Income Comparisons, the Easterlin Paradox and Public Policy Andrew E. Clark (Paris School of Economics and IZA) http://www.parisschoolofeconomics.com/clark-andrew/ APE/ETE Masters Course You might think that money might help us to achieve the variety of different kinds of wellbeing that have been put forward as important in the literature. Being poor certainly prevents us from doing many things that we would like to do. If you don’t believe me, then try it… But in addition to wishful thinking, what does the data say? One of the first, and most original, researchers in this area is Dick Easterlin (University of Southern California). He asked two questions: 1) Are richer individuals/countries happier than poorer individuals/countries? 2) As countries get richer, does everyone become happier? We might expect the answer to these two questions to be the same. I here present some of the results from: Easterlin, R. A. (2005). “Diminishing Marginal Utility of Income? Caveat Emptor”. Social Indicators Research. pp. 243-255. This specifically deals with the case of Japan. Japan was a poor country in the 1950s/early 1960s, but then experienced unprecedented growth. Fact 1. Richer countries are happier countries. The blue lines show the estimated relationship between income and happiness Japan Japan was in the middle of the income distribution in the early 1960s, and had a middling level of happiness So what happened as Japan became richer? Look at annual indices (1962=100) of life satisfaction and real GNP per capita for Japan, 1958-1987 Between 1962 and 1987 Japan experienced unprecedented economic growth, with GNP per capita (in real terms)rising 3.5-fold: growing from 22 to 77 percent of the United States level in 1962 We might then imagine that Japan would follow the blue lines above: as Japan became richer, it would become happier. In fact, happiness remained constant despite Japan’s remarkable economic growth What “should” have happened What did happen Are the Japanese strange? 40000 3 2.5 Average Happiness 30000 2 20000 1.5 1 Happiness Real Income Per Capita 10000 0.5 0 0 1973 1977 1981 1985 1989 1993 1998 Real Income Per Capita (2000 US$) Not necessarily: the same thing can be observed in 30 years of American GSS data 2003 Year This is the Easterlin Paradox. Richer individuals are happier, but as countries become richer over time they do not become happier. The challenge to social science is to try to explain why. This finding has generated a considerable amount of controversy: it just MUST be wrong One point to remember is that the Easterlin Paradox is a statement of why continuous GDP growth may not increase social welfare in the long-run. It is not a theory of recessions not mattering: we shouldn’t be surprised if life satisfaction and the economic cycle are correlated in the short run After all, unemployment is a robust significant indicator of individual subjective well-being (the blips in the US happiness line correspond to the business cycle) Recent work has considered (and reconsidered) time– series evidence suggesting that the average well-being lines over time above are “really” flat One well-known contribution is Stevenson and Wolfers (2008) - There are issues with data comparability over time in Japan: the questions changed over time Recent work has considered (and reconsidered) time– series evidence suggesting that the average well-being lines over time above are “really” flat - SW agree that life satisfaction in the USA follows the business cycle. But also that there is no trend in the GSS data. Recent work has considered (and reconsidered) time– series evidence suggesting that the average well-being lines over time above are “really” flat - There is a positive trend in both happiness and life satisfaction scores in the World Values Survey. - Easterlin points out that the trend in WVS happiness scores came from a change in the way the happiness question was administered. - And one of the two positive life satisfaction slopes is entirely driven by the recovery of transition countries. - While the other relies on two data points (and so wouldn’t survive a jackknife analysis) United Kingdom (BHPS): Real GDP per capita and life satisfaction 1996 - 2008 West Germany (SOEP): Real GDP per capita and life satisfaction 1984 - 2010 Australia (HILDA): Real GDP per capita and life satisfaction 2001 - 2009 Life Satisfaction in Five European Countries, (World Database of Happiness) 1973-2004 Average Life Satisfaction 4 3.5 3 2.5 2 1.5 UK 1 France Germany Italy Netherlands 0.5 0 1973 1977 1980 1983 1986 Year 1988 1990 1993 1996 2000 2004 It is easy to lose the will to live when reading the attacks and counter-attacks. There are fundamental issues with the analysis of timeseries happiness data. It is easy to lose the will to live when reading the attacks and counter-attacks. There are fundamental issues with the analysis of timeseries happiness data. 1) It is time-series happiness data. So we are making strong statements off of differences in slopes estimated using 20, or 10, or 4 observations. It is easy to lose the will to live when reading the attacks and counter-attacks. There are fundamental issues with the analysis of timeseries happiness data. 1) It is time-series happiness data. So we are making strong statements off of differences in slopes estimated using 20, or 10, or 4 observations. 2) There are never any control variables (age, sex, education, country of birth, urban/rural, labour force status, marital status, and so on): how much of this is a composition effect? 1) It is time-series happiness data. So we are making strong statements off of differences in slopes estimated using 20, or 10, or 4 observations. 2) There are never any control variables (age, sex, education, country of birth, urban/rural, labour force status, marital status, and so on): how much of this is a composition effect? 3) There are never any macro control variables It is easy to imagine macro “omitted variables” which may obscure the effect of income: inequality, crime, pollution etc. Perhaps we should stop looking at time series We often appeal to the notion of relative utility, whereby W = W(y, y*, …) to explain the Easterlin Paradox. So let’s turn the question around: if we find strong and consistent evidence of a role of some benchmark or comparison income in individual well-being, then the Easterlin Paradox must at least partly hold: - Then the time-series and cross-section relationships between subjective well-being and income cannot be the same BROAD IDEA A common idea across the Social Sciences: well-being or utility depends on some kind of comparison process of what you have relative to a reference level. Comparisons can be over “things” or over money. An example. Two people, A and B, who live next to each other, both like cars. WA = W(CarA,.....) WB = W(CarB,.....) Where “W” is the individual’s well-being function. Key question: is A more likely to buy a new car if B buys a new one? Standard economic theory: Comparisons/relative utility: No. Yes. If the answer is “yes”, then we could write A’s “happiness function” as WA = W(CarA/CarB,....): how good is my car relative to my neighbour’s? This might sound like a ridiculous proposition. It isn’t, at least not in the Netherlands. Kuhn, P., Kooreman, P., Soetevent, A., and Kapteyn, A. (2011). "The Effects of Lottery Prizes on Winners and their Neighbors: Evidence from the Dutch Postcode Lottery". American Economic Review, 101, 2226-2247. Each week, the Dutch Postcode Lottery (PCL) randomly selects a postal code, and distributes cash and a new BMW to lottery participants in that code. There are 430 000 postodes in the Netherlands. An average postcode includes around 20 households. A winning participant wins €12,500 per ticket. In addition, one participating household in the winning postcode receives a new BMW. Households in postcodes surveyed six months after the prize was won. PCL nonparticipants who live next door to winners have significantly higher levels of car consumption than other nonparticipants (sig. levels are all relative to column 2, the non-participants in non-winning PCs) Applied to Income, instead of Cars: Income and Subjective Well-Being (SWB) Standard model: Comparisons: W = W(y, ....) W = W(y/y*, ....) This is analogous to the car example. The variable y* is “comparison income”: the income to which we compare/income of the reference group. I mostly consider evidence here resulting from direct measurement of “W”, via job satisfaction, life satisfaction, mental stress etc. Validated by physiological/neurological studies, thirdparty raters, and (most importantly) future behaviours such as divorce, unemployment duration, quitting one’s job, and morbidity and mortality. There is nothing to stop us looking at behaviours too: I think of the analysis of behaviour and proxy measures of utility as complements, not substitutes. To whom do we compare? Peer group/people like me Others in the same household Spouse/partner Myself in the past Friends Neighbours Work colleagues “Expectations” We typically know nothing about the reference group. Wave 3 of the European Social Survey (22 countries) helps here. Table1. “How important is it to you to compare your income with other people’s incomes?” Not at all important 1 2 3 4 5 Very important 23.80 17.01 13.86 16.95 13.52 9.42 5.44 he rla Sw nds ite rla n Fi d nl a Ge nd rm an Au y str Un Be ia ite lg d i Ki um ng do Po m rtu ga Ir e l l Da and ne m a No r k rw a Bu y lg ar ia Fr an Hu ce ng a Sw ry ed Sl en ov en ia Ru ss i Es a to ni a Po lan Uk d ra in e Sp a Sl in ov ak ia Ne t 2.9 2.7 2.5 2.3 2.1 1.9 1.7 1.5 Work colleagues Family members Friends Others Don't compare Observations 6 159 929 2 382 1 192 5 185 Weighted % 38.93 6.03 14.94 7.39 32.72 Income and comparison intensity are negatively correlated, both within and between countries Work colleagues Family members Friends Others Don't compare Observations 6 159 929 2 382 1 192 5 185 Weighted % 38.93 6.03 14.94 7.39 32.72 Mostly we just impose a reference group, such as people like me, neighbours or family. I use the British Household Panel Study (BHPS) to look at the relationship between job satisfaction and labour income. Main findings: There is some evidence that job satisfaction is an increasing function of income. However, job satisfaction falls as others’ income rises. This holds for: The income of “people like you” (same characteristics, same type of job). Partner’s income. The income of other adults in the same household. The income that you yourself earned in the same job one year ago. Clark and Oswald (1996). BHPS Data on 5000 Employees Log income (y) Log comparison income (y*) -0.02 (0.039) --- Log NES comparison income (y**) --- 0.11 (0.050) -0.20 (0.062) --- -0.001 (0.04) ---0.26 (0.073) “Comparison Income” predicted from a Mincer Earnings equation (note: requires exclusion restrictions to avoid multicollinearity); “NES comparison income” matched in from another data set by hours of work, and thus avoids identification problems (but assumes reference group defined by hours of work). Clark (1996). BHPS Data on 5000 Employees Log hourly pay: ln(HPi) Log Hours Log spouse's hourly pay: (ln(HPs)) Dummy: HPi > HPs Log spouse's hourly pay (when HPs > HPi) 0.111 (0.060) -0.251 (0.061) -0.121 (0.044) ----- 0.039 (0.068) -0.246 (0.061) -0.056 (0.052) 0.171 (0.074) --- 0.060 (0.066) -0.250 (0.061) -0.047 (0.059) ---0.069 (0.037) Estimated only on couples where both partners are in work. Includes other standard control variables. Comparisons to the past: Clark (1999). BHPS Data Log current monthly pay 0.086 (0.071) Log current monthly hours -0.081 (0.215) Log monthly pay one year ago .. % Change in pay/100 .. 0.486 (0.166) -0.428 (0.295) -0.442 (0.163) 0.523 (0.288) .. % Change in hours/100 .. .. % Change in hourly wage/100 .. .. Log monthly hours one year ago.. 0.042 (0.072) 0.114 (0.236) .. 0.038 (0.072) 0.067 (0.219) .. .. .. 0.439 (0.146) -0.518 (0.285) .. .. .. 0.450 (0.126) Two waves only. Estimated on individuals who did not change job or get promoted between the two waves. Therefore, when we look at the effect of own pay and others’ pay on satisfaction, we find the following kind of stylised relationships: Satisfaction Income DOES bring happiness... As long as you get it and no-one else does Own pay (y), holding y* constant Satisfaction Others’ pay (y*), holding y constant Satisfaction Pay rises for everybody (y/y* constant) Others have replicated these broad findings with work on life satisfaction and local area average incomes: Ferrer-iCarbonell for Germany, and Luttmer for the US. There are three reasons to wonder whether these comparison income results are entirely right: • The Danish • Tunnels • Altruism 1) This is Denmark • From January 1, 2007, Denmark has been split up into five Regions: two in Zealand, two in Jutland, and one covering Funen and Southern Jutland. • Previous to this, Denmark was split up into 15 counties, and 273 municipalities. • We use new geo-referenced data, based on a geographical grid of size 100*100 meters (i.e. 10 000 square meters, or a hectare) covering the entire country. • Some of these grid cells are uninhabited, others are only very thinly inhabited: around two-thirds of inhabited hectare cells contain under five households. • Data confidentiality: Statistics Denmark aggregates to produce clusters of neighbouring hectare cells with a minimum of 150 (600) households. • Adjusted by Damm and Schultz-Nielsen (2008) to produce a classification Constant over time Marked out by physical barriers (roads, rivers) Compact Contiguous Homogenous in terms of type and ownership of housing (don’t mix flats and houses). Figure 1 Small neighbourhoods in the area of Taastrupgård, Høje Tåstrup Source: Damm and Schultz-Nielsen (2008). Economic Satisfaction, Income and Rank within Small Neighbourhoods: Panel Results Ln(HH income) Ln(median grid HH income) Ln(median municipality HH income) Relative rank in small grid See Neighbours Often Single Health problems dummy Age dummies (9) Education dummies (6) Socio-Economic Group dummies (3) No. and Ages of children dummies (5) No. Years in Grid dummies (5) Regional dummies (13) Year dummies (8) Observations Baseline Baseline and Municipality Baseline and Rank 0.390** (0.021) 0.228** (0.052) ---------0.019 (0.016) -0.057* (0.027) -0.023 (0.017) 0.390** (0.021) 0.236** (0.055) -0.062 (0.156) -----0.019 (0.016) -0.057* (0.027) -0.023 (0.017) 0.070* (0.028) 0.634** (0.057) ----1.124** (0.068) -0.016 (0.016) 0.025 (0.028) -0.023 (0.017) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 33 870 33 870 33 870 So individuals like living with richer (very close) neighbours. This probably reflects local public goods or social capital. In this sense, were we able to hold public goods and social capital constant, then I would expect the sign on neighbours’ income to become negative. This is what column 3 effectively does. It holds average neighbourhood income constant, and looks at rank effects. Consistent with previous work, this is positive. People like having rich neighbours…and being on top of the pile. 2) Tunnels Senik, C. (2004). "When Information Dominates Comparison: A Panel Data Analysis Using Russian Subjective Data.". Journal of Public Economics, 88, 2099-2123. Clark, A.E., Kristensen, N., and Westergård-Nielsen, N. (2009). "Job Satisfaction and Co-worker Wages: Status or Signal?". Economic Journal, 119, 430-447. A smaller number of recent papers have uncovered empirical results where some measure of individual well-being is positively correlated with reference group income or earnings: the more others earn, the happier I am. This finding has been interpreted as demonstrating Hirschman’s tunnel effect (Hirschman and Rothschild, 1973): while others’ good fortune might make me jealous, it may also provide information about my own future prospects. The distinction between status and signal depends on how likely you are to end up in the future with your reference group’s current income. Senik considers a very unstable labour market (Russia); Clark et al examine the average earnings of other workers within the same firm. But how pervasive are signal effects in general? 3) Altruism Dunn, E., Aknin, L., and Norton, M. (2008). "Spending Money on Others Promotes Happiness". Science, 319, 1687-1688. • Individuals are forced to be generous: they are given an envelope with either $5 or $20 to spend that day. • Half are told to spend the money on themselves, and the other half on someone else. • Spending money on others produces greater happiness than spending money on oneself. People do not realise this ex ante. Does this challenge the hypothesis that well-being is relative in income? Not necessarily. We can imagine that people’s well-being is affected by both envy and altruism. The objects of these two feelings are probably not the same. When individuals buy gifts, they may not buy gifts for those in their reference group. The results with respect to past income are interesting: the more you earned in the past, the more you need to earn now in order to be just as satisfied: wages are habit-forming. Job satisfaction This implies that someone who receives a pay rise will have job satisfaction over time as follows: Time Pay rises are good at the time, but then you get used to them. How can a firm keep its workers satisfied then? By starting them at a relatively low wage and giving them constant pay rises: profile C. Pay C B A Time Even a small amount of comparison to the past produces sharply-rising consumption profiles. Conclusion: There are strong comparison effects both spatially (between groups) and over time with respect to income. These two phenomena can explain the Easterlin paradox 40000 3 2.5 Average Happiness 30000 2 20000 1.5 1 Happiness Real Income Per Capita 10000 0.5 0 0 1973 1977 1981 1985 1989 Year 1993 1998 2003 Real Income Per Capita (2000 US$) FIGURE 1: Happiness and Real Income Per Capita in the US, 1973-2004 Subjective Well-Being Measures are not the only possible way of showing comparison effects. 1) The Leyden approach. Invert the question: Who needs more money to have a good life? Initiated by Bernard Van Praag. Ask individuals to assign income levels (per period) to six or nine different verbal labels (such as "excellent“,"sufficient" and "bad"). Van Praag can then estimate for each individual a lognormal “Welfare Function of Income” (the jump in income required to go from one label to another becomes increasingly large). The resulting individual estimated means () and variances () – there is one curve for each person – were then used as dependent variables in regressions to show which types of individuals require a higher level of income to be satisfied, and which individuals have valuations that are more sensitive to changes in income. Those with higher reference group income, and who had earned more in the past, had higher values of . Those with higher values of μ use lower verbal well-being labels at any given level of income 2) Ask people. Preference for rising income profiles, and preferences for lower absolute incomes: • A: Your current yearly income is $50,000; others earn $25,000. • B: Your current yearly income is $100,000; others earn $200,000. Individuals have a marked preference for A over B. Positionality differs according to the domain. In Alpizar et al. (2005) this is stronger for cars and housing, and weaker for vacations and insurance. 3) Experimental. a) Ultimatum game: responders frequently rejecting offers that are under 25% of the total sum; as such the the vast majority of offers are between 40% and 50% of the sum. b) Dictator game: non-strategic. The survey of 616 such experiments in Engel (2011) concludes that dictators give on average 28.35% of the sum of money to be divided. c) Zizzo and Oswald (2001) report the results of an experiment whereby subjects can pay to burn each other’s money. A majority of subjects chose to do so, even though it costs them real earnings. The average subject had half of her earnings burnt, and richer subjects were burnt more often. d) Psychological experiments. Danny Kahneman’s hand in bucket of water experiments show that the change in pain predicts overall evaluation (rather than the level). e) McBride (2010) introduces a novel way of calculating aspirations directly in a matching pennies game, where individuals play against computers. The computer chooses heads or tails according to (known) probability distributions (for example 80% heads, 20% tails). After each round of playing, individuals report their satisfaction with the outcome. Introduces social comparisons in some of the treatments (by telling the individual the outcomes of the other players). Aspiration effect identified by varying the heads and tails probabilities played by the computer. Each subject has five pennies to play. When paired with a 80% heads, 20% tails computer, the best strategy is to always play heads, which gives an expected payoff of four pennies. When paired with a 65% heads, 35% tails computer, the best strategy is still to always play heads, but now the expected payoff is only 3.25 pennies. Results: satisfaction is i) higher the more one wins ii) lower the more others win iii) lower the higher was the aspiration level. 4) Natural Experiments Card et al. (2012): the revelation of information on others' earnings. The natural experiment here is a court decision that made the salary of any California state employee public knowledge. A local newspaper set up a website making it easy to find this information. Following this website launch, Card et al. informed a random subset of employees at three UC campuses about the site. Some days later, all employees on the three campuses were surveyed. Compare the treatment group (informed about the website) to others to reveal the impact of information on others' salaries. The reference group was defined here as co-workers in the same occupation group (faculty vs. staff) and administrative unit in the university. The survey found lower job satisfaction for those with pay below the reference group median and a greater intention to look for a new job. The effect on both for those who were relatively well-paid was insignificant. There is some evidence of an actual quitting effect on those who were found to be in the bottom earnings quartile in the reference group. 5) Neuro. Fließbach, K., Weber, B., Trautner, P., Dohmen, T., Sunde, U., Elger, C., & Falk, A. (2007). "Social comparison affects reward-related brain activity in the human ventral striatum". Science, 318, 1305-1308. Payoffs vary according to whether the individual gets the task right, and also randomly when the task is correct Brain activity measured via BOLD in various voxels. Particular attention paid to the ventral striatum: the “neural circuitry of reward” This kind of striatal activity has been shown to predict both hedonic outcomes (subjective well-being) and physiological outcomes (cortisol output: the body’s response to stress) Brain activation depends on relative income: compare C6, C8 and C11 (where the individual receives 60 Euros), and C7 to C9. What Changes in Micro Analysis if Utility is Relative? A lot…. 1) Labour supply is determined by the income: leisure trade-off. Under relative utility, higher income may not be associated with lower marginal utility (latter is also determined by y*, and higher levels of y* increase the marginal utility of own income). There is a positive cross-partial between y and y*… Possibility of everyone working too much (with associated tax implications). 2) A taste for rising income profiles can explain why wages rise faster than productivity. Also explains wage compression, and wage secrecy. And optimal rising consumption profiles. 3) Poverty: defined in terms of income or utility? There is no longer a monotonic relationship between the two 4) Individuals accumulate wealth over their lifetime, and productivity generally increases: reference income when ‘old’ is always higher than that when ‘young’. Savings may be too low: individuals will not postpone consumption to the future as future general consumption levels then will likely be higher due to productivity growth. This is a large (theoretical) literature: see Section 5.6 of Clark et al. Journal of Economic Literature (2008). 5) Conspicuous consumption introduces externalities between individuals, which should be corrected by a tax. Taxing luxury cars will make no difference to utility if they are only consumed for rank reasons. 6) Migration. Now no longer only for income, but also for relative standing reasons. Anti brain-drain conclusion (Mexican Doctors). 7) Relative utility might imply following behaviour… or it might not. Consider an additive comparisons model: 8) Worker behaviour, such as quitting and effort (productivity) will depend not only on own income, but also income of others. See Clark, A.E., Masclet, D., and Villeval, M.-C. (2010). "Effort and Comparison Income". Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 63, 407-426. The rank-dependence of effort (Random-effect Tobit model) Macro Implication. As a result of the Easterlin Paradox: “Money/possessions aren’t making us any happier: we should spend our time concentrating on X instead” Candidates for X: A (good) job Marriage/Family Social Activities Freedom/Democracy Health Religion But what if we found the same phenomena of adaptation and comparisons there too? This is only rarely tested. Public Policy Important to note that policy can’t do anything about some of the things we know are important from 20 years of subjective well-being research. Gender Women often report higher life satisfaction scores than men... but also higher psychological stress scores Nolen-Hoeksema, S., and Rusting, C.L. (1999). "Gender differences in well-being". In D. Kahneman, E. Diener, and N. Schwartz (Eds.), Well-being: The foundations of hedonic psychology. New York: Russell Sage Foundation. Policy can’t do anything about some of the things we know are important from 20 years of subjective wellbeing research. Age 6.7 (mean) satlife 7.25 well-being by age and sex 20 40 60 Age of Individual female male 80 The “happiness smile” (or grimace) is almost ubiquitous. But we still are not sure what is behind it Policy can’t do anything about some of the things we know are important from 20 years of subjective wellbeing research. Country The happiest country in the world is … Australia!! Or Denmark, or Nigeria. Policy question: How do we make the French Australian? Well-being and the Labour Market They’re right! Unemployment really is important..... ECHP: Satisfaction Scale 1-6. 500 000 individuals. ECHP: Labour Force Status and Life Satisfaction 4.5 4 3.5 Life Satisfaction 3 2.5 2 Self-Employed Employed Unemployed Labour Force Status But do you adapt to it, and is it relative? NLF Main results: The psychological impact of unemployment is lower When the regional unemployment rate is higher (estimated: no impact for regional unemployment of 20-25%). When there is more unemployment in the household (estimated: no impact if all other adults in the household are unemployed too). When the individual’s past unemployment is greater (estimated: no impact if the individual has been unemployed for 2 out of the past 3 years). All of these effects are far stronger for men, especially prime-age men (16-50), than for women. Social Comparisons with respect to Unemployment? EA95 3 NW96 EM 91 2 GHQDifference RS91 EAE M 96 92 SW92 EM 93WA 9H 393 Y WM 95 9491 NW 95 RS95 SW SW SW 93 EA94 WA96 GL91 RS96 RS93 W M 91NW94 Y9 H 9 7A9W RS 2 W 7 A95WA 91 EA91 YH92 SS C9 2 NW97 RS94 CS 9N 1 W 91 EM 95YH96 C 94 GL96 EA97 NT96 NT91 NW93 SC96 YH94 WM 92 SC97 GL92 SW96 WM 93 GL95 G L 9 7 EM 97 YE HM 99 52 S C 9 3 NW92 EA WM 97 99 53 SW97 NT92 SW9S 5C E M 94 RS97 1 W 92 T97 YH9 1AN GL93 GL94 0 EA96 WM 96 94 WA94WM NT93 NT95 NT94 -1 5 10 Regional Unemployment Rate 15 The well-being gap between employees and the unemployed is smaller in regions with greater unemployment. Social Comparisons with respect to Unemployment? 70 60.2 60 57.9 57.6 55.6 50 40 38.4 40 30.9 30.8 30 20 10 U ar tn er .P U U .P tn er ar tn er E U E E. Pa r tn er E. Pa r Re g= 10 % U .U Re g= 5% U .U Re g= 10 % E. U E. U Re g= 5% 0 Unemployment hurts less when I share it with other household members But there is little adaptation to unemployment Unemployment starts bad, and stays bad We get used to marriage And we get used to divorce Even widowhood is worse at the beginning than afterwards And we can’t even count on our children Social Comparisons with respect to Divorce? Can these two possibly be related? Own divorce hurts less in a high-divorce region The estimated effect of divorce is zero in a region with a 25% divorce rate. Is this a “plenty more fish in the sea” effect? Not only: the largest effect is from the regional percentage of divorced men on male divorce Adaptation to Poverty We may adapt to income in general, but what about adaptation to poverty as a specific low-income state? 0 0-1 1-2 2-3 3-4 4-5 -0.1 -0.2 -0.3 -0.4 Whole Sample Men Poverty starts bad and stays bad Women 5+ Social Comparisons and Social Capital? Research on BHPS data shows that: Individuals are happier when their levels of social capital (measured by social activities) are higher (but beware of causality) 1) Individuals are also happier when they live with other household members who are active socially 2) But, given own social capital and others’ social capital, there is a happiness boost from being the most active individual in the household. Well-Being and Others’ Social Capital: WVS Evidence Spillovers are defined at the regional (NUTS2) level. We drop regions with fewer than 50 observations. Others’ social capital measured by the regional median level Own SK Activity 0.075** (.011) Regional SK Activity (median) -0.098+ (.059) It is still good to be active oneself: but well-being is higher when others’ social activity is lower, as if there were comparisons in social capital. This can be seen in the coefficient on the continuous measure of others’ median social capital above. Well-Being and Others’ Social Capital: ESS Evidence Meet Friends Regional Average Meet Friends Observations Log likelihood All 0.156** (0.004) All 0.158** (0.004) Women 0.167** (0.006) Men 0.145** (0.006) -0.164** -0.210** -0.112* (0.037) (0.050) 86555 86555 45700 -164054.3 -164044.7 -86998.9 (0.057) 40855 -76927.6 Social Comparisons and Health? Work on European data has shown that : 1) My own health problems have less effect on my own well-being when the problems are shared by others in the same household. 2) Individuals feel less overweight as the average weight in the region rises 3) Within the household, couples where both are obese have similar mental stress levels to couples where neither is obese Women like their partner to have the same BMI as they do (life satisfaction in the BHPS) And… so do men Well-Being and BMI: Household Results. BHPS Wave 14 GHQ Obese -0.101** (0.031) -0.092* (0.039) -0.035 (0.039) -0.162** (0.045) -0.104* (0.045) 0.263** (0.099) 10648 6035 6035 Spouse Obese Both Obese Observations Note: Plus controls for Age, Sex, Education, Marital Status, Labour Force Status, and Income. And for those of you who like it semiparametrically, the “Happiness Hills” The hill peaks are on a 45-degree line: your own weight doesn’t matter if it matches your partner’s Social Comparisons and Religion? Recent work on European Social Survey Data shows that: Religious individuals are happier when they live in religious regions 1) But atheists are happier when they live in religious regions too 2) Catholics get a happiness boost from being in a Catholic majority region The religious “spillovers” are mostly positive Spillover effects of specific religious denominations: Life satisfaction regressions Spillover effects of specific religious denominations: Life satisfaction regressions The religious like being with other religious; they don’t like being with atheists. Atheists are more satisfied when they live in more religious regions too. Atheists don’t like living with other atheists either. Conclusions 1) Let’s switch from the extensive to the intensive margin. How much does the EP hold? 2) Are comparisons cardinal or ordinal? If the latter, then the EP holds fully 3) Who is in the reference group? 4) Is this a rich country result? 5) What is well-being anyway - Life satisfaction? - Happiness? - Psychological functioning? - Eudaimonia? We need to find domains of life that are non-rival to which we do not adapt… A Summary Horizontal Comparisons (Status) Intertemporal Comparisons (Adaptation) Income Yes Yes Unemployment Yes (but small) No Poverty ? No Marriage/Divorce Yes Yes Health Perhaps? Partial? Social Activities Perhaps? No? Freedom ? ? Religion Perhaps? ? Is everything really lost for GDP per capita? Almost all discussion in the literature has looked at mean happiness. We might not be so utilitarian though, in that we care about the distribution of happiness too. Could give more weight to those at the bottom of the well-being distribution: misery-aversion. Here GDP per capita does seem to play a role Happiness inequality and GDP per capita across countries, WVS Last available year (2000s) Happiness inequality within Country over Time in Growing Countries, Selected Western countries (WVS) Happiness inequality Over Time with Some periods of Negative or Zero Growth (WVS) Happiness inequality Over Time during Periods of Decreasing GDP (WVS) Single Country Results United Kingdom (BHPS) West Germany (SOEP) Single Country Results Australia (HILDA) United States (GSS) Income growth reduces happiness inequality, as do “social programmes”; income inequality increases happiness inequality