Deep Integration: Free trade agreements heterogeneity and its impact on bilateral trade Séminaire DIAL Jaime Ahcar Olmos Under the supervision of : Jean-Marc Siroën PSL Université Paris-Dauphine Laboratoire LEDa-DIAL 24 avril, 2014 Contents 1) Introduction 2) Methodology and Data 3) Results 4) Conclusions 5) References 1 Introduction • International trade economists have apparently successfully dealt with the question : does free trade agreements increase trade flows? Rose (2004), Baier & Bergstrand (2007), Martinez et al. (2009) • This has been done neglecting thorny issues like heterogeneity and the concept of deep integration. 2 Introduction : Questions • So we now try to answer new questions : • Are all free trade agreements equal? What happens if not ? • Does a deeper free trade agreement really increase trade more than a shallow agreement ? • What would be a good indicator of deep integration like ? • Are other provisions related to trade but out of the traditional WTO framework of negotiation really important to expand trade ? 3 Introduction : Importance • Preferential Trade Agreements PTA heterogeneity little explored • Indicators of heterogeneity • Implications for the interpretation of PTA coefficients • Implications for our understanding of the limits of trade liberalization 4 Literature review • Bourgeois, Dawar & Evnenett (2007). A Comparative Analysis of Selected Provisions in Free Trade Agreements. • Magee (2008) controlled for some levels of trade integration. • Vicard (2009) on the depth of the agreements found that their trade creation effect does not statistically differ according to the depth of the RTA. • Vicard, V (2011) By using interactions terms found that large, similar and close countriesn benefit more from RTA. This approach doesn’t care about their dose or their design. 5 Literature Review • Horn, Mavroidis & Sapir (2010) and nontraditional WTO provisions in the analysis and explored legal enforcement effects, but ramained on the descriptive approach. • Orefice & Rocha (2013) carried out empirical analysis from Horn et al. observarions and found positive evidence. • Dür, Baccini & Elsig (2014) enlarged the database and introduced latent trade analysis. 6 Database • Two different classification of agreements databases: 1) WTO (2011) Research division for the World Trade Report 2) Design of Trade Agreements DESTA-WTI (2014) Then, we introduce this information in our gravity model unbalanced panel data set which encompasses 153 countries and 613.030 bilateral trade flows from 1980 to 2012. 7 Databases and methodology : • Following (Horn et al. 2010) approach: • 1) WTO+ provisions: topics under the competence of the WTO agreements. • 2) WTO-X provisions: topics outside the current mandate of the WTO.” • This database is exploited by Orefice & Roche (2013) • Their regressions account for 66 PTA from 1980– 2007. We include in our calculations 103 PTA including agreements for Peru & Colombia from 1980-2012. 8 Database variables WTO+ Policy Areas Negociated in PTAs Anti-dumping Countervailing Measures GATS General Agreement on Trade in Services Public Procurement Sanitary and Phytosanitary Measures State Aid (Subventions) State Trading Enterprises Technical Barriers to Trade Trade Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights TRIPs TRIMs Trade-Related Investment Measures Source: Orefice & Rocha (2013), Horn et al. (2010). WTO ( 2011) Research division for the World Trade Report 9 Database variables WTO-X Provisions Negociated in PTAs Agriculture Innovation policies Anti-corruption Investment measures Approximation of Legislation Audiovisual Competition policy Consumer protection Cultural cooperation Data protection Economic policy dialogue Education and training Energy Environmental laws Financial assistance Health Human rights Illegal immigration Illicit drugs Industrial cooperation Information society IPR Labour market regulation Mining Money laundering Movement of capital Nuclear safety Political dialogue Public administration Regional cooperation Research and technology SMEs Social matters Statistics Taxation Terrorism Visa and asylum Source: Orefice & Rocha (2013), Horn et al. (2010). WTO ( 2011) Research division for the World Trade Report 10 Methodology • Probit approach • We put forward two main kinds of indicators to try to capture deep integration. • They depend on a set of variables (provisions) that characterize PTA texts. • 1) Additive indicators • 2) Distilled indicators taken from PCA related methodologies. 11 Methodology Contributions : Additive indicators • Does an additive indicator tell us something about the depth of the agreement? • Reasonably yes. One can expect that more comprehensive agreements are deeper. • Isn’t the magnitude of the reduction on tariffs the main indicator of depth? Maybe not, as nontariff barriers can play a major role to block trade. 12 Methodology Contributions : Distilled indicators • We calculate a Multiple Correspondence Analysis MCA indicator for deep integration: • MCA is a technique that can be applied to obtain an indicator that summarizes in just one dimension the variability of a set of variables related with the content and design of PTA, and then with the depth of the integration. 13 Limits of the analysis • “Europe’s single market is probably the best example globally of successful deep integration” Claar S. & Nölke A. (2010). • Nevertheless, because of methodology consistency requirements, Dür et al. (2014) additive indicator give UE 1992 single market agreement a 5 while Colombia USA receive a 7 • Orefice & Rocha gives 6-11 to EU27 but 9-27 to EUChile. • Enforceability of the agreements. Too subjective, it implies going into the nuances of the language in PTA texts. 14 Methodological Limits • Due to the large size of our data set, we can not completely control for multilateral resistance in all specifications. Anderson and Van Wincoop (2003); Baldwin & Taglioni (2006) • We try to minimize this setback by introducing time fixed effects and time invariant fixed effects for importers and exporters countries. 15 Theoretical Model xij is export from region i to region j, σ is the elasticity of substitution between all goods, tij is a trade cost factor between i and j; yi and yj are GDP in region i and region j; yW is world nominal income; k is a constant, (1 – σ) and (1 – σ)ρ are coefficients. 16 Probit model with single EV for the median rta coeffient on some WTO+ provisions (1) brtamed brtamed brtamed brtamed brtamed brtamed brtamed brtamed brtamed sps 0.071 (0.252) tbt 0.206 (0.282) ste -0.268 (0.248) ad 0.096 (0.319) cvm 0.077 (0.275) publicprocurement -0.226 (0.250) trims -0.074 (0.247) gats -0.219 (0.273) trips -0.132 (0.253) Constant Observations r2_p Standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 -0.031 -0.140 0.145 -0.066 -0.043 0.140 0.050 0.168 0.092 (0.196) (0.242) (0.174) (0.288) (0.233) (0.187) (0.177) (0.230) (0.196) 103 103 103 103 103 103 103 103 103 0.000555 0.00375 0.00823 0.000634 0.000552 0.00576 0.000625 0.00454 0.00192 17 Probit model with single EV for the median rta coeffieient on WTO-X provisions brtamed brtamed brtamed consumerprotection -0.599* (0.330) -0.520** environmentallaws (0.252) -0.496* labourmarketregulation (0.276) 0.120 0.244 0.155 (0.137) (0.168) (0.147) 103 Observations 0.0238 r2_p Standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 103 0.0302 103 0.0228 Constant 18 Results • On a probit model regression with single EV. No evidence that the presence of any particular provision under WTO+ would increase trade above the median level, which PTAs are supposed to do. • Only 3 out of 36 WTO-X provisions show significant estimators : environmental laws, labour market regulation and consumer protection. All three show a negative coefficient. • It could open the door to the possibility of PTA that deters trade rather than promote it. 19 Results • Robustness. Possible bias in the estimation of the individual PTA coefficients and colinearity between provisions. • A better way could be capture the whole variability of the provisions in just one indicator. • This indicator would give us a clue about the depth of the integration. 20 Specification to estimate with PPML : Control for large zero value flow observations in GM data sets and gives consistent estimates. (Silva & Tenreyro, 2006; 2011) 21 Deep integration: Latent trait analysis (Rasch) indicator Dur and al (2014) and additive indicator on levels and logs. DESTA. xij dp_D_ra0 xij xij xij 0.129*** (0.006) lndp_D_ra00001 0.027*** (0.001) deep_DE_ad 0.085*** (0.003) ln_dp_d_ad 0.033*** (0.001) lnPIBi 0.730*** 0.729*** 0.746*** 0.729*** (0.024) (0.024) (0.024) (0.024) 0.647*** 0.645*** 0.662*** 0.642*** (0.023) (0.023) (0.023) (0.022) -0.803*** -0.792*** -0.775*** -0.759*** (0.009) (0.009) (0.009) (0.009) -6.577*** -5.617*** -6.215*** -5.424*** (0.864) (0.863) (0.845) (0.850) 587,654 587,654 587,654 587,654 R-squared 0.891 0.892 0.900 0.900 Exporter FE YES YES YES YES Importer FE YES YES YES YES NO NO NO NO YES YES YES YES lnPIBj lndist Constant Observations Country-pair FE Time FE Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 22 Deep Integration: Additive indicators and its log from WTO+ and WTO-X. PPML estimator. xij ad_ch1 xij xij xij 0.058*** (0.002) lnad_ch00001 0.036*** (0.001) ad_x1 0.023*** (0.001) lnad_x100001 0.035*** (0.001) lnPIBi 0.765*** 0.734*** 0.756*** 0.738*** (0.024) (0.024) (0.024) (0.024) 0.679*** 0.647*** 0.671*** 0.650*** (0.023) (0.023) (0.024) (0.023) -0.784*** -0.746*** -0.819*** -0.747*** (0.009) (0.009) (0.008) (0.009) -5.860*** -5.607*** -5.810*** -5.623*** (0.886) (0.889) (0.904) (0.886) 572,657 572,657 575,383 575,383 R-squared 0.900 0.903 0.894 0.903 Exporter FE YES YES YES YES Importer FE YES YES YES YES NO NO NO NO lnPIBj lndist Constant Observations Country-pair FE Time FE YES YES YES YES Time Varying Exporter FE NO NO NO NO Time Varying Importer FE NO NO NO NO Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 23 Conclusions • We are now more aware that not all PTA are equal. This would imply that much of previous estimations on the average effect of PTA on trade could be biased. • Through different indicators we have confirmed that deeper PTAs increase trade more than shallow ones. However these indicators also present limits to their interpretation. A better definition of deep integration continues to be a challenge. 24 Conclusions • A better deep integration indicator should show EC model as the deepest. Meanwhile, these imperfect indicators present enough power to give us sufficient clues about the direction of the impact of heterogeneity of the agreements on trade. • Other provisions out of the traditional WTO scope present significant positive impact on trade. Yet, some of them could individually bear a negative impact. • More research is needed specially to try to identify which provisions or combination of provisions presents a higher impact. 25 Data Set : Sources PTA provisionas database : WTO ( 2011) Research division for the World Trade Report. http://www.wto.org/english/res_e/publications_e/wtr11_dataset_e.htm World Trade Institute (2014) . The Design of trade agreements database DESTA. Bilateral Exports: International Monetary Fund (IMF) Direction of Trade Statistics Database DOTS (2013). Current GDP and population: World Development Indicators (WDI) database, World Bank, (2013) Area, Island and Landlocked, constructed by the author based on the World Factbook from the Central Intelligence Agency of the United States of America (CIA) Weighted distance, contiguity, col45 and comlang_eth9 : CEPII (2013): Head, K., Mayer, T. & Ries, J. (2010), Gravity dataset, obs. till 2006. Regional Trade Agreements: constructed by the author, based on the Regional Trade Agreements Information System (RTA-IS), World Trade Organization WTO (2013) GATT membership: constructed by the author based on the World Trade Organization WTO information (2013). CEPII: Head, K., Mayer, T. & Ries, J. (2010), Gravity dataset, obs. Till 2006. OCDE membership: constructed by the author based on the Organisation de coopération et de développement économiques OCDE (2013) information. 26 References • • • • • • • • • • • • • • Horn, H., Mavroidis, P. C. and Sapir, A. (2010), “Beyond the WTO? an anatomy of EU and US preferential trade agreements”, The World Economy 33(11): 1565-1588 Bourgeois, J., K. Dawar and S.J. evenett. 2007. A Comparative Analysis of Selected Provisions in Free Trade Agreements, Study commissioned by DG Trade, Brussels: European Commission, mimeo Claar S. & Nölke A. (2010) Cross-Border Cooperation: Deep integration. http://www.dandc.eu/en/article/even-though-deepintegration-could-serve-developing-countries-strategy-politically Dür, A., Baccini, L.& Elsig, M. (2014) The Design of International Trade Agreements: Introducing a New Dataset. The Review of International Organizations. Orefice & Rocha (2013) Deep Integration and Production Networks: An Empirical Analysis. The World Economy. John Wiley & Sons Ltd Le Roux, B. and H. Rouanet (2010). Multiple Correspondence Analysis. Series Quantitative Applications in Social Sciences. 163. Sage Publications. Anderson, J. E. (1979) “A Theoretical Foundation for the Gravity Equation,” American Economic Review 69, 106-16. Anderson, J & Wincoop, E. (2003) “Gravity with Gravitas: A Solution to the Border Puzzle” American Economic Review, 93 (1), p 170 – 193. Baier, S & Bergstrand, J. (2007) Do free trade agreements actually increase members’ international trade? Journal of International Economics. 71, 72-95. Baldwin, R. & D. Taglioni (2006). ¨Gravity for Dummies and Dummies for gravity equations¨ NBER working paper No.12516, National Bureau of Economics Research, Inc. Breusch, T. S., & Pagan, A. R. (1980). The Lagrange multiplier test and its applications to model specification in econometrics. Review of Economic Studies, 47, 239−253. Cipollina, M. & Pietrovito, F. (2011) The trade impact of European Union Preferential Policies: A Meta-Analysis if the Literature. In De Benedictis, L. and Salvatini, L. (2011) The trade impact of European Union Preferential Policies. An Analysis Throug Gravity Models. Springer. 91-109. Cipollina, M. & Salvatici, L. (2011) Trade Impact of European Union Preferences. Chp. 6, in: De Benedictis, L. and Salvatini, L. (2011) The trade impact of European Union Preferential Policies. An Analysis Throug Gravity Models. Springer. 111-125 De Benedictis, L & Vicarelli, C. (2005) Trade Potentials in Gravity Panel Data Models. The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & 27 Policy. Topics in Economic Analysis & Policy. V. 5, No. 1. References • Feenstra, R. (2004b) Advanced International Trade. Theory and Evidence. Chap. 5. Increasing Returns and the gravity equation. Princeton University Press. 137 -173. • Hausman, J. (1978) Specification Tests in Econometrics. Econometrica, Vol. 46, No. 6 (Nov., 1978), pp. 1251-1271. Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1913827. • Head, K. Mayer, T., & Ries, J. (2010) The Erosion of colonial linkages after Independence. Journal of International Economics. 81, 1-14. • Krugman, P. (1979) “Incresing Rerturns, Monopolistic Competition, and International Trade”, Journal of International Economics, 9, pp. 469-479. • Liu, X., Burridge P., and Sinclair, P. (2002) Relationships between economic growth, foreign direct investment and trade: evidence from China. Applied Economics, 2002, 34, 1433-1440. • McCallum, J. (1995) "National Borders Matter: Canada-U.S. Regional Trade Patterns."American Economic Review, 85(3), pp. 615-23. • Martínez-Zarzosoa, I. & Nowak-Lehmann, F. & Horsewood, N. (2009) Are regional trading agreements beneficial? Static and dynamic panel gravity models. North American Journal of Economics and Finance 20 46–65. • Markusen, J. (2002) Multinational firms and the theory of international trade. Cambridge Etats-Unis : MIT Press. • Muchielli, J-L. et Mayer, T. (2011) Economie International. Dalloz. 2e Edition. Paris. • Rose, A (2004) Do we really know that the WTO increases trade? American Economic Review 13 (4), 682–698. • Rose, A. (2005) Which international institutions promote trade? Review of International Economics 13 (4), 682–698. • Rose, A., & Engel, C., (2002) Currency Unions and International Integration, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Blackwell Publishing, vol. 34(4), pp. 1067-89. • Santos Silva, J. & Tenreyro, S. (2006) The log of gravity, The Review of Economics and Statistics, 88, 641-58. • Santos Silva, J. & Tenreyro, S. (2011) Further simulation evidence on the performance of the Poisson pseudo-maximum likelihood estimator. Economics Letters. Volume 112, Issue 2, August 2011, Pages 220–222. • Timbergen, J. (1962) Shaping the World Economy: Suggestions for an International Economic Policy, New York : Twentieth Century Fund. • Trefler, D. (1993) Trade liberalization and the theory of endogenous protection: an econometric study of U.S. import policy. Journal of Political Economy. 101 (1), 138– 160. • Subramanian, A., Wei, S. (2007) The WTO promotes trade strongly, but unevenly. Journal of International Economics 72 (1), 151–175. 28