Persuasion by Majorities and Minorities Running Head: CONVERSION THEORY VERSUS OBJECTIVE CONSENSUS Persuasion by Majorities and Minorities: Delineating the Scope of Conversion Theory and Objective Consensus Explanations Gerd Bohner Amanda Dykema-Engblade Universität Bielefeld Loyola University Chicago R. Scott Tindale Helen Meisenhelder Loyola University Chicago Loyola University Chicago Word count 5,007 Author Note Gerd Bohner, Abteilung für Psychologie, Universität Bielefeld, Germany; Amanda Dykema-Engblade, R. Scott Tindale, and Helen Meisenhelder, Department of Psychology, Loyola University Chicago. This research was partially funded by the National Science Foundation (#SES-0136332). We would like to thank Hans-Peter Erb for his thoughtful comments on a previous draft. Portions of this research were presented at Small Group Meetings of the European Association of Experimental Social Psychology on "Minority Influence Processes", Oxford, UK, September 22-26, 2003, and on "The Psychology of Minorities", London, June 27-29, 2003. Correspondence should be addressed to Gerd Bohner, Universität Bielefeld, Abteilung für Psychologie, Postfach 100131, 33659 Bielefeld, Germany (e-mail: gerd.bohner@uni-bielefeld.de), or to Amanda Dykema-Engblade, Department of Psychology, Loyola University Chicago, 6525 N. Sheridan Rd., Chicago, IL 60626 (e-mail: adykema@luc.edu). 1 Persuasion by Majorities and Minorities 2 Abstract Conversion theory and the objective consensus approach were contrasted in explaining effects of minority and majority sources on message processing and attitude judgments. Participants read a persuasive message containing weak, ambiguous, or strong arguments that was attributed to either a majority or a minority source. To prime either social comparison or accuracy concerns, the source was introduced as being either similar to participants or knowledgeable. The dependent variables were cognitive responses to the message and post-message attitudes. Under social comparison priming, the results supported conversion theory: Participants systematically processed minority messages, as indicated by effects of argument strength on thought valence and attitudes, whereas they generally accepted the majority message regardless of argument strength. Under accuracy priming, results supported the consensus approach: For ambiguous arguments, participants showed biased processing based on source consensus, whereas they showed contrast effects for weak (strong) arguments attributed to a majority (minority) source. Persuasion by Majorities and Minorities 3 Persuasion by Majorities and Minorities: Consensus as a Cue to Message Validity versus Normative Functions of Consensus Social consensus is an important determinant of human judgments. While this statement may be noncontroversial, theorists disagree about how consensus affects attitude judgments and information processing, and about the direction of its effects (e.g., Mackie, 1987; Moscovici, 1976, 1980; for discussion see Erb, Bohner, Rank, & Einwiller, 2002). Theories of Minority and Majority Influence According to Moscovici's conversion theory (1980), conflict between the majority and minority groups is the key to explaining influence processes. Majority support for a given position induces normative conflict, whereas minority support instigates informational conflict. Recipients who are exposed to majority influence are thought to engage in social comparison. Their main concern is thought to be the social conflict between their own position and the majority's position, and message content is assumed to be of little importance in determining outcomes. Recipients will show conformity with the majority independent of the majority's arguments. Quite differently, recipients who are under minority influence are thought to solve the informational conflict they experience through an active validation process in which issuerelevant information processing prevails. Hence, the minority message will be elaborated extensively, and this extensive processing may eventually lead to conversion, i.e. attitude change in the direction of the minority's position (see also Maass & Clark, 1984; Nemeth, 1986). Importantly, however, validation attempts will not necessarily lead to conversion. Although this aspect was not emphasized by Moscovici (1980), research guided by process theories of persuasion clearly demonstrated that the outcome of effortful message validation depends on the cogency of the available evidence: Whereas strong evidence will lead to acceptance of the minority's position, weak evidence will lead to its rejection (e.g., Bohner, Persuasion by Majorities and Minorities 4 Moskowitz, & Chaiken, 1995; Martin & Hewstone, 2003; Ziegler, Diehl, Zigon, & Fett, 2004). In contrast to Moscovici's ideas, there is a long tradition of approaches that emphasize the informational value of consensus information, even in the absence of social conflict. Within attribution theory, Kelley (1967) suggested that high consensus for a given position makes people “know that they know” and – all else being equal – promotes entity attributions. Accordingly, recipients under majority (vs. minority) influence should infer high message validity and be concerned with the issue under consideration rather than with the influence source (see Bohner, Erb, Reinhard, & Frank, 1996; Bohner, Frank, & Erb, 1998). In a similar vein, Mackie's (1987) objective consensus approach asserts that the majority position is usually perceived as reflecting "objective reality". Mackie predicted and found that recipients pay close attention to majority messages and process their content more extensively than that of minority messages. Finally, Erb, Bohner, Schmälzle, and Rank (1998) suggested that individuals use mere consensus regarding an attitudinal position to form an initial judgment about this position's validity. In terms of process analyses, Erb and his colleagues' research most clearly demonstrated that recipients of majority (vs. minority) messages indeed formed positive (vs. negative) initial judgments based on perceived consensus. These initial judgments then biased recipients’ subsequent message processing: Mixed evidence led to more positive cognitive responses and attitudes when it came from a majority than when it came from a minority. The consensus-related theories thus share the idea that a high degree of consensus in favor of a position creates an expectation in recipients that this position should be valid, which in turn causes recipients to focus on the issue under consideration. In this regard they are diametrically opposed to conversion theory, which suggests that majority influence (i.e., high consensus) instigates recipients to focus on social comparison, which goes along with a lack of issue-related considerations. The fact that supporting evidence has been reported for both Persuasion by Majorities and Minorities 5 conversion theory (for reviews, see Moscovici, 1980; Wood, Lundgren, Ouellette, Busceme, & Blackstone, 1994) and the consensus approaches (Erb et al., 1998; Erb & Bohner, 2001; Mackie, 1987), suggests that each approach may be valid under certain conditions. The aim of our current research is to explain more precisely what these conditions might be and to demonstrate that both types of effect may be obtained in a single experimental design. Researchers in each school of thought have tended to test their model under specific conditions that may be particularly conducive to producing the model's predicted result pattern, but without explicating these conditions. Evidence for conversion by minorities and compliance to majorities was usually demonstrated under conditions where the influence group's position was either clearly discrepant from recipients' initial attitude on involving issues (see Moscovici, 1976, 1980) or even conflicting with "physical reality", such as when the influence group claimed to perceive blue slides as green (e.g., Moscovici, Lage, & Naffrechoux, 1969). Research in the consensus tradition usually focused on novel issues (e.g., Mackie, 1987), where recipients could not have any clear expectations about the amount of consensus on the issue; also, to demonstrate that social conflict is not a necessary condition for consensus to affect judgments, researchers have studied influence groups that were of little social relevance to participants (Erb et al., 1998, 2002). One might thus be tempted to conclude that a useful way of delimiting the scope of each theory would be by applying each to particular topics and / or types of group. However, we believe that such a distinction by content areas would be less satisfactory than a distinction based on psychological constructs and processes (see Kruglanski & Thompson, 1999, for a similar argument regarding modes of persuasion). One psychological construct that seems to be useful in distinguishing between the conversion theory and objective consensus approaches is perceived message discrepancy, as was shown by Erb and his colleagues (2002). Holding topic Persuasion by Majorities and Minorities 6 and influence group constant, these researchers independently varied level of consensus and message discrepancy. They predicted that minority sources would instigate greater message scrutiny than majority sources for highly discrepant messages, whereas the opposite pattern would obtain for modrately discrepant messages. Two independent studies supported these predictions, showing that message discrepancy indeed moderates the effects of consensus on message processing. In the present paper we extend this research by studying a different moderator of consensus effects, namely the framing of the influence setting as one in which accuracy versus social comparison concerns prevail. Furthermore, we use an expanded experimental paradigm by studying both unambiguous and ambiguous messages. Before describing the method in detail, we will elaborate on each of these aspects and present our specific hypotheses. The Present Research We generally predict that message processing will depend on whether recipients are mainly concerned with potential social conflict, or mainly with determining message validity on the basis of consensus information. In natural situations, the relative strength of these different concerns may depend on various factors, of which the amount of message discrepancy is just one. To test their impact in a more generic way than had previously been done, we used a priming procedure to activate either social comparison concerns or accuracy concerns, holding constant factors such as the topic, the discrepancy of the message, and the influence group. If perceived consensus is used as a cue to message validity whenever accuracy concerns prevail, then consensus information should produce similar effects as other validity cues, for example information about source expertise (e.g., Bohner et al., 1995; Chen & Chaiken, 1999). We therefore modeled our design after recent research in which the effects of expertise cues on message processing had been investigated (Bohner, Ruder, & Erb, 2002). Drawing on the Persuasion by Majorities and Minorities 7 heuristic-systematic model's predictions about the interplay of source information and message arguments (see Bohner et al., 1995), Bohner and his colleagues proposed that information about low vs. high source expertise would create corresponding expectancies about message validity. The effect that these expectancies would have on message processing was predicted to depend on features of the message. For ambiguous messages, biased processing consistent with expectancies was predicted, with resulting attitudes being thus assimilated to the valence of the source information. For unambiguously strong or weak messages, however, expectancies were predicted to function as a standard of comparison, resulting in contrast effects if message quality was discrepant from the expectancies induced by the expertise cue (i.e. strong arguments coming from a nonexpert or weak arguments coming from an expert). Bohner et al.'s results supported these hypotheses: Message recipients reported less favorable thoughts and attitudes after reading weak arguments presented by a high (vs. low) expertise source, but reported more favorable thoughts after reading strong arguments presented by a low (vs. high) expertise source. Conversely, recipients' thoughts and attitudes were more favorable when a high expertise source presented ambiguous arguments than when a low expertise source did so. Following up on the above considerations and findings, the study we conducted featured an extended version of the experimental paradigm by Bohner et al. (2002). Participants in whom either social comparison concerns or accuracy concerns had been primed received information about either high or low source consensus and then read a message containing strong, ambiguous, or weak arguments. Later they reported their thoughts about the message and their attitudes toward the message position. We hypothesized that recipients in whom social comparison concerns were primed would show a processing pattern as predicted by conversion theory. The hallmark of this pattern is systematic processing of minority messages with agreement being a direct function of Persuasion by Majorities and Minorities 8 argument quality, but general agreement with majority messages independent of their quality. In the case of minority messages, we should therefore observe that cognitive responses and post-message attitudes are most positive if the minority's arguments are strong, less positive if those arguments are ambiguous, and the least positive if those arguments are weak. In the case of majority messages, however, strong, ambiguous, and weak arguments should cause hardly any differences in the valence of cognitive responses and all lead to relatively high agreement. This specific interaction pattern of argument quality and source status is depicted in Figure 1 (Panel b). The numbers in Figure 1 represent the weights for a priori contrasts to be used in data analysis. By contrast, we hypothesized that recipients in whom accuracy concerns are primed use consensus information as a cue to message validity ("high consensus implies correctness") in much the same way as recipients in the studies by Bohner et al. (2002) had used expertise information. Their initial consensus-based expectancies should interact with their subsequent processing of message arguments. Specifically, in the case of ambiguous arguments we should observe an assimilative processing bias as a function of consensus-based expectancies, with a majority source leading to more positive cognitive responses and attitudes than a minority source. In the case of unambiguous strong or weak arguments, however, we should observe contrast effects if consensus-based expectancies and message quality are discrepant: In these conditions (i.e. weak arguments coming from a majority or strong arguments coming from a minority), thoughts and attitude judgments should be opposite to the cue-based expectancies, with minorities leading to more positive cognitive responses and attitudes than majorities (see Bohner et al., 1995). This specific interaction pattern of argument quality and source status is depicted in Figure 1 (Panel a). The numbers again represent the weights for a priori contrasts to be used in data analysis. Persuasion by Majorities and Minorities 9 Priming Accuracy Concerns versus Social Comparison Concerns: A Note on Methodology Our aim of creating concerns with accuracy versus social comparison in our participants met with some difficulty, because the manipulation had to be more subtle than those used in previous research. Simply instructing participants to pay close attention to content or intensifying their feeling of accountability (cf. Tetlock, 1985) to raise accuracy concerns, for examples, might easily result in systematic processing of message content independent of minority or majority source status. Similarly, presenting an identity-relevant in-group as message source and directly instructing participants to think about their social relationship to that group to raise social comparison concerns might have eliminated any effect of message content. We therefore resorted to the use of an influence group that (a) could be presented as knowledgeable about the persuasion topic, thereby raising accuracy concerns in a relatively subtle manner, and (b) did not constitute a clear-cut in-group but could be presented as similar to participants, thereby raising social comparison concerns in a subtle manner. We are aware that this manipulation of knowledgeability versus similarity may be open to alternative interpretations, but they seemed sufficiently subtle to enable an initial investigation of our hypotheses without overshooting the mark. Method Adapting and extending the experimental paradigm used by Bohner et al. (2002), we exposed participants to strong, weak, or ambiguous arguments from either a majority or a minority source. In addition, we primed participants to perceive the source either mainly in terms of their knowledge regarding the domain of interest, thus making accuracy concerns salient, or mainly in terms of their similarity to the participants, thus making social comparison concerns salient. The main dependent variables assessed were participants' cognitive responses to the message and their post-message attitudes. The expected result patterns for each priming Persuasion by Majorities and Minorities 10 condition, as outlined above, are represented in Figure 1; the numbers in the figure represent contrast weights that will be applied in the analyses. Participants and Procedure Two hundred and forty two students at Loyola University Chicago participated for course credit in a study allegedly dealing with "text comprehension". Participants were randomly assigned to the conditions of a 2 (priming: accuracy, social comparison) x 2 (source status: minority, majority) x 3 (argument quality: strong, weak, ambiguous) betweenparticipants factorial design. The number of participants per condition ranged from18 to 21. They were asked to read a message about the construction of a traffic tunnel in the city of Rotterdam, and learned that the message source was a group of Rotterdam university students. Rotterdam students were described either as knowledgeable about the issue or as similar to Loyola students; participants also learned that the arguments they would read were endorsed by either a minority or a majority of Rotterdam students. Then participants were asked several questions related to their expectations of the source. Next, participants had one minute to read a strong, weak, or ambiguous message favoring the construction project. Then they were asked to list all of their thoughts that had come to mind while reading the message. Finally, participants reported their attitudes toward building the tunnel. At the completion of the study, participants were debriefed and thanked for their participation. Independent Variables Source status and salience manipulation. Prior to reading the message in favor of building the tunnel, participants received information about the source. In the accuracy priming conditions, the following description was given: "The students at the University of Rotterdam are both active in and informed regarding local politics and environmental issues in Rotterdam. They regularly attend urban planning and development meetings to voice their opinions and Persuasion by Majorities and Minorities 11 stay abreast of current issues. They have researched both the environmental and economic consequences of building the tunnel." In the social comparison priming conditions, the following description was given: "These students, much like you, are members of an introductory psychology class. They live, study, and work in a highly populated city that is culturally diverse and rich in both business and cultural opportunities. Their interests and activities are quite similar to students here at Loyola." Half of the participants were given the majority source version of the description, which indicated that 85% of the Rotterdam students were in favor of the proposal, while the other half were given the minority source version, which indicated that this was true of 15% of the Rotterdam students. Argument quality. The message contained four arguments. Depending on condition, all four arguments were strong, all four arguments were weak, or two arguments were strong and two were weak (ambiguous). For example, in the strong argument condition, participants read that "the tunnel will bring great advantages for residents because the traffic will be reduced by about 80%" and that "the volume of construction orders will increase by about 45%". In the weak argument condition, participants read that "the tunnel will bring great advantages for residents because the traffic will be reduced by about 4%" and "the volume of construction orders will increase by about 0.6%". In the ambiguous argument condition, arguments taken from the strong and weak versions (two each) were presented in alternating order. The message versions had been extensively pilot tested and used in previous research (see Bohner et al., 2002; Erb et al, 1998). Dependent Variables Manipulation checks: Expected message validity and perceived similarity of source. After receiving information about the source but before reading the message, participants responded to one filler question ("How well informed are you personally about the topic 'tunnel Persuasion by Majorities and Minorities 12 construction in Rotterdam'?"). Then they answered three questions designed to assess their expectancies regarding message validity (“How valid will the students’ arguments be?”; “How convincing will the students’ arguments be?”; “How expert do you think the students are with respect to the topic 'tunnel construction in Rotterdam'?”) and one question designed to assess the perceived similarity of the source to themselves (“How similar are the college students from University of Rotterdam to Loyola college students, like you?”). Each question was accompanied by a response scale ranging from 1, "not at all" to 9, "very". It should be noted that these manipulation checks, although not directly assessing concerns with accuracy or social comparison, tap into processes assumed to underlie the effects predicted by the objective consensus and conversion models, respectively. According to the consensus model, recipients form expectancies of message validity that guide their processing, and according to conversion theory, recipients are concerned with the similarity of self and influence group. Thought listing. After reading the message, participants were given three minutes to list any thoughts they had had while reading the text. To do so, they received a sheet with ten boxes and were asked to use one box per thought. It was pointed out that they could use as many or as few boxes as they thought appropriate. After listing their thoughts, participants were asked to read over their thoughts and place a "+" sign in the margin if the thought was positive or in favor of the text, the tunnel project, or the students. Likewise, they were asked to place a "–" sign in the margin if the thought was negative or against the text, the tunnel project, or the students. Attitudes. After completing the thought listing task, participants were asked to indicate their attitude toward the construction of the traffic tunnel in Rotterdam on four items: “The tunnel in Rotterdam should be built”; “Building the tunnel would bring great advantages for the economy”; “The tunnel would bring great advantages for the residents”; and “Harmful Persuasion by Majorities and Minorities 13 consequences of exhaust fumes could be reduced considerably by the tunnel”. All responses were made on nine point rating scales ranging from 1, “do not agree at all”, to 9, “completely agree”. Results Manipulation Checks Expected message validity. An index was formed by averaging participants' responses to the three items on expected message validity (Cronbach's = .78); this index was subjected to a 2 (priming: accuracy, social comparison) by 2 (source status: minority, majority) by 3 (argument quality: strong, weak, ambiguous) analysis of variance (ANOVA; MSE = 1.84). Participants for whom accuracy was primed (M = 5.73) reported higher expectations regarding message validity than did participants for whom social comparison was primed (M = 5.23), F (1, 229) = 8.10, p = .005. Also, participants in the majority condition (M = 5.67) reported higher expectations regarding message validity than did participants in the minority condition (M = 5.29), F (1, 229) = 4.53, p = .034. Although the priming by source status interaction was not significant, F (1, 229) = 1.16, the simple effect of source status was significant only when accuracy had been primed (Mmajority = 6.00 vs. Mminority = 5.45), F (1, 229) = 4.94, p = .027, but not when social comparison had been primed (Mmajority =5.32 vs Mminority = 5.13), F < 1. Thus, the priming manipulation worked as intended: Accuracy priming led to higher expectations of message validity, in particular if the source was a majority. Perceived similarity. An ANOVA on the single item assessing perceived similarity (MSE = 3.59) yielded only the intended main effect of priming: Participants for whom social comparison was primed (M = 6.11) rated the source as being more similar to themselves than did participants for whom accuracy was primed (M = 5.20), F(1, 229) = 13.97, p < .001. Overall, then, the salience manipulation produced the appropriate pre-message expectations. Persuasion by Majorities and Minorities 14 Attitudes and Cognitive Processing The four attitude items were averaged to form a composite attitude score (Cronbach’s = .82). A valenced index of cognitive responses was formed by subtracting, for each participant, the number of negative thoughts generated from the number of positive thoughts generated. Both variables were subjected to a series of contrast analyses associated with our hypotheses. First, for each dependent variable we computed overall contrast effects for all twelve conditions, using the contrast coefficients of Figure 1. In a second step, we analyzed the data from each priming condition separately, again using the contrast coefficients representing the hypothesized pattern (i.e. Figure 1, Panel a for the accuracy conditions and Figure 1, Panel b for the social comparison conditions). Finally, we applied the alternative contrast coefficients (i.e., Figure 1, Panel a for the social comparison conditions and Figure 1, Panel b for the accuracy conditions) in order to explore how well each model could explain the data in conditions "outside of its scope". For each contrast analysis, we also performed tests of residual betweencondition effects to assess not only whether contrasts were significant, but also whether they provided a good fit to the observed data (see Abelson & Prentice, 1997). Thought valence. The pattern of means for thought valence closely matched our predictions (see Figure 2). The overall contrast was highly significant, F (1, 228) = 13.37, p < .001 (MSE = 17.26). It also fit the data very well, as indicated by a nonsignificant test of residual between-condition effects, F (10, 228) = 0.41, ns. The results of separate contrast analyses for each priming condition are presented in Table 1. When accuracy was primed, the z-shaped contrast effect predicted by the consensus model was significant as predicted and represented the observed data pattern very well (see Table 1 and Figure 2, Panel a), whereas the conversion theory contrast was not significant, also as predicted. Thus, minorities produced more positive thoughts than did majorities for both Persuasion by Majorities and Minorities 15 strong and weak arguments (a contrast effect), but produced less positive thoughts than majorities for the ambiguous arguments (an assimilation effect). Conversely, when social comparison was primed, participants seemed to process the minority messages more carefully than the majority messages (see Table 1 and Figure 2, Panel b), the results resembling more the fan-shaped pattern predicted by conversion theory. Here, the consensus model contrast explained hardly any variance, whereas the conversion theory contrast was stronger as predicted, although, considered on its own, it failed to reach significance. An unexpected feature of the results under social comparison priming is the seeming reversal of strong versus weak message means (M = 1.22 vs. 2.25) for the majority source. However, this difference was nonsignificant, t(228) = -0.76, p = .447, for the pairwise comparison. (Statistical power to detect a medium sized effect was .97; Faul & Erdfelder, 1992). Attitudes. The pattern of means for participants' attitudes is presented in Figure 3. An inspection of Figure 3 suggests that the data pattern under social comparison priming closely matched our predictions: Participants' attitudes were differentially affected by the quality of minority arguments, whereas the majority messages were all similarly persuasive regardless of their quality (see Figure 3, Panel b). Under accuracy priming the match appears to be less good. Although the attitude data conformed to the expected pattern for the strong and ambiguous arguments, majorities presenting weak arguments unexpectedly tended to lead to more, rather than less, positive attitudes than minorities (see Figure 3, Panel a), although this difference is much less pronounced than under social comparison priming. We will get back to this point in the Discussion section. This slight deviation from predictions notwithstanding, the overall contrast was both highly significant, F (1, 228) = 30.77, p < .001 (MSE = 2.20), and provided a good fit to the data, as indicated by a nonsignificant test of residual between-condition effects, Persuasion by Majorities and Minorities 16 F (10, 228) = 0.97, ns. The results of separate contrast analyses for each of the priming conditions (see Table 1) were as follows: When accuracy was primed, the consensus model contrast was significant as predicted and explained a larger proportion of variance than the conversion theory contrast, although the latter was significant as well. Residual effects were significant in each case, indicating that neither contrast fully captured the differences between conditions. When social comparison was primed, the conversion theory contrast was significant as predicted and provided a good fit to the data, its residual variance test being nonsignificant. The consensus model contrast, as expected, was not significant and did not fit the observed data pattern, as indicated by a highly significant residual effect. Discussion The results of this study were generally in line with our predictions. Most importantly, the processing consequences of minority and majority source information differed depending on the context in which messages were embedded. When social comparison concerns had been made salient by pointing out similarities between the source and the recipients, the results were in line with the predictions of conversion theory (Moscovici, 1980) in combination with the insights of process models of persuasion (e.g., Bohner et al., 1995): Recipients thoroughly scrutinized minority arguments, and both their thoughts and their attitude judgments reflected the quality of those arguments; however, recipients accepted majority arguments independent of their quality. It is important to note that this pattern emerged with a novel issue of low personal relevance, in the absence of any social or perceptual conflict, and in a setting where any direct interaction between recipients and the influence group was obviously impossible. In other words, none of the conditions that were often described as necessary for conversion and Persuasion by Majorities and Minorities 17 compliance effects to occur was present. Our results thus suggest that high salience of social comparison concerns may be sufficient for such effects to occur. This both clarifies and expands the range of conditions for which conversion theory makes valid predictions. When accuracy concerns had been made salient by referring to the expertise of the influence group, a different result pattern emerged. Consensus information functioned in much the same way as did expertise information in previous work (Bohner et al., 2002). Recipients formed expectancies about message validity based on the amount of consensus present; then they processed the message arguments in light of these expectations, which resulted in assimilation effects for the ambiguous message, and in contrast effects for the unambiguous message when argument quality was discrepant from expectations. However, the contrast pattern emerged more clearly for thought valence than for attitudes. Specifically, weak arguments presented by a majority still caused moderately positive atttitude judgments, even though, as predicted, the cognitive responses to the message were the most negative in this condition. It seems possible then, that majorities have the power to cause favorable judgments despite the presence of other, more negative information (see, e.g., Darke, Chaiken, Bohner, Einwiller, Erb, & Hazlewood, 1998). The somewhat mixed data at the group level may indicate that different subgroups of participants were differentially responsive to the priming, such that our idealized predicted patterns failed to be fully supported. Another possibility is that both consensus-based expectancies and social comparison processes were driving the results in the accuracy priming conditions for all participants, with different weights of each applied to the different dependent variables. In other words, a majority's normative influence may come into play even when accuracy concerns prevail, preventing people from making negative attitude judgments although their issue-related thoughts are rather negative. Further research is certainly necessary to follow up on these conjectures. Persuasion by Majorities and Minorities 18 An interesting lead for potential follow-up investigations comes from a comparison of the present results with the precursor study by Bohner et al. (2002). Using high vs. low expertise cues, these authors also found the most clear-cut z-shaped pattern in their thought valence results, whereas the pattern of post-message attitudes was less congenial to predictions. The divergence of the attitude data, however, took an interestingly different shape in the two studies. Specifically, our present data suggest that a majority presenting weak arguments failed to produce more negative attitudes than a minority presenting weak arguments; the predicted contrast effect seemed to be absent. An expert presenting weak arguments, however, did produce a contrast effect, being much less influential than a non-expert presenting the same weak arguments (see Bohner et al., 2002, Figure 5). Conversely, Bohner et al. found that a nonexpert with strong arguments failed to evoke positive contrast, being no more influential than an expert with strong arguments, whereas in the present study the predicted contrast pattern was observed for a minority presenting strong arguments. Thus, it may be the case that high expertise coupled with weak arguments generally violates expectancies to a greater degree than does low expertise coupled with strong arguments. The opposite may generally be true for consensus, where high consensus coupled with weak arguments may violate expectancies less than low consensus coupled with strong arguments. This possible asymmetry in persuasion cues should be addressed in future studies. At a more general level, our findings demonstrate once more that persuasion is a complex sequential process in which inferences drawn from early information may alter the way in which subsequent information is perceived and elaborated (see Bohner et al., 1995; Chen & Chaiken, 1999; Kruglanski & Thompson, 1999; Petty & Wegener, 1998). One powerful type of "early information" in this respect are source cues; whereas previous studies have repeatedly demonstrated that different cues may evoke different inferences, our present Persuasion by Majorities and Minorities findings extend this line of research by showing that even identical source cues may have dramatically different effects depending on the social context in which they are evaluated. 19 Persuasion by Majorities and Minorities 20 References Abelson, R. P., & Prentice, D. A. (1997). Contrast tests of interaction hypotheses. Psychological Methods, 2, 315-328. Bohner, G., Erb, H.-P., Reinhard, M.-A., & Frank, E. (1996). Distinctiveness across topics in minority and majority influence: An attributional analysis and preliminary data. British Journal of Social Psychology, 35, 27-46. Bohner, G., Frank, E., & Erb, H.-P. (1998). Heuristic processing of distinctiveness information in minority and majority influence. European Journal of Social Psychology, 28, 855860. Bohner, G., Moskowitz, G. B., & Chaiken, S. (1995). The interplay of heuristic and systematic processing of social information. European Review of Social Psychology, 6, 33-68. Bohner, G., Ruder, M., & Erb, H.-P. (2002). When expertise backfires: Contrast and assimilation effects in persuasion. British Journal of Social Psychology, 41, 495-519. Chen, S., & Chaiken, S. (1999). The heuristic-systematic model in its broader context. In S. Chaiken & Y. Trope (Eds.), Dual-process theories in social psychology (pp. 73-96). New York: Guilford. Darke, P. R., Chaiken, S., Bohner, G., Einwiller, S., Erb, H.-P., & Hazlewood, J. D. (1998). Accuracy motivation, consensus information, and the law of large numbers: Effects on attitude judgment in the absence of argumentation. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 24, 1205-1215. Erb, H.-P., & Bohner, G. (2001). Mere consensus in minority and majority influence. In N. K. De Vries & C. K. W. De Dreu (Eds.), Group consensus and minority influence: Implications for innovation (pp. 40-59). Oxford, UK: Blackwell. Erb, H.-P., Bohner, G., Rank, S., & Einwiller, S. (2002). Processing minority and majority Persuasion by Majorities and Minorities 21 communications: The role of conflict with prior attitudes. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 28, 1172-1182. Erb, H.-P., Bohner, G., Schmälzle, K., & Rank, S. (1998). Beyond conflict and discrepancy: Cognitive bias in minority and majority influence. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 24, 620-633. Faul, F., & Erdfelder, E. (1992). GPOWER: A priori, post-hoc, and compromise power analyses for MS-DOS [Computer program]. Bonn: University of Bonn, Department of Psychology. [On-line: http://www.psycho.uni-duesseldorf.de/aap/projects/gpower/] Kelley, H. H. (1967). Attribution theory in social psychology. In D. Levine (Ed.), Nebraska Symposium on Motivation (Vol. 15, pp. 192-238). Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press. Kruglanski, A. W., & Thompson, E. P. (1999). Persuasion by a single route: A view from the unimodel. Psychological Inquiry, 10, 83-109. Maass, A., & Clark, R. D. III. (1984). Hidden impact of minorities: Fifteen years of minority influence research. Psychological Bulletin, 95, 428-450. Martin, R., & Hewstone, M. (2003). Majority versus minority influence: When, not whether, source status instigates heuristic or systematic processing. European Journal of Social Psychology, 33, 313-330. Moscovici, S. (1976). Social influence and social change. London: Academic Press. Moscovici, S. (1980). Toward a theory of conversion behavior. Advances in Experimental Social Psychology, 13, 209-239. Moscovici, S., Lage, E., & Naffrechoux, M. (1969). Influence of a consistent minority on the responses of a majority in a color perception task. Sociometry, 32, 365-380. Nemeth, C. J. (1986). Differential contributions of majority and minority influence. Persuasion by Majorities and Minorities 22 Psychological Review, 93, 23-32. Tetlock, P. E. (1985). Accountability: The neglected social context of judgment and choice. Research in Organizational Behavior, 7, 297-332. Wood, W., Lundgren, S., Ouellette, J. A., Busceme, S., & Blackstone, T. (1994). Minority influence: A meta-analytic review of social influence processes. Psychological Bulletin, 115, 323-345. Ziegler, R., Diehl, M., Zigon, R., & Fett, T. (2004). Source consistency, distinctiveness, and consensus: The three dimensions of the Kelley ANOVA model in persuasion. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 30, 352-364. Persuasion by Majorities and Minorities 23 Table 1 Results of Contrast Analyses by Priming Condition. Accuracy Priming Contrast Fa Social Comparison Priming Residual Effects Fb Contrast Fa Residual Effects Fb 0.49 0.01 1.75+ 2.22 1.53 2.01 1.55 Consensus Model Contrast 8.47** 3.19*** 2.49 3.79*** Conversion Theory Contrast 6.22* 3.42*** Thought Valence Consensus Model Contrast Conversion Theory Contrast 12.56*** Attitudes 27.63*** 1.28 Note: Statistics for those contrasts that were predicted to be significant and to fit the data well are shown in boldface. a Degrees of freedom are 1 and 228 for thought valence, and 1 and 230 for attitudes. b Degrees of freedom are 10 and 228 for thought valence, and 10 and 230 for attitudes. *** p < .001; ** p < .01; * p < .05; + p < .10. Persuasion by Majorities and Minorities Figure Captions Figure 1. Predicted results for accuracy priming, based on the consensus approach (Panel a), and for social comparison priming, based on conversion theory (Panel b). Figure 2. Pattern of means of thought valence in accuracy priming (Panel a) and social comparison priming conditions (Panel b). Figure 3. Pattern of means of attitudes in accuracy priming (Panel a) and social comparison priming conditions (Panel b). 24 Persuasion by Majorities and Minorities (a) Pattern Predicted for Accuracy Priming 4 3 +3 Response 2 +1 +1 1 Strong Ambiguous Weak 0 -1 -1 -1 -2 -3 -3 -4 Minority Majority Source (b) Pattern Predicted for Social Comparison Priming 2 Response 1 +1 +1 +1 +1 0 -1 -1 -2 -3 -3 -4 Minority Majority Source Strong Ambiguous Weak 25 Persuasion by Majorities and Minorities 26 Thought Valence (a) Thought Valence Results in Accuracy Priming Conditions 3.5 3 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 -0.5 -1 3.10 2.19 2.16 0.70 0.21 Strong Ambiguous Weak -0.86 Minority Majority Source (b) Thought Valence Results in Social Comparison Priming Conditions 4 Thought Valence 3 2 2.25 2.25 2.05 1.33 1.22 1 0 0.05 -1 Minority Majority Source Strong Ambiguous Weak Persuasion by Majorities and Minorities 27 (a) Attitude Results in Accuracy Priming Conditions 8 Attitude 7 6 6.79 6.46 6.47 6.06 5.43 5.77 Strong Ambiguous Weak 5 4 Minority Majority Source (b) Attitude Results in Social Comparison Priming Conditions 8 6.93 6.61 6.33 Attitude 7 6.48 6 5.71 5 4.74 4 Minority Majority Source Strong Ambiguous Weak