Partial Identification of Hedonic Demand Functions Congwen Zhang (Virginia Tech) Nicolai Kuminoff (Arizona State University) Kevin Boyle (Virginia Tech) 10/23/2011 ENDOGENEITY PROBLEM WITH HEDONIC DEMAND ESTIMATION Endogeneity arises because people choose prices and quantities/qualities simultaneously. Example: we are interested in X, an environmental good. Hedonic price function: P 0 1 ln( X ) (non-linear in X ) 1 X X P f ( X ) P Implicit price of X: ( is function of X ) 1 X Choice of X no based on an exogenous price. Why worry? Most policies result in nonmarginal changes in X. 2 “IMPERFECT” INSTRUMENTAL VARIABLES (NEVO & ROSEN, 2010) X: endogenous variable; Z: instrumental variable (IV) “perfect” IV: ZX 0 and ZU 0 “imperfect” IV : XU ZU 0 We allow correlation between IV and error (unobserved components of preferences! Z is “perfect”: IV Z is “imperfect”: is bounded by OLS and IV 3 1-SIDED AND 2-SIDED BOUNDS cov( X ,U ) var( X ) cov( Z ,U ) cov( Z , X ) OLS IV Proposition (Nevo & Rosen, 2010): Suppose both cov( X ,U ) and cov( Z ,U ) 0 Case 1: If cov( Z , X ) 0 , then IV OLS Case 2: If cov( Z , X ) 0 , then min{ OLS , IV } 4 “IMPERFECT” IVS IN DEMAND ESTIMATION Potential “imperfect” IVs: IV1. market indicator (M) IV2. interaction between M and income (M*INC) Why “imperfect” ? 1. sorting across markets 2. uncertainty about the spatial extent of a market Correlation Direction: cov(X, U)>0, cov(M, U)>0, cov(M, X)>0 cov(X, U)>0, cov(M*INC, U)>0, cov(M*INC, X)>0 both IVs give us one-sided bound ! 5 PARTIAL IDENTIFICATION OF MARSHALLIAN CONSUMER SURPLUS (MCS) Bounds on β Bounds on MCS Suppose we obtain a 2-sided bound: ˆL ˆU PX PX (slope = ˆU ) (slope = ˆL ) MCSl MCS2 6 X0 X1 X X0 X1 X PARTIAL IDENTIFICATION OF MCS px (slope = ˆU ) (slope = ˆL ) x0 x x1 x PARTIAL IDENTIFICATION OF MCS Suppose we obtain a 1-sided bound: ˆU PX S (slope = ˆU ) (slope = - ) X0 X X1 8 X AN EMPIRICAL DEMONSTRATION Water quality in markets for lakefront properties. Data description: (1) House transactions: from multiple markets in VT, ME, and NH. (2) Water clarity data: associated w/ each house. (3) Demographic data: associated w/ each home owner. Important features: (1) Each state includes data from multiple markets. (2) The spatial extent of a market is difficult to determine with certainty. 9 10 TWO-STAGE HEDONIC MODEL 1st stage: Estimate hedonic price function (market-specific) Pim 0m 1m BAREim 2m SQFTim 3m LOTim 4 m HEATim 5m FULLBATHim 6 m FFim 7 mWQim im WQ LAKESIZE ln(WT ) implicit price of water clarity: PimWT 7 m LAKESIZEim WTim 2nd Stage: Estimate demand function parameters (pooled) PiWT WTi ( 0 1SQFTi 2 FFi 3 AGEi 4 INCi 5 RETIREDi 6 KIDSi 7VISITi 8 FRIENDi ) U i 11 Table . Demand Estimation with Pooled Data Water Quality OLS M M*INC Bounds -710*** -2,253*** -2,975*** (-∞, -2,975] X 0 2.1, X 4.7, X1 5.4 [0, $2,732] (-∞, -$22,911] Boyle et al. (1999)’s point estimates fall into our bounds ! 16287; MCS ( X X1 ) $1270.36 State Maine New Hampshire Vermont Home Price Percent Effect $71,536 3.8 1.8 $159,299 1.7 $99,034 2.8 12 MCS ( X X1 ) MCS ( X X 0 ) CONCLUSIONS AND FUTURE RESEARCH Partial identification provides a more credible way to estimate demand and welfare. Provides approach to uncertainty analysis. How big can the injuries or benefits be? One-side bounds not always helpful. Partial identification logic can be a robustness check on point estimates. Implicit prices are plausible. 13 PREFERENCES FOR STORMWATER CONTROL IN RESIDENTIAL DEVELOPMENTS Jessica Boatright Kurt Stephenson Kevin J. Boyle Sara Nienow Virginia Tech 11/1/2011 APPLICATION Subdivision infrastructure that affects stormwater runoff. Hanover County, Virginia Residential home sales between 1995-1996 Mean sales price = $148,950 15 VARIABLES CUL = 1 if cul-de-sac and 0 otherwise CURBGUTTER = 1 if curb-and-gutters and 0 otherwise STW20 = 1 if street width 20 feet or less and 0 otherwise STW25 = 1 if street width 20 to 30 ft and 0 otherwise street width greater than 30 ft is omitted category 16 RESULTS Variables CUL CURBGUTTER STW20 STW25 Estimates 0.147** (0.007) 0.074*** (0.016) 0.032** (0.016) 0.040*** (0.014) 17 IMPLICATIONS Cul-de-sacs and curb and gutters channel and rapidly transport stormwater, which can exacerbate nonpoint-source pollution of surface waters. Narrower streets mean less impervious surface, which can reduce some of the residential stormwater effects, but the benefits to home owners are less that being on a cul-de-sac or having a curb and gutter on their street. 18