Theory of Income II - Winter 2025 Guido Lorenzoni Lecture notes 3 - Household Borrowing 1 Household borrowing in the NK model • Based on Eggertsson-Krugman • Preferences of consumer i X βi ln Cit Qt Bit+1 + Pt Cit = Wt Nt + Bit + Tt • We remove disutility of labor: agents just have a unitary fixed endowment of labor 1 and supply it inelastically • We introduce two elements: – heterogeneity, some consumers borrow some lend – a borrowing constraint • Simplest reason for borrowing and lending: different preferences • Two groups of agents with discount factors βs > βb • Borrowing constraint Bit ≥ −Φ 1 1 ≥ (1 + it ) βi Cit Cit+1 with inequality only if Bit = −φ • Mass α of impatient (b) agents and 1 − α of patient (s) agents • Firms use the linear technology Yt = Nt • We are interested in what happens when there is a shock to the borrowing limit Φ 1 1.1 Flexible prices • We begin with the neoclassical benchmark • Full employment equilibrium must have clearing in labor market Nt = 1 • Natural output is Y ∗ = N∗ = 1 1.1.1 Steady state • Steady state: – impatient agents have constant consumption C b = Y ∗ − Φ + QΦ – patient agents have constant consumption C s = Y ∗ + B − QB • Bond price 1 1+r (r real interest rate, nominal price of goods constant and normalized to 1) Q= • Bond market clearing α (−Φ) + (1 − α) B = 0 or B= α Φ 1−α • Patient agents are unconstrained, so their Euler equation must hold 1 1 = (1 + r) β s s s C C which requires 1+r = 1 βs • Impatient agents are always constrained, easy to check that 1 1 > (1 + r) β b b Cb C just because βb < βs 2 • Equilibrium allocation r Φ 1+r α r Cs = Y ∗ + Φ 1−α1+r Cb = Y ∗ − • Is the goods market in equilibrium? • Yes, by Walras Law since we checked bonds market equilibrium we automatically get goods market equilibrium: αC b + (1 − α) C s = Y ∗ 1.1.2 Financial shock • Suppose there is a shock and Φ goes from some positive level to zero • Then new steady state is especially simple Cb = Cs = Y ∗ and the same interest rate 1+r = 1 1 = s q β • But how do we reach the new steady state? • Transitional dynamics • They only last one period (guess and verify) • First period after the shock, call it time t, has – For impatient agents Ctb = Y ∗ − Φ – So for patient agents we need Cts = Y ∗ + α Φ 1−α • (Again this can come from bond market clearing or goods market clearing) • Check Euler equations 1 1 = (1 + rt ) β s ∗ α Y ∗ + 1−α Φ Y 1 Y∗−Φ > (1 + rt ) β b 3 1 Y∗ • So we need a temporary drop in the interest rate 1 + rt = 1 Y∗ 1 < s α s ∗ β Y + 1−α Φ β • Check Euler equation of borrowers α Y ∗ + 1−α Φ Y∗−Φ > βb βs b but this always holds because ββs < 1 • (Transition from low Φ to high Φ can last many periods, but transition from high Φ to low Φ always lasts only one period) • Result: a contraction in the borrowing capacity of households leads to a temporary drop in the interest rate • What happens when we add nominal rigidities? 2 With nominal rigidities • An especially simple assumption • Downward inflexible nominal wages Wt ≥ Wt−1 • If Nt < 1 wages remain at Wt−1 • (We could add gradual adjustment, or richer forms of stickiness, the basic message is similar) • Competitive firms produce identical goods, so no markup and prices are always Pt = W t • What happens after shock? • Suppose 1 Y∗ <1 α β s Y ∗ + 1−α φ • Now we need negative real interest rates in the flexible price economy 4 (1) • Suppose we have zero inflation in all periods t + 1, t + 2, ... • (This is an implicit assumption on monetary policy behavior in future periods, we’ll go back to this) • Guess and verify that in all periods t + 1, t + 2, ... we reach the new flexible price steady state with Yt+j = Y ∗ and Ci = Y ∗ for all agents and nominal interest rate 1+i= 1 >1 βs • What happens at period t? • Central bank sets it = 0 and expected inflation is 0 • Savers satisfy 1 1 = βs ∗ Cts Y • Borrowers Ctb = Yt − Φ • Let’s look at the goods market equilibrium condition Yt = α (Yt − Φ) + (1 − α) or Yt = Y∗ βs Y∗ α Φ<Y∗ − βs 1−α • The inequality follows from the negative natural rate condition (1) • There is unemployment caused by deleveraging and the inability of the central bank to counter its effects by lowering rates 3 Aggregate demand externalities • Suppose agents anticipate at t − 1 that there will be a financial shock to Φ at date t • Suppose impatient agents are sufficiently impatient that they still borrow Φ at t − 1 (see condition (2) below) 5 • Suppose there is zero inflation in all periods and the equilibrium at t − 1 has Yt−1 = Y ∗ • We will check below that the central bank can choose a positive interest rate at t − 1 to get that equilibrium • Equilibrium consumption levels are b Ct−1 = Y ∗ − (1 − Qt−1 ) Φ α s (1 − Qt−1 ) Φ Ct−1 =Y∗+ 1−α • We derive the interest rate from 1 α Y ∗ + 1−α 1 − 1+i1t−1 = β s (1 + it−1 ) Φ 1 1 2 = (β s ) (1 + it−1 ) ∗ Cts Y (using the s Euler equation at t − 1 and at t) • Notice that since it−1 is close to 1 the real rate required for this equation 2 is close to 1/ (β s ) so we have it−1 > 0 and the zero lower bound is not binding • To do a simple experiment we choose β b such that Euler equation of b agents holds exactly 1 Y ∗ − 1 − 1+i1t−1 Φ = (1 + it−1 ) β b 1 Yt − Φ (2) where Yt was derived above • Suppose we introduce a regulation to lower Φ a bit to Φ0 = Φ + dΦ with dΦ < 0 • Keep zero inflation throughout, suppose interest rate is kept at natural level at t − 1 • What are the welfare effects? • Consumption at t − 1 and t is b Ct−1 = Y ∗ − Φ + Qt−1 Φ0 Ctb = Yt − Φ0 and α (Φ − Qt−1 Φ0 ) 1−α Y∗ Cts = s β s Ct−1 =Y∗+ 6 • Consumption is still Y ∗ for all consumers at t + 1, t + 2, ... • Output at t is Yt = Y∗ α − Φ0 βs 1−α so the effect is to increase output at t dYt = − α dΦ > 0 1−α • This is an aggregate demand externality: by entering period t with less debt, b agents increase aggregate spending and thus aggregate activity • It is an externality because individual borrowers do not internalize the general equilibrium effect of their spending on aggregate income • Real rate at t − 1 from 1 1 = β s (1 + rt−1 ) β s ∗ α Y ∗ + 1−α (φ − qt−1 φ0 ) Y • It can be shown that dφ < 0 causes dqt−1 > 0 and d (qt−1 φ) < 0 so we have b dCt−1 <0 s dCt−1 >0 and also dCtb > 0 dCts = 0 • So patient agents are better off, what about impatient agents? • Notice that b dCt−1 = qt−1 dφ + φdqt−1 and dCtb = dYt − dφ • The marginal effect on borrowers’ welfare is 1 1 1 1 b dCt−1 + β b b dCtb = b (qt−1 dφ + φdqt−1 ) + β b b (dYt − dφ) b Ct−1 Ct Ct−1 Ct • Now the terms with dφ cancel due to condition (2) as 1 1 b 1 b 1 q dφ − β dφ = − (1 + r ) β qt−1 dφ = 0 t−1 t−1 b b Ct−1 Ctb Ct−1 Ctb 7 • So we are left with 1 1 φdqt−1 + β b b dYt > 0 b Ct−1 Ct • This effect is positive due to the combination of a pecuniary externality (lower borrowing reduces interest rates, transfering resources to borrowers) and of an aggregate demand externality • So the regulatory intervention to reduce debt at t − 1 leads to a Pareto improvement 8