Making the Rules Work: Assessing the Performance of Committee Systems in the State Legislative Process - A Preliminary Assessment By Nancy Martorano and Jeffrey Budziak University of Dayton Department of Political Science 300 College Park Dayton, Ohio 45469-1425 Nancy.Martorano@notes.udayton.edu ABSTRACT: Do committee systems that are given powerful procedural tools to impact the legislative process effectively use those tools to influence legislative outcomes? This question is explored using history data from the Iowa and North Dakota state legislatures for the 2001-02 legislative session. This study finds mixed evidence that committees in procedurally autonomous committee systems actually behave that way. Paper prepared for presentation at the 5th Annual Conference on State Politics and Policy, East Lansing, Michigan, May 13-14, 2005. Committee systems have long been of interest to legislative students (see Mezey 1993; Hamm and Squire 2001; Gamm and Huber 2003, for extensive reviews of research on legislative institutions). Most scholars agree that committee systems emerged in response to a need to make the legislative process more manageable. Thus, the primary purpose of committees was to divide an ever-increasing workload among smaller sub-units (Wilson 1885, McConachie 1898). Over time, the committee stage of the legislative process has become known as one of the most active and most important stages in the legislative process. Additionally, past research has shown that legislative structures and procedures have an impact on the legislative process. This research has focused predominately on the U.S. Congress and suggests that structures and procedures add stability to the process by ending majority vote cycling and promoting cooperative behavior amongst members (Sheplse 1979; 1986). Additionally, structures, like committees, can be used by members to gain control over policy areas and cultivate benefits for their districts (Mayhew 1974; Weingast and Marshall 1988). Procedures have been used in the past to suppress or expand the influence of congressional minorities in the legislative process (Dion 1997; Binder 1997). Further, some procedures (i.e., open vs. closed rules) have been used to reduce uncertainty over the outcomes of the legislative process (Bach and Smith 1988; Sinclair 1989, 1994; Rohde 1991). Finally, it has been argued, especially from a comparative perspective, that legislative structures and procedures also play an important role in the institutionalization of legislatures (Evans 1999; Liebert 1998). A last area that has been largely ignored by legislative scholars is assessing the actual effectiveness of a given set of institutions. That is, we know very little about whether or not legislative institutions are actually used and whether or not their adoption and usage leads to the desired outcomes. The goal of this paper is to explore the link between procedural adoption and 1 their usage. Specifically, this paper asks – does the adoption of structures and procedures that create an autonomous committee system effectively lead to a committee system that is in fact an autonomous actor in the legislative process? This question will be explored using data from the 2001-02 legislative sessions in Iowa and North Dakota. Literature and Theory Very little work at the state legislative level has focused on the issue of linking institutions to performance. Most studies of structures and procedure at the state level have focused attention on rule adoption and/or evolution (Hamm, Hedlund and Martorano 2001 and Martorano, Hamm and Hedlund 2000; 2001; Clucas 2001) or exploring the applicability of congressional theory at the state legislative level (Martorano 2004; Martorano, forthcoming; Brown et al. 1997; Overby and Kazee 2000; Overby, Kazee and Prince 2004). A much smaller number of studies have tried to actually relate rules and procedures affecting committees to their performance with mixed results (e.g., Rosenthal, 1974; Hamm and Moncrief, 1982), or have tried to account for changes in the number of committee positions using a variety of rule-based criteria (Hamm and Hedlund, 1990). The most comprehensive study of the role of committees in the state legislative process to date focuses on the relative importance of committees in the state legislative process, and is based largely on a survey of state legislator perceptions of the matter (Francis 1989). Thus, what is missing is a multi-state, longitudinal understanding of how committee systems develop and operate the state legislative level. The lack of organized data may be a reason for this lack of research as the collection and coding of longitudinal data for a large cross-section of state legislative chambers is an enormous and time consuming task. 2 This paper hopes to rectify this situation in part by developing a framework for studying the affect of rules on the functioning of committees in the legislative process. In previous research (Martorano, forthcoming) one of the authors of this study developed a rules based measure of committee system autonomy in the legislative process. This measure was developed by consulting earlier research that had attempted to address the notion of committee system development and effectiveness (Hamm, Hedlund and Martorano 2001 and Martorano, Hamm and Hedlund 2000; 2001; Rosenthal 1973; Davidson and Oleszek 1976). Specifically, the measure taps into the formal powers afforded to committees that allow them to initiate/write and screen bills during the legislative process, as well as protect their actions and decisions from alteration by the floor of the chamber (See Appendix A). This research discovered that there was a wide range of variability evident at the state legislative level regarding committee system autonomy and that some of this variance could be explained from an informational theory perspective of legislative organization (Martorano, forthcoming). What this research did not and could not do was determine whether or not the adoption of rules that foster an autonomous committee system actually translated into a committee system that acted with autonomy in the chamber. The only way to determine whether or not the adoption of autonomous committee rules “matters” is to collect data that explores the actual behavior of committees in the legislative process. Bill history data provides some insight into the behavior of committees. Specifically, it provides a way to determine the extent to which committees introduce, amend, and screen legislation. It also provides a way to assess how “permanent” committee actions are during the final floor stages of the legislative process. In this case, “permanent” refers to the extent to which the decisions made by committees are upheld during the floor consideration stage. 3 Theoretically, we should expect that committees that enjoy rules that lead to higher autonomy would be committees that engage in a higher degree of influence over legislative product. That is, they are more likely to introduce, amend and screen legislation, and they are more likely to have their decisions stand on the floor of the chamber. Thus, our hypotheses in this research are that committees in high committee system autonomy chambers will: 1) Sponsor and introduce more legislation 2) Amend more of the legislation referred to them 3) Screen (i.e.: kill in committee) legislation at a higher rate 4) Have their decisions overruled less by floor amendments; and 5) Possess higher agreement rates between committee recommendations and floor actions Data and Methods The state legislatures of Iowa and North Dakota are the focus of this very preliminary investigation into the linkage between committee procedures and committee behavior. Originally, this paper was to include data on three state legislatures – one that exhibited a highly autonomous committee system, one with a moderately autonomous committee system, and one with a committee system that exhibited a low level of autonomy. However, the availability and quality of bill history data varies tremendously from state to state and given time constraints a decision was made to collect and code data for only four chambers: the Iowa House, Iowa Senate, North Dakota House and North Dakota Senate. In the end, one chamber possesses a committee system that can be considered highly autonomous (Iowa House), one is considered moderately autonomous (Iowa Senate) and two can be classified as possessing a relatively low level of autonomy (North Dakota House and North Dakota Senate). 4 Both states provide complete histories of all legislation introduced that includes detailed information on all committee and floor action. All of this information was accessed via each state legislature’s Internet sites. These data were coded into an Access database by the authors. The narrow cross-section of data employed in this study means that there are significant limitations to the conclusions that can be drawn from it. Therefore, this research accomplishes two, more limited goals. First, it provides the beginnings of a method for determining whether or not legislative institutions (in this case committees) are efficiently utilizing the tools at their disposal. Second, it provides a preliminary test of several hypotheses relating to the linkage between institutional adoption and real behaviors. However, a broader cross-section of states would be necessary to draw major conclusions from this research. Analysis Due to the small sample size in this research, the analysis will be limited to the exploration of descriptive statistics, bivariate correlations and difference of means tests. The dependent variables in the analysis are the extent to which a particular committee engages in a certain activity. A rate of activity was calculated for each standing committee in each chamber. For example, we recorded the history of each bill introduced in each chamber and calculated the percentages of bills sponsored, screened, amended, etc. for each committee. This analysis contains 54 cases representing the 16 standing committees of the Iowa House, the 15 standing committees of the Iowa Senate, the 12 standing committees of the North Dakota House and the 11 standing committees of the North Dakota Senate.1 Table 1 provides some simple summary statistics for the 13 committee activities explored in this analysis. What is clear from this 1 Since the general hypothesis concerns the autonomy of the committee system chamber wide, the most appropriate test would be to calculate rates of committee activity aggregated to the chamber level. We chose to aggregate the data to the committee level to ensure that we attained the minimum number of cases needed to conduct analysis. 5 summary table is that there is quite a bit of variance in the rates at which individual committees engage in any number of behaviors. In all 13 categories there is at least one committee in the dataset that did not engage in a given activity (most likely these are committees like Ethics or Administration and Rules that only had one or sometimes no bills referred to it in a session) and in several cases the maximum value is 100 percent. There is also a good deal of variation of the mean rate of activity in each category with a low of 2.4 percent in the area of committee bill sponsorship and a high of 73.7 percent in floor-committee agreement. Also, many of the standard deviations are quite large indicating that there is a substantial degree of variance in the rates in which particular committees engage in each of these activities. [Table 1 about here] Figures 1 through 4 provide the average rates of individual committee activity assessed by state and chamber (e.g. Iowa House, North Dakota Senate, etc.), committee type as defined by Fenno,2 chamber (i.e., house vs. senate), and committee system autonomy. Thus, the first set of graphs display the averages by state and chamber, the second set by committee type, the third set by chamber and the final set by committee system autonomy. The percentages presented in the figures is the mean rate of activity for the committees that fall in each category. [Figures 1-4 about here] Figure 1 displays three sets of graphs concerning the average rates of activity of committees in the Iowa House and Senate and the North Dakota House and Senate. In all four 2 Fenno (1973) asserted that within the House of Representatives there were three distinct types of committees. First, there are reelection committees such as Agriculture and Interior that allowed members to secure benefits for their constituents. Second, there are committees such as Ways and Means and Appropriations that allow members to accumulate political power within the chamber. Finally, there are policy committees such as Education and Business and Labor that allow members to broadly influence public policy. Given the assumptions and principles of the distributive theory (Shepsle and Weingast 1981), reelection committees should enjoy more autonomy than the other types of committees. Appendix B provides a breakdown of the committees in this analysis by Fenno committee type. 6 chambers, there is a relatively low rate of committee bill sponsorship with committees sponsoring on average only about 2-3 percent of the bills introduced.3 Startlingly, in the North Dakota Senate, on average a committee could expect to have 90 percent of the bills it sponsors referred back to it for further work. This rate is much higher than the other three chambers. Regarding passage rates for committee sponsored legislation, the average rate of passage is substantially higher for committees in the North Dakota legislature than in the Iowa legislature. What happens to bills in these chambers during the committee stage? Not unexpectedly, bills are much more likely to die in committee in the Iowa House and Senate. This difference between the Iowa and North Dakota chambers is due largely by the fact that in both the North Dakota House and Senate, the rules of procedure require that committees consider and report all referred legislation back to the floor. This formal rule does not exist in either the Iowa House or Senate. Because committees in both chambers of the North Dakota legislature are required to consider and report back all legislation, they exhibit a higher rate of activity of recommending that bills either “pass,” “pass with amendments” or “fail.” In the Iowa legislature, committees simply sit by and do nothing to legislation that they deem in appropriate. The findings are more mixed regarding floor activity. On average, committee amendments are adopted at a higher rate by the floor in the North Dakota House and Senate than in the Iowa House and Senate. It is also the case that the floor takes no action on committee reports more in the North Dakota chambers. Once again this difference can be accounted for largely by rules of procedure. Committees in neither Iowa chamber are required to report legislation back to the floor, and so they simply let matters that have no chance of passage die on the committee calendar. Interestingly, both North Dakota chambers enjoy a higher rate of 3 The number of bill introductions for the 2001-02 legislative session are: 1392 (IA House); 888 (IA Senate); 479 (ND House) and 455 (ND Senate). 7 passage and a higher rate of floor-committee agreement. However, when it comes to the floor adopting the report of the committee or amending bills on the floor there is little significant variation. Figure 2 displays the same rates of activity as Figure 1, except now committees have been categorized by Fenno committee type. Is it the case that one type of committee is more active than another type of committee? The answer it appears is largely no. A difference of means test revealed that the only significant difference in mean committee activity by type involves the rate at which the floor adopts committee reports and the rate at which referred bills are passed. Specifically, the committee reports of political power committees are adopted by the floor at rates higher than re-election or policy oriented committees. Additionally, bills referred to political power committees are passed on the floor at higher rates that bills referred to policy committees (but not re-election committees). Chamber also seems to matter little when considering committee activity rates (Figure 3). The only statistically significant difference in mean activity between house and senate chambers is in the area of floor amending. On average senate chambers amend 6 percent more bills on the floor than house chambers. Of primary interest in this research is the impact of the adoption of rules of procedure that afford committees autonomy in the legislative process. Do these rules cause committees to actually behave and/or be treated with more autonomy. Figure 4 displays activity rates by committee system autonomy categorized as being either low, moderate or high.4 There appears to be some very significant differences in activity rates across committees with differing levels of committee system autonomy. However, not all the differences are in the hypothesized direction. 4 Committee system autonomy was calculated for all 99 state legislative chambers by one of the authors (Martorano 2004). Autonomy scores range from 0 to 11. The Iowa House ranks possesses one of the most autonomous committee systems with a score of 9, the Iowa Senate with a score of 7 possesses a moderately autonomous committee system and finally both the North Dakota House and Senate rank at the bottom with autonomy scores of 4 and 3 respectively. 8 Recall that it was hypothesized earlier that committees in chambers with rules fostering an autonomous committee system would be very active in introducing, screening and amending legislation as well as have few of their decisions overruled on the floor of the chamber. In the limited sample of states included in this study, this does not appear to be entirely the case. Committees in more autonomous chambers do in fact screen legislation at a higher rate than less autonomous committee system chambers – only 0.6 percent of the legislation in the low committee system autonomy chambers died in committee compared to 79.7 percent and 93.6 percent in the moderate and highly autonomous committee system chambers.5 This is quite a big difference that is further exasperated by the rule in both North Dakota chambers that requires the reporting of all referred legislation. Interestingly, in most of the other cases our primary hypothesis is not borne out. It is the case that in most of the areas explored in this analysis, the committees in the low committee system autonomy chamber engage in more frequent committee and enjoy a larger degree of support on the floor of the chamber. Committees in the low autonomy category have the bills that they sponsor and review pass at a significantly higher rate. The floor adopts their amendment suggestions at a much higher rate and there is a significantly higher rate of agreement (e.g., the floor carries out the wishes of the committee) between the floor and committee in the low committee system autonomy chambers. A notable exception is the activity of floor amending where committees in moderately autonomous committee system chambers are significantly more likely to have bills referred or sponsored by them amended on the floor. Two other significant differences to note are that committees in the low committee system autonomy chambers recommend that referred bills pass or pass with amendments more 5 Difference of means tests confirmed that this and all subsequent differences in means discussed were indeed statistically significant at the 0.05 (two-tailed) level. 9 than those committees in moderate or high committee system autonomy chambers. Taken at face value this finding also seems to run contrary to expectations. However, it could be the case that since (at least in this sample of states) in the moderate and high committee autonomy chamber there is no requirement to report bills back, that these committees only act on the small number of bills that they know have a good chance at passage in the chamber. Table 2 provides bivariate correlations between committee activity and committee system autonomy.6 These correlations accurately match the patterns evident in the line graphs. Ten of the 13 correlations are statistically significant and only one is positive. There is a positive statistically significant and very strong correlation between committee system autonomy and the percentage of bills that die in committee. This indicates that bills referred to committees are reported back to the floor at much lower rates in highly autonomous committee system chambers than in lower committee system autonomy chambers. This is what we would expect from committees in highly autonomous settings. However, there are negative, statistically significant and relatively strong correlations between committee system autonomy and the percentage of committee sponsored bills passed, the rate at which the floor adopts committee amendments, the overall rate at which bills referred to committees are passed and the extent to which the floor agrees to and carries out recommendations of committees. This is opposite to what we should theoretically expect. Summary and Conclusions In sum, this limited analysis has provided some evidence that committees in state legislative chambers do in fact follow the rules that dictate their activities. The North Dakota 6 The raw committee system autonomy score (see Footnote 4) from Martorano (2004) was used to calculate the correlation. 10 House and Senate each have rules that state that all committees must consider and report back to the floor all legislation referred to them. This appears to be the case. The low floor amending rate in the North Dakota House is due largely to the fact the chamber rules also dictate that floor amending must occur by unanimous consent or bills can be re-referred to committees for amendment consideration by a majority vote. What was surprising to some extent was the degree to which the floor exercised its right to “check” the activity of committees in the more autonomous committee system chambers. This is evident by the extent to which the average rate of committee bill passage, committee amendment passage, referred bill passage and floor-committee agreement was significantly lower than in more autonomous chambers. However, these results must be interpreted and used with extreme caution. This analysis is based on a sample of only four chambers in two states. Thus, it lacks the empirical leverage necessary to draw general conclusions about state legislative behavior. The bottom line is that more data in the form of an increased sample of states is necessary if we are to draw any confident conclusions about the nature of the relationship between rule adoption and behavior in this area. Collecting and coding bill history data is a time consuming process, and it will take a significant time investment to acquire an adequate sample. Thus, a significant contribution of this current paper is that it provides a starting point for framing and organizing this type of data collection. However, the benefits of such a data collection effort would be a tremendous asset to state legislative scholars. The collection of bill history data would allow us to begin to assess whether or not the adoption of particular institutions actually results in the desired behavior. A major shortcoming of much of the institutional research (especially as it relates to rules of 11 procedure studies) is that it is focused much more on the theoretical rather than the empirical. That is, most studies “prove” their hypothesized effect of rule adoption using formal modeling rooted in social choice or game theory. Very few of these models are then empirically tested on real data. I suspect that much of this is driven by the difficulty of working with this data. Further the collection of these data can also allow for research concerning inter-chamber variability in the behavior of legislators and legislative structures, like committees. Is it the case that even in chambers that have rules that allow committees to behave in autonomous ways that some committees are allowed to behave more autonomously than others? This is one of many questions that can be addressed using the type of data employed in this paper. 12 Appendix A: Measuring Institutional Committee Power Power to Receiving Legislation 3 points = All bills must be referred to committees for consideration; bills may be pre-filed; and committees may meet in the interim 2 points = Any two of the three 1 point = Any one of the three 0 points = None of the three Power to Screen Legislation 4 points = Committees do not have to consider all referred bills; no deadline for committee action exists; do not have to report all bills back to the floor; and difficult for the floor to withdraw a bill from committee consideration 3 points = Any three of the four 2 points = Any two of the four 1 point = Any one of the four 0 points = None of the four Power to Shape Legislation 3 points = Committees can introduce legislation; committee amendments are incorporated into bills before floor consideration; and committees may propose substitute bills 2 points = Any two of the three 1 point = Any one of the three 0 points = None of the three Power to Affect Floor Passage 3 points = Adverse committee reports are difficult to overturn on the floor; bills are considered on the floor in the order reported from committees; and amending of bills on the floor is difficult 2 points = Any two of the three 1 point = Any one of the three 0 points = None of the three Power to Gather Information 4 points = Committees may subpoena people; subpoena documents; conduct investigations, and must hold public hearings 3 points = Any three of the four 2 points = Any two of the four 1 point = Any one of the four 0 points = None of the four 13 Appendix B: Iowa and North Dakota Standing Committees Categorized by Type* State/ Chamber Political Committees Re-Election Committees Policy Committees Iowa House Administration & Rules Appropriations Judiciary Ways & Means Agriculture Local Government State Government Transportation Commerce & Regulation Economic Development Education Environmental Protection Ethics Human Resources Labor & Industrial Relations Natural Resources Iowa Senate Appropriations Judiciary Rules & Administration Ways & Means Agriculture Local Government State Government Transportation Business & Labor Relations Commerce Education Ethics Human Resources Natural Resources & Environment Small Business, Economic Development & Tourism North Dakota House Appropriations Finance & Taxation Judiciary Agriculture Government Affairs & Veteran’s Administration Political Subdivisions Transportation Education Human Services Industry, Business & Labor Natural Resources North Dakota Senate Appropriations Judiciary Taxation & Finance Agriculture Government Affairs & Veteran’s Administration Political Subdivisions Transportation Education Human Services Industry, Business & Labor Natural Resources *Type designation taken from Fenno (1973) 14 References Bach, Stanley and Steven S. Smith. 1988. Managing Uncertainty in the House of Representatives: Adaptation and Innovation in Special Rules. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution. Binder, Sarah A. 1997. Minority Rights, Majority Rule, Partisanship and the Development of Congress. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Brown, Robert D., Jennifer M. Davis, L. Marvin Overby, Charles E. Smith, Jr., and David Holian. 1997. “The Dynamics of Committee Outliers: Evidence from the House of Representatives, 1951-90.” Journal of Legislative Studies. 3: 70-88. Clucas, Richard. 2001. “Principal Agent Theory and the Power of State House Speakers,” Legislative Studies Quarterly. 26: 319-38. Davidson, Roger H. and Walter J. Oleszek. 1976. “Adaptation and Consolidation: Structural Innovation in the U.S. House of Representatives.” Legislative Studies Quarterly. 1 (1): 37. Dion, Douglas. 1997. Turning the Legislative Thumbscrew, Minority Rights and Procedural Change in Legislative Politics. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press. Evans, C. Lawrence. 1999. “Legislative Structure: Rules, Precedents, and Jurisdictions.” Legislative Studies Quarterly. 24: 605-42 Fenno, Richard. 1973. Congress in Committees. Boston, MA: Little, Brown. Frances, Wayne L. 1989. The Legislative Committee Game: A Comparative Analysis of Fifty States. Columbus, Ohio: Ohio State University Press. Gamm, Gerald, and John Huber, 2002. “Legislatures as Political Institutions: Beyond the Contemporary Congress.” In The State of the Discipline III, Ira Katznelson and Helen Milner, (eds). Washington, D.C.: American Political Science Association. Hamm, Keith and Ronald Hedlund. 1990. “Accounting for Change in the Number of State Legislative Committee Positions.” Legislative Studies Quarterly. XV: 201-226. Hamm, Keith E., Ronald D. Hedlund, and Nancy Martorano. 2001. “Structuring Committee Decision Making: Rules and Procedures in U.S. State Houses and Senates.” Journal of Legislative Studies. 7: 13-34. 15 Hamm, Keith E. and Gary Moncrief. 1982. “Effects of Structural Change in Legislative Committee Systems on Their Performance in U. S. States,” Legislative Studies Quarterly. 7: 383-99. Hamm, Keith, and Peverill Squire. 2001. “A ‘Tools of the Trade’ Look at Comparing Congress with State Legislatures.” Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association. Maass, Arthur. 1983. Congress and the Common Good. New York, NY: Basic Books. Maltzman, Forrest. 1997. Competing Principles: Committees, Parties and the Organization of Congress. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press. Martorano, Nancy. forthcoming. “Balancing Power: Committee System Autonomy and Legislative Organization.” Legislative Studies Quarterly . 2004a. “Distributing Power: Exploring the Relative Powers of Presiding Officers and Committees in the State Legislative Process,” Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Chicago, Illinois. . 2004b. “Cohesion or Reciprocity? Majority Party Strength and Minority Party Procedural Rights in the Legislative Process,” State Politics and Policy Quarterly. 4: 55-73. Martorano, Nancy, Keith E. Hamm and Ronald D. Hedlund. 2000. “Examining Committee Structures, Procedures, and Powers in U.S. State Legislatures, A Comparative Chamber Analysis.” Paper presented at the annual meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, Chicago, Illinois, April 27-30. Mayhew, David. University Press. 1974. Congress: The Electoral Connection. New Haven, CT: Yale McConachie, Lauros G. 1898. Congressional Committees: A Study of the Origin and Development of Our National and Local Legislative Methods. New York, NY: Crowell. Mezey, Michael. 1993. “Legislatures: Individual Purpose and Institutional Performance,” pp. 335-364 in The State of the Discipline II, Ada W. Finifter, (ed.). Washington, D.C.: American Political Science Association. Overby, L. Marvin and Thomas. A. Kazee. 2000. “Outlying Committees in the Statehouse: An Examination of the Prevalence of Committee Outliers in State Legislatures.” Journal of Politics. 62: 701-28. Overby, L. Marvin, Thomas A. Kazee and David Prince. 2004. “Committee Outliers in State Legislatures,” Legislative Studies Quarterly. 29: 81-107. 16 Rhode, David W. 1991. Parties and Leaders in the Postreform House. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Rosenthal, Alan. 1973. “Legislative Committee Systems: An Exploratory Analysis,” Western Political Quarterly 20: 252-262. Sheplse, Kenneth A. 1979. “Institutional Arrangements and Equilibrium in Multidimensional Voting.” American Journal of Political Science. 23: 27-60. . 1983. “Institutional Equilibrium and Equilibrium Institutions,” In Political Science: The Science of Politics, ed. Herbert F. Weisberg. New York: Agathon Press. . 1986. “Institutional Equilibrium and Equilibrium Institutions.” In Political Science: The Science of Politics, ed. Herbert Weisberg. New York, NY: Agathon. Sheplse, Kenneth A. and Barry R. Weingast. 1981 “Structure Induced Equilibrium and Legislative Choice.” Public Choice. 37: 503-19. Sinclair, Barbara. 1989. The Transformation of the U.S. Senate. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press. . 1994. “House Special Rules and the Institutional Design Controversy.” Legislative Studies Quarterly. 19: 477-94. Weingast, Barry R. and William Marshall. 1988. “The Industrial Organization of Congress.” Journal of Political Economy. 96: 132-63. Wilson, Woodrow. 1885. Congressional Government. New York, NY: Houghton Mifflin. 17 Table 1 Descriptive Statistics (N=54) Minimum Maximum Mean Standard Deviation % Committee Sponsored 0.0 7.2 2.4 1.7 % Committee Bills Re-referred 0.0 100.0 30.6 36.1 % Committee Bills Passed 0.0 100.0 65.0 28.2 % Died in Committee 0.0 100.0 51.1 46.6 % Do Pass 0.0 100.0 17.2 19.1 % Pass w/Amendments 0.0 61.1 18.7 22.2 % Fail 0.0 38.2 9.3 12.3 % Floor Adopts All Comm. Amends 0.0 100.0 58.5 46.6 % Floor Adopts Comm. Report 0.0 100.0 57.7 28.3 % Floor Takes No Action 0.0 75.9 22.1 27.7 % Floor Amends 0.0 29.4 3.3 6.4 % Bills Passed 0.0 100.0 65.0 30.3 % Floor-Committee Agreement 0.0 100.0 73.7 28.0 18 Table 2 Correlation between Committee Activity and Committee System Autonomy (N=54) Pearson’s R^ % Committee Sponsored -.138 % Committee Bills Re-referred -.445*** % Committee Bills Passed -.514*** % Died in Committee .902*** % Do Pass -.623*** % Pass w/Amendments -.889*** % Fail -.849*** % Floor Adopts All Comm. Amends -.688*** % Floor Adopts Comm. Report .112 % Floor Takes No Action % Floor Amends -.914*** .197 % Bills Passed -.826*** % Floor-Committee Agreement -.570*** ^Pearson’s R is employed given that the raw committee system autonomy score, not a categorization, was used to calculate the correlation. *p<.05, **p<.01, ***p<.001 19 Figure 1: Averages by State/Chamber Committee Sponsored Legislation by State/Chamber Committee Action by State/Chamber 100 100 90.9 93.6 90 83.8 90 80.8 80 79.7 80 70 70 IA House IA Senate ND House ND Senate 60 Percent 50.9 53.5 50 40 50 45.1 40 IA House IA Senate ND House ND Senate 42.7 35.7 30 30 21.5 24.8 18.4 20 22.3 22.5 20 12.1 10 1.9 2.6 2.9 2.4 2.8 10 4.0 0 1.2 Committee sponsored Re-referred to sponsoring committee 1.6 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.0 0 Committee bills passed Died in committee Do Pass Pass w/Amends. Fail Floor Action by State/Chamber 120.0 99.0 99.4 100.0 90.8 87.5 80.0 71.0 67.1 Percent Percent 60 60.4 61.5 58.9 60.0 55.6 51.6 50.4 47.7 IA House IA Senate ND House ND Senate 45.1 40.0 31.3 27.8 20.0 11.5 10.7 0.0 0.0 0.7 0.0 0.3 2.7 0.0 Floor adopted all comm. amends. Floor adopted comm. report Floor takes no action Floor amends. Bills passed FloorCommittee agreement 20 Figure 2: Averages by Fenno Committee Type Committee Sponsored Bills by Committee Type Committee Action by Committee Type 80 70 71.5 70 66.9 60 57.3 59.5 60 47.6 50 45.0 Percent 41.7 40 29.0 30 40 30 20.4 21.3 20.5 20.6 20.4 20 16.3 20 12.3 8.9 10 10 3.3 1.9 10.5 8.7 2.3 0 0 Committee sponsored Political Re-referred to sponsoring committee Committee bills passed Re-election Died in committee Do Pass Policy Political Pass w/Amends. Re-election Fail Policy Floor Action by Committee Type 100 87.7 90 80 70 76.2 69.5 66.5 67.3 67.7 60 Percent Percent 50 52.9 50 47.5 50.0 40 34.2 30.9 30.2 30 19.7 20 20.8 18.0 10 4.4 1.9 3.7 0 Floor adopted all comm. amends. Floor adopted comm. report Floor takes no action Political Floor amends. Re-election Bills passed Floor-Committee agreement Policy 21 Figure 3: Averages by Chamber Committee Sponsored Bills by Chamber Committee Action by Chamber 70 66.3 60 63.7 56.0 60 50 46.0 50.8 50 Percent 30 30 22.1 19.3 20 18.1 20 12.5 11.7 2.3 9.5 9.1 10 10 2.5 0 0 Committee sponsored Re-referred to sponsoring committee House Committee bills passed Died in committee Do Pass Senate House Pass w/Amends. Fail Senate Floor Action by Chamber 90 80.1 80 67.4 70 60 Percent Percent 40 40 58.9 58.1 59.0 56.3 50 40 35.0 30 24.9 20.0 19.4 20 10 6.3 0.4 0 Floor adopted all comm. amends. Floor adopted comm. report Floor takes no action House Floor amends. Bills passed Floor-Committee agreement Senate 22 Figure 4: Averages by Committee System Autonomy Committee Sponsored Bills by Committee System Autonomy Committee Action by Committee System Autonomy 90 100 93.6 82.2 90 80 79.7 80 70 70 60 50.9 60 Percent 50 45.0 40 50 43.9 40 30.2 30 30 21.5 22.4 18.4 20 20 12.1 10 10 2.6 2.6 4 1.9 1.6 0.0 Pass w/Amends. Fail 0.6 0 0.0 0 0 Committee sponsored Re-referred to sponsoring committee Low Moderate Committee bills passed Died in committee Do Pass High Low Moderate High Floor Action by Committee System Autonomy 120 100 99.2 89.1 80 71.0 Percent Percent 53.5 61.5 60.4 60 53.6 56.1 53.3 50.4 40 31.3 27.8 20 11.5 10.7 0.0 0 0.2 0.7 2.7 0 Floor adopted all comm. amends. Floor adopted comm. report Floor takes no action Low Floor amends. Moderate Bills passed Floor-Committee agreement High 23