WELFARE ANALYSIS OF CONTROLLING INDOOR AIR POLLUTION (THE CASE OF URBAN ETHIOPIA) By: Wondwossen Tsegaye Aselet E-mail: wendsentsgay@yahoo.com 1 Content Page Abstract CHAPTER ONE Introduction 1.1Bakground………………………………………………………………………….4 1.2 Statement of the Problem………………………………………………………….5 1.3 Significance of the Study………………………………………………………….6 1.4 Objectives of the study…………………………………………………………….7 CHAPTER TWO Literature Review 2.1Theoretical Literature………………………………………………………………9 2.2 Empirical literature……….. …………………………………………………….15 CHAPTER THREE Methodology of the study 3.1 Model Specification……………………………………………………………..18 3.2 Data collection…………………………………………………………………..22 CHAPTER FOUR Empirical Results………………………………………………………………….23 CHAPTER FIVE Summary and Conclusion………………………………………………………..25 References 2 Abstract The main reason for the failure of many policy measures in developing countries is the fact that interaction of different social as well as economic activities are not taken in to consideration before they are being implemented. It is important that governments in these countries should focus on addressing welfare, environmental and social aspect of their policy measures before implementing them. Thus, mainly this paper focuses on introducing welfare analysis by taking a single policy measure, which helps to control indoor air pollution. This study by using the marginal tax reform approach attempts to analyze the welfare effect of indoor air pollution control in urban Ethiopia. No study has been done regarding this issue, thus the study tries to show one way of analyzing welfare on the implementation of pollution-controlling-policy instrument. Hence, the 2000 urban household socio-economic data collected by the Department of Economics of the Addis Ababa University is used in order to identify goods that are heavily concentrated in the consumption of poor households. Accordingly, the study found that introducing or increasing tax on commodities which are the main sources of air pollution (kerosene, charcoal) would affect the welfare of the urban households as the consumption of these commodities are more concentrated on poor than rich households. Differently, the study has found that a tax increase or introduction on commodities such as fuel wood and Cigarettes would not have a significant welfare loss for the urban society. 3 CHAPTER ONE I. Introduction 1.1 Background There are three broad sources of air pollution from human activities; stationary or point, mobile, and indoor air polution (Kathuria, V. 2001). Industries, power plants, etc are the causes of stationary air pollution, where as indoor air pollution refers to pollutions from open fires for cooking and heating. It is mostly a problem in developing countries, and its effect become intense in rural areas. Mobile or Vehicular air pollution is particularly a serious problem in urban areas. Since most economic activities or transactions are concentrated in urban Ethiopia, the air pollution that resulted from these three sources is a serious problem. However, it seems that, in Ethiopia, compared to other developed countries, there is no serious problem related to air pollution. But this is only because of the fact that no body gives a serious attention to the effects of air pollution. Moreover, there is no study or reliable data regarding the effects of air pollution on the health condition of the people living in the country. In now days, in Addis, vehicles are increasing alarmingly. Ethiopians (mostly students and trainees), who have been in other western countries, have a legal- right to import any cars from the country where they have been. Following this legal- right most of them import second hand cars (old cars). It is known that these vehicles contribute much for air pollution than the new ones. However from the government side there is no measure taken to regulate or decrease the importation of these polluting vehicles. Indoor air pollution, which is mostly ignored by the people affected by and government as well has a serious effect on the health of children as well as residents in the house. In urban areas of Ethiopia, where large part of the population is using fuel wood, charcoals, and kerosene for cooking purposes in their daily life, it is unreasonable to ignore the air pollution that results from these burnings. Almost more than 85 % of the people in urban areas of the country use fuel wood, charcoals and kerosene for cooking as well as for other daily activities. Thus the contribution of this process to the environment pollution 4 should not be treated as insignificant. Nevertheless, controlling the air pollution resulting from these sources is also a problem in connection with their effect on the living condition of the people. For instance, taxing or charging these commodities is one method of controlling the air pollution by discouraging the consumption of these commodities. But, since the consumption of these commodities may be more concentrated on poor households than the rich ones the effect of taxing or charging the commodities should be analyzed first. 1.2. Statement of the Problem Policies that affect consumer and producer prices have an impact on welfare. According to Duclos et al. (2000), most governments use indirect taxes; mainly VAT, to raise tax revenues thus affecting consumer and producer prices. An increase or a decrease in the tax of a good will have an effect on producer or consumer prices and this in turn would entails a decline or an improvement in the welfare of an individual. Policy analysts must routinely evaluate the impact of such polices on social welfare. Marginal social cost of revenue from the tax on a particular good depends on the rate at which household welfare falls as the tax rate increases, and on the rate at which public revenue rises (Ahmad and Stern 1984). If many people consume more of a particular good and the less responsive is government revenue to a tax increase, then policy makers should focus on decreasing the tax rate on that good. If any reform of indirect taxes is to be welfare improving, it requires detailed empirical analysis. In Ethiopia, where per capita income is one of the lowest in the world, indirect tax reform should not only focus on targeting higher revenue, but the tasks of tax reform should also include analyzing whether the directions of the reform would not aggravate the poverty of the people. In almost all developing countries, the livelihood of the society is dependent on products that are obtained from the environment. Based on this fact, it could be argued that there is 5 a need to control for the rapid environmental deprivation, such as reduction in air quality, deforestation, soil degradation and noise pollution. Nevertheless, In these countries, where most part of the population is living under the poverty line, environmental assets protection only may not be the crucial thing that government should focus on, rather government or policy makers should also give due emphasis for the improvement of the living condition of the society. In this regard, the study attempts to demonstrate empirically the possible welfare impact of introducing tax on indoor pollution sources (fire wood, kerosene and charcoal). Hence, the main task of this paper is to pave a way for making welfare analysis before any tax policy instrument is used for controlling negative environmental impacts. Thus, the paper, specifically, focuses on making welfare analysis on an increase or decrease of tax or charge on indoor air pollution sources (fuel wood, kerosene and charcoal) by calculating the distribution characteristics of these commodities. The study attempts to measure the distributional characteristics, which reassure how heavily the consumption of each good is concentrated on the poor. This measure helps to answer which item should have to have a tax increase or a tax decrease on the ground of distributional equity and poverty alleviation. it also helps to identify goods that are good candidate for introducing a new tax. 1.3 Significance of the Study Ahmad and Stern (1991) have pointed out that the main purpose of taxation is to raise resources to finance government expenditure. They underline the problem of tax design as one of finding a way of raising resources in a manner which is administratively and politically feasible and which promotes equity and efficiency. In a similar vein, a recent publication by the IMF (cited in Islam 2003) notes that taxation creates distortions and the main objective of tax policy is to design a system that raises enough revenue while minimizing the level of associated distortions. . Ethiopia is currently implementing a Tax Reform Program, which includes the replacement of single stage sales tax by Value Added Tax (VAT). The indirect tax reform mainly focuses on raising more revenue, facilitating the economy and 6 modernizing the tax administration. However, little is known about the likely effects of the tax reform on the welfare of the society. Despite its significance, no study has been done in analyzing the welfare effect of a tax reform in Ethiopia. In Ethiopia, particularly in urban areas, air pollution is increasing surprisingly. Though there is no reliable figure of the effects of air pollution on health, it would not be difficult to see that air pollution is a serious problem in urban areas. In Ethiopia, where Per Capital Income of the population is below the thresholds that people should have for a living, it seems ridiculous to discus environmental issues. This is because of the fact that no body gives attention to the effects of pollution, rather they prefer to focus on how to improve their living conditions. No study has been conducted regarding the welfare effects of air pollution in urban areas. Hence the paper is a pioneer by attempting to investigate whether applying policy instruments, particularly; tax policy to decrease air pollution in the urban Ethiopia would lead to welfare gain. This study by using marginal tax reform approach introduces for the first time how welfare analysis should be done before policy instruments are applied for the purpose of curbing environmental damage. This would help especially the governments in developing countries to check first the effect of the policy on the welfare of the society and tries to compare whether the gain from the implementation of the environmental policy does compensate the welfare loss. Hence, this study by showing the need to make welfare analysis before implementing any policy for the purpose of controlling environmental hazards, addresses the issue of streamlining economic development with environment. 1.4 Objectives of the Study The main objectives of the paper are: To see empirically the welfare effects of controlling indoor air pollution in urban Ethiopia. Hence, the paper tries to investigate whether an attempt for controlling air pollution using taxation or charging the source may result in welfare loss of the people.This 7 would be done by identifying goods whose consumption is more heavily concentrated on poor households. The paper attempts to introduce ways of analyzing welfare in an attempt of controlling negative environmental impacts, particularly air pollution. To identify or recommend other ways of controlling indoors air pollution, which may not result in serious welfare loss for the society. 8 CHAPTER TWO Literature Review 2.1. Theoretical Literature 2.1.1. Welfare Measurements Most people would agree that, other things being equal, increased consumption of goods and services raises individuals’ levels of welfare. There may be other factors other than the consumption of goods and services that affect welfare, but since these tend to be much more difficult to measure, economists usually restrict themselves to that portion of human welfare which is attributable to consumption. In welfare economics the starting point for measuring welfare is the utility function (Glewwe and Twum 1998). It asserts that welfare rises as the consumption of various goods and services increases. But, most consumption and household data are collected at the household level and thus require analysis using a household level utility function rather than individual. Hence one should assume: i) A household’s utility is a function of the consumption of goods and services and the composition of household members. The composition is needed to account for the fact that house holds with different compositions require different consumption levels to attain the same level of welfare (for example, house- holds with large number of members need more goods and services to attain the same welfare level as households with small household size. ii) Each household possesses the same household utility function in order to compare the welfare of different households. If they posses different welfare function it would be impossible or meaning less to compare welfare among different categories of people. iii) Since one does not know the distribution of welfare with in the household, one has to assume that all household members enjoy the same level of welfare (Glewwe and Twum 1998) When government wants to impose an indirect tax on a commodity it may be better first to find out whether such tax may not significantly increase the price of the 9 commodity and therefore substantially reduce the welfare of people. Similar information may be needed with respect to imposition of indirect tax on commodities. This necessitates a welfare measure that could help governments or policy makers in their decision on the policy measures. Several welfare measures have shown great progress in the last twenty-five years. Consumer Surplus: It is the difference of the total amount that an individual is willing to pay and the amount he actually pays. Consumer surplus is used to measure individual welfare and social welfare based on its unweighted sum over the population. According to Slesnick (1991), consumer surplus is the overwhelming choice as a welfare indicator, because it is an intuitive concept with modest data requirement. Slesnick (1991) has shown that in the simplest case of a change in the price of a single good say, a commodity from P01 to P11, the change in consumers surplus simply is the negative of the change in the area under the demand curve. 0 P 1 CSk= x1(t,p2.........pn,Mk,Ak) dt 1 P 1 Where Mk= the level of expenditure of the kth household P= (P1,P2, ..................Pn) is a vector of prices Ak= is a vector of demographic characteristics Xi (P1,Mk,Ak) = the demand function for good i The use of Marshallian consumer surplus as a measure of welfare change is problematic for the following reasons. i) It works only for one price change. If several price changes or price and income changes, we need a more potent approach for estimating the welfare implication. ii) Even for the case of a single price change Marshallian consumer surplus, as a measure of welfare change is problematic on account of maintaining the marginal utility of income as constant. 10 The validity of consumer surplus as welfare measure has been questioned and John Hicks developed two approaches to welfare measurement, which do not have the same shortcomings as consumer surplus. These two welfare measures are (Creedy 1999): Compensation Variation (CV): It is the amount of money that must be given to a loser, or taken from a gainer in order to keep the individual on the initial indifference curve. If prices change from Po to P1 as a result of the imposition of indirect taxes then individual utility changes from Uo to U1 (after the associated change in consumption). In terms of the expenditure function E(P,U) it can be written as: CV = E (P1, Uo) – E (Po, Uo) Equivalent Variation (EV): is the amount of income that must be given to the consumer in the initial situation in order to attain a new (higher) indifference curve. Equivalently, it can be thought of as the minimum amount of income the consumer would be willing to accept in order to forgo the move from the status quo to the new situation. EV=E (P1, U1) – E (Po, U1) The Hicksian demand function (XiH (P,U) ) can be obtain from the expenditure function XiH (P,U) = E (P,U) Pi The welfare changes defined by compensating and equivalent variation are represented by areas to the left of the Hicksian demand curves between price Pio & Pi1, for Uo and U1 respectively. P i1 CV = XiH (P, Uo) dpi Pio Pi1 EV= XiH (P,U1)dpi Pio The two welfare measures resolve the conceptual problem of welfare measurement, but they do not help the practitioner because the two measures depend on compensated demand and therefore they are not observable. Robert Willig made the first attempt to tackle this problem by demonstrating that, “in the case of a single price change, (observable) estimates of consumer’s surplus can be 11 used to provide a good approximation to the equivalent or compensating variation. Since these welfare indicators provide upper and lower bounds for consumer’s surplus, the accuracy of the approximation depends on the magnitude of the income effect”. (Slesnick 1991, p. 2112) 2.1.2. Marginal Tax Reform Approach Tax reform, as defined by John and Smolensky (1994), may take variety of forms. It can cover increase or decrease in tax rates, brackets or thresholds and changes in the tax base, the introduction of new taxes and the abolition of new taxes, and changes in the tax mix. Tax reform loosely speaking deals with improving welfare by making marginal changes in tax design and structure. The theory of tax reform is concerned with small departure from an existing tax structure. The marginal tax reform method, pioneered by Feldstein (1972) and extended by Ahmad and Stern (1984), involves comparing for each commodity, the marginal change in social welfare arising from a tax change with the small change in total tax revenue. Newberry and Stern (1987) have tried to make clear the theory of marginal tax reform. According to them the theory shows that the social welfare effect of a marginal tax change is given by the weighted sum of each household’s consumption of the good. The weight reflects the social marginal value of consumption by each household. “The social welfare impact of a tax or price change therefore depends on the total level of consumption of the good and (if social weights differ across households) the distribution of that consumption amongst the population” (Gibson 1998, pp. 4). Deaton (1997) contrasts this view with the theory of optimum taxes. The optimal tax theory, as explained by Deaton, focuses on the prices that maximize a social welfare function subject to budgetary behavioral constraints. That is, it is a constrained optimization of a social welfare function by the social planner, given the revenue constraint, available tax instruments and the influence of these instruments on private behavior. It provides a systematic and essential framework for thinking about the standard issue of distribution and economic efficiency that are the basis for any intelligent discussion of price and tax reform. 12 The main criticisms against optimal tax theory are as follows: (i) The model could not describe the social and political equilibrium that exist in developing countries, because of its unrealistic assumptions (Deaton 1997). (ii) Calculation of optimal indirect tax rates requires a great deal of data about preferences and demand patterns (Creedy 1999). The theory of marginal tax reform solves the above problems faced by the optimal tax theory. Especially its limited data requirement makes it easy to apply even in developing countries. In real life it is rarely possible to reach optimal tax rate immediately. Thus, its practical applicability attracts policy makers in analyzing a tax system using marginal tax reform approach. This paper mainly follows this approach in analyzing the direction of the tax reform in Ethiopia. The approach to the analysis of marginal indirect tax reform is based on the use of social welfare function representing the value judgments of a decision maker or judge. The social welfare function (w) is a function of the individual welfare value u, which, in turn is given by the value of the indirect utility functions that gives the maximum attainable welfare in terms of prices (p) and outlays (yh). Uh = (yh, p) W = V(u1, u2,….uN) A simplistic model of price determination assumes that the consumer price is the sum of a fixed price and the tax or subsidy (Deaton 1997), so that Pi = pio + ti Where ti = tax Government revenue is the sum over all goods and all households of tax payments: M R= i=1 H ti qih h=1 Where qih = amount of good i purchased by household h and there are M goods in all. The theory assumes that; i) A change in the tax rate is equivalent to a change in the price 13 ii) Any change in the tax or price is fully transferred or passed on to consumers. Hence revenue with respect to tax change is H H R/t = qih + h=1 h=1 M tj qih/pi i=1 A given change in the tax rate will produce a large revenue effect, the greater is the aggregate consumption of a good and the less the substitution away from the taxed good. The welfare effect for marginal tax change is given by the weighted sum of each household’s consumption of the good. H W/ti = h = 1qih Where η = W . h = w uh yh yh ‘η’ reflects the social marginal utility of income for each household, h. It measures the increase in welfare (W) resulting from a change in the households’ income. The social weights(η ) are estimated as follows. Suppose that we use the Atkinson social welfare function where there are ‘n’ individuals in house hold h. W = (Ch) (1 – e) 1-e W = 1n(Ch) e > 0 and e 1 Where W = is the value that one judge places on the income distribution Ch = consumption level for household h e= coefficient of inequality aversion. With this social welfare function, the social weight applied to consumption by household h is given by the social marginal utility of consumption. Bh = (Ch) -e 14 “Different values of the coefficient e reflect different judgment about the desirability of making transfers to reduce income inequality. Because of this, a range of values for e is commonly used to see whether conclusions are robust to practical ethical judgments” (Ahmad and Stern 1991). The source of behavioral estimates of e is the information contained in the patterns of private transfers between households. An increase in the inequality aversion parameter (e) would imply an increasing weight toward the consumption of the poor. Therefore, the cost - benefit ratio of tax is: Where i = W/ti R/ti w/ti =the change in welfare with a marginal increase in tax R/ti . = the change in revenue with a marginal increase in the tax rate After substituting the value of W/ti and R/ti i = W/ti = R/ti we get; H qih j=1 H qi + ti qih/Pi j=1 i is the social cost of raising one unit of government revenue by increasing the tax on good i. It measures the change in social welfare per birr of extra tax revenue resulting from a marginal change in the tax. For an optimal tax system, the marginal revenue cost of reform must be equal for all goods. Hence the direction of a marginal tax reform is indicated by relative magnitudes of this ratio for each commodity group. The rule for optimal tax reform is therefore to lower ti relative to tj, if i is greater than j (Ahmad and Stern 1984) 2.2. Empirical Literature Review As it has been explained in the above discussion, since this study is a pioneer in attempting to use the marginal tax reform approach for the purpose of analyzing welfare 15 impact of applying pollution controlling policy instruments, the empirical literatures may not directly related to the objective of this paper. In spit of this, it is better to raise some studies that have been made using marginal tax reform approach. Ahmad and Stern (1984) have developed the theory of marginal tax reform and empirically tested for India. They found that i (the social cost to benefit ratio) for cereals ranks lower than that of all other commodity groups with the exception of milk and milk products. This suggests an increase in tax on cereals relative to the other groups and a decrease in the tax on the clothing group relative to all others. In their empirical analysis they also found that for moderate level of inequality aversion, e = 1, i for cereals is greater than for all commodities except fuel and light and that for clothing has dropped to the third lowest position. For highest level of inequality aversion, say e = 5, i for fuel and light and cereals ranking highest and clothing dropped to the second lowest position. Thus they concluded that for the value judgment represented by e = 1, increasing the tax on clothing by an amount sufficient to raise revenue and decreasing taxes on cereals by a corresponding amount increases social welfare. Creedy (1998) has examined indirect tax reform in Australia using the method developed by Ahmad and Stern (1984). He calculated the marginal revenue cost for 16 commodity categories. He found a change in the ranking as inequality aversion (e), which indicates higher social value for poor household, is increased from a zero level to a positive level. Gibson (1998) made empirical analysis on the distributional effect of indirect tax reform in Papua New Guinea. He used nationally representative household survey data to identify the items that are consumed mainly by poor household in Papua New Guinea. By using the distributional characteristics formula for a good, which is defined by Newberry (1995), he calculated the distributional characteristics for 87 goods and services. The study showed that at both low and high level of inequality aversion, sago is the food whose consumption is most heavily skewed towards the poor households. When the 16 lowest level of inequality aversion (v = 0.5) is used in the calculation, among the items that have to be purchased and hence could be taxed, axes, bush knifes, and other garden tools, school fees, children's clothing, pots and pans, salt, rice, and finned fish have consumption most heavily skewed towards the poor. Adult clothing joins the list when higher level of inequality aversion is used. In our country, though much work has not been done regarding the welfare aspect of indirect tax reform, a paper by Munoz and Cho (2003) addressed the poverty and social impact of replacing Ethiopia's sales tax with a value-added tax (VAT). In their study, the calculation of the distributional characteristics of exempted goods showed that health expenditure and public transport, which are exempted items, ranked lowest. This showed that these items are not much consumed by the poor. The goods disproportionably consumed by the poor were primarily basic food items and traditional fuel sources such as dung cakes and firewood. From these results Munoz and Cho (2003) concluded that exempted goods and services do not properly serve the purpose of alleviating poverty or improving inequality. Marginal tax reform approach, after its empirical analysis pioneered by Ahmad and Stern (1984), has got acceptance from many researchers and policy makers for identifying welfare effects of indirect tax reforms. The study by Munoz and Cho (2003) compared the value added tax with the replaced sales tax, in their impact on the poor. However, by following the marginal tax reform approach, the current study tries to identify how a tax increase or decrease on environmentally bad items should be directed to improve the welfare of the society. Vinish Kathuria(2001), attempted to investigate whether the enactment of policy instruments and efforts have led to commensurate fall in pollution in Delhi or not. His results and analysis showed that the imposition has not resulted in concomitant improvement in air quality. He found that enacting a policy instruments has not lead to any fall in the air pollution as none of the coefficients attain significance, though coefficients for all the parameter s have the correct sign. 17 CHAPTER THREE Methodology And Data Source 3.1. Model Specification This study mainly follows the marginal tax reform approach which was initially developed by Feldstein (1972 cited in Ahmad and Stern 1984) and empirically applied first by Ahmad and Stern (1984). This helps to identify the possible directions of indirect tax or subsidy reforms on environmentally bad commodities that would improve the welfare of the society. In this study, calculation of the distributional characteristics for 75 items is done. This approach follows Deaton A. (1997) theory of marginal tax reform. Using this approach the paper attempts to identify whether a tax increase on a specific commodity, such as on fuel wood, kerosene and charcoals, to control air pollution could be effective policy instrument. Its effectiveness depends on whether it will decrease pollution with out affecting the welfare of the society. If it affects the welfare of the society by increasing the price of the commodities then its effectiveness is questionable. Hence alternative policy instruments should be recommended. This kind of analysis is necessary especially in developing countries, to asses the issue that a policy change would not lead to an increase in the cost of the living for poor households. The social welfare function (w) is a function of the individual welfare value u, which, in turn is given by the value of the indirect utility functions that gives the maximum attainable welfare in terms of prices (p) and Outlays (yh) is: Uh = (yh, p) W = V(u1, u2,….uN) 18 A simplistic model of price determination,(Deaton (1997)), assumes that the consumer price is the sum of a fixed (for example, world) price and the tax or subsidy, so that Pi = pio + Ri Where Ri = tax or subsidy rate Government revenue (GR) is the sum over all goods and all households of tax payments: M GR = i=1 H Ri qih i=1 Where qih = amount of good i purchased by household h and there are m goods Hence revenue with respect to tax change is R/ti = qir + i= 1 i=1 Ri qih/pi j=1 The effect of social welfare is W/ti= qih j=1 Where = v . h = w ,is the marginal utility of income uh xh xh The cost - benefit ratio of tax is: i = W/ti = R/ti H qih j=1 H qi + ti qih/Pi j=1 i is the social cost of raising one unit of government revenue by increasing the tax on good i. This figure gives us whether an increase in the tax rate on environmentally bad commodities in order to decrease air pollution would result in welfare decline. 19 If this ratio is large, social welfare would be improved by decreasing the price of the good either because its right price is hurting those whose incomes are socially valuable, or because the taxation of the good is discretionary, or both. Goods with low i ratios are those that are candidate for a tax increase. When all the ratios are the same there is no scope for beneficial reform. By aggregating some of the variables in the social cost benefit ratio the distributional characteristic could be obtained. The distributional characteristic (dih) of a good is defined by Newberry (1995) as a measure, which shows how heavily the consumption of each good is concentrated on the poor, which is derived from the marginal tax reform theory and is given by: dih = h qih *Qi Where h = The social weight qih = Consumption of the ith good by household * = Average of the social weights Qi = The aggregate consumption of good i. The distributional characteristic will be higher, the more heavily the consumption of good i is concentrated on the socially deserving (i.e. those with high social marginal values of consumption, βh) The distributional characteristics is a scale neutral measure, which makes it useful for identifying goods that are candidate for having reduced rates of tax on equity grounds. For this calculation, it will be possible to get information about consumption level of each good. However the problem lies on how to calculate welfare weight (βh). Welfare weight (βh) According to Ahmad and Stern (1984), policy choices generally involve implicit or explicit trade-offs of gains or losses to different group. In practice, estimation of distributional characteristics as well as marginal social cost benefit analysis requires some approximation to the welfare weights, rather than deriving them from estimated preferences. The social weight applied to consumption by household h is given by the social marginal utility of consumption. 20 And hence it is approximated by: βh = (yh)-e Where Y = income, for which total expenditure can be taken as a better proxy. The only uncertainty concerns the appropriate value for the inequality aversion parameter, e. Different values of the coefficient e reflect different judgment about the desirability of making transfers to reduce income inequality. “The source of a behavioral estimate of e is the information contained in the patterns of private transfers between households. Inequality aversion that is equal to zero (e = 0) implies that there is no aversion to inequality on the part of people donating transfers”(Olivia and Gibson 2003). This means that a one birr addition (transfer) to a poor household taken from the rich one doesn’t change the welfare of the two individuals. That is the cost to the rich individual by losing one birr is equivalent to the benefit to the poor individual, and thus do not alter the distribution of income. Inequality aversion which is greater than zero (e > 0) implies that a one birr increase to a poor individual from the rich one would have a higher benefit to the poor than the cost to the rich individual. In this case transfers make the distribution more equal, implying aversion to inequality on the part of donors (e > 0). To put it differently, for instance, when inequality aversion parameter is, say, e = 2, taking one extra birr (indirect tax) from a poor household is judged to cause four times as much social cost as does taking one extra birr in tax from a household with twice the consumption level. In contrast if e = 0, taking one more birr in tax from the poorest household has the same social cost as taking another birr in tax from the richest household (Gibson 1998). Since calculating this values require greater data need the paper uses, four values of the inequality aversion parameter (e = 0.5, e = 1,e =2 and e= 5). These values are used in many similar studies such as Ahmad and Stern (1991) , Gibson (1998) and others. 21 3.2. Sources of Data Urban household socio-economic survey data of year 2000 collected by the Department of Economics of Addis Ababa University in collaboration with Goteborg University is used for this study. Urban households are chosen because of many different reasons, but it is mainly because of the fact that economic activity is relatively more concentrated (transactions are active) in urban areas and also the change in the tax reform will mostly affect the welfare of the urban population directly rather than the rural population. The life of the rural population follows hand to mouth subsistence economy and hence may not actively participate in the economic activity of the country. A total of 1472 urban households were surveyed. Seven major urban centers- Addis Ababa, Awassa, Bahr Dar, Dessie, Dire Dawa, Jimma, and Mekele were selected. The household survey contains information about demographic characteristics and income of the household. In addition to this information about household characteristics and income, households were asked about their last week expenditure and consumption of different food items from the market. The survey also collects data on non-food expenditures over the past months and year. 22 Chapter Four Empirical Results By using the urban household survey the study has calculated the distributional characteristics for 75 items. The distributional characteristics will help us to identify which items are consumed mainly by the poor. Thus, according to the result obtained from own calculation (see appendix), charcoal, kerosene and fuel wood, rank 9th ,6th and 35 th respectively at a higher inequality aversion (e = 5). This indicates that these items (except fuel wood) are more heavily concentrated on the consumption of poor households and hence it would be inequitable to levy additional or introduce a new tax on these items. Though there are other considerations such as health and environment effects that should be analyzed together with this, at least using this methodology, it could be clearly seen that using tax policy instrument for controlling pollution will result in welfare loss of the urban people in Ethiopia. Despite the above result, fuel wood, ranks 35 at higher inequality aversion, seems more concentrated in the consumption of rich households. This indicates that introducing tax on this commodity would not affect the welfare of the urban society. From the appendix, one can see that at a low inequality aversion (e = 0.5) modern medical service rank 12th in terms of its consumption being heavily concentrated on poor households, and ranks 33rd at a high inequality aversion (when distribution does mater). But traditional medicine (healers) rank 70th at low inequality, and 10th at a high inequality aversion in terms of their consumption being heavily concentrated on poor. This result implies that at a high inequality aversion, that is when distribution favors poor households, it is only traditional medicine (healer) that is relatively more concentrated on poor households’ consumption. Therefore only traditional medicine (healers) deserves the privilege of being exempted from the newly implemented value added tax. From this we could see that even if the negative health effect of kerosene and charcoal is higher on poor households the chance that poor households get modern medical service is much 23 lower than the rich households. Poor households prefer to go to traditional healers. Thus, with respect to the welfare analysis and according to the result obtained from this study, it could be concluded that government should be careful when a tax is introduced on charcoal and increased on kerosene. Further, government should also be selective whether to exempt modern medical service or traditional medicine and healers. From the result it could be clearly seen that Value Added tax exemption of modern medical service does not favor equity, since poor households use traditional medical services than the modern ones. This result is logical in the sense that as long as one of the main objectives of a tax policy is to maintain equitable income distribution, the good with the highest social cost of welfare should be exempted. Excise taxes are levied on goods and services in order to discourage the consumption of luxuries items and goods whose consumption is not favored. Cigarettes are the main sources of revenue from excise taxes, but are one of the commodities that could contribute for indoor air pollution. Cigarettes ranks 63rd and 50th at the lowest and highest inequality aversion respectively, in terms of their consumption being heavily concentrated on poor households. Hence, this result justifies the fact that it is equitable to increase tax on these items in addition to the need to tax them for the purpose of controlling indoor air pollution. 24 CHAPTER FIVE Summary And Conclusion The main aims of the currently implemented indirect tax reform, specifically the Value Added Tax, are to raise government revenue, to facilitate the economy and modernize the tax administration. The current reform of indirect taxes is likely to have considerable effects on consumer welfare. But due to small number of exempted items under VAT compared to sales tax, VAT seems to contribute to the increase of the cost of living for the poor. According to Gibson (1998), indirect tax reform should be designed so as to avoid excessive increases in the cost of living for the poor. In this study an attempt has been made to analyze empirically how indirect tax reform should be directed so that it could increase the welfare of the society. The study applied marginal tax reform approach for analyzing the welfare effect of introducing or increasing tax on commodities that are the source of indoor air pollution (Kerosene, fuel wood, charcoal and others). Distributional characteristics of 75 goods and services has been calculated. In the paper, household urban socio-economic data of 2000 collected by the Department of Economics of the Addis Ababa University has been used. The results obtained from the calculation of the distributional characteristics show that kerosene and charcoal are commodities, which have higher social cost ratio, hence from poverty alleviation and distribution point of view these commodities deserve a tax reduction as their consumption is concentrated more on poor households. Further, modern medical services, which are exempted from the value added tax, have higher ratio of distributional characteristics, thus rank lower than traditional medical services. This implies that since only traditional medicine is concentrated on the consumption of poor households, exempting modern medical service does not contribute to equity and fair resource distribution objective of a tax system. 25 REFERENCES Ahmad, E, and Stern N. H. (1984). The Theory of Tax Reform and Indian Indirect Taxes. Journal of Public Economics 28, 259-298. Ahmad E. and Stern N. H. (1991). The Theory and Practice of Tax Reform in Developing Countries. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Atkinson,A.B. and Stiglitz,J.E (1980). Lectures on Public Economics. McGraw-Hill International Editions-Economic series. Belew, F. (2001). Fiscal Reform. Paper Presented for the 11th Annual Conference on the Ethiopian Economy. Ethiopian Economic Association, Nazareth. Bibi, S and Ducles, J. (2003). Poverty-Decreasing Indirect Tax Reforms: Evidence from Tunisia. Retrieved from www.wider.unu.edu/conference/conference /conference2003.2 Bird. M. R. and Oldman O. (1967). Reading on Taxation in Developing Countries. The Johns Hopkins Press, Baltimore. Creedy, J. (1998). Measuring Welfare Changes and Tax Burdens. Edward Elgar Cheltenham, UK. Creedy, J. (1999). Modeling Indirect Taxes and Tax Reforms. Edward Elgar Cheltenham, UK. Cropper,Maureen L(1981). Measuring the Benefits from Reduced Morbidity: American Economic Review vol. 71,no 2,pp235-240. Deaton A. (1977). Equity, Efficiency, and the Structure of Indirect Taxation. Journal of Public Economics, vol.105, pp. 299-312. Deaton, A. (1997). The Analysis of Household Surveys: a Micro econometric Approach to Development Policy. The Johns Hopkins University Press, London. Duclos, J., Makdissi, P. and Wodon, Q. (2002). Socially Efficient Tax Reforms. Retrieved from www.eco.ulaval.ca/w3/recherche/cahiers/2002/0201 26 Due, J.F. (1981). Government Finance and Economic Analysis. Second edition, Long man Economic Series, Homewood Gerking,S.and Stanley,L.(1986) .An Economic Analysis of Air Pollution and Health: Review of Economics and Statistics,68(1):115-121 Gibson, J. (1998). Indirect Tax Reform and the Poor in Papua New Guinea. Pacific Economic Bulletin, vol 13, No 2. Glewwe,P. and Twum, B.A.(1998). The Distribution of Welfare in Ghana, 1987-88. Living Standards Measurement Study Working Paper No.75. Islam. A. (2003). Issues in Tax reform. Asia-Pacific Development Journal, Vol.8 and No. 1 . John,M. and Smolensky,E. (1994). Modern Public Finance. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts and London. Joseph P. Pinto and Lester D. Grant(1999), Approaches to Monitoring of Air Pollutants and Evaluation of Health Impacts Produced by Biomass Burning. National Centre for Environmental Assessment-WHO Background Papers, 147 Junghun K. (2003). The Welfare Effect of Property Transaction Tax. Korean Institute of Public Finance. Retrived from www.gemini.econ.umd.edu/cgi-bin/conference/ Kathuria,V. (2001). Vehicular Pollution Controls in Delhi, India-Are the efforts enough? The Beijer Institute, International institute of Ecological Economics . King, M.A. (1983). Welfare Analysis of Tax Reforms Using Household Data. Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 21 pp. 183-214. Mulat, T. (1979). The Revenue Effectiveness of Ethiopian Coffee Export Taxation. Public Finance, Vol. xxxiv, No. 3. Munoz,S. and Cho, S.W. (2003). Social Impact of a Tax Reform. The Case of Ethiopia, IMF working paper, wp 03/232. Musgrave,R.(1967) .Fiscal Systems. New Haven and London, Yale University Press. Newberry, D. and Stern, N.H. (1987). The Theory of Taxation for Developing Countries. Oxford University Press, New York. Newberry, D. (1995). The Distributional Impact of Price Changes in Hungary and the United Kingdom. The Economic Journal, vol. 105(3): 847-863. 27 Olivia S. and Gibson J. (2003). Equity and Efficiency Aspects of Indirect Tax and Subsidy Reform in Indonesia. Retrieved from URL: www.nzae.org.nz/files/%2358-OLIVIA-GIBSON Ostro, Bart. (1992) Estimating the Health and Economic Effects of Particulate Matter in Jakarta: A Preliminary Assessment, Paper Presented at the Fourth Annual Meeting of the International Society for Environmental Epidemiology, 26-29 August. Cuernavaca, Mexico Profeta, P. (2003). Tax Systems and Tax Reforms in Europe: Public Finance and Political Economy. Working paper No. 197 197/2003, Societal Italiana Dieconomic Pubblica. Pudney, M. Markvov, N. and Ackrill, R. (1990). Indirect Tax Reform in Bulgaria. Public Sector Economics Research Center, University of Leicester. Sadoulet, E. and de Janvry, A. (1995). Quantitative Development Policy Analysis. The Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore and London. Schenk, A. (2002). On the Implementation of the Ethiopian Value Added Tax. Seminar on Proposed Ethiopian Value Added Tax, May , Ministry of Revenue. Seifu, M. (1998). Performance of The Ethiopian Sales and Excise Tax. Addis Ababa University, School of Graduate Studies. M.Sc. Thesis. Slesnick, D.T. (1991). Empirical Approaches to the Measurement of Welfare. Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 37, pp. 2108-2165. Yeshanew, T. (2001). Household Consumption Behavior in Ethiopia. An Urban-Rural Comparison using Microeconomic Data. M.Sc thesis, Addis Ababa University. Zelalem, Y. (1998). Revenue Productivity of the Tax System in Ethiopia. M.Sc. Thesis, Addis Ababa University. 28 Appendix -The distributional characteristics of goods and services (Di) Items E=0 Pepper (Berbere) 0.014421 Abish (Local spice) 0.002636 Jinger (Jinjible) 0.001573 Other Spices 0.00394 Milk 0.012927 Cheese 0.005023 Butter 0.051098 Beef 0.071751 Mutton 0.075671 Chicken 0.005891 Eggs 0.007153 Fish 0.001953 Bread (Local bread) 0.000119 Bread 0.03452 Furno Duket( Wheat flour) 0.010911 Pasta (Spaghetti) 0.017492 Enset (Popular food in the southern Ethiopia) 0.001926 Salt 0.007998 Cooking oil 0.036647 Potatoes 0.015865 Tomatoes 0.011164 Carrot 0.006506 Gomen (Cabbage) 0.005447 Keyser (Red Potatoes) 0.001218 Karia (Green Pepper) 0.0047 Oranges 0.006264 Banana 0.005332 Papaya 0.001165 Pineapple 2.74E-05 Avocado 0.00028 Tella (Local beer) 0.002447 Tejj (Local drink) 0.001492 Araki (Local drink) 182458.4 Soft Drinks 0.012879 Beer 0.004688 Other liquor 0.000253 Coffee bean 0.035869 Tea leaves 0.009119 Chat (Stimulant leaves) 0.007348 29 Rank 29 56 64 52 32 48 6 4 5 45 42 60 76 11 E=0.5 0.002636 0.000682 0.000687 0.00115 0.002305 0.00064 0.005085 0.00779 0.00866 0.000938 0.001784 0.000388 3.62E-05 0.006969 35 24 61 39 9 26 34 43 46 66 49 44 47 67 77 73 58 65 1 33 50 75 10 36 41 Rank 28 57 56 45 33 58 16 6 7 47 38 65 76 8 E=1 0.000827 0.000319 0.000469 0.000613 0.000635 0.000138 0.000778 0.00127 0.00128 0.000215 0.000635 0.000119 1.48E-05 0.002183 Rank 33 52 48 42 40 64 34 23 24 58 40 66 75 12 E=2 5.89E-05 4.33E-05 0.000106 0.000138 2.25E-05 3.92E-06 1.08E-05 1.5E-05 1.6E-05 5.43E-06 2.84E-05 5.44E-06 9.27E-07 0.000107 Rank 36 40 31 25 50 70 59 53 54 65 45 64 75 30 E=5 4.79E-08 6.73E-09 6.26E-08 3.99E-07 7.61E-11 7.73E-12 8.76E-10 8.17E-13 8.18E-13 8.85E-12 3.26E-11 2.9E-11 4.09E-12 3.22E-09 0.001238 43 0.003366 23 0.000299 0.000909 53 30 1.08E-05 2.51E-05 58 47 4.33E-11 62 1.61E-11 66 0.00047 0.002189 0.005668 0.004712 0.003784 0.001722 0.002219 0.000584 0.002353 0.001539 0.001427 0.00031 7.41E-06 4.39E-05 0.000564 0.000254 302096.3 0.00207 0.000317 7.1E-05 0.007797 0.003132 0.001049 0.000178 0.001373 0.001433 0.002183 0.001934 0.000936 0.001294 0.000395 0.001902 0.000541 0.000538 0.000121 2.47E-06 1.23E-05 0.000222 6.67E-05 404875.1 0.000538 5.93E-05 2.72E-05 0.002512 0.001885 0.000235 60 20 19 12 15 28 22 49 16 44 45 65 77 76 57 71 1 45 72 74 10 17 56 1.35E-05 0.000297 6.08E-05 0.000182 0.000211 0.00013 0.000176 7.25E-05 0.000573 2.39E-05 2.89E-05 7.7E-06 7.27E-08 5.05E-07 1.65E-05 2.29E-06 2751855 1.79E-05 2.35E-06 1.5E-06 0.000133 0.000376 6.27E-06 56 12 34 17 16 28 19 32 6 48 44 61 77 76 52 73 1 51 72 74 27 9 63 2.04E-09 47 1.43E-07 23 5.71E-09 44 2.83E-09 46 1.18E-08 39 4.52E-08 31 4.77E-08 30 7.59E-08 26 8.52E-07 15 4.47E-11 61 9.94E-10 49 9.84E-11 57 0 77 2.72E-13 76 2.01E-10 54 5.14E-12 70 2.94E+11 1 1.88E-11 65 5.57E-11 59 4.63E-12 71 2.62E-08 34 4.96E-07 16 1.11E-11 67 64 36 12 18 20 39 35 60 32 40 42 68 77 75 62 70 1 37 67 74 5 25 46 Rank 29 43 28 18 58 69 51 74 75 68 63 64 72 45 Cigarettes 0.001672 63 0.000296 69 8.4E-05 69 4.76E-06 Sugar 0.039062 8 0.008485 4 0.002776 7 0.000148 Honey 0.008243 38 0.000938 48 0.000168 61 6.66E-06 Injera (pancake like bread) 0.18257 2 0.043943 2 0.018514 2 0.002126 Clothes /Shoes for men 0.020494 17 0.002462 31 0.000479 47 1.21E-05 Clothes /Shoes for women 0.01763 22 0.002632 29 0.00064 39 2.31E-05 Clothes /Shoes for boys 0.01967 20 0.002799 27 0.000669 37 2.57E-05 Clothes /Shoes for girls 0.018411 21 0.002882 26 0.000721 36 3.34E-05 Sheets, Towels, Blanket 0.003383 53 0.000577 61 0.000146 63 4.14E-06 Kitchen Equipments 0.002544 57 0.000525 63 0.000242 55 4.6E-05 Furniture 0.00898 37 0.000621 59 0.000101 67 4.89E-06 Lamp/Torch 0.000276 74 0.000223 71 0.000273 54 0.000173 Matches 0.002396 59 0.002222 34 0.003284 4 0.003216 Batteries 0.00056 71 0.000374 66 0.000359 50 0.000136 Candles 0.001119 68 0.000906 49 0.001191 25 0.001007 Bulbs 0.001011 69 0.000841 52 0.00105 26 0.0006 Charcoal 0.016164 25 0.005137 15 0.002397 11 0.000309 Fuel wood 0.017575 23 0.004946 17 0.002013 14 0.000152 Kerosene 0.022535 15 0.006371 10 0.002573 9 0.000234 Laundry Soap 0.014527 28 0.005488 14 0.003047 6 0.000444 Toilet Soap 0.001906 62 0.000857 51 0.000609 43 0.000154 Other Personal care 0.004495 51 0.001448 41 0.000746 35 0.000115 Building Material 0.014261 30 0.000809 53 9.88E-05 68 4.81E-06 Housing maintenance 0.019775 19 0.001208 44 0.000163 62 7.93E-06 Ceremonial expenses 0.080685 3 0.006484 9 0.001358 21 6.08E-05 Contribution to Iddir (association) 0.020212 18 0.006169 11 0.002746 8 0.000272 Donation to religious service 0.003072 55 0.000891 50 0.000666 38 0.000334 Taxes (excluding income tax) 0.007579 40 0.000776 54 0.00018 59 1.43E-05 Other contribution 0.003176 54 0.000726 55 0.000351 51 6.92E-05 Modern Medical service 0.032098 12 0.003703 21 0.000919 29 5.62E-05 Traditional Medicine and Healers 0.000735 70 0.00017 72 7.92E-05 70 3.49E-05 School fees 0.030591 13 0.003592 22 0.000901 32 5.74E-05 Other education 0.014218 31 0.002594 30 0.000943 27 0.00016 Water bill 0.015528 27 0.005583 13 0.003071 5 0.000437 Electricity 0.047361 7 0.009947 3 0.00343 3 0.000259 Telephone bill 0.020584 16 0.003311 24 0.000904 31 4.28E-05 Rent 0.025404 14 0.004423 19 0.00175 18 0.000179 Source: Calculation based on urban socio-economic data, 2000,of Addis Ababa University 30 68 24 62 3 57 8.9E-10 1.13E-08 3.41E-08 1.61E-06 1.64E-10 50 40 32 12 55 49 46 43 69 39 66 20 2 26 4 5 11 23 15 7 22 29 67 60 35 1.01E-10 1.21E-09 8.71E-08 3.23E-12 6.96E-08 3.29E-10 2.3E-05 0.000724 4.31E-06 4.02E-05 6.06E-06 3.15E-06 1.6E-08 2.24E-05 3.3E-07 1.7E-07 1.58E-06 5.67E-10 1.33E-08 9.45E-09 56 48 25 73 27 53 5 2 8 4 7 9 35 6 20 22 13 52 38 42 13 3.14E-07 21 10 0.000288 3 55 33 38 1.42E-08 36 4.64E-07 17 2.92E-08 33 42 37 21 8 14 41 18 1.76E-06 1.02E-08 2.48E-06 3.88E-07 1.5E-06 1.34E-07 1.37E-08 11 41 10 19 14 24 37 31