Profit-Maximization 利润最大化 A firm uses inputs j = 1…,m to make products i = 1,…n. Output levels are y1,…,yn. Input levels are x1,…,xm. Product prices are p1,…,pn. Input prices are w1,…,wm. The competitive firm takes all output prices p1,…,pn and all input prices w1,…,wm as given constants. The economic profit generated by the production plan (x1,…,xm,y1,…,yn) is p1y1 pnyn w1x1 wmxm . Profit: Revenues minus economic costs. Accounting cost: a firm’s actual cash payments for its inputs (explicit costs) Economic cost: the sum of explicit cost and opportunity cost (机会成本) (implicit cost). All inputs must be valued at their market value. Labor Capital Opportunity cost: The next (second) best alternative use of resources sacrificed by making a choice. Item Wages (w) Interest paid Accounting cost $ 40 000 Economic cost $ 40 000 10 000 10 000 w of owner 0 3000 w of owner’s wife Rent 0 1000 0 5000 Total cost 50 000 59 000 Output and input levels are typically flows(流量 ). E.g. x1 might be the number of labor units used per hour. And y3 might be the number of cars produced per hour. Consequently, profit is typically a flow also; e.g. the number of dollars of profit earned per hour. How do we value a firm? Suppose the firm’s stream of periodic economic profits is 0, 1, 2, … and r is the rate of interest. Then the present-value of the firm’s economic profit stream is PV 0 1 1r 2 (1 r ) 2 A competitive firm seeks to maximize its presentvalue. How? Suppose the firm is in a short-run circumstance ~ in which x 2 x2 . Its short-run production function is ~ ). y f ( x1 , x 2 ~ The firm’s fixed cost is FC w 2x 2 and its profit function is ~ . py w1x1 w 2x 2 A $ iso-profit line (等利润线) contains all the production plans that yield a profit level of $ . The equation of a $ iso-profit line is I.e. ~ py w1x1 w 2x 2 . ~ w1 w 2x 2 y x1 . p p y w1 p ~ w 2x 2 x1 p has a slope of w1 p and a vertical intercept of ~ w 2x 2 p . y Slopes w1 x1 p The firm’s problem is to locate the production plan that attains the highest possible iso-profit line, given the firm’s constraint on choices of production plans. Q: What is this constraint? A: The production function. y The short-run production function and ~ . x x technology set for 2 2 ~ ) y f ( x1 , x 2 Technically inefficient plans x1 y ~ ) y f ( x1 , x 2 Slopes w1 p x1 y Slopes * y * x1 x1 w1 p y ~ , the short-run Given p, w1 and x 2 x 2 * ~ * profit-maximizing plan is ( x1 , x 2 , y ). Slopes * y * x1 x1 w1 p y ~ , the short-run Given p, w1 and x 2 x 2 * ~ * profit-maximizing plan is ( x1 , x 2 , y ). And the maximum possible profit is . Slopes * y * x1 x1 w1 p y At the short-run profit-maximizing plan, the slopes of the short-run production function and the maximal iso-profit line are equal. Slopes * y * x1 x1 w1 p y At the short-run profit-maximizing plan, the slopes of the short-run production function and the maximal iso-profit line are equal. Slopes * y MP1 w1 p * ~ * at ( x1 , x , y ) 2 * x1 x1 w1 p MP1 w1 p p MP1 w1 is the value of marginal product of (边际产品价值) of input 1, p MP1 the rate at which revenue Increases with the amount used of input 1. If p MP1 w1 then profit increases with x1. If p MP1 w1 then profit decreases with x1. Suppose the short-run production 3 ~ 1/ 3 function is y x1/ 1 x2 . The marginal product of the variable y 1 2/ 3 ~ 1/ 3 input 1 is MP1 x1 3 x1 x2 . The profit-maximizing condition is MRP1 p MP1 p 3 * 2 / 3 ~ 1/ 3 x 2 w1 . ( x1 ) Solving p 3 * 2 / 3 ~ 1/ 3 ( x1 ) x 2 w1 for x1 gives 3w 1 * 2/ 3 ( x1 ) . ~ 1/ 3 px 2 That is, * 2/ 3 ( x1 ) so ~ 1/ 3 px * 2 x1 3 w 1 1/ 3 ~ px 2 3w 1 3/ 2 p 3w 1 3/ 2 1/ 2 ~ x2 . * x1 p 3w 1 3/ 2 1/ 2 ~ x2 is the firm’s short-run demand for input ~ x 1 when the level of input 2 is fixed at 2 units. The firm’s short-run output level is thus * 1/ 3 ~ 1/ 3 y ( x1 ) x2 * p 3w 1 1/ 2 ~ 1/ 2 . x 2 What happens to the short-run profit-maximizing production plan as the output price p changes? The equation of a short-run iso-profit line ~ is w w x y 1x 1 p 2 2 p so an increase in p causes -- a reduction in the slope, and -- a reduction in the vertical intercept. y ~ ) y f ( x1 , x 2 * y Slopes * x1 w1 p x1 y ~ ) y f ( x1 , x 2 * y Slopes * x1 w1 p x1 y ~ ) y f ( x1 , x 2 * y Slopes * x1 w1 p x1 An increase in p, the price of the firm’s output, causes an increase in the firm’s output level (the firm’s supply curve slopes upward), and an increase in the level of the firm’s variable input (the firm’s demand curve for its variable input shifts outward). The Cobb-Douglas example: When 1/ 3 ~ 1/ 3 y x1 x 2 then the firm’s short-run demand for its variable input 1 is * x1 p 3w 1 3/ 2 p y 3w 1 1/ 2 * * 1/ 2 ~ x2 and its short-run supply is ~ 1/ 2 . x 2 increases as p increases. * y increases as p increases. x1 What happens to the short-run profit-maximizing production plan as the variable input price w1 changes? The equation of a short-run iso-profit line ~ is w w x y 1x 1 p 2 2 p so an increase in w1 causes -- an increase in the slope, and -- no change to the vertical intercept. y ~ ) y f ( x1 , x 2 * y Slopes * x1 w1 p x1 y ~ ) y f ( x1 , x 2 * y Slopes * x1 w1 p x1 y ~ ) y f ( x1 , x 2 Slopes * y * x1 w1 p x1 An increase in w1, the price of the firm’s variable input, causes a decrease in the firm’s output level (the firm’s supply curve shifts inward), and a decrease in the level of the firm’s variable input (the firm’s demand curve for its variable input slopes downward). The Cobb-Douglas example: When 1/ 3 ~ 1/ 3 y x1 x 2 then the firm’s short-run demand for its variable input 1 is * x1 p 3w 1 3/ 2 p y 3w 1 1/ 2 * * 1/ 2 ~ x2 and its short-run supply is ~ 1/ 2 . x 2 decreases as w1 increases. * y decreases as w1 increases. x1 Now allow the firm to vary both input levels, i.e., both x1 and x2 are variable. Since no input level is fixed, there are no fixed costs. Long-Run Profit-Maximization The profit-maximization problem is max pf ( x1 , x2 ) w1 x1 w2 x2 . x1 , x2 FOCs are: p f ( x1*, x2 *) p x1 f ( x1*, x2 *) x2 w1 0. w2 0. Demand for inputs 1 and 2 can be solved as, x1 x1 ( w1 , w2 , p) x2 x2 ( w1 , w2 , p) For a given optimal demand for x2, inverse demand function for x1 is w1 pMP1 ( x1 , x2 *) For a given optimal demand for x1 inverse demand function for x2 is w2 pMP2 ( x1*, x2 ) w1 pMP1 ( x1 , x2 *) x1 The production function is yx 1/ 3 1 1/ 3 2 x First-order conditions are: 1 3 1 3 2 / 3 1 1/ 3 2 x w1 1/ 3 1 2 / 3 2 w2 px px x Solving for x1 and x2 : p x * 1 . 2 1 27 w w2 p * x2 3 3 2 27w 1w 2 Plug-in production function to get: p * y 3w 1 1/ 2 p 2 27w 1w 2 3 1/ 2 p 2 9 w 1w 2 . If a competitive firm’s technology exhibits decreasing returns-to-scale(规模报酬递减), then the firm has a single long-run profitmaximizing production plan. y y f(x) y* Decreasing returns-to-scale x* x If a competitive firm’s technology exhibits exhibits increasing returns-to-scale(规模报酬递增), then the firm does not have a profit-maximizing plan. y y f(x) y” y’ Increasing returns-to-scale x’ x” x So an increasing returns-to-scale technology is inconsistent with firms being perfectly competitive. What if the competitive firm’s technology exhibits constant returns-to-scale (规模报酬不变)? y y f(x) y” Constant returns-to-scale y’ x’ x” x So if any production plan earns a positive profit, the firm can double up all inputs to produce twice the original output and earn twice the original profit. Therefore, when a firm’s technology exhibits constant returns-to-scale, earning a positive economic profit is inconsistent with firms being perfectly competitive. Hence constant returns-to-scale requires that competitive firms earn economic profits of zero. y y f(x) =0 y” Constant returns-to-scale y’ x’ x” x Economic profit Short-run profit maximization Comparative statics Long-run profit maximization Profit maximization and returns to scale