Lecture Notes for Economics 435: Economics of Resources Prepared by Gunnar Knapp, Professor of Economics January 17, 2000 MEASURING NON-MARKET VALUES There is currently a great deal of interest among economists in the problem of valuing nonmarket resources. Non-market resources provide outputs or services which are not bought and sold, such as recreation, wilderness, and clean air. We know that these are valuable and important--but how valuable and important are they? There are many important public policy issues which involve tradeoffs between these nonmarket outputs and other outputs which have easily measurable values, such as timber, oil, or electricity. For instance, forests may be used to produce timber or to produce scenic environments for hiking trails. City land may be used for convention centers or for parks. Air may be used for cheaply disposing of residues from burning coal to produce electricity--or may instead be kept clean so that we can see distant mountains. We can keep the Grand Canyon as it is to enjoy the scenery, or we could fill it up to generate hydroelectric power. Economists, who are concerned with efficiency in the allocation of scarce resources, are concerned with how these kinds of tradeoffs should be evaluated. They argue that we can make better decisions about such tradeoffs if we can devise ways to measure the value of non-priced outputs. Kinds of Value Economists suggest that there are different reasons for which we attach value to nom-market resources, or different kinds of value. The most obvious of these is use value: the value we derive from actually using or enjoying a resource. If I visit Alaska's Prince William Sound and enjoy the magnificent views and the wildlife and the sense of wilderness, then I am deriving use value from this non-market resource. However, I may still derive value from Prince William Sound even if I never visit. I may have never been to Prince William Sound, but I may place some value on it just because of the possibility that I will be able to go there at some time in the future. Economists use the term option value for the value we derive from the option of using a non-market resource in the future. Or I may know that I will never be able to go to Prince William Sound, but I may still place value upon just knowing that it is there. Economists use the term existence value for the value we derive purely from the existence of a resource. In our discussion below we will focus primarily upon the problem of defining and measuring use value. Defining Value Economics of Resources Lecture Notes: Nonmarket Values, page 1 In order to measure value, it is first necessary to define it. Economists generally define value in either terms of willingness-to-pay (WTP) or willingness-to-accept (WTA). Which definition is appropriate depends on the purposes for which we are measuring value: in many situations, the definitions are equivalent. In this lecture, we will discuss how economists measure value defined in terms of willingness-to-pay. At the end of the lecture, we will discuss when willingness-toaccept is a more appropriate definition. Economists define the value of a market good which is consumed by one buyer, such as an apple, as whatever that buyer is willing to pay for it If a good which is individually consumed is regularly bought and sold in a market, then the price paid provides a good indication of the value of that good to the people who actually buy it. (For reasons I discuss below, the price paid may not be the precise willingness-to-pay or value, but it is likely to be fairly close). Economists define the value of a market good which is collectively consumed, such as a theater performance or a professional boxing match, as the total amount which the ticket-buyers are willing to pay for it . If a good which is collectively consumed is regularly bought and sold, then we can get a good sense of the value of that good by observing the total amount actually paid by consumers. The value of a non-market good or service--one which is not regularly bought and sold--cannot be observed from a market price. Using the concept of willingness-to-pay, economists define the value of an individually consumed nonmarket good as what the individual consumer would be willing to pay to consume the good--if he or she had to pay for the right to pick berries. If I pick berries for free in the park, their value is what I would be willing to pay for the right to pick the berries, if I had to pay. Economists define the value of a collectively consumed nonmarket good as the total amount the public would be willing to pay for the good if they actually did have to pay for it directly. If my neighbors and I use a local park, the value of the park is the total of what each of us would be willing to pay for the right to use the park, if we had to pay. This is the definition which is relevant for measuring the value of collectively consumed nonmarket goods such as clean air, wilderness, and the existence of species. Value and the demand curve We can use a demand curve to depict these definitions of value. Recall that the demand curve illustrates, for any given price, the total quantity which buyers would be willing to buy during a given time period. At any given quantity, the height of the demand curve shows the amount which some buyer is willing to pay for the last unit purchased. The area under the demand curve corresponding to that last unit also shows the amount which some buyer is willing to pay for this last unit (since this area is approximately a rectangle with a width of one and the height of the demand curve). Economics of Resources Lecture Notes: Nonmarket Values, page 2 Height of the demand curve shows amount that someone would be willing to pay for the first unit. Because the width is one, area also shows approximate amout that someone would be willing to pay for the first unit. Price Height and area show willingness to pay for sixth unit. Q*. 1 6 Quantity The total area under the demand curve, out to any given quantity, shows the total willingness-topay for that quantity.1 It represents the total amount which could theoretically be extracted from buyers if units were sold one at a time to the highest bidder. Economists divide this total willingness to pay into two parts: the amount which is actually paid (or the price times the quantity) and the amount which consumers don't have to pay, which they refer to as consumer surplus. The consumer surplus is the area under the demand curve down to the market-clearing price. Price Area = consumer surplus Area = actual payment P* Q* Quantity For market goods, the willingness-to-pay for marginal quantities (the last units consumed) is mostly captured in the actual price the buyer pays.2 In contrast, for non-market goods, which are consumed for free, the willingness-to-pay for marginal quantities is entirely consumer surplus. 1Technically, willingness-to-pay may vary slightly from the area under the demand curve due to the effects on buyers' ability to pay of changes in the amounts which they actually purchase. However, the area under the demand curve is a valid approximation of willingness-to-pay for our purposes. 2The extent to which willingness-to-pay is reflected in the actual price depends upon the shape of the demand curve. If the demand curve is flat, or "perfectly elastic," then consumer surplus is zero. The steeper the demand curve, or the more "inelastic," the greater consumer surplus will be. Economics of Resources Lecture Notes: Nonmarket Values, page 3 Price For a market good, the total willingness to pay for the last unit Q* is primarily captured in the price the buyer pays. Consumer surplus is small. Consumer surplus P* Amont paid by buyer Q* = market clearing quantity. Price Quantity For a non-market good in limited supply (such as a free campground with a limited number of camping spaces), the total willingness to pay for the last unit Q* is entirely consumer surplus, since the consumer of the last unit doesn't have to pay for it. Consumer surplus Q* = last unit consumed. Quantity In defining value it is very important to distinguish between the value (market or non-market) of the last or marginal units consumed, and the total value provided by all goods. For market goods, the value of the last or marginal unit is essentially equal to the price. This is not the case if we wish to discuss the total value of all goods consumed, however, since the total value of all goods may include significant consumer surplus. When we talk about the value of market resources, we are usually talking about the value of these resources at the margin. Similarly, when we measure the value of non-market resources, we are usually interested in measuring the value associated with small changes in the quantity or character of the resource. You should be cautious about extending the average value measured for marginal units of a resource to the total resource. This is a common and potentially serious error. Value varies Saying that marginal value depends upon the total quantity consumed is another way of saying one of the basic principles of resource economics: value varies. Value is not absolute. Value depends upon the circumstances. This is because our willingness-to-pay for another unit of a resource is not fixed: it depends upon the circumstances. Economics of Resources Lecture Notes: Nonmarket Values, page 4 This is simply another way of saying that the demand curve slopes downward. The more we have of a resource, the less we are willing to pay for the next unit. If we can easily obtain water from abundant nearby lakes or streams or faucets, then we are not willing to pay very much for an additional gallon of water. But if we are dying of thirst in the desert, then we are willing to pay a lot for an additional gallon of water. If the whole country is wilderness, then our willingness-to-pay to preserve one additional valley as wilderness is likely to be fairly small. However, if the valley is the last remaining wilderness in the country, then we may be willing to pay a lot to preserve it as wilderness. Methods of Measuring Willingness-to-Pay It is one thing to define value as willingness-to-pay. It is another thing to measure it. How do we learn what people are willing to pay if they don't actually have to pay? Over the past three decades, economists have devoted a great deal of attention to this problem. They have devised a variety of methods for measuring willingness-to-pay. Although the basic principles behind these methods have gained general acceptance among economists, there is still a lot of debate about the details. Economists have developed both direct and indirect methods for measuring willingness-to-pay. Direct Methods of Measuring Willingness-to-Pay Direct methods of measuring non-market values are based upon asking people directly about their willingness-to-pay, in interviews or by using survey questionnaires. For example, if we wished to know the non-market value of keeping the Arctic National Wildlife Refuge (ANWR) an undeveloped wilderness, we could interview everyone in the United States and ask them what they would be willing to pay to keep ANWR an undeveloped wilderness. Or we could extrapolate the answers by interviewing a sample of the total population. There are two major problems with direct methods for measuring willingness to pay. The first is that is that interviewing people is expensive. The second problem, which is perhaps more serious, is that people may give inaccurate answers about willingness-to-pay, for various reasons: o They may wish to influence the survey results by making the value appear either high or low (this is known as strategic answering, which causes strategic bias). For example, if the city is measuring the non-market value of the flower gardens it plants, and I like flower gardens, then I may deliberately overstate my willingness-to-pay for flower gardens. On the other hand, if I like flower gardens, but worry that my tax liability will be based directly upon my answer, I may deliberately understate my willingness-to-pay. Economics of Resources Lecture Notes: Nonmarket Values, page 5 o They may not give much thought or effort to answering the question accurately. For example, they may exaggerate their actual ability to pay for something they know they like. This problem is known as hypothetical bias. o They may give different answers depending upon how the question is framed. For example, asking people about how much they would be willing to pay using different methods or vehicles for payment (for example, an annual payment vs. a per-visit payment) may result in different answers. This problem is known as vehicular bias. For these reasons, it is very important to design contingent valuation survey questions as carefully as possible to minimize these kinds of biases. Some economists question whether it is even possible to get accurate answers about willingness to pay by asking people directly. Indirect Methods of Measuring Willingness-to-Pay Indirect methods of measuring non-market values are based upon inferring willingness-to-pay from their actual payments for other goods or services which are associated with their use of the non-market resource. The basic advantage of indirect methods is that they are based on actual behavior. The basic disadvantage of indirect methods is that they can only be used to measure use value: they cannot be used to measure other kinds of non-market value such as option value or existence value. Hedonic Valuation One indirect method of inferring willingness-to-pay for non-market resources is to observe how much people are willing to pay for other resources which convey the right or ability to use a nonmarket resource. This method is known as hedonic valuation. One common application of hedonic valuation is the study of how housing prices are affected by scenic views or by proximity to parks. Houses near parks or with scenic views tend to be worth more (and houses under airport runway approaches tend to be worth less). Measuring these differences (while accounting for other possible reasons for which housing prices may vary) is one way of inferring the value of parks or scenic views. Although the property owners or renters don't pay directly for these non-market outputs, they do pay indirectly by paying for the property which provides them the ability to enjoy the park or view. The Travel Cost Method Another indirect method of measuring non-market values is to infer willingness-to-pay from differing usage patterns for people who face different costs in using a resource. One cost which differs among different users of nonmarket resources is the travel cost in getting to the resource, such as expenditures for fuel or tickets and the opportunity cost of travel time. Some people live close to a resource and can use it at little cost. Others live farther away and face greater costs. The travel-cost method of measuring willingness-to-pay is based on how usage varies among people who face different travel costs. The Travel Cost Method: A Simple Example Economics of Resources Lecture Notes: Nonmarket Values, page 6 The calculations involved in using the travel cost method can be quite complicated. As a simple example, we can describe how we might use this method to measure calculate the aggregate demand for a fishing stream. Suppose that there are only four fishermen: John, Paul, George and Ringo. They are identical in all respects except that they live different distances from the stream, which means that they face different costs in getting to the stream. The distances and costs are shown in the table on the next page. Derivation of a demand curve for fishing stream use, given different assumed prices for stream use, based on observed behavior with different travel costs. John Travel distance to stream Total cost of using the stream when the price of using the stream is 0: Cost per fishing trip, @ 20 cents/mile P rice paid to use stream Total cost of using stream Actual f ishing trips per year when the price of using the stream is 0: Total cost of using the stream if the price of using the stream were 1: Cost per fishing trip, @ 20 cents/mile P rice paid to use stream Total cost of using stream *Assumed f ishing trips per year if the price of using the stream were 1: Total cost of using the stream if the price of using the stream were 2: Cost per fishing trip, @ 20 cents/mile P rice paid to use stream Total cost of using stream *Assumed f ishing trips per year if the price of using the stream were 2: 0 P aul George Ringo 5 10 15 0 0 0 1 0 1 2 0 2 3 0 3 15 10 5 0 0 1 1 1 1 2 2 1 3 3 1 4 10 5 0 0 0 2 2 1 2 3 2 2 4 3 2 5 5 0 0 0 Total fishing trips 30 15 5 Total cost of using the stream if the price of using the stream were 3: Cost per fishing trip, @ 20 cents/mile 0 1 2 3 P rice paid to use stream 3 3 3 3 Total cost of using stream 3 4 5 6 *Assumed f ishing trips per year if the price of using the stream were 3: 0 0 0 0 0 * Calculated based on actual usage of otherwise identical individuals facing different travel costs, when the price paid to use the stream is zero. As a result of these differences in travel costs, the fishermen fish different numbers of times per year. John, who faces no travel costs, fishes 15 times per year. George, who faces a travel cost of $2 each time he uses the stream, fishes only 5 times per year. Economics of Resources Lecture Notes: Nonmarket Values, page 7 Observed Trips per Year for Individuals Facing Different Travel Costs Travel cost per trip Ringo 3 2.5 George 2 1.5 Paul 1 0.5 John 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 Trips per year We can use our data on trips and travel costs to estimate an aggregate demand curve for the using the stream. At present, the fishermen pay no price to use the stream: no one is standing at the bank collecting a fishing permit charge. In other words, the price is zero. This represents one point on our estimated demand curve. We can estimate how many trips the fishermen would make if the price were one if we assume that they would each respond to an increase in the price at the stream bank in the same way that they would respond to an increase in travel cost. If an official collected a price of $1 at the stream bank, this would raise the total cost of fishing by $1 for each fishermen. Paul, who formerly faced a total fishing cost of only $1, now would face a total fishing cost of $2. We know that when George faced a total fishing price of $2, he only fished 5 times per year. We can therefore assume that Paul would now fish only 5 times per year. Using the same method, we can work out how much each of the others would fish at a price of $1, as well as how much they would fish at a price of $2 and a price of $3. This gives us the aggregate demand curve shown below which shows estimated use as a function of price (paid at the stream bank) per use. Study the table carefully and make sure you understand how the demand curve is derived! Estimated Aggregate Demand Curve for S tream price per use 3 2.5 Demand curve 2.5 Area under the demand curve = consumer surplus; numbers show area of different rectangles and triangles. 2 1.5 5 10 1 0.5 10= 2 x 5 7.5= 1/2 x 1 x 15 0 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 Total use per year Using this estimated demand curve, we can estimate the total use associated with different prices. We can also estimate the consumer surplus or value the fishermen receive from using the stream. The total consumer surplus is the area under the curve, which can be estimated as 35 by dividing the area into different triangles and rectangles. (Remember that the formula for Economics of Resources Lecture Notes: Nonmarket Values, page 8 the area of a triangle is one-half the base times the height!) We can also estimate the value of marginal uses. For example, the consumer surplus, or area under the curve, for the last fifteen uses is 1/2 x 1 x 15 = 7.5. Problems with Indirect Methods of Measuring Non-Market Values Indirect methods such as the travel cost method have the important advantage of being based upon what people actually do, rather than what they say. Unfortunately, these methods usually require collection of extensive data on both usage patterns as well travel costs and other costs incurred by the users of non-market resources. One potentially important cost, which is not easy to measure, is the value of the time people spend in using the resource. Travel cost models usually require numerous simplifying assumptions in order to estimate demand curves. In our example, we had to assume that all four fishermen would respond identically to changes in the total costs of fishing. The actual calculations to derive the demand curves can be quite complicated. Measuring Option Value and Existence Value As we stated earlier, adding to the problems associated with measuring non-market value, economists have pointed out that the persons who place value upon non-market goods or services, and who might be willing to pay for them, are not necessarily limited to direct users of the goods or services. Some people may be willing to pay for the option to use a resource in the future, or even just to know that it exists. A wide variety of philosophical and practical questions are associated with the issue of whether to include these kinds of value in non-market value, and if so how to measure them. It may well be that many people in society place both option value and existence value upon many market goods, even if they never spend the money to buy them. Does Disneyland have option value and existence value? Do Porsche sports cars? If we don't (usually) include option and existence values in measuring the value of market goods and services, should we for non-market goods and services? Willingness-to-Pay vs. Willingness-to-Accept Our discussion in this lecture has been based on defining non-market value in terms of willingness-to-pay. As we mentioned at the beginning of the lecture, economists sometimes define value in terms of willingness-to-accept. We can measure the value of something that we don't have in terms of what we would be willingto-pay to get it. How shall we value something that we do have? It may be appropriate to define the value in terms of our willingness-to-accept compensation for giving it up. Willingness-to-pay and willingness-to-accept are likely to be similar for goods which can be easily bought and sold. If there are no transaction costs, I will be willing to accept the same price in selling an apple that I would have to pay to get another apple. Economics of Resources Lecture Notes: Nonmarket Values, page 9 However, willingness-to-pay may differ substantially from willingness-to-accept for goods or resources which have a high value, and for which the amount we would have to pay represents a substantial portion of our income. In this case our willingness-to-pay is not only affected by how much pleasure or utility we get from the good or resource relative to other goods or resources, but also by our income. We may be constrained in what we are willing to pay by our ability to pay. Consider the example of what you would be willing to pay in ransom money to save your life. All your wealth, perhaps, and all you can borrow as well. But no more, because you're not able to pay more. On the other hand, consider what you would be willing-to-accept as a payment from somebody in order for the right to kill you. You might not accept any amount of payment. In technical terms, there is no upper income constraint to your willingness-to-accept payment for your life. Which value definition is appropriate for non-market resources can be a matter of considerable debate. If we are considering flooding the Grand Canyon to generate hydro-electric power, should we be asking what Americans are willing to pay to preserve the Grand Canyon as it is? Or should we be asking what we are willing to accept in order to give up what we have? Not everyone agrees. Using Non-Market Value Information Once we have calculated non-market values, what do we do with the information? Generally the purpose of estimating non-market values is to use the information for cost-benefit analysis, in order to better take account of non-market values which may be involved in public policy decisions. Several kinds of problems can arise in using non-market value information. One problem is improper interpretations of what has been calculated. One common logical mistake is to use the total non-market value of a resource as an argument in cost-benefit reasoning, rather than the marginal change in non-market value associated with the specific public policy choice. For example, in making the policy decision over whether to explore for and develop oil in the Arctic National Wildlife Refuge (ANWR), the total non-market value ANWR is probably irrelevant to correct cost-benefit analysis. What matters is how the total non-market value of ANWR would change as a result of oil drilling and development. A second problem, which perhaps troubles me more than most economists, is whether knowing non-market values is actually useful for public policy discussions. Non-market values are calculated to ensure that non-market benefits receive proper weighting in cost-benefit calculations. But cost-benefit calculations never resolve public policy issues anyway: ultimately public policy decisions are settled through the public policy process. If we need to decide whether or not to flood the Grand Canyon for a hydro-electric power project, do we need economists to tell us what we think the Grand Canyon's non-market values are worth? Ultimately, what we decide as a society about how to use the Grand Canyon will reveal our willingness-to-pay as a society for the non-market values of the Grand Canyon--regardless of what our collective total willingness-to-pay as individuals may be. Economics of Resources Lecture Notes: Nonmarket Values, page 10 I raise this argument in part because I am troubled by the temptation to think that we can leave public policy decisions up to bureaucratic technicians who can balance the costs and benefits and tell us the "optimal" thing to do. I worry that we may go too far: in trying to make sure that we not forget about non-market values, we may weaken rather than strengthen the case for nonmarket values. We should not forget that future generations are not asked--and can't be asked-about their willingness-to-pay. Most economists respond to this objection by pointing out that like-it-or-not, many public policy decisions are made by bureaucrats based on technical criteria, and that if these bureaucrats are not told to include non-market values in their cost-benefit decision-making, they won't. Historically, this is exactly what happened. Until economists began to derive measures for nonmarket values, they were often ignored in public policy discussions about the costs and benefits of resource development projects and policies. Theoretical problems with non-market valuation aside, they also raise a very practical problem: calculating non-market values is expensive. It requires extensive data collection and analysis, and even when the calculations are done we are usually quite limited in the ways they can be applied. I personally wonder if the calculation of non-market values is the best use of our limited resources for application of economic analysis to certain public policy issues. Other economists might respond that the costs of not measuring non-market values, in resulting poor policy decisions, are far higher. Economics of Resources Lecture Notes: Nonmarket Values, page 11