospects of political innovation. Federalism and decentralization lead to a higher innovative capacity of the political system. Already in 1932, Louis Brandeis, judge at the U.S. Supreme Court, summarized this argument in the following way: lt is one of the happy incidents of the federal system that a single courageous State may, if its citizens choose, serve as a laboratory; and try novel social and economic experiments without risk to the rest of the country (quoted from Oates 1999, p. 1132). In this context Oates (1999) speaks of laboratory federalism’ and points out that the reform of welfare in the USA in 1996 followed exactly these considerations (Inman and Rubinfeld 1997). This competition may induce regions to create favorable conditions for the use of agglomeration advantages and to counter agglomeration disadvantages (Zimmermann 1990). In a slightly different fashion, Weingast (1995) points to the advantages of a ‘market preserving federalism’. Starting from a ,,fundamental political dilemma”, according to which “a government strong enough to protect property rights and enforce contracts is also strong enough to confiscate the wealth of its citizens” (p. 1), he considers competitive federalism as a chance to reduce the scope of the government and thus to maintain market efficiency. Because of the better migration chances of mobile investors, the governments of sub-central jurisdictions conduct investor-friendly policies and adopt solutions promoting market outcomes. Weingast continues an earlier analysis by Hayek (1939), according to which ,,planning in a federation cannot assume the forms which today are preeminently known under this term; ... In a federation economic policy will have to take the form of providing a rational permanent framework within which individual initiative will have the largest possible scope and will be made to work as beneficently as possible’ (p. 268). This competition appears as particularly favorable, whenever fiscal regimes do not provide a reliable protection against excessive taxation (Schnellenbach 2003). Similar conclusions can be drawn from the political economy analysis by Brennan and Buchanan (1980). Weingast does however not provide more precise considerations as to the growth effects of federalism. He only considers to the advantageous regulatory framework in England in the 18(11 century and in the US in the 1gth century as such systems of market- preserving federalism’. Rodden and Rose-Ackerman (1997) doubt that matters are so simple. They argue that decentralized government may follow the demand of local interest groups and possibly protect these by protectionist measures from external competion instead of serving the general interests of mobile investors. Whether federalism produces market-preserving or protectionist policies thus depends on further elements of the institutional framework. The higher innovative capacity of federations as compared to unitary states as possible explanations of differences in economic development is also contested in general. In a decentralized system, citizens use the performance of the governments of other jurisdictions as yardstick when considering their re-election (‘yardstick competition’ according to Salmon 1987, Besley and Case 1995, Feld, Josselin and Rocaboy 2003). A government is re-elected if it provides a bundle of services and tax prices that are at least not worse as compared to other jurisdictions. Governments thus have incentives to initially wait to see which policies of other jurisdictions turn out to be relatively successful, and then imitate these. Uncertain about their re-election prospects, governments have an incentive to free ride with respect to the policy innovations of other jurisdictions such that the absolute amount of policy innovations in a federation is reduced (Rose-Ackerman 1980). Strumpf (2002) emphasizes that this free-rider position strongly depends on homogeneity and on the number of jurisdictions. Heterogeneous jurisdictions less probably free ride, because it pays off to them to proceed with custom-made policy innovations. Kotsogiannis and Schwager (2001) argue that in a federation policy innovations offer the possibility to selfish politicians to obtain personal advantages while marketing them as the result of the uncertainty of policy innovations. Schnellenbach (2003a) takes the incentives of voters in a decentralized process of political innovations into account. As voters are normally rationally ignorant — due to the low incentives to be politically n formed — policy innovations are mainly possible in times of crises. The incentives of citizens to be informed about policy innovations are improved by high mobility and by elements of direct democracy in political decision-making processes. Thus, political rents of governments can be reduced by competition and politicians have incentives to innovate. Leadership Federalism Key to Heg US leadership is preserved by the balance of federalism Rivlin 92 (Alice, Brookings Institution, “Reviving the American Dream: The Economy, The States, and the Federal Government) The inexorably rising frequency and complexity of U.S. interaction with the rest of the world add to the stress on federal decisionmaking If the United States is to be an effective world leader, it cannot afford a cumbersome national government overlapping responsibilities between the federal government and the states, and confusion over which level is in charge of specific domestic government functions. processes and underline the need for making those processes simpler and more effective. As the world shrinks, international concerns will continue threatening to crowd out domestic policy on the federal agenda. Paradoxically, effective domestic policy is now more crucial than ever precisely because it is essential to U.S. leadership in world affairs. Unless we have a strong productive economy, a healthy, well-educated population, and a responsive democratic government, we will not be among the major shapers of the future of this interdependent world. however, If the American standard of living is falling behind that of other countries and its government structure is paralyzed, the United States will find its credibility in world councils eroding. International considerations provide additional rationale, if more were needed, for the United One answer to this paradox is to rediscover the strengths of our federal system, the division of labor between the states and the national government. Washington not States to have a strong effective domestic policy. only has too much to do, it has taken on domestic responsibilities that would be handled better by the states. Revitalizing the economy may depend on restoring a cleaner division of responsibility between the states and the national government. Heg Good Hegemony prevents all wars through cooperation and democracy Brooks et al 13 STEPHEN G., is Associate Professor of Government at Dartmouth College. G. JOHN Ikenberry, is Albert G. Milbank Professor of Politics and International Affairs at Princeton University and Global Eminence Scholar at Kyung Hee University in Seoul. WILLIAM C. Wohlforth, is Daniel Webster Professor of Government at Dartmouth College. This article is adapted from their essay "Don't Come Home, America: The Case Against Retrenchment," International Security, Winter 2012-13. “Lead Forward: In Defense of American Engagement” January/February 2013 http://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/138468/stephen-g-brooks-g-john-ikenberry-and-william-cwohlforth/lean-forward?page=show. Web. 05 July 2014. CS KEEPING THE PEACE of course, even if it is true that the costs of deep engagement fall far below what advocates of retrenchment claim, they would not be worth bearing unless they yielded greater benefits. In fact, they do. The most obvious benefit of the current strategy is that it reduces the risk of a dangerous conflict. The United States' security commitments deter states with aspirations to regional hegemony from contemplating expansion and dissuade U.S. partners from trying to solve security problems on their own in ways that would end up threatening other states. Skeptics discount this benefit by arguing that U.S. +security guarantees aren't necessary to prevent dangerous rivalries from erupting. They maintain that the high costs of territorial conquest and the many tools countries can use to signal their benign intentions are enough to prevent conflict. In other words, major powers could peacefully manage regional multipolarity without the American pacifier. But that outlook is too sanguine. If Washington got out of East Asia, Japan and South Korea would likely expand their military capabilities and go nuclear, which could provoke a destabilizing reaction from China. It's worth noting that during the Cold War, both South Korea and Taiwan tried to obtain nuclear weapons; the only thing that stopped them was the United States, which used its security commitments to restrain their nuclear temptations. Similarly, were the United States to leave the Middle East, the countries currently backed by Washington -- notably, Israel, Egypt, and Saudi Arabia -might act in ways that would intensify the region's security dilemmas. There would even be reason to worry about Europe. Although it's hard to imagine the return of great-power military competition in a post-American Europe, it's not difficult to foresee governments there refusing to pay the budgetary costs of higher military outlays and the political costs of increasing EU defense cooperation. The result might be a continent incapable of securing itself from threats on its periphery, unable to join foreign interventions on which U.S. leaders might want European help, and vulnerable to the influence of outside rising powers. Given how easily a U.S. withdrawal from key regions could lead to dangerous competition, advocates of retrenchment tend to put forth another argument: that such rivalries wouldn't actually hurt the United States. To be sure, few doubt that the United States could survive the return of conflict among powers in Asia or the Middle East -- but at what cost? Were states in one or both of these regions to start competing against one another, they would likely boost their military budgets, arm client states, and perhaps even start regional proxy wars, all of which should concern the United States, in part because its lead in military capabilities would narrow. Greater regional insecurity could also produce cascades of nuclear proliferation as powers such as Egypt, Saudi Arabia, Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan built nuclear forces of their own. Those countries' regional competitors might then also seek nuclear arsenals. Although nuclear deterrence can promote stability between two states with the kinds of nuclear forces that the Soviet Union and the United States possessed, things get shakier when there are multiple nuclear rivals with less robust arsenals. As the number of nuclear powers increases, the probability of illicit transfers, irrational decisions, accidents, and unforeseen crises goes up Answers To Fed key to international relations The federal government is no longer needed for effective international relations Spiro 2001 (Peter J., Professor of Law, Hofstra University. This essay is based on a panel presentation delivered at an American Enterprise Institute conference, "American Sovereignty: Issues for the New Administration and the New Decade" (April 3-4, 2001)., “Contextual Determinism and Foreign Relations Federalism”, Chicago Journal of International Law, 2 Chi. J. Int'l L. 363, Fall, 2001, Lexis Nexis) Take the late nineteenth century example of Louisiana's failure to afford adequate protection (as required by international law) to Italian nationals from mob violence. n18 Even assuming that Italy understood American federalism and the general autonomy afforded states in matters involving local law enforcement, it would have been difficult for Italy to have sought a remedy directly from Louisiana, in the absence of established communication channels and leverage points. Remedial entreaties, and the threat of retaliation, were more efficiently directed against Washington, and that efficiency was reflected in international law doctrines under which Italy could respond against the United States as a whole for the misdeeds of the component part. This context dictated the rule against state-level interference with foreign relations; the externalities of state action were too great to tolerate in a fragile international environment. But globalization shifts the balance. International actors, for the most part, do now understand the internal workings of other nations. They have regular contact with subnational authorities, and, perhaps most importantly, they have gained leverage over subnational entities. In the face of globalization, international economic [*368] competitiveness is critical to local economic prosperity. The threat of lost foreign investment or lost global sales offers the possibility of effective direct remedial action against subnational jurisdictions. If these direct remedial channels become entrenched, national-level responsibility may become redundant or obsolete. In that context, the subnational activity no longer poses a risk of interfering with national policy, and there is no need to depart from the federalism construct that governs other areas of regulation. Aff Harmonizes Policy Harmonization of federal and state law fails without a framework leads to vague laws that courts have to interpret- doesn’t ensure an adequate balance of power Rachael E. Salcido in 2008 Associate Professor of Law, University of the Pacific, McGeorge School of Law, Offshore Federalism and Ocean Industrialization, Tulane Law Review 82 Tul. L. Rev. 1355 As the foregoing cases illustrate, physical boundaries alone are not enough to prevent the extension of federal management imperatives to state lands under the Property and Supremacy Clauses of the United States Constitution. As we increase different uses of offshore areas, the potential for a similar set of conflicts grows. Furthermore, conservation and restoration activities now play a greater role in the mix of ocean uses because of the decline in commercial fisheries and other valuable marine resources (such as coral reefs and [*1410] kelp beds). n353 Thus, states will increasingly have to contend with the potential for federal prerogatives that cross the three-mile border. And while humans do have the capacity to recognize and abide by borders, the ones we have constructed offshore are merely a legal fiction: they are not consistent with ecosystem management, nor do they have any binding power over wildlife. n354 Secondly, as shown in Ventura County and Granite Rock, regulated industries frequently push for consolidated permitting. n355 Private developers often balk at multiple layers of regulation due to added cost, delay and unpredictability. n356 Nonetheless, while preemption is always theoretically available, Congress may choose instead to encourage harmonization of federal and state efforts. This requires a legal framework that clearly defines the relative roles and responsibilities of each level of government. Such a framework, however, is frequently lacking. As the cases on cooperation and coordination mandates illustrate, vague mandates often leave courts with little room to reinforce the political compromise reached in legislation promoting "cooperative" approaches between the states and the federal government. n357 These mandates may be politically difficult to achieve within legislation, as with section 302(b) of the FLPMA. The more unified Congress can be in encouraging a cooperative approach and including express statements thereof in statutory language, the more appropriate it will be to turn to the judicial branch for enforcement of these mandates. AFF Uniqueness States don’t have control Court Rulings Supreme Court ruling on Arizona immigration law single biggest blow to American federalism in history Chicago Tribune, June 28 [2012, Federalism Destroyed; http://articles.chicagotribune.com/201206-28/news/chi-120628shinn_briefs_1_federalism-arizona-immigration-law-individual-mandate] So the Supreme Court has upheld the individual mandate after striking down most of the Arizona immigration law. This has truly been an historical week. Never before has more power been taken from the states and the people and transferred to Washington in a single week. On Monday the court said that states cannot legislate in areas where the federal government legislates, and given how the federal government legislates on just about every issue, this means the states can legislate in very few areas indeed. On Thursday the court ruled that the federal government can compel individuals to engage in commerce, whether they want to or not, and penalize them if they do not purchase whatever the government says they must. In a single week, federalism, the 10th Amendment and any ability of an individual to control his or her own money were destroyed. "Conservative" court? Ha! Supreme court ruling on health care effectively destroyed federalism – Turley, June 30 2012, Jonathan Turley, the Shapiro Professor of Public Interest Law at George Washington University, is a member of USA TODAY's Board of Contributors. http://www.guampdn.com/article/20120630/OPINION02/206300321/Federalism-biggest-loserdecision?odyssey=nav|head] The Supreme Court's blockbuster health care ruling caused a spasm of celebration and recrimination around the country Thursday as the Affordable Care Act was upheld on a 5-4 vote. In reality, the case was never really about health care but federalism -- the relative authority of the federal government vs. the state. I support national health care, but I oppose the individual mandate as the wrong means to a worthy end. Indeed, for federalism advocates, the ruling reads like a scene out of Julius Caesar-- a principal killed by the unseen hand of a long-trusted friend. Brutus, in this legal tragedy, was played by Chief Justice John Roberts. The opinion starts out well. Roberts defends federalism by ruling that the administration exceeded its authority under the commerce clause. Just as many readers were exalting in the affirmation of federalism, however, Roberts struck a deadly blow by upholding the individual mandate provision as an exercise of tax authority. Federalism rose and fell so fast it didn't have time to utter, "Et tu, Roberts?" Roberts joined the four liberal justices in upholding the law. He clearly believed that the law was constitutional, and he refused to yield to the overwhelming public pressure. Indeed, he must have known that people would view this as a betrayal of states' rights, but he stuck with his honest view of the Constitution. None of that will diminish the sense of betrayal. After all, Brutus acted for the best reasons, too. The health care case was viewed as the final stand for federalism. If the top court could make a federal issue out of a young person in Chicago not buying health insurance, it was hard to imagine any act or omission that would not trigger federal authority. Roberts agreed that this was beyond the pale of federalism: "Allowing Congress to justify federal regulation by pointing to the effect of inaction on commerce would bring countless decisions an individual could potentially make within the scope of federal regulation, and -- under the government's theory -- empower Congress to make those decisions for him." But no sooner had Roberts proclaimed his love for federalism than he effectively killed it. Roberts held that the individual mandate still fell squarely within the taxing authority of Congress. If so, all those "broccoli" questions asked by Roberts and other justices simply move over to the tax side. If Congress can "tax" people for not having health insurance, how about taxes on people who don't have cellphones (as Roberts asked)? Just as there was no clear limiting principle in the commerce clause debate, there is a lack of such a principle in the tax debate. Instead, Roberts simply says the individual mandate is supported by a "functional approach" that has long allowed federal taxes to "seek to influence conduct" by citizens. Roberts did rule that states could not be threatened with the loss of Medicaid funds if they didn't want to be part of the program. That was an unexpected protection for the states facing threats from Congress. But this still leaves citizens of every state subject to the penalties of the federal government for failing to get insurance. Moreover, in mandating the right to opt out, Roberts rewrote the law, precisely what most justices didn't want to do. Before the law was enacted, Congress refused to add an opt-out provision. After the justices complained in oral arguments that they did not understand the massive law, this judicial amendment could increase health care costs and undermine the uniform national character of the program. Given such problems, President Obama might have been better off losing before the court than accepting this victory from the hands of Roberts. In the end, the court's decision could be viewed as a success only to the extent that a crash landing is still considered a landing. It is hard to see who will be the ultimate winner from this decision. But the biggest loser is federalism. Roberts lifted it up only to make it an exquisite corpse. In that sense, the decision reads like the funeral speech of another character in Julius Caesar. To paraphrase Mark Anthony, Roberts came to bury federalism, not to praise it. Federal Gov. Overrides states now The federal government can override a state’s objection to ocean policy and require it to be responsible for updates to the infrastructure. Dhanju and Firestone 2009 (Amardeep and Jeremy, College of Marine and Earth Studies, Center for Carbon-free Power Integration, University of Delaware, “Access System Framework for Regulating Offshore Wind Power in State Waters”, Coastal Management. Sep2009, Vol. 37 Issue 5, p441-478. 38p., Business Source Premier, Date Accessed: 11 July 2014) Because the state resource agency will likely be the lead government agency and because USACE does not have expertise in resource management, USACE may rely in large part on the MMS programmatic EIS for alternative energy projects in federal waters and any state environmental evaluation of the offshore wind power proposal. A further complicating issue would arise if a project straddled state and federal waters. Given the close proximity of the state–federal boundary line to the coast, such an eventuality is conceivable. In that case, the state would be the lead agency for the project in state waters while MMS would be the lead agency in federal waters. Concerns of various federal agencies such as the Federal Aviation Administration will also need to be addressed. For a full list of pertinent regulations, their jurisdiction, and potential applicability refer Firestone et al. (2004). The federal Coastal Zone Management Act (CZMA) of 1972 adds another regulatory layer. It encourages coastal states to prepare and gain federal agency approval of state coastal zone management plans. Most importantly for present purposes, it allows a coastal state with an approved coastal program plan to review for consistency with that state’s coastal zone management plan, federal projects, and applications for federal permits and licenses that “affect any land or water use or natural resource of the state coastal zone, regardless of location or activity”9 (NOAA, 2009, 21). The review under the provisions of federal consistency is a comprehensive review of an activity’s effect on the coastal zone, including impacts to environmental quality, navigation, fish Upon completion of the review, a coastal state can choose to concur, issue a concurrence that places conditions on the license or permit should one be issued, or file an objection. If a coastal state decides not to concur in the issuance of a federal permit or license, the permit or license cannot be issued without a decision by the U.S. Secretary of Commerce to override the state position—a and wildlife, commerce, and tourism. decision that is rarely made and that in any event only can be made on very narrow grounds. The key here, however, is that the consistency review can only be based on enforceable policies included in the state’s National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration (NOAA)- approved coastal zone management plan. These enforceable policies need to be based on existing state regulations and cannot go beyond (be stricter) As federal consistency review limits a coastal state’s authority over a proposed project to speak to the arguable effects of an activity, a state cannot categorically prohibit or allow a particular use, such as offshore wind. As all enforceable policies are rooted in existing laws, the state coastal program is responsible for including updates and additions to existing laws in relevant Routine Program Changes submitted to than state law. NOAA. Oil and Natural Gas States don’t have jurisdiction over the outer continental shelf SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES decision on MARYLAND ET AL. v. LOUISIANA in 1981 (451 U.S. 725; 101 S. Ct. 2114; 68 L. Ed. 2d 576; 1981 U.S. LEXIS 27; 49 U.S.L.W. 4562; 40 P.U.R.4th 1; 69 Oil & Gas Rep. 553, January 19, 1981, Argued, May 26, 1981, Decided DECISION: Louisiana's "first use" tax imposed on certain uses of natural gas brought into state, principally from outer continental shelf, held violative of supremacy clause and commerce clause of United States Constitution. SUMMARY: Eight states filed a motion for leave to file a complaint under the United States Supreme Court's original jurisdiction pursuant to Article III, Section 2 of the United States Constitution, seeking a declaratory judgment that Louisiana's "first use" tax imposed on certain uses of natural gas brought into the state, principally from the outer continental shelf, was unconstitutional under, among other things, the United States Constitution's commerce clause (Art I, 8, cl 3) and supremacy clause (Art VI, cl 2), and sought injunctive relief against Louisiana or its agents collecting the tax with respect to any gas in interstate commerce as well as the refund of taxes already collected. The Supreme Court granted the motion for leave to file (61 L Ed 2d 307), and subsequently appointed a Special Master to facilitate handling of the suit (63 L Ed 2d 597). The Special Master issued two reports, the first report recommending that the Supreme Court approve the motions of New Jersey, the United States, the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, and several pipeline companies to intervene as plaintiffs, and the second report recommending that (1) the Supreme Court deny Louisiana's motion to dismiss and reject the submissions that the plaintiff states had no standing to bring the action and that the case was not an appropriate one for the exercise of the Supreme Court's original jurisdiction, and (2) the plaintiff states' motion for judgment on the pleadings on the grounds that the tax was unconstitutional on its face be denied and that further evidentiary hearings be conducted, even though the statute was constitutionally suspect in certain respects. On exceptions to the reports of the Special Master, the United States Supreme Court overruled exceptions and adopted the recommendations contained in the first report, rejected exceptions to the second report's recommendation that the motion to dismiss be denied, and sustained exceptions to the recommendation that judgment on the pleadings be denied pending further evidentiary hearing. In an opinion by White, J., joined by Burger, Ch. J., and Brennan, Stewart, Marshall, Blackmun, and Stevens, JJ., it was held that (1) the plaintiff states, as substantial consumers of natural gas, had standing to bring suit against Louisiana since their gas costs had increased as a direct result of the imposition of the first use tax so that they were directly affected in a substantial and real way so as to justify the exercise of the Supreme Court's original jurisdiction, and jurisdiction was supported by the states' interest as parens patriae in protecting their citizens from substantial economic injury presented by imposition of the tax, since individual consumers could not be expected to litigate the validity of the tax and were foreclosed from suing for a refund in the state's courts, (2) the action was an appropriate case for the exercise of the Supreme Court's exclusive jurisdiction under 28 USCS 1251(a), even though there were pending state court lawsuits raising the identical constitutional challenges to the validity of the tax, since neither the plaintiff states nor the United States was a named party in any of the state actions nor had they sought leave to intervene and the tax implicated serious and important concerns of federalism fully in accord with the purposes and reach of the Supreme Court's original jurisdiction and the tax affected the United States' interest in the administration of the outer continental shelf thus making the case an appropriate one for the exercise of the Supreme Court's original jurisdiction under 28 USCS 1251(b)(2) permitting suits by the United States against a state, (3) a provision of Louisiana's tax declaring that the tax be deemed a cost associated with uses made by the owner in preparation of marketing of the gas and prohibiting allocation of the costs to any party except the ultimate consumer violated the supremacy clause by interfering with the authority of the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, under the Natural Gas Act (15 USCS 717a et seq.), as amended by the Gas Policy Act of 1978 (15 USCS 3301 et seq.), to regulate the determination of the proper allocation of costs associated with the sale of natural gas to consumers, and (4) Louisiana's first use tax violated the commerce clause by discriminating against interstate commerce in favor of local interests as a necessary result of various tax credits and exclusions in the statute and other state statutes, whereby state consumers of outer continental shelf gas were substantially protected against the impact of the tax and had the benefit of untaxed outer continental shelf gas which could be cheaper than locally produced gas, while outer continental shelf gas moving out of the state was burdened by the tax, the tax not being justified as a compensatory tax, compensating for the effect of the state's severance tax on local production of natural gas, the state having no sovereign interest in being compensated for the severance of resources from federally-owned outer continental shelf land. States Don’t Challeng Fed States don’t use their power to veto federal ocean projects in the status quo Russell 2004 (Robert H., J.D., Harvard Law School. Mr. Russell teaches environmental law in the graduate program at Tufts University, and has taught energy regulation, environmental law and policy, and property law at other universities and law schools in the Boston area. He also consults with nonprofit organizations and government agencies on environmental matters., “COASTAL WIND ENERGY GENERATION: CONFLICT AND CAPACITIE: SYMPOSIUM ARTICLE: Neither Out Far Nor in Deep: The Prospects for Utility-Scale Wind Power in the Coastal Zone”, 2004 Boston College Law School, Boston College Environmental Affairs Law Review, Lexis Nexis) But even if most agree that the consistency doctrine is more than a hobgoblin, is it in fact a barrier to projects like an offshore wind farm? No formal analysis has addressed this question. n147 Yet, the way in which the process plays out suggests that it might not be a substantial barrier. State consistency objections to federal license and permit applications are reviewed by the Secretary of Commerce. n148 The Secretary may override an objection if the proposal is found to be consistent with the objectives of the CZMA, or if it is otherwise essential to national security. n149 In the first instance, the Secretary must base a consistency finding on each of three criteria, one of which also requires the presence of a strong national interest. n150 As the discussion [*249] below suggests, if review by the Secretary has had any impact at all, it has helped to stimulate oil and gas exploration on the Outer Continental Shelf. n151 Whether it also might be of assistance to offshore wind power projects is questionable, given long-standing federal energy policy. Indeed, initial data suggest that the consistency doctrine has had minimal impact. The simple truth is that most states go along with most federal licensing decisions almost all of the time. The federal Office of Ocean and Coastal Resource Management estimates that states have consented to approximately ninety-five percent of all reviewable federal actions. n152 Nonetheless, of the forty cases decided on petition to the Secretary of Commerce since the early 1980s, more than a third have involved energy exploration. n153 The Secretary upheld the state's objection in half of them. n154 Although one cannot confidently declare this a trend, it underscores a tendency that may be of importance to near-shore wind generation: states scrutinize big projects closely. n155 Even though such proposals have been relatively infrequent, such consistently searching scrutiny, over time, may create a powerful preference for the status quo. n156 Policy is Inclusive Federalism is no longer exclusion of the states, policies implemented now promote inclusion of all levels Hamilton ’03 (Lee, Director of the Center on Congress at Indiana University. He was a member of the U.S. House of Representatives for 34 years, Why Federalism Works, the Center on Congress at Indiana University, http://congress.indiana.edu/why-federalism-works, accessed: 7/10/14 GA) Early in my congressional career, I discovered a simple truth about our governmental system: it's confusing. Like most new members of Congress, I'd taken office with visions of wrestling with the future of our Republic. So it came as a small shock to learn that much of what my constituents wanted from me was help in navigating the federal, state and local bureaucracies. If you think back to your seventh-grade civics class, you'll remember learning about a system that resembles a layer cake, with local government at the bottom, the states in the middle, and the federal government at the top, all clearly delineated. That's still how most of us think of "federalism," or the division of responsibilities among different levels of government. But we're hopelessly out of date. If anything, the American political system is like a marble cake, with a blend of elected and appointed officials from all levels of government sharing policy and program duties. Think about transportation, for instance. It's difficult enough to figure out which agency at which level of government maintains a particular stretch of roadway. But it can be next to impossible to untangle how a given decision got made about, say, widening a road. The funding was provided by Congress, as were certain guidelines on how the money could be spent, but the specifics were up to a welter of state, county and local elected officials and highway engineers. You can find the same assortment of responsibilities in everything from the administration of welfare benefits to law enforcement to cleaning up toxic waste. There's a reason for this. As with many of the questions we sort through as a nation, the basic framework for dividing governmental responsibilities was set by the Constitution. Though the Founders were quite specific on some matters– states, for instance, don't have the power to declare war or coin money– they deliberately left much room for flexibility. Just as they believed that dividing power among the various branches of the federal government would make it more responsive, so would dividing power among the different levels. "[It]is not by the consolidation, or concentration of powers, but by their distribution, that good government is effected," Thomas Jefferson wrote in his Autobiography. "Were not this great country already divided into states, that division must be made, that each might do for itself what concerns itself directly, and what it can so much better do than a distant authority... Were we directed from Washington when to sow, and when to reap, we should soon want bread." And so, over the decades, each level of government has seen its share of responsibilities ebb and flow with the demands of the era. The New Deal, for instance, brought new power to Washington, with its myriad of federal agencies helping American individuals and communities cope with the aftermath of the Depression; so, too, did the civil rights movement, which relied on federal authority to bring about change in the states. On the other hand, over the last two decades a mix of federal cutbacks, legislative changes, and Supreme Court decisions have returned authority to the states and even local communities. In some cases, this has been driven by the belief that problems should be resolved closer to where people actually live, rather than by federal power. In other cases, it has been driven by practicality, as new approaches to problems bubble up from the states– as was the case with welfare reform. We live in an era that is more difficult to categorize. On the one hand, the federal government is responding to the threat of terrorism by expanding and consolidating its power, especially for its various law enforcement and national security agencies. At the same time, however, the attorneys general in the various states have responded to a vacuum at the federal level by taking on responsibility for consumer enforcement in everything from policing Wall Street to tackling antitrust cases, as when they sued drug makers for trying to block lower-cost generic competitors. The distribution of power is constantly shifting, and sometimes, as at the moment, it moves in different directions simultaneously. For an ordinary citizen trying to get answers to a specific problem, this can be confusing; it's why, when I was in Congress, my staff and I spent so much time directing constituents to the office and the level of government that could best help them. It can also lead to conflict within the system, as when states sue a federal agency they believe has failed to live up to its responsibilities. But in the end, the flexibility created by our Constitution allows for a pragmatic response to the evolving challenges we face as a nation. It creates the chance for policymakers to gauge whether problems are best confronted in town halls or state capitals or in Washington– or in some combination of all of them– and then to work together to assign each level of government its appropriate role. That these roles change over time is a sign not of weakness, but of the system's enduring strength. Alt Causes Economic Decline Economic decline harms federalism Tubbesing, 2k2 (Carl, NCSL's deputy executive director, State Legislatures, February 1, lexis) When the economy slows, he argues, the federal government has to step in to get it back on track. The federal government has many tools to do this. It can lower interest rates; it can cut taxes; and it can spend money. The states are more constrained in what they can do to help. In fact, the requirements that states have balanced budgets often forces them into policy decisions that actually exacerbate the economic downturn. They may have to raise taxes when cutting them could help the economy. They may have to cut funding just when more spending might create jobs and encourage economic activity. Congressional and administration proposals to stimulate the economy surfaced immediately after the terrorist attacks. Debate, posturing and negotiations over the proposals dragged well into December and eventually broke down. The conflict over economic stimulus revealed classic, philosophical fissures between Republicans and Democrats. But the debate, less conspicuously perhaps, also demonstrated tensions in the federal system. "State legislators understood that some of the recovery proposals were better for the states than others," notes Saland. "Some, in fact, would actually be harmful. Good intentions at the national level do not necessarily translate into benefits for the states." One major proposal that would have been included in a final package would have done considerable harm to the states. Negotiators rejected several proposals that state officials had advanced. The economic stimulus proposal most damaging for states was an accelerated depreciation schedule for business investments. Supported by both Republicans and Democrats in Congress and the administration, this proposal would actually have caused revenue losses for state governments as high as $ 15 billion over the next three years-at a time when their budgets are already reeling from the recession. The reason? Most states tie their business depreciation to the federal schedule. A change in the federal structure means a change in state schedules. Most of the proposals that would have been sensitive to state concerns were not included in 11th hour negotiations. State officials liked those that freed them of financial obligations, made tax changes without affecting states or sent new federal money in their direction. NCSL, for example, supported a plan offered by New Mexico Senator Pete Domenici that would have created a month-long federal payroll tax holiday. For a month, employees and employers would stop making their FICA (Social Security) contributions. Employers-including state governments-would save money and employees would have bigger paychecks. Both outcomes would generate economic activity. Negotiators flirted with the Domenici proposal, but eventually dropped it. The National Governors Association made changes in Medicaid matching rates its biggest economic stimulus priority. The governors' organization likened reductions in state Medicaid spending to revenue sharing. The Bush administration and congressional negotiators rejected this plan as cumbersome, expensive and politically unfeasible. NCSL leaders argued for tax rebates for individuals instead of permanent changes to the income tax code. Negotiators, instead, opted for a reduction in one of the middle income tax brackets-a change that would substantially reduce revenues in states that link their income tax system to the federal one. Panelist No.2, our FDR look-alike, claims he has won the argument-that is that the center of federalism gravity moves toward the national government when the economy is weak. "What would the states have gotten out of that stimulus package?" he wonders. "Not much. If anything, their budgets would have been in worse shape because of the changes in the federal tax code." He's willing, though, to give Ben Franklin a chance. No Link Aquaculture NOAA is best suited to oversee aquaculture—has greatest responsibility for sustainable use NOAA No Date (National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration, “NOAA'S AQUACULTURE POLICY”, http://www.nmfs.noaa.gov/sfa/sfweb/aqua_policy.htm” Worldwide fisheries production will be inadequate to meet the needs of the world's population, without supplementation through aquaculture. Constituent and Congressional support for aquaculture dictates that the National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration (NOAA) bring together its diverse programs to develop a comprehensive aquaculture policy and strategy to provide a context for agency activities for the next ten to twenty years. The impetus for the development of aquaculture extends beyond food production. NOAA involvement in aquaculture can help to foster sustainable economic development and environmentally friendly technologies, create new employment opportunities, reduce the trade deficit in fish products, reduce fishing pressure on living marine resources, and rebuild depleted stocks. The 1980 Memorandum of Understanding (MOU) between the Departments of Agriculture (USDA), Commerce (DOC) and Interior (DOI), defined aquaculture as "the propagation and rearing of aquatic species in controlled or selected environments." Pursuant to this MOU, DOC, through NOAA's National Marine Fisheries Service (NMFS), and the National Sea Grant College Program, carried out aquaculture research and development on marine, estuarine, and anadromous species. Work on anadromous species has been coordinated with DOI and USDA (Forest Service). The National Sea Grant College Program has conducted research, education, training and advisory services in aquaculture; its advisory services programs have been carried out in collaboration with USDA's Extension Service. Subsequent to the establishment of this MOU, the Fisheries Finance Program, administered by NMFS, and the Coastal Zone Management Act (CZMA), administered by NOAA's National Ocean Service (NOS), were amended to include comprehensive planning, conservation and management of aquaculture facilities within the coastal zone. Furthermore, the National Aquaculture Development Act of 1980, amended in 1985, established a coordinating group, the Joint Subcommittee on Aquaculture (JSA), chaired by USDA. The JSA has been responsible for developing the National Aquaculture Development Plan, which identifies the relative roles of USDA, DOI and DOC, and establishes a strategy for the development of an aquaculture industry in the United States. NOAA, the Federal Oceans agency, has a strong statutory basis for the promotion and regulation of marine aquaculture. A listing of the legislative authorities is attached (Attachment 1). NOAA, having the greatest responsibility for the sustainable use and conservation of marine resources and the environment, is best suited to oversee aquaculture activities that affect marine ecosystems and occur in public waters. NOAA has a variety of established responsibilities for marine, estuarine, and anadromous species aquaculture; including research, development, and outreach, for stock enhancement and private sector development, as well as the adoption of appropriate environmental safeguards and technology. NOAA has jurisdiction over aquaculture except when limited by written agreement with the state NOAA 11 ((National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration, “MARINE AQUACULTURE POLICY”, http://www.nmfs.noaa.gov/aquaculture/docs/policy/noaa_aquaculture_policy_2011.pdf) NOAA may engage in regulatory actions in the Exclusive Economic Zone under the authority of the MagnusonStevens Fishery Conservation and Management Act (Magnuson-Stevens Act) through Fishery Management Plans for species in need of conservation and management. NOAA may also engage in regulatory action under National Marine Sanctuaries Act (NMSA) authority with respect to aquaculture activities within or potentially affecting Sanctuaries. NOAA has a direct regulatory role for aquaculture within the sanctuaries, in both state and federal waters, except in state waters when limited by formal written agreement with the Governor of that state. NOAA also engages in consultations with other federal permitting agencies under the authority of the Endangered Species Act, Marine Mammal Protection Act, the Essential Fish Habitat provisions of the Magnuson-Stevens Fishery Conservation and Management Act, the National Environmental Policy Act, and other statutes. Through the Coastal Zone Management Act, NOAA also reviews and approves state coastal management programs, which identify permissible uses in the coastal zone, and oversees federal consistency with these programs.5 Energy Generic State ocean energy projects currently require federal approval Vartabedian 2014 (Ralph, National correspondent for the latimes covering energy, space, bullet trains and auto safety issues, “Offshore wind farm is planned; Five huge turbines off Oregon's coast get the initial OK to test the emerging technology.”, Los Angeles Times, February 6, 2014 Thursday, Lexis Nexis) A Seattle energy company received initial regulatory approval Wednesday to build five massive wind turbines floating 16 miles off the Oregon coast. The pilot project off Coos Bay would be the first offshore wind facility on the West Coast. It also would be the biggest demonstration of technology that places floating turbines on platforms in deep water, according to federal officials and executives at Principle Power, the developer. The turbines would be as tall as a 60-story building, vastly larger than typical turbines on landbased wind farms, and able to tap strong winds that blow consistently off southern Oregon, said Kevin Banister, Principle's vice president for business and government affairs. Each turbine, generating 6,000 kilowatts of power, would be supported on three floating platforms moored by cables anchored to the sea floor, about 1,400 feet below the surface. The electricity would be transmitted to shore via underwater cable. The Interior Department's Bureau of Ocean Energy Management, Regulation and Enforcement gave approval for the company to submit a formal plan for the 30-megawatt project. Principle Power would lease 15 square miles of ocean away from shipping lanes and barely visible from the coast. Interior Secretary Sally Jewell and Democratic Gov. John Kitzhaber announced the project Wednesday in Oregon, invoking the Obama administration's vision for clean energy and reducing carbon pollution. Banister said the venture would cost about $200 million and was expected to be operational by 2017. It has received $4 million in Energy Department funding as an advanced demonstration project. Principle hopes for a power purchase agreement with Oregon utilities. Approval for the lease followed a process to ensure that other parties had no competitive interest in the part of the ocean that Principle would use. The company still must go through the federal regulatory approval process under the National Environmental Protection Act, said Doug Boren, the bureau's West Coast renewable energy manager. Ocean Management/Monitoring NOAA, which is part of the United States Department of Commerce, has full jurisdiction over ocean monitoring NOAA No Date (National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration, “Monitoring Oceans and Coasts”, http://oceanservice.noaa.gov/observations/monitoring/) Our planet is constantly changing in ways that impact every facet of our society. To keep coastal communities, economies, and ecosystems healthy requires keeping track of ocean and coastal areas—monitoring and assessing how these areas are changing. From tracking contaminants in the water, assessing environmental change, monitoring sea-level rise, or surveying the coastline and coastal sea floor, NOS physical, chemical, and biological observations help coastal communities make the best decisions for them and for the environment. Scientists all over the globe are monitoring how our planet is changing. They use tools, such as satellites, thermometers, and tide gauges, to collect observations. However, not all collected observations are in the same format, meaning they cannot be easily used together. Also, there are gaps in the information that is collected. Enter the Integrated Ocean Observing System, or IOOS®. Led by NOAA, IOOS brings together federal and non-federal people and technology, building a network to fill observing gaps. IOOS is also establishing standards for data collection, so that data can be used together and be more accessible to users. All of this means more information, which means a more comprehensive understanding of our planet OTEC OTEC projects fall under NOAA or Department of Energy jurisdiction NOAA 2011 (National Oceanic and Atmospheric Association, http://coastalmanagement.noaa.gov/otec/oteca.html, accessed 7/11/14) Ocean Thermal Energy Act of 1980 In 1980, the Ocean Thermal Energy Conversion Act (OTECA) granted the authority for licensing OTEC facilities located within the territorial sea of the United States to the Administrator of the National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration (NOAA). Under the Ocean Thermal Energy Conversion Research, Development, and Demonstration Act the U.S. Department of Energy may authorize demonstration projects which are exempt from the NOAA licensing requirements after consulting with NOAA. Internal Link Federalism Flexible American Federalism is flexible—it is no longer a constitutional doctrine Morgan 6(Denise C., Professor at New York Law School , New York Law School Law Review, "A Tale of (At Least) Two Federalisms,") The first four pieces in this volume, which were presented at the Federal Courts section panel at the 2005 AALS convention, ask some version of the Federal Courts scholar's distressed query. My colleague, Professor Edward A. Purcell, Jr., opens the volume by putting that question into a broader historical and theoretical context. His articleasks: Whether, and to what extent, it is possible for "federalism" to serve as a meaningful and independent norm in the nation's constitutional enterprise. In other words, are the provisions of the Constitution that establish the federal structure, sufficiently clear, specific, and complete to direct those who construe them to "correct" decisions or, at least, to eliminate wide ranges of discretion in such decision making?n29 Can an examination of history set us on the proper path prescribed by the Constitution, or, when it comes to American federalism, are we condemned to muddle through, always wondering, "What on earth is going on?"Professor Purcell's interrogation provides some lessons and yields some insights into the "true" nature of American federalism, but more fundamentally, it "reveals disagreement, uncertainty, conflict, and change."n30 Indeed, he contends that federalism has been, remains, and always will be a contested issue, in part because "some of our most basic conceptions and assumptions about the federal system have changed substantially over the years."n31 In sharp contrast to the work of Federal Courts scholars who propound[*624]clear cut prescriptive theories of federalism,n32 Professor Purcell concludes that "the idea of 'constitutional federalism' - that is, federalism as a directive constitutional norm - [is] deeply problematic."n33 Each of the sections of Professor Purcell's article examines one of the moving parts of American federalism: our ideas about the proper role of the Supreme Court in the federal system; our ideas about the values of federalism; our understanding of the nature of federalism as a structure of government; and our ideas about the nature and meaning of the Constitution itself. He finds that even the founding generations had at least five conflicting ideas about the appropriate role of the Supreme Court and judicial review. Moreover, "although the five views were distinct, they were also frequently intermixed in the minds of the founders."n34 Professor Purcell traces those different understandings of the Court's proper function from the ante-bellum period to the modern era and attributes our failure to settle on one dominant conception to the fact that "neither the Constitution nor any other authoritative source unequivocally defined such a system or such a role."n35 Professor Purcell contends that discussions of the values of federalism - "usually described as including protecting liberty, encouraging diversity and innovation, ensuring political accountability, promoting democratic participation, and protecting local values and interests" - are similarly unhelpful in identifying clear lines between state and federal authority.n36 Indeed, he asserts [*625] that those conversations, which began to proliferate in the late twentieth century, were driven by an anxious sense that many"traditional" lines ostensibly separating national and state power were no longer sound, easily detectable, or even operationally plausible. Some kind of functional analysis seemed necessary to justify the existence of the states as independent governing units, to assure Americans that those state governments actually produced public benefits, and to identify useful and intelligible lines that could be drawn between federal and state authority. Federalism is resilient and flexible Greston 7 (Larry, San Jose St-Politics, American Federalism: A concise introduction, p. 13-4) To be sure, over the past two hundred twenty years, the powers of some institutions have been clarified, while the resources of others have evolved considerably. Even more remarkable, some power relationships have shifted over time, revealing a profound flexibility within the American government framework. More times than not, such shifts in power have not occurred with unanimity. In fact, great debates over the appropriate assignments of government functions continue to this day. Nevertheless, the basic elements of American federalism remain in place, even if the applications are different. And other than the Civil War nearly one hundred and fifty years ago, the political “operating system” of the nation has functioned without serious bloodshed. Along federalism has demonstrated a great sense of continuity. with resilient adaptability, American Not Zero Sum Federalism is not zero-sum Kasprzyk 10 (Karissa, Sr. Thesis-Stetson U., http://www2.stetson.edu/library/seniorprojects_2010004.pdf) Since 1965, the U.S. Congress has taken a more active role in using the “elastic clause” to legislate in areas traditionally regulated by the states (Zimmerman 1992). This Congressional preemption of state power has expanded the role of the national government in many policy areas and resulted in the expectation that Congress will legislate in any areas of national significance with at least minimum standards and rules. This trend would seemingly take away many of the powers given to the states as they defer to national rules, but scholars have noted that, due to the cooperative nature of U.S. federalism, the power relations are not “zero-sum” (Zimmerman 2005). Most Congressional preemption of power occurs when rules and regulations are established for the states to carry out in their own manner, because excessive command and control to establish uniform state actions has historically been ineffective. This cooperative federalism creates overlapping structures and regulations that may seem inefficient, but actually ensure that there are no policy gaps (Buzbee 2006). Therefore, in the past few decades, states have taken a larger role in many of these policy areas, such as environmental or banking regulations, which has resulted in more capable and active state governments even while acting. Impact Ocean Federalist division of power over the oceans creates conflict between the states and federal government that prevents effective management of ocean resources Rachael E. Salcido in 2008 Associate Professor of Law, University of the Pacific, McGeorge School of Law, Offshore Federalism and Ocean Industrialization, Tulane Law Review 82 Tul. L. Rev. 1355 Ocean and coastal resources of the United States are managed through a proliferation of laws for living and nonliving resources. n69 [*1369] The first generation of environmental laws was designed to address one issue at a time, such as water quality, air quality, or wildlife preservation. n70 Therefore, among the laws governing ocean and coastal resources, different provisions address water pollution, n71 construction of fixed objects, n72 extraction of minerals, n73 fisheries management, n74 marine mammal protection, n75 and so forth. Different agencies have responsibilities for implementing these laws, and the lead regulatory responsibilities may be vested at the federal, state, or local government level, or some combination thereof. n76 This fragmentation of laws has been blamed for the "regulatory failure" that is being addressed by experimenting with laws that integrate decision making over a variety of human actions that impact the environment. n77 Professor Bradley C. Karkkainen has explained this as a shift from "rules-to-governance." n78 [*1370] One of the most significant challenges in making the shift from rules-to-governance effective to overcome past regulatory failures is synchronizing regulatory efforts across political borders. n79 As further explained earlier in Part II, the dividing line between state and federal jurisdiction of the oceans exists three miles from shore. n80 Resource management across this three-mile state-federal border is the root of significant tension between coastal states and the federal government. n81 The resulting conflict presents two challenges: first, it impedes the efficient review of specific development proposals, and second, it frustrates efforts to enhance the overall quality and effectiveness of ocean management. And beyond specific project or resource conflicts, the three-mile border presents an additional challenge to transitioning to much-needed comprehensive marine ecosystem management, where all parts of the environment are considered synergistically in management decisions. n82 Econ A strong federal government works better for the economy- Canada proves COYNE 2013 (ANDREW, “An integrated national economy calls for national oversight”, The Gazette (Montreal), The Gazette, SECTION: EDITORIAL / OP-ED; Andrew Coyne; Pg. A21, March 7, 2013 Thursday, Lexis Nexis) My colleague John Ivison of the National Post had something of a scoop this week. The coming federal budget, it appears, will see Ottawa reclaim the $2.5 billion it now gives the provinces for job training, and deliver the program itself. This is the same money the Harper government had earlier made a great show of handing over to the provinces, though the bulk of it comes out of the federal employment insurance envelope, on the ground that provincial job trainers were innately superior to federal job trainers, what with being "closer to the people" and all. It's never been clear to me just how a provincial bureaucrat in Halifax is in any meaningful sense closer to an unemployed worker than a federal bureaucrat living and working in the same city. Perhaps they stand a little nearer? But never mind. It seems the provinces weren't in fact doing a very good job of it, after all: skills shortages have persisted, particularly in the resource sectors, even as workers in other parts of the country waste away on the dole. A national approach, in a national economy, makes a certain sense. Now, it's perfectly possible the feds will make an even bigger mess of it, to the point that some future government will see fit to send the money back to the provinces again (lather, rinse, repeat). What's interesting to me is less the substance of the issue than what it tells us about the Harper government's thinking. Which, as shorthand, has the disadvantage of being several syllables longer than Harper's thinking, which is all that matters. Every so often, one or another of my fellow hacks will deliver themselves of a Grand Unified Theory of Harper as a fervent decentralist, driven by nothing so much as a desire to redesign the federation in the shape of a doughnut, with a great hole where Ottawa used to be. This postulate has had to be flown in to take the place of Harper the principled free marketer, previously the most popular theoretical Harper, who you'll remember collapsed, in a horrifying conjectural mishap, with the whole country watching. But as long as we're in the mood for evidence-based punditry, perhaps it's time this chimera were laid to rest as well. I don't doubt that one of Harper's knees jerks in that direction from time to time. But the other is as likely to jerk in the opposite way. It is true, for example, that Finance Minister Jim Flaherty's brusque, "take it or take it" promise to the provinces that federal transfers would go on rising in line with the economy, if not at the six per cent annual rate they had previously, was conceded without the expected haggling over conditions. But that came only after the failure of a previous effort at conditionality, the Conservatives' promised "waittimes guarantee." And it reflects a bipartisan reality - no party is going to enforce the Canada Health Act. In any case, how is it decentralizing for Ottawa to keep paying the provinces' rent, in perpetuity? You'd expect a genuinely decentralizing government to cut them off at some point, or at least convert the transfers to tax points. Maybe the game is to ship the money off to the provinces so Ottawa can't spend it? Except that direct federal spending, as a share of the total, has been consistently higher under the Harper government than it was under its "centralizing" predecessors (although it is scheduled to fall back to pre-Harper levels in the next few years). The "decentralist" Harper government is also the government that has poked, prodded and flat-out bribed the provinces into harmonizing their provincial sales taxes with the federal GST. It has pushed hard for a national securities regulator, to replace the 13 separate provincial and territorial regulatory regimes, and has even muttered under its breath - a throne speech here, an election platform there - about hauling out the federal trade and commerce power if the provinces do not get serious about dismantling their trade barriers. That the results have been, charitably speaking, mixed does not invalidate the point. And we're not done yet. It would be hard to overlook the federal-provincial implications, in matters from procurement to agriculture, of the Harper government's ambitious international trade agenda: other national governments may succeed in bringing the provinces to heel, where it has not. Even Senate reform is implicitly federalizing, though again, progress is scant. I don't mean any of this as criticism. This increasingly ungovernable country, whose provinces have lately grown bold enough to demand payment of ransom before they will allow each other's exports to pass, could use the firm smack of federal authority. But it does rather call into question the simple decentralist model of Harperian federalism. His views have changed on a lot of things, and on a lot of others, he's merely been inconsistent. But in this case, I think you can see a pattern. Neither "domineering federalism" nor "open federalism," it might best be called "logical federalism." Both the constitution and common sense would assign health care, for example (among other of what the BNA Act called "merely local" matters), to the provinces. But an integrated national economy demands national oversight. For the federal government to shirk its responsibility in this regard is not consistency, but dereliction. Indeed, a federal government that was more respectful of provincial prerogatives in the first instance might find it had more latitude to proceed on the second. Federalism hurts economic stability. Sudarshan Gooptu, Economist with the Debt and International Finance Division in the International Economics Department of the World Bank. 2005. The World Bank Report: East Asia Decentralizes. “Making Local Government Work.” http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEAPDECEN/Resources/dcfull-report.pdf , gooptu is Sector Manager, Economic Policy & Debt at The World Bank. International experience since the early 1980s, especially in Latin America, suggests that without appropriate accountability and transparency mechanisms, decentralization can encourage dangerous opportunistic behavior by state and local authorities. If left unchecked, such opportunism could undermine macroeconomic stability. The most vivid manifestation of this phenomenon is the softening of subnational budget constraints (Rodden 2000a; World Bank 2002). Avoiding this risk depends on the ability of the central government to prevent subnational authorities from passing their liabilities to higher-level governments.12 This, in turn, requires institutional mechanisms to discipline borrowing by state and local governments. Environment State competition results in bad environmental policies Oates 01< Wallace E. Oates, Professor of Economics, University of Maryland, College Park, MD, and University Fellow, Resources for the Future, Washington, DC, A Reconsideration of Environmental Federalism, http://www.rff.org/Documents/RFF-DP-01-54.pdf> The basic contention in this literature is that in a setting of interjurisdictional economic competition, local officials, in their eagerness to attract new business investment and create new jobs, will introduce measures to reduce costs to local business in the form of low taxes and excessively lax environmental standards, which will result in suboptimal outputs of local public goods (including environmental quality). In one sense, the argument is puzzling. If local governments seek to promote the well-being of their residents, then they should care about local environmental quality. If the benefits from a marginal improvement in the local environment exceed the costs, we should expect the improvement to receive support and be carried out. What is going on here? There is now a large—in fact an enormous—theoretical literature on all this.4 Let me first point out that it is straightforward to construct a standard kind of model of local public decisionmaking in which competition among governments induces efficient local choices (e.g., Oates and Schwab 1988; Wellisch 2000). In these models, jurisdictions compete for mobile firms to increase local wage income and expand the local tax base. The models generate what are effectively analogues to the purely competitive model for the private sector; they provide invisible-hand theorems in which interjurisdictional competition guides local public choice into Pareto-efficient outcomes. Modeling Generic New states don’t model US federalism Moravcsik 05, Moravcsik, Andrew, Professor of Politics and director of the European Union Program at Princeton University.. "Dream On America: World Rejects the US Model."Common Dreams. Newsweek International, 31 Jan. 2005. Web. 14 July 2014. CS Once upon a time, the U.S. Constitution was a revolutionary document, full of epochal innovations--free elections, judicial review, checks and balances, federalism and, perhaps most important, a Bill of Rights. In the 19th and 20th centuries, countries around the world copied the document, not least in Latin America. So did Germany and Japan after World War II. Today? When nations write a new constitution, as dozens have in the past two decades, they seldom look to the American model. When the soviets withdrew from Central Europe, U.S. constitutional experts rushed in. They got a polite hearing, and were sent home. Jiri Pehe, adviser to former president Vaclav Havel, recalls the Czechs' firm decision to adopt a European-style parliamentary system with strict limits on campaigning. "For Europeans, money talks too much in American democracy. It's very prone to certain kinds of corruption, or at least influence from powerful lobbies," he says. "Europeans would not want to follow that route." They also sought to limit the dominance of television, unlike in American campaigns where, Pehe says, "TV debates and photogenic looks govern election victories." So it is elsewhere. After American planes and bombs freed the country, Kosovo opted for a European constitution. Drafting a post-apartheid constitution, South Africa rejected American-style federalism in favor of a German model, which leaders deemed appropriate for the social-welfare state they hoped to construct. Now fledgling African democracies look to South Africa as their inspiration, says John Stremlau, a former U.S. State Department official who currently heads the international relations department at the University of Witwatersrand in Johannesburg: "We can't rely on the Americans." The new democracies are looking for a constitution written in modern times and reflecting their progressive concerns about racial and social equality, he explains. "To borrow Lincoln's phrase, South Africa is now Africa's 'last great hope'." Much in American law and society troubles the world these days. Nearly all countries reject the United States' right to bear arms as a quirky and dangerous anachronism. They abhor the death penalty and demand broader privacy protections. Above all, once most foreign systems reach a reasonable level of affluence, they follow the Europeans in treating the provision of adequate social welfare is a basic right. All this, says Bruce Ackerman at Yale University Law School, contributes to the growing sense that American law, once the world standard, has become "provincial." The United States' refusal to apply the Geneva Conventions to certain terrorist suspects, to ratify global human-rights treaties such as the innocuous Convention on the Rights of the Child or to endorse the International Criminal Court (coupled with the abuses at Abu Ghraib and Guantanamo) only reinforces the conviction that America's Constitution and legal system are out of step with the rest of the world. U.S. federalism isn’t modeled Kymlicka, 2k (Will, Professor of Philosophy at University of Toronto, July, Canadian Journal of Law and Jurisprudence) Can the Model be Exported? Given this success in the West, one might expect that there would be great interest in multination federalism in other countries around the world, from Eastern Europe to Asia andAfrica, most of which contain territorially-concentrated national minorities. The phenomenon of minority nationalism, including the demand for [*217] territorial autonomy, is a truly universal one. The countries affected by it are to be found in Africa (for example, Ethiopia), Asia (Sri Lanka), Eastern Europe (Romania), Western Europe (France), North America (Guatemala), South America (Guyana), and Oceania (New Zealand). The list includes countries that are old (United Kingdom) as well as new (Bangladesh), large (Indonesia) as well as small (Fiji), rich (Canada) as well as poor (Pakistan), authoritarian (Sudan) as well as democratic (Belgium), Marxist-Leninist (China) as well as militantly anti-Marxist (Turkey). The list also includes countries which are Buddhist (Burma), Christian (Spain), Moslem (Iran), Hindu (India), and Judaic (Israel)." n12 Indeed, some commentators describe the conflict between states and national minorities as an ever-growing "third world war", encompassing an everincreasing number ofgroups and states. n13. We need to think creatively about how to respond to these conflicts, which will continue to plague efforts at democratization, and to cause violence, around the world. I believe that federal or quasi-federal forms of territorial autonomy (hereafter TA) are often the only or best solution to these conflicts. To be sure, TA is not a universal formula for managing ethnic conflict. For one thing, TA is neither feasible nor desirable for many smaller and more dispersed national minorities. For such groups, more creative alternatives are needed. So it would be a mistake to suppose that TA can work for all national minorities, no matter how small or dispersed. But I believe it would equally be a mistake to suppose that non-territorial forms of cultural autonomy can work for all national minorities, no matter how large or territorially concentrated. What works best for small and dispersed minorities does not work best for large, concentrated minorities, and vice versa. n14 Where national minorities form clear majorities in their historic homeland, and particularly where they have some prior history of self-government, it is not clear that there is any realistic alternative to TA or multination federalism. Yet TA is strongly resisted in most of Eastern Europe, Africa and Asia. And it is resisted for the same reasons it was resisted historically in the West: fears about disloyalty, secession and state security. n15 In many countries, majority- minority [*218] relations are "securitized"--e.g., viewed as existential threats to the very existence of the state, which therefore require and justify repressive measures. n16 Where ethnic relations become securitized in this way, states are guided by a series ofinter-related assumptions: (a) that minorities are disloyal, not just in the sense that they lack loyalty to the state, but also in the sense that they are likely to collaborate with current or potential enemies; (b) that minorities are likely to use whatever power they are accorded to exit or undermine the state; (c) that a strong and stable state requires weak and disempowered minorities. Put another way, ethnic relations are seen as a zero-sum game: anything that benefits the minority is seen as a threat to the majority; and (d) that the treatment of minorities is above all a question of national security. Where one or more of these premises is accepted, there is virtually no room for an open debate about the merits of federalism. The perceived connection between federalism and destabilizing the state is too powerful to allow such a debate. Indeed, in many countries, for a minority to demand federalism is itself taken as proof of its disloyalty. It is not only advocates of secession who are put under police surveillance: anyone who advocates federalism is also seen as subversive, since it is assumed that this is just a covert first step to secession. Under these conditions, the whole question of what justice requires between majority and minority is submerged, since national security takes precedence over justice, and since disloyal minorities have no legitimate claims anyway. This resistance is so strong that TA is typically only granted as a last-ditch effort to avoid civil war, or indeed as the outcome of civil war. n17 On this issue, therefore, there is a wide and perhaps growing gulf between most Western countries and most countries in the rest of the world. In the West, it is considered legitimate that national minorities demand TA, and indeed these demands are increasingly accepted. Most national minorities in the West have greater autonomy than before, and none have been stripped oftheir autonomy. The idea ofTA is accepted in principle, and adopted in practice. The old self-image ofstates as unified nation-states is being replaced with the new self-image of states as multination federations and/or as partnerships between two or more peoples. By contrast, in many countries in Eastern Europe or the Third World, many national minorities have less autonomy than they had 30 or 50 years ago, and it is considered illegitimate for minorities to even mention autonomy, or to make any other proposal which would involve redefining the state as a multination state. These countries [*219] cling to the old model ofunitary nation-states, in which minorities ideally are politically weak, deprived of intellectual leadership, and subject to long-term assimilation. Nations do no model US federalism – no state has done so since the French revolution Stepan 99, Stepan, Alfred C, rofessor of Government at Oxford University in 1996-99, is now Wallace Sayre Professor of Government at Columbia University.. "Federalism and Democracy: Beyond the U.S. Model." Journal of Democracy 10.4 (1999): 19-34. Project MUSE. Web. 14 July 2014. CS The U.S. model of federalism, in terms of the analytical categories developed in this article, is "coming-together" in its origin, "constitutionally symmetrical" in its structure, and "demos-constraining" in its political consequences. Despite the prestige of this U.S. model of federalism, it would seem to hold greater historical interest than contemporary attraction for other democracies. Since the emergence of nation-states on the world stage in the after-math of the French Revolution, no sovereign democratic nation-states have ever "come together" in an enduring federation. Three largely unitary states, however (Belgium, Spain, and India) have constructed "holding-together" federations. In contrast to the United States, these federations are constitutionally asymmetrical and more "demos-enabling" than [End Page 32] "demos-constraining." Should the United Kingdom ever become a federation, it would also be "holding-together" in origin. Since it is extremely unlikely that Wales, Scotland, or Northern Ireland would have the same number of seats as England in the upper chamber of the new federation, or that the new upper chamber of the federation would be nearly equal in power to the lower chamber, the new federation would not be "demos-constraining" as I have defined that term. Finally, it would obviously defeat the purpose of such a new federation if it were constitutionally symmetrical. A U.K. federation, then, would not follow the U.S. model. The fact that since the French Revolution no fully independent nation-states have come together to pool their sovereignty in a new and more powerful polity constructed in the form of a federation would seem to have implications for the future evolution of the European Union. The European Union is composed of independent states, most of which are nationstates. These states are indeed increasingly becoming "functionally federal." Were there to be a prolonged recession (or a depression), however, and were some EU member states to experience very high unemployment rates in comparison to others, member states could vote to dismantle some of the economic federal structures of the federation that were perceived as being "politically dysfunctional." Unlike most classic federations, such as the United States, the European Union will most likely continue to be marked by the presumption of freedom of exit. Finally, many of the new federations that could emerge from the currently nondemocratic parts of the world would probably be territorially based, multilingual, and multinational. For the reasons spelled out in this article, very few, if any, such polities would attempt to consolidate democracy using the U.S. model of "coming-together," "demos-constraining," symmetrical federalism. 7 Violence/Conflicts Federalism does not work to solve conflicts McGarry and O’Leary, 94 (John Warren and O'Leary. The political regulation of national and ethnic conflict. Parliamentary Affairs v47.n1 (Jan 1994): pp94(22).) Unfortunately, federalism has a poor track record as a conflict-regulating device in multi-national and polyethnic states, even where it allows a degree of minority self-government. Democratic federations have broken…Federal failures have occurred because minorities continue to be outnumbered at the federal level of government. The resulting frustrations, combined with an already defined boundary and the significant institutional resources flowing from control of their own province or state, provide considerable incentives to attempt secession, which in turn can invite harsh responses from the rest of the federation…genuine democratic federalism is clearly an attractive way to regulate national conflict, with obvious moral advantages over pure control. The argument that it should be condemned because it leads to secession and civil war can be sustained only in three circumstances: first, if without federalism there would be no secessionist bid and, second, if it can be shown that national or ethnic conflict can be justly and consensually managed by alternative democratic means; and third, if the secessionist unit is likely to exercise hegemonic control (or worse) of its indigenous minorities. Federalism sparks ethnic conflict Mutunga 1 (Willy, Executive Director of the Kenya Human Rights Commission, The Nation) Federalism promotes localism, ethnic and racial xenophobia and undermines the sense of nationhood. Unsurprising the United States and Nigeria are living survivors of debilitating separatist wars between their regions; India, despite its federal miracle still bleeds from secessionist movements. The introduction of ethnic-based 'quasi-regionalism' in post-Mengistu Ethiopia has fuelled the conflict over the proposed Oromia state by members of the Oromo ethnic population. Majimboism in the early 1960s had let off the lid of secessionist movements, particularly by Kenyan Somalis in North Eastern Province and the clamour for an autonomous "Mwambao" on the Coast. There is no guarantee that this time around, majimboism will not trigger ethnic recidivism and separatist movements, especially in North Eastern, Coast and Eastern province where the Oromo population may lean towards the movement for an Oromia state. Federalism's main weakness is that it is a very expensive system that duplicates services and office holders at the regional and federal levels. It lacks uniform policies on such issues of national concern as laws regulating marriages, divorce, abortions, liquor, voting rights and public education. Rather than ensuring economic equity, as many proponents of majimboism assume, it sets those regions, states or cantons with a weak market-base, capital, and resources down the spiral of economic decline. It subjects local governments to double subordination-by the central and regional governments-and the citizens to triple taxation. At a time when the country's economy is on its knees, the feasibility of a well-financed transition is highly doubtful. Federalism just creates support bases for secessionist movements, increasing the likelihood of ethnic conflict – federalism only works where there are zero security threats. Galligan 7 (Brian, Professor at the University of Melbourne, Australia. 2007 APSA Conference, “Federalism, Subnational Government and Rights Protection” 26 September 2007. www.arts.monash.edu.au/psi/news-and-events/...nz.../galligan.doc AD 7/6/09) JM If this is what makes the multinational version of federalism attractive, it is also the source of its weakness. Using federalism to provide an institutional basis for ethnoculturally distinct peoples can ‘either exacerbate or mitigate ethnic conflict’, as Horowitz (1985, 603) has pointed out. Where there are deep divisions that divide regions, such as slavery in the United States, federalism can provide institutional assistance for secession ‘by creating opportunities for conflict and providing the region’ with the opportunity and the institutions needed to mobilize support for secession (Anderson 2004, 96). Canada’s long-standing national crisis over Quebec separatism shows how vulnerable multinational federalism can be, even in a long standing liberal democracy. Studies of failed federations and attempts to deal with regions of ethnic conflict provide ample evidence of this dangerous aspect of federalism (Dorff 1994, 99-114). Federalism is in trouble where there is too little national sense among the people, and too sharp differences among regionally based ethnic, religious and linguistic groups. Examples abound in post-colonial federations hastily drawn up by retreating European powers (Franck 1968), or in the recent failure of Yugoslavia where there was insufficient cohesion in the multiethnic Yugoslav community (Zagar 2005, 107-33). As Kymlicka points out, multinational federalism works best where there are no security risks and deep consensus on liberal democratic values and respect for human rights, including the recognition of and tolerance for ethnic differences. This explains why Europe has become the main theatre for multinational federalism: the European Union ensures joint security and reduces the sovereign independence of nation states, and there is deep consensus on liberal democratic values. In such a congenial environment, multi-national member states like Belgium and Spain can adopt multinational federalism. Countries without an overarching transnational association to ensure national security and without a deep consensus on liberal democratic values, such as many of the Asian countries, will not be drawn to federalism in the same way.