Introduction Cartels (Draft) Chi Leng, Ph.D. David C. Sharp, Ph.D. Nathan Associates Inc. October 2010 General Types of Antitrust Analyses • Economic antitrust analysis can be broken into two broad categories • Exclusion - firms attempt to raise prices by excluding rivals • Exclusive dealing • Tying contracts • Collusion (broadly defined) – firms attempt to raise prices through collaboration with rivals • Horizontal mergers • Price fixing 1 Price Fixing • Agreements between business rivals to sell (or buy) the same product or service at the same artificially elevated (or depressed) price • Considered by many to be the most central element of competition economics • Regarded with approval even by those generally skeptical of government competition policy* • Price fixing is perhaps the most common form of collusion * Whinston, M.D. (2006). Lectures on Antitrust Economics, p. 15. 2 Theory of Collusion - Competitive Market P CONSUMER SURPLUS PCOMP MC = ATC D QCOMP Q 3 Theory of Collusion - Collusive Market P CONSUMER SURPLUS PCOLL CARTEL PROFITS PCOMP MC = ATC D DEADWEIGHT LOSS QCOLL QCOMP Q 4 Theory of Collusion • The basic theory reveals a strong incentive (i.e., profits) for firms to jointly reduce output and increase price • But basic theory also shows a strong incentive for individual firms to cheat on the cartel • Cheater produces extra output or lowers its price • Common “real world” defense in antitrust litigation that actually reconciles with theory • Incentive to cheat best illustrated with a “Prisoners’ Dilemma” (duopoly) example 5 Prisoners Dilemma: Airlines Example • American Airlines and United Airlines* • The two compete for customers on flights between Chicago and Los Angeles * From Perloff, J.M. (2004). Microeconomics, 3rd Edition, p, 427 6 Prisoners Dilemma: Airlines Example Nash Equilibrium Cartel Equilibrium 7 Classic Conditions for Cartel Success • • • • • Concentrated industry (few firms) High barriers to entry Homogeneous product Inelastic demand No monopsony power (many small buyers) • Mechanism to monitor cartel • Industry organization • Gives pretext for meetings • Detects cheating 8 Duration of Cartels • Many cartel scholars use duration to measure cartel success, but recognize it is a highly imperfect measure • Results from the literature are mixed, due to different samples (i.e., types of cartels and time periods) observed • But two relatively recent studies calculate the average duration at 5.4 years • Gallo, J.C., Craycraft, J.L., Dau-Schmidt, K. and Parker, C.A. (2000). Department of Justice Antitrust Enforcement, 1955-1997: An Empirical Study. Review of Industrial Organization, 17(1). • Levenstein, M.C. and Suslow, V.Y. (2004). International Cartels: Then and Now. Working Paper presented to the NBER Development of the American Economy Summer Institute. 9 Duration of Cartels Distribution of Duration for Contemporary International Cartels 10 9 Number of Cartels 8 7 6 Mean = 5.4 5 4 3 2 1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 11 13 17 20 23 Years Duration From Levenstein, M.C. and Suslow, V.Y. (2004). International Cartels: Then and Now. Working Paper presented to the NBER Development of the American Economy Summer Institute. 10 What Else Does the Literature Say? • Cartels are more likely to form in industries where prices have been falling • Stigler (1964)* argued that cartels are fundamentally unstable: firms agree to restrict output, then engage in secret cheating that erupts in price wars • Modern studies indicate that cartels break up occasionally because of cheating, but biggest challenges are entry and responding to changing economic conditions** * Stigler, G. (1964). A Theory of Oligopoly. Journal of Political Economy, 72(1). ** Levenstein, M.C. and Suslow, V.Y. (2006). What Determines Cartel Success? Journal of Economic Literature, 44. 11 How Do We Measure Compensatory Damages? • Damage methodologies compare the prices paid during the period of alleged wrongdoing with the “but for” price • The “but for” price is the price that would have prevailed in the absence of (i.e., but for) the cartel • Two general approaches • Utilizing benchmarks • Econometrics 12 Benchmarks • “Before-during-after” approach • Examine product price before, during, and after cartel period; difference between the cartel price and the competitive price measures the damage • May meet objection that changes in factors other than the cartel may have produced price changes during cartel period • “Yardstick” approach • Examine price movements of a comparable product, unaffected by the cartel, and compare to price of the cartelized product to determine damages • Variant examines production costs, and “cost plus” pricing determines what the price would have been absent the cartel • “Geographic area” approach • Examine product price from a region or part of the world where the cartel did not occur. Prices in the affected and unaffected areas are compared to estimate damages 13 Benchmarks • Benchmarks may be fine (or necessary due to data constraints) in some cases • But they may fail to account for other systematic factors (other than the cartel) that may have influenced price during the cartel period • We need an approach that allows us to account for all relevant factors 14 Econometrics (Multiple Regression) • Econometrics is the application of statistical methods to economic data • The basic idea underlying econometrics is to build a model that accurately describes the “real world,” in equation form • It is a technique that allows us to account for any factor (variable) thought to be potentially relevant, and have its actual influence examined 15 Econometrics (Multiple Regression) • Each variable’s impact is disentangled from all others, allowing us to measure the isolated influence of each • In price-fixing, the allegation is that cartel members conspired to impact the price • With econometrics, we can measure the cartel’s impact on price, alone, net of all other influences 16 Case Study: Graphite Products* • Graphite is an intermediate product used in diverse downstream industries • • • • • Chemicals Glass Aerospace Metallurgy Semiconductors * While there were allegations of price fixing in various graphite product markets, the discussion below is entirely hypothetical for the purposes of this case study. 17 Case Study: Graphite Products* • Three U.S. suppliers of graphite products: • Company A • Company B • Company C • Each company had 25% of the market • Imports from China, India and other countries represented the other 25% * While there were allegations of price fixing in various graphite product markets, the discussion below is entirely hypothetical for the purposes of this case study. 18 Case Study: Graphite Products* • Inputs to graphite production • • • • Petroleum coke Natural gas Electricity Labor * While there were allegations of price fixing in various graphite product markets, the discussion below is entirely hypothetical for the purposes of this case study. 19 Graphite Case Study: Price Fixing Data $20 Competitive Period Conspiracy Period $18 $16 $14 $12 $10 $8 Cartel members claim this price increase is attributable to rising costs $6 $4 $2 Enforcement authority alleges rising costs were a pretext for additional conspiratorial price hikes Jan-99 Oct-98 Jul-98 Apr-98 Jan-98 Oct-97 Jul-97 Apr-97 Jan-97 Oct-96 Jul-96 Apr-96 Jan-96 Oct-95 Jul-95 Apr-95 Jan-95 Oct-94 Jul-94 Apr-94 Jan-94 Oct-93 Jul-93 Apr-93 $0 Actual Price Let’s use econometrics to disentangle supply, demand, and cartel effects 20 Graphite Case Study: Binary Model Equation • General form: price = (supply, demand, conspiracy) Coefficients: • Linear form: Measure the impact of the explanatory variables on the dependent variable price = α + β1(supply) + β2(demand) + β3(cartel) Dependent Variable: The variable to be explained Intercept: Reveals the value of the dependent variable when all explanatory variables take on a 0 value Explanatory Variables: Aid in explaining the dependent variable “Cartel” is a binary variable. It takes on a value of 1 during the cartel period and a value of 0 during the competitive period 21 Graphite Case Study: Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) Estimation • Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) estimates values of α and the βs • Not a new tool, going back in its origins to Carl Friedrich Gauss (1777-1855) • OLS also provides tests of statistical significance (T-stats, F-stat) and goodness of fit measures (Adjusted R2) • OLS estimation can be done with a variety of software, such as SAS® and Stata® (and even Excel®) 22 Graphite Case Study OLS Estimation of the Binary Model SUMMARY OUTPUT Regression Statistics Multiple R 0.9755 R Square 0.9515 Adjusted R Square 0.9494 Standard Error 0.6368 Observations 72 Adj R2: Approximately 95% of the variation in price is explained by the three explanatory variables ANOVA df Regression Residual Total Intercept Supply Demand Cartel SS 541.3121 27.5769 568.8890 MS 180.4374 0.4055 F Significance F 444.9284 0.0000 Coefficients Standard Error 19.6984 α -56.0090 1.7421 0.0884 β1 β2 4.3440 1.5627 β3 2.0354 0.3271 t Stat -2.8433 19.6994 2.7799 6.2232 P-value 0.0059 0.0000 0.0070 0.0000 3 68 71 T stats: Easy rule of thumb… if > |2|, it is statistically significant Lower 95% Upper 95% Lower 95.0% Upper 95.0% -95.3166 -16.7014 -95.3166 -16.7014 1.5656 1.9185 1.5656 1.9185 1.2258 7.4622 1.2258 7.4622 1.3828 2.6881 1.3828 2.6881 price = -56.01 + 1.74(supply) + 4.34(demand) + 2.04(cartel) 23 Graphite Case Study OLS Predictions & Inference with the Binary Model • Let’s see how well it predicts prices for, say, April 1993 (i.e., the beginning) • In April 1993, supply (costs) = $5.53, demand (index) = 12.51, & cartel= 0 price = -56.01 + 1.74(supply) + 4.34(demand) + 2.04(cartel) price = -56.01 + 1.74(5.53) + 4.34(12.51) + 2.04(0) price = -56.01 + 9.62 + 54.29 price = $7.90 • Actual April 1993 price = $7.94 • Error = predicted – actual = -$0.04 • Direct interpretation of the cartel’s impact, in isolation • Average overcharge during the cartel period = $2.04 per unit • Damages = the quantity sold (Q) multiplied by the average overcharge 24 A Variant: Forecast Model • With the forecast method we estimate the coefficients using data during the competitive period only; there is no cartel binary variable • Use the estimated coefficients above with values for the explanatory variables during the cartel period to predict what prices would have been, but for the cartel 25 Forecast Data $20 Estimation Period Forecast Period $18 $16 $14 $12 $10 $8 Estimate the equation using prices and explanatory variables during this period only $6 $4 $2 Use that equation to forecast price during this period (i.e., the cartel period) Jan-99 Oct-98 Jul-98 Apr-98 Jan-98 Oct-97 Jul-97 Apr-97 Jan-97 Oct-96 Jul-96 Apr-96 Jan-96 Oct-95 Jul-95 Apr-95 Jan-95 Oct-94 Jul-94 Apr-94 Jan-94 Oct-93 Jul-93 Apr-93 $0 Actual Price 26 Forecast: Predicted and Actual $20 Estimation Period Forecast Period $18 $16 $14 $12 $10 $8 The difference between actual and predicted is damages per unit $6 $4 $2 Actual Price Jan-99 Oct-98 Jul-98 Apr-98 Jan-98 Oct-97 Jul-97 Apr-97 Jan-97 Oct-96 Jul-96 Apr-96 Jan-96 Oct-95 Jul-95 Apr-95 Jan-95 Oct-94 Jul-94 Apr-94 Jan-94 Oct-93 Jul-93 Apr-93 $0 Predicted Price 27 Binary Model • Advantage: • Direct estimation of the average overcharge across the cartel period • Disadvantage: • No pretty picture; it does not provide a clear graphical comparison of the actual and “but for” price 28 Forecast Model • Advantage: • Provides a clear graphical comparison of the actual and “but for” price • Disadvantages: • Damages calculated month-by-month (no big deal, really) • Literature suggests that forecast models tend to produce large confidence intervals* * Rubinfeld, D.L. (1985). Econometrics in the Courtroom. Columbia Law Review, 85(5), pp. 1048-1097. 29 Conclusion • Economic analysis is an integral part of competition enforcement • Econometric analysis has also become prevalent, particularly in price-fixing cases 30 Conclusion Cartels (Draft) Chi Leng, Ph.D. David C. Sharp, Ph.D. Nathan Associates Inc. October 2010