Damien Moore Rebecca Evans POL-242-A 10 December 2024 The Role of Ruling Parties in Sustaining Competitive Authoritarianism In “The New Competitive Authoritarianism,” Steven Levitsky and Lucan Way explore the persistence of competitive authoritarian regimes, focusing on the international and institutional factors that contribute to their continued existence. However, while their analysis is extensive, they fail to fully consider how the internal dynamics of political institutions within these regimes—specifically the structure of the ruling party—can significantly influence the longevity and stability of competitive authoritarianism. The authors focus heavily on external factors like the waning power of Western liberalism and the influence of regional powers like Russia and China. While these factors are undeniably important, they do not adequately address how the internal structures of competitive authoritarian regimes, particularly the consolidation of power within ruling parties, can either solidify or undermine the grip of authoritarian leaders. By looking closer at how ruling parties in these regimes manage internal conflict, control political elites, and maintain cohesion, we can see how these internal dynamics are just as crucial in sustaining competitive authoritarianism. Levitsky and Way argue that “competitive authoritarianism was a post-Cold War phenomenon—a product of an international environment that was uniquely hostile to full-scale dictatorship” (Levitsky & Way, 52). This argument focuses on how the external international environment forced elites to adopt hybrid political structures. While they acknowledge the importance of domestic political conditions, they primarily attribute the persistence of competitive authoritarianism to external pressure—or the lack thereof. As the authors note, “Western linkage and leverage had lost much of their force,” leading to a “diminished interest in democracy promotion” (Levitsky & Way, 53). This argument is certainly valid when analyzing the role of external forces like the European Union and the United States in promoting democracy. However, it fails to account for how the internal dynamics of ruling parties themselves play a critical role in either reinforcing or destabilizing competitive authoritarian regimes. One of the most significant internal dynamics is the capacity of ruling parties to manage factionalism and prevent elite fragmentation. In many competitive authoritarian regimes, the ruling party plays a central role in maintaining control over the state. Leaders who consolidate power within a cohesive, loyal party can more effectively suppress opposition and create the appearance of democratic processes, such as elections, that are not competitive in substance. The ability to prevent splits within the ruling party ensures that the leader can rely on a loyal base of support that provides both political stability and the suppression of dissenting voices within the government. Levitsky and Way mention how ruling elites are often “compelled to permit a degree of pluralism and electoral competition” under pressure from external forces (Levitsky & Way, 52). However, they do not delve into how ruling parties manage the internal dynamics that allow them to navigate this pluralism. In regimes like Venezuela under Hugo Chávez or Russia under Vladimir Putin, the internal cohesion of the ruling party has been essential in maintaining the facade of democracy. In Venezuela, for example, Chávez's United Socialist Party of Venezuela (PSUV) effectively consolidated power by co-opting opposition parties, managing internal dissent, and ensuring that key institutions—such as the military and judiciary—remained loyal to the party. This internal unity allowed Chávez to present his regime as a competitive authoritarian system, with elections that were widely criticized but still technically held. The authors’ focus on external pressures misses the critical role that party cohesion plays in maintaining control within these regimes. Furthermore, the authors’ analysis does not consider how competitive authoritarian regimes adapt to internal challenges, especially when factionalism arises within the ruling party. In some cases, the fragmentation of the ruling party can destabilize a regime. This is evident in the collapse of competitive authoritarianism in countries like Peru and Taiwan, where ruling parties failed to maintain internal cohesion, leading to democratic transitions. As Levitsky and Way note, “some competitive authoritarian regimes democratized,” but they do not explore in depth how the inability of ruling parties to manage internal divisions led to these transitions (Levitsky & Way, 51). In contrast, regimes like Belarus and Zimbabwe have managed to avoid democratization by maintaining unity within their ruling parties, despite significant external and internal challenges. A key example of the role of party cohesion in competitive authoritarianism is found in Hungary under Viktor Orbán. The authors highlight Orbán’s manipulation of parliamentary power, but they do not explore the role of his party, Fidesz, in cementing his hold on power. Orbán’s ability to centralize authority within Fidesz allowed him to control the political agenda, suppress opposition, and subvert democratic institutions. The ruling party’s unity enabled Orbán to effectively shut down dissent within Hungary’s political system, making it more difficult for competitive authoritarianism to transition into full authoritarianism or democracy. Levitsky and Way’s failure to address this aspect of internal dynamics in competitive authoritarian regimes overlooks a critical element in understanding their persistence. Additionally, the role of the ruling party in creating a “party-state” structure—where the state apparatus is co-opted by the party—also plays a significant role in sustaining competitive authoritarian regimes. The authors briefly mention how regimes in competitive authoritarian systems have “hardened” into full-blown authoritarianism, but they do not fully explain how ruling parties often contribute to this hardening process by gradually eroding the independence of key institutions. In Russia, for instance, the consolidation of power within the United Russia party has been accompanied by the gradual dismantling of independent media, courts, and opposition parties. The control over state resources and the patronage system, which are distributed through the ruling party, help maintain a firm grip on power. This internal consolidation of power, however, is rarely discussed in the authors’ analysis, which focuses more on the impact of external pressures on these regimes. In conclusion, while Levitsky and Way provide an insightful analysis of the role of external factors in shaping competitive authoritarianism, their argument would be more robust if it considered the internal dynamics of ruling parties in these regimes. The ability of ruling parties to maintain cohesion, manage factionalism, and control key state institutions is essential to understanding why some competitive authoritarian regimes persist while others transition toward democracy or full authoritarianism. The internal consolidation of power within ruling parties, as seen in cases like Venezuela, Russia, and Hungary, is a critical factor that sustains competitive authoritarianism, even in the face of diminished external pressures. By overlooking these internal factors, Levitsky and Way miss a crucial piece of the puzzle in explaining the persistence of competitive authoritarian regimes.