Lausanne 2011 Inequality and economic crises A B Atkinson, Nuffield College, Oxford Salvatore Morelli, University of Oxford 1 1. Introduction; 2. Economic crises 1911-2010; 3. Which inequality of what? 4. Empirical evidence: case studies of Nordic and Asian crises; 5. Do crises lead to inequality? 6. Does inequality lead to crises? 7. What can we conclude so far? 2 1. Introduction: social cohesion and economic crises Two way relationship: Inequality and lack of social cohesion Economic crises: financial crises and collapses in output/consumption 3 DIFFERENT VIEWS: How do crises affect inequality? FALL: US 1929 Great Crash: “The upward drift [in inequality] accelerates from the turn of the century up to America’s entrance into World War I. Inequality fell between 1929 and the early years after World War II” (Williamson and Lindert, 1980, page 95). “The share of years … that a country was exposed to a banking crisis has a substantive negative impact on top income shares” [5 year crisis reduces share of top 1 per cent by 1 percentage point]” (Roine, Vlachos and Waldenström, Journal of Public Economics, 2009). 4 How do crises affect inequality? RISE: Asian financial crisis of 1997: “After nearly a decade of either declining or stable trend since the mid 1980s, the family income inequality in Korea sharply increased in the course of the financial crisis, and remained high even after the economy recovered from the recession” (Lee, 2002). “The current economic crisis has shown that it is the poor and vulnerable groups in society who are disproportionately affected by such shocks” (OECD, January 2011). 5 DIFFERENT VIEWS: Does inequality increase the risk of crises? NO: The indexes to three authoritative accounts of financial crises, by Kindleberger and Aliber (2005), Krugman (2009) and Reinhart and Rogoff (2009), contain neither “inequality” nor “income distribution”. The US Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission, set up in 2009 to investigate “the most significant financial crisis since the Great Depression”, was charged with examining 22 specific areas. None of these refer to inequality. 6 Does inequality increase the risk of crises? YES: According to Stiglitz, in the face of stagnating real incomes, households in the lower part of the distribution in the US borrowed to maintain a rising standard of living. This borrowing later proved unsustainable, leading to default and pressure on over-extended financial institutions. According to Rajan, “growing income inequality in the United States stemming from unequal access to quality education led to political pressure for more housing credit. This pressure created a serious fault line that distorted lending in the financial sector.” 7 2. Economic crises 1911-2010 Consider: • systemic banking crises (not limited to a few banks); • “collapses” in real consumption per capita. The study of crises requires long run data: “a data set that covers only twenty-five years simply cannot give one an adequate perspective” (Reinhart and Rogoff, 2009). It requires cross-country data: “to use history to gauge the probability and size distribution of macroeconomic disasters, it is hopeless to rely on the experience of a single country” (Barro, 2009, page 246). 8 The data challenge: Banking crises We have relied on three major sources to identify systemic banking crises: • Bordo, Eichengreen, Klingebiel and Martinez-Peria, 2001; • Reinhart and Rogoff, 2008, 2009 and Reinhart, 2010; • Laeven and Valencia, 2009 and 2010. They do not cover all the same countries or the same time periods, and they do not always agree. We have applied a majoritarian criterion. Where there are only two entries (one data-base does not cover the country or period), and they disagree, we have in general included the crisis. 9 Figure 1 62 Banking crises in 25 countries over 100 years (exc war times) US Norway Sweden Finland Iceland India Japan Indonesia Malaysia Mauritius Singapore Argentina Brazil Australia Canada New Zealand South Africa France Germany Italy Netherlands Portugal Spain Switzerland UK 1911 1921 1931 1941 1951 1961 1971 1981 1991 2001 10 The data challenge: Consumption crises Barro defines consumption (or GDP) “disaster” as peak to trough decline of at least 10 per cent: e.g. consumption in Argentina fell from a peak in 1998 to a trough in 2002 by 22.5 per cent. On the basis that perception of a “crisis” depends on expectations, we apply the Barro criterion before 1950, but a cut-off of 5 per cent after 1950. 11 Figure 2 55 consumption "collapses" in 25 countries over 100 years (exc war) US Norway Sweden Finland Iceland India Japan Indonesia Malaysia Mauritius Singapore Argentina Brazil Australia Canada New Zealand South Africa France Germany Italy Netherlands Portugal Spain Switzerland UK 1911 1921 1931 1941 1951 1961 1971 1981 1991 2001 12 Systemic No systemic TOTAL banking banking crisis crisis Consumption 18 37 55 “collapse” No consumption “collapse” 44 TOTAL 62 13 First need to clarify 3. Which inequality of what? • Inequality of what? Earnings versus income versus consumption versus wealth; • Snapshots versus lifetime outcomes; inequality of opportunity; • Which part of the parade should we be watching? • Horizontal dimensions of inequality. 14 Chartbook of economic inequality: 5 indicators 3. Poverty rate Poverty line 1. Overall inequality: Gini coefficient Income 2. Top income share “Middle class” The income “parade” + (4) top earnings decile and (5) top wealth share 15 Inequality: the data challenge • Crises are rare events, so that we need a long run of years; • To explore the impact of a crisis, we need to be able to monitor change year by year: we need annual series; • For the present crisis, we lack up-to-date distributional data for many countries; • For past years, we cannot simply download annual series on inequality covering a range of countries; • Data have to be pieced together from a variety of national sources; data for earlier parts of the century are hard (or impossible) to find; • Priority given to time series consistency over cross-country comparability. 16 Figure 3 Banking crises for which distributional data US Norway Nordic crises Sweden Finland Iceland India Asian crises Japan Indonesia Malaysia Mauritius Singapore Argentina Brazil Australia 62 banking crises: distributional data for 35. Canada New Zealand South Africa France Germany Italy Netherlands Portugal Spain Switzerland UK 1911 1921 1931 1941 1951 1961 1971 1981 1991 2001 17 Figure 4 consumption "collapses" for which distributional data US Norway Sweden Finland Iceland India Japan Indonesia Malaysia Mauritius Singapore Argentina Brazil Australia Canada New Zealand South Africa 55 consumption collapses: distributional data for 33 France Germany Italy Netherlands Portugal Spain Switzerland UK 1911 1921 1931 1941 1951 1961 1971 1981 1991 2001 18 4. Empirical evidence: case studies of Nordic and Asian crises Figure NO1 Economic crises and inequality in Norway 1911-2010 40 170 35 160 30 150 Gini coefficient, equivalised (EU-scale) household income, weighted by persons Share of top 1 per cent in gross income 20 Per cent living in households with equivalised (EU-scale) disposable income below 60 per cent median Share of top 1 per cent in total wealth 140 Per cent Per cent 25 Earnings at top decile as % median, series 1 (RH scale) 130 Earnings at top decile as % median, series 2 (RH scale) 15 120 10 110 5 0 1911 100 1921 1931 1941 1951 1961 1971 1981 1991 2001 Vertical line indicates start of banking crises; rectangle shows consumption collapse (peak to trough) 19 Figure SWE1 Economic crises and inequality in Sweden 1911-2010 Gini coefficient, equiv after tax income using EU scale household income, weighted by persons Share of top 1 per cent in gross income 35 175 Share of top 1 per cent in equiv after tax income using EU scale household income, weighted by persons Per cent below 60 per cent median 30 150 Top earnings decile as % median (RH scale) 25 125 20 100 15 75 10 50 5 25 0 1911 0 1921 1931 1941 1951 1961 1971 1981 1991 Per cent Per cent Share of top 1 per cent in total wealth (RH scale) 2001 Vertical line indicates start of banking crisis; rectangle shows consumption collapse (peak to trough) 20 Figure FIN1 Economic crises and inequality in Finland 1911-2010 40 Income Distribution Survey, equiv after tax income using EU scale household income, weighted by persons 200 Share of top 1 per cent in gross income, series 1 190 Share of top 1 per cent in gross income, series 2 180 Per cent below 60 per cent of median 30 Top decile of earnings (RH scale) 170 Per cent 25 160 20 150 Per cent 35 140 15 130 10 120 5 110 0 1911 100 1921 1931 1941 1951 1961 1971 1981 1991 2001 Vertical line indicates start of banking crisis; rectangle shows consumption collapse (peak to trough) 21 Figure JA1 Economic crises and inequality in Japan 200 Gini coefficient, Income Redistribution Survey 70 Share of top 1 per cent in gross income 190 Share of top 0.1 per cent in gross income 60 180 Per cent 50 Wealth Gini coefficient 170 Earnings top decile as per cent of median (RH scale) 160 40 150 30 Per cent Per cent below 60% median 140 130 20 120 10 110 0 100 1911 1921 1931 1941 1951 1961 1971 1981 1991 2001 Vertical line indicates start of banking crisis 22 60 24 50 20 40 16 30 12 Per cent Per cent Figure INDON1 Economic crises and inequality in Indonesia 1911-2010 Gini, expenditure data Gini, income data 20 8 Income share top 0.05 per cent (RH scale) Per cent below poverty line Income share top 1 per cent (RH scale) 10 4 0 0 1911 1921 1931 1941 1951 1961 1971 1981 1991 2001 Vertical lines indicate start ofbanking crises; rectangles show consumption collapses (peak to trough) 23 Figure MYA1 Economic crises and inequality in Malaysia 1911-2010 30 60 Income share top 1 per cent Income share top 0.1 per cent 25 50 Share of bottom 40 per cent Per cent Gini gross income (RH scale) 20 40 15 30 10 20 5 10 0 1911 0 1921 1931 1941 1951 1961 1971 1981 1991 2001 Vertical lines indicate start of banking crises; rectangles show consumption collapses (peak to trough) 24 Figure SI1 Economic crises and inequality in Singapore 1911-2010 60 250 Gini coefficient among employed population, series 1 Gini coefficient among employed households, income from work after government benefits and taxes, series 3 Share of top 1 per cent in gross income 40 Per cent 225 Gini coefficient among households, ranked by income from work, series 2 200 Share of top 10 per cent in gross income 30 175 Per cent 50 Earnings at upper quintile as % median (RH scale) 20 150 10 125 0 100 1911 1921 1931 1941 1951 1961 1971 1981 1991 2001 Vertical line indicates start of banking crisis; rectangle shows consumption collapse (peak to trough) 25 5. Do crises lead to inequality? Figure US1929 Window diagram Figure US1984-88 Window diagram 4.0 2.0 4.0 12.00 3.0 9.00 2.0 6.00 1.0 3.00 0.0 0.00 -1.0 -3.00 0.0 -2.0 -4.0 Gini coefficient -2.0 Gini coefficient -3.0 Income share top 1 per cent, disposable income (exc capital gains) Income share top 1 per cent, disposable income (inc capital -9.00 gains) Percent in poverty -4.0 Share of top 1 per cent in total wealth -6.0 Income share top 1 per cent, disposable income (exc capital gains) Income share top 1 per cent, disposable income (inc capital gains) Share of top 1 per cent in total wealth -8.0 -6.00 -12.00 Top decile as % median (Right hand scale) -5.0 -10.0 t-5 t-4 t-3 t-2 t-1 t t+1 t+2 t+3 t+4 t+5 -15.00 t-5 t-4 t-3 t-2 t-1 t t+1 t+2 t+3 t+4 t+5 Figure US2007 Window diagram Window diagrams 4.0 8.0 2.0 4.0 0.0 0.0 -2.0 -4.0 Gini coefficient -4.0 -8.0 Income share top 1 per cent, disposable income (exc capital gains) Income share top 1 per cent, disposable income (inc capital gains) Percent in poverty -6.0 -12.0 Top decile as % median (Right hand scale) -8.0 t-5 t-4 t-3 t-2 t-1 t t+1 t+2 t+3 t+4 t+5 -16.0 ? 26 Evidence from all 25 countries 1911-2010 Did inequality rise before and fall after? Classification of 31 banking crises (4?). After \ Classic US 1929 Before TOTAL = / 4 6 4 14 3 3 6 12 \ 1 2 2 5 TOTAL 8 11 12 31 / = 27 Evidence from all 25 countries 1911-2010 Did inequality rise before and fall after? Classification of 33 consumption collapses. After \ Classic US 1929 Before / = \ TOTAL TOTAL = / 6 3 4 13 3 1 6 10 4 2 2 8 13 6 12 31 28 6. Does inequality lead to crises? Evidence from all countries 1911-2010 Level of inequality in 2007 compared with ten years earlier and identification of a banking crisis in 2007-8 GINI coefficient Identified crisis No identified crisis TOTAL Higher inequality 2 5 7 No higher inequality 4 10 14 TOTAL 6 15 21 29 A matter of judgment: • classification of banking crises (B); • classification of consumption collapses (B/A); • identification of direction of change in inequality (C/B). The data do not lend themselves to straightforward statistical tests. 30 Interpretation: Co-incident or causal? 1. Banking model, with competitive consumption: Increased demand for consumer borrowing to finance desired consumption to keep up with those whose earnings are rising faster; banks respond by raising rates but take on more risk. Change in inequality (top, overall and bottom) is causal. 2. Banking model, with introduction of securitization: Change in banking practices with introduction of securitization, taking on greater risk to an extent that is greater the higher the degree of inequality. Level of inequality (overall and bottom) is jointly causal. 3. Banking model, with shift in remuneration practices: Remuneration becomes tied more closely to sales, so that banks behave more like sales maximisers than maximisers of shareholder value, increasing the exposure to risk. Observe increased top inequality and increased risk of crisis. Co-incident, not causal. 31 4. Financial sector model, with bubbles: Asset bubble draws skilled workers into financial sector, causing wage dispersion to rise. Change in inequality (top) is co-incident, not causal. 5. Political economy model of monetary policy: In response to rise in inequality, uses deregulation of banking for distributional reasons. Change in inequality (overall and bottom) is causal. 6. Political economy model of deregulation: Increased inequality at the top leads to lobbying for deregulation. Change in inequality (top) is co-incident. 7. Political economy model of pensions: Government decides to reduce size of welfare state. Loss of income to current beneficiaries causes inequality to rise. Households respond by saving more in private pensions, driving up equity prices, and by “buy-to-let” purchases of housing, driving up house prices. Change in inequality (bottom) is co-incident, not causal. 32 7. What can we conclude? • Economic inequality has many dimensions; here focused on income and its components, but some of the most important dimensions of inequality from the standpoint of social cohesion may be those not measured, such as inequality of opportunity; • Heterogeneity is important; different parts of the distribution may change differently: it depends which part of the parade we are watching; different parts are relevant to different explanatory models and have differing impact on social cohesion; • The role of inequality in the origins of crises and the distributional impact of banking crises may differ over time: “this time it may be different”; specifically, in the US there was a substantial rise in inequality leading up to the 1929 and S+L crises, but this was not the case with the present crisis; on the other hand, in terms of levels of inequality, 2007 may be more like 1929 than the 1980s; 33 7. What can we conclude (continued) • Outside the US, the history of crises in different countries round the world does not suggest that either rising or high levels of inequality have been adduced as significant causal factors; there is a range of possible mechanisms, but it is not evident that there is a smoking gun; • Cannot write off high inequality as temporary feature of bubble; in the US the only sustained period of inequality-reduction was in the early 1940s; quite a number of European (and Asian) countries have seen inequality and poverty rise after a banking crisis; • Much unfinished business, and, in order to make progress, need to bring together different branches of social science. 34