The Law of Securities, Commodities and Bank Accounts ELGAR FINANCIAL LAW Series Editor: Takis Tridimas, Queen Mary, University of London, UK This important series comprises high quality monographs on a wide range of topics in the field of financial law, hosting work by established authors of international reputation, alongside younger and more emerging authors. The series is synonymous with original thinking and new, challenging research. The subjects under consideration range from financial services law, through securities regulation, to banking law and from financial fraud, through legal aspects of European Monetary Union and the single currency, to the legal workings of international financial institutions. Titles in the series include: Law and Corporate Finance Frank B. Cross and Robert A. Prentice Secured Transactions Reform and Access to Credit Edited by Frederique Dahan and John Simpson Financial Regulation in Crisis? The Role of the Law and the Failure of Northern Rock Edited by Joanna Gray and Orkun Akseli Law Reform and Financial Markets Edited by Kern Alexander and Niamh Moloney Regulating Credit Rating Agencies Aline Darbellay The Law of Securities, Commodities and Bank Accounts The Rights of Account Holders Marek Dubovec The Law of Securities, Commodities and Bank Accounts The Rights of Account Holders Marek Dubovec Senior Research Attorney, National Law Center for Inter-American Free Trade and Visiting Professor, James E. Rogers College of Law, University of Arizona, USA ELGAR FINANCIAL LAW Edward Elgar Cheltenham, UK + Northampton, MA, USA © Marek Dubovec 2014 All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical or photocopying, recording, or otherwise without the prior permission of the publisher. Published by Edward Elgar Publishing Limited The Lypiatts 15 Lansdown Road Cheltenham Glos GL50 2JA UK Edward Elgar Publishing, Inc. William Pratt House 9 Dewey Court Northampton Massachusetts 01060 USA A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library Library of Congress Control Number: 2013954380 This book is available electronically in the ElgarOnline.com Law Subject Collection, E-ISBN 978 1 78254 902 4 ISBN 978 1 78254 901 7 03 Typeset by Columns Design XML Ltd, Reading Printed and bound in Great Britain by T.J. International Ltd, Padstow Dedicated to Boris Kozolchyk Contents viii xi Preface List of abbreviations Introduction PART I 1 SECURITIES ACCOUNT RELATIONSHIPS 1. Introduction to Part I 2. Securities account relationships 3. Transfers of intermediated securities, finality and security interests 4. Summary of Part I PART II 21 46 68 81 BANK ACCOUNT RELATIONSHIPS 5. Introduction to Part II 6. Bank account relationships 7. Funds transfers, finality and security interests 8. Summary of Part II PART III 87 113 132 153 COMMODITY ACCOUNT RELATIONSHIPS 9. Introduction to Part III 10. Commodity account relationships 11. Commodity transfers, finality and security interests 12. Summary of Part III 159 187 202 218 Conclusion Index 222 233 vii Preface This book originated out of a doctoral thesis I wrote at the University of Arizona, James E. Rogers College of Law. The thesis, originally completed in the summer of 2009, has been updated and enriched numerous times with new material, however the focus, substance and analysis have not changed. This book examines legal aspects of the relationships between intermediaries and their customers based on securities, bank and commodity accounts. Initially, it was the transformation in the holding of securities to an intermediated system that drew my attention to the topics. Realizing the wealth of literature that already existed at that time, and the many more books and academic articles written since then on the subject, I decided to focus my writings on the comparison of the structure, rights in, transfers of, and security interests over securities, funds and commodity contracts held in accounts. For quite some time both funds and commodity contracts have been held in accounts maintained by intermediaries. More recently, traditional security certificates have been largely replaced with entries in electronic accounts. The holding of these assets in accounts complements their trading, which has also been brought onto electronic platforms. Accordingly, securities and commodity contracts are no longer issued and exchanged for funds in their physical form. Rather, intermediaries complete transfers by entries to bank, commodity and securities accounts. This account-based nature of these holding systems brought to light a number of legal issues and highlighted the inadequacy of laws that facilitate transactions completed by physical delivery of assets. The nature of rights associated with these assets has also been affected, most prominently for securities held in accounts. The account-based nature of assets permeates all aspects of the holding, including clearing and settlement of the transaction, the transfer between customers and the granting of security interests to creditors. These aspects are the primary focus of this book. This book not only compares the three major account-based systems but it does so from a comparative law perspective. While developed countries have established efficiently functioning account-based systems, this is not the case in the majority of developing countries that are yet to viii Preface ix implement or modernize their accounts holding systems. This is true not only in terms of the technological infrastructure of such systems but also in terms of the governing legal framework. In order to remain competitive in the global marketplace and increase the cost-efficiency of commercial transactions as a whole, developing countries should strive to ensure that their accounts systems reflect modern technological and legal standards. Their successful functioning also requires an adequate regulatory framework governing the conduct of all participants. This book addresses neither the technological nor regulatory aspects of the three account-based systems but it is limited to the commercial law aspects of their operation. My foremost debt is to Boris Kozolchyk, who inspired me to write on this topic and who subsequently chaired the doctoral committee for my original thesis. The other two members of the committee, David Gantz and Dale Furnish, provided invaluable guidance and suggestions that enriched not only the content of the thesis, but also its structure and flow of ideas. José Maria Garrido and Bill Henning provided insightful criticism along the way and Elizabeth Pocock, fellow attorney at the National Law Center for Inter-American Free Trade, assisted immensely in the final stages of preparing the book for publication, for which I am very grateful. In discussions, many others have made me understand the issues covered in this book further. I would also like to thank my employer, the National Law Center for Inter-American Free Trade, for making it possible to enroll in and obtain the doctoral degree while maintaining full-time employment. Lastly, and of no less significance, I would like to thank my wife Mariya and son Ivan. That being said, all and any errors contained in this book are solely my own responsibility. I hope that this book will foster a better understanding of each of the types of accounts examined and the nature and scope of the differences among them as well as their governing legal regimes. Even though this book examines only the fundamentals of account-based systems, it may inspire legislators to re-think their approach to regulating account-based rights and thus contribute to reform and modernization of this area of the law. Legal reforms designed to facilitate commercial transactions have proven to be an important driving force of economic development. The ability of participants in a commercial marketplace to complete their transactions expeditiously, at a low cost and with minimum risks fosters economic development by increasing the revenues of businesses and employment as well as by reducing operational costs. My main objective was to identify the underlying principles that should be embodied in modern legislation underpinning the law of accounts. Many of these principles are common to all three accounts x The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts systems but some exhibit peculiarities. This identification process and analysis of the underlying principles is an attempt to conceptualize the emerging law of commercial accounts. This conceptual framework should assist the reader in understanding this area of law, facilitate its evolution and contribute to the modernization of legal frameworks in need of reform. Abbreviations BM&F BMV CBLC CBOE CBOT CCP CEDEVAL CEVAL CFTC CHIPS CME CSD Deceval Reglamento DTC DTCC DVP ECB EU EU Financial Collateral Directive EU Regulation 648/2012 EU Settlement Finality Directive EuroCCP Brazilian Mercantile and Futures Exchange Bolsa Mexicana de Valores (Mexico) Brazilian Clearing and Depository Corporation Chicago Board Options Exchange Chicago Board of Trade Central counterparty Central de Depósito de Valores (El Salvador CSD) Central de Valores (Costa Rica CSD) Commodity Futures Trading Commission Clearing House Inter-Bank Payments System (US) Chicago Mercantile Exchange Central securities depository Resolución 0816 del 26 May 2011 emitida por la Superintendencia Financiera de Colombia, Reglamento de Operaciones Deceval S.A. (Colom.) Depository Trust Company (US) Depository Trust & Clearing Corporation (US) Delivery-versus-payment European Central Bank European Union Council Directive 2002/47/EC on Financial Collateral Arrangements, 2002 O.J. (L 168) Council Regulation 648/2012 on OTC Derivatives, Central Counterparties and Trade Repositories, 2012 Council Directive 98/26/EC on Settlement Finality in Payment and Securities Settlement Systems 1998 O.J. (L 166) European Central Counterparty Limited xi xii The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts EuroCCP Rules European Central Counterparty Limited Rules (1 October 2012) Geneva Securities UNIDROIT Convention on Substantive Rules for Convention Intermediated Securities (2009) German Banking Act Gesetz über das Kreditwesen, 9 September 1998 (Federal Law Gazette I S.2776) Hague Securities Convention on the Law Applicable to Certain Convention Rights in Respect of Securities Held with an Intermediary (2006) HTA Hedge-to-arrive IADB Inter-American Development Bank IMF International Monetary Fund Indeval Regulations Indeval, Reglamento Interior IOSCO International Organization of Securities Commissions LVFTS Large-value funds transfer systems MexDer Mercado Mexicano de Derivados, S.A. de C.V (Mexico) Mexican Securities Ley del Mercado de Valores [LMV] (Securities Market Law Market Law) Diario Oficial de la Federación [DO], 30 December 2005 MiFID Council Directive 2004/39/EC on Markets in Financial Instruments, 2004 O.J. (L 145) NS Net settlement NSCC National Securities Clearing Corporation (US) NYSE New York Stock Exchange OAS Organization of American States OTC Over-the-counter PSD Payment Services Directive (EU) ROFEX Rosario Futures Exchange RTGS Real-time gross settlement Ley de Anotaciones Electrónicas de Valores en Salvadoran Law Cuenta (Law on Electronic Entries of Securities to on Electronic Accounts) Diario Oficial [DO] 57, 22 March 2002 Entries (2002) SEC Securities and Exchange Commission (US) SELIC Sistema Especial de Liquidação e de Custódia (Brazilian CSD) Abbreviations SINPE xiii El Sistema Nacional de Pagos Electrónicos (Costa Rica) SIPC Securities Investor Protection Corporation (US) SIPS Slovak Interbank Payment System SITRAF Sistema de Transferência de Fundos (Brazil) Slovakian Payments Zákon o platobnom styku, 19 September 2002, Law (Z.z. 510/2002) Slovakian Securities Zákon o cenných papieroch a investičných Act službách, 9 November 2001 (Z.z. 566/2001) (Slovk.) SPEI Sistema de Pagos Electrónicos Interbancarios (Mexico) STR Sistema de Transferência de Reservas (Brazil) SWIFT Society for Worldwide Interbank Financial Telecommunication TARGET2 Trans-European Automated Real-time Gross Settlement Express Transfer UCC Uniform Commercial Code UNCITRAL United Nations Commission on International Trade Law UNCITRAL Model UNCITRAL Model Law on International Credit law Transfers (1994) UNIDROIT The International Institute for the Unification of Private Law Introduction Ordinary commercial transactions are typically concluded in two phases. The first involves an agreement to sell and buy. For example, Steve agrees to sell IBM stock or 100 bags of corn to Brian who in turn commits to pay the purchase price. These agreements are composed of reciprocal promises to deliver and pay. The second phase of these transactions involves performance of these promises, which in this case will be delivery of the stocks or corn in exchange for payment. This second phase is known as settlement. Commercial transactions and undertakings consist of these two components. First, parties agree or promise to do something and second they execute or settle those prior promises. For the most part, intermediaries facilitate the completion of both phases. Securities brokers execute their customers’ orders to sell IBM stock and then credit the proceeds of those sales to the customers’ securities accounts. Banks issue letters of credit at the request of customers and then pay the beneficiaries by crediting funds to their deposit accounts if they present complying documents. Futures commission merchants execute their customers’ orders to purchase commodity contracts on commodity exchanges and then credit those contracts to commodity accounts. These intermediaries and the functions they perform have become the cornerstone of contemporary commercial transactions. Banks facilitate transfers of funds, securities intermediaries execute their customers’ orders to buy and sell investment securities and futures commission merchants acquire commodity contracts for their customers. The contemporary commercial marketplace cannot function effectively without ensuring that participants are able to undertake such promises. Of equal importance is the need for the marketplace to be equipped with modern legal and technological mechanisms to settle promises, make the corresponding rights acquired upon execution of those promises available to investors and allow investors to dispose of such rights efficiently. Intermediaries not only play a significant role in the first phase of commercial transactions but they also ensure that the 1 2 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts second phase is completed efficiently. They do so primarily by maintaining accounts for their customers, to which they make credit and debit entries representing rights and assets resulting from transactions. These two phases of commercial transactions are completed in different segments or ends of the marketplace. One segment, which may be referred to as the ‘front-end’, is the market in which assets, such as shares, bonds and commodity contracts are issued and traded. The front-end thus involves the exchange of promises, execution of buy and sell orders and conclusion of agreements. Historically, front-end transactions were completed in personal meetings between buyers and sellers and later in the form of distance selling with the parties entering into contracts remotely. These transactions are now executed at centralized markets, including stock exchanges such as the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) and commodities exchanges such as the Chicago Mercantile Exchange (CME). In these markets, assets are issued, listed and traded among investors remotely. The front-end is the environment for floor traders, brokers and banks that execute sell and buy orders. This environment is based on electronic communication channels through which orders to buy and sell securities, commodity contracts and transfer funds are submitted and executed. The other segment of the marketplace, referred to below as the ‘back-end’, is where transactions concluded in the front-end are ultimately settled. The back-end involves the actual transfer of assets. Unlike the front-end, represented by transactions conducted on stock and commodities exchanges, the back-end has remained largely ignored and hidden from the sight and interest of investors as well as the public at large.1 The function of the back-end is to ensure that investors will be able to enjoy the rights they have acquired no matter how risky or safe these rights are. The back-end is not concerned with the quality or marketability of financial assets and its mechanisms equally process transfers of safe instruments such as AAA-rated government bonds and risky instruments such as junk bonds issued by low-rated corporations. The back-end is the quiet mechanism ensuring investors that they receive what they originally bargained for. Entities operating in the back-end include central securities depositories such as the Depository Trust Company (DTC), central counterparties such as the CME clearinghouse and administrators of large-value funds transfer systems (LVFTS) such as the US Federal Reserve Banks. 1 Nathalie Aubry, Regulating the Plumbing of Europe, 23(11) J.I.B.L.R. 578 (2008). Introduction 3 These entities do not operate a trading marketplace. Instead, they supply the technological framework in which transactions executed in the front-end are settled and commercial assets are delivered from sellers to buyers, debtors to creditors and vice-versa. Overall, the two segments complement each other and their co-existence may be illustrated as follows. Suppose that Brian instructed his securities intermediary Morgan Stanley to buy shares of IBM and commodity contracts for the delivery of corn. Morgan Stanley executed his order to buy the stock on the NYSE. Similarly, a commodities trading unit of Morgan Stanley executed Brian’s order on the CME to buy the corn commodity contracts. Brian received confirmation that both trades were successfully executed. Once Brian’s orders are executed on the NYSE and on the CME, the transactions proceed to the settlement phase, which entails the transferring of assets. The IBM stock and the corn commodity contracts will be transferred to Brian’s securities and commodities accounts and in exchange his accounts will be debited for the funds corresponding to the purchase price of the stock and commodity contracts. In this illustration, settlement is the exchange of funds for securities and commodity contracts. Modern settlement mechanisms for such transactions do not rely on the physical delivery of security certificates for cash or checks. Instead commercial assets whether they are securities, commodity contracts or funds are held in accounts maintained by intermediaries and transferred by electronic book entries to such accounts. Custody and maintenance of securities, bank, and commodity accounts, and the transferring of assets to and from such accounts, are all back-end functions. A number of differences exist between front-end trading and back-end transfers. From the commercial perspective, the most important difference is the distinction between the discrete notions of the contract and account relationship. While a front-end transaction is centered on a contract to buy or sell securities or commodity contracts, the ensuing back-end transfer is based on a pre-established relationship. This relationship exists in the form of an account maintained by an intermediary whose rights and duties are not necessarily derived from a specific time and transaction-circumscribed contract. For example, in the front-end, a contract is entered into between sellers and buyers, such as when Brian chooses to buy IBM stock from another investor who wants to sell. Subsequently the back-end transfer creates, or more typically modifies, the relationship between Brian and his intermediary Morgan Stanley when Morgan Stanley credits the IBM stock to Brian’s securities account. Although the focus of this book is on this relationship, transactions that 4 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts are executed in the front-end will nevertheless be explained in a summary fashion before a discussion of the back-end functions is introduced. Securities, bank and commodity accounts are special types of relationships that differ from other types of accounts, such as accounts receivable or credit card accounts. The entity obligated on these commercial accounts is an intermediary that is typically a financial institution. In contrast, an account receivable may be owed by a retailer that has just purchased a shipment of toasters from a manufacturer agreeing to pay the purchase price within 90 days. Commercial accounts also hold items of property belonging to customers that credit card accounts and receivables do not. The quality of commercial accounts is reinforced not only by creditworthy intermediaries but also through mandatory insurance, segregation of customer assets from those of the intermediaries and strict regulation. For instance, banks that are authorized to maintain deposit accounts are subject to capital reserves and securities intermediaries are subject to the requirement to segregate customer assets from their own. Credit card issuers are not required to segregate their customers’ assets from their own because they do not hold any assets, and ordinary accounts receivable are not required to be insured through mandatory schemes. The back-end systems for the holding and transfers of securities, funds and commodity contracts are all critical components of the contemporary commercial marketplace. This marketplace also includes derivatives (such as swaps), the investment activities of insurance companies, special purpose vehicles that purchase mortgage loans and issue mortgagebacked securities and the like. All these segments have their respective front and back-ends. However, this book focuses only on those segments in which the rights of participants are incorporated into commercial accounts maintained by intermediaries and that are available to individual investors. Analyses of the various types of securities, commodity contracts and monetary items, their functions, uses and risks are also outside the scope of this book. The ultimate objective of this book is to identify a set of principles that underlie securities, bank and commodity account relationships. This book attempts to explain how securities, funds and commodity contracts are transferred, who account holders and intermediaries are, what the nature of the relationship is between the two, what the connection is between these relationships, what the rights of account holders are against their intermediaries and how account holders may use their assets as collateral. Another equally important objective is to provide recommendations on reforms and modernizations of the law of commercial accounts in developing countries. Introduction 5 This book is divided into three Parts, which separately address the back-ends transfers of I) securities, II) funds and III) commodity contracts. Each of these Parts will examine: 1) 2) 3) 4) 5) 6) 7) 8) historical evolution of transactions and relationships in securities, payments and commodities markets; transformation from property rights in identifiable assets to intangible rights against intermediaries; structure of holding systems where accounts are maintained; top-level relationships between a central entity and their (clearing) participating intermediaries; lower-level relationships between intermediaries and their account holders; rights of account holders against their intermediaries; transfers of account-based rights; and security interests in account-based rights. HISTORICAL EVOLUTION Each Part includes a short history of the transaction and the particular relationship into which it evolved. While the purpose is not to provide a detailed historical report, some of the key developments in each area are highlighted. It will be demonstrated that securities, bank and commodities transactions trace their roots to the era of Hammurabi, where the first primitive securities and commodity contracts were introduced. The historical summary then proceeds with a discussion of the particular aspects of Roman law that had a significant impact on the evolution of modern account-based relationships. It will be argued that modern accounts in which intermediaries hold assets for their customers, to a certain extent, rely on the law of deposit as developed by the Romans. The sections on history then examine the medieval practices shaped by merchants, primarily during the trade fairs. Many of these business practices laid the foundation for the later development of negotiable promises to pay and to deliver, which in turn, over time, became the backbone of many modern commercial undertakings. This medieval era culminated in the establishment of the first organized exchanges for securities and commodity contracts as well as rudimentary account-based relationships. The sections will then examine the practices of English goldsmiths in the seventeenth century. By accepting deposits and issuing 6 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts receipts that represented deposited money and valuables, these goldsmiths had a considerable impact on the development of modern money and credit. Lastly, these sections will cover the last decades of the twentieth century, since it was a time that witnessed a number of transformative processes in the marketplace. Securities began to be immobilized within central securities depositories (hereinafter CSD) and dematerialized in the form of electronic entries to accounts maintained by intermediaries. Balances on bank accounts gradually replaced banknotes and checks as the primary payment mechanism in commercial transactions. Commodity exchanges introduced new futures and options contracts and clearinghouses facilitated their holdings in accounts with intermediaries. CHARACTERIZATION OF THE RIGHTS OF ACCOUNT HOLDERS: THE TRANSFORMATION FROM PROPERTY RIGHTS IN IDENTIFIABLE ASSETS TO FUNGIBLE RIGHTS AGAINST INTERMEDIARIES The history sections in the Introduction to each Part will set the stage for an analysis and characterization of the rights conferred on holders of contemporary accounts. The nature of rights held by contemporary investors has changed alongside the transformation from a transaction between a seller and a buyer to the established relationship between a seller/buyer and his intermediary. Historically, sellers dealt directly with buyers and their dealings involved direct exchanges of securities or commodities for payment. No third party facilitated these exchanges. These transactions involved both the trade and its settlement completed by transferring possession of the physical securities and cash. Nowadays, most commercial transactions involving securities and commodity contracts, and many transactions involving goods, are not concluded in the presence of the seller and the buyer. Instead, the parties order their intermediaries to buy/sell securities and commodity contracts. Intermediaries do not deliver security certificates to their customers but credit and debit their accounts. Unlike physical delivery of cash and certificates between two parties, in this case, intermediaries facilitate trading, transfers and settlement. A similar transformation occurred on the seller’s side with respect to the form of payment. Instead of receiving cash, intermediaries credit their customers’ accounts. The bilateral transaction that previously involved an exchange of security certificates for payment in cash has been replaced with a relationship under which Introduction 7 intermediaries electronically transfer funds, securities and commodity contracts. One can identify two different levels of fungibility present in the three types of account relationships. On the one hand, securities and commodity account holders retain property rights to their fungible assets while bank account holders’ rights are of a contractual nature. Funds deposited to bank accounts become ‘ultrafungible’ because the depositors lose any property rights thereto. THE PYRAMIDAL STRUCTURE OF ACCOUNTS HOLDING SYSTEMS AND THE LINKAGE Accounts relationships between intermediaries and their customers are units in a larger structure of accounts holding systems. These systems operate in a pyramid-like model, which typically consists of at least three different levels.2 At the bottom of the pyramid are investors who enter into transactions, which are reflected by credits and debits to their commodity, securities and bank accounts maintained by intermediaries. These individual account relationships between investors and intermediaries constitute the bottom level of securities, bank and commodity accounts holding systems. The upper or intermediate level is populated by intermediaries and their respective arrangements with other intermediaries and central entities. Similar to the bottom level, these arrangements are represented by accounts maintained by intermediaries for one another. Only some intermediaries have been authorized to access central entities, and therefore those that have not must establish a relationship with one of these clearing intermediaries. Finally, at the top of the pyramid are the operators of LVFTSs, CSDs and commodity clearinghouses. These central entities maintain accounts for their participating (clearing) intermediaries. Unlike the Egyptian pyramids that were built from stone and mud bricks, the commercial system pyramids are assembled from intangible account relationships. The account-based systems that involve securities, funds and commodity contracts are closely linked. This linkage is legal and, risk-based as well as technological. Furthermore markets, central entities, intermediaries and investors are connected on a global level through modern 2 Edward Gerald Corrigan, Perspectives on Payment System Risk Reduction, in THE U.S. PAYMENT SYSTEM: EFFICIENCY, RISK, AND THE ROLE OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE: PROCEEDINGS OF A SYMPOSIUM ON THE U.S. PAYMENT SYSTEM SPONSORED BY THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND 129, 130 (David B. Humphrey ed., KLUWER ACADEMIC PUBLISHERS, BOSTON, MA, 1989). 8 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts communications systems.3 With the advent of new technologies, access to various segments of the marketplace located in different parts of the world has become almost effortless. One may buy commodity contracts on a futures exchange established in Europe and use a US-based intermediary to hold those contracts in a commodity account. Of course, these connections also have the potential to expose accounts holding systems to various risks, the most critical being systemic risk, or the risk of the failure of one institution causing a domino effect of collapses to the other institutions.4 Every level of the accounts holding system is exposed to a certain degree of risk and uncertainty. While failures at the bottom level should not endanger the stability of the entire system, default of a critically important intermediary or the central entity may expose the entire system to the domino effect of failures. Central entities are typically viewed as systematically important and subject to special regulation and supervision.5 The higher in the pyramid a failure occurs, the higher the chances of systemic failure.6 Central entities and particularly clearinghouses are one of the systematically important connectors 3 Robert C. Merton & Zvi Bodie, A Conceptual Framework for Analyzing Financial Environment, in THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL SYSTEM, A FUNCTIONAL PERSPECTIVE 3 (Dwight B. Crane, Robert C. Merton, Kenneth A. Froot, Zvi Bodie, Scott P. Mason, Erik R. Sirri, André F. Perold & Peter Tufano eds., HARVARD BUSINESS SCHOOL PRESS, BOSTON, MA, 1995); DALVINDER SINGH, BANKING REGULATION OF UK AND US FINANCIAL MARKETS 24 (ASHGATE PUBLISHING LTD., HAMPSHIRE, UK, 2007) and Peter Allsopp, Bruce Summers & John Veale, The Evolution of Real-Time Gross Settlement: Access, Liquidity and Credit, and Pricing, in FINANCIAL INFRASTRUCTURE SERIES: PAYMENT SYSTEMS POLICY AND RESEARCH 10 (The World Bank, 2009). 4 Corrigan, supra note 2, at 130. The European Central Bank defined systemic risk as ‘one institution’s inability to meet its obligations that makes other institutions unable to meet their obligations, resulting in significant liquidity and credit problems that threaten the stability of, or confidence in, markets.’ Diana Chan, Florence Fontan, Simonetta Rosati & Daniela Russo, The Securities Custody Industry, European Central Bank, Occasional Paper Series No. 68, 34 (August 2007), available at http://www.ecb.int/pub/pdf/scpops/ ecbocp68.pdf (last visited 9 December 2013). 5 The DTC has been designated as a systemically important financial market utility by the US Financial Stability Oversight Council, see http://www. treasury.gov/initiatives/fsoc/Documents/2012%20Appendix%20A%20Designation %20of%20Systemically%20Important%20Market%20Utilities.pdf (last visited 9 December 2013). 6 The Committee on Payment and Settlement Systems of the Bank for International Settlements in its Consultative Report on Principles for Financial Market Infrastructures 5 (2011) found that ‘… FMIs (payment systems, central Introduction 9 for the three types of holding systems. Ben Bernanke, until January 2014 Chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, observed that clearinghouses provide one of the links that connect individual segments of the financial marketplace and, more specifically, that the clearing and settlement systems of commodity and securities markets are closely interconnected with the banking system.7 THE CLEARINGHOUSE AND RELATIONSHIPS AT THE TOP LEVEL All three accounts holding systems for securities, funds and commodity contracts are supported by a central entity that provides specialized services at the top of the pyramid. The central entity may perform various functions, including ensuring stability in the system and protecting its participants against the risk of default. However, the primary role of central entities is to provide clearing and settlement, also known as post-trade services. Clearing is less glamorous than trading but is the core function of modern commercial systems and significantly increases market efficiency.8 Both clearing and settlement processes occur after trades between individual buyers and sellers have been executed. Clearing is a process that involves administrative functions, such as matching trade data submitted by intermediaries, as well as risk management that involves, inter alia, novation of transactions.9 In contrast, settlement is the final transfer (delivery) of assets, such as securities and commodity contracts, in exchange for funds. Each of the three Parts in this book will examine in detail the clearing and settlement functions. Most securities holding systems are supported by an entity that performs clearing and settlement functions. However, unlike in the commodities accounts systems, a number of securities central entities do not become counterparties to all securities transactions. In payments securities depositories, securities settlement systems and central counterparties) also concentrate risk. If not properly managed, FMIs can also be sources of financial shocks, such as liquidity dislocations or credit losses …’. 7 Ben S. Bernanke, Clearing and Settlement during the Crash, National Bureau of Economic Research Conference: Stock Market Volatility and the Crash, Dorado Beach (16–18 March 1989) in 3(1) REV. FIN. STUD., 1990, at 139. 8 TINA P. HASENPUSCH, CLEARING SERVICES FOR GLOBAL MARKETS 1 (CAMBRIDGE UNIVERSITY PRESS, NEW YORK, NY, 2009). 9 Robert R. Bliss & Robert S. Steigerwald, Derivatives Clearing and Settlement: A Comparison of Central Counterparties and Alternative Structures, 4Q ECON. PERSP. 22 (2006). 10 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts systems, the operator does not become the central counterparty to every obligation to pay and receive payment. If Morgan Stanley is obligated to pay one million dollars to JP Morgan Chase, the Federal Reserve Bank will neither become the beneficiary of the Morgan Stanley credit transfer, nor assume an obligation to pay JP Morgan Chase. Fedwire, operated by the Federal Reserve Banks, merely credits and debits transfers to the banks’ accounts. Clearing and settlement in securities and commodities accounts systems entail processes not characteristic for clearing and settlement in the bank accounts system. Furthermore, clearing and settlement of funds in the bank accounts systems involve only the ‘cash leg’ in which one participant makes a transfer and its bank account is debited, and the other participant receives the transfer and its bank account is correspondingly credited. In contrast, clearing and settlement in securities and commodities accounts systems also modify proprietary rights to securities and rights to future delivery of commodities that are transferred in exchange for payment. These and other differences will be further examined in the respective Parts. RELATIONSHIPS AT LOWER LEVELS BETWEEN INTERMEDIARIES AND ACCOUNT HOLDERS Intermediation is at the core of the law of accounts holding systems.10 Intermediaries perform a number of critical functions, including to: 1) 2) 3) 4) 5) 6) 7) 8) establish and maintain accounts for their customers; execute customers’ orders to transfer assets and funds in and out of those accounts; perform clearing functions for certain transactions of their customers; provide credit to their customers; enable third parties to perfect security interests in assets and funds maintained in accounts; provide advisory services; facilitate enforcement of corporate rights embedded in securities; and reduce monitoring costs for customers. 10 Joseph H. Sommer, A Law of Financial Accounts: Modern Payment and Securities Transfer Law, 53(4) BUS. LAW. 1181, 1200–1 (1998). Introduction 11 While in developed economies intermediaries specialize in servicing particular areas of the marketplace with a clear distinction among securities intermediaries, commodity intermediaries and commercial banks, in many developing countries, banks are the dominant intermediaries through which investors can access all three accounts holding systems.11 The objects of accounts relationships between intermediaries and their customers are fungible assets of an intangible nature, including funds, securities and commodity contracts. Fungibility benefits issuers, obligors and holders of these assets because assets divided into standardized units are much easier to trade.12 These fungible assets are dealt and transferred by values, numbers, and other measurements, and held as such in accounts.13 One of the main objectives of this book is to explain the nature of these relationships. All three types of account relationships trace their roots to the law of irregular and regular deposits, as developed by the Romans. Under the irregular deposit, ownership rights to deposited assets were transferred from the depositor to the depository, and this deposit became the basis for modern bank account relationships. In contrast, under the regular deposit, the depositor remains the owner and the depository obtains ‘naked’ possession, without any rights to dispose of the object deposited. For centuries, securities, money and commodities were placed with intermediaries for regular deposits (custody).14 This type of deposit presently exists in the form of safe-deposit boxes provided by intermediaries. It will be argued below that modern accounts holding structures now rely instead on irregular deposits because they dispense with the appropriation of rights to specific items of property. Gradually it became a common practice for intermediaries to commingle the property of their customers. Once commingled, the depositor could no longer trace his rights to specific securities, banknotes or commodities. The inability to trace rights to specific objects transformed 11 See AUGUSTO DE LA TORRE & SERGIO L. SCHMUCKLER, EMERGING CAPITAL MARKETS AND GLOBALIZATION, THE LATIN AMERICAN EXPERIENCE 4 (STANFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS, PALO ALTO, CA, 2007). 12 Eva Micheler, The Legal Nature of Securities: Inspirations from Comparative Law, in INTERMEDIATED SECURITIES, LEGAL PROBLEMS AND PRACTICAL ISSUES 131, 145 (Louise Gullifer & Jennifer Payne eds., HART PUBLISHING LTD., OXFORD, UK, 2010). 13 DAVID COX, PROPERTY RIGHTS IN MONEY 24 (OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS, OXFORD, UK, 2008). 14 ‘Custody’ may have different meanings and is not typically a legal term of art. Edward H. Klees, How Safe Are Institutional Assets in a Custodial Bank’s Insolvency?, 68(1) BUS. LAW. 103, 105 (2012). 12 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts the ownership into a different kind of right. For funds deposited to a bank account, the ownership right became a contractual claim against the bank for repayment of the funds. The bank account has become a credit relationship. For commodities, ownership right became a co-ownership interest in the bulk belonging to multiple depositors, and eventually a contractual claim against the intermediary. Holders of securities have been granted a special right (security entitlement) in some jurisdictions that does not fit into any of the existing categories of property rights. In contrast to this special right, many civil-law jurisdictions apply co-ownership property concepts to the rights of securities accounts holders. RIGHTS AND PROTECTIONS OF ACCOUNT HOLDERS Account holders must be provided an assurance of safety and protections against losses that may be sustained by the improper conduct of an intermediary. Otherwise, account holders may be reluctant to hold their assets through intermediaries. As a result, appropriate protective mechanisms must be built into accounts holding systems. The demand for such protective measures has been recently increased as a result of failures by major intermediaries, including Lehman Brothers, Washington Mutual, MF Global and the largest Colombia broker, Interbolsa S.A. The accounts holding systems studied in this book provide a variety of such protective measures, including regulation and capital reserve requirements that in combination create a safety net for the rights of account holders.15 The safety net is composed of different components in each of the three accounts holding systems. The primary safeguard for customers of commodity and securities intermediaries is the requirement to segregate the customer property from that of the intermediary. In other words, the intermediary may not maintain its own securities and commodity contracts in the same account with the securities and commodity contracts of its customers. Customers also regularly deposit funds with their securities and commodity intermediaries for trading purposes. Similarly, such funds must be segregated from the funds belonging to intermediaries. In contrast, bank customers do not have the right to demand that the bank segregate their funds from its own funds because upon deposit the bank becomes the owner of such 15 Jerry W. Markham, The CFTC Net Capital Rule – Should a More Risk-Based Approach be Adopted?, 71 CHI.-KENT L. REV. 1091, 1098 (1996). Introduction 13 funds.16 Upon deposit, there is no longer a distinction between ‘their’ and ‘the bank’s’ own funds. As a consequence of segregation, commodity and securities intermediaries are obliged to maintain the same quantity of securities and commodity contracts that are credited to the accounts of their customers. On the other hand, banks are required to maintain only fractional reserves against the deposits of their clients, which allows them to use deposit funds for loans and similar activities. Insurance of claims is the primary safeguard for bank account holders, yet it is only a secondary safeguard for the holders of securities accounts. In the case that insurance coverage is insufficient, bank account holders have a claim against the general assets of the intermediary. In other words bank depositors’ uninsured claims will be satisfied from the general assets of the bank within the class of unsecured claims. The rights of securities account holders are protected first by segregation and second, in the case of shortfalls, by insurance. If insurance does not cover all losses, the accounts holders then have a claim to pro-rata distribution of the intermediary’s own unencumbered assets of the relevant issue.17 Their claims are secured to the extent that the intermediary maintains securities. As for the rights of commodity account holders, their primary safeguard is the segregation of assets. In the past, legislative proposals to institute mandatory insurance protecting customers of commodity intermediaries have been repeatedly rejected in the United States. However, such proposals have been recently revived in the aftermath of a number of failures by commodity intermediaries such as MF Global. Additionally, absent of any insurance coverage, when the claims of commodity account holders have not been satisfied in full, holders may assert their claims pro-rata with other unsecured creditors against the commodity intermediary. Accordingly, rights of securities accounts holders are protected by segregation, secured claims against the intermediary’s assets and insurance. Rights of commodity accounts holders are also protected by segregation and unsecured claims against the intermediary’s assets, but remain uninsured. Finally, rights of deposit accounts holders are protected by insurance and unsecured claims against the insolvent bank’s general estate but their claims do not relate to any segregated assets. 16 Harry Boul, Money in the Bank Is Not Money, and It’s Not in the Bank, XXXI(3) AM. INSOL. INST. J. 22, 23 (2012). 17 Joseph H. Sommer, International Securities Holding and Transfer Law, 18 ARIZ. J. INT’L & COMP. L. 685, 695 (2001). 14 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts TRANSFERS OF ACCOUNT-BASED RIGHTS Since settlement of contemporary commercial and financial transactions does not rely on the physical delivery of money, security certificates and actual commodities, the law must recognize an alternative transfer mechanism that ensures that the transferee effectively acquires the bargained-for rights, and that those rights are immune from the claims of third parties. It will be demonstrated that the common transfer mechanism for all three types of accounts systems is book entries. Rights to securities, funds and commodity contracts are effectively acquired and transferred by book entries made by intermediaries to the accounts of their customers. However, since book entries are merely accounting functions, the law must provide for the consequences of such entries. Credits and debits mechanically transfer securities, funds and commodity contracts as well as modify relationships of customers with their intermediaries. From the mechanical perspective, credits and debits do not transfer identifiable assets such as specific banknotes or security certificates. Instead, ‘the title to the value’ is transferred, rather than a title to an identifiable asset or to the money itself.18 These transfers modify the relationship between the customer and his intermediary. From the customer’s perspective, the value of such relationships may increase or decrease over time as transfers are credited or debited to the account.19 Alan Greenspan, the former Chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, explained that when a funds transfer is completed, the monetary claim of the transferor against the bank is reduced and almost simultaneously the monetary claim of the beneficiary against its bank is increased.20 From a legal perspective a book entry causes rights or value to be transferred by novation. Book entries to accounts do not rely on the traditional concepts of assignment and negotiation because of the phases in which book-entry transfers are effectuated. These phases are: 1) the extinguishment (modification) of the original obligation and 2) establishment of a new obligation (or modification of the already existing one).21 COX, supra note 13, at 165. Book entry transfers reflect changes in liability to the account holder. PHILIP R. WOOD, SET-OFF AND NETTING, DERIVATIVES, CLEARING SYSTEMS 323 (2nd edn., SWEET & MAXWELL LTD., LONDON, UK, 2007). 20 Ibid., at 270 and Alan Greenspan, Remarks on Evolving Payment System Issues, 28(4), Part 2, JOURNAL OF MONEY, CREDIT AND BANKING 689, 691 (1996). 21 J. B. Ames, Novation, 6(4) HARV. L. REV. 184, 185 (1892). 18 19 Introduction 15 The negotiability doctrine is inapplicable to transfers in modern accounts holding systems because of the absence of writings. Yet the goal of negotiability, which is to free the asset of conflicting claims and liability, remains important for intermediated account-based systems.22 Professor Rogers, the Reporter for the 1994 revision of the Uniform Commercial Code (UCC) Article 8, noted that negotiability rests on the assumption that abstract rights are embodied in writings that are physically held or delivered to the claimant of these rights.23 In contemporary systems rights are no longer transferred by delivery of writings. Professor Rogers added that ‘one must constantly bear in mind that what matters is not the instruments themselves, but the abstract rights represented by the instruments, and that the objective is to design an effective system of title recognition for the abstract rights’.24 Abstract rights have been divorced from writings and have become embedded in securities, bank and commodity accounts, which provide an effective system of title recognition. In addition to the recognition of novation, laws and rules that govern securities, bank and commodity accounts systems must clearly identify the moment at which the transfer order, as well as the actual book entry, becomes final and irreversible.25 Finality of transfer is one of the most important features in all three accounts systems. The high velocity of transfers and the millions of transactions that are processed on a daily basis require clear and predictable rules of finality. Each Part of this book will examine the finality rules present in the particular accounts holding system. 22 Charles W. Mooney, Jr. & Hideki Kanda, Core Issues under the UNIDROIT (Geneva) Convention on Intermediated Securities: Views from the United States and Japan, in INTERMEDIATED SECURITIES, LEGAL PROBLEMS AND PRACTICAL ISSUES 69, 95 (Louise Gullifer & Jennifer Payne eds., HART PUBLISHING LTD., OXFORD, UK, 2010). 23 James S. Rogers, Negotiability, Property, and Identity, 12 CARDOZO L. REV. 471, 480 (1990). 24 James S. Rogers, Negotiability as a System of Title Recognition, 48 OHIO ST. L.J. 197, 224 (1987). 25 Robert R. Bliss & Chryssa Papathanassiou, Derivatives Clearing, Central Counterparties and Novation: The Economic Implications, 20 (8 March 2006), available at http://www.ecb.int/events/pdf/conferences/ccp/BlissPapathanassiou_ final.pdf (last visited 9 December 2013). 16 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts THE USE OF ACCOUNT-BASED RIGHTS AS COLLATERAL Account holders may not only sell their rights but they may also use them as collateral to secure obligations. Account-based rights are very valuable collateral for three particular reasons. First, the value of securities, funds and commodity contracts is easily determinable because there is a public market for all of them. Second, account-based rights are highly liquid. In other words, securities and commodity contracts may easily be disposed of, practically immediately upon default of the borrower. Finally, perfection of security interests in account-based rights may be achieved without having to satisfy onerous formalities typical for most secured transactions in some jurisdictions. Despite the attractive collateral value of rights held in securities, bank and commodity accounts, only a few jurisdictions (e.g., Canada and the United States) provide for comprehensive special rules on taking security interests in such rights and accounts. Security interests typically become effective against third parties once the creditor has taken some action to make them public. This is typically achieved by filing or registration. Publicity of security interests in account-based rights is achieved through the presence of an independent third party – i.e., the intermediary – that functions as the bookkeeper for all transactions with the account-based rights, whether outright transfers or collateral arrangements. Perfection of security interests in accountbased rights should depend on the ability of the secured creditor to control the collateral also allowing the debtor to retain disposal rights.26 Nevertheless, in some economies filing (registration) continues to play an important role and is viewed as the only mechanism that provides sufficient transparency for collateral arrangements. Each Part of this book will analyse and compare the requirements for perfecting security interests in account-based rights. 26 See Luc Thévenoz, Intermediated Securities, Legal Risk, and the International Harmonization of Commercial Law, 13 STAN. J.L. BUS. & FIN. 384, 443 (2008), for a similar recommendation with respect to security interests in securities and bank accounts. Introduction 17 LEGAL REGULATION – IDENTIFICATION OF BEST PRINCIPLES The ultimate objective of this book is to identify the key principles and features that underlie contemporary accounts holding systems. A number of efforts to bring about some level of harmonization on an international level have already failed. Drafters of future legislation should realize that the new world of securities, bank and commodity accounts is based upon mechanical communications, intangible rights and relationships.27 The core of the emerging law of commercial accounts addresses the relationships between customers and their intermediaries rather than the property rights to identifiable assets.28 Rapid development of commercial markets outpaces not only legal regulation but also the implementation of tools for mitigation and more effective management of risks.29 In a number of jurisdictions laws still focus on and regulate transactions with identifiable assets and property rights while transactions in contemporary markets involve intangible and fungible assets and account-based relationships.30 Legislators must take responsibility for adopting efficient rules on enforcing rights, protecting investors and adequately regulating participants in these systems.31 Legislation and regulation of account-based rights must be comprehensive and take into account the linkages among the three accounts holding systems. The call for effective legislation governing these systems has been made by the most prominent figures in contemporary finance. Bernanke, until January 2014 Chairman of the Board of Governors of the Sommer, supra note 10, at 1183. Ibid. at 1184. 29 Donald L. Kohn, The Evolving Nature of the Financial System: Financial Crises and the Role of the Central Bank, Speech at the Conference on New Directions for Understanding Systemic Risk, New York (18 May 2006). 30 ERICA JOHANSSON, PROPERTY RIGHTS IN INVESTMENT SECURITIES AND THE DOCTRINE OF SPECIFICITY 1 (SPRINGER-VERLAG BERLIN HEIDELBERG, BERLIN, GERMANY, 2009). 31 Governments should also be mindful and supportive of self-imposed industry regulations. However, self-regulation standing on its own will not work without a government-sponsored and effective oversight framework. See Andrea M. Corcoran, Ronald B. Hobson, Gregory J. Kuserk, Karen K. Wuertz & Derek West, Designing a Derivatives Complement to Cash Markets in Developing Countries, in INTER-AMERICAN DEVELOPMENT BANK, FOCUS ON CAPITAL, NEW APPROACHES TO DEVELOPING LATIN AMERICAN CAPITAL MARKETS 373 (INTERAMERICAN DEVELOPMENT BANK, WASHINGTON, DC, 2003). 27 28 18 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts Federal Reserve System, referred to such legislation as the ‘software’ of the financial system, and said that: I want to construe ‘financial infrastructure’ very broadly, to include not only the ‘hardware’ components of that infrastructure – the physical systems on which market participants rely for the quick and accurate execution, clearing, and settlement of transactions – but also the associated ‘software,’ including the statutory, regulatory, and contractual frameworks and the business practices that govern the actions and obligations of market participants on both sides of each transaction.32 Bernanke’s ‘software’ (legal infrastructure) and ‘hardware’ (organizational infrastructure) will be referenced throughout this book. The Conclusion of this book identifies a set of principles underlying contemporary account-based relationships. 32 Ben S. Bernanke, Reducing Systemic Risk, Speech at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City’s Annual Economic Symposium, Jackson Hole, Wyoming (22 August 2008), available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/ bernanke20080822a.htm (last visited 9 December 2013). PART I Securities Account Relationships 1. Introduction to Part I Securities markets provide venues for companies to raise capital by issuing shares and bonds and for interested parties to invest. Over the last few decades, securities markets have transformed into electronic impersonal venues that are more accessible to the public at large.1 Many of these changes are ‘visible’ to a lay person. Every individual with access to the Internet may easily locate quotes from securities markets, monitor prices of shares, download reports from analysts or watch footage from the NYSE and other exchanges. Anyone can also observe what securities markets ‘are doing’ at any particular moment. Today passive observation through electronic technology has become effortless and practically cost-free. Securities markets also underwent other critical changes that may be less visible to a lay person. For years, the NYSE, the London Stock Exchange and the Deutsche Börse were traditionally associated in the minds of many with trading floors, populated by brokers wearing uniform-like jackets shouting, running, waving their hands and throwing paper tickets around. Gradually floor trading has been replaced with electronic technologies and now instead of raising their hands, accepting orders and making notes on paper tickets, brokers sit in their offices and execute orders electronically. Investors no longer fax or call their orders to buy or sell securities and brokers no longer call a trader on the floor to execute such orders. Presently investors log-in to their trading accounts such as through the websites of intermediaries and place their orders electronically. The issuance of orders and their execution is practically seamless. Electronic communication technologies have also impacted the actual settlement of trades, or the processes that occur after the trade is executed, even though the transformation of settlement processes is less 1 Marek Dubovec, Securities Holding Patterns and Their Impact on the Rights of Securities Holders: Lessons for Developing Nations, in LATIN AMERICAN COMPANY LAW: A COMPARATIVE AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT PERSPECTIVE, VOL. 1, 213, 214 (Boris Kozolchyk & Francisco Reyes eds., CAROLINA ACADEMIC PRESS, DURHAM, NC, 2013). 21 22 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts visible to the lay person. Investors in Mexico City need no longer worry how their recently purchased IBM certificates will be delivered to them. They no longer should be concerned with what might happen if the certificates are lost or stolen in transit. Electronic communications make the transfer of IBM shares possible by electronic bookkeeping entries to securities accounts maintained by intermediaries. Securities are no longer mailed in envelopes or handed over in face-to-face meetings. In terms of modernization and implementation of new technologies, the back-end transfer functions have been keeping pace with the front-end trading functions in that both have become almost exclusively electronic. That being said, electronic trading with securities is a front-end function and therefore is not the subject of this Part. This Part of the book examines the transformation from settlement of trades by physical deliveries of certificates to the electronic transfers effectuated by book entries to securities accounts. It analyzes both the ‘hardware’ (organizational and structural infrastructure) and the ‘software’ (legal infrastructure) of contemporary securities transfer systems. The discussion of the software component includes an analysis of legal rules applicable to the relationships that form the securities holding systems. The most advanced software components, as they have been formulated to implement the US Article 8 of UCC, are compared with those in the European Union (EU) and Latin America. It will be demonstrated that the EU Member States’ frameworks have not been harmonized similarly to the United States’ laws. The relevant EU Directives ‘fell short of creating a wholly consistent and sound set of legal provisions governing the acquisition, disposition, enforcement, and priority of rights in intermediated securities’.2 Latin American laws differ from UCC 8 and the EU legal frameworks in many aspects, including the degree of formalities required for the perfection of security interests. It will be argued that socio-economic context is an important factor that determines both the legal infrastructure and the functioning of securities holding systems in the specified jurisdiction. Recommendations to implement one or another type of the securities holding systems should not be formulated without understanding the functions of securities markets in those jurisdictions. This is especially true in those Luc Thévenoz, Intermediated Securities, Legal Risk, and The International Harmonization of Commercial Law, 13 STAN. J.L. BUS. & FIN. 384, 398 (2008). See further CHANGMIN CHUN, CROSS-BORDER TRANSACTIONS OF INTERMEDIATED SECURITIES, A COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS IN SUBSTANTIVE LAW AND PRIVATE INTERNATIONAL LAW 118 (SPRINGER-VERLAG BERLIN HEIDELBERG, NEW YORK, NY, 2012). 2 Introduction to Part I 23 economies and cultures where companies may or may not be accustomed to raising funds in capital markets, where investors may or may not trust the market value of securities, and where intermediaries are generally distrusted. This book seeks to lay out a path to modernization of the legal infrastructure that governs domestic systems for the holding of securities. Such modernization is a necessary step towards achieving harmonization across borders. The international lawmaking community has already undertaken important projects in the area of holding securities to support increasingly globalized markets.3 First, the International Institute for the Unification of Private Law (UNIDROIT) drafted the UNIDROIT Convention on Substantive Rules for Intermediated Securities (the Geneva Securities Convention) that was signed on 9 October 2009.4 As stated in the overview of the project, the objective of this Convention was to ‘improve the legal framework for securities holding and transfers, with a special emphasis on cross-border situations’.5 This special emphasis was identified because the number of failed deliveries of securities was and remains significantly higher in cross-border transactions as compared to domestic transactions.6 Second, the predecessor to the Geneva Securities Convention was a project undertaken by the Hague Conference on Private International Law that resulted in the adoption of the Convention on the Law Applicable to Certain Rights in Respect of Securities Held with an Intermediary (Hague Securities Convention).7 The Hague Securities Convention determines the applicable law for rights and obligations 3 Wayne Gray & Robert M. Scavone, Retreat from a Federal Securities Transfer Presence: Next Stage in the Development of the Canadian Securities Settlement System, 27 B.L.F.R. 375, 379 (2012). 4 The full text of the Geneva Securities Convention and working documents are available at http://www.unidroit.org/english/conventions/2009intermediated securities/main.htm (last visited 9 December 2013). 5 Given the functional and minimalistic approach taken in the drafting of the Geneva Securities Convention, some authors have criticized it for not providing sufficient predictability and legal certainty. CHUN, supra note 2, at 34. 6 Explanatory Memorandum to the proposed Regulation on Improving Securities Settlement in the EU and on Central Securities Depositories (CSDs), at 2 COM(2012) 73 final (7 March 2012), available at http://eur-lex.europa.eu/ LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=CELEX:52012PC0073:EN:PDF (last visited 9 December 2013). 7 The full text of the Hague Securities Convention is available at http:// hcch.e-vision.nl/index_en.php?act=conventions.text&cid=72 (last visited 9 December 2013). See also Sandra M. Rocks, The Hague Convention on the Law 24 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts in relationships based on securities accounts and does not deal with substantive issues related to the holding of securities in accounts with intermediaries. Both of these Conventions reflect the prevailing practice of holding securities in accounts maintained by intermediaries.8 The conventional relationship in which the investor holds a certificate and/or was registered on the books of the issuer has been replaced by an intermediated holding structure in which the rights of shareholders are represented by balances on securities accounts. This new pattern of securities holding also impacts the cost of operating in the stock market. Rudimentary clearing and settlement structures for intermediated securities increase the cost in many countries, including those in the Caribbean and Latin America.9 In many developing countries, the number of companies listed on the local securities exchanges has dwindled.10 To stop the outflow of public listings, the Inter-American Development Bank (IADB) recommended the following changes for developing countries: to establish systems to facilitate the comparison of trade details, clearance and settlement of securities by delivery versus payment (DVP); to implement risk control systems to reduce the operational risk; to create independent central depository systems for the safekeeping, immobilization and dematerialization of securities; and to facilitate the settlement process and other aspects of custody.11 This is a challenge that currently faces many developing countries not only in Latin America but also in Eastern Europe, Africa and Asia. Without a modern infrastructure for the holding and transferring of Applicable to certain Rights in Respect of Securities Held with an Intermediary, 36 U.C.C.L.J. 1 (2003). 8 The two Conventions neither duplicate nor compete against each other. Christophe Bernasconi & Thomas Keijser, The Hague and Geneva Securities Conventions: a Modern and Global Legal Regime for Intermediated Securities, 13(3) UNIF. L. REV. 549, 550 (2012). 9 Kenroy Dowers, Felipe Gomez-Acebo & Pietro Masci, Developing a Strategy for Reforming Capital Markets in Latin America and the Caribbean, in INTER-AMERICAN DEVELOPMENT BANK, FOCUS ON CAPITAL, NEW APPROACHES TO DEVELOPING LATIN AMERICAN CAPITAL MARKETS 8 (INTER-AMERICAN DEVELOPMENT BANK, WASHINGTON, DC, 2003). 10 See AUGUSTO DE LA TORRE & SERGIO L. SCHMUCKLER, EMERGING CAPITAL MARKETS AND GLOBALIZATION, THE LATIN AMERICAN EXPERIENCE 58 (STANFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS, PALO ALTO, CA, 2007). 11 The IADB found that 19% and 27% (respectively) of companies delisted their shares from the stock exchanges in Brazil and Argentina in 2002. Dowers, Gomez-Acebo & Masci, supra note 9, at 12, 23. Introduction to Part I 25 securities and interests therein, the liquidity of these domestic securities markets will be negatively affected. Less liquid markets are characterized by the issuance of very few securities, the presence of very few buyers and very low trading volumes. As a result, businesses are not able to raise capital and economic development in these countries languishes. Establishment of securities holding systems and enactment of the relevant legislation must also address the increasing danger of systemic risk. The 1994 revision of UCC 8 was prompted by considerations to address systemic risk.12 In this context, Professor Rogers noted that while ‘commercial law cannot protect against the failure of one’s own intermediary; it can help protect against the risk that an investor will suffer as a result of the failure of someone else’s intermediary’.13 While investors may manage intermediary risk by due diligence or by taking out insurance against losses, systemic risk is unpredictable and unmanageable by individual investors. Laws already adopted in a number of economies recognize that adequate management and reduction of systemic risk is critical for the efficient functioning of securities markets and their supporting accounts holding systems.14 This Part seeks to highlight the new concepts of holding securities in accounts with intermediaries and explain the processes and functions involved in the intermediated holding systems. The desire to manage systemic and other risks underlies all these reforms and is relatively well understood. What is missing is the understanding of these related concepts, such as the nature of rights to account-based securities and rights against the intermediary and the form of transfers and their legal nature in addition to other functions that underpin a modern intermediated holding structure. PROTOTYPICAL TRANSACTION Before introducing a concise history of securities, one needs to first understand the context in which transactions with securities are executed, the markets where securities are traded and the parties that are involved. Suppose that Brian bought 100 shares of IBM from Steve. The agreement James S. Rogers, The Revision of Canadian Law on Securities Holding Through Intermediaries: Who, What, When, Where, How and Why, CA. BUS. L. J. 49, 65 (2007). 13 Ibid. 14 See L. 964, julio 8, 2005, Diario Oficial [D.O.] 45.963 (Colom) art. 1(a)(3). 12 26 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts between Brian and Steve to sell the stock was a front-end trade between two parties. Once Brian and Steve agreed on all of the details of the trade they then met in Brian’s office where they exchanged the stock certificates for banknotes. Delivery of the certificates against the banknotes is the back-end function. This transaction involved a trade, that is, an agreement to buy the stock for a certain price, and its settlement, that is, the delivery of certificates in exchange for the banknotes. Only the seller and the buyer themselves are involved. Presently, this type of transaction would be concluded through intermediaries on a stock exchange such as the NYSE. If Brian wanted to buy 100 shares of IBM, he would not call potential sellers trying to find out who is willing to sell for the price Brian is willing to pay. Instead Brian would instruct his intermediary (e.g., Charles Schwab) to buy the stock for him. Brian would issue a ‘buy order’ to Charles Schwab to be executed on the NYSE, where IBM shares are traded. For the purposes of this illustration, assume that Steve instructed his intermediary JP Morgan Chase to sell 100 shares of IBM for the market price. Unlike in the first scenario, the transaction now involves four parties: the buyer, the seller and the two intermediaries. Once the trade is completed, Brian and Steve will exchange money for securities. However they will not meet each other to exchange the certificates for cash. Instead Charles Schwab will credit Brian’s securities account with 100 IBM shares and JP Morgan Chase will debit Steve’s securities account for the 100 IBM shares. Since this transaction was not gratuitous, payment must also be made. Accordingly, Charles Schwab will debit Brian’s cash balance on the securities account for the purchase price of the stock and JP Morgan Chase will credit Steve’s cash balance on his securities account with the sale price of the stock. Credits and debits to the securities accounts of Brian and Steve are the back-end functions. As discussed below in detail, these entries to Brian’s and Steve’s accounts do not affect the relationships at the top level between IBM and the CSD or those between the CSD and its participating intermediaries. The back-end functions may thus involve delivery of tangible assets, such as certificates against banknotes, or transfers of intangible assets made by credits and debits to securities accounts. Contemporary securities markets rely on the latter transfer mechanism – credits and debits to securities accounts maintained by intermediaries for their customers. This illustration of the prototypical transaction and the parties involved is characteristic for most jurisdictions. However, laws governing transactions with securities, their clearing, settlement, holding and transfers differ widely. It would be impossible to cover every type of market and their related legal frameworks in this book. Instead the following Introduction to Part I 27 jurisdictions will be referred to throughout this Part and compared with one another when appropriate. The securities holding system of the United States and its legal infrastructure will be used as the main reference point in this Part because it is one of the most advanced systems in terms of transactional volumes and legal infrastructure. The largest securities exchange of the United States is the NYSE, which trades shares of approximately 8000 issuers from 55 countries, representing almost 40 percent of global trading in shares.15 In 2011, the DTC, which is the US-based CSD, had US$ 39.5 trillion worth of securities on deposit.16 German securities exchanges are also an important player in credit markets. Deutsche Börse Group Frankfurt Stock Exchange is the largest securities exchange in Germany and the third largest in the world with close to 7000 listed companies from over 80 countries.17 Clearstream Banking Frankfurt is the CSD for securities issued in Germany18 and in 2011 it had €5.8 trillion worth of international and €5.2 trillion worth of domestic securities on deposit.19 The technological and legal infrastructure of the US and German securities holding systems will be contrasted with those in developing countries, including Brazil, Mexico, Costa Rica, El Salvador and Slovakia.20 These developing countries typically only host a single nation-wide securities exchange, such as the Bratislava Stock Exchange in Slovakia or the Bolsa de Valores in El Salvador. Yet within this category of developing countries two groups must be distinguished: 1) economies in 15 See NYSE Euronext, Company Overview, available at http://www.nyx. com//en/who-we-are/company-overview (last visited 9 December 2013). 16 See DTCC, Transaction Statistics and Performance, available at http:// www . weforum.org / industry-partners / depository-trust - clearing-corporation-dtcc (last visited 10 December 2013). 17 See Deutsche Börse Group, Statistics, available at http://xetra.com/xetra/ dispatch/en/kir/navigation/xetra/200_listing/500_statistics (last visited 9 December 2013). 18 See Clearstream, CSD Services, available at http://www.clearstream.com/ ci/dispatch/en/kir/ci_nav/1_settlement/025_csd (last visited 9 December 2013). 19 In 2011, Clearstream Banking Frankfurt settled over 116 million transactions. See Deutsche Börse Group, Global Presence, 115–16 (Annual Report 2011), available at http://deutsche-boerse.com/dbg/dispatch/en/binary/gdb_ content _ pool/ imported_files /public_files /10_downloads /12_ db_annual_ reports / 2011/10_complete_version/Annual_Report_2011.pdf (last visited 9 December 2013). 20 DE LA TORRE & SCHMUCKLER, supra note 10, at 45. 28 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts which securities markets are relatively efficient and growing in significance and 2) economies in which securities markets are in disarray and practically ignored by issuers and investors alike. As a result, the needs of these two groups in terms of establishing a modern securities holding system differ. Slovakia, Brazil and Mexico belong to the first group of developing countries. The Slovakian CSD, Centrálny Depozitár Cenných Papierov SR (CSD Slovakia), settled approximately 120 000 transactions in 2011 worth over €40 billion.21 In Mexico, the Bolsa Mexicana de Valores (BMV) listed shares of 135 companies as of August 2012.22 The Mexican CSD, Indeval, had over 15 billion pesos worth of securities on deposit in 2011 and on a daily basis settled transactions worth in excess of US$ 270 million.23 In 2008, the Sao Paulo Stock Exchange Bovespa merged with the Brazilian Mercantile and Futures Exchange (BM&F) to create BM&F Bovespa.24 For 2011, the daily trading volume averaged 6.5 billion real out of which 2.3 billion real was traded by foreign investors.25 As of July 2011, 467 companies listed their shares at BM&F Bovespa.26 Bovespa’s CSD, the Brazilian Clearing and Depository Corporation ‘CBLC,’ had 1.1 trillion real of securities on deposit as of June 2011.27 As highlighted in a working paper published by the International Monetary Fund’s (IMF) research staff assessing Central America: ‘… Centrálny Depozitár Cenných Papierov SR, Annual Statistics (2011), available at http://www.cdcp.sk/dokumenty/statistika/Statistics_2011_en.pdf (last visited 9 December 2013). 22 See Grupo BMV, Listado de Empresas Emisoras, available at http:// www.bmv.com.mx/wb3/wb/BMV/BMV_empresa_emisoras/_rid/177/_mto/3/_url/ BMVAPP/emisorasList.jsf?st=1 (last visited 9 December 2013). 23 Indeval, 1 Trimestre (February 2012), available at http://www.indeval. com.mx /wb3/wb /indeval /archivos_publicos /_vtp/indeval /1c85_boletin /_rid/81/_ mto /3 /Newsletter_Feb12.pdf?repfop=view&reptp=1c85_boletin&repfiddoc = 463 &repinline=true (last visited 9 December 2013). 24 See BM&F Bovespa, What the Exchange Does, available at http://www. bmfbovespa.com.br/en-us/intros/intro-about-us.aspx?idioma=en-us (last visited 9 December 2013). 25 BM&F Bovespa, 2011 Annual Report, 62–4, available at http://www. bmfbovespa.com.br/en-us/bmfbovespa/download/BMFVOVESPA-Relatorio-Anual2011.pdf (last visited 9 December 2013). 26 Patrı́cia Pellini, Latin American Roundtable, Stock Exchanges as an Engine for Corporate Governance Improvements: Reaching out to Non-listed Companies (30 November 2011), available at http://www.oecd.org/daf/ca/ corporate governanceprinciples/49287485.pdf (last visited 9 December 2013). 27 See CBLC in Numbers, available at http://www.bmfbovespa.com.br/en-us/ intros/intro-securities.aspx?idioma=en-us (last visited 9 December 2013). 21 Introduction to Part I 29 private capital markets in several countries are under-developed in terms of size, liquidity, and a number of issues relative to some regional peers …’.28 In Central America bank loans are the preferred source of financing, with corporate debt second and equity financing a distant third.29 In May 2008 the securities markets of Costa Rica, El Salvador and Panama together traded shares of only seven companies with the total value of trades equaling US$ 650 000.30 The shares of the 90 companies listed on stock exchanges in these three countries were highly illiquid.31 The IMF found that secondary trading was practically nonexistent with only 1 to 3 percent of issued shares trading annually.32 From January to the end of August 2012, the Costa Rican CSD, Central de Valores (CEVAL), settled transactions worth approximately US$ 180 million.33 The Salvadoran CSD, Central de Depósito de Valores (CEDEVAL), had just over US$ 5 billion of securities in its custody as of January 2012.34 This predominantly statistical overview of the selected securities markets and related holding systems is relevant for an understanding of the account-based framework that exists in these economies.35 BRIEF EVOLUTION OF SECURITIES This section examines the evolution of securities dating back to medieval times when raising capital by issuing securities first became popular. The other two Parts of this book examine the history of money and commodities from the era in which the origins of holding those assets through intermediaries can be traced. Securities entered the scene when medieval 28 Hermant Shah, Ana Carvajal, Geoffrey Bannister, Jorge Chan-Lau & Ivan Guerra, Equity and Private Debt Markets in Central America, Panama and the Dominican Republic, IMF Working Paper WP/07/288, 5 (2007). 29 Ibid., at 8. 30 Peter Krupa, To Build an Equity Market, CENTRAL AMERICA, Issue 8, 16 (June/July 2008). 31 Dubovec, supra note 1, at 217. 32 Shah, Carvajal, Bannister, Chan-Lau & Guerra, supra note 28, 35. 33 Bolsa Nacional de Valores, Actividad de Mercado, available at http:// www.bolsacr.com/principal/index.php?action=estadisticas-negociacion (last visited 9 December 2013). 34 CEDEVAL en Estadı́sticas, available at https://www.cedeval.com/ estadistica_custodia_local_internacional.php (last visited 9 December 2013). 35 For further information about the Latin American securities markets see Dubovec, supra note 1, at 216–17. 30 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts governments were looking for sources to finance their military activities.36 Unlike contemporary bonds, the ability of the issuing government or city to service the debt and honor redemption requests in a timely fashion depended primarily on the success of the wars.37 Even though bonds were issued as unsecured promises to pay, the war loot functioned as a quasi security. The marketability of governmental bonds was initially restricted. Bonds were bought by a small number of wealthy individuals who could bequeath or sell them but usually only within the same group of investors. A public market for securities did not exist at this time and no special intermediaries were employed to take custody of the certificates. Concentration of government bonds in the hands of a chosen few persisted until the sixteenth century. The profile of a typical bondholder changed in the sixteenth century when guilds, ecclesiastical and charitable institutions emerged as the dominant investors.38 Limited circulation and the holding of bonds by a small number of investors were well suited for the then existing transfers mechanism – book entries made by their issuers. Accordingly, when investors decided to sell their bonds they informed the issuer who then recorded the transfer on its books. Transfers of Venetian government bonds completed by book entries laid the foundation for modern securities transfers systems that rely entirely on mechanical credits and debits to securities accounts.39 The strength and reliability of the promise to pay that backed up these bonds led to their transformation into payment instruments. Thus, in addition to being instruments of finance, bonds came to be recognized as the equivalent of cash.40 Fixed-rate bonds and shares issued by jointstock companies in England and the Netherlands were recognized as 36 Some authors trace the first issuance of a security to twelfth century Venice, in which long-term municipal debt was issued: MICHAEL BLAIR QC & GEORGE WALKER, FINANCIAL MARKETS AND EXCHANGES LAW 7 (OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS, OXFORD, UK, 2007). 37 EDWARD J. SWAN, BUILDING THE GLOBAL MARKET, A 4000 YEAR HISTORY OF DERIVATIVES 117 (KLUWER LAW INTERNATIONAL, HAGUE, NETHERLANDS, 2000). The nominal interest rate on bonds issued by Italian states between the thirteenth and fifteenth centuries ranged between 2.8% in Genoa, 5% in Venice, and 12% in Florence: WILLIAM N. GOETZMANN & K. GEERT ROUWENHORST, THE ORIGINS OF VALUE: THE FINANCIAL INNOVATIONS THAT CREATED MODERN CAPITAL MARKETS 156 (OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS, OXFORD, UK, 2005). 38 Ibid., at 158. 39 SIDNEY HOMER & RICHARD SYLLA, A HISTORY OF INTEREST RATES 94 (4th edn., WILEY, HOBOKEN, NJ, 2005). 40 SWAN, supra note 37, at 117. Introduction to Part I 31 negotiable by the end of the seventeenth century, and price quotations for such bonds were made available at the Amsterdam and London Stock Exchanges.41 The establishment of securities markets with readily available prices for negotiable shares and bonds, significantly widened access to credit for companies that used to rely on funding provided by the owners and family members.42 Negotiability and the establishment of public securities exchanges attracted investors, who previously had not been able to buy bonds for investment or speculative purposes. The fact that bonds were negotiable bearer instruments equivalent to cash exposed their holders to significant risks, including loss and theft.43 The money-like features, presumed ownership, and full negotiability of these bearer securities that could ultimately be transferred free of defenses eventually led their holders to deposit these securities for safekeeping and custody with specialized intermediaries. The figure of a commercial intermediary thus emerged as a reaction to the gradual development of securities markets. Initially, the function of the intermediaries was to provide safe custody service, similar to the services of warehouse operators. The intermediary was an entity distinct from the issuer of the security, and its main function was to take the security into custody and protect it against the risks of loss and theft. Securities transactions thus experienced an important transformation that introduced a crucial player to the existing relationships between the issuer, investor and transferees – an intermediary. The initial role of the intermediary was to keep the security safe and only later did the intermediary also begin to perform other functions, such as the transfer of rights to securities and provision of loans. Although, the seventeenth century intermediary was a mere safe-keeper, its emergence had a significant impact on the evolution of the securities holding system. The deposit of securities with an intermediary established a relationship with the holder. This type of relationship was based on a contract of deposit, in which the depositor retained ownership rights and the intermediary became the possessor of the security. The intermediary had a duty to segregate the deposited securities and maintain them as THOMAS MUNCK, SEVENTEENTH CENTURY EUROPE 113 (ST. MARTIN’S PRESS, BASINGSTOKE, UK, 1990). 42 Ibid. 43 Absence of any identification of the transferor and transferee makes bearer securities excellent mechanisms to hide transactions from governmental authorities. See JAMES S. ROGERS, THE END OF NEGOTIABLE INSTRUMENTS, BRINGING PAYMENT SYSTEMS LAW OUT OF THE PAST 50 (OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS, NEW YORK, NY, 2012). 41 32 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts identifiable to individual depositors. This type of deposit is known as ‘regular’ or ‘special’. The duties and functions of the intermediary with respect to deposited securities are similar to those of the ordinary warehouseman of commodities. As will be demonstrated in Part II, the relationships between depositors and custodians of other valuable assets, such as gold and money, were also those of owners and bailees (custodians), in which the depositors retained ownership rights in the particular assets. Only later did such custody transform itself into a system whereby money and securities of depositors were allowed to commingle. As a result of such commingling, the traceable ownership rights of depositors were disintegrated and replaced with different rights. Consequently, the nature of deposits of securities, as well as money, made it impossible for individual depositors to assert traceable ownership rights.44 Gradually the ownership right of a depositor was transformed into a proprietary interest enforceable against his intermediary.45 In contemporary securities holding systems, this proprietary interest is classified differently in various jurisdictions in the catalog of existing property rights and includes a co-ownership right in the pool of fluctuating assets, a co-possessory right to an immobilized security, and an equitable right that is based on a trust relationship or a security entitlement.46 Whereas the right of a depositor of money shed all of its proprietary features, the contemporary right of a security depositor still includes a proprietary element. 44 Roman law introduced the concept of an irregular deposit that did not require restoration in specie. Under the irregular deposit, once possession of the asset, such as money, passed to the depository so did its ownership. The depository acquired the right to commingle and re-use the deposited object. See J.A.C. THOMAS, TEXTBOOK OF ROMAN LAW 278 (ELSEVIER SCIENCE & TECHNOLOGY BOOKS, PHILADELPHIA, PA, 1976). 45 Intermediaries also provide individualized custodial services in which the customer retains absolute ownership rights with respect to the deposited securities. See German Safe Custody Act, § 2. 46 See ROY GOODE, HIDEKI KANDA & KARL KREUZER, EXPLANATORY REPORT ON THE HAGUE CONVENTION ON THE LAW APPLICABLE TO CERTAIN RIGHTS IN RESPECT OF SECURITIES HELD WITH AN INTERMEDIARY 10 (MARTINUS NIJHOFF PUBLISHERS, HAGUE, NETHERLANDS, 2005). Introduction to Part I 33 DEMATERIALIZATION AND IMMOBILIZATION OF SECURITIES Securities have traditionally been transferred by their physical delivery and/or through entries on the issuer’s books. Transfers of securities completed by physical delivery and registration on the issuer’s books are suited for closely held securities with only a few investors and for shares that trade only occasionally. Given the small market capitalization and the low volume of trading in the Central American markets, physical transfers of certificates and registration on issuers’ books may work well for the relatively occasional transfers of securities. While these modes of transfers should be sufficient to support the low volume of trading, it does not mean that more efficient and less costly mechanisms should not be implemented. The volume of trading is just one aspect that affects the transfer mechanism; efficiency, security, cost and the introduction of electronic securities, along with other related aspects are also equally relevant. The traditional transfer mechanisms that rely on physical delivery of certificates do not work efficiently for publicly traded securities that change investors frequently. Registration capabilities of issuing companies with thousands of security holders that are located all over the world may not keep up with the large volume of trading. Physical transfers increase transactional costs, often result in late delivery and impede the liquidity of securities.47 As the volume of securities trading increases, traditional transfer mechanisms are rendered obsolete. The Process of Dematerialization In securities markets, electronic technologies were deployed not only to facilitate trading, but also to make settlement more efficient and less costly. The benefits of fully electronic front-end trading would have been severely undermined if the trades executed on electronic exchanges had to be settled by the manual delivery of certificates. Accordingly, both the front and back-end functions should be dematerialized. In this section dematerialization should not be understood as only a technological 47 Investors also face the risk of certificates being lost, stolen, or counterfeited during the course of transport. For instance, in 2004, 1.7 million physical certificates were lost in the United States. See the DTCC, News and Information for DTCC Customers, Naked Short Selling and the Stock Borrow Program, Issue Index, March 2005. 34 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts transformation but should also be thought of as a legal concept.48 The following paragraphs document dematerialization in the United States occurring in the late 1960s, after the increasing volume of securities trading and enduring inefficiencies in settling those transactions led to a ‘paper crunch’.49 The way that Wall Street was doing business at that time did not differ too much from the ways of the late nineteenth century: The tape was still a paper tape spewing out from a ticker. Paper stock certificates were stored by each broker, necessitating armies of runners to move them about the Street as they were traded. Brokerages had telephone clerks at the stock-exchange floor. The clerks would write out the orders to buy and sell, which would be phoned in from the headquarters. The clerks would hand them to floor brokers, who would execute the orders and hand the clerk a confirmation, which went back to the back-office to be recorded.50 Dematerialization is a process that converts paper certificates into electronic entries. For such transformation to be accomplished, the law must recognize this new breed of electronic securities and adequately protect the rights of those that purchase and take a security interest in such securities. While the form of securities changes, the relationship of the investor against the issuer typically remains unaffected.51 Upon adoption of dematerialization laws a new form of uncertificated security emerges. This form of security is constituted and evidenced by entries on the issuer’s books. Unlike transactions with a security certificate, transfers of uncertificated securities do not require the delivery of writing to the purchaser. However, legal measures related to dematerialization did not Ley de Anotaciones Electrónicas de Valores en Cuenta (Law on Electronic Entries of Securities to Accounts) Diario Oficial [DO] 57, 22 March 2002 (El Salvador) [hereinafter Salvadoran Law on Electronic Entries] defines dematerialization as ‘a process that results in juridical transformation of securities to annotations in accounts.’ 49 CARL S. BJERRE & SANDRA M. ROCKS, THE ABCS OF THE UCC ARTICLE 8: INVESTMENT SECURITIES 2 (2nd edn., AMERICAN BAR ASSOCIATION, CHICAGO, IL, 2004) and DTCC, A Proposal to Fully Dematerialize Physical Securities, Eliminating the Costs and Risks They Incur, A White Paper to the Industry, 3 (July 2012). 50 John S. Gordon, The Solution Became the Problem, BARRON’S, 27 August 2012, at 45. 51 Jennifer Payne, Intermediated Securities and the Right to Vote in the UK, in INTERMEDIATED SECURITIES, LEGAL PROBLEMS AND PRACTICAL ISSUES 187, 194 (Louise Gullifer & Jennifer Payne eds., HART PUBLISHING LTD., OXFORD, UK, 2010). 48 Introduction to Part I 35 entirely replace certificated and bearer securities and most laws typically continue to recognize and regulate all three types.52 The 1977 revision of the US UCC Article 8 (UCC 8) was based entirely on the idea of dematerialization and envisaged a system where transfers of dematerialized securities would be completed by issuers on their books.53 In Europe, laws providing for dematerialized corporate securities were first adopted in Denmark and France in 1981 and 1982 respectively.54 In Central America, Costa Rica provided for electronic securities in the 1998 Law on the Securities Market (Ley Reguladora del Mercado de Valores) and El Salvador adopted its law on dematerialized securities, the Law on Electronic Entries of Securities Held in Accounts (Ley de Anotaciones Electrónicas de Valores en Cuenta), in 2002 (hereinafter called ‘Salvadoran Law on Electronic Entries’). Despite the adoption of these measures many companies in these two countries today still prefer to issue shares in certificated form to monitor the identity of the security holders.55 In addition, a number of countries have adopted laws that preclude the issuance of certain types of securities in certificated form.56 However, these dematerialization reforms did not lead to the establishment of intermediated account-based systems because the issuer itself remained the entity empowered to complete transfers of uncertificated securities. Despite the laws’ anticipation of the widespread use of dematerialized securities, in the United States the system in which intermediaries maintain accounts for their customers and transfer securities between accounts essentially emerged from the bottom up. The market practice ignored the 1977 revision of UCC 8. As noted by Professor Mooney ‘although uncertificated (electronic) securities were seen as a response to the paperwork crunch, the depository system and technology-aided methods of clearance and settlement basically solved that problem even 52 See the definition of security in UCC § 8-102(15) (1994) that refers to a security certificate in bearer form, a security certificate in registered form, and a security transfer which may be registered on the books of the issuer. 53 EGON GUTTMAN, MODERN SECURITIES TRANSFERS, § 1:8 Statutory Evolution (3rd edn., THOMSON WEST, BOSTON, MA, 2007). 54 See Article 94-II of the 1982 Finance Law that became effective in November 1984. Sylvie Hebert, Certificateless Shares in France, J.B.L. 60 (1987) and Diana Chan, Florence Fontan, Simonetta Rosati & Daniela Russo, The Securities Custody Industry, European Central Bank, Occasional Paper Series No. 68, 8 (August 2007). 55 Shah, Carvajal, Bannister, Chan-Lau & Guerra, supra note 28, at 92. 56 See DTCC, A Proposal to Fully Dematerialize Physical Securities, supra note 49, at 1. 36 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts before the revised UCC 8 was promulgated in the 1990s’.57 What emerged in the United States was a system where intermediaries, rather than issuers, recorded the respective transfers on the accounts they maintained for their customers. Issuers’ records were being quickly replaced with the accounts of intermediaries as the source of rights and transfers. This market practice necessitated yet another legal development that would establish a framework to recognize the rights created and transferred by book entries made by intermediaries. Immobilization and Central Securities Depositories In contemporary markets, most securities have ceased to circulate as certificates and instead are immobilized with intermediaries. Upon depositing securities with an intermediary, subsequent transfers can be completed by entries to the accounts maintained by the intermediary.58 This process is similar to the immobilization of banknotes and coins that allows the bank to transfer the funds belonging to the customer by electronic entries to the customer’s bank account. Securities may be, and typically are, immobilized in a specially designated institution, known as the CSD, or with a financial institution that offers custodial services to its clients. The process of immobilization at the CSD does not necessarily involve the elimination of certificates.59 Securities may be immobilized at the CSD by: 1) deposit of the physical certificate or by 2) the CSD being registered as the security holder on the books of the issuer in a dematerialized form.60 The latter has become the more predominant form of immobilization but corporations and financial entities still issue securities in the form of a single certificate that represents the entire issue and that is delivered as such to a CSD.61 Charles W. Mooney, Property, Credit, and Regulation Meet Information Technology: Clearance and Settlement in the Securities Markets, 55-SUM LAW & CONTEMP. PROBS. 131, 140 (1992). 58 Dubovec, supra note 1, at 219. 59 Benjamin Geva, Recent International Developments in the Law of Negotiable Instruments and Payment and Settlement Systems, 42 TEX. INT’L L.J. 685, 688 (2007). The US DTCC annually accepts over 50 000 physical certificates for deposit. See DTCC, A Proposal to Fully Dematerialize Physical Securities, supra note 49, at 9. 60 HANS VAN HOUTTE, THE LAW OF CROSS-BORDER SECURITIES TRANSACTIONS 52 (SWEET & MAXWELL LTD., LONDON, UK, 1999). 61 See JOANNA BENJAMIN, INTERESTS IN SECURITIES, A PROPRIETARY LAW ANALYSIS OF THE INTERNATIONAL SECURITIES MARKETS 24 (OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS, OXFORD, UK, 2000). 57 Introduction to Part I 37 Physical certificates may be immobilized at the CSD in two forms: 1) a jumbo certificate or 2) a global certificate.62 The fundamental difference between the two types is that whereas a jumbo certificate may be divided into individual paper certificates upon request of the investors, the terms and conditions of global certificates preclude the possibility of their division into individual securities.63 The jumbo security may also be initially delivered to the CSD in the form of multiple certificates that altogether represent the entire issue. However, the holders of rights to the global certificate may not require their intermediaries or the CSD to issue individual certificates representing any proportions of the global certificate. As there are different types of securities, there may also be different types of CSDs. Most countries have established a special CSD for corporate (private) securities and another one for government (public) securities. The former take custody of securities issued by private entities such as corporations, banks and insurers. These CSDs are organized as private entities that are independent of the government. In contrast, other CSDs, typically operated by central banks, are organized to take custody of securities issued by governments and their instrumentalities.64 In the United States the DTC is the CSD for privately issued securities and the Federal Reserve System is the CSD for government securities. Similarly, in Brazil the Special System for Settlement and Custody (Sistema Especial de Liquidação e de Custódia) or SELIC is the CSD for securities issued by both the Brazilian government and Banco Central do Brasil and the Brazilian Clearing and Depository Corporation (CBLC) is the CSD for private securities. This duopoly of CSDs also exists in Costa Rica where the National System for Book-Entry Registration of Securities has two components: 1) for public securities managed by the Central Bank of Costa Rica and 2) for private securities managed by authorized private CSDs including CEVAL.65 This Part deals only with the depositories of private securities. CSDs for private securities are typically organized as corporate entities or as banks that are owned by holding companies or securities exchanges. 62 See Ley del Mercado de Valores [LMV] (Securities Market Law), art. 282, Diario Oficial de la Federación [DO], 30 December 2005 (Mex.) [hereinafter Mexican Securities Market Law] and Salvadoran Law on Electronic Entries, art. 2(d). 63 GUTTMAN, supra note 53, at § 1:9. 64 Dubovec, supra note 1, at 219–20. 65 Ibid., at 220. 38 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts Euroclear S.A./NV, a European-based CSD, comprises individual domestic CSDs that are part of the structure under the umbrella parent company – the Euroclear Plc.66 The other major European CSD, Clearstream, is wholly owned by the Deutsche Börse.67 In the United States, the DTC is a subsidiary of the Depository Trust & Clearing Corporation (DTCC).68 DTCC is a holding company that consolidated the DTC, the National Securities Clearing Corporation (NSCC), previously formed by the NYSE, the American Stock Exchange, and the National Association of Securities Dealers. DTCC provides clearing and settlement for equities, corporate and municipal bonds, government and mortgage-backed securities, money-market instruments and over-the-counter derivatives.69 CSDs in most developing countries also operate as corporations. The Slovakian CSD is a joint-stock company fully owned by the Bratislava Stock Exchange70 and the Mexican CSD, Indeval, is organized as a sociedad anónima whose shareholders are stockbrokers, banks, insurance companies and other entities, including the Mexican Stock Exchange.71 The Brazilian CBLC is a subsidiary of the Bovespa Holding Group, which operates the stock exchange and is owned by its members, including stockbrokers and banks.72 In El Salvador, it is a legal requirement for CSDs to 66 Euroclear, Our Structure, available at https://www.euroclear.com/en/about/ our-structure.html (last visited 9 December 2013). 67 Clearstream, About Us, available at http://www.clearstream.com/ci/ dispatch/en/kir/ci_nav/about_us (last visited 9 December 2013). 68 About DTCC, The Depository Trust Company (DTC), available at http:// www.dtcc.com/about/businesses-and-subsidiaries/dtc.aspx (last visited 9 December 2013). 69 Larry Thompson, DTCC: An Overview (August 2013), available at http:// dtcc.com /~ /media / Files / Downloads /About / government-relations / LThompsonDTCC-Overview-Aug2013.ashx (last visited 10 December 2013). 70 According to § 99 of the Securities Act, the CSD may not transform into another corporate form. As of May 2012, the Slovakian CSD had 19 participants. Centrálny Depozitár Cenných Papierov SR, Základné fakty, available at http:// www.cdcp.sk/general/cinnost.php#zakladne_fakty (last visited 9 December 2013). 71 David F. Muñoz, Arturo Palacios & Miguel de Lascurin, Modeling, Simulation and Analysis of a Securities Settlement System: The Case of Central Securities Depository of Mexico, 17(33) J. ECON. FIN. & ADMIN. SCI. 48 (2012). 72 Brazilian Clearing and Depository Corporation – CBLC, available at http://www.brazilcompany.com/html/clbc.html (last visited 9 December 2013). Introduction to Part I 39 be organized as sociedades anónimas.73 Finally, the Costa Rican CSD, CEVAL, is a subsidiary of the local stock exchange.74 Immobilization of securities is a concept and practice that has been embraced uniformly in the vast majority of economies. Developed, as well as developing, economies have established CSDs for public and private securities. While similarities among these CSDs exist in terms of their structure and organization, many differences may be identified, particularly in the process of transferring and acquiring securities, the nature of the rights thereto, the granting and perfecting of security interests, etc. These and other characteristics and differences are examined below. THE TYPOLOGY OF DIRECT AND INTERMEDIATED HOLDING SYSTEMS The corollary to the immobilization of securities is the gradual erosion of the direct relationship between the issuer and the holders of its securities. Intermediaries took on the role of facilitating the enforcement of rights embedded in immobilized securities and thus the nature of holding systems has morphed from direct to the so-called intermediated. In a direct holding system the investor, who is in possession of a security certificate and/or is registered on the issuer’s books, may enforce his rights directly against the issuer. The investor is not claiming through an intermediary and therefore the issuer’s obligations correspond to the rights of individual investors. Security holders and issuers are in privity. Transfers of securities in a direct holding system are effectuated by delivery of certificates or registration on the issuer’s books. In an intermediated holding system the investor is neither in possession of a security nor registered on the issuer’s books. The investor does not deal directly with the issuer but instead holds a securities account with an intermediary, which may also be the CSD. Its rights to the security may be enforced through the intermediary. In this case the security holder is not in privity with the issuer but with its intermediary. Transfers of 73 Ley del Mercado de Valores (Securities Market Law), arts. 74–78, Decree 809, Diario Oficial [DO] 73-bis, 21 April 1994 (El Salvador). 74 See Bolsa Nacional de Valores, Subsidiarias de la BNV, available at http://www.bolsacr.com/principal/index.php?action=subsidiarias (last visited 9 December 2013). 40 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts securities in an intermediated holding system are completed by book entries to securities accounts maintained by intermediaries for their customers. Co-existence of Direct and Intermediated Holding Systems Direct and intermediated holding systems are not mutually exclusive. In most markets a few securities are held directly and the majority is held through intermediaries. Laws governing the holding of securities also reflect the co-existence of these two holding patterns. Even the Geneva Securities Convention recognizes that multiple systems may function in parallel and does not require the contracting states to entirely replace their existing systems with an intermediated holding system. Most laws provide security holders with the right to order their intermediaries to change the holding pattern from intermediated to direct and vice-versa, if available. The holder of a certificated security may endorse a certificate that he is holding directly, place it with an intermediary and receive a credit to his securities account. Conversely, a securities account holder may request that the intermediary debit his account and deliver a security certificate unless the execution of such request is prohibited by the terms of the issuance. This possibility to change the holding pattern is not different than depositing and withdrawing cash from a bank account. The bank account holder may similarly change the holding with respect to his cash from direct to intermediated and vice-versa. The right to change the holding pattern for securities may be incorporated in the substantive law, such as in UCC § 8-508, the German Safe Custody Act § 7 or Article 56 of the Salvadoran Law on Electronic Entries, which subjects an intermediary to a duty to comply with the account holder’s order to change the holding. The right of investors to change the holding pattern may also be included in a subsidiary legislative measure, such as the rules governing operations of the German CSD, Clearstream, that provide for the right of withdrawal of certificates from the central custody.75 75 Clearstream, Deutchse Börse Group, General Terms and Business Conditions of Clearstream Banking Aktiengesellschaft, art. 41 (1 February 2004). For Mexico, see S.D. Indeval, Reglamento Interior, art. 23º [hereinafter Indeval Regulations]. Introduction to Part I 41 Some securities immobilized with CSDs prohibit their rematerialization or transformation from electronic securities to certificates.76 Accordingly the duty of the intermediary to change the holding pattern is not absolute, as the terms of some securities provide that the issuer will register only a depository on its books.77 In developed economies, such as the United States and Germany, it is not a common practice for investors to request certificates or for issuers to re-materialize electronic securities. However, this remains a practice in some developing countries such as in El Salvador.78 This discussion begs the question of whether to reform the existing legal framework for the holding of securities to provide only for the intermediated type of holding, therefore discarding entirely the possibility of holding securities directly. While most of this discussion may suggest that the future lies in intermediated holding, it is expected that many securities will remain directly held. Similarly, there are transactions that are routinely settled by payment in cash. Although this may not be practical, cultural attitudes and local practices are not uniform. It is also possible that technological advances and market practices will make the direct holding of securities once again the norm in the future. Even the Prefatory Note to UCC 8 acknowledges that ‘it is not clear whether the long-term evolution will be toward decreased or increased use of direct holdings’.79 Finally, strong views to achieve more transparency in securities markets and to be able to identify the ultimate holders of securities are also expected to have a significant influence on the type of holding used in the future. Laws should therefore preserve the flexibility noted above and leave it up to the market to develop the most efficient holding pattern from the bottom-up rather than imposing such a pattern by regulation. Intermediated Systems and their Variations While in the not so distant past literature focused primarily on the transformation from direct to intermediated holding systems, recently the spotlight has shifted to focus on the classification of various types of Under Depotgesetz (the German Securities Deposit Act), 1 November 1995 (BGB1. S.2512), § 9a(3), the issuer is not obligated to honor the request of an investor to issue a certificate if the securities were issued under such restrictions. 77 See Official Comment 1 to UCC 8-508 (1994) on the restrictions that are frequently included in municipal bonds. 78 Shah, Carvajal, Bannister, Chan-Lau & Guerra, supra note 28, at 92. 79 Prefatory Note to UCC Article 8 (1994) Investment Securities, at II. A. 76 42 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts intermediated holding systems and the identification of their intricate features.80 The project that led to the adoption of the Geneva Securities Convention gave momentum to this shift towards identification and classification.81 Structurally, all intermediated holding systems look alike. The securities holding pyramid is composed of the CSD at the top, intermediaries in the middle and accounts holders at the lower-level. However the nature of rights and the individual components of accounts relationships differ significantly. One may distinguish between two fundamental types of intermediated holding systems: 1) indirect and 2) transparent. While indirect holding systems have uniform features and structures, the typology of transparent holding systems is far from uniform. A typical characteristic of an indirect holding system is that the CSD remains unaware of the identity of particular account holders other than its participating intermediaries. In contrast, in transparent holding systems the CSD preserves a relationship with, and knows the identity of, all account holders. In indirect holding systems, the relationships between the CSD and intermediaries and the relationships between the intermediaries and account holders are independent one from one another. In transparent systems middle-level entities maintain accounts for investors but the purpose of such holding is merely administrative. Only transfers recorded at the CSD level have constitutive effects. This Part of the book refers to these entities as account operators because the securities accounts they maintain and book entries they make neither transfer nor constitute rights to securities. Thus, one needs to distinguish account operators that provide administrative functions in transparent systems, from actual intermediaries that effect transfers of securities in indirect holding systems. In transparent systems only CSDs are actual intermediaries. 80 For a discussion of direct and indirect holding systems see BJERRE & ROCKS, supra note 49; Philipp Paech, Harmonising Substantive Rules for the Use of Securities Held with Intermediaries as Collateral: The UNIDROIT Project, 4 UNIF. L. REV. 1140 (2002); and Steven L. Schwarcz & Joanna Benjamin, Intermediary Risk in the Indirect Holding System for Securities, 12 DUKE J. COMP. & INT’L L. 309 (2002). 81 For a discussion of various types of intermediated holding systems see Working Paper Regarding So Called ‘Transparent Systems’ prepared by the Secretariat on the Basis of Contributions Submitted by Delegations to the GCE, Doc. 44 (October 2006). Introduction to Part I 43 TYPES AND FORMS OF SECURITIES AND FINANCIAL ASSETS Preceding sections distinguished between directly-held securities and those that are held through intermediaries. Directly-held securities include bearer certificates, registered and uncertificated securities. It will be argued below that while the scope of direct holding systems is based on a closed-end list of securities, the scope of intermediated holding systems is much more flexible. UCC 8 provides three requirements for a security to fall under the scope of the direct holding rules: 1) a security must be represented by a security certificate in bearer or registered form or the transfer of such a certificate may be registered by the issuer; it must be one of a class or series or must be, by its terms, divisible; and it must be of a type dealt in or traded on securities exchanges or securities markets, or it must be a medium for investment that, by its terms, expressly provides that it is a security governed by Article 8.82 2) 3) If securities are held through an intermediary, the UCC 8 rules regulating the indirect holding system become applicable and securities qualify as a type of ‘financial asset’.83 The definition of a financial asset in conjunction with the definition of a securities account establishes the scope of the UCC 8 indirect holding system.84 Professor Rogers noted that the definition of securities account is as critical for the indirect holding system as the definition of security is for the direct holding system.85 An instrument may become a UCC 8 financial asset upon the undertaking of the intermediary to the account holder to execute instructions related to the enforcement of the rights embedded in the financial asset. The UCC 8 category of financial assets includes: UCC 8-102(15) (1994). BJERRE & ROCKS, supra note 49, at 6–7. 84 UCC 8-102, Official Comment 9. 85 Rogers, supra note 12, at 49 and 59. UCC 8-501(a) (1994) defines a securities account as ‘an account to which a financial asset is or may be credited in accordance with an agreement under which the person maintaining the account undertakes to treat the person for whom the account is maintained as entitled to exercise the rights that comprise the financial asset’. 82 83 44 1) 2) The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts securities; obligations of a person, or shares, participations or other interests in a person or in property, which are of a type dealt in or traded on financial markets or are recognized as a medium of investment; and any property that is held by a securities intermediary in a securities account if the securities intermediary has expressly agreed with the other person that the property is to be treated as a financial asset.86 3) The common denominator for all three categories of financial assets is their susceptibility of being credited to and held in a securities account. This attribute of being ‘creditable’ to a securities account determines whether or not an instrument qualifies as a financial asset under UCC 8. Whether or not an asset is traded on official markets and whether or not it is a debt obligation or a share is irrelevant for the UCC 8 indirect holding rules. Professor Rogers observed that ‘the rules of the indirect holding system are rules about how property is held, not what that property is’.87 As long as an asset may be credited to a securities account, it will be treated as a financial asset. A similar distinction between securities and other financial assets has been drawn in EU law. The EU Financial Collateral Directive provides for a concept of financial instrument that includes shares, equivalent securities in companies, bonds, and other forms of debt instruments provided they are negotiable on the capital markets, as well as any other securities that grant the right to acquire shares or bonds.88 Similar to the UCC concept of financial assets, the EU’s financial instrument includes traditional securities and other assets tradable in capital markets. Unlike UCC 8, the EU Financial Collateral Directive does not provide for any asset to be treated as a financial instrument when the intermediary merely agrees or undertakes to hold it as such. The EU’s financial instrument, limited only to those assets that are transferable and of which market value may be easily established, is therefore narrower, less flexible and less accommodative for instruments that may emerge in the future. Even so, it also seems to provide more predictability and clarity than UCC 8. UCC 8-102(9) (1994). Rogers also stated that ‘the indirect holding system rules could just as well apply to a banana as to a bond’. Rogers, supra note 12, at 55. 88 Council Directive 2002/47/EC on Financial Collateral Arrangements, art. 2(1)(e), 2002 O.J. (L 168) [hereinafter EU Financial Collateral Directive]. See also Council Directive 2004/39/EC on Markets in Financial Instruments, art. 4(2)(14), 2004 O.J. (L 145) [hereinafter MiFID] that defines financial instruments by reference to Section C of Annex I. 86 87 Introduction to Part I 45 Article 2(XXIV) of the Mexican Securities Market Law contains a definition of securities that is very broad and includes a wide variety of financial instruments but limits these instruments to those that are susceptible to trading in securities markets. This qualification is similar to that included in the EU law, which seems to exclude non-financial assets with values that cannot readily be established in the securities market. The Indeval Regulations in Article 1.2 do not provide any specific definition of securities and, instead, refer to the definition included in the Law on Securities Market. The Salvadoran Law does not limit the securities to those that have a financial nature or of which the value must be readily determined. Accordingly, the scope of the Salvadoran intermediated regime is more flexible than Mexico’s, which is limited to those assets susceptible to trading in securities markets. From the previous discussion, it becomes clear that legislation to regulate intermediated holding systems must clearly determine its scope by defining securities, financial assets/instruments and securities accounts. These definitions should be based on the susceptibility of financial assets/instruments to be credited to a securities account. Reliance on a laundry list of various types of securities and other numerus clausus enumerations is inapposite in the contemporary marketplace that evolves and changes quickly.89 The scope of legislation regulating intermediated holding systems must be determined on the basis of a flexible criterion that would allow ready accommodation of new securities and other financial assets to facilitate their trading and transfers. However, this approach should incorporate an objective criterion that requires assets held in securities accounts to have a financial nature and market-based value. 89 The definition of security should be flexible but also ensure legal certainty. Guiliano G. Castellano, Towards a General Framework for a Common Definition of ‘Securities’: Financial Markets Regulation in Multilingual Contexts, 13(3) UNIF. L. REV. 449, 457 (2012). 2. Securities account relationships CSD RELATIONSHIPS Immobilization of securities with CSDs changed the pattern in which securities are held and transferred. In contemporary intermediated holding systems CSDs play a critical role. Accordingly it is necessary to examine the relationships that CSDs typically engage in including: 1) 2) 3) the relationship with the issuer of the security; the relationship among CSDs; and the relationship of the CSD vis-à-vis its participating intermediaries. The relationships of the CSD with the issuer, with other CSDs, and with its participants are characterized similarly in transparent and indirect holding systems. First, the relationship of the CSD with the issuer is direct. Second, the relationships among multiple CSDs and the relationships of the CSD and its participating intermediaries are account-based. Third, the relationship of the intermediaries with direct access to the CSD against the issuer is indirect because these intermediaries may assert their claims only against the CSD and have no privity with the issuer. These upper-level relationships are complemented by the relationships of the CSD participating intermediaries with other intermediaries and the ultimate account holders. As discussed below, all of these relationships are in some respects dependent on one another yet in other respects completely independent of one another. Delivery of a global or jumbo certificate to a CSD or the CSD’s registration on the issuer’s books creates a relationship between the two.1 This relationship may be characterized as direct and it is similar to the relationship between the issuer and its shareholders that hold certificated 1 The Canadian Supreme Court in TELUS Corporation v. CDS Clearing and Depository Sevices Inc., 2012 BCSC 1350 characterized the role of the CSD as follows: ‘CSD acts as registered shareholder on behalf of financial institutions, investors, brokers, and other entities known as “participants”.’ 46 Securities account relationships 47 securities. However, there is an important difference between these two types of relationships. In exercising its functions as the central depository, the CSD is not an investor that acquires ownership or other interests in the security for investment purposes.2 Furthermore, the CSD is not authorized to create a security interest in the deposited securities because it has no rights thereto.3 In some systems, the CSD may maintain an ‘issuer account’ or ‘registry’ for the issuer. In this role, the CSD functions as a custodian or guardian of the integrity of the security.4 The Salvadoran CEDEVAL must maintain an electronic depository registry for emissions of securities (Registro Electrónico de Depósito de Emisiones) in which the emissions and any acts that purport to modify or have juridical effects on the emissions must be recorded. Similarly the Slovakian CSD is required to establish an issuer’s register.5 None of these functions make the CSD an intermediary of the issuer because the issuer accounts and registers are still not securities accounts of the nature analyzed in this Part. The CSD is an intermediary only with respect to its participants and other CSDs for whom it maintains securities accounts. In contemporary markets, many securities are acquired by investors located in jurisdictions other than that of the issuer. Access of investors to foreign securities markets is greatly facilitated by: 1) international CSDs that serve multiple domestic securities markets and 2) links established among domestic CSDs. Domestic CSDs may deposit certificates with international CSDs or establish mutual accounts with each other to facilitate transfers of securities on a cross-border basis.6 These inter-CSD links may be established in different formats, which may authorize the CSD to participate at another CSD as an ordinary intermediary or be entitled to customized services.7 Irrespective of the types of services, this See Official Comment 14 to UCC 8-102 (1994). See, for instance, Salvadoran Law on Electronic Entries, art. 34. 4 DERMOT TURING, CLEARING AND SETTLEMENT IN EUROPE 392 (BLOOMSBURY PROFESSIONAL, LTD., HAYWARDS HEATH, UK, 2012). 5 Central Securities Depository of the Slovak Republic, Rules of Operation, Part III – The Rules for Registration of Issues, Rule 6 (November 2011). 6 These relationships are typically regulated by formal agreements. See CEDEVAL General Internal Regulation, art. 2(i) that defines the ‘international custody contract’ that CEDEVAL may enter into with foreign CSDs. 7 See Zákon o cenných papieroch a investičných službách, § 99(4)(e), 9 November 2001 (Z.z. 566/2001) (Slovk.), available at http://www.nbs.sk/_img/ Documents/_Legislativa/_UplneZneniaZakonov/Z5662001.pdf (last visited 9 December 2013) [hereinafter Slovakian Securities Act]. 2 3 48 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts relationship is formalized as a securities account.8 Such inter-CSD securities accounts have the same features as the accounts established for lower-level intermediaries. Accordingly, CSDs may act as ordinary securities intermediaries.9 CSDs in developing countries often seek to establish relationships and accounts with CSDs in developed economies to facilitate access for local investors to securities issued and traded in foreign markets. A number of Latin American CSDs have been granted access to the DTC.10 CSDs facilitate the holding and transfers of securities and for this purpose they maintain securities accounts for intermediaries and investors. Once the security is immobilized with a CSD, intermediaries may acquire securities by obtaining credits to their securities accounts. Only those intermediaries for whom the CSD maintains securities accounts and that have been previously authorized may have direct access to the CSD.11 Intermediaries authorized to participate directly at the CSD are typically large banks and other institutional investors. In some systems (e.g., El Salvador’s CEDEVAL), only legal entities are allowed direct access to the CSD and natural persons may be only indirect participants.12 In other systems (e.g., Brazilian CBLC), even natural persons may be direct participants at the CSD.13 Regulations and CSD rules may further divide the participants into a number of categories depending on the types of services to which these participants have been granted access. As a condition to establishing a securities account, intermediaries are typically required to execute an agreement with the CSD and consent to The Slovakian CSD allows participation of foreign CSDs through ‘holder accounts’. Ibid., § 105a(3). In addition, linked CSDs typically execute an agreement that may be based on the ECSDA Model Agreement Template; see http: //www.ecsda.eu /site/uploads/ tx_doclibrary/2001_03_Model_Agreement_01. pdf (last visited 9 December 2013). 9 The UNIDROIT Securities Convention in art. 1(d) defines ‘intermediary’ to include a central securities depository. 10 See DCV, DTCC Sign Agreement to Expand Offerings, Capabilities, available at http://www.bnamericas.com/news/banking/DCV,_DTCC_sign_agreemeent _to_expand_offerings,_capabilities (last visited 9 December 2013). 11 See CEDEVAL General Internal Regulation (Reglamento General Interno Central de Depósito de Valores S.A. De C.V. CEDEVAL) (2002) art. 2(g). 12 Ibid. 13 Best Brazil, Brazil Market Profile, 52 (February 2012), available at http://www.bestbrazil.org.br/media/Market%20Profile.pdf (last visited 9 December 2013). 8 Securities account relationships 49 the terms and conditions of the service that will be provided.14 Securities accounts maintained by the CSD for its participating intermediaries represent the second level relationship in the holding chain. The relationship between the CSD and its participants differs from the one against the issuer. The issuer-CSD relationship is direct because the CSD holds a security certificate or is registered on the issuer’s books. In contrast, once the CSD participants acquire rights to the security, they will neither be registered on the issuer’s books nor will they receive possession of the security. From the legal relationship standpoint, their rights against the issuer are indirect. CLEARING In many systems, CSDs provide a wider range of functions including clearing, netting and settlement services. Clearing occurs between the trade and settlement and may be defined as the process which definitively establishes the obligations to deliver securities and transfer funds.15 In other words, the fundamental function of clearing is to establish the amounts of securities and funds to be credited or debited to accounts. At a minimum, clearing involves a comparison and confirmation of the transactional details provided by the trading platform to the clearing entity. In this sense, clearing is limited to administrative functions. When clearing also involves netting, it performs the additional function of reducing the number and value of transactions with securities that are eventually settled on accounts maintained by intermediaries. However, clearing may not necessarily involve a netting component. Clearing may be performed either in the centralized form in which outstanding trades are netted and the final position is calculated – ‘the clearinghouse clearing’ – or by the imposition of a central counterparty that novates all outstanding contracts and becomes the counterparty to every contract – 14 See CEDEVAL General Internal Regulation art. 2(b) that defines securities account contract (contrato de cuenta de valores) and European Central Counterparty Limited Rules, Rule 2, Section 2: Participant’s Agreement of the EuroCCP Rules (1 October 2012) [hereinafter EuroCCP Rules]. 15 See L. 964, julio 8, 2005, Diario Oficial [D.O.] 45.963 (Colom), art. 9. CBLC, Operating Rules, Rule 3.14 defines clearing as ‘the process of calculating the mutual obligations of counterparty market participants, on a net basis, for the exchange of securities and money by way of settlement of mutual net settlement obligations’. 50 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts ‘the central counterparty clearing’. The advantage of the central counterparty clearing for securities transactions is the reduction of risk but the downside is its relatively high cost.16 Upon receipt of trade information, the clearinghouse will first compute all outstanding obligations to deliver between the intermediaries and then will net any obligations that cancel each other out. Netting reduces multiple delivery obligations that would otherwise overlap each other into a single delivery obligation. Under the clearinghouse clearing, outstanding obligations are reduced to a single obligation through netting and the clearinghouse acts as a mere calculation agent instructing some intermediaries to deliver securities and others to submit payments. The clearinghouse does not assume any obligation to transfer, and thus the obligations remain enforceable between the intermediaries. Clearing of obligations to deliver securities may also be effectuated in the form of central counterparty clearing. In this type of clearing, a central counterparty (CCP) interposes itself between the original contracting parties.17 This additional step is performed by novation. This type of clearing involves three separate functions: 1) calculation of trades, 2) novation and 3) netting. The first function is administrative and entails mechanical comparison of trade details. The two other functions entail risk management directed towards the reduction in counterparty risk.18 CCPs provide a special financial risk management service that neutralizes counterparty risk.19 Due to novation, the satisfaction of ultimate delivery obligations differs in the systems that utilize these two types of clearing functions. While in the clearinghouse clearing systems securities are delivered directly between the participants, in the central TURING, supra note 4, at 16. Council Directive 98/26/EC on Settlement Finality in Payment and Securities Settlement Systems, art. 2(c), 1998 O.J. (L 166) [hereinafter EU Settlement Finality Directive] defines central counterparty as an entity which is interposed between the institutions in a system and which acts as the exclusive counterparty of these institutions with regard to their transfer orders. 18 For a definition of ‘counterparty risk’ see Council Regulation 648/2012 on OTC Derivatives, Central Counterparties and Trade Repositories (4 July 2012) art. 2(11), 2012 O.J. (L 201) 1. 19 Christian Chamorro-Courtland, Central Counterparties (CCP) and the New Transnational Lex Mercatoria, FLA. ST. U. BUS. REV. 57, 60 and 115 (2011). 16 17 Securities account relationships 51 counterparty clearing securities are delivered to the CCP and then from the CCP to the participating intermediary entitled to receive delivery.20 As a result of novation, the original delivery obligation between two intermediaries is broken up into two new delivery obligations that involve the CCP. These two new obligations are independent from one another and, after novation, the CCP is contractually required to perform on one obligation even if its counterparty defaults on the other.21 Novation results in the intermediaries eliminating the risk of one another’s default. However, on the downside, CCPs concentrate credit risk, creating a potential systemic collapse if a number of CCP counterparties default.22 For this reason, CCPs must have in place adequate risk management measures that preserve their capital.23 Furthermore CCPs must concern themselves only with the clearing of securities transactions.24 The counterparty risk is further managed by netting, a process that is typically effectuated by the CCP upon novation. In securities markets, intermediaries typically enter into a number of transactions with respect to the same security daily.25 In CCP systems, their mutual obligations are both novated and netted, resulting in a significant reduction in final delivery obligations. 20 MATTHIAS HAENTJENS, HARMONISATION OF SECURITIES LAW, CUSTODY AND TRANSFER OF SECURITIES IN EUROPEAN PRIVATE LAW 46 (KLUWER LAW INTERNATIONAL, ALPHEN AAN DEN RIJN, NETHERLANDS, 2008). 21 JOANNA BENJAMIN, INTERESTS IN SECURITIES, A PROPRIETARY LAW ANALYSIS OF THE INTERNATIONAL SECURITIES MARKETS 24 (OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS, OXFORD, UK, 2000). 22 JIABIN HUANG, THE LAW AND REGULATION OF CENTRAL COUNTERPARTIES 174–5 (HART PUBLISHING LTD., PORTLAND, OR, 2010) and TINA P. HASENPUSCH, CLEARING SERVICES FOR GLOBAL MARKETS 45 (CAMBRIDGE UNIVERSITY PRESS, NEW YORK, NY, 2009). 23 Jean-Claude Trichet, Issues Related to Central Counterparty Clearing, Speech at the joint European Central Bank-Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Conference, Frankfurt (4 April 2006), available at http://www.bis.org/review/ r060411c.pdf (last visited 9 December 2013). 24 The NSCC, the central counterparty for over 50 million transactions executed daily on US securities exchanges, maintained a cash clearing fund of US$ 7 billion and a US$ 6.275 billion line of credit as of October 2011. DTCC, Proposal to Launch a New Cost-Benefit Analysis on Shortening the Settlement Cycle, at 6–7 (December 2011). 25 HASENPUSCH, supra note 22, at 25. 52 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts In the United States, the NSCC performs clearing functions for transactions with securities settled through the DTC.26 The NSCC acts as a middleman that assumes the delivery and payment obligations of the original parties and, in that capacity, reduces the settlement requirements for trades by 98 percent.27 The Supreme Court of Nevada summarized the clearing procedures of the NSCC and its interactions with the DTC as follows: After the NSCC calculates a broker’s payment or delivery obligation with respect to a specified security for a designated trading period, the broker normally owes or is owed shares of that security. The NSCC then transmits that information to the DTC for processing. For the selling broker, the DTC compares the broker’s share delivery obligation, if any, to the amount of that share held in the broker’s DTC account, to determine whether the broker possesses enough shares to fulfill his delivery obligation. If enough shares are present in the selling broker’s DTC account to fulfill that delivery obligation, delivery of those shares occurs by sending the shares through the NSCC to the DTC account of the party owed the securities, the buying broker.28 In 2007, the European Central Bank (ECB) conducted a survey of domestic central clearing systems in the EU Member States.29 The ECB survey found that there were nine CCPs operating in the EU countries of Austria, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Italy, Spain, Sweden and the United Kingdom. As a result of integration and mergers, multinational clearing entities have been established to clear securities transactions executed in a number of EU markets. For instance, Belgian, French, Dutch and Portuguese local clearing entities merged together to form LCH.Clearnet S.A., which now provides CCP clearing for transactions A similar clearing structure exists in Canada where the Ontario Securities Commission appointed the CSD to provide central counterparty clearing services. CDS Participant Rules, Release 3.3. (January 2009), available at http:// www.cds.ca/cdsclearinghome.nsf/Downloads/-EN-CDSParticipantRules3.3/$File/ CDS+Participant+Rules_3.3_en.pdf?OpenElement (last visited 9 December 2013). 27 DTCC, The US Model for Clearing and Settlement, An Overview of DTCC, 3 (2007). 28 Nanopierce Techn. v. DTC, 168 P.3d 73, 78 (St. C. NV, 2007). 29 George Kalogeropoulos, Daniela Russo & Andreas Schonenberger, Link Arrangements of Central Counterparties in the EU – Results of an ESCB Survey, in The European Central Bank, The Role of Central Counterparties, 50 (July 2007), available at http://www.ecb.eu/pub/pdf/other/rolecentralcounterparties 200707en.pdf (last visited 9 December 2013). 26 Securities account relationships 53 executed in securities markets of any of the included countries.30 More recently, European Central Counterparty Limited (EuroCCP) was established to provide organizational support for cross-European securities trading, clearing and settlement. Presently it clears securities transactions from eighteen European markets.31 Despite the regionalization of clearing services within the EU, a single pan-European clearing and settlement system along the lines of the US DTCC system has yet to be established.32 The clearing landscape in developing countries of Latin America is split between systems in which clearing services are provided and systems in which clearing is absent. One of the few clearing entities in Latin America is the Brazilian Clearing and Depository Corporation, CBLC, which provides CCP clearing services. In Mexico, Contraparte Central has been providing CCP services for securities immobilized with Indeval since 2004. A study undertaken by the IMF concluded that in Central America the concepts of netting and clearing are not well understood and, as a result, the legal framework governing clearing is inadequate.33 The clearing process at the Salvadoran CSD, CEDEVAL, is limited to the submission of trade details from the stock exchange and their confirmation by counterparties.34 A number of systems in Latin America, including Bolivia, Ecuador, Honduras and Panama, do not provide any clearing services at all. 30 LCH.Clearnet S.A. is owned 73.3% by users, 10.9% by exchanges and 15.8% by Euroclear. See LCH.Clearnet, About Us, available at http:// www.lchclearnet.com/about_us/ (last visited 9 December 2013). 31 EuroCCP is a clearing subsidiary of the US DTCC. See EuroCCP, Overview: The EuroCCP Advantage, available at http://www.euroccp.co.uk/ about/ (last visited 9 December 2013). 32 Establishment of such a system was strongly advocated by the former Chairman of the London Stock Exchange, Don Cruickshank; see Nathalie Aubry, Regulating the Plumbing of Europe, 23(11) J.I.B.L.R. 578, 580 (2008). 33 Hermant Shah, Ana Carvajal, Geoffrey Bannister, Jorge Chan-Lau & Ivan Guerra, Equity and Private Debt Markets in Central America, Panama and the Dominican Republic, IMF Working Paper WP/07/288, 16 (2007). 34 CEDEVAL, Manual de Operaciones, Capı́tulo VI, Compensación y Liquidación de Valores, at A. Proceso de Compensación, available at https:// www.cedeval.com/pdf/mop_cedeval.pdf (last visited 9 December 2013). 54 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts SETTLEMENT Clearing, if provided in a particular system, precedes the settlement, or the process that involves the actual transfer of securities between securities accounts. The settlement of a transaction with securities involves two transfers: 1) a transfer of securities and 2) a transfer of funds. The CSD will effectuate the first transfer by crediting and debiting the securities accounts of the intermediaries. This type of settlement is effectuated centrally when the transfers are settled through the CSD. However, many transfers are completed on a decentralized basis by intermediaries, such as when two customers of the same intermediary execute a transaction with the same security, one buying and the other selling. This transaction will be settled by the intermediary effectuating credits and debits to the respective customer accounts without involving the central clearing and settlement facilities. Intermediaries that participate at the CSD must also open bank settlement accounts typically with the central bank or with one of the authorized settling banks. If a central counterparty clearing is provided in the system, the clearing entity must also have established a deposit account for the purposes of transferring funds in the settlement of securities transactions. In the United States, the DTC authorizes settling banks to open bank accounts at a Federal Reserve Bank to effectuate payments in the settlement of securities transactions.35 In Europe, participants at the Clearstream Germany system must open a bank account with the Bundesbank and grant Clearstream the authority to submit payment orders for the purpose of settling securities transactions.36 A similar structure was adopted in Slovakia, in which transfers of securities at the Slovakian CSD are settled against payments on the bank accounts maintained by the Slovakian National Bank.37 Brazil and Mexico have 35 DTCC Rules and Procedures, Rule 9(d) (June 2009). Settling banks must sign agreements with the DTCC to function as such. 36 Clearstream, Deutchse Börse Group, General Terms and Business Conditions of Clearstream Banking Aktiengesellschaft, art. 9(1)(a) (1 February 2004). If the participant does not have an account at Bundesbank, it may request a correspondent banking institution with such an account to authorize Clearstream to make respective entries in the account to settle transactions entered into by the participant. 37 Central Securities Depository of the Slovak Republic, Rules of Operation, Part IV – The Rules on Clearing and Settlement (July 2007) art. 1(2)(l). Securities account relationships 55 adopted a similar central settlement design.38 Maintenance of bank accounts by the central bank for CSDs, securities intermediaries and officially designated settling banks protect the securities settlement system against the insolvency and credit risk of a financial institution. Transfers among bank and securities accounts maintained for CSD participants are typically completed on a delivery-versus-payment (DVP) basis. A DVP settlement may operate on a net basis, whereby individual transfers are netted and only a single entry is made, or on a gross basis, in which both the payment and transfer of securities occur in real time.39 DVP settlement completed on a gross basis minimizes counterparty risk, eliminating situations in which one party receives securities but then fails to provide payment or vice-versa. Many securities settlement systems regardless of the size of securities markets, the volume of transactions or the liquidity of secondary markets, provide DVP settlement services. In the United States, the DTC Rule 9A – Transactions in Securities and Money Payments – established the basis for the DVP settlement.40 Latin American CSDs, including those in Brazil,41 Mexico42 and Costa Rica,43 also effectuate settlement on the DVP basis. Similarly in Europe, Clearstream Germany, Clearstream Luxembourg, and the smaller CSD in Slovakia, provide for DVP gross settlement.44 Clearing and settlement functions of CSDs and other intermediaries are significantly impacted by the legal and regulatory requirements to settle 38 For Brazil see Banco Central do Brasil, BM&FBOVESPA Securities, available at http://www.bcb.gov.br/?BMFSECURITIES (last visited 9 December 2013) and CBLC, Rule 3.19, which defines settlement account as ‘an account that CBLC, as a provider of settlement services, holds with the Central Bank …’. For Mexico, see Indeval Regulations, art. 28º. 39 ECB, Settlement Fails – Report on Securities Settlement Systems (SSS) Measures to Ensure Timely Settlement, 2 (April 2011), available at http:// www.ecb.int/pub/pdf/other/settlementfails042011en.pdf (last visited 9 December 2013). 40 DTCC Rules and Procedures, Rule 9(A) (June 2009). 41 See Banco Central do Brasil, BM&FBOVESPA-CBLC, available at http:// www.bcb.gov.br/pom/spb/ing/securitiesderivativesforeign/cblcingles.asp (last visited 9 December 2013). 42 Indeval Regulations, art. 27º. 43 THE WORLD BANK, MASSIMO CIRASINO, JOSÉ ANTONIO GARCÍA, MARIO GUADAMILLAS & FERNANDO MONTES-NEGRET, REFORMING PAYMENTS AND SECURITIES SETTLEMENT SYSTEMS IN LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN 141–2 (THE WORLD BANK, WASHINGTON, DC, 2007). 44 For a list of European CSDs and the types of settlement services that they provide see ECB, Eligible SSSs, available at http://www.ecb.int/paym/coll/coll/ eligiblesss/html/index.en.html (last visited 9 December 2013). 56 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts transactions within a certain number of days after the trade was executed. These requirements are known under acronyms such as T+3 and T+1 in which the ‘T’ stands for the day of trade. Regulations require intermediaries to make the respective entries to the accounts they maintain a certain number of days after the trade was concluded in a securities market. The settlement cycles differ in individual systems, but generally vary from T+0 to T+5. These cycles also vary for the settlement of transactions with individual types of securities and are generally longer for shares than for bonds.45 Currently the global trend is to implement measures leading to the reduction of the settlement cycle to T+2 for securities transactions, aligning them with that of foreign exchange transactions.46 ACCOUNT RELATIONSHIPS AT LOWER TIERS AND RIGHTS TO SECURITIES The preceding section identified the top-tier entities and examined the functions they perform in contemporary securities holding systems. The traditional relationship between the issuer of securities and investors incorporated in a security certificate or registration on the issuer’s book has been replaced with an account-based relationship in the form of securities accounts. These securities accounts are not maintained by issuers for their individual investors but by CSDs and lower-level intermediaries. Contemporary laws on the holding of securities focus on relationships represented by securities accounts instead of the actual security. These account-based relationships may take various forms and be subject to different rules. Depending on the characterization of account holders’ rights to securities, systems may be classified into two categories: 1) those that apply the traditional proprietary concepts that allow account holders to trace their rights to the security deposited with a CSD and 2) those that provide for a new legal concept, such as the security entitlement that does not allow for tracing through the tiers of intermediaries. In most systems today investors hold securities in the form of electronic entries to securities accounts. Like possession of a bearer ECB, supra note 39, at 3. OMGEO, How to Make Settlement More Efficient and Less Risky: The Global Move towards Shorter Settlement Cycles as a Significant Driver of Operational Change, 3 (2012) available at https://www.omgeo.com/ settlementpaper (last visited 9 December 2013). 45 46 Securities account relationships 57 security or registration on the issuer’s books, a securities account establishes the right to securities or financial assets. This right of the account holder is quantitatively determined by the balance on his securities account which is the equivalent to the aggregate value of certificated securities that the investor may possess. However, the account balance does not speak to the quality of the rights to securities. By looking at the balance on a securities account, one may not determine whether the investor has ownership rights, other property rights or contractual claims. First, it is important to determine whether the rights acquired by account entries are proprietary or contractual. Generally property rights provide a person with priority over the rights of third parties and, in the context of securities holding, protect the investor against the insolvency of his intermediary. Property rights, whether in the form of absolute ownership or limited proprietary interests, ensure that the account holder’s claim against the intermediary will be satisfied from the assets that the intermediary maintains for the investor. The property interests of account holders are limited because they may be enforceable only against the intermediary, as in a security entitlement, or they may be shared pro-rata with other investors, as in co-ownership. The remaining question is to determine the nature of these proportional proprietary interests that could include co-ownership, indirect co-possession, an interest in trust property, etc.47 The following section contrasts two predominant approaches to the characterization of pro-rata proprietary interests in the context of intermediated holding systems: 1) the fashioning of new legal concepts, such as the security entitlement, and 2) the application of co-ownership concepts.48 A New Legal Concept The holding systems of Canada and the United States are known as indirect. Under these laws pro-rata proprietary interests of account Classification of the account holders’ rights depends on their jurisdiction. José M. Garrido, The Loss-sharing Rule in the Insolvency of Financial Intermediaries, 15(3–4) UNIF. L. REV. 779, 781 (2010). 48 Marek Dubovec, Securities Holding Patterns and Their Impact on the Rights of Securities Holders: Lessons for Developing Nations, in LATIN AMERICAN COMPANY LAW: A COMPARATIVE AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT PERSPECTIVE, VOL. 1, 213, 221–4 (Boris Kozolchyk & Francisco Reyes eds., CAROLINA ACADEMIC PRESS, DURHAM, NC, 2013). 47 58 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts holders are characterized as security entitlements.49 The 1994 revision of UCC 8 introduced a number of important concepts to support the already existing indirect holding system. During the drafting of the revised UCC 8 the interest of the account holder in an indirectly held security was described and then labeled a security entitlement.50 A securities account consists of the sum of all the security entitlements maintained therein. The approach of the drafters was both practical and functional in that they captured the function of the rights in the security entitlement concept. The Canadian Uniform Securities Transfer Act, modeled on the 1994 revision of UCC 8, also followed this functional approach.51 Professor Rogers recalled the following discussion on the security entitlement during the UCC 8 drafting process: Several of the early drafts avoided explicit mention of the concept of ‘property interest’ on the theory that the use of the older language might be problematic. It is certainly true that a security entitlement is not a property interest in some specific item held by the intermediary, of the sort that might be asserted against someone else to whom that specific security has been transferred … However, many lawyers who were involved in the project warned that lawyers from other legal systems would be confused if it were not possible to provide a simple answer to the question ‘Is a security entitlement a property interest?’ In response to those concerns the language used in the statute was changed to make it possible to provide a simple, unambiguous answer to exactly that question. The answer is ‘Yes. A security entitlement is a property interest.’ The text makes this point absolutely clear.52 So what kind of a property interest is a security entitlement? Professor Guttman answered that ‘a security entitlement represents a distinct property interest embodying rights in a financial asset, but does not 49 See UCC 8-102(17) (1994) and Part VI of the Canadian Uniform Securities Transfer Act. 50 Mohamed F. Khimji, Intermediary Credit Risk – A Comparative Law Analysis of Property Rights in Indirectly Held Securities, J.B.L. 287, 316 (2005). 51 Mohamed F. Khimji, The Securities Transfer Act – The Radical Reconceptualization of Property Rights in Investment Securities, 45 ALBERTA L. REV. 137, 138 (2007). See further RONALD C.C. CUMING, CATHERINE WALSH & RODERICK J. WOOD, ESSENTIALS OF CANADIAN LAW, PERSONAL PROPERTY SECURITY LAW 35–6 (IRWIN LAW INC., TORONTO, ONTARIO, 2005). 52 James S. Rogers, The Revision of Canadian Law on Securities Holding Through Intermediaries: Who, What, When, Where, How and Why, CA. BUS. L. J. 49, 61 (2007). Securities account relationships 59 represent a property interest in the underlying financial asset itself’.53 The critical difference being that the object of the latter is an identifiable security certificate whereas the object of the former is the rights held in the account maintained by the intermediary. Accordingly, an entitlement holder does not have the same ownership rights to the security as a holder of the actual certificate. UCC 8-102(a)(17) defines security entitlement as a bundle of ‘the rights and property interest of an entitlement holder with respect to a financial asset’. The entitlement holder is thus vested with a number of contractual rights and a proprietary interest. Additionally the property interest bundled within the particular security entitlement is not derived from the issuer, the CSD or an upper-tier intermediary and these third parties do not actually know who the account holder is. It is only the relevant intermediary who knows the identity of the entitlement holder and the quantity of his holding. For that reason, the first feature bundled within the security entitlement is that its holder remains unknown to other participants in the indirect holding chain with the exception of his own intermediary. The property element embodied in the security entitlement is ‘the investor’s interest in its account with the intermediary’.54 The account holder may not exercise any property rights directly against the issuer, the CSD or other intermediaries. The property interest exists only in the account relationship with the intermediary.55 As an illustration, if IBM issued 1000 shares and an intermediary acquired 100 shares of that total, the intermediary would acquire a 10 percent undivided share to the IBM stock deposited with the CSD. If, subsequently, the intermediary sold 50 IBM shares to one of its customers, that customer would acquire an undivided 50 percent interest in the intermediary’s undivided 10 percent interest. The customer would not acquire a 5 percent interest in the IBM stock enforceable against the CSD because his claim would remain enforceable only against the intermediary.56 The entitlement holder is in privity only with the intermediary that maintains the securities account to 53 EGON GUTTMAN, MODERN SECURITIES TRANSFERS, § 11A:1 (3rd edn., THOMSON WEST, BOSTON, MA, 2007). 54 Charles W. Mooney, Beyond Negotiability: A New Model for Transfer and Pledge of Interests in Securities Controlled by Intermediaries, 12 CARDOZO L. REV. 305, 310 (1990). 55 The property interest of entitlement holders originates from their intermediaries. E. Perry Hicks, Transfer Restrictions in the Indirect Holding System: Is Alienability in the Form of Holding?, BUS. L. TODAY 1, 2 (2012). 56 Steven L. Schwarcz, Intermediary Risk in Global Economy, 50 DUKE L.J. 1541, 1548 (2001). 60 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts which the entitlement is credited and may not assert his rights against any other participant, including the CSD.57 Likewise, the entitlement holder’s rights are not traceable through the tiers of intermediaries to other account-based relationships.58 The proprietary interest of the securities account holder corresponds to the intermediary’s duty to maintain financial assets that match the aggregate of all security entitlements it is holding for its customers.59 Accordingly, the proprietary interest protects the entitlement holder against the intermediary and any creditors of the intermediary, including the insolvency trustee.60 This element also localizes any potential losses within the particular account relationship, leaving other account relationships unaffected. This insulation of individual account relationships is based on the principle of privity of contract. Sommer explained the privity of contract function as follows: ‘Privity does to account relationships what negotiability does to property relations. Privity cuts off adverse claims, and abolishes the relevant history of the account.’61 The fact of existence of a security entitlement within the particular account relationship is also supported by the mode of its creation. A security entitlement may be established when the intermediary actually credits securities to an account or it may be deemed established by law. The constitution of a security entitlement may, under some circumstances, be divorced from the account entry and be created at the moment when the intermediary accepts a financial asset for credit to the securities account.62 If the intermediary was obligated to credit the customer’s account, but failed to do so, the security entitlement is deemed to have been established from the moment the duty of the intermediary to create such a credit in the customer’s account arose. The intermediary may also credit its customer’s account before it receives a credit to its own account.63 In this respect, Official Comment 2 to UCC § 8-501 provides UCC 8-102(a)(7) (1994). ROYSTON MILES GOODE, LEGAL PROBLEMS OF CREDIT AND SECURITY 215 (3rd edn., SWEET & MAXWELL, LONDON, UK, 2003). 59 See UCC 8-504(a) (1994) and Official Comment 1. 60 Dubovec, supra note 48, at 222. 61 Joseph H. Sommer, Commentary: Where is the Economic Analysis of Payment Law?, 83 CHI.-KENT. L. REV. 751, 755 (2008). 62 UCC 8-501(b) (1994). 63 See Amicus Curiae Brief by the Security and Exchange Commission (SEC) in Whistler Investments, Inc. v. DTCC, 2008 WL 3876577 (9th Cir. 2008) at 10. 57 58 Securities account relationships 61 that ‘… what circumstances give rise to security entitlements turns on the intermediary’s conduct … ’. In summary, what are the features characteristic of the property interest embedded within a security entitlement? First, it is not an ownership right to a specific asset. Second, it is an interest in the pool of financial assets shared pro-rata with other entitlement holders. Third, the rights embedded in the security entitlement are enforceable only against the intermediary that maintains the relevant account. Fourth, the intermediary has the duty to maintain sufficient assets that must correspond to the security entitlements of its account holders. Fifth, its constitution may be independent of the account entry arising at the time the intermediary becomes obligated to credit the customer’s account. Traditional Proprietary Concepts Some systems have not adopted specialized laws to address the rights of investors to securities held in accounts with intermediaries and, by analogy, apply the traditional proprietary concepts, such as those incorporated in Civil Codes. Others have adopted special custody laws that specifically characterize the rights of account holders yet, overall, reforms in many systems have not been as far-reaching as those in the United States. The first jurisdictions that reformed their securities transfer laws to accommodate the new system of account-based intermediated holding were Belgium and Luxembourg. These jurisdictions characterized the interest of account holders as co-ownership rights in a pool of fungible securities.64 Belgium and Luxembourg became pioneers primarily because they became the host countries to the then largest CSDs – Euroclear and Clearstream, respectively. Legal reforms in other European and Latin American countries were implemented much later with the establishment of their respective domestic CSDs. German law applies the concept of possession to characterize the rights of account holders. Article 868 of the BGB (German Civil Code) creates 64 MICHAEL BLAIR QC & GEORGE WALKER, FINANCIAL MARKETS AND EXCHANGES LAW 210 (OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS, OXFORD, UK, 2007) and UK Financial Markets Law Committee (2004), Analysis of the need for and nature of legislation relating to property interests in indirectly held investment securities with a statement of principles for an investment securities statute – Report, Issue 3 Property Interests in Investment Securities available at http://www.fmlc.org/ Pages/papers.aspx (last visited 9 December 2013). Co-ownership was also the underlying concept of the previous 1977 revision of UCC Article 8 of 1977. See Mooney, supra note 54, at 403–4. 62 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts a structure in which intermediaries possess the security for their account holders constructively (indirectly). German scholars argued that account holders are thus vested with an indirect right to possession of the security.65 One may wonder how possession, albeit constructive, fits into a system that is based on electronic accounts and entries and in which the only tangible object may be the global or jumbo security immobilized with a CSD. Paradoxically, it is the global security that provides the answer to this question. When the CSD is in possession of the global security it may be characterized as direct.66 Intermediaries and account holders who claim rights to the immobilized security may be said to have an indirect (constructive) possessory right. This theory relies on the possibility of tracing the account holders’ rights through the chain of intermediaries to a common source – the immobilized security. One may explain this possessory right as the right to possession that gives the account holder the right to shared control over the certificate.67 It is a type of possessory interest that is based on the control rights of the account holder to a tangible object rather than on its physical custody. Since the adoption of the Securities Deposit Act in 1972, German law also classifies the rights of securities account holders as co-ownership interests if the securities are held in the form of collective safe custody.68 Accordingly, in Germany the rights of account holders are characterized as both co-possessory under the Civil Code and as co-ownership under the Securities Deposit Act.69 The principles of indirect possession incorporated in Article 868 of the BGB, joint possession as reflected in the General Terms and Business Conditions of German Clearstream Banking, and co-ownership as reflected in the Securities Deposit Act create 65 Bernd Geier, Comparison of the Electronic Securities Settlement Systems for the Secondary Securities Markets in Germany and England, 23(3) J.I.B.L.R. 97, 102 (2008) and EVA MICHELER, PROPERTY IN SECURITIES, A COMPARATIVE STUDY 189 (CAMBRIDGE UNIVERSITY PRESS, CAMBRIDGE, UK, 2007). 66 See General Terms and Business Conditions of German Clearstream Banking, which, in art. 8(1)(b), provide that the CSD is the direct holder of possession. 67 Khimji also observed that control serves as a means of identifying the party that has the ability to alienate investment securities. This is akin to the notion of constructive possession. Khimji, supra note 51, at 162. 68 Depotgesetz, § 6(1). Collective safe custody is defined in § 5. 69 CHANGMIN CHUN, CROSS-BORDER TRANSACTIONS OF INTERMEDIATED SECURITIES, A COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS IN SUBSTANTIVE LAW AND PRIVATE INTERNATIONAL LAW 118 (SPRINGER-VERLAG BERLIN HEIDELBERG, NEW YORK, NY, 2012). Securities account relationships 63 unnecessary complexity, although in practice, no operational difficulties have arisen.70 In a number of other EU jurisdictions, including Slovakia, the rights of account holders are classified as co-ownership interests.71 Under the co-ownership theory, individualized property rights in a specific asset no longer apply and investors instead have a right to a pro-rata share corresponding to the quantity of securities credited to their securities accounts.72 Some of these countries have adopted special custody laws that preempt the property concepts enshrined in the Civil Codes. In Slovakia fungible securities are kept in bulk safekeeping (deposit) and investors acquire joint ownership to such securities subject to the special regime of securities laws.73 The joint ownership to securities held in bulk is excluded from the application of the general rules on joint ownership incorporated in the Slovakian Civil Code.74 The joint ownership right of an investor therefore becomes a pro-rata share to the bulk.75 Latin America in general follows the property law classifications that are characteristic of the EU jurisdictions and applies the concept of co-ownership to characterize the rights of securities account holders.76 Brazil characterizes the rights of accounts holders as that of co-ownership, with the CSD functioning as the fiduciary owner of the immobilized security for the benefit of accounts holders.77 Accordingly, it preserves the relationship between the CSD and individual beneficial owners that is established by a duty of the intermediaries to allocate all securities at the beneficial-customer level to a particular securities account number.78 In Central America, Article 15 of the Salvadoran Law on Electronic Entries provides that the rights of account holders are of a Ibid., 195–6. Slovakian Securities Act, § 39(3) characterizes the rights of investors as ‘joint property’. See further Peter Baláž, Implikuje účet majitel’a cenných papierov depozitný vzt’ah?, 59(3) JUSTIČNÁ REVUE 383, 385 (2007). 72 Clearstream Banking Luxembourg, General Terms and Conditions, art. 11 (January 2006). 73 Slovakian Securities Act, §§ 39(3) and 42. 74 Ibid. 75 Ibid. See also § 39(2) under which a separate custody for individual securities, segregated from the same securities of others, is also available. 76 See Resolución 0816 del 26 May 2011 emitida por la Superintendencia Financiera de Colombia, Reglamento de Operaciones Deceval S.A. art. 27 (Colom.) [hereinafter Deceval Reglamento], which defines the rights of account holders to the immobilized security as ‘collective ownership’. 77 Dubovec, supra note 48, at 224. 78 Best Brazil, supra note 13, at 50. 70 71 64 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts co-ownership nature.79 It is noteworthy that the Mexican Securities Market Law, the Internal Regulation of Indeval, and its Manual, do not define the nature of rights to securities credited to accounts. The co-ownership right may allow for the tracing of accounts holders’ interests to the security deposited with the CSD. If the intermediary acquired 100 shares of the total number of 1000 shares issued by IBM, the intermediary would acquire a 10 percent undivided share to the IBM stock deposited with the CSD. If subsequently the intermediary sold 50 IBM shares to one of its customers, that customer would not acquire an undivided 50 percent interest in the intermediary’s undivided 10 percent, as in the indirect holding system. Instead, the customer would acquire a 5 percent interest in the IBM stock enforceable against the CSD. PROTECTION OF INVESTORS’ RIGHTS The core protection for investors holding their securities in intermediated systems is the duty of their intermediaries to ‘allocate’ securities to their account holders’ rights. Intermediaries may satisfy this duty by holding or maintaining sufficient securities to satisfy all claims of their account holders.80 In indirect holdings systems, intermediaries regularly maintain financial assets of their account holders on a fungible basis in an omnibus account with an upper-tier intermediary.81 These omnibus accounts are segregated from the proprietary accounts of the intermediary but individual securities and financial assets are not allocated to particular customers of the intermediary.82 Accordingly the upper-tier intermediary knows only that the omnibus account holds financial assets belonging to the customers of the lower-tier intermediary but does not know the identities of these customers. The account holders do not acquire specific property interests in the financial assets maintained in the omnibus account but their interests extend pro-rata to the entire account.83 The concept of a pro-rata proprietary interest is characteristic of the law 79 Salvadoran Law on Electronic Entries, art. 15 provides: ‘Los valores anotados podrán poseerse en copropiedad’. 80 See Official Comment 3 to UCC 8-504 (1994). 81 Omnibus accounts have advantages, such as that they allow for net settlement, and disadvantages, such as that they require loss-allocation formulas. TURING, supra note 4, at 238. 82 CCPs regularly set up clearing member accounts separately from those of their customers. HUANG, supra note 22, at 91. 83 UCC 8-503(b) (1994). Securities account relationships 65 concerning bailment of fungible goods, such as grain and oil. Professor Rogers observed that UCC Article 7, dealing with documents of title and bailment relationships, is based on the ‘proportionate ownership’ approach that is similar to the rule applicable to the rights of investors to securities held in bulk.84 This pro-rata property interest protects bailors/ investors against the bailee/securities intermediary’s insolvency and the claims of their creditors because the entitlements are not property of the intermediary.85 As a consequence, the securities intermediary may not grant a security interest in the financial assets which it maintains for its entitlement holders without their consent.86 In transparent holding systems, financial assets of investors must also be separated or segregated from those of the intermediary.87 While customer securities must be segregated, intermediaries in transparent systems are mere conduits that facilitate the holding of their customers’ co-ownership rights against the CSD. CSDs in transparent systems distinguish between the proprietary accounts of intermediaries and those that they maintain for customers. Under German law, customer securities may be commingled with those of the intermediary only when the customer expressly waives the requirement of segregation.88 These two types of accounts are designated as such in the CSD’s records.89 In Brazil, CBLC is not authorized to open omnibus accounts for intermediaries.90 As a result, in the case of a default by either the intermediary or one of its account holders, the rights to securities of the other 84 James S. Rogers, Negotiability, Property, and Identity, 12 CARDOZO L. REV. 471, 485 (1990). 85 Ibid., 486. However, the pro rata rule provides comparatively weaker protection to the direct holding system in which investors are protected by specificity in the form of direct ownership to identifiable assets. Garrido, supra note 47, at 788. 86 UCC 8-504(b) (1994). 87 Insolvenzordnung (InsO), 5 October 1994 (BGB1. I S.2082) (F.R.G.) [hereinafter German Insolvency Code] § 47 provides that the securities are not part of the intermediary’s insolvency estate and must be returned to the customer. 88 IOSCO, 2013 Survey of Regimes for the Protection, Distribution and/or Transfer of Client Assets, Collated Responses to the Client Protection Survey, Germany, at 141, available at http://www.normativafinanciera.com/normafin/ hemero.nsf /0/3704d483226f67a9c1257b0f003322fe / $FILE/3%20-%20Appendix %20B%20 -% 20Collated%20Responses %20to %20the % 20Client % 20Asset %20 Protection%20Survey.pdf (last visited 9 December 2013). 89 Article 2(j–k) of the CEDEVAL Internal General Regulation defines ‘proprietary account’ and ‘account of a third party’. 90 OXERA, What Would be the Costs and Benefits of Changing the Competitive Structure of the Market for Trading and Post-Trading Services in 66 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts non-defaulting customers are unaffected and their securities may not be used to cover any shortfall.91 The Salvadoran CEDEVAL also maintains ‘nominative accounts’ for all investors. These investors must sign an agency agreement with a direct participant to represent them in dealings with CEDEVAL.92 The account operator thus satisfies its allocation duty by having the CSD open an individual-specific account for all investors to which their securities will be credited. In the case of a shortfall, if the claims of the intermediary’s customers may not be satisfied in full, they will be entitled to a proportional distribution and the resulting loss, or at least a portion thereof, will be covered by insurance.93 In addition to the laws and regulations, rules of the CSD and clearinghouses also provide for similar protections of customers’ rights to securities. Rule 2, Section 2.3 of the EuroCCP Rules expressly requires its participating intermediaries to deal with their house accounts separately from their client accounts. The proposed EU CSD Regulation goes even further in that it enables CSD participants to segregate accounts of each of their customers.94 This segregation at the customer level is not a requirement and therefore it is up to each CSD to decide whether to offer to keep such records for its participating intermediaries.95 In February 2013, the International Organization of Securities Commissions issued a consultation report entitled ‘Recommendations Regarding the Protection of Client Assets’ in which it set forth eight principles. Principle 1 requires intermediaries to maintain accurate and current records with respect to the client assets, including their nature, amount, location and ownership status. Allocation and segregation are the primary protection of customers’ rights. However, it may be the case that the intermediary fails to satisfy its allocation duty and does not maintain sufficient securities to satisfy all claims of its customers. Most jurisdictions provide additional protection Brazil?, 37 (June 2012), available at http://www.oxera.com/Oxera/media/Oxera/ downloads/reports/Report-1-Brazil.pdf?ext=.pdf (last visited 9 December 2013). 91 Best Brazil, supra note 13, at 54. 92 See CEDEVAL, Manual de Operaciones, supra note 34, at Capı́tulo I, Servicios y Participantes, C.2. 93 See Depotgesetz, § 32(3). 94 Explanatory Memorandum to the proposed Regulation on Improving Securities Settlement in the EU and on Central Securities Depositories (CSDs), available at http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=CELEX: 52012PC0073:EN:PDF (last visited 10 December 2013) at 8. Article 35(1) also provides that ‘… a CSD shall keep records … to distinguish … the securities of a participant from the securities of any other participant …’. 95 Ibid., art. 35(3). Securities account relationships 67 mechanisms in cases such as these. Primarily these mechanisms are designed in the form of compensation funds that cover losses up to a certain threshold. Some intermediaries offer their customers supplementary insurance beyond the statutory insurance cap.96 The US Securities Investor Protection Act created the Securities Investor Protection Corporation (SIPC) with the mandate to cover losses incurred by customers of securities intermediaries of up to US$ 500 000.97 Within the EU, Article 2(1) of the Directive 97/9/EC on Investor-Compensation Schemes mandates every Member State to establish at least one compensation scheme to cover the customer claims of up to € 20 000.98 The EU Commission recently proposed amendments to this Directive that would, amongst other changes, increase customer coverage to € 50 000.99 In Brazil, Article 76 of Instruction No. 461 issued by the Brazilian Securities and Exchange Commission provided the basis for the creation of a lossrecovery mechanism to cover any potential losses that might be incurred by investors due to the actions of, or omissions by, intermediaries.100 Edward H. Klees, How Safe Are Institutional Assets in a Custodial Bank’s Insolvency?, 68(1) BUS. LAW. 103, 120 (2012). 97 15 U.S.C. § 78aaa et seq. (2013). SIPC does not cover certain investments, including commodity futures contracts. In re MF Global Inc., 2013 Bankr. LEXIS 1578 *4 (S.D.N.Y. Bkrt. 2013). 98 Slovakian Securities Act § 87(2) provides that individual customer claims will be satisfied up to € 50 000. 99 See European Parliament Proposal for a Directive amending Directive 97/9/EC on Investor-compensation Schemes COM(2010)0371, at Recital 12. 100 Bovespa implemented this requirement in the form of the Investor Compensation Mechanism (MRP). OXERA, supra note 90, at 40. 96 3. Transfers of intermediated securities, finality and security interests One of the fundamental rights of account holders is to transfer their securities. Outright transfers, such as sales, are typically completed by book entries whereby the account of the transferor is debited and the account of the transferee is credited. However, book entries are equally utilized by creditors that receive credits of encumbered securities to their accounts. Both types of transfers are effectuated by intermediaries in the same way banks execute payment orders of their depositors. The purpose of this chapter is to analyse the mechanics of transfers and their effects on the rights of account holders. Transfer is an act that changes the owner or fragments the rights to the security. It is functionally equivalent to the delivery of an asset that occurs upon or after the conclusion of a purchase agreement. Transfer may be accomplished differently depending on the type of asset being transferred. Transfers of securities add an extra layer of complexity resulting from the various forms of the holding systems. On the one hand, while transfers of securities in a direct holding system may involve an issuer that registers the names of transferees and issues new certificates, transfers in intermediated holding systems do not require any entries on the issuer’s books.1 The common feature for transfers of all forms of securities, irrespective of the type of holding, is the assistance of the transferor who transmits an order to the intermediary to cause the security to be transferred.2 1 Marek Dubovec, Securities Holding Patterns and Their Impact on the Rights of Securities Holders: Lessons for Developing Nations, in LATIN AMERICAN COMPANY LAW: A COMPARATIVE AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT PERSPECTIVE, VOL. 1, 213, 225 (Boris Kozolchyk & Francisco Reyes eds., CAROLINA ACADEMIC PRESS, DURHAM, NC, 2013). 2 Egon Guttman, Investment Securities as Collateral, 36(3) U.C.C.L.J. 3, 12 (2004). 68 Transfers of intermediated securities 69 TRANSFERS OF INTERMEDIATED SECURITIES Given the intangible nature of securities held in accounts, it is not surprising that laws that regulate intermediated holding systems uniformly use the concept of transfer as opposed to the concept of delivery of possession.3 The book-entry transfer system for securities operates similarly to the system for transfers of funds between bank accounts.4 No items of property, such as written certificates or bank notes, change holders in either system. Instead the balance on the transferor’s account is reduced while a balance on the transferee’s account is increased. Book entries made to securities accounts substitute for the physical delivery of certificates and registration on the issuer’s books.5 The possession based negotiability title recognition system for security certificates has been replaced in intermediated systems by the records of intermediaries.6 The mechanics of book entries to accounts raises the question whether rights are transferred by negotiation or assignment.7 It has been argued that novation is the mechanism that transfers rights in a book-entry accounts system. Professor Rogers explained that: what matters is not the instruments themselves, but the abstract rights represented by the instruments, and that the objective is to design an effective system of title recognition for the abstract rights … there seems to be a general tendency to evolve away from the negotiability system in favor of various formal or informal systems relying not on possession of the instruments but on the records of financial institutions.8 3 Egon Guttman, Transfer of Securities: State and Federal Interaction, 12 CARDOZO L. REV. 437, 441 (1990). 4 Charles W. Mooney, Beyond Negotiability: A New Model for Transfer and Pledge of Interests in Securities Controlled by Intermediaries, 12 CARDOZO L. REV. 305, 403–4 (1990). 5 Luc Thévenoz, Intermediated Securities, Legal Risk, and the International Harmonization of Commercial Law, 13 STAN. J.L. BUS. & FIN. 384, 386 (2008). 6 James S. Rogers, Negotiability, Property, and Identity, 12 CARDOZO L. REV. 471, 485 (1990). 7 The Geneva Securities Convention does not take a position on the type of legal theory supporting transfers of intermediated securities by book entries nor does it provide that a book-entry transfer is accomplished by novation, assignment, negotiation, or otherwise. 8 James Steven Rogers, Negotiability as a System of Title Recognition, 48 OHIO ST. L.J. 197, 224 (1987). 70 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts Novation does not cause a transfer or passage of one investor’s rights to another. Instead, upon novation the transferee acquires a bundle of rights distinct from the bundle held by the transferor.9 The effects of book entries made at an intermediary level may differ in systems. In some systems, book entries made to securities accounts maintained by an intermediary will suffice to make the transfer effective between the transferor and transferee, as well as render it effective against third parties.10 No entries are required to be made to the accounts of any entity other than the relevant intermediary. Accordingly, the settlement system is decentralized in such systems.11 In other systems entries at the intermediary level are not sufficient to render the transfer effective against third parties.12 They become effective only upon a book entry made at the CSD level. Legislation, under which CSDs in these systems are constituted, typically includes in the list of the functions of the CSD the completion of transfers and perfections of security interests.13 Entries made by account operators do not constitute, transfer or novate any property rights in these systems.14 THE CONCEPTS OF FINALITY AND INDEPENDENCE Finality is crucial in many areas of commercial law, particularly those that involve sequels of credits and debits. The concept of finality may take on a variety of meanings not only of the legal type but also of the Official Comment 5 to UCC § 8-501 (1994). See UCC § 8-501(b) (1994). 11 JIABIN HUANG, THE LAW AND REGULATION OF CENTRAL COUNTERPARTIES 27 (HART PUBLISHING LTD., PORTLAND, OR, 2010). 12 CHANGMIN CHUN, CROSS-BORDER TRANSACTIONS OF INTERMEDIATED SECURITIES, A COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS IN SUBSTANTIVE LAW AND PRIVATE INTERNATIONAL LAW 118 (SPRINGER-VERLAG BERLIN HEIDELBERG, NEW YORK, NY, 2012). 13 See Slovakian Securities Act, § 22 and Salvadoran Law on Electronic Entries, art. 2(c). 14 In the EU, the Legal Certainty Group, which has been studying the possible harmonization of the substantive securities transfer laws, observed that: ‘the effects of a book entry by the intermediary are merely evidentiary or administrative and no title to the securities is acquired or disposed of’. Klaus Lober & Ulrik Rammeskow Bang-Pedersen, Legal Certainty Group, Subject 1 (‘book-entry securities’), Extract from the Draft Report: Validity of Credits, 5 (ECB, 13 November 2007). 9 10 Transfers of intermediated securities 71 purely technical type, such as the irreversibility of a book entry.15 One of the critical elements affecting the finality of transfers is their (in)dependence on other transfers involved in the related relationships. For instance, under one approach a debit entry to a securities account of the transferor may not be effective and final unless a corresponding credit entry is made to the account of the transferee. Under the opposite approach, the debit entry to the transferor’s account may become final even before a corresponding credit entry is made to the transferee’s account. Furthermore, the effectiveness, and thus finality, of the transfer may depend on the validity of the underlying transaction executed in the front-end. Consequently, in alternate systems the steps for transfers to become final will differ. In the systems where account relationships are independent from one another, finality applies to every single relationship between the account holder and his intermediary. Finality is internal to individual relationships. This may not be the case in the systems where the transfer is final only once the CSD has made a book entry.16 This is because the account operator’s book entry is merely administrative and thus incapable of providing finality.17 Here finality is external to account relationships because factors outside the particular account relationship, such as entries made by the CSD, affect finality. Finality of transfers inevitably impacts the rights of transferors who may not have actually authorized such transfers, did so mistakenly or who have been defrauded. In contemporary systems that transfer billions of securities on a daily basis, the unwinding of sequels of transactions due to some subsequently discovered defenses or errors could potentially destabilize their integrity and reliability. Instead of unwinding the entire chain of transfers, errors should be cured by corrective book entries between the two affected parties, a remedy already used in many systems.18 Corrective transfers restore the position of the account holder 15 HIDEKI KANDA, CHARLES MOONEY, LUC THÉVENOZ, STÉPHANE BÉRAUD, ASSISTED BY THOMAS KEIJSER, OFFICIAL COMMENTARY ON THE UNIDROIT CONVENTION ON SUBSTANTIVE RULES FOR INTERMEDIATED SECURITIES 169 (OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS, OXFORD, UK, 2012). 16 For Costa Rica see Reglamento del Sistema de Anotación en Cuenta, art. 1 & 9 [D.O. 198] (17 October 2006). 17 Klaus M. Lober & Ulrik Rammeskow Bang-Pedersen, supra note 14. 18 See CEDEVAL, Manual de Operaciones, Capı́tulo VI, Compensación y Liquidación de Valores, at A. Proceso de Liquidación, available at https:// www.cedeval.com/pdf/mop_cedeval.pdf (last visited 9 December 2013). This approach is also recommended by the EU Legal Certainty Group. See Hans Kuhn & Franziska Loew, Legal Certainty Group – Information about non-EU Legal Systems, MARKT/G2/MT/ccD (2005) 9489, 11 (25 January 2006). 72 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts prior to the unauthorized or ineffective book entry without disrupting the already executed chain of transfers. Independence is also crucial in the context of defenses and equities present in underlying contracts for the sale of securities and their impact on account relationships. Systems that allow such defenses to be raised against intermediaries undermine the finality of transfers, potentially compromising the entire integrity of the transfer system. The EU Legal Certainty Group observed that jurisdictions approach the interrelationship between the underlying transaction and its settlement by credits and debits to securities accounts from one of two different perspectives. Under the first approach an account relationship between the account holder and its intermediary is independent of the underlying transaction to purchase the security. Under the second approach the validity of the book entry is conditional or causal on the validity of the underlying contract. The first approach is the one that provides more predictability and certainty in securities transfer systems. SECURITIES AS COLLATERAL Securities are one of the most desirable collateral assets to secure loans due to their liquidity, the relative ease in their valuation and the efficient methods for their disposal upon default. The securities industry has developed two fundamental forms for using securities as collateral. First the creditor can take a security interest in the securities of the borrower who will remain the owner. Second the creditor and debtor may enter into a repurchase agreement whereby the creditor acquires title to the securities and assumes an obligation to transfer the securities back to the debtor at a higher price sometime in the future.19 This financing technique is also known as a repurchase or repo transaction.20 A repo involves two simultaneous transactions – the sale of the security and an agreement to repurchase it sometime in the future for the original In Europe, central banks of France and Belgium became heavy users of repos in early 1990s. See Collateral Initiatives Coordination Forum, Collateral Fluidity, A White Paper, at 4 (November 2012), available at http://www. icmagroup.org /assets /documents /Regulatory /CICF/Collateral-Fluidity-WP-7Nov 2012.pdf (last visited 9 December 2013). 20 The repo borrower pays a ‘repo rate’ which is a special form of interest rate. DERMOT TURING, CLEARING AND SETTLEMENT IN EUROPE 483 (BLOOMSBURY PROFESSIONAL, LTD., HAYWARDS HEATH, UK, 2012). 19 Transfers of intermediated securities 73 purchase price plus a pre-determined interest.21 Security interests and repurchase transactions may be collectively referred to as ‘collateral arrangements’.22 It should also be noted that creditors regularly prefer collateral in the form of bonds and other debt securities as opposed to equity securities whose market value is more volatile.23 The following paragraphs discuss the requirements to render collateral arrangements perfected, i.e., effective against third parties. Perfection of a security interest and its effectiveness against the world (erga omnes) presupposes a public notice of its existence. The purpose of providing public notice is to inform third parties about existing and potential encumbrances in the borrower’s assets.24 When dealing with securities, the creditor must be mindful of the various holding patterns and the applicable perfection requirements.25 Perfection by Control With the increase in dematerialization and intermediation, control has emerged as the relevant perfection mechanism for security interests in intermediated securities and securities accounts. In its function, control over intangible rights is similar to possession over tangible objects. The legal consequences of transferring possession and control to the creditor are the same – holders of possession or control enjoy the right to dispose of the underlying asset upon default of the debtor. As long as the creditor 21 In re Comark, 145 B.R. 47, 49 (9th Cir. BAP, 1992). See also CMN Resolution No.4040 (CMN Res.4040/2011), which amended CMN Resolution No. 3339 of 26 January 2006 (CMN Res. 3339/2006), governing repo operations (operações compromissadas) in Brazil, issued by the Brazilian Monetary Council (Conselho Monetário Nacional – CMN) and Walter Stuber & Adriana Maria Godel Stuber, Brazil: Bonds – Repo Operations, 27(7) J.I.B.L.R. 115 (2012). 22 See EU Financial Collateral Directive art. 2(1)(a) and Chapter V of the Geneva Securities Convention. The economic substance of both transactions is the same. Steven L. Schwarcz, Distorting Legal Principles, 35 J. CORP. L. 697, 719 (2010). 23 Joanna Benjamin, Securities Collateral, in THE REFORM OF UK PERSONAL PROPERTY SECURITY LAW: COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVES 223, 228 (John de Lacy ed., ROUTLEDGE, LONDON, UK, 2010). 24 For the types of interests that should be subject to public notice achieved by registration see Marek Dubovec, UCC Article 9 Registration System for Latin America, 28(1) A.J.I.C.L. 117, 118 (2011). 25 Dubovec, supra note 1, at 226. 74 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts is empowered to dispose of the collateral without further consent of the debtor it has control.26 However, under a possessory pledge, the debtor gives up access to the collateral and thus its productive use. Dispossession also protects the creditor’s interest because effectively the debtor is unable to transfer the collateral to a third party free of the security interest. While arguably providing a form of public notice, dispossession also provides an important measure of protection. Lack of possession by the debtor should raise a red flag and induce the third party to conduct further inquiry. With control, the security arrangement may be structured so that the debtor retains access to the collateral. Retention of access to encumbered securities under a security interest perfected by control rather than by public registration or delivery of possession may raise concerns with respect to insufficient public notice. As illustrated below, for this reason a number of economies do not recognize control as the functional equivalent of public registration and delivery of possession. Control may exist in two different forms – either absolute or shared.27 Under absolute control the debtor does not retain any rights to deal with the encumbered securities. A book entry indicating that the securities have been transferred to and are being held in the creditor’s account typically achieves this result. This type of control should not raise any public notice concerns as the debtor would not appear to be authorized to deal with the encumbered securities. Control is shared if the disposal rights are divided between the debtor and creditor. Despite sharing the disposal rights the creditor effectively acquires control and perfects its security interest as long as the execution of its disposal rights is not contingent upon the debtor’s consent; that is, the intermediary is obligated to execute the creditor’s disposition orders without obtaining further consent from the debtor. Control agreements typically achieve this result and no book credit entry needs to be made to the creditor’s 26 Official Comment 1 to UCC 8-106 (1994) and RONALD C.C. CUMING, CATHERINE WALSH & RODERICK J. WOOD, ESSENTIALS OF CANADIAN LAW, PERSONAL PROPERTY SECURITY LAW 223 (IRWIN LAW INC., TORONTO, ONTARIO, 2005). Negative control in the form of contractual restrictions imposed on the borrower to dispose of the securities may not be sufficient to perfect a security interest. Ben McFarlane & Robert Stevens, Interests in Securities, Practical Problems and Conceptual Solutions, in INTERMEDIATED SECURITIES, LEGAL PROBLEMS AND PRACTICAL ISSUES 46 (Louise Gullifer & Jennifer Payne eds., HART PUBLISHING LTD., OXFORD, UK, 2010). 27 For a further discussion of the typology of control see Benjamin, supra note 23, at 223, 259, who distinguished positive and negative control that may exist in the form of either legal or operational control. Transfers of intermediated securities 75 account. This is the type of control that may raise public notice issues because there is neither a transfer of securities to the creditor’s account nor public registration. To achieve absolute control encumbered securities may be transferred by a book entry to the creditor’s securities account or to a special collateral account.28 They may also be flagged as encumbered by a designating entry but remain in the debtor’s securities account. The designating entry is contemplated in the Geneva Securities Convention under which the intermediary effectively earmarks certain securities in the borrower’s account as being subject to a security interest.29 Such a designation or earmark will also be indicated on any statements and other documentation related to the account.30 All of these three types of book entries should provide sufficient public notice to third parties. In those systems where entries made by intermediaries have constitutive effects and convey property interests, security interests may be perfected by the intermediary’s entry itself.31 Involvement of the relevant intermediary is sufficient to render the collateral arrangement perfected without any action of the CSD or the issuer. Therefore whether or not control has been validly created will be determined only from the relationship between the debtor, his intermediary and the creditor. This type of perfection is similar to that utilized for goods stored in a warehouse whereby the bailee issues a warehouse receipt or acknowledges receipt of goods and their holding for the creditor. In contrast, in other systems where intermediaries’ entries only have administrative effects, security interests must be perfected at the CSD level where the book entries constitute and transfer rights.32 Whether or not control has been validly constituted will depend on factors outside the debtorintermediary-creditor relationship, such as an action of the CSD.33 28 In German practice, securities of the debtor are typically transferred to a special account for pledged securities. CHUN, supra note 12, at 187–8. 29 The draft EU Securities Law Directive provides for earmarking as the special method of disposing of account-based securities, including the creation of security interests. TURING, supra note 20, at 231. 30 However, third parties should not rely on account statements that are essentially snapshots of the state of affairs at a particular point in time and the account affairs may have changed subsequent to its issuance. KANDA, MOONEY, THÉVENOZ & BÉRAUD, supra note 15, at 24. 31 UCC 8-106(d)(1) (1994). 32 See Slovakian Securities Act, § 45(2). 33 Comments of the Brazilian Delegation to the Working Group on so called Transparent Systems (March 2007), available at http://www.unidroit.org/english/ 76 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts Shared control is typically established pursuant to an agreement among the account holder, his intermediary and the creditor.34 Professor Guttman explained that a control agreement does not transfer mere trading authority to the creditor but it transfers a limited property right in the form of a security interest to the creditor.35 Trading authority may remain vested with the debtor. Control agreements are typically trilateral in nature, binding the debtor, the creditor and the intermediary that maintains the debtor’s securities account.36 Under US law, the control agreement does not bind the intermediary unless it has become a party to such an agreement.37 The intermediary is not obligated to enter into a control agreement even if requested by the account holder. Similarly, the intermediary may not do so on its own unless requested by the account holder.38 A trilateral control agreement subject to US law typically provides that ‘The intermediary will not change the name or number of the Account … without the prior written consent of Creditor. Intermediary will send copies of all statements and confirmations concerning the Account to each Debtor and Creditor … .’39 The key obligation of the intermediary assumed in a control agreement is to abide by instructions as to the disposition of the securities submitted by the creditor without further consent of the debtor. documents/2007/study78/s-78-062-e.pdf (last visited 9 December 2013) and Slovakian Securities Act, § 50(2-3). 34 See Geneva Securities Convention, art. 1. 35 EGON GUTTMAN, MODERN SECURITIES TRANSFERS, § 5:5 (3rd edn., THOMSON WEST, BOSTON, MA, 2007). 36 The intermediary will not be a party to the security agreement that remains a private matter between the debtor and the creditor. 37 First National Bank of Palmerton v. Donaldson, Lufkin & Jenrette Securities Corp., 1999 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 3275 *9 (E. Dis. Pen., 1999). United Hudson Bank v. PNC Bank New England, 2006 Conn. Super. LEXIS 255, *5 (Superior Court of Connecticut, Judicial Dist. of Stamford-Norwalk at Stamford, 2006). Delivery of the security agreement or an assignment agreement purporting to create a security interest in the securities to the relevant intermediary is not sufficient to perfect a security interest. In re Jerimiah L. Richards, 336 B.R. 722, 729 (East. D. Vir. Richmond Div. 2004). The court also rejected the argument that delivery of the financing document to the intermediary amounts to the creation of an equitable lien. Ibid., at 730. Similarly, a power of attorney granted to the secured creditor to act in the name of the account holder is not sufficient to perfect a security interest by control under UCC. See Official Comment 5 to UCC 8-106 (1994). 38 UCC 8-106(g) (1994). 39 Sandra M. Rocks, Securities Account Control Agreement, SL051 ALIABA 513, 518 (2005). Transfers of intermediated securities 77 The Geneva Securities Convention allows bilateral agreements and notices thereof to bind the intermediary, recognizing that such collateral arrangements are valid in many jurisdictions.40 The UCC approach is protective of the rights of intermediaries but arguably at the expense of account holders, who may not be able to utilize their securities as collateral unless the intermediary becomes a party to a control agreement. In contrast, the Geneva Securities Convention effectively renders intermediaries the deciders of priorities as they will have to determine in which order notices of control were received. An approach that requires a trilateral control agreement but that limits the intermediary’s right to refuse to become a party to such an agreement would balance the interests of all parties involved. Many secured transactions laws permit the debtor to use assets while encumbered by a perfected security interest primarily for economic reasons.41 However such laws do so at the expense of the creditor having to provide sufficient public notice, such as by registration. In some economies publicity of the security interest achieved through the intermediary may not be adequate and comparable to that of registration. As a result, only a form of absolute control is available. This is particularly the case in those jurisdictions that are yet to recognize non-possessory security interests in general. In these jurisdictions, the control agreement contradicts the fundamental requirements for publicity of security interests because the debtor ostensibly remains the owner or retains the right to deal with the collateral. The argument follows that an inquiry with an intermediary is not as transparent as registration in a publicly available registry. Even under the EU Financial Collateral Directive it remains questionable whether control required for perfection of a collateral arrangement could be satisfied by entering into an agreement that leaves the disposal rights with the debtor. In other economies, intermediaries’ records serve as a functional equivalent of a public registry. The role of the intermediary is functionally no different than that of warehousemen, carriers and other entities that issue representative documents of title that their holders use as collateral. Book entries and control agreements are typically utilized in transactions where a third-party lender provides secured credit. Alternatively the intermediary may also provide financing to its account holders and such loans are common in practice. Account holders utilize these loans KANDA, MOONEY, THÉVENOZ & BÉRAUD, supra note 15, at 24. See EU Financial Collateral Directive, art. 5(1)(4) and UCC 8-106(f) (1994). 40 41 78 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts especially for the acquisition of new securities. In the securities industry such securities are known as purchased on margin and the credit provided by the intermediary is known as a margin loan.42 In a margin transaction the account holder does not pay the entire purchase price for the securities and uses the credit provided by his intermediary.43 The intermediary thus functions as an entity that maintains accounts for their customers as well as a creditor that provides purchase money financing to account holders. In the latter case the intermediary uses the purchased securities as collateral to secure the margin loan that it extended to the customer. Under some laws,44 such security interests of intermediaries are perfected automatically and the intermediary is not required to register a public notice or enter into a special collateral/control agreement with the customer.45 The securities purchased on margin and those that have been fully paid for by the customer must be segregated by the intermediary. Segregation of such securities prevents the intermediary from using fully paid for securities in its own business, including securing the intermediary’s own loans. For margin securities the intermediary will typically request an authorization to re-pledge the same securities.46 Third Kenneth C. Kettering, Repledge and Pre-Default Sale of Securities Collateral Under Revised Article 9, 74 CHI.-KENT L. REV. 1109, 1112 (1999). The securities margin lending market may be driven either by borrowers who seek specific securities to satisfy their settlement obligations and to cover short positions, or by lenders who seek to obtain funding by using securities as collateral. Rasiah Gengatharen, Margin Loans: Secured Credit or Secured Lending, 23(11) J.I.B.L.R. 595, 596 (2008). 43 The intermediary, in turn, would typically obtain a loan from a third party securing that loan by repledge of its customers’ margin securities. Ibid.; Kettering, supra note 42, at 1115–16. As of the end of March 2013, the margin debt at NYSE member firms stood at US$ 379.5 billion which was just shy of the record set in July 2007. Alexandra Scaggs & Steven Russolillo, Investors Rediscovering Margin Debt, WALL STREET JOURNAL C 1-2 (10 May 2013). 44 UCC 9-206(a–b) and 9-309(10) (1999), UCC 8-106(e) (1994) and Official Comment 6 to UCC 8-106 (1994). 45 On the risks and costs created by automatic perfection see Schwarcz, supra note 22. 46 NYSE Rule 402(b). Customer Protection – Reserves and Custody of Securities, SEC Rule 8c-1 and Rule 15c2-1, and Depotgesetz art. 12(1). See also 17 C.F.R. § 240.8c-1 (2012) and Explanatory Memorandum to the EU Financial Collateral Directive, Section 2.4 and Recital 19, and the US Supreme Court decision in Provost v. United States, 269 U.S. 443, 454 (1925) recognizing the power and authority of the intermediary to re-pledge the customer’s margin securities, to the extent of the advances made by the intermediary. On the 42 Transfers of intermediated securities 79 parties will find out about the encumbrance by inquiring with the intermediary. Again in some economies this arrangement may raise the issue of sufficient public notice similar to that described in relation to a control agreement. Perfection by Filing Many jurisdictions have devised mechanisms that allow creditors to perfect their security interest other than by control.47 The Geneva Securities Convention recognizes non-control perfection mechanisms but it does provide for the priority of security interests perfected by one of the Convention recognized mechanisms.48 This priority provided to the control-type of perfection mechanisms reflects the market practice in some economies where creditors seldom utilize filing or central registration to perfect their security interests. Other jurisdictions operate special registries solely for the purpose of registering documents that create collateral interests in account-based securities.49 Such specialized registries typically require registration of both consensual security interests and non-consensual liens that remain ineffective against third parties unless properly registered.50 While arguably this form of perfection provides sufficient public notice, the registration procedure in these jurisdictions is typically cumbersome. A registration form must commonly be accompanied by a written confirmation regarding the content of the security agreement that is signed by both the debtor and the creditor.51 Similarly, a request to register a statutory lien must be accompanied by a valid decision establishing the lien.52 Furthermore public notice is not provided by registration but rather by transferring the encumbered securities to a pledge account and stripping the borrower of disposal rights. This is because registries of this kind (e.g., in El Salvador) are not typically accessible to the public. consequences of the Lehman failure on the rehypothecation costs see Schwarcz, supra note 22, at 710. 47 See also Geneva Securities Convention, art. 13. 48 Ibid. art. 19(2). 49 See Slovakian Securities Act § 45(1–2) that mandates the CSD to maintain a lien register and CEDEVAL, Manual de Operaciones, supra note 18, at Capı́tulo I, Gravámenes, Embargos y Prendas Reglamento, Section I. 50 Slovakian Securities Act § 47(1). 51 Ibid. 52 Ibid., § 52(2). 80 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts While registration may be a useful perfection mechanism it should not be made subject to onerous requirements. One may contrast the requirements imposed by UCC Article 9 and the law of El Salvador. A security interest in intermediated securities held by CEDEVAL becomes perfected when the following four conditions have been cumulatively satisfied: 1) 2) a security agreement is concluded in a notarized public deed; such security agreement is delivered to the CSD that registers it under the respective securities account; the intermediated securities granted as collateral are transferred to a securities account maintained for the creditor; and finally the CSD transmits a notice of the security interest to the stock exchange where the security is listed.53 3) 4) In contrast, under UCC 9, only a one-page financing statement must be filed with the relevant office. One of the primary objectives of the EU Financial Collateral Directive was to reduce the formalities necessary for the creation, perfection and enforcement of collateral arrangements. To this end, Recital 10 of the Directive provides that ‘execution of documents in a particular form, notarization or other formal validation of the document, a filing with an official body or registration in a public register should not be required in the EU Member States’. Nevertheless implementation of the Directive in Member States varies and interested parties should examine the applicable local law to determine which formalities are required.54 While the trend in EU countries is to move away from requiring excessive formalities this does not yet seem to be the case in Latin America. The contemporary pattern of holding securities through electronic accounts necessitates the enactment of rules facilitating the efficient perfection of security interests. See Salvadoran Law on Electronic Entries, arts 36 and 41. Ewa Klima, The Implementation of Directive 2002/47 on Financial Collateral Arrangements, 21(4) J.I.B.L.R. 203, 207 (2006). 53 54 4. Summary of Part I Securities transfer law is an area of commercial private law that regulates the holding and transferring of securities including the creation of encumbrances. All of these processes occur in the back-end environment subsequent to the execution of a trade with securities within particular securities holding systems that may be classified on the basis of relationships into the direct and intermediated holding systems. The latter exist in a number of varieties. This Part focused primarily on analyzing the distinctive features of intermediated holding systems. Rights and duties of market players participating in contemporary securities holding systems should be clearly set out in a legislative framework that addresses, at a minimum, the following features and functions. Securities no longer circulate in the form of certificates but are immobilized at CSDs and transferred by entries to electronic accounts maintained by intermediaries. Accordingly, laws must recognize the validity of securities maintained in accounts with intermediaries and provide such accounts with legal effects equivalent to those for certificated, bearer and uncertificated securities. As Professor Goode writes, ‘in most countries the law has yet to catch up with these developments’.1 This lack of appropriate legal regulation perpetuates the risk of legal uncertainty.2 Securities transfer laws have been moving away from an approach based on the nature of security (certificated vs. uncertificated) to one based on the type of holding (intermediated vs. direct).3 The key feature of securities held in intermediated systems is their capability of being 1 Roy Goode, Foreword to INTERMEDIATED SECURITIES, LEGAL PROBLEMS AND PRACTICAL ISSUES (Louise Gullifer & Jennifer Payne eds., HART PUBLISHING LTD., OXFORD, UK, 2010). 2 Louise Gullifer, Ownership of Securities, The Problems Caused by Intermediation, in INTERMEDIATED SECURITIES, LEGAL PROBLEMS AND PRACTICAL ISSUES 5 (Louise Gullifer & Jennifer Payne eds., HART PUBLISHING LTD., OXFORD, UK, 2010). 3 Sandra M. Rocks & Penelope L. Christophorou, Memorandum Regarding the Uniform Version of Article 8 of the Uniform Commercial Code and the Treatment of Investment Property under the Uniform Version of Article 9 (with 81 82 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts credited to a securities account. Legislation governing modern securities holding systems should provide for a broad category of financial assets and securities that may be held in such accounts. Susceptibility of being credited to a securities account, coupled with the ability to objectively determine the market value of the security, should be the only requirements for the holding of securities in accounts with intermediaries. Legislation should facilitate the holding of securities both directly and through intermediaries as these two securities holding patterns co-exist with each other. A difficult question arises when the legislator is presented with a choice of the type of intermediated holding system. The role of the legislator is to select the appropriate holding structure most suitable for their particular domestic market. So far countries have been divided. Common-law countries and Quebec have implemented indirect holding systems based on new property concepts embedded in securities. However, the majority of economies still adhere to the transparent pattern for the holding of intermediated securities that relies on traditional proprietary concepts such as co-ownership. Intermediated holding systems are supported by modern and highly efficient clearing and settlement systems that apply novation and netting. These functions may not be necessary if the volume of transactions and the risk of a systemic catastrophe are negligible. Yet efficient settlement systems that complete transfers of securities in exchange of funds on a DVP basis should be implemented in all systems, irrespective of transactional volumes. One of the most important tasks for the legislator is to define properly the property right of investors who hold their securities in accounts with intermediaries. In contemporary intermediated systems investors no longer enjoy identifiable ownership rights to the security. The departure from direct rights against the issuer necessitates a redefinition of the rights embedded in securities held in accounts. These rights have been cast as co-ownership interests, joint possession, security entitlements, etc. The common denominator for all these classifications is the proprietary interest that is granted to account holders. The bottom-line rule is that rights of account holders in all systems must be protected by proprietary interests. Addenda Regarding Book-Entry Regulations and International Developments), SK090 ALI-ABA 249, 252 (2005). Summary of Part I 83 Once the rights are adequately defined, legislation should provide for an effective mechanism for their constitution and transfer. In an intermediated holding system, rights of investors are constituted by entries made to securities accounts and evidenced by balances on such accounts. There is a significant difference between various types of intermediated holding systems with respect to the nature of securities accounts. While accounts maintained by relevant intermediaries in some systems are the source of rights and the intermediaries’ entries transfer rights to securities, accounts maintained by operators in other systems have mere administrative functions and their entries do not constitute or transfer rights. Legislation should also provide for efficient transfer mechanisms. In intermediated holding systems securities are customarily transferred by book entries, and such transfers should provide the same legal effect as delivery of a certificate and registration on the issuer’s books. Legislation should also recognize that book entries transfer rights to securities by novation effectively replacing negotiation as the primary transfer mechanism. Many jurisdictions already recognize novation as a transfer mechanism for intangible rights. An explicit reference in securities transfer laws may be necessary to provide clarity for transfers effectuated by book entries. Finality is also an important concept underlying contemporary securities transfer systems. Efficient systems for transfers of securities must be supported by clear and predictable rules on finality. The speed and volume of transactions with securities requires that transferees be able to rely on the credits made to their accounts. Legislators may find the rules governing the finality of payments useful as a guideline. Typically, the finality of transfer coincides with the credit entry made by the intermediary to the transferee’s account. Legislators should refrain from crafting rules that postpone the occurrence of finality beyond making a book entry. Account holders should be able to rely on book entries made to their accounts without being concerned that the entry might be later cancelled and their rights revoked. Lastly, legislation governing accounts holding structures should provide for effective rules on using intermediated securities as collateral. In this new environment, the concept of control has replaced possession, delivery and registration as the principal perfection mechanism. Perfection of a security interest by control requires that the creditor be placed in a position to exercise disposal rights over the securities without any further consent of the debtor. Many jurisdictions rely on the traditional methods of perfecting security interests that require absolute disposition of the debtor. Access to financing secured with intermediated securities is 84 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts further hindered, in some jurisdictions, by onerous formalities such as notarization of the security agreement and its delivery to the CSD. Legislation in developing countries should remove as many formalities as appropriate and thus reduce the cost of credit. Modernization of securities transfers systems and recognition of account-based relationships is important to attract foreign investors. These investors may be reluctant to buy securities when faced with onerous requirements, formalities, excessive costs and legal uncertainty in general. A legal system providing for a modern securities holding structure would benefit the economy and entice foreign capital to local markets. Otherwise local markets that are isolated and characterized by negligible trading volumes will likely remain illiquid and will thus fail to provide an efficient source of financing. Harmonization of securities transfer laws on the basis of the Geneva Securities Convention and the eventual ratification of the Convention itself would provide more clarity and certainty than reliance on conflict of law rules.4 4 Gabriel Moss, Intermediated Securities: Issues Arising from Insolvency, in INTERMEDIATED SECURITIES, LEGAL PROBLEMS AND PRACTICAL ISSUES 61, 68 (Louise Gullifer & Jennifer Payne eds., HART PUBLISHING LTD., OXFORD, UK, 2010). PART II Bank Account Relationships 5. Introduction to Part II Money is a human creation. It originated in the form of metals and coins and now exists and circulates in the form of banknotes and bank deposits. Like the systems for transferring securities examined in Part I, the systems for transferring money have undergone a significant transformation. Contemporary money transfer systems no longer rely on physical delivery of cash but now rely on electronic entries to deposit accounts maintained by intermediaries. The holding system for money is intermediated and largely electronic. Promises to deliver securities, transfer money or offset commodity contracts may be analyzed in the context of the front-end and back-end environments. Similar to Part I of this book on securities account relationships, this Part also does not deal with front-end transactions that result in money transfers, such as the sale of goods. The functioning of modern commercial societies requires that monetary value be transferred expeditiously, efficiently and at a reasonably low cost. All contemporary payment devices such as funds transfers, letters of credit, negotiable instruments and credit cards share an important feature: a device used (e.g., payment order, check, debit card, etc.) only represents an obligation or promise to pay and is not the money itself. When someone accepts a negotiable instrument or agrees to be paid by a letter of credit he does not acquire any money in the legal sense. The law deems only coins and banknotes authorized by the government as money. However, it is monetary obligations and promises that are at the core of contemporary payments systems.1 These obligations and promises circulate in the marketplace in the form of debits and credits to deposit accounts. Sections included in this chapter are concerned with the transformation of payments effectuated by physical transfers of monetary objects, such as the delivery of banknotes into electronic funds transfers completed by book entries to bank accounts. Various types of money are identified and contrasted including everything from actual money, such as coins and 1 LINDA J. RUSCH, PAYMENT SYSTEMS, PROBLEMS, MATERIALS, AND CASES 1 (2nd edn., WEST GROUP, ST. PAUL, MN, 2003). 87 88 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts banknotes, to bank money, which is essentially balances on deposit accounts. Once this historical and technological transformation is illustrated, the focus of this Part will shift to examine the legal infrastructure of the back-end systems in which these funds circulate. In the words of Ben Bernanke, both ‘the hardware’, i.e., the organizational infrastructure, and ‘the software’, i.e., the legal framework of funds transfer systems, are examined. Contemporary back-end systems for the holding of money are intermediated and similar to securities accounts holding systems in that they are structured as pyramids with a central entity at the top. However the nature of rights granted to account holders is uniform across jurisdictions and as such it is not necessary to classify money holding systems into various categories. In other words, all deposit account holders, no matter their jurisdiction, are granted contractual rights enforceable against their depository institutions. As in the case of holding systems for and transfers of securities, on the international level rules regarding payments are included in the United Nations Commission on International Trade Law (UNCITRAL) Model Law on International Credit Transfers (UNCITRAL Model Law).2 However, the UNCITRAL Model Law has not fulfilled its aspiration to become the basis for future legislation in the area of funds transfers and is yet to be implemented by any jurisdiction. Similar to securities accounts holding systems, there is no effective international regime to govern the holding and transfers of money. However, contemporary money holding systems exhibit similar features in terms of legal rights as well as functions provided therein. The enormous growth of funds transfers deserves not only the attention of legislators but also regulators. High-value funds transfers may pose systemic risks that central banks and other regulators must take into account, and implement adequate safeguards against.3 Like securities accounts systems, any legal reform considered should address systemic 2 UN Communication on International Trade Law, UNCITRAL Model Law on International Credit Transfers, UN Doc. A/RES/47/34, (1992), available at http: // www.uncitral.org / pdf / english/texts / payments / transfers /ml-credittrans.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013) [hereinafter UNCITRAL Model Law]. 3 One of the objectives of the Slovakian National Bank is to contain systemic risk. See the National Bank of Slovakia, Payment System Oversight in the Slovak Republic, 5 (2003), available at http://www.nbs.sk/en/paymentsystems/oversight/business-continuity (last visited 11 December 2013). In 2002, the Central Bank of Brazil restructured its LVFTS with the objective to reduce systemic risk. Best Brazil, Brazil Market Profile, 36 (February 2012), available Introduction to Part II 89 risk. The failure of an important banking institution that maintains deposit accounts and executes payment orders for thousands of customers may have a negative impact on the entire economy, particularly within financial markets. Without banks and their payment services an enormous number of commercial transactions will not be completed. Proper management of risk in the bank accounts holding system is also critical for the functioning and completion of transfers in securities and commodity accounts systems. This Part seeks to explain the fundamental concepts underlying bank accounts systems such as: the nature of the rights of depositors against banks; the functions provided by central entities; the form of settlement; the modes of transfers and their legal nature as compared to traditional transfers initiated by the deposit of checks; the finality of payment; and the creation of security interests in funds deposited in bank accounts. While Part I focused primarily on the explanation of the fundamental concepts underlying securities accounts systems this Part assumes that the reader already understands the key concepts underlying bank accounts systems. With this assumption in mind the discussion focuses predominantly on the concepts that differentiate bank accounts and securities accounts systems. PROTOTYPICAL TRANSACTION As in the other two Parts of this book it may be useful to illustrate and distinguish between front-end transactions and back-end holding systems. Suppose that Brian’s US company wants to market high-quality shoes manufactured in Italy. He has located a manufacturer of shoes in Italy, Silvio, and signed a distribution agreement to supply the shoes to retail stores. A sale contract between Brian and Silvio for the shoes is a front-end trade. It is a transaction that involves a contract between the two parties that also regulates transportation, insurance and provides for the issuance of various certificates of quality, quantity and origin. Brian orders the first container with 1000 boxes of shoes for US$ 50 000 and flies to Milan to meet Silvio in his office. Brian brings a briefcase with US$ 50 000 in cash. In exchange, Silvio provides Brian with a bill of lading confirming shipment of the shoes. This delivery of the bill of lading against the banknotes is a back-end function. This deal involves: 1) a transaction, an agreement to buy the shoes for a certain price and 2) at http://www.bestbrazil.org.br/media/Market%20Profile.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013). 90 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts its settlement, the delivery of the bill of lading against banknotes. Only the seller and buyer are involved. Presently very few people would even think of doing business this way and instead would use the following model. After completing his first order, Brian orders his bank to ‘wire’ US$ 50 000 to Silvio. The bank executes Brian’s order by a debit to his bank account and a credit to a bank account of Silvio’s bank. For one bank to credit an account of another bank, they must maintain a correspondent banking relationship. More commonly, Brian’s bank will route its payment order through a central payments system and Silvio’s bank will credit his deposit account. As illustrated, the back-end functions may involve transfers of tangible assets, such as banknotes, or transfers of intangible assets, such as funds held in bank accounts. Settlement of the obligation to pay by transferring intangible assets involves the relationships between Brian and his bank and Silvio and his bank. This form of payment is no longer a bilateral transaction in which the buyer delivers cash to the seller. Contemporary payments are accomplished within relationships between banks and their account holders in practically all economies with large-value payment systems. While structurally (the ‘hardware’) large-value payment systems in both developed and developing countries are comparable, they differ in terms of the legal infrastructure (the ‘software’). The US legal infrastructure for funds transfers is more developed and elaborate than in the rest of the world, which still relies on the law of deposit to regulate the transfer of funds. This Part will reference jurisdictions representative of different systems in terms of size and transactional complexity. The US Fedwire is the world’s largest electronic payments system that operates on a real-time gross settlement (RTGS) basis. In 2011, the average daily value of payments routed through Fedwire was US$ 2.6 trillion.4 The net settlement system and the RTGS system are the two main types of central payment systems. Their respective features and functions are explained below. In some countries, such as Brazil and the United States, both systems co-exist. The second point of comparison will be the payments system of the EU. The EU has adopted a number of legal measures to regulate funds transfers binding the Member States. The Eurosystem operates TARGET2 (Trans-European Automated Real-time Gross Settlement Express Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 98th Annual Report, 136 (2011), available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/publications/annualreport/files/2011-annual-report.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013). 4 Introduction to Part II 91 Transfer), which is an RTGS system for transfers of funds denominated in euros. In 2011 the average daily total value transferred was €2.3 trillion.5 EURO1 is the main net settlement system for intra-European transfers and as of March 2013 its daily volume averaged at €210 billion in transferred funds.6 In Latin America, the systems of Brazil, Costa Rica and Mexico will be the main reference points for this Part. Brazil operates both an RTGS (Sistema de Transferência de Reservas (STR)) and a net settlement system. On 30 January 2013, the STR settled approximately US$ 294 billion in payments, which is indicative of its daily settlement volumes.7 SITRAF (Sistema de Transferência de Fundos) is the other Brazilian payments system that became operational in December 2002. SITRAF is a hybrid settlement system operated on the basis of a continuous net settlement whose daily average value of payments in December 2012 was the equivalent of US$ 6.8 billion.8 The Central Bank of Costa Rica operates the RTGS system SINPE (El Sistema Nacional de Pagos Electrónicos). However, daily statistics of the SINPE are not available to compare with the other systems mentioned above.9 Finally, the Central Bank of Mexico operates an RTGS known under the acronym SPEI (Sistema de Pagos Electrónicos Interbancarios). In 2013, the average daily value of payments for SPEI was approximately US$ 680 billion.10 5 ECB, Target2 (October 2012), available at http://www.ecb.eu/paym/pdf/ Sibos_2012_Target2.pdf?8189c51bc95919d6c07c8b63b82fb196 (last visited 11 December 2013). 6 EBA Clearing, Statistics on EURO1/STEP1, available at https://www. ebaclearing.eu/Statistics-on-EURO1%2fSTEP1-N=E1_Statistics-L=EN.aspx (last visited 11 December 2013). 7 Banco Central do Brasil, Sistema de Pagamentos Brasileiro – SPB, available at http://www.bcb.gov.br/pom/spb/ing/evoldiariaPlanx_i.asp (last visited 11 December 2013). 8 Banco Central do Brasil, Statistical Data, available at http://www.bcb. gov.br/Pom/Spb/Ing/cip_i.asp?idpai=PAYSYSDATA (last visited 11 December 2013). 9 Banco Central de Costa Rica, Estadı́sticas de Servicios en SINPE, available at http://www.bccr.fi.cr/sistema_pagos/estadisticas/ (last visited 11 December 2013). 10 Banco de México, Sistemas de Pago, available at http://www.banxico. org.mx/SieInternet/consultarDirectorioInternetAction.do?accion=consultarCuadro &idCuadro=CF252&sector=5&locale=es (last visited 11 December 2013). 92 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts BRIEF EVOLUTION OF MONEY While the understanding of money and its various forms and functions is important to introduce the ensuing discussion, an understanding of deposit relationships is also critical to the analysis of modern bank account relationships. The historical overview that follows highlights some of the key developments in the history of transactions with money and traces the emergence of deposit accounts. Traditionally, money has been defined by identifying its functions, including those of: 1) 2) a medium of exchange;11 a unit of account that expresses the value of obligations or commodities; and a storage of economic value.12 3) Since early commercial societies, all of these functions have been performed by a variety of assets, including commodities, metals, coins, negotiable instruments, banknotes and balances on deposit accounts. Some of these ‘money-like assets’ have already become obsolete (e.g., commodities), while others are slowly falling into disuse (e.g., checks). One may trace the earliest signs of money and deposits to the era of Hammurabi. In this period, deposit banking as we know it today did not exist. Instead, a deposit relationship existed in the form of safekeeping, whereby depository institutions accepted assets for deposit and agreed to restore them upon demand of the depositor in specie.13 In other words, deposited assets had to remain readily identifiable, segregated, and could not be commingled. Additionally, the exact same asset had to be returned on demand. Depositors retained ownership of the deposited assets, and Cox highlighted that the legal conception of the medium of exchange function is narrower than the economist’s because it is concerned primarily with the performance and discharge of obligations. David Cox, The Case of Mixed Monies: Confirming Nominalism in the Common Law of Monetary Obligations, 70 CAMBRIDGE L.J. 144 (2011). 12 DAVID COX, PROPERTY RIGHTS IN MONEY 7–9 (OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS, OXFORD, UK, 2008). What distinguishes money from all other objects of trade is its function as a medium of exchange and the functions derived therefrom. See also Carl Menger, Money, translated by Leland B. Yager with Monika Streissler in CARL MENGER AND THE EVOLUTION OF PAYMENTS SYSTEMS, FROM BARTER TO ELECTRONIC MONEY 38 (Michael Latzer & Stefan W. Schmitz eds., EDWARD ELGAR PUB., CHELTENHAM, UK, 2002). 13 SIDNEY HOMER & RICHARD SYLLA, A HISTORY OF INTEREST RATES 29 (4th edn., WILEY, HOBOKEN, NJ, 2005). 11 Introduction to Part II 93 their relationship against the safekeepers was that of bailor(s) and bailee(s). The bailor remained the owner and the bailee acquired mere possession without the right to use or commingle the assets. Modern banking in its early form did not emerge in Greece14 and Rome until the fifth and fourth century BC respectively.15 Unlike the Hammurabi-era deposit, which was in fact a safekeeping relationship based on ownership, Roman law introduced another type of deposit, which allowed commingling and imposed a duty on depository institutions to return deposited assets of an equivalent value. Under this type of deposit the restitution in specie was not required. Roman law16 recognized two types of deposit contracts: 1) regular and 2) irregular. Under the regular deposit the depository institution acquired the right of possession while the depositor retained ownership. Since the depository did not acquire ownership to the deposited asset, as current banks do with respect to funds, it was not allowed to use the deposited object.17 The relationship between the bailor and bailee was based on ownership. Professor Watson argued that with respect to money and the evolution of banking, regular deposit took money out of circulation and hampered the credit function.18 Roman law also recognized another type of deposit that did not require restoration in specie – the irregular deposit.19 Under the irregular deposit once possession of an asset such as money passed to the depository so did the ownership right thereto. By virtue of that passage of ownership the depository acquired the right to commingle and re-use the deposited object. Consequently, the depositor–depository institution relationship 14 The Greek bankers were known as ‘trapezites’ whose main function was to verify the value of coins: JEAN ANDREAU, BANKING AND BUSINESS IN THE ROMAN WORLD 36 (CAMBRIDGE UNIVERSITY PRESS, CAMBRIDGE, UK, 2004). 15 Ibid. 16 Roman law recognized four types of real contracts: 1) mutuum, 2) commodatum, 3) pignus and 4) depositum. These real contracts became binding as of the moment of the transfer of a thing. Accordingly, only movable things could be made subject to the real contracts, such as the Roman law depositum. J.A.C. THOMAS, TEXTBOOK OF ROMAN LAW 271 (ELSEVIER SCIENCE & TECHNOLOGY BOOKS, PHILADELPHIA, PA, 1976). 17 Ibid., at 276. In Greece, the regular deposit was confined to non-financial transactions that involved deposits of legal documents and valuables. See EDWARD E. COHEN, ATHENIAN ECONOMY AND SOCIETY: A BANKING PERSPECTIVE 113 (PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS, PRINCETON, NJ, 1992). 18 ALLAN WATSON, ANCIENT LAW AND MODERN UNDERSTANDING: AT THE EDGES 29 (UNIVERSITY OF GEORGIA PRESS, ATHENS, GA, 1998). 19 THOMAS, supra note 16, at 278. 94 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts was transformed from that of the bailor–bailee to that of the creditor– debtor. The irregular deposit, as developed by the Romans, inspired many legal systems with civil-law origins. Professor Zimmermann traced the modern rules that underpin current accounts in the German Civil Code to the Roman institution of the irregular deposit.20 The German Civil Code, in turn, influenced a number of jurisdictions that follow the Germanic legal tradition.21 Latin American jurisdictions also adopted the concept of the irregular deposit that applies to bank account relationships.22 In addition to the classification of deposits, the Romans also provided the basis for modern account relationships, including the concept of an account as the register of debts and other expenses. Performance of the depository’s functions in Rome – taking deposits and providing credit – was based on the underlying concept of account (ratio).23 The Roman Digest provided the following definition of account: ‘account is made up of mutual affairs which consist of accepting and collecting payments, lending, and paying off one’s debts’.24 The Roman concept of account resembles a modern bank account relationship that also involves accepting deposits, making payments and extending loans. In terms of organization, Roman bankers’ accounts were similar to the register of expenses of a household that was maintained by the father of the Roman family.25 The banker’s register (rationes) was arranged in alphabetical order of depositors individually listed on a separate page.26 All transactions with respect to the particular depositor were recorded on the same page. The banker’s register was not only a tracking system for debts and depositors’ claims but also served important procedural functions. In the event of a legal dispute, the banker was required to present an original or a copy of 20 REINHARD ZIMMERMANN, THE LAW OF OBLIGATIONS: ROMAN FOUNDATIONS OF THE CIVILIAN TRADITION 219 (JUTA AND COMPANY, CAPE TOWN, SOUTH AFRICA, 1993). 21 The Roman law irregular deposit had also been incorporated into the texts of Socialists Civil Codes as an underlying concept of the relationship between the depositor of fungible assets, such as grain and meat, and a custodian. OLIMPIAD S. IOFFE, SOVIET CIVIL LAW 270 (M. NIJHOFF, BOSTON, MA, 1988). 22 See CÓDIGO CIVIL [C. CIV.], art. 2246 (Colom.) that regulates deposit of money and provides for restoration in genre and CÓDIGO CIVIL [C. CIV.], art. 2188 (Arg.) that classifies deposits into regular and irregular. 23 ANDREAU, supra note 14, at 17. 24 Uplian Digest 2.14.47.1, reprinted in Ibid., at 44. 25 RICHARD BROWN, A HISTORY OF ACCOUNTING AND ACCOUNTANTS 29 (A.M. KELLEY, NEW YORK, NY, 1968). 26 Ibid., at 30. Introduction to Part II 95 the records related to the account of the person involved in the dispute.27 Some authors observed that the Roman register of accounts, and the effects of book entries evidencing debts and transfers, became the model for the organization of medieval banking.28 The depositor had the power to make dispositions with its credit balance recorded on the register of the banker. Roman law also validated settlement of debts by the transfer of bank credit.29 The actual money thus became immobilized in the form of the irregular deposit and the claims were settled in ‘book-entry money’.30 In Rome the debtor and creditor could visit the bank and order the banker to debit the account of the debtor and credit the account of the creditor. Alternatively, the debtor could ‘give his banker a payment order’ to pay the creditor.31 These orders were issued primarily by fathers of rich families and delivered to the bankers by slaves.32 Accordingly, transfers of money were transforming into an impersonal service. Andreau found that Roman bankers maintained deposit accounts even with one another to complete correspondent transfers.33 The moneychanger emerged as an important figure in the medieval period.34 His main function was to ‘exchange the currency’ needed to settle debts but also to transfer funds to distant locations without the actual transmission of money. For these purposes moneychangers maintained offices or correspondent relationships with local counterparts. Customers of moneychangers could thus send payments, in various currencies, to merchants and sellers located in different parts of Europe where a correspondent of the moneychanger maintained an office. In the ANDREAU, supra note 14, at 46. Abbott P. Usher, The Early History of Deposit Banking in Mediterranean Europe, Vol. LXXV, HARV. ECON. STUD. 11 (1943). 29 Ibid., at 4. 30 Meir Kohn, Early Deposit Banking, Working Paper 99-03, 2 (1999), available at http://www.dartmouth.edu/~mkohn/Papers/99-03.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013). 31 ANDREAU, supra note 14, at 42. 32 BROWN, supra note 25, at 30. 33 ANDREAU, supra note 14, at 43. 34 ALICE TEICHOVÁ, GINETTE KURGAN-VAN HENTENRYK & DIETER ZIEGLER, BANKING, TRADE AND INDUSTRY: EUROPE, AMERICA AND ASIA FROM THE THIRTEENTH TO THE TWENTIETH CENTURY 175 (CAMBRIDGE UNIVERSITY PRESS, CAMBRIDGE, UK, 1997). 27 28 96 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts second half of the fourteenth century, the moneychangers of Bruges adopted a payment system based on book entries.35 Medieval bankers performed a variety of functions that required an initial funding in the form of deposits. Charters from the late thirteenth century authorized individuals in Lille and Bruges to engage in moneychanging but more importantly also in ‘receiving money on deposit’.36 The deposits they accepted were of the irregular nature.37 Lopez provides the following example of a medieval deposit contract:38 Genoa, November 7, 1200 I, Oberto, banker of Pollanexi, acknowledge that I have received from you, Maria, wife of Rolando Generifico, 50 Genoese … I am to keep them in the bank and employ them in trade in Genoa as long as it shall be your pleasure; and I promise to give you the profit according to what seems to me ought to come to you. Moreover, I promise to return and to restore the aforesaid 50 Genoese or just as much instead of them, myself or through my messenger, to you or to your husband or to your accredited messenger, within eight days after you tell me and make the request, and similarly to give you the profit; otherwise the penalty of double and the seizure of my goods as security … Deposits of funds and other valuables with medieval bankers were documented in deposit contracts and by written instructions (book entries) in the banks’ ledgers.39 Book-entry credits represented and constituted deposits, transfers and extensions of loans.40 Bankers’ ledgers provided a trustworthy record of transactions whose legitimacy was buttressed by the banker’s oath as to the accuracy and truthfulness of the ledger.41 Book entries that effectively transferred monetary claims became a valid method for satisfaction of debts. According to the 1248 Statute of Douai, debtors could satisfy their debts by assignment of deposit balances to the creditor when both individuals were customers of 35 RAYMOND DE ROOVER, MONEY, BANKING AND CREDIT IN MEDIEVAL BRUGES 203 (MEDIAEVAL ACADEMY OF AMERICA, CAMBRIDGE, MA, 1948). 36 Ibid., at 202–3. 37 Ibid., at 247. 38 ROBERT S. LOPEZ & IRVING W. RAYMOND, MEDIEVAL TRADE IN THE MEDITERRANEAN WORLD 214 (COLUMBIA UNIVERSITY PRESS, NEW YORK, NY, 1955). 39 Ibid., at 212. 40 Usher, supra note 28, at 11. 41 Mier Kohn, supra note 30, at 3. Introduction to Part II 97 the same banker.42 The banker’s ledger was thus elevated to the status of a public register of deposit contracts and the source of rights to money.43 Nevertheless, before the 1500s, dispositions with bank credit by way of written orders were sporadic.44 The practice at the fairs of Champagne was to orally dictate the order to the banker who executed the transfer by a bookkeeping entry in the presence of both the depositor and the transferee.45 The entry in the banker’s ledgers thus remained the only evidence of the transaction.46 Only later did a written payment order emerge.47 Gradually money as corporeal property in the form of gold and coins was replaced with intangible property – a promise of the banker. The transition from bailment of specific corporeal property to an irregular deposit and bank credit was progressing.48 However, it was not entirely completed until the era of the seventeenth century English goldsmiths who, in addition to providing deposit, custody and credit services, also issued negotiable instruments that represented the rights to money. These instruments made the claims to money highly mobile. From the legal perspective, goldsmiths transformed the promise to pay from assignable to negotiable. Withers observed that ‘the original note, issued by a goldsmith in the form of a receipt for metal deposited, took the form of a promise to pay metal, and so passed as currency’.49 Cox also noted that ‘the issuance of receipts by goldsmiths in 17th century England was in fact the issuance of first bank money’.50 Depositors were given a highly liquid instrument in the form of a demand note to money that in fact functioned as money and book entries ceased to be required to complete transfers. Money in the form of goldsmiths’ notes was dealt with as an intangible right to receive the amount of gold or other precious metal represented by the note. The intrinsic value of notes was rooted in the belief that they 42 DE ROOVER, supra note 35, at 262. Usher, supra note 28, at 11. Ibid., at 8. 45 DE ROOVER, supra note 35, at 263. 46 Ibid., at 265. 47 CHIARA FRUGONI, BOOKS, BANKS, BUTTONS: AND OTHER INVENTIONS FROM THE MIDDLE AGES 53 (COLUMBIA UNIVERSITY PRESS, NEW YORK, NY, 2005). 48 JOHN R. COMMONS, LEGAL FOUNDATIONS OF CAPITALISM 256 (TRANSACTION PUBLISHERS, PISCATAWAY, NJ, 1995). 49 HARTLEY WITHERS, THE MEANING OF MONEY 24 (SMITH, ELDER & CO., LONDON, UK, 1909). 50 COX, PROPERTY RIGHTS, supra note 12, at 47. 43 44 98 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts were convertible into gold or coins.51 Negotiable notes issued by goldsmiths and other intermediaries introduced the credit function of money. This function was made possible due to the requirement to maintain only fractional reserves.52 Accordingly, the value of notes and loans issued by the goldsmiths exceeded the value of gold and metals that they held on deposit. Notes became a universally accepted means of payment even though they were only fractionally supported by gold or coins. Similar to the medieval Italian moneychangers, English goldsmiths used accounting entries in their ledgers to record deposits.53 Only initial deposits were recorded but the subsequent transfers were completed by delivery of notes and checks without the necessity of accounting entries. Notes and checks issued by the goldsmiths thus facilitated the settlement of debts without any actual transfer of coins or gold and without having to submit orders to the goldsmith to make any entries. The goldsmiths also provided safekeeping services. At first the safekeeping relationship was proprietary in nature because the goldsmith had a duty to return the gold to the customer who also retained title upon his request. Since the goldsmith was a bailee of the gold, this relationship was based on property.54 Gradually the goldsmiths transformed from bailees into lenders and began lending the gold left with them on deposit. This practice also changed the relationship between the goldsmith and the depositor from that of the owner and bailee to that of the debtor and creditor. This originally proprietary relationship thus transformed into one based on contract.55 The depositor lost his ownership rights and in exchange acquired a contractual claim against the goldsmith. Contemporary deposit relationships and transfers of funds are based on the same principles. The main difference between the practices of goldsmiths to contemporary relationships is the mode of transferring WITHERS, supra note 49, at 23. Intermediaries transformed themselves from mere custodians to banking institutions when they realized that it was unnecessary to carry gold or other precious metal reserves equal to 100% of their demand notes. They began to lend out all but a fraction of the gold. Randall D. Guynn, Modernizing Securities Ownership, Transfer and Pledging Laws, A Discussion Paper on the Need for International Harmonization, 19 (Capital Markets Forum, 1996). 53 FRANK T. MELTON, SIR ROBERT CALYTON AND THE ORIGINS OF ENGLISH DEPOSIT BANKING, 1658–85 96 (CAMBRIDGE UNIVERSITY PRESS, CAMBRIDGE, UK, 1986). 54 Bruce A. Markell, Symposium of Revised UCC Article 9, From Property to Contract and Back: An Examination of Deposit Accounts and Revised Article 9, 74 CHI.-KENT L. REV. 963, 966 (1999). 55 Ibid., at 967. 51 52 Introduction to Part II 99 funds. This mode is no longer dominated by written negotiable promises but instead occurs by electronic payment orders and entries made by banks. Electronic transfers further increase the mobility of bank money because transferees get access to funds much faster than if accepting written promises representing claims to such funds. DEMATERIALIZATION OF MONEY Money originated as a tangible object, first as a commodity, then as gold and eventually as a banknote before gradually transforming itself into a modern-day account-based right. Today the substance of money is bank credit that exists in the form of customers’ balances on deposit accounts maintained by banks.56 When Brian opens a bank account and deposits US$ 1000 at a local branch of Bank of America, he will receive a credit to his new bank account. His money in the form of cash or check will turn into a balance of US$ 1000 in his account. While the legal nature of money changes, its essence and the fundamental functions do not.57 The essential function of banks is the creation and transfer of bank money.58 In order for bank money to be created, someone must incur a debt. For instance, a depository bank (Bank of America) incurs a debt to its depositor (Brian) when it accepts a check for deposit.59 This debt may be modified later when the bank accepts incoming wire transfers for Brian’s account or executes his orders to transfer funds out of the account. Modern money exists in the form of debt and many regular transactions performed by banks, whether the collection of checks or the transferring of funds in and out of deposit accounts, involve debts. Such debts are represented in the form of balances on deposit accounts. The reliance on coins and banknotes in modern commercial societies is gradually diminishing.60 Very few commercial transactions are settled 56 COX, PROPERTY RIGHTS, supra note 12, at 44 and TOM GRECO, JR., MONEY, UNDERSTANDING AND CREATING ALTERNATIVES TO LEGAL TENDER 5 (OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS, OXFORD, UK, 2001). 57 BARBARA ANN GOOD, CHANGING FACE OF MONEY: WILL ELECTRIC MONEY BE ADOPTED IN THE UNITED STATES? 16 (GARLAND PUBLISHING INC., NEW YORK, NY, 2000). 58 Usher, supra note 28, at 3. 59 Similarly, a credit card company creates money and credit when it allows its card holders to use the credit balance for purchases. 60 For instance, only about 3.5% of all the money in the UK economy circulates in the form of coins and banknotes. COX, PROPERTY RIGHTS, supra note 12, at 43. 100 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts other than via electronic funds transfers by electronic book entries to bank accounts. Coins and banknotes are particularly inept to settle obligations arising in contemporary commercial and financial transactions, including those that involve payments for ordinary goods, securities or other financial instruments. The amount of physical money circulating in any economy is dwindling. Even consumer and retail payments are increasingly completed by electronic transfers through the use of credit and debit cards.61 Similar to security certificates, money has been immobilized or taken out of circulation and substituted for claims to money represented by balances on deposit accounts that are transferable by book entries. The process of immobilization of money preceded that of securities. While the process involving money has already been completed, immobilization of securities with financial intermediaries is still ongoing. As in the case of the securities markets, in which certificates held directly against issuers and financial assets maintained in accounts with intermediaries co-exist, physical money co-exists with bank money. Dematerialization of money significantly decreases the cost of payments, as expensive check-clearing systems may eventually be phased out.62 Alan Greenspan noted that ‘a key historical innovation that allowed the development of modern payment systems was the deposit balance that is freely transferable’.63 The free transferability of bank money has been facilitated by the domestic and world banking systems that ‘circulate money much like blood moves through the circulatory system of a living organism’.64 According to Greenspan, ‘electronic funds transfer systems have not altered the fundamental structure of the payment system; they merely decreased the time for the transmission of payment instructions and reduced the float’.65 61 ROBERT GUTTMANN, CYBERCASH: THE COMING ERA OF ELECTRONIC MONEY 6 (PALGRAVE MACMILLAN, NEW YORK, NY, 2003). 62 BENTON E. GUP, THE FUTURE OF BANKING 143 (QUORUM BOOKS, WESTPORT, CT, 2003). 63 Alan Greenspan, Payment Systems Research and Public Policy Risk, Efficiency, and Innovation, 28(4) Part 2 JOURNAL OF MONEY, CREDIT AND BANKING 689, 690 (1996). 64 Thomas C. Baxter, Jr. & Raj Bhala, Proper and Improper Execution of Payment Orders, 45 BUS. LAW. 1447 (1990). 65 Greenspan, supra note 63, at 690. Introduction to Part II 101 THE TYPOLOGY OF FUNDS HOLDING SYSTEMS The payments system is the whole technological and legal framework that facilitates consumer as well as commercial transactions. The World Bank defines a payments system as ‘the entire matrix of institutional and infrastructure arrangements and processes in a country for initiating and transferring monetary claims in the form of commercial bank and central bank liabilities’.66 Typically, the framework for consumer transactions operates separately from the one established to process commercial payments. This Part is concerned only with LVFTSs and the related framework of banking relationships that process payments by making entries to deposit accounts. It does not cover payment systems such as that provided by PayPal because such systems do not effectuate payments in ‘bank money’.67 LVFTSs process transfers individually as compared to the networks for collecting checks and completing credit cards payments that processes transactions in bulk. Individual processing makes LVFTSs more expensive to use and thus limited to high-value payments.68 Unlike securities holding systems, the organization of bank accounts and funds holding systems is largely uniform. They may not be classified into direct, indirect or transparent. The absence of structural and legal differences among funds holding systems may largely be attributed to the fact that no property rights are held in bank account relationships. The rights of depositors against their banks are solely contractual. From the structural perspective, one may characterize bank accounts holding systems as ‘indirect’ because rights and obligations exist only within the particular customer–intermediary (bank) relationship. The nature of bank account relationships is such that customers neither have 66 Ibid. Greenspan similarly defined the payment system as ‘a mechanism that provides an infrastructure for transferring money’; THE WORLD BANK, MASSIMO CIRASINO, JOSÉ ANTONIO GARCÍA, MARIO GUADAMILLAS & FERNANDO MONTES-NEGRET, REFORMING PAYMENTS AND SECURITIES SETTLEMENT SYSTEMS IN LATIN AMERICA AND THE CARIBBEAN 2 (THE WORLD BANK, WASHINGTON, DC, 2007), ANDREW G. HALDANE, STEPHEN MILLARD & VICTORIA SAPORTA, GENERAL INTRODUCTION, THE FUTURE OF PAYMENT SYSTEMS 2 (ROUTLEDGE, NEW YORK, NY, 2008). Payment systems may also be described as ‘organized arrangements for transferring value between participants and the circulation systems for the lifeblood of economies – money’. 67 Bruce J. Summers & Kirstin E. Wells, Emergence of Immediate Funds Transfer as a General-Purpose Means of Payment, 3Q ECON. PERSP. 97 (2011). 68 BENJAMIN GEVA, THE LAW OF ELECTRONIC FUNDS TRANSFERS, 1–3, § 3.02 Overview, [1] Wire Transfer Systems (MATTHEW BENDER & CO., US, 2013). 102 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts any rights against banks, other than the bank that maintains their relevant deposit account, or payment system operators, such as the central bank. In both indirect holding systems for securities and bank accounts, account holders may assert their rights solely against the intermediary that maintains their relevant securities or bank account. The difference is that the rights of securities account holders are proprietary while those of bank account holders are contractual. Funds holding systems constitute an important component of the monetary and financial system of every economy. An IMF study observed that an efficient payments system is critical for the development of modern financial markets, including those for securities and inter-bank money products.69 Funds holding systems support practically every other financial and commercial system where transactions are settled in ‘bank money’. All of these systems are being increasingly interconnected and funds holding systems have truly become the circulation system that facilitates the settlement of critical financial and commercial transactions.70 One of the most critical connections of funds holding systems is the one they share with the securities settlement systems. In the majority of economies there is only a single LVFTS that sits at the top of the funds holding system. LVFTSs are typically operated by central banks but some, such as Clearing House Inter-Bank Payments System (CHIPS) in the United States, may be owned and operated by private consortia of banks and financial institutions. These systems complete settlement of commercially important transactions by debits and credits to the participants’ bank accounts.71 Generally there are two fundamental types of LVFTSs: 1) the RTGS system in which payments are settled immediately and 2) the net settlement (NS) system in which settlement occurs only at the end of the day. However many LVFTSs are hybrid systems and incorporate features of both types.72 For instance the Central Bank of Brazil (Banco Central do Brasil) operates a hybrid system, SITRAF, in which transfer orders may be settled immediately by Summers & Wells, supra note 67, at 1. Stephen L. Harris & Stephanie Heller, Symposium: Rethinking Payments Law: Introduction to Rethinking Payments Law: Appendix: A Proposal for Consideration of a Unified Payments Law, 83 CHI.-KENT. L. REV. 477, 485 (2008). 71 See Article 2o.III of the Mexican Payments Law that defines settlement (liquidación) as ‘los cargos y abonos realizados en las cuentas de los Participantes’. 72 DERMOT TURING, CLEARING AND SETTLEMENT IN EUROPE 419 (BLOOMSBURY PROFESSIONAL LTD., HAYWARDS HEATH, UK, 2012). 69 70 Introduction to Part II 103 credits/debits to the accounts maintained by the central bank or in a batch after netting.73 Below these top-level relationships between the operator of LVFTSs and participating banks, the structure and nature of relationships is largely uniform. Banks complete transfers of funds by debit and credit entries between each other as well as for their customers. Accordingly, the following paragraphs focus only on the typology of funds holding systems from the perspective of LVFTSs. It should be emphasized that the operators of LVFTSs are neither parties to funds transfers nor intermediaries acting for third parties.74 Operators do not become central counterparties to payment orders that are lodged by the participants. This feature distinguishes bank accounts holding systems from securities and commodity systems where: 1) a clearing entity becomes the central counterparty to every transaction and 2) intermediaries internally clear transactions for their customers. A payment system operator merely books transfers to the bank accounts of its participants without providing any central counterparty clearing functions. Similarly, a bank transferring funds of one customer to another merely makes the relevant credit and debit entries. LVFTSs must also be distinguished from communication networks that transmit payment orders and other banking data such as the Society for Worldwide Interbank Financial Telecommunication (SWIFT) network. SWIFT only communicates instructions to credit and debit accounts and does not maintain accounts for participants, execute payment orders or provide any clearing and settlement services. SWIFT is a mere messenger that performs the functions previously provided by telex, fax and electronic data interchange. More than 62 LVFTSs providing payments services in over 90 countries rely on SWIFT to communicate with their participants.75 73 See http://www.bcb.gov.br/?SITRAF (last visited 11 December 2013). Every SITRAF participating institution must make an initial deposit to the SITRAF settlement account at the Central Bank. 74 Fed. Reserve Banks, Operating Circular No. 6 Funds Transfers Through the Fedwire Funds Service, § 5.3 (Effective 12 July 2012), available at http://www. frbservices.org/files/regulations/pdf/operating_circular_6_07122012.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013) [hereinafter FED Circular 6]. 75 See http://www.swift.com/solutions/solutions/solution_for_payments_ clearing/index.page (last visited 11 December 2013). 104 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts Real-time Gross Settlement Systems RTGS systems are those that ‘effect final settlement of interbank funds transfers on a continuous, transaction-by-transaction basis throughout the processing day’.76 In other words payment orders are executed as they are entered into the payment systems and the bank accounts of participating banks are adjusted simultaneously. The RTGS systems, typically operated by central banks, provide intraday finality and eliminate credit risk – i.e., the risk that a banking institution will not have sufficient funds to cover its daily payments at the end of the business day. Since the first RTGS system – the US Fedwire – was established in 1985, the number of systems has grown exponentially.77 The first European country to implement an RTGS system was Denmark and the first country in Latin America to do so was Uruguay.78 TARGET2, the payment system established within the EU to process large-value transfers, is also an RTGS system. These systems effectively eliminate the risk that a transfer will be revoked and provide liquidity to beneficiary banks, who may use the funds as soon as their accounts are credited. A number of LVFTSs have also been recently ‘upgraded’ from the NS to RTGS model. For instance in April 2002, the Brazilian STR implemented the RTGS model, thus ensuring irrevocable and unconditional finality. In some aspects RTGS systems vary. For instance some RTGS systems require that participating banks have sufficient funds in their central bank accounts to process payment orders. Otherwise orders to transfer funds exceeding the account balance of the participant shall be rejected. Only when the bank replenishes its account may the payment order be re-submitted for execution. The Brazilian LVFTS is representative of this category.79 In other RTGS systems payment orders are not automatically rejected if the account balance of the transferor is insufficient. Execution of such orders may be temporarily suspended by the operator’s internal processing system and will be released for execution once the transferor has replenished the balance. The Mexican LVFTS is representative of this type. Still, in some other RTGS systems central banks provide credit See http://www.bis.org/publ/cpss22.htm (last visited 11 December 2013). Morten L. Bech & Bart Hobijn, Technology Diffusion within Central Banking: The Case of Real-Time Gross Settlement, Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports, Staff Report No. 260, (September 2006), at 2. 78 Ibid., at 9. 79 Banco Central do Brasil, Brazilian Payment System, 9 (September 2009), available at http://www.bcb.gov.br/Pom/Spb/Ing/TheBrazilianPaymentSystem. pdf (last visited 11 December 2013). 76 77 Introduction to Part II 105 known as ‘daylight overdraft’ to the participants in cases in which their balances are insufficient. In these systems the payment order will be executed if the originator is authorized to draw on the credit made available by the central bank.80 For instance, the Slovakian RTGS system, operated by the National Bank, provides an intraday overdraft facility that must be fully collateralized by securities81 and the intraday credit must be repaid by 1p.m. on the same trading day.82 Finally, in certain other systems the participants may be able to draw on their reserves that are required to be held with the central bank for monetary policy purposes.83 LVFTSs may also use a combination of these options. For instance the central bank may provide credit but when the credit limits are exhausted the execution of payment orders will be temporarily suspended. In these varieties of RTGS systems there is little need for a loss-sharing arrangement because settlements do not fail for the insufficiency of funds.84 The Federal Reserve Bank may request repayment at any time if it deems itself insecure and provides notice to the account holder. Federal Reserve Banks, Operating Circular 1, Account Relationships (effective 1 February 2013), available at http://www.frbservices.org/files/regulations/pdf/operating_circular_1_ 02012013.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013) [hereinafter FED Circular 1], § 5.2. The Fed charges fees, requests collateral and imposes credit limits to manage its exposure to the participants. Antoine Martin & David C. Mills, An Economic Perspective on the Enforcement of Credit Arrangements: The Case of Daylight Overdrafts in Fedwire, FRBNY ECONOMIC POLICY REVIEW, September 2008, at 161 & 165. Although collateralization of most daylight overdrafts is not explicitly required, a significant amount of the Reserve Banks’ exposure is secured by collateral. 81 Decision of the National Bank of Slovakia No. 6/2003 provides details on the collateralization of intraday credit. The securities must be registered in the system operated by the National Bank of Slovakia. Customers’ securities, and those already subject to a security interest, are not eligible as collateral. The value of securities must exceed the amount of intraday credit by 2%. 82 Ibid., § 4(5). If the borrower does not repay the debt, the pledged securities may be taken in satisfaction of the outstanding debt. Ibid., § 7(2). 83 Peter Allsopp, Bruce Summers & John Veale, The Evolution of Real-Time Gross Settlement: Access, Liquidity and Credit, and Pricing, in FINANCIAL INFRASTRUCTURE SERIES: PAYMENT SYSTEMS POLICY AND RESEARCH 18 (The World Bank, 2009). 84 TURING, supra note 72, at 418. 80 106 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts Net Settlement Systems Unlike RTGS systems operators of NS systems do not credit and debit accounts of the participants as soon as payment orders are executed. It is not necessary that operators even maintain any accounts for participants. The settlement is typically deferred until the end of the business day, when the sums of all transfers are aggregated and only a single credit or debit entry is made to the participants’ accounts. The end-of-the-day settlement is the result of during-the-day clearing and netting. Clearing in NS systems does not significantly differ from clearing in securities clearing systems. The clearing process in NS systems involves calculation of positions and then multilateral netting or offsetting of overlapping balances.85 NS systems are a significant minority to the RTGS systems.86 With the enormous increase in the volume and number of payments handled by such systems, regulators became concerned about the risk that a participant would not be able to settle its obligations at the end of the day after netting has been performed. As a result NS systems began their transformation into RTGS systems. The World Bank labeled the 1990s as the decade of this transformation.87 The Canadian Payments Association operates an NS system – the Large Value Transfer System (LVTS).88 The LVTS provides intraday finality with settlement to be completed by the Bank of Canada at 7:30 p.m. every day as a result of clearing and netting of outstanding obligations.89 Payment orders may not be revoked as soon as they have been logged into the system even though the participants’ accounts shall not be adjusted until the end of the day. 85 For instance, Official Comment 4 to UCC § 4A-403(b) (1989) provides that ‘this provision is intended to invalidate any arguments that multilateral netting is not valid because mutuality of obligations is not present’. 86 Bech & Hobijn, supra note 77, at 1. ‘Historically, settlement of interbank payments has been achieved through end-of-day netting systems.’ 87 THE WORLD BANK, MASSIMO CIRASINO ET AL., supra note 66, at 6. 88 Bank of Canada, Canada’s Major Payments Systems, available at http:// www . bankofcanada . ca / financial-system / payments / canadas - major - payments systems/ (last visited 11 December 2013). 89 Intraday obligations of the participants must be secured with eligible collateral that includes government-issued debt securities, high-rating corporate and municipal securities, etc. Bank of Canada, Neville Arjani & Darcey McVanel, A Primer on Canada’s Large Value Transfer System 18, (March 2006), available at http://www.bankofcanada.ca/wp-content/uploads/2010/05/lvts_ neville.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013). Introduction to Part II 107 In the United States, the RTGS Fedwire system co-exists with the CHIPS system that was established in 1970 as an NS system. CHIPS processes and settles over 350 000 payment orders with the daily aggregate amount averaging US$ 2 trillion.90 Since its establishment the system has been modified to the extent that there is a minimal difference, in terms of achieving finality, from Fedwire. In its present form CHIPS belongs to the category of hybrid systems. CHIPS participants send and receive payment orders during the business day but the orders are not released if the sender has insufficient funds in the pre-funded account to cover the amount of the payment.91 Release of a payment message into the CHIPS system bestows an obligation on the sender to pay the amount of the payment message.92 The moment of release of the message is critical because it establishes finality of the transfer and the transferor’s right to cancel the order terminates.93 CHIPS is not a banking institution that maintains accounts for its participants so at the end of the day it sends payment orders over the Fedwire to credit or debit the accounts of such participants. Obligations of the CHIPS participants are ultimately settled on the accounts maintained by the New York Federal Reserve Bank. The CHIPS account at the Reserve Bank must be pre-funded by its participants with the sums they expect to transfer during the day.94 The funds may be transferred only pursuant to instructions submitted by CHIPS as an agent of the participants.95 Clearing House Interbank Payments System, Self-Assessment of Compliance with Core Principles for Systematically Important Payment Systems, 1 (November 2007) [hereinafter CHIPS Self-assessment]. 91 Clearing House Interbank Payments System, Rules and Administrative Procedures, Rules 2(c) and 12(e) (March 2012) [hereinafter CHIPS Rules]. CHIPS is eligible to issue ‘funds-transfer system rules’ under UCC 4A-501(b) (1989). However these Rules govern only the relationships of CHIPS and its participants. Relationships of participants between one another and their customers are outside the scope of the Rules. 92 CHIPS Self-assessment, at 5. 93 CHIPS Rules, at Rule 2(d). 94 CHIPS prefunded balance account is defined as ‘a special deposit account established at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York for the joint benefit of all funding participants to hold balances pursuant to the CHIPS Prefunded Balance Account Agreement’. CHIPS Rules, at Rule 1(5). 95 Ibid., at Rule 12(a)(2). 90 108 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts EURO1 is an EU-based NS payment system operated by EBA Clearing.96 Transfers processed through EURO1 are final and irrevocable. However, the accounts of participants at the ECB are settled at the end of the day.97 During the business day participants have a single amount that they owe or that is owed to them. This amount is continuously adjusted with incoming and outgoing transfers.98 EURO1 thus operates similarly to CHIPS. TYPES OF MONEY This section examines the various types of money with the objective to define the scope of the bank accounts holding systems that fall under this Part. The following paragraphs look at monetary assets and values held in bank accounts and distinguish between account-based money and the money that circulates outside of bank accounts systems. It has been said that ‘next to language, money is the most important medium through which modern societies communicate’.99 Money is not only an important communication tool but it is also an indispensable device that facilitates economic development. Economies could not have transformed from subsistence to specialized production and distribution of goods and services unless a medium of exchange had been created. Over the centuries various objects and rights functioned as money. Money in the form of coins first emerged near Troy in the Kingdom of Lydia. They were of equal weight and size, which eliminated the need to weigh them before every transaction could be completed. Their value EBA Clearing was established in 1998 by 52 banks with the objective to operate a large-value payment system. EBA Clearing, The Leading Private Provider of EURO Clearing Services, available at https://www.ebaclearing.eu/ About-EBA-CLEARING-N=EBACLEARING-L=EN.aspx (last visited 11 December 2013). 97 For a detailed description of EURO1, see EBA Clearing, EURO1: The Pre-eminent Private Euro Clearing and Settlement System, available at https:// www.ebaclearing.eu/EURO1-N=EURO1-L=EN.aspx (last visited 11 December 2013). 98 EBA Clearing, EURO1 Takes Advantage of an Innovative Legal Structure, available at https://www.ebaclearing.eu/Legal-basis-N=E1_Legalbasis-L=EN. aspx (last visited 11 December 2013). 99 BERND WIDDIG, CULTURE AND INFLATION IN WEIMAR GERMANY 79 (UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA PRESS, BERKELEY, CA, 2001). 96 Introduction to Part II 109 could easily be determined by simply counting the coins.100 For centuries coins were the primary means of payment until the medieval moneychangers and then the English goldsmiths began issuing demand notes. Presently coins as money are largely obsolete in commercial transactions. The primary use of coins is in consumer transactions for the purchase of low value items. Professor Rogers observed that: The important characteristic of a specie-based monetary system is that money is completely reified. A gold or silver coin that the sovereign has minted and declared to be current coin of the realm is money; it does not represent money or substitute for money; it is money.101 Property law can sufficiently govern the rights of parties where payment is made by delivery of coins. Contractual rules and account relationships are not necessary or applicable to regulate payments with coins. Similarly, property law is sufficient to govern transfers of bearer securities and physical commodities. Paper money emerged as a medium of exchange not by way of law but by way of custom when the goldsmiths and other custodians began issuing notes.102 Notes were initially issued by non-bank or quasi-bank intermediaries in turn affecting the purchasing power and acceptability of such notes. If the creditworthiness of the issuer was unknown or questionable sellers were reluctant to accept the notes in payment. Modern currency is not issued by individual banks but by central banks under the authority of governments.103 Currency is thus a banknote that The Lydians produced the first coins from a natural mixture of gold and silver. JACK WEATHERFORD, THE HISTORY OF MONEY 29–31 (THREE RIVERS PRESS, NEW YORK, NY, 1997). 101 James S. Rogers, The Irrelevance of Negotiable Instruments Concepts in the Law of the Check-Based Payment System, 65 TEX. L. REV. 929, 931–2 (1987). 102 Menger, supra note 12, at 33. 103 In Juiliard v. Greenman, 110 U.S. 421 (1884) the US Supreme Court held that: ‘… Under the power to borrow money on the credit of the United States, and to issue circulating notes for the money borrowed, its power to define the quality and force of those notes as currency is as broad as the like power over a metallic currency under the power to coin money and to regulate the value thereof. Under the two powers, taken together, Congress is authorized to establish a national currency, either in coin or in paper, and to make that currency lawful money for all purposes, as regards the national government or private individuals …’. 100 110 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts expresses a promise of the government to pay the bearer on demand.104 In a banknote system bank credit is used as a medium of exchange because individual banknotes are complete reifications of the money substitute – bank credit.105 In other words just like the transfer system for coins, the transfer system for banknotes is proprietary. Property law determines when coins and banknotes are delivered and payments get completed. Coins and notes have been issued exclusively under the authority of governments. This monopoly is also reflected in the legal definitions of money.106 In the United States, UCC § 1-201(a)(24) defines money as ‘a medium of exchange currently authorized or adopted by a domestic or foreign government…’. The EU Maastricht Treaty Article 105a provides that the ECB is the exclusive body to authorize the issuance of banknotes, which may be issued by the ECB itself or states’ central banks. Similarly, Article 4 of the Mexican Central Bank Law provides that ‘Banco de México shall be the sole entity authorized to issue bank notes and order the minting of metallic coins, as well as to put into circulation both types of currency …’.107 Checks, credit, and debit cards that are commonly used in commercial and consumer transactions are not money in the legal sense. In the context of a banknote payment system the nature and functions of notes must be distinguished from checks. Withers observed that: The use of the note involves the element of belief to a much greater extent than that of the check. Whereas the exchangeability of the former depends on the credibility of the central bank that issues currency, the liquidity of the latter depends on the solvency of the drawer. This element of belief in credit makes the extensive use of checks possible only in a community which has reached a high stage of economic civilization and that which is also blessed with a high level of general honesty among its members.108 104 CHARLES PROCTOR, MANN ON THE LEGAL ASPECT OF MONEY 25 (6th edn., OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS, OXFORD, UK, 2006). 105 Rogers, supra note 101, at 932. 106 This is not the case of the Model Law that defines ‘funds’ or ‘money’ in art. 2(h) as ‘includes credit in an account kept by a bank …’. 107 For a similar exclusive right granted to the Central Bank of Costa Rica see Ley Orgánica del Banco Central de Costa Rica, art. 44, 3.11.1995, (Ley No. 7558), which provides: ‘El Banco Central de Costa Rica tendrá el derecho exclusivo de la emisión de billetes y monedas en el territorio nacional’. 108 WITHERS, supra note 49, at 32. Introduction to Part II 111 Unlike banknotes checks do not reify or represent money. While money is transferred by delivery of the banknote sanctioned by a government, delivery of a check does not transfer any money or bank credit. Accordingly, property law does not determine whether payment occurs when one tenders a check. A check is a mere instruction ordering the drawee bank to transfer bank credit but it is not a medium for the transfer of bank credit.109 Once this instruction in the form of a check is properly presented and honored, the transfer of bank credit is executed by book entries to bank accounts. A check performs similar functions as oral instructions submitted to medieval moneychangers to debit the account of the transferor and credit the account of the transferee.110 Another type of money is bank money. Payments and settlement of debts in contemporary commercial transactions require the assistance of intermediaries. Intermediaries such as commercial banks maintain deposit accounts for their customers and provide the means to manage effectively the rights embedded in such bank account relationships. Banks place themselves between the suppliers of funds and the users of those funds.111 ‘Bank money’, that is to say the money embedded in bank accounts, has become the primary means of payment in financial markets and the key provider of credit.112 Central bank money is also a type of bank money with the exception that it is more certain and robust than commercial bank money.113 Money is now largely embedded in bank deposits that people customarily refer to as ‘their money’.114 However bank deposits do not fall under the legal definition of money because they are neither authorized nor adopted by a government. Bank money is an intangible right to sue Rogers, supra note 101. Ibid., at 935–6. 111 Edmund M.A. Kwaw, The Evolving Law on the Eurobank-Customer Relationship and the Common Law: The Need for Clarity, 32 SYRACUSE J. INT’L. L. & COM. 87, 91 (2004). 112 PHILIP R. WOOD, SET-OFF AND NETTING, DERIVATIVES, CLEARING SYSTEMS 266 (2nd edn., SWEET & MAXWELL LTD., LONDON, UK, 2007). 113 TURING, supra note 72, at 217. Allsopp, Summers & Veale, supra note 83, at 7. 114 Stephen Millard & Victoria Saporta, Central Banks and Payment Systems, Past, Present and Future, in THE FUTURE OF PAYMENT SYSTEMS 23 (Andrew G. Haldane, Stephen Millard & Victoria Saporta eds., ROUTLEDGE, NEW YORK, NY, 2008). 109 110 112 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts the bank.115 The relationship between the bank and its depositor, who placed currency into a safe-deposit box, is not a general (irregular) deposit type of relationship but a custodial type of relationship (i.e., regular deposit). A custodial relationship, or regular deposit, does not generate ‘bank money’. However, an irregular deposit generates bank money, creating what are essentially liabilities of banks that then function as the essential medium of exchange in modern commercial and financial transactions.116 The bank’s liability corresponds to the customer’s right to draw on the credit balance or any overdraft facility, if available, and to instruct the bank to make payments from such an account.117 Bank money is embedded in a deposit relationship; it is neither an object nor a traceable property right. While a bank deposit account is a relationship between the account holder and its bank, it may be a property right in the eyes of third parties. For instance, secured lenders may take a security interest in the deposit account and judgment creditors may levy on the deposit account. These proprietary aspects of the bank deposit relationship are explored in Chapter 7 in the context of security interests in deposit accounts. Bank money, however, exists only within the depositor-bank relationship. If the funds leave the relationship, such as by a funds transfer, the relationship is modified but its components do not travel with the transfer. Brian McCall, Money, Money Everywhere but not a Drop to Secure: A Proposal for Amending the Perfection Rules for Security Interests in Money and Deposit Accounts, 74 TENN. L. REV. 669, 672 (2007). 116 James S. Rogers, The New Old Law of Electronic Money, 58 SMU L. REV. 1253, 1261 (2005). 117 COX, PROPERTY RIGHTS, supra note 12, at 12. 115 6. Bank account relationships The central bank payment is a unique form of payment because it results in a claim on an institution that cannot go bankrupt, i.e., the central bank. The counterparty credit and liquidity risks are not present in central bank payments.1 In contrast, completion of a payment using a private bank’s money not only depends on a sufficient amount of funds being held in the bank account but also on the bank’s creditworthiness.2 Payments effectuated at the top level through a central system are typically subject to a special regulatory framework adopted by the central bank (e.g., the Central Bank of Mexico) or a private operator of the system (e.g., CHIPS).3 Transfers made over the Fedwire are regulated by Regulation J issued by the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve, which incorporates UCC Article 4A,4 and FED Circular 6, which is binding on the parties to a funds transfer made through the Fedwire.5 1 Hans J. Blommestein & Bruce J. Summers, Banking and the Payment System, in THE PAYMENT SYSTEM, DESIGN, MANAGEMENT, AND SUPERVISION 22 (Bruce J. Summers ed., INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND, WASHINGTON, DC, 1994). 2 Kenneth A. Froot, Incentive Problems in Financial Contracting, Impacts on Corporate Financing, Investment, and Risk Management Policies, in THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL SYSTEM, A FUNCTIONAL PERSPECTIVE 273 (Dwight B. Crane, Robert C. Merton, Kenneth A. Froot, Zvi Bodie, Scott P. Mason, Erik R. Sirri, André F. Perold and Peter Tufano eds., HARVARD BUSINESS SCHOOL PRESS, BOSTON, MA, 1995). 3 Some authors observed that in the United States the law embodied in statutes is being replaced by the regulations and operating circulars issued by the Federal Reserve. Sarah Jane Hughes, Duty Issues in the Ever-Changing World of Payments Transactions: Is It Time for New Rules?, 83 CHI.-KENT. L. REV. 721, 722 (2008). 4 Regulation J does not incorporate the New York or other state version of UCC Article 4A, but the uniform model promulgated by the National Conference of Commissioners on Uniform State Laws (NCCUSL). See Mark Sneddon, Symposium: Is the UCC Dead, or Alive and Well? International Perspectives, The Effect of Uniform Commercial Code Article 4A on the Law of International Credit Transfers, 29 LOY.L.A.L.REV. 1107, 1121 (1996). 5 Fed. Reserve Banks, Operating Circular No. 6 (Effective 12 July 2012), available at http://www.frbservices.org/files/regulations/pdf/operating_circular_ 113 114 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts Such circulars and regulations supersede any inconsistent provisions of UCC 4A.6 Rights and obligations of participants in CHIPS are governed by the New York version of UCC 4A and the CHIPS Participant agreements. EU Member States have also adopted specific legislation regulating rights and obligations of parties to funds transfers and the operation of central payment systems. These national enactments implemented certain EU Directives and Regulations, particularly Directive 97/5/EC on Crossborder Credit Transfers,7 Directive 98/26/EC on Settlement Finality in Payment and Securities Settlement Systems (EU Settlement Finality Directive), Payment Services Directive 2007/64/EC (PSD) and Regulation 2560/2001 on Cross-Border Payments. Furthermore, regulators in EU Member States have issued rules and decisions that govern the operations of central payment systems.8 Implementation of these Directives and Regulations also affected relationships at lower levels, as will be examined further in this chapter. Finally, the operations of TARGET2 are governed by the amended ECB’s Guideline 2007/2.9 In Latin America the Central Bank of Mexico issued Circular 2019/95 to regulate transfers of funds. The Circular requires participants in the central payment system to maintain special accounts (cuenta única) to credit and debit all executed orders.10 Similarly the Central Bank of Costa Rica issued a special regulation to govern some aspects of funds transfers executed through its central payment system (Reglamento del Sistema de Pagos). Article 2 provides definitions of some key terms such 6_07122012.pdf., art. 1.1. Pursuant to art. 1.2, each Reserve Bank has issued an identical Circular 6. 6 See UCC 4A-107 (1989). 7 The scope of this Directive was very limited in that it applied only to transfers of up to the equivalent of ECU 50 000. 8 See Rozhodnutie Národnej Banky Slovenska zo 16. októbra 2012 č. 7/2012 o pravidlách platobného systému SIPS (National Bank of Slovakia, Decision 7 of 16 October 2012 on regulation for payment system SIPS) [hereinafter NBS Decision 7], available at http://www.nbs.sk/_img/Documents/_ Legislativa/_Vestnik/ROZ7-2012.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013). 9 See the ECB Guideline and amendments thereto at http://www.ecb.int/ecb/ legal/1003/1349/html/act_11949_amend.en.html (last visited 11 December 2013). 10 Banco de México, Operaciones de la Banca Múltiple, at M. 72.22.2, available at http://www.banxico.org.mx/sistema-financiero/disposiciones/dirigi das / instituciones-de-credito /disposiciones-dirigidas-a-las-instituciones-de-cre /dis posiciones-dirigidas-a-las-instituciones-de-ban/otras/circular-2019-95-.html (last visited 11 December 2013). Bank account relationships 115 as the originator (cliente origin), the beneficiary (cliente destino) and the bank account (cuenta de fondos). Pursuant to Article 39, all bank accounts opened and maintained for individuals by financial institutions that participate in the central payment system must be identified by the number of the account owner. In addition, every payment order submitted by the financial institution on behalf of its client must indicate the number of the originator as well as the number of the beneficiary. These regulations also include rules that set forth the requirements participants must meet in order to gain and continue to have access to the central payment system. Access to large-value payment systems, whether RTGS or net settlement systems, has traditionally been restricted only to banks and large financial institutions.11 However, the World Bank found that in many RTGS systems non-banks are also granted direct access.12 For instance a CSD is eligible for membership at the Slovakian Interbank Payment System (SIPS).13 Nevertheless, like other central systems for clearing and settlement of securities and commodity contracts, controlled access protects all participants against the risk of default. Only well-capitalized and supervised institutions qualify for membership. Payment system operators typically impose various conditions on access, such as connection to the SWIFT network or other secure message networks, adequate capitalization, establishment of a bank account for settlement of payment transactions, etc.14 Participants at the Canadian payment system must be members of the Canadian Payments Association, a non-profit organization that owns and operates the payment system, must also be connected to the SWIFT network, establish settlement accounts with the Bank of Canada and enter into an agreement 11 Only banks and other financial institutions may participate in CHIPS. For the list of the 48 participating institutions see the Clearing House, About CHIPS, Customers, available at http://www.chips.org/about/pages/033742.php (last visited 11 December 2013). 12 Peter Allsopp, Bruce Summers & John Veale, The Evolution of Real-Time Gross Settlement: Access, Liquidity and Credit, and Pricing, in FINANCIAL INFRASTRUCTURE SERIES: PAYMENT SYSTEMS POLICY AND RESEARCH 13 (The World Bank, 2009). 13 NBS Decision 7 at § 2(2) lists the types of institutions eligible for a membership. 14 Ibid., § 3(1)(c). For a list of requirements to participate in EURO1 see EBA Clearing, Admission, available at https://www.ebaclearing.eu/AdmissionN=E1_Admission-L=EN.aspx (last visited 11 December 2013). 116 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts that permits the Bank of Canada to provide loans and take collateral.15 These are typical of the type of requirements that applicants for membership in a central payment system must satisfy. Some payment systems may also allow different categories of membership. Participants at the US Fedwire system are classified as correspondents or respondents.16 Correspondents are institutions that maintain master accounts with a Federal Reserve Bank to which credits and debits may be made on behalf of their respondent institutions.17 Thus a respondent institution may not settle its payment transactions directly but only through a master account of a correspondent.18 Member banks and depository institutions, as defined in the Federal Reserve Act, as well as other entities are eligible to apply for a correspondent membership. Every correspondent must sign a standardized master account agreement that is appended to the FED Circular 1.19 EURO1 distinguishes between participants and those with a subparticipation status. Sub-participants are typically branches and subsidiaries of participants thus gaining direct access to EURO1. However, sub-participant transfers are included within the overall liquidity position of the main participant.20 The Slovakian payment system also categorizes its participants into direct and indirect. Direct participants maintain accounts with the National Bank of Slovakia that are used for settlement purposes. Indirect participants are non-bank entities for which the National Bank does not maintain settlement accounts.21 A primary example of an indirect participant is the Bratislava Stock Exchange, which uses the central payment 15 Bank of Canada, Neville Arjani & Darcey McVanel, A Primer on Canada’s Large Value Transfer System, 11 (March 2006), available at http:// www.bankofcanada.ca/wp-content/uploads/2010/05/lvts_neville.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013). 16 A correspondent must be one of the institutions listed in Federal Reserve Banks, Operating Circular No. 1, Account Relationships, § 2.2(c) (Effective 1 February 2013), available at http://www.frbservices.org/files/regulations/pdf/ operating_circular_1_02012013.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013) [FED Circular 1]. 17 Ibid. § 2.7. 18 Ibid. 19 The list of account agreements and forms is available at http:// www.frbservices.org/forms/account_services.html#oc1 (last visited 11 December 2013). 20 EBA Clearing, supra note 14. 21 National Bank of Slovakia, SIPS, The Slovak Interbank Payment System, 7 (2004) (on file with author). Bank account relationships 117 system for the settlement of securities transactions. Every applicant must file a request for membership and sign a contract with the National Bank of Slovakia available in standardized form on the bank’s website. Additionally, every applicant must satisfy the requirements provided in the Slovakian Act on the Payment System.22 Participants in the Costa Rican central payments system, SINPE, are called ‘associated entities’ (entidades asociadas).23 In order to participate in SINPE these entities must comply with various conditions and requirements set forth in the Regulations issued by the central bank and other applicable norms. Membership at payment systems is limited and strictly regulated. Since the central payment system supports the entire economy it is critical that only well-capitalized and regulated institutions are granted access. Smaller banks or non-bank institutions may be allowed indirect access through a direct participant or correspondent. The relationship between the central bank operating a high-value payment system and its participants is account-based.24 Participants must sign membership contracts and establish settlement accounts for payment purposes. The central bank then credits and debits participants’ deposit accounts with the transfers that they send and receive. In addition to settlement account services, central banks provide settlement credit services in which they extend credit facilities in the form of overdrafts to cover outgoing payments in the case that account balances are insufficient.25 It may be the case that some participants utilize only settlement account services without having access to the credit services of the central bank, or participants may have access to both services, directly or indirectly, through an agent.26 Similar to central securities depositories, central banks that operate an LVFTS also enter into relationships with entities other than their own participants. The German Bundesbank maintains around 200 euro Zákon o platobnom styku, 19 September 2002, (Z.z. 510/2002), available at http://www.nbs.sk/_img/Documents/_Legislativa/_UplneZneniaZakonov/Z5102002_567-08.PDF (last visited 11 December 2013) [hereinafter Slovakian Payments Law]. 23 See Reglamento del Sistema de Pagos, issued by Banco Central de Costa Rica (27 March 2009), available at http://costarica.eregulations.org/media/ reglamento%20del%20sistema%20de%20pagos.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013), art. 3. 24 NBS Decision 7, at § 12(1). 25 Allsopp, Summers & Veale, supra note 12, at 9. 26 Ibid., at 10. 22 118 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts accounts for foreign business partners as well as approximately 65 foreign currency accounts abroad for the purpose of settling payments.27 The National Bank of Slovakia maintains correspondent accounts with a number of commercial and central banks, including the Deutsche Bank and Federal Reserve Bank of New York.28 The Federal Reserve Bank of New York also offers correspondent banking services.29 All of these relationships are account-based, whereby central banks maintain accounts for one another or their business partners. Special account relationships exist within the TARGET2 system, which facilitates secure and expeditious funds transfers within the EU.30 From a legal perspective each central bank acts as a separate system operator within TARGET2. For instance, the German system is called TARGET2-Bundesbank and the Slovakian system is called TARGET2SK.31 Authorized financial institutions that are members of a state’s RTGS system may also become direct participants in TARGET2. A financial institution wishing to participate in TARGET2 is required to execute the standard contract with the central bank which sets forth the conditions of participation.32 Direct participants may then provide correspondent services and access to TARGET2 for non-members that are Deutsche Bundesbank Eurosystem, Correspondent Banking, available at http://www.bundesbank.de/Navigation/EN/Core_business_areas/Payment_systems/ Correspondent_banking/correspondent_banking.html (last visited 11 December 2013). 28 The full list of correspondents is available at Národná Banka Slovenska, Zoznam korešpodenčných bánk, http://www.nbs.sk/sk/operacie-na-financnychtrhoch/zoznam-korespodencnych-bank (last visited 11 December 2013). 29 It opened the first correspondent account for a foreign central bank in 1913. Federal Reserve Bank of New York (FRBNY), International Affairs, President’s Letter, 2 (2013), available at http://www.newyorkfed.org/banking/ fed_brochure.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013). 30 Deutsche Bundesbank Eurosystem, Payment Systems, available at http:// www.bundesbank.de/Redaktion/EN/Standardartikel/Core_business_areas/Payment _systems/payment_systems.html (last visited 11 December 2013). 31 Deutsche Bundesbank Eurosystem, TARGET2 – An Integrated Europe for Individual Payments, available at http://www.bundesbank.de/Redaktion/EN/ Standardartikel/Core_business_areas/Payment_systems/target2.html (last visited 11 December 2013) and NBS Decision 7 at § 1(1). 32 The standard contract that must be executed by Slovakian financial institutions with the National Bank of Slovakia is available at https:// www.nbs.sk /_img / Documents / BANKY/ MPS / TARGET2 / Zmluva_o_ucasti_v_ T2SK.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013). 27 Bank account relationships 119 characterized as indirect participants.33 Each direct participant must hold a payment transaction account in TARGET2 that is administered by the central bank that operates the state’s RTGS system to which the direct participant belongs.34 BANK ACCOUNT RELATIONSHIPS AT LOWER TIERS AND RIGHTS TO MONEY A typical relationship between a customer and its bank involves two elements that are relevant in the context of this Part: 1) the depositary relationship and 2) the funds transfer relationship. The depositary relationship is concerned with the opening of an account and deposits or withdrawals of funds. The funds transfer relationship regulates transfers of funds from and to the deposit account.35 In most jurisdictions (e.g., Slovakia), the funds transfer relationship is regulated as part of the depository relationship. Typically, Civil or Commercial Codes provide for deposit account contracts and regulate funds transfers as their integral element. Funds transfers at the highest level are regulated in special laws and regulations issued by central banks. In other jurisdictions (e.g., the United States), funds transfers are regulated in a specific law separate from deposit account relationships. This law (e.g., UCC 4A) may be applicable to all relationships in the holding structure, irrespective of the level. The following paragraphs examine relevant aspects of both of these relationships. Bank Deposits Customers may enter into two fundamental types of depositary relationships with banks, known as: 1) irregular (general) and 2) regular (special).36 The distinction between the irregular and regular deposit has 33 Deutsche Bundesbank Eurosystem, TARGET2 – Participation, available at http://www.bundesbank.de/Navigation/EN/Core_business_areas/Payment_systems/ TARGET2/Participation/participation.html (last visited 11 December 2013). 34 Bundesbank Eurosystem, TARGET2 – Services, available at http://www. bundesbank.de/Navigation/EN/Core_business_areas/Payment_systems/TARGET2/ Services/services.html (last visited 11 December 2013). 35 In addition to these two functions, banks also provide other services such as loans, credit cards, collections, etc. 36 See Marine Bank v. Fulton Bank, 69 U.S. 252, 256 (1864) in which the US Supreme Court stated ‘there are two types of deposits; one where the bank 120 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts a number of consequences. For instance, the bank’s right of set-off may or may not be available depending on the classification of the deposit as either irregular or regular. For the irregular deposit the bank may be able to exercise its right of set-off. In contrast, the regular deposit does not permit offsetting an asset against a debt and the proper remedy instead may be foreclosure or forfeiture.37 Under the regular deposit the relationship between the depositor and the bank is that of bailor and bailee.38 It is not a relationship based on contract but is instead based on property. The depositor does not surrender ownership rights to the bank and the bank does not acquire any rights to use or commingle the object of deposit. This type of relationship is established when the bank accepts cash or other valuables for ‘safekeeping’. Unlike in the case of the irregular deposit, cash held in a safe-deposit box may not be commingled with the funds of other depositors. The bank has a duty to restore the identical asset to the depositor on demand.39 The core of this relationship is not a transferable account balance but a fiduciary duty of the bank to care for the property of its depositors. Civil-law jurisdictions regulate depository relationships in their Civil and Commercial Codes.40 In Mexico, bank depository relationships are regulated in the General Law on Negotiable Instruments and Credit Operations (Ley General de Tı́tulos y Operaciones de Crédito of 27 August 1932) rather than in the Civil or Commercial Code. Under the regular type of deposit the bank undertakes to receive certain items into its custody in exchange for the customer’s obligation to pay a fee for the bank’s services. Money and other valuables may be given in regular deposit and ‘they will be locked in a safe box and a key to the safe box given to the depositor’.41 The depository is required, on demand, to becomes bailee of the depositor who retains title to the deposited funds; and the other where the depositor relinquishes title to the funds and loans it to the bank’. 37 Carl v. Republic Sec. Bank, 282 F.Supp. 2d 1358 (So. Dist. Fl. 2003). 38 Scammon v. Kimball, 92 U.S. 362, 369 (1876). 39 Obchodný zákonnı́k, (Slovakian Commercial Code) 5 November 1991, (513/1991 Z.z.), § 706, available at http://www.szk.sk/files/legislativa/1991-513_ znenie_20130201.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013). 40 See BGB §§ 372-386 and Slovakian Commercial Code §§ 700–7 that provide for ‘a contract on deposit of an item left for safekeeping with a bank,’ and CÓD. CIV. (Arg.), art. 2188 that provides ‘El depósito voluntario es regular o irregular’. 41 This is the wording in CÓDIGO CIVIL [C. CIV.], art. 2246 (Colom.). Bank account relationships 121 return the deposited asset with any accrued proceeds (e.g., dividends collected with respect to a stock). In the absence of specific statutory regulations, it is up to the courts to determine the nature of deposit. US courts have held that a special deposit may be created by an express or implicit agreement that the bank will hold funds for safekeeping with ownership remaining with the customer.42 The first step is for the court to analyse the terms of any bank account agreement to determine the nature of the deposit. If an agreement has not been executed or is ambiguous, the second step for the court is to determine whether the bank had actual knowledge of the source of the deposited funds. For instance, if the bank was aware of an interest of a third party in the deposited funds the court will establish a special deposit was made by implication.43 The bank may gain such knowledge when, for instance, the bank account is designated as a ‘Security Escrow Account’.44 In contrast, names and indications on checks and deposit slips may not impute such knowledge to the bank.45 Unlike the regular deposit that is based on property, irregular (general) bank deposits are based on contractual rights. A general bank deposit is essentially a loan transaction whereby the depositor lends funds to the bank in exchange for receiving credit to his bank account. Under the general deposit, customers transfer ownership and the right to use the funds to the bank and the relationship between the depositor and the bank is that of a creditor and debtor.46 If the account balance is positive the depositor is the creditor and the bank is the debtor. If the balance is negative, such as when the depositor overdraws the account balance, then the positions are reversed. At the core of this relationship is the transferable bank account balance that is of a contractual nature. According to Professor Ellinger ‘the essence of the contract of banker and Carl v. Republic Sec. Bank, 282 F.Supp. 2d 1370 (So. Dist. Fl. 2003). Aetna Cas. & Sur. Co. v. Atlantic Nat., 430 F.2d 574, 577 (5th Cir. 1970) and Carl v. Republic Sec. Bank, 282 F.Supp. 2d 1369 (So. Dist. Fl. 2003). 44 Nardi v. Continental Nat. Bank, 559 So.2d 307, 309 (District Ct. of Appeal Fl, 3rd Dist. 1990). 45 In Sony Corp. of Am. v. Bank One, 85 F.3d 131, 139 (4th Cir. 1996), the court held that special words on checks and deposit slips have a mere recordkeeping function that in no way earmark the transferred funds. 46 CHARLES PROCTOR, MANN ON THE LEGAL ASPECT OF MONEY 7 (6th edn. OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS, OXFORD, UK, 2006). 42 43 122 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts customer is the bank’s right to use the money for its own purposes, and its undertaking to repay it on demand’.47 In civil-law jurisdictions the bank deposit is classified as an irregular deposit.48 The Slovakian Commercial Code regulates the current account contract (the irregular deposit) in Articles 708–715. The current account is equivalent to a checking account that is used for day-to-day purchases and other retail payments. Articles 716–719a regulate the deposit account contract that is a type of a savings account. Both of these banking contracts are based on the irregular deposit. In Mexico the irregular deposit of money is governed by the General Law on Negotiable Instruments and Credit Operations. Pursuant to Article 267 the deposit of a certain sum of money transfers ownership to the depository. This Law also provides detailed rules on the opening of checking accounts and related transactions. The Central Bank of Mexico also issued regulations that govern bank deposits, various banking operations as well as some aspects of transactions with funds deposited in accounts.49 Absence of statutory rules leaves the questions related to the nature of deposits and the mutual rights and duties of depositors and banks to the courts. In Bank of the Republic v. Millard 77 U.S. 152, 155 (1869), the US Supreme Court noted that ‘… it is an important part of banking to receive deposits, but when they are received, unless there are stipulations to the contrary, they belong to the bank, become part of its general funds, and can be loaned by it as other moneys’.50 The irregular bank account relationship does not involve the actual money as it is merely a representation of the creditor-debtor relationship. 47 E.P. ELLINGER, E. LOMNICKA & R.J.A. HOOLEY, ELLINGER’S MODERN BANKING LAW 122 (4th edn., OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS, OXFORD, UK, 2006). 48 BENJAMIN GEVA, BANK COLLECTIONS AND PAYMENT TRANSACTIONS, COMPARATIVE STUDY OF LEGAL ASPECTS 71 (OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS, OXFORD, UK, 2001). See also CÓD. CIV. (Arg.), art. 2189. 49 Circular 2019/95 relativa a las operaciones activas, pasivas y de servicios de la banca múltiple, issued 20 September 1995, available at http://www. interacciones.com/storage/Circular_2019-95_Banxico.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013). 50 See the decision of the US Supreme Court in Scammon v. Kimball, 92 U.S. 362, 369–70 (1876) in which the court held ‘under the type of deposit that is known as general, the title to the money passes to the banker and the resulting relationship is that of debtor and creditor’. Bank account relationships 123 Protection of Customers The regular deposit protects the depositor by recognizing his property rights to the object of the deposit. Items on regular deposits, including those held in custodial, trust and fiduciary accounts, are not subject to the claims of the bank’s creditors.51 With respect to funds held in irregular deposits the customer has no property rights and is regarded as an unsecured creditor who shares pro-rata with other depositors. However, such a customer is not left unprotected against the woes of its bank. Bank customers’ contractual (unsecured) rights to demand the repayment of deposited funds are reinforced by deposit insurance provided by governments.52 In addition to mandatory insurance schemes in which licensed banks must participate and contribute to, some states have set up supplementary voluntary deposit insurance schemes. For instance, German private banks may become members of the Deposit Protection Fund of the Association of German Banks and German public banks may participate in the Voluntary Guarantee Fund of the Association of German Public Sector Banks.53 An unsecured claim of the depositor against the bank may, through various insurance schemes, become as safe as a property right to money.54 Edward H. Klees, How Safe Are Institutional Assets in a Custodial Bank’s Insolvency?, 68(1) BUS. LAW. 103, 104 (2012). 52 For Mexico, see El Instituto para la Protección al Ahorro Bancario (IPAB), available at http://www.ipab.org.mx/ (last visited 11 December 2013); for Germany, Gesetz über das Kreditwesen, 9 September 1998 (Federal Law Gazette I S.2776) [hereinafter German Banking Act] § 23a, according to which banks and financial institutions have a duty to inform their customers about the deposit guarantee; and for the United States see 12 U.S.C. § 1821(a)(1) (2013). 53 IOSCO, 2013 Survey of Regimes for the Protection, Distribution and/or Transfer of Client Assets, Collated Responses to the Client Protection Survey, Germany, at 160, available at http://www.normativafinanciera.com/normafin/ hemero.nsf /0/3704d483226f67a9c1257b0f003322fe/$FILE /3%20-%20Appendix %20B%20 - %20Collated %20Responses %20to %20the %20Client %20Asset %20 Protection%20Survey.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013). 54 Insurance limits vary across the countries. Most of them are capped, but some systems offer unlimited protection. Some schemes of insurance for bank deposits are based on the principle of co-insurance. DALVINDER SINGH, BANKING REGULATION OF UK AND US FINANCIAL MARKETS 193 (ASHGATE PUBLISHING LTD., HAMPSHIRE, UK, 2007). 51 124 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts REGULATION OF FUNDS TRANSFER RELATIONSHIPS As highlighted above, bank money derives its value from legal claims against the banks that maintain deposit accounts for their customers.55 Legal claims against the bank are of a contractual nature and the bank account holder is not granted any traceable property rights to coins or banknotes that he deposits.56 The contractual nature of the depository relationship is also a basis for the funds transfer relationship. As a consequence of the absence of specific money and identifiable property rights in the depository relationship, funds transfers do not affect any property rights or circulate actual money. Instead they modify contractual relationships. In some jurisdictions funds transfer services are regulated as a component of the depository relationship and the law of deposit provided for in Civil and Commercial Codes. However a number of European and Latin American countries recently adopted specific legislation governing transfers of funds, which largely applies to the relationships at the top level between the operator of a LVFTS and its participants. In the United States the law of payments has been codified in UCC 4A for about 20 years.57 UCC 4A applies to any funds transfer relationships irrespective of the level in which they arise. Nevertheless, the law that governs funds transfer relationships is a relatively new phenomenon. A legal framework to govern funds transfers became a necessity in the 1990s after the check system was pushed aside by the use of funds transfers.58 Funds transfer law is unique because it affects the movement of much larger volume of funds than the law of checks and other negotiable instruments.59 Absence and uncertainty of the rules applicable to funds 55 See also CARL MENGER, Money, translated by Leland B. Yager with Monika Streissler in CARL MENGER AND THE EVOLUTION OF PAYMENTS SYSTEMS, FROM BARTER TO ELECTRONIC MONEY 36 (Michael Latzer & Stefan W. Schmitz eds., EDWARD ELGAR PUB., CHELTENHAM, UK, 2002). 56 DAVID COX, PROPERTY RIGHTS IN MONEY 12 (OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS, OXFORD, UK, 2008). 57 UCC Article 4A (1989) was amended in 2012 to implement a change brought about by the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act that amended the federal Electronic Funds Transfer Act, effective as of February 2013. The UCC Article 4A Amendment expressly excludes remittance transfers from its scope. 58 James S. Rogers, Unification of Payments Law and the Problem of Insolvency Risk in Payment Systems, 83 CHI.-KENT. L. REV. 689, 690 (2008). 59 Raj Bhala, The Inverted Pyramid of Wire Transfer Law, 82 KY. L.J. 347, 349 (1993). Bank account relationships 125 transfers may present a significant risk in the entire payment system.60 Presently, in an environment where almost every individual and institution uses funds transfers, adequate regulation of the relationships, rights and duties implicated in funds transfers merits attention. In the United States, prior to the codification of the law of funds transfers in UCC 4A rights and obligations arising from funds transfers were governed by banking contracts (deposit account agreements) and the law of negotiable instruments, particularly the rules applicable to payments by checks.61 The law of checks provided guidance to the participants, but only to a certain extent because this payment mechanism is totally different from a funds transfer. Nevertheless, US courts found a number of important analogies within the checks law to resolve complex issues involved in funds transfer relationships.62 Gradually the old statutes that formed the negotiable instruments law developed for a paper-based world have become insufficient to regulate the world of electronic payment systems.63 Given the importance of LVFTSs, UCC 4A was drafted in a ‘machine code’ that provided very little room for variation by agreement.64 UCC 4A may be supplemented by funds transfer system rules issued by Jeffrey C. Marquardt, Payment System Policy Issues and Analysis, in THE PAYMENT SYSTEM, DESIGN, MANAGEMENT, AND SUPERVISION 134 (Bruce J. Summers ed., INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND, WASHINGTON, DC, 1994). 61 Some authors observed that this contractual regulation of funds transfers was unfair to the user community because banks regularly reserved the right to unilaterally change the terms of account agreements. Peter A. Alces & Jason M. Hopkins, Carrying a Good Joke too Far, 83 CHI.-KENT. L. REV. 879, 886 (2008). 62 The 2nd Circuit court in the Delbrueck case used the finality of cashier checks rules as the benchmark to determine the finality rule for funds transfers. Delbrueck & Co. v. Manufacturers Hanover Trust Co., 609 F.2d 1047 (2d Cir. 1979). 63 Thomas C. Baxter Jr., The UCC Thrives in the Law of Commercial Payment, Symposium: Is the UCC Dead, or Alive and Well? Practitioners’ Perspectives, 28 LOY. L. A. L. REV. 113, 122 (1994). See also Stephanie Heller, An Endangered Species: The Increasing Irrelevance of Article 4 of the UCC in an Electronic-Based Payments System, 40 LOY. L.A. L. REV. 513 (2006), who noted that ‘The rules on bank collection set forth in U.C.C. Article 4 (2002) (supplemented by federal statutes and regulations issued by the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System) are increasingly losing their relevance as the bank collection process shifts away from paper check processing and moves toward electronic processing.’ 64 Joseph H. Sommer, Commentary: Where is the Economic Analysis of Payment Law?, 83 CHI.-KENT. L. REV. 751, 759 (2008) and Rogers, supra note 58, at 704. 60 126 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts operators.65 The scope of UCC 4A is built around the key concept of ‘funds transfer’. This concept is broader than ‘wire transfer’ because it applies irrespective of the form in which the payment order is submitted to the bank, including by wire, over the phone or through other electronic means.66 UCC 4A defines a funds transfer as ‘the series of transactions, beginning with the originator’s payment order, made for the purpose of making payment to the beneficiary of the order’.67 The definition contemplates issuance and execution of multiple payment orders that are needed to complete a typical funds transfer. For its completion it requires an acceptance of the payment order by the beneficiary’s bank. Transactions that involve retail transfers, such as those initiated by debit cards, will be covered by other laws such as the Electronic Funds Transfer Act (EFTA).68 In civil-law jurisdictions, Civil and Commercial Codes still provide the fundamental legal framework for the bank deposit relationship and related transfers of funds that arise below the top level. These provisions apply in conjunction with the rules set forth by the relevant EU Directives, such as the PSD, as implemented by the Member States. Nevertheless, domestic laws of EU Member States differ with respect to a number of issues, including the characterization of intermediary banks as substituted agents, sub-agents, etc. and the finality of payment.69 The Directives themselves also deviate from UCC 4A in a number of aspects, such as their expansive scope that applies to debit transfers and consumer transactions. The Codes provisions may apply as they were originally written or as they have been modified recently pursuant to the implementation of supranational rules embodied in EU Directives. As will be seen below some civil-jurisdictions have enacted special payments codes to regulate funds transfers at all levels supplementing the Codes provisions that apply to the low-level relationships. Germany implemented the EU 65 See THOMAS C. BAXTER JR., STEPHANIE A. HELLER & PAUL S. TURNER, THE ABCS OF THE UCC, ARTICLE 4A: FUNDS TRANSFERS 17 (2nd edn. AMERICAN BAR ASSOCIATION, US, 2006). 66 Prefatory Note to UCC Article 4A (1989). 67 Ibid., § 4A-104(a). 68 EFTA is to consumer payments as UCC Article 4A is to commercial payments. Baxter, supra note 63. See also Thomas C. Baxter, Jr. & Raj Bhala, Proper and Improper Execution of Payment Orders, 45 BUS. LAW. 1447, 1450 (1990). 69 BENJAMIN GEVA, THE LAW OF ELECTRONIC FUNDS TRANSFERS, § 4.06, [4] Allocation of Risks: Default by a Bank Other than that of the Beneficiary (MATTHEW BENDER & CO., DANVERS, MA, 2013). Bank account relationships 127 Settlement Finality Directive that resulted in amendments to its Civil Code. Under Article 676(f) of the BGB, the bank has a duty to open a current account for the customer and to credit/debit payments to the account. Article 676(a) of the BGB provides that by entering into a bank transfer contract the bank assumes a duty to the customer to make a specified amount of money available to the beneficiary. In the case that the completion of a funds transfer requires involvement of an intermediary bank, the originator’s bank is required to submit a payment order to the intermediary to make the funds available to the beneficiary’s bank for credit to the beneficiary’s account. The bank is also obligated to notify the customer of any information related to the identity of the transferor for incoming transfers and of the purpose of the transfer.70 The BGB also regulates relationships between banks involved in funds transfers in the form of inter-bank contracts. Article 676(d) provides for an inter-bank payment contract pursuant to which ‘an intermediate banking institution assumes a duty to another banking institution to forward a funds transfer amount to another banking institution or to the banking institution of the beneficiary’. Accordingly, an intermediary bank assumes an obligation to execute a payment order it receives from another banking institution by issuing its own payment order addressed to another intermediary bank or to the beneficiary’s bank. BGB thus provides for two specific funds transfer contracts: 1) one that regulates the relationship between the originator and its bank and 2) another that applies between the originator’s bank and any intermediary bank. However, the regulation of wire transfer relationships is not as comprehensive in the German Civil Code as it is under UCC 4A. Slovakia has implemented the relevant EU Directives by enacting the Law on Payments. Pursuant to Article 1 it regulates execution of domestic and cross-border payments, issuance and use of electronic payment mechanisms, establishment and functioning of payments systems, oversight of payments systems, and resolution of disputes that arise in payment systems. The Law on Payments is very comprehensive and supplements the regulation of deposit accounts and the rights of account holders to dispose of funds included in the Commercial Code. Article 2 provides definitions of funds transfer, payment order, originator, beneficiary and other terms typical for payment systems.71 The payment BGB art. 676(a). A funds transfer is defined as ‘an action undertaken on the basis of a payment order submitted by an originator to an executing institution with the intent to make the funds available to the beneficiary’. A payment order is defined 70 71 128 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts system operator is also obligated to issue and publish payment systems’ rules in the national language.72 Civil and Commercial Codes of a number of Latin American jurisdictions provide only skeletal rules on the bank-customer funds transfer relationship. Such legal regulation of funds transfers is based on checks and generally outdated. The Costa Rican Commercial Code includes rules governing a current account contract.73 Under this type of a contract the depositor acquires the right to dispose of its funds. However, the Commercial Code of Costa Rica presumes that such dispositions shall be made exclusively with checks.74 The right to dispose of the funds by payment orders must be expressly agreed on in the current account contract because it is not presumed.75 On the international level, UNCITRAL adopted a Model Law to provide guidelines for domestic legislators in crafting legislation governing funds transfers. However the Model Law covers only international credit transfers. Although the Model Law was inspired by UCC 4A, on many issues it deviates and even provides rules that are contradictory to the US law, such as the possibility of banks facing liability for consequential damages.76 In addition, one of its defects is the failure to anticipate the existence of funds transfer systems’ rules.77 In comparison to UCC 4A the Model Law provides wider latitude for the parties to account agreements to vary their respective rights and obligations. Variations to the statutory text agreed to in bank account agreements may as an ‘unconditional and certain instruction of the originator, in written or electronic form, to an executing institution to transfer funds’. 72 Slovakian Payments Law § 37(1). 73 See also CÓD. CIV. (Arg.), arts 771–96, which regulate current accounts (cuentas corrientes) in Title XII and provides for its two types: one maintained by commercial entities (cuenta corriente mercantil) and the other maintained by banks (cuenta corriente bancaria). 74 Similarly, CÓD. CIV. (Arg.) does not provide any rules on funds transfers or related rights and obligations. 75 CÓD. COM. (Costa Rica), art. 612 provides: ‘Los giros contra los fondos en cuenta corriente bancaria se harán exclusivamente por medio de cheques, sin perjuicio de las notas de cargo que el depositario emita, cuando para ello estuviere autorizado’. 76 Sneddon, supra note 4, at 1127. Consequential damages, as long as they were foreseeable, may also be recovered under the laws of many civil-law jurisdictions. See GEVA, supra note 69, at § 4.06, [4] Allocation of Risks: Default by a Bank Other than that of the Beneficiary. 77 In the United States, system rules are effective even if they contradict UCC Article 4A provisions governing the rights and obligations between participating banks. See UCC 4A-501(b) (1989). Bank account relationships 129 undermine certainty, predictability and finality of payments. Article 2(a) of the UNCITRAL Model Law defines a credit transfer as a series of operations, beginning with the originator’s payment order, made for the purpose of placing funds at the disposal of a beneficiary. This definition is similar to the UCC 4A definition of funds transfer.78 NATURE OF FUNDS TRANSFER RELATIONSHIPS The following paragraphs examine the nature of funds transfer relationships in light of the preceding overview of their regulation. When banks execute payment orders they do not transfer any property of the depositor because the relationship between a bank and its depositor does not involve any items of property that belong to the depositor. Thus banks executing payment orders submitted by their customers transfer their own funds. Similarly, when they accept incoming payment orders and credit deposit accounts of their customers, funds credited to the customers’ accounts become property of the bank and customers acquire contractual claims for the repayment of funds enforceable against the banks. One may then ask what exactly is the relationship of the bank against an account holder when it executes or accepts a payment order? Is the bank an agent of the customer or does it act as an independent entity that is contractually bound to execute payment orders? If the bank is an agent of the customer, can the customer claim and attempt to enforce its rights against the other banks involved in the chain of transfers? The agency theory characterizing the relationship between the originator and its bank in a funds transfer does not apply under UCC 4A. UCC 4A-212 expressly provides that ‘a receiving bank is not the agent of the sender or beneficiary of the payment order it accepts, or of any other party to the funds transfer, and the bank owes no duty to any party to the funds transfer’. Accordingly, a bank is neither an agent of the originator nor that of the beneficiary. Rather it is an independent entity that is not liable under agency rules when it executes payment orders. Under UCC 4A the bank is liable only for the breach of its duties provided for in the account agreement and applicable funds transfer law. The EU Directives and Member States’ laws do not provide any characterization for the customer-bank funds transfer relationship. Professor Geva argued that ‘under the civil law, the entire relationship between a customer and a bank, under which the latter is to carry out the former’s payment 78 See UCC 4A-104(a) (1989). 130 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts instructions, may be regarded as a mandate’.79 The bank is thus treated as an agent of the customer for purposes of executing his payment orders as well as for purposes of accepting payment orders for his account. The nature of the funds transfer relationship should be examined from the perspective of the rights of depositors in the funds on deposit with their banks. When the beneficiary’s bank receives a funds transfer for its customer it credits his account. By giving the beneficiary credit for the incoming transfer, the bank does not act as an agent because it receives funds in its own right as a borrower vis-à-vis the customer. The beneficiary’s balance is increased and, correspondingly, so is the debt of the beneficiary’s bank owed to the depositor. For an agency to exist the bank must deal with a property of the depositor. A new agency relationship does not arise every time a credit is made to the customer’s bank account. Instead, the existing debtor-creditor relationship is modified as reflected in the adjustments to the account balance.80 Proper characterization of relationships between the account holder and its bank in a funds transfer as either an agency or a loan contract is also relevant to determine the relationships between individual transfers involved in a chain. The question is to what extent the funds transfer relationship affects other relationships that gave rise to the initial transfer or the relationships that arise subsequently after the original transfer in the chain of transfers. First, the relationship that involves a transfer of funds should be independent from any underlying transaction that created the obligation to pay and pursuant to which the payment is to be effected. If the originator agreed to buy inventory for its business that turns out to be defective, the originator should not have any right to unwind a previously completed funds transfer or sue the seller’s bank. The effectiveness of the funds transfer should be abstract from the effectiveness of the underlying transaction.81 Just as a bank that issued a letter of credit need not be concerned with any underlying transaction, so should not the bank that executed a payment order. This is the first level of independence that should be present in funds transfers. The second level of independence should be recognized among the individual funds transfer relationships including: GEVA, supra note 48, at 89. See also GEVA, supra note 69, at § 4.06, [2] Basic Concepts: Characterization, Irrevocability and Discharge. 80 Edmund M.A. Kwaw, The Evolving Law on the Eurobank-Customer Relationship and the Common Law: The Need for Clarity, 32 SYRACUSE J. INT’L. L. & COM. 87, 129 (2004). 81 COX, supra note 56, at 72. 79 Bank account relationships 1) 2) 131 the relationship between the transferor and his bank; the relationship between the transferor’s bank and the beneficiary’s bank; and the relationship between the beneficiary’s bank and the beneficiary. 3) These relationships should also be independent of each other. As a consequence, the originator of a funds transfer should not be able to assert rights against any other entity involved in the chain of transfer, with the exception of its own bank that executed the payment order. Banks should not owe any duties to participants in funds transfers other than the immediate parties that they deal with. This is the rule under UCC 4A where intermediary banks neither owe any duties to originators and beneficiaries nor act as their agents. The independence of funds transfer relationships is based on the principle of ‘privity’.82 Sommer explained that ‘payment systems are built on contract; they rely on bank money; bank money relies on bank deposits; bank deposits are debt obligations; debt is contract. Payment transactions are built from these contractual units.’83 Privity, that is characteristic for these contractual units or relationships, ensures that participants in a particular contractual relationship may not assert any claims against participants in other contractual units. Sommer equated privity with negotiability of rights and concluded that ‘like negotiability, privity demolishes the history of the account, providing finality’.84 Privity not only insulates funds transfer relationships from one another, it also provides the finality of payment, as will be further examined in the next chapter. Sommer noted that payment law is based on principles of ‘privity’ and ‘nominalism’. The latter will not be discussed in this chapter because privity by itself is sufficient to justify independence of funds transfer relationships. Sommer, supra note 64, at 751. 83 Ibid. at 754. 84 Ibid. at 760. 82 7. Funds transfers, finality and security interests The nature of money whether coins, banknotes, or funds in bank accounts determines the relevant legal rules governing transfers. Recall from an earlier discussion that coins and banknotes are items of property whereas funds held in deposit accounts are in their nature contractual claims against banks. Cox noted that ‘A transfer of corporeal money involves an alteration in the spatial location of money with consequent changes in the parties’ rights to possession and ownership of it. In contrast, a transfer of incorporeal money involves an adjustment of the debt liabilities owed by the depository institutions to the transferor and transferee’.1 Accordingly, property law governs transfers of physical money while contract law determines when a transfer of account-based funds occurs. The following paragraphs are concerned only with the latter. TRANSFERS OF ACCOUNT-BASED FUNDS When one analyses a transfer of funds between bank accounts one must forget about property and one must think in terms of contract rights and debt liabilities. Physical location, possession and delivery are relevant only in the analysis of transfers of coins and banknotes, similar to transfers of security certificates and actual physical commodities. The consequence of the nature of bank account relationships as debt liabilities is that in a funds transfer, the transferor’s title to the money is not transferred for the depositor is not the owner thereof. What is transferred is ‘the title to the value’ rather than a title to an identifiable asset.2 The value is represented in a claim of the depositor against its bank. Depending on the involvement of banks and central payments systems funds transfers may be classified into three categories: 1) intra-bank DAVID COX, PROPERTY RIGHTS IN MONEY 31 (OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS, OXFORD, UK, 2008). 2 Ibid., at 165. 1 132 Funds transfers, finality and security interests 133 transfers, 2) inter-bank or correspondent transfers and 3) central payment system transfers. In an intra-bank transfer the depository institution maintains accounts for both the transferor and transferee and completes the transfer by adjusting its own debt liabilities against both the transferor by debit and against the transferee by credit. Both entries are made concurrently or with a short delay. In an inter-bank transfer deposit accounts of the transferor and transferee are maintained by different banks. Accordingly, at least two banks are involved. These two banks may maintain correspondent bank accounts, also known as nostro and vostro accounts, with one another and complete the transfer by entries to those accounts. Alternatively the two banks may maintain correspondent accounts with a third bank that will debit the account of the transferor’s bank and credit the account of the transferee’s bank. However, banks do not maintain such accounts with all correspondents and if this is the case a central payment system, such as the Fedwire, will be utilized. With the increasing volume of payments the correspondent transfer system has been, to a large extent, substituted by central payment systems.3 The funds transfer process is initiated by delivery of an instruction to the bank. This instruction may either be a check or payment order. In the case of a check the payor first hands it over to the payee who in turn delivers the check to his bank for collection. In this process funds are pulled from the payor’s account. In contrast a payment order is delivered by the payor directly to his bank, which will then push funds to the payee’s bank. A payment order is a mere instruction addressed to the bank that does not transfer any funds on its own.4 The payment order is not considered an item of property.5 Other than the receiving bank that executes it, no third party has any rights and duties with respect to such a payment order.6 Accordingly, both the check and payment order trigger the payment process but the funds flow in opposite directions. Depending on the type of payment instruction submitted to the bank, funds transfers 3 BENJAMIN GEVA, BANK COLLECTIONS AND PAYMENT TRANSACTIONS, COMPARATIVE STUDY OF LEGAL ASPECTS 9 (OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS, OXFORD, UK, 2001). 4 Roger Cowie, Cancellation of Wire Transfers under Article 4A of the Uniform Commercial Code: Delbrueck & Co. v. Manufacturers Hanover Trust Co. Revisited, 70 TEX. L. REV. 739, 741 (1992). 5 E.P. ELLINGER, E. LOMNICKA & R.J.A. HOOLEY, ELLINGER’S MODERN BANKING LAW 209 (4th edn. OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS, OXFORD, UK, 2006). 6 Official Comment 3 to UCC 4A-402 (1989). 134 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts are either debit (check) or credit (payment order) transfers.7 This chapter is concerned only with credit transfers that are initiated by payment orders. Payment orders are subject to certain requirements as to their content and form. One of the critical data elements that must be indicated in a payment order is the identification of the beneficiary. Customarily, the transferor is responsible for supplying the correct name of the beneficiary, the account number of the beneficiary and the bank code of the beneficiary’s bank. If the name, bank account number or other information refers to a non-existent beneficiary, the receiving bank may not be able to accept the payment order.8 If the payment order includes a name that is different than the name associated with the bank account number indicated in the same payment order, the beneficiary’s bank may rely on the bank account number and credit such account.9 Reliance on the number facilitates automated processing of payment orders.10 Funds transfers adjust contractual relationships (debt liabilities) among banks and account holders. Such transfers may theoretically be characterized as being accomplished by: 1) negotiation, 2) assignment or 3) novation. For a transfer to be accomplished by negotiation delivery of some document (e.g., a banknote) that reifies intangible rights is required. Only transfers of banknotes involve writings and thus satisfy the requirements for negotiation. Similarly, only bearer securities and documents of title representing commodities may be transferred by negotiation. A payment order to transfer funds is not a negotiable instrument that embodies any rights to money. This leaves the remaining two options to characterize transfers of funds. In an assignment the assignee is said to step into the shoes of the assignor. However, in a funds transfer the transferee does not acquire the same asset or rights that previously belonged to the transferor.11 The 7 Benjamin Geva, Payment Finality and Discharge in Funds Transfers, 83 CHI.-KENT. L. REV. 633, 636 (2008). 8 UCC 4-207(a) (1989). 9 Ibid., 4-207(b)(1). The beneficiary’s bank is not required to determine whether the name and number refer to the same person. 10 PSD permits payors to identify the payee by a unique identifier. Pursuant to art. 74, if a payment order is executed on the basis of the unique identifier, the payment order shall be deemed to have been executed correctly with regard to the payee designated by the unique identifier. In contrast, if the unique identifier provided by the payer is wrong, the payment service provider shall not be liable for erroneous execution. 11 COX, supra note 1, at 171. Funds transfers, finality and security interests 135 transferor does not assign its claims against the bank to the transferee.12 The transferee acquires a new claim against his own bank when the bank accepts the payment order. The transferor’s rights are modified (reduced) against his bank and the rights of the transferee are correspondingly increased against his own bank. No proportion of the transferor’s rights is passed or assigned to the transferee. This is also the case for transfers of account-based securities whereby a claim of one securities account holder against his intermediary is not assigned to another account holder. The assignment theory seems to support only one type of funds transfer where the originator and the beneficiary are the same person, such as when a customer is transferring funds between two of his own accounts.13 Given the mechanics of funds transfers, novation should be the proper characterization.14 When banks debit and credit accounts of their customers their respective rights are newly created or their existing rights are modified. Similar to transfers of account-based securities, transferees do not acquire any assets or rights that previously belonged to their transferors. When banks execute payment orders they transfer their own funds. As a consequence, creditors of the transferor or a transferee should not be able to attach any funds transferred by intermediary banks. Intermediary banks neither hold any property of account holders nor are they in a contractual relationship with the originator or beneficiary. UCC 4A-502(d) is illustrative of this concept in that it provides that ‘the creditor may not serve process on any bank other than the beneficiary’s bank with respect to a payment by the originator to the beneficiary’. The Official Comment 4 then adds: ‘Under English law, regardless of the number of banks involved in a funds transfer process, there is not a single assignment.’ Roy M. Goode, Concepts of Payment in Relation to the Expropriation or Freezing of Bank Deposits, 2(2) J.I.B.L. 80, 81 (1987). 13 Explanatory Note 49 of the UNCITRAL Secretariat to the Model Law on International Credit Transfers notes that ‘in such a case, completion of the credit transfer obviously does not change the legal relationship between the originator and the beneficiary’. See also COX, supra note 1, at 171. 14 Novation is recognized in civil-law jurisdictions as a mechanism that extinguishes debts. See CÓDIGO CIVIL [C. CIV.], art. 1687 (Colom.) that defines novation as a substitution of the existing obligation that results in discharge of the existing obligation. CÓDIGO CIVIL [C. CIV.], art. 2213 (Mex.) provides that novation occurs when interested parties agree to substitute an existing obligation for a new one. 12 136 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts A creditor of the originator can levy on the account of the originator in the originator’s bank before the funds transfer is initiated, but cannot reach any other funds because no property of the originator is being transferred. A creditor of the originator cannot levy on property of the originator and until the funds transfer is completed it may not levy on the account of the beneficiary because the beneficiary has no property interest in the funds transfer prior to its completion by acceptance of the beneficiary’s bank. Intermediary banks must be protected from creditors’ processes and injunctions. Any injunction served on an intermediary bank attempting to enjoin the bank from executing a payment order should be ineffective.15 Such attachments should not be allowed, not only on legal grounds but also due to policy considerations (e.g., protection of international banking) and practical considerations (e.g., increased costs).16 While UCC 4A strictly prohibits attachments to be served on intermediary banks, New York courts have found grounds and ways to circumvent the restriction. In particular, federal maritime law has become the source of arguments justifying the legality of attachments.17 Interests of individual claimants that seek to attach property of others to secure a potential source of payment for future judgments conflict with interests of the banking community. The legal system should provide rules that fairly balance the interests of both groups, such as by providing and enforcing remedies capable of attaching funds but only at the originator’s or beneficiary’s bank not while they are in transit. FINALITY The critical moment for any transfer of funds, securities or other account-based rights is its finality. Only when the transfer becomes final may its recipient rely on it and rest assured that it will not be revoked or Official Comment to UCC 4A-503 (1989). In Reibor Int. Ltd. v. Cargo Carriers, 759 F.2d 262, 268 (2nd Cir. 1985), the court held that ‘a decision permitting attachment of funds transfers might have disruptive consequences for the state banking system and international banking practices’. Recent decisions of US courts also denied requests for continuous service of attachment orders, arguing that it would have disruptive effects on the New York banking industry. See Cala Rosa Marine Co. Ltd. v. Sucres Et Deneres Group, 2009 WL 274486 *4 (2009). 17 See Winter Storm Shipping Ltd. v. TPI, 310 F.3d 263 (2d Cir. 2002); Navalmar (U.K.) Ltd. v. Welspun Gujarat Stahl Rohren, Ltd., 2007 WL 1200067 *9 (S.D.N.Y. 2007); and General Tankers Pte. Ltd. v. Kundan Rice Mills Ltd., 475 F. Supp. 2d 396, 398 (S.D.N.Y. 2007). 15 16 Funds transfers, finality and security interests 137 cancelled by the transferor or a third party. Finality is of utmost importance in funds transfers because payments in a significant majority of financial and commercial transactions are completed as such. Furthermore, funds transfers and deliveries of financial assets such as securities are interconnected and rely on one another. Finality may be defined as ‘a receipt of advice of payment or confirmation of delivery through a system for a particular transaction; the money in question is “good money,” even if at the next instant the sending institution goes bankrupt’.18 The finality of a funds transfer thus translates into the beneficiary receiving the equivalent of cash.19 The following paragraphs examine two types of finality in the context of funds transfers: 1) the finality of a payment order and 2) the finality of a funds transfer (payment). Accordingly, finality is present in two different contexts: 1) between the originator and its bank and 2) between the beneficiary’s bank and the beneficiary. The fundamental rule with respect to execution of payment orders is that the receiving bank has no duty to execute the order unless it has previously agreed to do so. If the originator has an insufficient balance on its account the bank may refuse to execute the order. Once the bank decides to reject a payment order a notice of rejection must be provided to the originator.20 With respect to the finality of payment orders the general rule is that the originator may revoke a payment order before it is executed by the bank. However, mere receipt of revocation instructions by the bank prior to execution may not be sufficient. In addition, the revocation must be received in sufficient time to allow the bank to act.21 The deadline when a revocation must be received may be regulated in See Edward Gerald Corrigan, Perspectives on Payment System Risk Reduction, in THE U.S. PAYMENT SYSTEM: EFFICIENCY, RISK, AND THE ROLE OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE: PROCEEDINGS 130 (David B. Humphrey ed., KLUWER ACADEMIC PUBLISHERS, BOSTON, MA, 1988). Corrigan also added that ‘finality is the key to the containing and minimizing risks that are presented at each level of the payments pyramid’. 19 Jeffrey C. Marquardt, Payment System Policy Issues and Analysis, in THE PAYMENT SYSTEM, DESIGN, MANAGEMENT, AND SUPERVISION 136 (Bruce J. Summers ed., INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND, WASHINGTON, DC, 1994). 20 UCC 4A-210 (1989) and PSD art. 65 provide that ‘where the payment service provider refuses to execute a payment order, the refusal and, if possible, the reasons for it and the procedure for correcting any factual mistakes that led to the refusal shall be notified to the payment service user’. 21 Under UNCITRAL Model Law art. 12(1), a payment order may not be revoked by the sender unless the revocation instruction is received by the bank in a manner sufficient to afford it a reasonable opportunity to act before the actual 18 138 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts funds transfer system rules or private agreements between the parties. In the CHIPS system ‘release’ of a payment message determines its finality.22 Release of a message to the CHIPS operating system is analogous to the execution of a payment order under UCC 4A and unreleased payment messages do not trigger an obligation to pay.23 Upon release of a payment message the sender may no longer revoke the order. In contrast, upon submission of a payment order to a bank under UCC 4A the sender may still revoke the order unless it has been accepted. On average 77 percent of all CHIPS payment messages are released within one second of receipt24 and only about 3 percent are not released for more than 15 minutes.25 Acceptance and release are thus the critical actions that establish finality. In the EU, finality of transfer and payment orders is regulated in the EU Settlement Finality Directive, which applies to both payment orders as well as to orders to transfer securities.26 The objective of the EU Settlement Finality Directive is to ensure that transfer orders cannot be revoked after a moment defined by the rules of the system.27 However, the Directive does not provide a uniform finality rule and instead defers to the rules of the system to which a payment order is submitted.28 A report issued by the European Commission found that ‘none of the EU Member States has any legislation to define the “moment of entry” of a payment order; all Member States defer to the system’s rules’.29 For instance, Article 34 of the Slovakian Payments Law provides that an order becomes irrevocable from the moment of its acceptance by the payments system, which is defined in the rules of such payments time of execution. UCC 4A-211(b) (1989) with respect to modification and cancellation of payment orders is similar. 22 Upon release of a payment message, the obligation is deemed to be finally settled and the receiver is deemed to have received payment for purposes of UCC 4A-209(2)(b). Clearing House Interbank Payments System, Self-Assessment of Compliance with Core Principles for Systematically Important Payment Systems, 1 (November 2007), at 16. 23 Ibid., at 29. 24 Ibid., at 25. 25 Ibid., at 21. 26 EU Settlement Finality Directive Recital 1. 27 Ibid., Recitals 2 and 14. 28 Ibid., art. 5. 29 Report from the Commission, Evaluation Report on the Settlement Finality Directive 98/26/EC (EU 25), at 7. Funds transfers, finality and security interests 139 system.30 In TARGET2 some payment orders submitted by participants may be queued instead of immediately executed or rejected. Such orders whose execution is suspended while in a queue may be revoked by the sender. In Latin America the Costa Rican Regulations on Payments System (Reglamento del Sistema de Pagos) do not provide for a rule that establishes the moment of finality. In contrast, the Mexican Payments Law provides for unconditionality of transfer orders31 as well as their finality and irrevocability in Article 11. With respect to the rules on finality of payment orders the emerging approach among the jurisdictions examined above seems to be that the originator may revoke a payment order only prior to its execution/ acceptance by the receiving bank or its lodgment to the central payments system. Furthermore, the receiving bank must also be afforded a reasonable timeframe to act on the instruction to cancel. Funds transfer legislation typically defers to the system rules to provide specific regulation that determines the finality of payment orders. Finality of transfer must be distinguished from other concepts underlying funds transfer law, including discharge, irreversibility and unconditionality. Discharge is a concept that affects the originatorbeneficiary relationship, while finality of payment affects the beneficiary’s bank-beneficiary relationship.32 Discharge means the satisfaction of an underlying monetary obligation that gave rise to the funds transfer.33 It may be achieved by a funds transfer, delivery of cash, honor of a check, etc. In contrast there is no underlying obligation to be discharged by the beneficiary’s bank vis-à-vis the beneficiary. Finality See also Rozhodnutie Národnej Banky Slovenska zo 16. októbra 2012 č. 7/2012 o pravidlách platobného systému SIPS (National Bank of Slovakia, Decision 7 of 16 October 2012 on regulation for payment system SIPS), available at http://www.nbs.sk/_img/Documents/_Legislativa/_Vestnik/ROZ72012.pdf, at § 15. 31 Article 2o.V defines a payment order as ‘la instrucción incondicional dada por un Participante, a través de un Sistema de Pagos, a otro Participante en ese mismo Sistema de Pagos, para que ponga a disposición del beneficiario designado en dicha instrucción, una cantidad determinada en moneda nacional o extranjera …’. UNCITRAL Model Law defines payment order in art. 2(b) as ‘an unconditional instruction …’. 32 Geva, Payment Finality, supra note 7, at 668. 33 UCC 4A-406(b) (1989) provides for discharge of an obligation owed by the originator to the beneficiary. Official Comment 2 further explains that a discharge is completed by the replacement of the obligor of the obligation, i.e., the originator for the beneficiary’s bank. 30 140 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts may be achieved simultaneously with discharge but that is not the general rule. Finality does not mean an absolute irreversibility of payment in the sense that it eliminates all rights of the originator to recover a payment that was made by mistake or fraud. Laws provide remedies to recover such payments but their enforcement should not lie in the unwinding of individual payments in the chain of transfers.34 Lastly, finality does not allow for conditionality, which distinguishes funds transfer law from the law that regulates the collection of checks. This is because a bank account of the customer who deposited a check for collection may be immediately credited but the final payment or settlement is not made until the check is honored by the payor’s bank. In contrast, credits in funds transfer systems are not conditional or temporal. Once the beneficiary’s bank accepts a payment order and credits the beneficiary’s account the payment should become final. As a result of conditionality the moment when finality occurs differs between the credit and check transfer systems.35 Wood defines payment as ‘the conferring of an unconditional claim in favor of the creditor against a bank acceptable to the creditor in the amount of the agreed payment’.36 Finality of payment determines when the beneficiary acquires such a claim. Under UCC 4A a payment becomes final when the beneficiary’s bank pays the beneficiary, which occurs upon acceptance of the payment order.37 A payment order may be accepted only by the beneficiary’s bank. The originator’s bank and any other intermediary banks do not accept payment orders that they receive but they execute them by issuing their own orders.38 Acceptance by the beneficiary’s bank must be absolute and UCC 4A invalidates any The fact that a payment has become final does not mean that it cannot be unwound on the basis of, for instance, being a preferential transfer under the insolvency law. The return of funds ordered by the insolvency court should not affect the originally settled transfer. DERMOT TURING, CLEARING AND SETTLEMENT IN EUROPE 412 (BLOOMSBURY PROFESSIONAL LTD., HAYWARDS HEATH, UK, 2012). 35 Marquardt, supra note 19, at 136. 36 PHILIP R. WOOD, SET-OFF AND NETTING, DERIVATIVES, CLEARING SYSTEMS 266 (2nd edn., SWEET & MAXWELL LTD., LONDON, UK, 2007). 37 When the bank accepts the payment order it becomes obligated to pay the beneficiary. Official Comment 2 to UCC 4A-405 (1989). 38 Execution of a payment order is in fact issuance of a new payment order that is intended to carry out the sender’s order. Official Comment 2 to UCC 4A-209 (1989). 34 Funds transfers, finality and security interests 141 agreement that allows the bank to recover payment from the beneficiary.39 Unconditional acceptance produces finality of payment under US law. Professor Geva noted that ‘upon acceptance, the bank’s incurring of the debt to the beneficiary is tantamount to finality of payment; it constitutes both a mode and result of acceptance’.40 Under US law acceptance, and thus finality, is not necessarily synonymous with the crediting of the beneficiary’s deposit account. Acceptance is broader than crediting a bank account and may also occur under UCC 4A-209(b) by notification of payment to the beneficiary, receipt of payment from the sender, or on the opening of the next funds transfer business day following the payment date of the order. Recall from Part I that a security entitlement may be acquired under UCC 8-501(b) upon receipt of a financial asset and its acceptance for credit by the intermediary. In other words a security entitlement may be constituted even before the securities intermediary formally credits a securities account of its customer. Similarly, a payment may occur and become final when the bank receives funds from the sender even before it formally credits an account of the beneficiary. The EU Settlement Finality Directive and other rules issued by regulators and operators of central payment systems focus primarily on the finality of the payment order and the right of the originator to revoke such an order. They neither address the finality of payment nor the concept of acceptance. Likewise, one of the frequently cited deficiencies of the UNCITRAL Model Law is the absence of a ‘receiver finality rule’. This gap creates an uncertainty as to the moment from which a credit made by a bank to an account becomes irrevocable.41 In general, civil-law jurisdictions rely primarily on the straightforward rule of crediting the beneficiary’s account to establish the finality of payment. Professor Geva found that this objective test is followed in Germany, Switzerland, Quebec and Japan.42 In Germany, for the finality of payment Article 676(a)(4) of the German Civil Code defers to the Ibid. at 4A-405(c). Geva, Payment Finality, supra note 7, at 646. 41 At the heart of the problem is the ‘execution period’ concept that allows a receiving bank ‘one or two days’ to execute a payment order. Raj Bhala, Paying for the Deal: An Analysis of Wire Transfer Law and International Financial Market Interest Groups, 42 U. KAN. L. REV. 667, 682–9 (1994). 42 GEVA, BANK COLLECTIONS, supra note 3, at 212. See also BENJAMIN GEVA, THE LAW OF ELECTRONIC FUNDS TRANSFERS, § 4.06, [2] Basic Concepts: Characterization, Irrevocability and Discharge (MATTHEW BENDER & CO., DANVERS, MA, 2013). 39 40 142 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts system rules and thus indirectly recognizes the crediting of an account as the point at which transfers become final. The German Federal Supreme Court held that notification to the creditor is unnecessary to complete the payment.43 Accordingly no action other than credit to the beneficiary’s account is required to establish finality. Under Article 676(g) of the German Civil Code the beneficiary’s bank must credit an account of the customer within a fixed period of time. In the case that no agreement between the bank and its customer exists, the bank must credit the customer’s account within one banking day after the day on which it received the payment.44 Credit to the beneficiary’s account also produces the finality of transfer in Slovakia. Neither the Slovakian Commercial Code nor the Payments Law provides a clear finality rule. Instead both defer to the rules applicable to the SIPS administered by the National Bank of Slovakia, under which banks acquire the right to dispose of the funds once SIPS credits the bank’s account with the incoming wire transfer. The Brazilian payment system also follows the approach under which substantive law defers to the system rules to establish a finality rule. In Brazil the finality of payment coincides with the moment of posting the credit to a settlement account. Only thereafter is the participant notified that it received the credit but the notification itself is irrelevant to establish finality.45 In Mexico, banks that participate in the central payment system must execute customers’ payment orders within ten minutes after they have received them. Recipient banks must then credit payments to their customers’ accounts within ten minutes after a payment is received from the originator’s bank. Although these deadlines do not provide a clear finality rule, it may be inferred that the payment becomes final when the beneficiary’s bank receives payment from the originator’s bank and credits the beneficiary’s account.46 43 See the decision 25 January 1988, BGHZ 103, 143, cited in CHARLES PROCTOR, MANN ON THE LEGAL ASPECT OF MONEY 172 (6th edn., OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS, OXFORD, UK, 2006). 44 If the bank fails to credit the account of the customer, pursuant to an agreement or the fallback rule provided in the Civil Code, it shall be responsible for interest for the duration of the delay. 45 Banco Central do Brasil, Brazilian Payment System, 10 (Sep. 2009). See also Banco Central do Brasil, Reserves Transfer System – STR, available at http://www.bcb.gov.br/?STREN (last visited 11 December 2013). 46 Some authors argue that in the Mexican system, payments become final when the bank receives a settlement notice which may precede the actual credit to its account. See Bruce J. Summers & Kirstin E. Wells, Emergence of Funds transfers, finality and security interests 143 The preceding paragraphs examined the finality of transfer in the systems that provide central payment services on an RTGS basis. NT systems also provide intraday finality even though deposit accounts of the participants are not adjusted until the end of the day. In NT systems the moment that establishes finality of payment does not coincide with the crediting of the recipient’s account. CHIPS provides intraday finality although the relevant accounts of its participants are not finally settled until the end of the day when CHIPS sends payment orders over Fedwire. FUNDS CREDITED TO BANK ACCOUNTS AS COLLATERAL Funds maintained in bank accounts are used not only for payment purposes but may also secure obligations such as loans provided to bank account holders.47 The asset that is taken as collateral is not any actual money or physical object but is the rights of depositors against their banks. These rights may be encumbered as original collateral or claimed as proceeds arising from the disposition of some other collateral (e.g., sale of inventory). On an imaginary liquidity scale deposit accounts are the most liquid type of collateral and creditors ordinarily rely on the bank account balances of their debtors for the repayment of secured debts.48 In the case of default it is much easier to satisfy an outstanding debt by debiting a credit balance from a bank account than selling inventory in an auction. Sommer explained the nature of a security interest in deposit accounts and funds credited to accounts as follows: Immediate Funds Transfer as a General-Purpose Means of Payment, 3Q ECON. PERSP. 104 (2011). 47 On the use of money to secure obligations between counterparties to a derivative contract see Sterling H. Dietze, Is Cash Collateral King Again in Quebec?, 28 B.F.L.R. 277 (2013). 48 UN Commission on Int’l Trade Law, UNCITRAL Legislative Guide on Secured Transactions, UN Sales No. E.09.V.12 (2010) [hereinafter UNCITRAL Legislative Guide] refers to a security right in a right to payment of funds credited to a bank account. See Recommendation 26 on the creation of a security right. UCC 9-314(a) (1999) provides that a security interest may be perfected in a deposit account. Some authors argue that security interests may be created only over the right to payment of funds credited to the bank account rather than the bank account itself. N. ORKUN AKSELI, INTERNATIONAL SECURED TRANSACTIONS LAW, FACILITATION OF CREDIT AND INTERNATIONAL CONVENTIONS AND INSTRUMENTS 157 (ROUTLEDGE, ABINGDON, UK, 2011). 144 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts the point is that the deposit account is indeed a floating security interest, which ebbs and flows; one day, the secured creditor might have no security (the account is overdrawn) and the next day it might be oversecured. The security interest is in the debt; there is no property in the flow. The security interest does not attach to the funds in any way. It attaches to the promises of the bank relating to the deposit account. In this sense, the deposit account is similar to an account or other receivable. A security interest attaches to the monetary obligation of the account debtor and not to any funds that the account debtor might have to satisfy the obligation with. The deposit account, like an account receivable, is a discrete property item.49 Until recently, secured transactions laws did not regulate security interests in deposit accounts.50 This was primarily because banks could exercise their rights of set-off, sufficiently protecting their interests, and third parties that did not maintain deposit accounts could have arranged with the debtor to open a special pledge account in which the proceeds of the debtor’s collateral were to be deposited. Countries intending to reform their secured transactions regimes are encouraged to include rules on security interests in bank accounts so as to create a comprehensive legal framework that regulates all types of interests in personal property of the debtor. If bank accounts were to be excluded from the secured transactions law it should, at a minimum, address the potential conflict of the right of set-off with a security interest in the proceeds of some collateral that takes the form of funds deposited in a bank account. A security interest in a bank account is economically and functionally similar to the right of set-off.51 However, legally set-off is not a security interest rather it is a defense to the claim for payment as well as a form of payment that discharges mutual obligations.52 Generally the following four conditions must be satisfied before a bank may exercise its right of set-off: 1) 2) the debtor must have deposited ‘its own’ funds to the bank; the funds may not be deposited for a special purpose or with restrictions; On file with the author. UNCITRAL Legislative Guide also promotes lending secured with deposit accounts and provides rules that facilitate such lending. 51 See the exclusions listed in UCC 9-109 (1999) one of which is set-off. WOOD, supra note 36, at 5 noted that set-off shares similar economic functions with a security interest, but it does not involve any transfer of property. 52 Ibid., at 4. 49 50 Funds transfers, finality and security interests 3) 4) 145 the depositor must owe an existing debt to the bank;53 and mutuality of obligations between the bank and depositor must be present.54 In the case of regular (special) deposits in which the bank does not become the owner of deposited funds, the relationship between the depositor and the bank is that of a bailment which prevents the bank from exercising its right of set-off. In contrast in the case of irregular deposits that represent the creditor-debtor relationship, the bank may exercise its right of set-off provided that all other requirements are satisfied. In the United States the bank’s right of set-off remains uncodified.55 In civil-law countries set-off is regulated in Civil and Commercial Codes. Also the EU Financial Collateral Directive recognizes set-off in Article 4(b) as a tool that the creditor may utilize when enforcing a financial collateral arrangement. Under the common-law approach and any laws following the German legal system, the debtor has to assert the defense of set-off. However, in civil-law countries that follow the French tradition set-off automatically extinguishes mutual debts.56 Legal systems in Latin America follow the French automatic approach to set-off.57 The Mexican Federal Civil Code regulates the right of set-off in Title V and Article 2186 provides that qualifying mutual debts are automatically extinguished by operation of law. In contrast, under Article 388 of the German Civil Code set-off must be accomplished by declaration or demand by one of the parties. Slovakian law follows the German Civil Code and provides that the bank has the right to claim reimbursement for the expenses incurred with respect to the execution of payment orders and 53 Difficulties arise when one of the debts become existing and matured because of its automatic acceleration on the occurrence of an event such as the filing for insolvency. 54 JOHN P.C. DUNCAN, PHILIP F. FRANKLIN, BRUCE PRIDDY & HOWARD RUDA, 4-39 ASSET BASED FINANCING: A TRANSACTIONAL GUIDE, Interests in Borrowers’ Depository Accounts, § 39.02[3] (MATTHEW BENDER & CO., US, 2007). 55 A few states, including Kansas and South Dakota adopted specific legislation to govern the right of set-off. 56 DUNCAN, FRANKLIN, PRIDDY & RUDA, supra note 54, at § 39.02[2]. 57 CÓDIGO CIVIL [C. CIV.] arts 1714–23 (Colom.) regulate set-off. Similar to the French Civil Code, set-off occurs automatically, by the operation of law, without knowledge of the parties. 146 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts may exercise its right of set-off against the customer’s balance.58 However the bank must first make a demand to exercise its right of set-off. Set-off rights may thus be statutory, common-law or contractual. Even in the presence of a specific legal regulation banks routinely reserve set-off rights in their standard bank account agreements. Accordingly, depending on the domestic legislation banks may have to take a number of steps to be able to enforce their set-off rights. Similarly, the process of granting a security interest in a deposit account involves several steps, including creation and perfection. The first task for a creditor is to classify properly the deposit account and funds contained therein as a particular collateral type. Proper classification is important for both the creation of a security interest as well as its perfection. Some secured transactions laws classify deposit accounts as a separate collateral type and provide specific definitions and rules for such accounts while other laws neither provide for a specific type nor include any definitions. Under the latter types of laws it may still be possible to create and perfect such security interests unless bank accounts, and funds deposited in such accounts, are expressly excluded from the scope of those laws. UCC Article 9 (UCC 9) recognizes deposit accounts as discrete property items and provides for a special collateral type and definition of such accounts.59 The UCC 9 definition of a deposit account focuses on the debtor-creditor relationship.60 Similar to UCC 9 the EU Financial Collateral Directive provides for a specific collateral type under the definition of cash that means ‘money represented by a credit to an account, or similar claims on repayment of money (e.g., money market deposits) excluding banknotes’.61 Accordingly, the EU notion of cash is similar to the UCC notion of deposit account. The EU definition of cash does not seem to correspond to the ordinary meaning of cash and may be misleading particularly for some less sophisticated users. Under both COM. C., § 711(1) (Slovk.). UCC 9-102(29) (1999) defines deposit account as ‘a demand, time, savings, passbook, or similar account maintained with a bank’. In turn, UCC § 9-102(8) defines bank as ‘an organization that is engaged in the business of banking. The term includes savings banks, savings and loan associations, credit unions, and trust companies’. 60 Bruce A. Markell, Symposium of Revised UCC Article 9, From Property to Contract and Back: An Examination of Deposit Accounts and Revised Article 9, 74 CHI.-KENT L. REV. 963, 974 (1999). 61 EU Financial Collateral Directive Recital 19 and art. 2(1)(d). 58 59 Funds transfers, finality and security interests 147 legal frameworks the critical element that determines the classification of property as cash or a deposit account is that it must be an obligation owed by a bank or financial institution. Legal money, such as banknotes, is excluded because it is not a claim on a bank. EU Member States generally do not classify deposit accounts as a specific collateral type in their domestic secured transactions legislation.62 Consequently, special perfection and priority rules for security interests in funds credited to deposited accounts do not exist within the EU. The Organization of American States Inter-American Model Law on Secured Transactions (OAS Model Law) does not provide a specific collateral type or a definition of deposit account.63 This is also the case in Mexico. However, the absence of a specific type and definition does not impede the ability of creditors to use deposit accounts as collateral under the OAS Model Law and the local laws in Latin America. Guatemala and Honduras are the pioneering jurisdictions in Latin America whose laws expressly provide for security interests in deposit accounts.64 As noted earlier, bank accounts are special types of receivables owed by banks. This special status may require particular forms of perfecting security interests in deposit accounts. This is also because ordinary businesses that owe debts to others are not typically subject to special legislation such as bank secrecy laws. Furthermore, banks should not be excessively burdened by their customers’ arrangements with third-party creditors and forced to determine priorities among conflicting security interests granted to multiple third parties. Finally, the interests of banks should be protected when third parties creditors attempt to enforce their allegedly perfected security interests in deposit accounts that they claim as proceeds of some other collateral. The following paragraphs discuss the two main forms of perfection for security interests in deposit accounts: 1) control and 2) filing. Perfection by Control As in the case of account-based securities, control is the functional equivalent of delivery of banknotes or coins. Control may involve only 62 See CIV. C. (Slovk.) (Občiansky zákonnı́k), 1.4.1964 (40/1964 Zb.) art. 151(d)(1). 63 ORG. OF AM. STATES (OAS), MODEL INTER-AM. LAW ON SECURED TRANSACTIONS (2002), available at http://www.oas.org/dil/cidipvi-securedtransactions_eng.htm (last visited 11 December 2013). 64 See Ley de Garantı́as Mobiliarias, Decree No. 182-2009, art. 2, 28 de enero del 2010, DIARIO OFICIAL [D.O.] [hereinafter Honduran LGM]. 148 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts the debtor and a bank that is also the creditor, as in a situation in which the creditor itself takes possession of the collateral. Control may also exist in the form of a trilateral arrangement that involves the debtor, bank and a third-party creditor, similar to a situation in which a third party holds possession of the collateral on behalf of the creditor. However, there is a significant difference between possession of cash and control of funds. Under control, the debtor’s right to dispose of the funds is not necessarily frozen yet this is typically the case when the debtor is dispossessed of the collateral. Like a creditor with a perfected security interest in account-based securities, the creditor with control acquires ‘management rights’ over the bank account. In this regard this security interest is in essence non-possessory. Control has been incorporated into a number of secured transactions laws to allow creditors to perfect their security interests in funds credited to bank accounts.65 The EU Financial Collateral Directive provides in Recital 9 that ‘in order to limit the administrative burdens for parties …, the only perfection requirement which national law may impose … should be that the financial collateral is under the control of the collateral taker …’. However, the Directive does not define what constitutes control or whether it may arise in more than one form, thus control is subject to interpretation by domestic courts. In contrast, UCC 9 clearly defines control and sets out the steps necessary for its achievement. The UNCITRAL Legislative Guide on Secured Transactions also defines control and a control agreement in its Terminology section, and includes specific rules on perfecting security interests by control in Chapter III. Control may be achieved differently depending on whether the creditor is the bank that maintains the relevant deposit account or a third party. If the bank that maintains the deposit account takes control, the security interest is automatically perfected without the bank having to file a financing statement in a registry or having to sign a special control agreement.66 The first type of control is automatic and it may be taken only by the bank that maintains the deposit account. This type of automatic control is functionally similar to the bank’s right of set-off. Third parties do not have the option to perfect their security interests automatically because they do not maintain deposit accounts. Such a creditor may either become the bank’s customer with respect to the deposit account or it may enter into a trilateral agreement with the debtor 65 66 Ibid. art. 5(7) defines control. UCC 9-104(a)(1) (1999). Funds transfers, finality and security interests 149 and the bank.67 Perfection by control in which the creditor becomes a customer with respect to the deposit account is primarily used for blocked accounts in which the debtor does not need immediate access to the funds in the account to pay its operating costs.68 In terms of the debtor’s rights to dispose of the encumbered collateral, it is similar to the absolute control over intermediated securities or a possessory pledge. If the debtor needs to retain access to the funds the parties may execute a trilateral control agreement. He may enjoy the use of funds until the creditor submits instructions to the bank enforcing its right of control.69 This type of control adequately balances the rights of all three parties involved. It allows the debtor to use the funds in its business, it grants the creditor the right to block the use of funds and it also protects the interests of the bank. Recall, however, that many jurisdictions do not recognize control agreements with respect to account-based securities and like these securities this is also the case with respect to funds held in deposit accounts. UCC 9 and the UNCITRAL Legislative Guide provide that a control agreement must be concluded among three parties who are the account holder (borrower), the depository bank and the creditor.70 While a control agreement under UCC 9 and the UNCITRAL Legislative Guide requires signatures of the three parties, this is not the case under the EU’s Financial Collateral Directive. The Directive provides that an agreement between the depositor and the creditor without the requirement to obtain acknowledgment from the bank may arguably be sufficient to establish adequate control over the bank account. The ‘EU control’ may thus be established bilaterally without knowledge of the bank. This approach forces banks to resolve potential conflicts of priority and react to demands of unknown creditors who claim to have acquired control. Legislation in a number of Latin American countries, including the already enacted laws in Colombia, El Salvador, Guatemala, and See the definition of control with respect to a right to payment of funds credited to a bank account in the Terminology of the UNCITRAL Legislative Guide. 68 Markell, supra note 60, at 987. 69 In the instruction, the creditor may also order the bank to transfer the funds to the creditor or to a designated third party. Sandra M. Rocks, Perfection without Filing: Often the Better (and Sometimes the only) Way, PLI ORDER NO. 8836, 281 (2006). 70 UNCITRAL Legislative Guide 34 (‘control exists … if the depository bank has concluded a control agreement with the grantor and the secured creditor’). 67 150 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts Honduras follow the UCC 9/UNCITRAL approach that requires participation of all three parties for a control agreement to be enforceable.71 Banks in these jurisdictions supported the inclusion of control agreements on the condition that such security interests would not be perfected without their knowledge and consent. Secured transactions laws should not prejudice the set-off rights of banks. Accordingly, the bank may exercise its rights even if the deposit account is subject to a security interest perfected by filing or via a control agreement in favor of a third party, unless the bank has expressly waived such a right. However, under some circumstances set-off will not be available against a secured creditor when the creditor acquired control by becoming the bank’s customer with respect to the deposit account.72 In this case the mutuality of obligations required for set-off is absent. Even though the debtor owes a debt to the bank, the bank does not owe a debt to the debtor but to the creditor. Creditors seeking to perfect their security interests via control agreements regularly demand that the bank waives its right of set-off. Perfection by Filing or Registration Filing or public registration has been the traditional method for perfecting security interests in all types of personal property. However, jurisdictions have taken a number of approaches when it comes to the possibility of perfecting security interests in deposit accounts by filing, and the priority of such perfection vis-à-vis security interests perfected by control. On the one hand – in the systems such as UCC 9, the Colombian and the Honduran Secured Transactions Laws – filing may not be sufficient or permissible to achieve perfection of a security interest in deposit accounts.73 The proposals to permit perfection by filing were rejected in the initial stages of the UCC 9 revision process by the banking industry.74 The bankers claimed that filing would subject the banks to a duty to determine priorities and deal with unknown parties. The same argument applies to perfection through a bilateral control agreement. Furthermore, it was argued that this possibility may even undermine the 71 See the definition of control in Ley por la cual se promueve el acceso al crédito y se dictan normas sobre garantı́as mobiliarias (Colom.), L. 200, art. 8, 14 May 2013 [hereinafter Colombian LGM]; and Honduran LGM, art. 5(7). 72 UCC 9-104(a)(2) (1999). 73 Ibid., § 9-312(b)(1), Colombian LGM, art. 36 and Honduran LGM, art. 15(5). 74 Markell, supra note 60, at 983. Funds transfers, finality and security interests 151 efficiency of the payment system.75 Many authors have rejected these arguments and pointed out the advantages of filing.76 For instance, filing could be a useful tool limiting the debtor’s opportunities to defraud the creditor. Control over a deposit account does not prevent the debtor from opening a new account at a different bank and siphoning off the funds to that bank account. Perfecting a security interest by filing would extend perfection to all deposit accounts that the debtor may open.77 Recommendation 49 of the UNCITRAL Legislative Guide allows filing to perfect a security interest in deposit accounts as an alternative method to control. However it also recommends that in the case that a security interest has been perfected by filing, the creditor must obtain a court order to initiate enforcement.78 In other words a security interest may be perfected by filing but the bank’s compliance with attempted enforcement measures undertaken by the creditor requires a court order. The OAS Model Law also arguably permits filing to achieve perfection of a security interest in deposit accounts. Article 3(V) defines ‘movable property collateral’ without excluding deposit accounts and Article 10 provides that ‘a security interest in any type of collateral may be publicized by registration …’ Accordingly a deposit account would be treated as an ordinary account receivable and a security interest would require registration for perfection purposes. However, the countries that have thus far implemented the OAS Model Law introduced special rules on deposit accounts and provided for the possibility of perfection by control. 75 Having rejected the proposals for filing, UCC Article 9 provisions ‘protect the integrity of the Fed payment systems in that they give banks control over the settlement of their balances in the payment system’. Steven Walt, After Article 9: Security Interests and Bank Setoffs in Consumer Deposit Accounts, 125 BANKING L.J. 224 (2008). 76 Brian McCall, Money, Money Everywhere but not a Drop to Secure: A Proposal for Amending the Perfection Rules for Security Interests in Money and Deposit Accounts, 74 TENN. L. REV. 669 (2007) at 694 argued that ‘an objection that filing would impede the functioning of the banking system and the finality of payment should be dismissed’. 77 Ibid. 78 UNCITRAL Legislative Guide Recommendation 175. 152 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts Approaches to Perfection Barring full or partial79 exclusion of deposit accounts from the scope of secured transactions laws, four approaches to regulating security interests in deposit accounts may be identified. Under the first approach (as in the OAS Model Law and Mexico), a bank account is treated as any other ordinary receivable and a security interest in it may be perfected by filing, notification or another mechanism provided for the perfection of security interests in accounts receivable, depending on the domestic law. This approach ignores the special nature of deposit accounts and may not provide acceptable protection to the banking industry. Under the second approach (as in UCC 9, Guatemala and Honduras), filing is not permitted and only control achieves perfection. This approach has proven to be the most acceptable to the banking industry. The third approach is represented by the UNCITRAL Legislative Guide, which recommends both filing and control for the perfection of security interests with the priority given to the creditor who perfected by control. This approach seems to balance fairly the rights and interests of bank and non-bank creditors. Finally, the EU Financial Collateral Directive provides for control but does not define what steps are necessary to achieve such control. This approach is problematic because it allows control without consent of the bank. For a jurisdiction that contemplates reforming its secured transactions law, the first approach should not be adopted. If deposit accounts are treated as ordinary accounts receivable, the banking community is expected to oppose the reform as it would subject it to an increased duty to monitor notifications of assignment and public registries, effectively becoming the enforcer of priorities. The second or third approaches are much more credit-friendly and bank-protective. Adoption of the third approach would align the perfection of security interests in deposit accounts with the perfection of security interests in securities accounts and allow non-bank creditors the means to perfect their security interests if the bank has refused to enter into a control agreement. The fourth approach is unacceptable because the lack of definition of control creates legal uncertainty and potentially puts undue burdens on banks. 79 See UCC 9-109(d)(13) (1999), which excludes from its scope assignments of deposit accounts in consumer transactions. 8. Summary of Part II Payment systems are essential components of contemporary commercial infrastructures. Without efficient payments systems the settlement of transactions with securities, commodity contracts and other instruments would be impractical, complicated and expensive. Sellers of securities and other financial assets, as well as providers of services, would be reluctant to fulfill their sides of the bargain unless they were assured that a payment is not only forthcoming but also expeditious. Funds transfers have replaced checks as the dominant payment mechanism for the settlement of commercial and financial transactions. Although the practice of paying via funds transfers is quickly developing and expanding, that is not always the case of the law that supports funds transfer systems. Over the previous two decades a number of LVFTSs, especially in the form of RTGS, have been established. In parallel, national laws of many countries have been reformed and a number of international drafting efforts, at the EU and UN levels, have been undertaken to address the structure of modern payment systems that are composed of bank account relationships. Most jurisdictions have enacted laws and promulgated regulations to govern funds transfers. However, many of these laws and regulations apply only to the relationships at the top level between the operator of the LVFTS and its participants. On the lower levels, legal regulation relies on the concepts underlying payments by checks. Legislators in such jurisdictions should recognize the differences between payments by checks and wire transfers. This is particularly the case of Latin American Civil Codes that recognize bank account contracts and depository relationships but largely address only payments by checks. A legislative framework governing funds transfers must address, at a minimum, the following features and functions. Money no longer circulates in the form of coins and banknotes. In modern economies money circulates in the form of claims against banks embedded in bank accounts (bank money). Claims against banks are transferred and payments are made by electronic entries to bank accounts maintained by intermediaries (banks). Accordingly, laws should recognize funds transfers from/to bank accounts as a valid form of payment 153 154 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts that discharges underlying obligations. Legal definitions of money exclude funds credited to bank accounts because they are not authorized by governments. Bank account funds transfers do not involve transfers of tangible assets and property rights but are completed by adjustments of contractual debts owed by depository banks to their customers. Funds transfers should be recognized as producing the legal effect on underlying obligations equivalent to the delivery of cash and banknotes. However, to distinguish payments by funds transfers from those in cash they require regulation that is based on contracts separate from property law. For the most part this aspect has already been adequately addressed in the legislation of the jurisdictions examined in this Part. Funds transfers are completed within a particular legal (software) and structural (hardware) framework. In terms of the hardware, central payment systems come in two forms: 1) RTGS and 2) NT systems. The RTGS model has become the dominant type of system and the few jurisdictions without any LVFTS should implement the RTGS model due to the number of benefits highlighted above. The RTGS model does not rely on clearing and netting but provides immediate booking of all transfers to the deposit accounts of participants as soon as they are processed. Unlike in securities transfer systems clearinghouses and central counterparties are not utilized by LVFTSs. While the previous Part distinguished between the various types of securities holding systems, bank accounts holding systems may not be divided structurally into direct, indirect and transparent. The structure of bank accounts holding systems, as well as the relationships on which they are built, are uniform. Bank account holding systems recognize and, with some minor exceptions, protect the independent nature of individual bank account relationships and prevent third parties from claiming rights under relationships that they are not parties to. When executing payment orders banks act as independent entities. From the nature of bank account relationships it should be apparent that banks deal with deposited funds as their own and do not act as agents dealing with property of their principals, i.e., deposit account holders. Bank accounts holding systems are indirect because rights of the parties exist only within the particular relationship. For instance, bank account holders may not assert claims against intermediary banks or operators of central payment systems. The principles of independence of relationships should be incorporated into legislation governing funds transfers. Unlike in the case of securities accounts systems in which jurisdictions have adopted different classifications for the rights of account holders (e.g., security entitlement, co-ownership, etc.), since the time of Roman law, the right of the depositor against his bank has been characterized Summary of Part II 155 either as proprietary under the regular deposit or as contractual under the irregular deposit. Only the latter provides the basis for modern bank account and funds transfer relationships. Proprietary types of deposit are used only for specific purposes, such as when money or other valuables are segregated and kept identifiable in safe-deposit boxes. Safekeeping relationships based on property may be found in other areas of commercial relationships as well (e.g., custody of securities and physical commodities). Although the right of the depositor against its bank is merely contractual, it is typically protected by deposit insurance that provides almost as effective a protection as property rights. Laws and regulations should also adequately characterize transfers of rights to funds and recognize that the traditional concepts of negotiation and assignment do not apply to funds transfers. Funds transfers neither involve writings that reify rights to money required for negotiation nor assign the right of the transferor against its bank to a transferee. Legislation should recognize that book entries made to deposit accounts transfer rights to funds by novation. Many jurisdictions already recognize novation as a transfer mechanism. An explicit reference in payments laws may be necessary to provide clarity and legal certainty for transfers between deposit accounts. Novation is the key transfer mechanism for both securities held in accounts as well as for funds maintained in accounts. A critical element of every transfer is its finality that determines the moment from which the transferee acquires irrevocable rights to the funds. Efficient systems for transfers of any account-based rights, including securities, funds and commodity contracts, must be supported by clear and predictable rules on finality. Finality must be distinguished from discharge, absolute irreversibility and conditionality. Two types of finality rules were identified in the context of funds transfers: the finality of a payment order and the finality of transfer (payment). While the former applies between the transferor and its bank, the latter applies to relationships between the transferee’s bank and the transferee (beneficiary). The finality of a payment order is regularly established upon its execution by the receiving bank. Most payments have been automated and the bank may not be able to cancel the previous execution once its internal system for processing payment orders is already in motion. Finality of transfers typically coincides with a credit entry made by the bank to the transferee’s bank account. Legal systems that lack clear rules on the finality of transfer should refrain from applying the law of checks by analogy. A credit entry made upon the deposit of a check is merely provisional and does not become final until the check is honored. Finality and irrevocable acquisition of rights should not be delayed beyond 156 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts making a book entry. Legislation should clearly provide that a transfer is final when a book credit entry is made or at some earlier-in-time point when the bank accepts the payment order. At the same time the law should preserve the right of the transferor to recover payments made by mistake or fraudulently. Such recoveries should not be permitted by unwinding executed transfers but only by enforcing remedies outside the chain of transfers. Legislation should provide for effective rules on using funds credited to bank accounts as collateral. Only recently, a number of secured transactions laws extended their scope to deposit accounts that may be used as original collateral. Secured transactions reform projects should enable the taking of security interests in deposit accounts. These laws should not rely on the traditional definitions and perfection mechanisms that apply to other intangible rights such as accounts receivable. A bank account is a special type of receivable that must be recognized as such in secured transactions legislation. Two mechanisms for the perfection of such security interests have emerged: 1) filing and 2) control. Filing is the traditional method for perfecting security interests in all personal property. However, with respect to deposit accounts it has been rejected in some jurisdictions as harming the interests of the banking industry. Other laws permit filing but subject its priority to control, the primary mechanism for perfecting security interests in funds credited to deposit accounts. Perfection of security interests by control requires that the creditor be placed in a position to exercise ‘management rights’ over the funds without further consent of the debtor. Recognition of control as a perfection mechanism, and the form in which it is incorporated into a legal framework, raise a number of policy and practical issues that should be considered in the drafting of the legislation. Modernization of funds transfer and supporting bank accounts holding systems is critical for economic development. Contemporary commercial and financial transactions must be supported by efficient legal and structural frameworks for funds transfers. This Part attempted to highlight the fundamental principles of such a framework. The critical principles and features include independence of bank account relationships, the RTGS model, novation as the transfer mechanism, finality of transfer, and facilitation of security interests. Many of these principles and features are common to both securities and bank accounts holding systems. PART III Commodity Account Relationships 9. Introduction to Part III Similarly to the systems in which securities and funds circulate, systems for the holding and transferring of commodity contracts underwent a significant modernization process in which deliveries of actual commodities against immediate cash payments were replaced with an exchange of promises tradable like securities. Commodities trading became centralized and supported by webs of account relationships that facilitate transfers. Like securities markets, contemporary commodity markets for the acquisition and trading of commodity contracts are electronic, having replaced the markets populated by human traders who executed and confirmed trades by exchanging paper tickets.1 Commodity intermediaries execute orders of their customers on centralized exchanges and maintain commodity accounts for their customers. The essence of commodity contracts and commodity accounts is a contractual promise. Unlike in a traditional spot contract in which an asset is sold and its possession delivered to the buyer in exchange for a purchase price, the buyer of a promise embedded in a commodity contract is not acquiring an asset expecting its delivery. He is acquiring a right to demand delivery of the underlying commodity.2 This promise is ‘delivered’ to the buyer by his intermediary, which credits the buyer’s commodity account. Since the establishment of centralized commodity markets, sellers no longer need to find buyers for their products and for the right price. Long before the harvest the seller may acquire a commodity futures contract to sell his corn through an intermediary who will then credit the seller’s commodity account. For this commodity contract there must be another party willing to buy the corn in the future whose intermediary will also 1 ‘The world’s largest operator of commodity exchanges, CME Group, considers selling its buildings that house trading floors, as a sign of the quick adoption of computer trading.’ Jacob Bungle, For Sale: Top Location (and Trading History), WALL STREET JOURNAL, 21 March 2013, at C1. 2 ‘Futures exchanges deal in contracts for sale or purchase of a commodity that are final and enforceable.’ Ray L. Ross, Financial Consequences of Trading Commodity Futures Contracts, 15(2) ILL. AGRI. ECON. 27 (1975). 159 160 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts make an entry in the commodity account of the buyer. Contracts are held in the form of electronic bookkeeping entries in commodity accounts and settled by similar electronic offsets or deliveries of electronic warehouse receipts. This Part is not concerned with the trading of commodity contracts but examines the transformation from the settlement of trades by physical exchanges of commodities for cash to electronic acquisitions and transfers by book entries to commodity accounts. It analyses both the ‘hardware’ (organizational and structural infrastructure) and the ‘software’ (legal infrastructure) of contemporary systems for the holding of commodity accounts. Throughout this Part, it must be borne in mind that there are two distinct worlds of relationships that arise as a result of commodities trading – one in which actual commodities are sold and bought and another in which rights to commodities are held. These two worlds co-exist but are populated by the entirely different types of market players. The world of physical commodities and their delivery is controlled by growers, farmers, sellers, buyers and other entities that handle actual commodities in their ordinary course of business. In contrast, the world of rights to commodities is controlled by financial ‘paper traders’ who frequently lack the mentality for the world of physical products.3 In their ordinary course of business, these paper traders deal with promises, commodity contracts and commodity accounts. Paper traders neither inspect commodities to determine their soundness or place of origin nor deliver warehouse receipts to settle transactions. Executory promises to future delivery of commodities belong to the broader family of derivatives contracts whose function is not to facilitate consummation of commercial transactions by delivery, but effectively to distribute the risks inherent in such transactions. Derivatives, such as futures contracts and commodity options, are risk-shifting mechanisms that deal in rights and promises independent of the underlying asset.4 The nature of the promise is a monetary obligation to pay the difference in price rather than to make/take delivery of a commodity. For this reason organized commodity markets attract commercial entities that deal in commodities in their ordinary course of business, such as growers of corn, but also attract speculators who take the other side of commodity contracts, thus relieving commercial entities of their risks. If these promises were not in their nature monetary obligations but required 3 LISA ENDLICH, GOLDMAN SACHS, THE CULTURE OF SUCCESS 99–100 (ALFRED A. KNOPF, NEW YORK, NY, 1999). 4 Jayashree B. Gokhale, Hedge to Arrive Contracts: Futures or Forwards, 53 DRAKE L. REV. 55, 57 (2004). Introduction to Part III 161 actual delivery, speculators, such as investment banks, hedge funds and small-scale retail investors, would not participate in such commodity markets. Promises to deliver that are settled by actual delivery are not traded on organized commodity markets but instead are largely traded in over-the-counter (OTC) markets for forward and spot contracts.5 Organized commodity markets for future delivery presuppose the existence of a risk that is marketable and transferable.6 However, commodity markets deal only in those marketable risks that are of a commercial nature, such as volatility in the market price of corn, volatility in the exchange rate of the US dollar against the euro, volatility in the price of government bonds, etc. In contrast, non-marketable risks are ‘the risks whose occurrence is so unpredictable or governed by imponderables that no reasonable odds could be given’ (e.g., the risk of whether a new product will successfully sell in the market).7 Institutionalized commodities trading involves transfers of marketable risks that necessitate the creation of a centralized system supported with commodity accounts holding structures. These marketable risks trade separately from actual commodities, exist embedded within commodity contracts, and are held in accounts maintained by commodity intermediaries. This Part primarily seeks to explain and compare the legal infrastructure that governs systems for the holding of commodity contracts. This analysis conceptualizes these systems within the larger framework of global financial markets and seeks to provide guidance to the legislator in future modernization of the infrastructure. Unlike the holding systems for securities and funds, no international framework, whether binding or model-like, governs the operations of commodity holding systems. The main objective of this Part is to highlight the benefits of commodity contracts and markets for standardized promises of future delivery, as well as to provide a justification for modernization of the legal framework governing their functioning. The fact that commodity markets trade in and hold marketable risks in accounts also raises a question as to the 5 Sometimes the terms ‘market’ and ‘exchange’ are used interchangeably. MICHAEL BLAIR QC & GEORGE WALKER, FINANCIAL MARKETS AND EXCHANGES LAW 19 (OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS, OXFORD, UK, 2007). 6 Kenneth A. Froot, Incentive Problems in Financial Contracting, Impacts on Corporate Financing, Investment, and Risk Management Policies, in THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL SYSTEM, A FUNCTIONAL PERSPECTIVE 256 (Dwight B. Crane, Robert C. Merton, Kenneth A. Froot, Zvi Bodie, Scott P. Mason, Erik R. Sirri, André F. Perold and Peter Tufano eds., HARVARD BUSINESS SCHOOL PRESS, BOSTON, MA, 1995). 7 Ibid., at 257. 162 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts necessity to protect the participants and the uninvolved from the failures of such markets. PROTOTYPICAL TRANSACTION Before providing a historical overview of commodity transactions and the relationships involved one must understand the context in which commodity contracts are acquired/held and identify the parties involved. Suppose that Steve is a farmer that grows corn. Brian owns a pig farm and wants to buy some corn from Steve for feed. Steve stores his corn in a warehouse operated by a third party. Once Steve and Brian agree on all details of the sale, they meet in Steve’s office where they exchange the warehouse receipts representing corn for banknotes. Suppose that Steve endorses and hands over warehouse receipts to 500 kilos of corn and Brian brings US$ 5000 in cash. This transaction involves 1) an agreement to buy corn for a fixed price and 2) its settlement by delivery of warehouse receipts for banknotes. Only the seller and the buyer are involved and they consummate their transaction without any involvement of intermediaries. This type of transaction is known as the spot contract and it is not concluded in an organized commodity exchange. Now suppose that Brian expects the price of corn to increase in the near future and wants to buy as much corn as he can at the present market price. He can buy the corn now and take its delivery. However, this may be impractical because he will have to pay for storage before the corn is consumed. Steve’s other option is to enter into a contract for future delivery whereby he agrees to sell corn for the current market price six months later. Steve will deliver the corn to Brian in six months and Brian will pay Steve at the same time. Brian may be required to provide a down payment when the contract is signed. Delivery of corn in exchange for payment, to be performed in six months, is the back-end function. This type of transaction is known as a forward contract and it is also not concluded in an organized commodity exchange. Brian may thus buy corn on a spot or forward basis and take its delivery now or in the future. Organized commodity markets provide Brian with another opportunity to fix the price of corn for the foreseeable future. Brian may order his intermediary (e.g., Goldman Sachs) to acquire futures commodity contracts to buy corn. To acquire a futures contract, Brian must submit an order to Goldman Sachs that it will execute on the Chicago Board of Trade (CBOT) or some other commodity exchange. CBOT and similar commodity exchanges provide a ready market for buy and sell orders for Introduction to Part III 163 futures commodity contracts. If Brian’s buy order is matched by a sell order the contract to take delivery of corn in six months will be concluded. For the purposes of this illustration assume that Steve instructed his intermediary (e.g., RJO Futures) to acquire a futures contract to sell corn in six months for the price quoted today at the CBOT. Submission of orders, their execution and matching on a commodity exchange are all front-end functions. Unlike in the case of spot and forward contracts, this transaction involves four parties: Brian the buyer, Goldman Sachs his intermediary, Steve the seller, and RJO Futures his intermediary. How then do Steve and Brian receive their respective rights to the future delivery of corn? Steve and Brian never meet each other and do not exchange actual commodities or warehouse receipts for cash. Instead Goldman Sachs will credit Brian’s commodity account with the futures contracts to buy corn and RJO Futures will credit Steve’s commodity account with a futures contract to sell corn. This crediting of commodity accounts will complete one portion of the transfer – the acquisition of futures contracts. Goldman Sachs will then debit Brian’s account for the purchase price (margin) corresponding to the corn futures contracts and RJO Futures will also debit Steve’s account for the portion (margin) of the purchase price for the corn futures contract that he acquired. These entries to Steve’s and Brian’s commodity accounts are an essential back-end function. In commodity markets the back-end functions may thus involve transfers of tangible assets, such as warehouse receipts against banknotes, or transfers of intangible rights to delivery of commodities made by bookkeeping entries to commodity accounts. Organized commodity markets, such as the one where Steve and Brian enter into their futures contracts, are not venues for the delivery of actual commodities. Such commodity markets deal only with promises to make and take delivery that are consummated (performed) by payment. The preceding illustration of the prototypical transaction and the relationships involved is characteristic of commodity markets and their related holding systems in a number of economies. These markets and holding systems, whether situated in developed or developing countries, exhibit similar features. Unlike in the case of securities holding systems, laws governing clearing, settlement, holding and transfers of commodity contracts are based on the same fundamental principles. As in the preceding two Parts, commodity markets from jurisdictions that represent different systems and regions have been selected for points of comparison. Central America has not been selected as a reference market in this Part because no country in that region has established an organized commodity exchange. 164 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts US commodity markets, in many aspects, have provided a model for the establishment of contemporary commodity markets. Established in 1848, the CBOT was the world’s first commodity exchange. In 2007 it merged with the CME to create the world’s largest commodity exchange. For the month of January 2013 the CME Group traded 240 million contracts.8 CME Group trades contracts to delivery of agricultural commodities, energy products, metals, and various financial assets but also trades contracts on some exotic assets such as weather and real estate products.9 One of the largest commodity exchanges in the world is Eurex, which is jointly operated by Deutsche Börse AG and SIX Swiss Exchange. In January 2013 the daily trading volume at exchanges that belong to the Eurex Group averaged 8.7 million contracts.10 Eurex trades contracts to future delivery of financial assets, agricultural commodities as well as metals. It is a fully electronic trading platform without floor brokers. In the eastern part of the EU Slovakia’s Commodity Exchange Bratislava (CEB) was founded in 1992 and commodity contracts may be traded electronically as well as through authorized floor brokers.11 However, presently the exchange does not offer contracts to future delivery of financial assets. A 2008 study by the Futures Industry Association found that 39 percent of all global futures trading was concentrated in North America, 28 percent in Asia-Pacific, 23 percent in Europe and slightly less than 5 percent in Latin America.12 Latin America is characterized by the lowest presence of commodity and securities trading among these regions. The Argentinian commodity exchange, Rosario Futures Exchange (ROFEX), Chicago Mercantile Exchange Group (CMEG), Exchange Volume Report – Monthly, January 2013, available at http://investor.cmegroup.com/investorrelations/releasedetail.cfm?ReleaseID=737570 (last visited 11 December 2013) 19. 9 Trading Volume, FUTURES INDUSTRY, January 2013, at 13. 10 Deutsche Börse AG, Average Daily Volume of 8.7 million Contracts at EUREX Group in January (1 January 2013), available at http://deutsche-boerse. com /dbg /dispatch/en /notescontent /dbg_nav/press/10_Latest_Press_Releases/30_ Eurex/INTEGRATE/mr_pressreleases?notesDoc=C1B8B27A2F1715D8C1257B0 5005E0067&newstitle=averagedailyvolumeof8.7million&location=press (last visited 11 December 2013). 11 CEB History is available at http://www.en.kbb.sk/About%20CEB/ (last visited 11 December 2013). 12 Galen Burghardt & Will Acworth, 2008 A Wild Ride, Global Futures and Options Volume Rises 13.7%, but Credit Crisis Damages Liquidity in the Core Markets, FUTURES INDUSTRY, March 2009, at 17. 8 Introduction to Part III 165 was chosen as the reference point for Latin America in this Part instead of Brazil because it is an example of an agricultural commodity exchange that emerged from pre-existing market practices. ROFEX trades futures contracts and options to delivery of agricultural commodities and financial assets. In its fiscal year ending July 2011 its financial derivatives division traded over 54 million contracts and its agricultural derivatives division traded contracts related to over 8 million tons of agricultural products.13 The efforts to establish a commodity exchange in Mexico date back to the 1994 initiative of the Mexican Stock Exchange and the central securities depository Indeval. The Mexican Stock Exchange financed the establishment of the commodity exchange – Mercado Mexicano de Derivados, S.A. de C.V (MexDer) and Indeval provided technological and financial support to the clearinghouse Asigna, Compensación y Liquidación (Asigna). In the month of January 2012 over 16 000 trades were executed on MexDer, totaling almost 4 million futures contracts.14 Currently MexDer does not provide a market for futures contracts to delivery of agricultural commodities and its trading platform is restricted to financial assets. This context is important for the upcoming discussion concerning the types of commodity contracts, the structure of exchanges and clearinghouses, the rights and obligations of parties involved and the settlement of transactions. BRIEF EVOLUTION OF COMMODITIES The following paragraphs highlight the key developments in the history of trading with commodities from which the present-day structure of organized commodity markets evolved. Since contemporary systems for the holding of commodity accounts are in their nature intermediated, the historical overview begins in the era when the first intermediaries became involved in transferring commodities. Intermediation was also a crucial milestone in the development of modern banking and securities holding systems. While goldsmiths were instrumental in the evolution of the custody of money and securities, religious temples laid the foundation for the custody of commodities. To facilitate grain trading, temple granaries often provided space for warehousing of grain, established quantity and 13 ROFEX, Annual Report and Financial Statements, Fiscal Year 102, 1 (August 2010–July 2011). 14 MexDer, Market Statistics, January 2012 available via http:// www.mexder.com.mx/wb3/wb/MEX/estadisticas (last visited 11 December 2013). 166 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts quality standards and provided clearing services.15 They systematically catalogued stored commodities and even developed a color-coding system that they used to identify individual types of assets.16 The temples provided an assurance of availability and quality of grain to be delivered in the settlement of commodity contracts. The second important time period in the evolution of commodity contracts was medieval Europe. The fairs of Champagne17 organized in the twelfth century were probably the first marketplace formally based on contracts for future delivery.18 Trading at the fairs was ongoing throughout the week with the settlement of accounts and outstanding debts reserved for the last few days.19 Despite the deferral of settlement, both promises to pay and to deliver were enforceable from the moment they were incurred. Furthermore, the emerging medieval code of mercantile law informally codified the existing practices related to the methods of sampling, inspecting and grading of commodities.20 Similar to the system of weights and finesses that facilitated the exchangeability of precious metals as money, the commodities grading system was one of the key factors that made commodity contracts easily transferable.21 The recognition of executory promises in the medieval fair practice, and standardization of commodities grading systems, facilitated trading in ‘commodity rights’. Soon the promises to deliver and pay incurred during a particular fair were to be settled at the next fair. This further deferral of settlement led to the creation of an impersonal market in 15 EDWARD J. SWAN, BUILDING THE GLOBAL MARKET, A 4000 YEAR HISTORY OF DERIVATIVES 36 (KLUWER LAW INTERNATIONAL, HAGUE, NETHERLANDS, 2000). 16 Richard L. A. Sterba, The Organization and Management of the Temple Corporations in Ancient Mesopotamia, 1(3) ACADEMY OF MANAGEMENT REV. 16, 18 (1976). 17 For a general description of trading practices used at the Champagne fairs see R. D. Face, Techniques of Business in the Trade between the Fairs of Champagne and the South of Europe in the Twelfth and Thirteenth Centuries, 10(3), ECON. HIST. REV. 427–38 (1958). 18 RICHARD J. TEWELES, CHARLES V. HARLOW & HERBERT L. STONE, THE COMMODITY FUTURES GAME, WHO WINS?, WHO LOSES?, WHY? 6 (MCGRAWHILL, NEW YORK, NY, 1974). 19 Ibid. 20 Ibid., at 7 and JULIUS B. BAER & OLIN GLENN SAXON, COMMODITY EXCHANGES AND FUTURES TRADING, PRINCIPLES AND OPERATING METHODS 8 (HARPER, NEW YORK, NY, 1949). 21 Randall S. Kroszner, Can the Financial Markets Privately Regulate Risk? The Development of Derivatives Clearing Houses and Recent Over-the-Counter Innovations, 31(3) Part 2 JOURNAL OF MONEY, CREDIT AND BANKING 3 (1999). Introduction to Part III 167 which the promises of parties needed to be formalized in writing. The medieval fairs spawned a formalized contract that evidenced an obligation to deliver a commodity sometime in the future and that became known as a lettre de faire.22 The written promise incorporated in a lettre de faire was first personalized to the original holder, who claimed the promised goods at the next fair. However, shortly thereafter the holders of these written promises began transferring them to other buyers in anticipation of the next fair.23 The original holders were either not able to attend the next fair or realized they could make a profit if the price of the goods increased in the interim. The market practice and the speculative element thus transformed the lettre de faire from a personalized obligation to deliver into a negotiable document of title, a forerunner to the modern warehouse receipt. The promise of the buyer to pay incurred during the fairs also underwent significant changes. A lettre de faire was exchanged for a formal obligation to pay in the future. Accordingly, the transaction was concluded by incurring two future obligations, to deliver and to pay. Like the obligation to deliver, which was reified in writing, the obligation to pay the purchase price in the future was incorporated into a written form – the bill of exchange. Some fairs even began to specialize in liquidating and settling obligations to pay represented by such bills of exchange. Braudel described the Piacenza as follows ‘No merchandise came to the fair, and very little cash, but literally masses of bills of exchange, which in fact represented the entire wealth of Europe, with payments by the Spanish Empire as the mainstream’.24 Trading in bills of exchange became institutionalized when the Antwerp Exchange was established in 1531.25 These medieval fairs spawned a new type of transaction with commodities, in which both the obligations to deliver and to pay were to be performed in the future. Furthermore, both of these executory promises were formalized in writing and eventually became transferable through TEWELES, HARLOW & STONE, supra note 18, at 7. Ibid. 24 FERNAND BRAUDEL, THE WHEELS OF COMMERCE 91 (UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA PRESS, BERKELEY, CA, 1982). 25 In Antwerp, speculation proliferated and hedgers placed bets on the safe return of ships, on the possibility of Philip II visiting the Netherlands, or the purchase of herrings before they had been caught. E.E. Rich & C.H. Wilson, Vol. V The Economic Organization of Early Modern Europe in THE CAMBRIDGE ECONOMIC HISTORY OF EUROPE 330–1 (CAMBRIDGE UNIVERSITY PRESS, CAMBRIDGE, UK, 1977). 22 23 168 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts market practice. Written promises were still closely related to the underlying commodity and eventually performed by its delivery. Only later, with the establishment of centralized commodity exchanges, did these written promises become divorced from commodities and cease to be performed by actual delivery. Some authors observed that ‘the stock and commodity exchanges of the United States … are the direct or indirect outgrowth of these medieval fairs’.26 Gradually, individualized promises were being transformed into fungible contracts. The transferability of rights to commodities and their divorce from the individualized characteristics were facilitated by two important factors: 1) reification of rights in written documents and 2) standardization/grading of commodities. An efficient commodities market requires that promises, both to pay and to deliver, be fungible, standardized and easily transferable. In medieval times goods were custom-made and manufactured on the basis of pre-existing orders. With the advent of modern manufacturing processes and improvements in growing techniques, standardized products and equal-quality crops began to be produced and grown. The standardized manufacturing procedures and grading of agricultural products facilitated the emergence of transferable promises to deliver. Enforceability and transferability of rights to future delivery of commodities, whether individualized or stored in bulk, became recognized in the European markets in the sixteenth century.27 Having recognized the enforceability of contract promises for future delivery and having taken advantage of the proven viability of the standardized grading system for commodities, England created one of the first modern commodity exchanges when Thomas Gresham established the Royal Exchange in Lombard Street.28 The next milestone in the evolution of commodity markets was the trading of tulips at the beginning of the seventeenth century in the Netherlands. The Dutch tulipomania introduced an important element to commodities trading when it opened access to the general public.29 Professionals as early as the 1550s had traded in Baltic grain and North BAER & SAXON, supra note 20, at 9. SWAN, supra note 15, at 144. 28 TEWELES, HARLOW & STONE, supra note 18, at 7. The Royal Exchange was modeled after the Antwerp Exchange. See Rich & Wilson, supra note 25, at 348. 29 MIKE DASH, TULIPOMANIA, THE STORY OF THE WORLD’S MOST COVETED FLOWER & THE EXTRAORDINARY PASSIONS IT AROUSED 116 (GOLLANCZ, LONDON, UK, 1999). 26 27 Introduction to Part III 169 Sea herring for future delivery but these markets had remained inaccessible to the common people.30 The primary driving force behind the staggering expansion of tulip trading was the widespread acceptance of credit sales. Buyers acquired rights to growing tulips by tendering written promises of payment, known as payment notes, which obligated them to pay the purchase price on delivery. In exchange, sellers issued delivery notes to the buyers committing to deliver the flowers sometime in the future. Flowers were thus no longer sold only when they were in the possession of sellers and were being sold when they were still in the ground.31 Trading in and settlement by delivery of actual commodities morphed into the trading in and settlement by delivery of promises – a promise to deliver was exchanged against a promise to pay. The tulip payment and delivery notes are similar to those traded and transferred at the medieval fairs but with one noticeable difference. The holders of the ‘tulip promises’ were speculators from the general public, while the holders of the ‘fair promises’ were merchants who entered into these contracts for legitimate commercial purposes. The first centralized exchanges of the kind that still exist today for trading in rights to future delivery of commodities were established in the mid-nineteenth century in the United States.32 Organized commodity markets will be explained in the rest of this Part as those in which futures commodity contracts and commodity options are traded and held by investors in commodity accounts with intermediaries. The nineteenth century exchanges were not organized with the purpose of acquiring/ transferring rights to commodities in the form of futures contracts. The primary purpose for the establishment of the CBOT in 1848 was to provide a general meeting place for merchants where they could discuss and resolve commercial issues.33 On the other side of the Atlantic, the London and Liverpool commodity markets also originated as informal 30 JAN DE VRIES & AD VAN DER WOUDE, THE FIRST MODERN ECONOMY, SUCCESS, FAILURE, AND PERSEVERANCE OF THE DUTCH ECONOMY 1500–1815 150 (CAMBRIDGE UNIVERSITY PRESS, CAMBRIDGE, UK, 1997). 31 DASH, supra note 29, at 114. 32 The first evidence of organized trading dates before the Civil War when Chicago became the center for trading in commodities. GEORGE WRIGHT HOFFMAN, FUTURE TRADING UPON ORGANIZED COMMODITY MARKETS IN THE UNITED STATES 9 (UNIVERSITY OF PENNSYLVANIA PRESS, PHILADELPHIA, PA, 1932). 33 JONATHAN LURIE, THE CHICAGO BOARD OF TRADE 1859–1905 25 (UNIVERSITY OF ILLINOIS PRESS, CHAMPAIGN, IL, 1979). Similarly, the corporate charter of the New York Cotton Exchange authorized it to provide a suitable space for trading to its members. Kenneth J. Lipartito, The New York Cotton 170 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts gatherings of merchants.34 These nineteenth century commodity exchanges functioned as modern-day medieval fairs. Their utility was limited in that they provided a mere forum where transactions in commodities were concluded and settled. Only later, at the beginning of the twentieth century in the United States and in the late nineteenth century in Europe, did organized commodities exchange models supported with multilateral settlement of contracts structured around a central clearinghouse emerge.35 This became possible by the introduction of common grading standards. These standards added an important layer of predictability and certainty, thus elevating commodity contracts to the category of highly liquid and marketable financial instruments.36 Initially the nineteenth century futures contracts were based (written) exclusively on agricultural commodities.37 The first standardized futures contract for delivery of grain was traded on the CBOT in 1865.38 In contrast to the market price stabilizing function of the first agricultural futures contracts traded in Chicago, many European countries viewed futures commodity contracts negatively at that time. In 1896 Germany entirely outlawed all futures trading in grains39 and the French parliament unsuccessfully attempted to replicate the German prohibition in 1898.40 Exchange and the Development of the Cotton Futures Market, 57(1) BUS. HIST. REV. 50, 54 (1983). 34 See Ross Cranston, Law Through Practice: London and Liverpool Commodity Markets c. 1820–1975, LSE Law, Society and Economy Working Papers 14/2007, at 3. 35 Robert Bliss & Chryssa Papathanassiou, Derivatives Clearing, Central Counterparties and Novation: The Economic Implications 11 (8 March 2006), available at http://www.ecb.int/events/pdf/conferences/ccp/BlissPapathanassiou_ final.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013). 36 LURIE, supra note 33, at 26. 37 European Central Bank, Daniela Russo, Terry L. Hart & Andreas Schonenberger, The Evolution of Clearing and Central Counterparty Services for Exchange-Traded Derivatives in the United States and Europe: A Comparison, Occasional Paper Series No. 5, 10 (2002). 38 PETER G. ZHANG, BARINGS INSOLVENCY AND FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES 31 (WORLD SCIENTIFIC PUBLISHING CO. PTE. LTD., SINGAPORE, 1995). 39 Paragraph 65 of the Law provided that dealing in futures on exchanges in grain and mill products is forbidden. Hans Hirchstein, Commodity Exchanges in Germany, in ANNALS OF THE AMERICAN ACADEMY OF POLITICAL AND SOCIAL SCIENCE, VOL. 155, PART 1: ORGANIZED COMMODITY MARKETS 208, 210 (AMERICAN ACADEMY OF POLITICAL AND SOCIAL SCIENCE, PHILADELPHIA, PA, 1931). 40 Arthur G. Peterson, Futures Trading with Particular Reference to Agricultural Commodities, 7(68) AGRIC. HIST. 68, 76 (1933). Introduction to Part III 171 Commodity exchanges that emerged at the turn of the twentieth century were largely developed from the bottom-up. In other words the incentive for their creation came from the private sector and associations of merchants that had already standardized their mutual dealings in the spot market. These uniform practices, whether regarding the grading of commodities or standardized contractual terms for delivery, became the template and building blocks for the organized trading in rights to commodities. Since their inception many commodity markets that transplanted existing practices from the spot market became commanding players in their relevant economies. An ECB study confirmed that ‘establishment of futures exchanges requires familiarity of the designers with the organization of the underlying spot market, payment terms and arrangements for delivery of the physical commodity or financial instrument’.41 Intermediaries that traded on commodity exchanges and maintained records of executed contracts for their customers came to play an increasingly important role. These intermediaries established accounts to which the commodity contracts of their customers were credited and debited. In addition, they greatly facilitated the actual settlement of commodity contracts by their offset or exchange of warehouse receipts for payment, as will be examined below. Similar to securities intermediaries, commodity intermediaries operate in the front-end, where they facilitate trading and the execution of orders, as well as in the back-end, where they maintain commodity accounts and effectuate the settlement of contracts. DEMATERIALIZATION AND IMMOBILIZATION OF COMMODITIES The preceding section traced the transformation from trading and settlement by the exchange of a physical commodity for cash, to the exchange of promises to deliver and pay in the future that are evidenced in writing. Eventually these promises to deliver and pay became fungible and subject to trading at commodity exchanges that currently operate largely as impersonal electronic trading venues. This dematerialization of trading processes is similar to the dematerialization of securities trading and the settlement of transactions in both securities and commodity contracts is accomplished electronically. However, there is a significant difference in 41 ECB, Russo, Hart & Schonenberger, supra note 37, at 9. 172 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts terms of the dematerializing of the underlying asset, whether it be securities and money on the one hand or commodities on the other. In the context of commodities, the dematerialization process is not the same as for securities and money because physical commodities, such as grain or corn, did not suddenly become electronic. In contrast, banknotes and security certificates have been largely replaced with electronic entries to accounts maintained by intermediaries. In commodity markets actual commodities still exist in their physical form and it is the rights to their delivery and obligations to pay that have been dematerialized. Entries to accounts in all three holding systems represent claims against intermediaries. However, the nature of these claims differs, as will be explained with respect to commodity accounts below. Commodities have also been immobilized but in a form different from the central deposit of securities. Contracts that are traded at commodity markets are supported by actual commodities that are stored in authorized warehouses. There is a connection between entries in commodity accounts and stored commodities similar to the connection between entries in securities accounts and the immobilized security held by the CSD. However, this connection is only seemingly similar because commodity account holders do not acquire any property interest until they exercise their rights under commodity contracts, while securities account holders acquire a property interest in the security when their account is credited. The second difference is in the volume of claims that are credited to accounts maintained by securities and commodity intermediaries, respectively. While in general the number of securities credited to accounts of investors should not exceed the number of securities represented by the security immobilized with the CSD, the number of contracts credited to commodity accounts typically far exceeds the volume of commodities stored in warehouses and ready for delivery in settlement of commodity transactions. THE TYPOLOGY OF THE SYSTEMS FOR THE HOLDING OF COMMODITY CONTRACTS This section identifies the assets that underlie commodity contracts and options. It then classifies the commodity accounts holding systems into types depending on the asset covered by the commodity contracts held in accounts with intermediaries. The following paragraphs classify various commodities and assets into three main categories: 1) agricultural products, 2) metals and 3) financial assets. Commodity markets may specialize in commodity contracts written on one of these types of assets or may Introduction to Part III 173 offer a combination of all three. Some commodity exchanges specialize in agricultural commodity contracts (e.g., the Minneapolis Grain Exchange), others in contracts to future delivery of metals (e.g., the London Metal Exchange) and some in contracts written on financial assets (e.g., the Mexican Derivatives Exchange). Commodity laws and regulations issued by commodity exchanges typically define the term ‘commodity’, setting forth the types of assets on which commodity contracts can be written and traded. In Slovakia the Law on Commodity Exchange in Article 2 defines commodity as ‘a tangible object or natural force, including a product, energy and metals, with the exception of gold …’. Article 2(4) of the Charter of the Bratislava Commodity Exchange provides a list of which commodities rights to delivery may be traded. This list includes: metals, fuels, chemical products, electrical energy, emissions, exchange rates and dozens of agricultural products. Whether or not the commodity exchange specializes in contracts written on one or more types of asset will have a significant impact on the back-end settlement procedures. On the one hand the vast majority of commodity contracts written on all types of assets are settled by offset. However, for those that are settled by actual delivery, commodity markets must have appropriate mechanisms in place that allow commodity accounts holders to take possession of and pay the purchase price for the relevant commodity. Accordingly, on the front-end, commodity markets may be structured similarly and operate electronic trading platforms while on the back-end the accounts holding systems may have to be supplemented with the appropriate settlement mechanism to complete the actual delivery of assets. Historically the first commodity markets of the nineteenth century dealt in agricultural contracts. Shortly thereafter the first organized markets for metal contracts emerged.42 While contracts written on agricultural commodities and metals have been traded, held in accounts with intermediaries and settled for well over a century, contracts on financial assets emerged only later in the 1970s. In 1986 the Nobel Prize winner Merton Miller singled out financial futures as the most significant financial innovation of the previous 20 years.43 Since then, financial intangible assets have become the driving force of contemporary commodity markets. 42 The London Metal Exchange was established in 1877, see http:// www.lme.co.uk/who.asp (last visited 11 December 2013). 43 Merton H. Miller, Financial Innovation: The Last Twenty Years and the Next, 21(4) JOURNAL OF FINANCIAL & QUANTITATIVE ANALYSIS 459, 463 (1986). 174 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts The common feature of all of these commodity markets is price fluctuations in the underlying assets that expose all involved parties to a risk. For instance, agricultural producers face uncertainty regarding payment for their crops that may result in substantial losses if prices sharply fall before the sale. The farmer may eliminate this market risk by transferring it outright under a contract or by acquiring an option to transfer it in the future.44 Hedging through commodity contracts allows the risk of price fluctuations to be transferred to whoever is willing and financially capable of bearing such a risk.45 Commodity markets with their supporting accounts holding systems were established to provide protection against such risks and potential losses. Commercial risks of this nature existed already in pre-commercial society. Emery noted that: The primitive man who started on a hunt, or who planted corn, necessarily took a risk of failure. The game might be scarce, or the crop might fail. These were risks of production, and were borne necessarily by the producer. But as soon as our primitive man began to kill more game or raise more corn than was needed for individual use, in the hope of bartering his surplus for more desired commodities, he began to incur a risk of quite another kind. However successful his production, it would profit him nothing unless he found others who wanted his commodities and had other commodities to exchange, that is, unless there was a demand for his goods.46 Commodity markets and accounts holding systems equip the involved with a mechanism to insure against the risk that they might not sell their crops, metals or shares at all or sell them below the incurred costs. Risk insurance is the primary function of commodity markets.47 All commodity contracts held in accounts with intermediaries, whether written on agricultural commodities, metals or financial assets, embed this risk element. A US Circuit court noted that: 44 Scott P. Mason, The Allocation of Risk, in THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL SYSTEM, A FUNCTIONAL PERSPECTIVE 162 (Dwight B. Crane, Robert C. Merton, Kenneth A. Froot, Zvi Bodie, Scott P. Mason, Erik R. Sirri, André F. Perold and Peter Tufano eds., HARVARD BUSINESS SCHOOL PRESS, BOSTON, MA, 1995). 45 ‘… immediate beneficiaries of healthy futures markets are the producers and processors of commodities who can minimize the risk of loss from wide fluctuations in cash market prices by hedging on the futures markets …’ NRT Metals, Inc. v. Manhattan Metals, 576 F.Supp. 1046, 1050 (S.D.N.Y. 1983). 46 HENRY C. EMERY, SPECULATION ON THE STOCK AND PRODUCE EXCHANGES OF THE UNITED STATES 103 (AMS PRESS, NEW YORK, NY, 1896). 47 MERTON H. MILLER, MERTON MILLER ON DERIVATIVES 79 (JOHN WILEY & SONS, INC., US, 1997). Introduction to Part III 175 hedging is a manufacturer’s or merchant’s insurance against price fluctuation of materials, and no more demnatory than insurances of property and life, which in one sense are wagers that the property will not be destroyed during the term, and that the life will not fail in less than the expectancy in the actuaries’ tables.48 The market for this type of insurance is the commodity market that effectively permits the transfer of certain risks to those who are willing to bear them.49 Merton Miller argued that derivatives markets, such as futures markets, are selling insurance that protect against risks.50 This insurance is sold at commodity markets and held in accounts with intermediaries. The inherent function and objective of commodity markets may be best summarized by quoting Rule 1002 of the MexDer Internal Regulations: The futures contracts market is established in order to contribute to the strength of the Mexican financial system, to make its participants more competitive by offering contracts that facilitate risk management and control and that diversify positions and investment strategies. COMMODITY MARKETS FOR AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS Agricultural commodities must possess certain characteristics and features before they may become subject to commodity contracts. The following paragraphs identify these features. The first requirement is the uncontrolled output of the product and its unrestricted demand and supply. Supply controls are considered to be one of the main obstacles to the establishment of agricultural commodity markets.51 Many developing countries impose artificial controls on outputs of some products that they deem of public interest. Such measures then prevent or significantly inhibit the establishment of commodity markets for those products. Second, the price of every agricultural product must fluctuate in response to supply and demand. Volatility in the market price of commodities creates an interest in hedging the risk of price fluctuations. Board of Trade v. L. A. Kinsey Co., 130 F. 507, 512 (7th Cir. 1904). BAER & SAXON, supra note 20, at 15. 50 MILLER ON DERIVATIVES, supra note 47, at 82. 51 Sidney Hoos, Futures Trading in Perishable Agricultural Commodities, 6(4) Part 1, JOURNAL OF MARKETING 358, 363 (1942) and BAER & SAXON, supra note 20, at 12. 48 49 176 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts Production of agricultural commodities faces the perpetual risk of price fluctuations that may be managed through two fundamental mechanisms: 1) hedging/speculation or 2) government price-fixing.52 The more the volatility in price increases, the higher the demand for the transfer of risk becomes. Third, an active and un-manipulated trading of agricultural products in the spot market with predictable patterns of supply and demand is a necessity.53 Melamed observed that ‘Successful futures contracts need, at a minimum, 20 to 25 percent commercial participation. You cannot make a market just for speculators.’54 If there is no connection to the underlying spot market and only speculators enter into commodity contracts for future delivery, such a market does not fulfill its ultimate goal to manage the market risk. In commodity markets without participation of any commercial interest, what is held in commodity accounts is not a market risk but a risk of a speculative nature. The fourth requirement is that the units of the commodity be interchangeable or, fungible. Fungibility is necessary because speculators buy on the basis of established grades and descriptions without examining samples of the commodity.55 The success and increase in liquidity of commodity contracts significantly depends on the adoption of uniform grading procedures,56 which eliminate the need for subjective judgments about the quality of the commodity.57 52 BOB TAMARKIN, THE NEW GATSBYS, FORTUNES AND MISFORTUNES OF COMMODITY TRADERS 86 (WILLIAM MORROW AND COMPANY, NEW YORK, NY, 1985). 53 Andrea M. Corcoran, Ronald B. Hobson, Gregory J. Kuserk, Karen K. Wuertz & Derek West, Designing a Derivatives Complement to Cash Markets in Developing Countries, in FOCUS ON CAPITAL, NEW APPROACHES TO DEVELOPING LATIN AMERICAN CAPITAL MARKETS 345–7 (Inter-American Development Bank, 2003). 54 LEO MELAMED, ESCAPE TO THE FUTURES 174 (JOHN WILEY & SONS, INC., US, 1996). 55 BAER & SAXON, supra note 20, at 110. 56 Ben S. Bernanke, Clearing and Settlement during the Crash, National Bureau of Economic Research Conference: Stock Market Volatility and the Crash, Dorado Beach (16–18 March 1989) in 3(1) REV. FIN. STUD., 1990, at 133 & 141. 57 Judgments of quality became standardized. Abbott Payson Usher, The Technique of Medieval and Modern Produce Markets, 23(4) J. POL. ECON. 365, 370 (1915). Introduction to Part III 177 Fifth, the commodity must be divisible into multiple standard grades.58 Grades and qualities of commodities are documented by authorized and licensed warehouse operators that issue warehouse receipts and certificates of quality. All agricultural commodities that may be potentially delivered in settlement of commodity contracts must typically carry an exchange certificate.59 Exchanges license warehouses that store inspected commodities ready for delivery under executed contracts.60 Licensed warehouses that issue warehouse receipts representing rights to delivery of various commodities are the guarantors of quality.61 Sixth, the commodity must be durable and storable.62 Originally, commodity markets developed to provide a hedge for producers of storable commodities produced seasonally.63 Although many agricultural commodities are durable some, such as cattle, eggs or butter lack this feature. Yet, at some point in history even rights to delivery of perishable commodities were traded on commodity exchanges and held in accounts with intermediaries. For instance, at the end of the nineteenth century a futures market for eggs developed64 and later in the early 1960s, a futures market in live beef-cattle briefly functioned.65 Seventh, the system for establishing commercial grades must be free of a subjective human factor.66 Commodity markets, particularly for beverages and foods do not exist. National tastes significantly differ and such commodity markets could function only to a limited extent on a domestic level. Finally, uniformity in the production and growing processes is required.67 Wide disparities in the quality and production to this day prevent the establishment of commodity markets in a number of BAER & SAXON, supra note 20, at 112. Chicago Mercantile Exchange, Rulebook, § 707, available at http:// www.cmegroup.com/rulebook/CME/I/7/7.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013) [hereinafter CME Rulebook]. The Exchange Certificate must also bear the signature of the president of the clearinghouse and must indicate the grade of the commodity as well as the expiration date of the certificate. 60 Typical requirements for a warehouse to be approved by a futures exchange are listed in the CME Rulebook § 703.A. 61 BAER & SAXON, supra note 20, at 87. 62 Ibid., at 118. 63 T. A. Hieronymus, Futures Trading in Hogs, 6(2) ILL. AGRIC. ECON. 1 (1966). 64 Ibid., at 2. 65 J. Marvin Skadberg & Gene A. Futrell, An Economic Appraisal of Futures Trading in Livestock, 48(5) J. FARM ECON. 1485 (1966). 66 BAER & SAXON, supra note 20, at 119. 67 Ibid., at 120. 58 59 178 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts commodities. These eight features are critical for agricultural commodities to become a subject of contracts traded on commodity exchanges and held in accounts with intermediaries. COMMODITY MARKETS FOR METALS Commodity markets in metals, first established in the second half of the nineteenth century, began to flourish with the onset of the industrial revolution. At that time many metals were imported to Europe from different parts of the world but mainly Latin America. Effective trading depended on telecommunication technologies since traders needed to know when the ships would arrive at the shores of England. This was not an issue for the agricultural commodity markets in the United States that traded rights to commodities produced locally. Trading on metal commodity exchanges was facilitated by the invention of the telegraph that allowed traders to obtain information on the sailing of ships and their estimated arrival.68 Since then trading volumes have grown. The first metals subject to commodity contracts were copper and tin. Presently many metals are traded on commodity markets and the resulting contracts are held in accounts with intermediaries. The New York Mercantile Exchange, a member of the CME Group, is the venue for the trading of crude oil, gasoline, heating oil, natural gas, electricity, propane, coal, uranium, environmental commodities, gold, silver, copper, aluminum, platinum and palladium. Similarly to agricultural commodities, differences in production processes have prevented the establishment of commodity markets in many metals, such as iron ore. The variability of ore in the levels of impurities and moisture makes it less fungible, which makes establishing benchmark prices more complicated.69 Like agricultural commodity markets, operators of commodity exchanges license warehouses that store metals ready for delivery under commodity contracts. 68 London Metal Exchange, History, available at http://www.lme.co.uk/ who_ourhistory.asp (last visited 11 December 2013). 69 Liam Denning, At the Dawning of a New Iron Age, THE WALL STREET JOURNAL C6 (9 March 2009). Introduction to Part III 179 COMMODITY MARKETS FOR FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS Commodity contracts may also be written on financial assets, including currencies, securities or stock indexes. Unlike in the case of agricultural products, a uniform grading and standardization system did not need to be developed for intangible financial assets because securities and currencies are, by their nature, issued and circulate in a standardized and homogenous form. A major obstacle to the emergence of commodity markets in intangibles had been artificial price controls. One of these price-control measures was the fixed exchange rates system established pursuant to the 1944 Bretton Woods Agreement. As a result of this artificial fixing of exchange rates, commercial entities did not have sufficient incentives to hedge their currency risks. This all changed in 1972 when the United States abandoned the fixed exchange rates system and the currencies were permitted to fluctuate (float). In 1972, the CME obtained an authorization to offer the first currency futures contract.70 As a reaction, in 1974 the US Congress expanded the definition of commodity in the Commodities Exchange Act to include currencies.71 Accordingly, currency became a commodity covered by the legislation regulating commodity contracts.72 Commodity contracts for future delivery of securities, such as stocks, bonds and stock indices, were introduced shortly thereafter.73 Commodity exchanges that trade in financial instruments must also take into account the possibility that an investor decides to take delivery of the underlying asset, such as shares. Accordingly, their infrastructure must include appropriate delivery mechanisms. Nevertheless, settlement by offsetting financial commodity contracts has established itself as the 70 Kip Schlegel, Crime in the Pits: The Regulation of Futures Trading, in ANNALS OF THE AMERICAN ACADEMY OF POLITICAL AND SOCIAL SCIENCE, VOL. 525, WHITE-COLLAR CRIME 59, 61 (AMERICAN ACADEMY OF POLITICAL AND SOCIAL SCIENCE, PHILADELPHIA, PA, 1993). 71 CFTC v. Standard Forex, Inc., 1993 WL 809966 *8 (1993). 72 See CFTC v. Int’l Foreign Currency, 334 F.Supp.2d 305, 312 (E.D.N.Y. 2004). 73 The Chicago Mercantile Exchange introduced the futures contract on S&P 500 in 1982. Tamarkin had the following to say about stock index futures: ‘It is like trading a fantasy because unlike a carload of wheat or $100 000 of treasury bonds, stock index futures can’t be delivered. Speculators buy and sell contracts for the imaginary delivery of an imaginary portfolio of stocks at a fixed date’. TAMARKIN, supra note 52, at 89. 180 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts norm. This type of settlement, rather than actual delivery, eliminated the risks and costs associated with clearing and transferring a large number of securities underlying commodity contracts.74 TYPES OF COMMODITY CONTRACTS This section identifies and examines various types of commodity contracts. Like funds and securities that are held in bank and securities accounts maintained by intermediaries, only certain commodity contracts are held in commodity accounts with intermediaries. It will be recalled that security certificates and banknotes are outside the securities and bank accounts holding systems. Similarly, certain types of rights to commodities and related contracts are excluded from the commodity accounts holding system. Commodity contracts may be classified into two categories: 1) contracts that are traded on officially organized commodity markets (e.g., futures exchanges); and 2) contracts entered into outside official exchanges, in the OTC markets. Both of these types of contracts are held in commodity accounts but of a different nature and type. Exchangetraded futures contracts are held in one type of account, which is separate from an account established for investors that trade OTC derivatives such as swaps. The requirement to maintain separate commodity accounts for different types of contracts is necessitated by the different risk profile embedded in the contracts.75 This section is concerned primarily with the exchange-traded commodity contracts. The typical examples of exchange-traded commodity contracts are futures and options.76 Futures are executory contracts of a fungible nature that provide for deferred delivery of a commodity of the fixed grade, quantity and price.77 Paragraph 1.2.5 of the Rulebook of the Argentina André F. Perold, The Payment System and Derivative Instruments, in THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL SYSTEM, A FUNCTIONAL PERSPECTIVE 63 (Dwight B. Crane, Robert C. Merton, Kenneth A. Froot, Zvi Bodie, Scott P. Mason, Erik R. Sirri, André F. Perold and Peter Tufano eds., HARVARD BUSINESS SCHOOL PRESS, BOSTON, MA, 1995). 75 Futures Industry Association, Protection of Customer Funds, Frequently Asked Question, Version 2.0, 2 (June 2012). 76 Recently OTC swaps have been converted into exchange-traded futures. See Will Acworth, Futurization: Market Participants Clash, 23(2) FUTURES INDUS. 36, 37 (2013). 77 Salomon Forex, Inc. v. Tauber, 8 F.3d 966, 970–1 (4th Cir. 1993). 74 Introduction to Part III 181 Clearing S.A. defines a futures contract as ‘the instrument with standardized terms and conditions that is traded on a futures exchange and approved as part of the rules of the Clearinghouse’.78 The fungible nature of futures contracts reduces transactional costs because the terms of the contract need not be negotiated by the parties. Just like an investor that buys a share of GE does not negotiate any terms of the security neither does a purchaser of a futures contract. Futures markets operate similarly to financial markets. Futures markets neither ensure delivery of commodities nor provide a forum in which transactions may be consummated by transferring actual lots of commodities. The primary function of futures markets is to provide insurance against market and credit risks.79 Futures contracts are regulated in special commodity laws that also govern the functioning of futures exchanges. For a commodity contract to be governed by a commodity law it must be of the nature of a futures contract that is traded on a futures market. OTC commodity contracts, such as forwards and hedgeto-arrive agreements, are typically regulated by general contract law. Like futures contracts, options are risk management tools that allow commercial entities effectively to reduce, eliminate and otherwise manage risks. An option conveys a contractual right to buy or sell a commodity at/by some fixed date and at the pre-determined (striking) price.80 Options began to be traded on official exchanges more than a century later than the first futures contracts, when the first options exchange – the Chicago Board Options Exchange (CBOE) – was established in 1973.81 Options traded on official exchanges are subject to special commodity laws that also govern futures contracts. The structure of options exchanges is similar to the structure of futures markets, with a Similarly, MexDer, Internal Regulations § 1001 (January 21, 2013), available at http://www.mexder.com.mx/wb3/wb/MEX/MEX_Repositorio/_vtp/MEX/ 1ea7_reglamento_interior_mexder/_rid/21/_mto/3/MexDer_Internal_Regulations_ Jan_21_2013.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013), defines futures contract as ‘a standardized legal agreement specifying the term, amount, quantity and quality, among other features, to buy or sell an underlying asset at a certain price, to be settled at a future date’. See also German Banking Act § 1(11)(1). 79 BAER & SAXON, supra note 20, at 138. 80 British American Commodity Options Corp. v. National Association of Commodity Options Dealers, 552 F.2d 482, 484 (2d Cir. 1977) and Commodity Futures Trading Commission v. The American Board of Trade, 473 F.Supp. 1177, 1183 (S.D.N.Y. 1979). 81 For the history of CBOE see About CBOE, available at http:// www.cboe.com/AboutCBOE/History.aspx (last visited 11 December 2013). 78 182 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts clearinghouse at the top and clearing members and other intermediaries that maintain commodity accounts for individual investors at the lower levels. An option involves a unilateral promise which binds the option holder to do nothing.82 In other words an option holder is not required to do anything and may let his right to exercise the option simply expire.83 The fundamental differences between futures contracts and options may be summarized as follows: 1) 2) 3) the premium for an option (a contango fee) is nonrefundable and covers commission and costs; in contrast a futures contract requires margin that varies according to the value of the contract; the option conveys only rights but no obligations whereas a futures contract conveys both rights and obligations; and an option holder profits if the price of the underlying commodity exceeds the fee, while the futures contract holder profits if the price of the futures contract exceeds the purchase price on the spot market.84 Options are issued, traded and held in two fundamental types: 1) a call option that conveys the right to buy the underlying asset at a fixed price and at or within a pre-determined time; and 2) a put option that conveys the right to sell the underlying asset at a fixed price within or at a pre-determined time. In terms of the timing of settlement, there are two types of options: 1) ‘American options’ that may be exercised any time before their expiration and 2) ‘European options’ that may be exercised exclusively on their expiry date. Rule 110 of the MexDer clearinghouse Asigna Internal Regulations defines American Style Option as ‘an option contract that gives the buyer the right to exercise the put or call option at any time within regular Exchange trading hours, before the expiration of the contract’. The European Style Option is defined as ‘an option 82 Commodities Futures Trading Commission (CFTC), Characteristics Distinguishing Cash and Forward Contracts and ‘Trade’ Options, 50 FR 39656, 39658 (30 September 1985). 83 Rulebook of Argentina Clearing S.A. (ed. no. 7, 9 July 2010), available at http://www.argentinaclearing.com.ar/English/legal_members/files.aspx (last visited 11 December 2013), § 1.2.8 defines an option as ‘a standardized contract in which the buyer, upon payment of a premium, obtains the right but not the obligation to buy or sell an underlying asset’. 84 Commodity Futures Trading Commission v. U.S. Metals Depository Co., 468 F.Supp. 1149, 1155 (S.D.N.Y. 1979). Introduction to Part III 183 contract that allows the buyer to exercise the put or call option only on the expiration date’. The following paragraphs identify the types of commodity contracts that are concluded in OTC markets. OTC contracts are privately negotiated and generally excluded from commodity laws. These contracts are not held in commodity accounts with exchange-traded futures and options. A forward contract is probably the most common type of OTC contract for future delivery, whereby two parties agree to sell and buy a certain quantity of commodities at a fixed price. A forward contract creates an obligation for the buyer to take delivery of the specific grade of a commodity and to pay the purchase price.85 Correspondingly, the seller undertakes to sell and deliver such commodity at a fixed price regardless of the fluctuations in the commodity’s market price. Accordingly, for both parties the quality of the commodity, its purchase price and the place and time of delivery are of significance. Obligations of the parties are negotiated and not pre-established in a standardized agreement. Forward contracts are regularly used to acquire the underlying commodity and in parallel to hedge against price risks.86 This is not the case of futures and options that are not traded with the intent to make/take delivery of commodities. The forward market is primarily used by producers of commodities that require the ingredients or components for their own business operations and manufacturing processes. Commodity laws have traditionally exempted certain transactions for immediate and future delivery from their scope. First, spot transactions in which delivery is executed instantaneously are excluded because they lack a ‘future element’. These types of sales are executed contracts that do not provide the same opportunities for speculation and manipulation because the risk of price fluctuations is effectively eliminated by immediate performance.87 The second notable exemption from commodity laws applies to forward contracts. Even though forwards defer performance of the obligations, their exemption from commodity laws is justified because ‘they allow farmers to sell part of the next season’s harvest at a set price to a grain elevator or millers’.88 In other words, both ‘forward promises’ are undertaken by commercial entities in the regular course of their business with the intent to be settled by delivery of the actual The forward buyer may pay the purchase price on delivery or pre-pay for the commodity, in which case it finances the production of the commodity. 86 CFTC, Statutory Interpretation Concerning Forward Transactions, 55 Fed. Reg. 39,188 (25 September 1990). 87 Salomon Forex, Inc. v. Tauber, 8 F.3d 966, 970–1 (4th Cir. 1993). 88 See H.R.Rep. No. 345, 67th Cong. 1st Session 7 (1921). 85 184 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts commodity against payment. Commodity laws deal primarily with executory promises that are typically closed out by offset, while sales laws deal with promises that the parties perform by actual delivery. The promise of actual delivery of the commodity exempts forward contracts from commodity laws.89 In practice it is frequently difficult to determine whether the particular agreement is a forward or futures contract judging solely from the contractual terms.90 Proper classification of these two types of commodity contracts requires factual inquiry and evaluation of various aspects of the individual relationship. Courts and regulators in their classification of contracts, as either forwards or futures, consider the following: whether both parties are commercial entities; whether there was any negotiation concerning the mechanics of the transaction; whether the parties agreed on the precise quality of the commodity involved, a particular delivery point, or a fixed delivery date; whether their ability to make/take delivery was sufficiently demonstrated; and whether their established practice is indeed to make/take delivery under such contracts.91 Negotiations are not characteristic for futures contracts that are standardized, interchangeable and traded on organized exchanges.92 Courts and legislators may distinguish futures and forward contracts on the basis of the following criteria. First, forwards are individualized tailor-made contracts that reflect the requirements of the contracting parties. Second, since delivery of the actual commodity plays an important role in the forward contracts market, typically only merchants enter into such contracts.93 Third, forwards typically set forth a specific delivery obligation. If the understanding between the parties is in terms of contracts rather than in terms of specific quantities and one of the parties is required to post a margin such contract has a strong indicium of a futures contract.94 Fourth, under a forward contract that contemplates delivery, only the commodity of the specific grade agreed on may be delivered to the buyer. In contrast, under a futures contract the seller may Grain Land Coop v. Kar Kim Farms, 199 F.3d 983, 990 (1999). Nagel v. ADM Investor Servs., 217 F.3d 436, 440 (7th Cir. 2000). 91 CFTC, Characteristics Distinguishing Cash and Forward Contracts and ‘Trade’ Options, 50 Fed. Reg. 39656, 39658 (30 September 1985). See also NRT Metals, Inc. v. Manhattan Metals, 576 F.Supp. 1046, 1051 (S.D.N.Y. 1983). 92 REFCO PRIVATE CLIENT GROUP, THE COMPLETE GUIDE TO FUTURES TRADING 5–6 (JOHN WILEY & SONS, INC., HOBOKEN, NJ, 2005). 93 Salomon Forex, Inc. v. Tauber, 8 F.3d 966, 970–1 (4th Cir. 1993). 94 NRT Metals, Inc. v. Manhattan Metals, 576 F.Supp. 1046, 1051 (S.D.N.Y. 1983). 89 90 Introduction to Part III 185 choose one of the deliverable grades permitted by the rules of the futures exchange.95 Fifth, the margin requirement is an inherent feature of futures contracts.96 In contrast, the performance of obligations of the parties under a forward contract is not typically guaranteed by a margin. Sixth, settlement by offset that is typically accomplished in futures markets is not available for forward contracts that are settled by actual delivery of commodities.97 Other factors, such as restrictions against assignment without consent of the parties, provision for exchange-style offset and presence of a clearinghouse, will be indicative of the nature of the contract. The borderline between forward contracts and futures may occasionally become blurred. In practice many hybrid contracts that combine some features of forwards and futures have emerged. These hybrid commodity contracts are known in the US market as hedge-to-arrive contracts (HTAs).98 The US Appellate Court for the Seventh Circuit observed that an HTA contract is an agreement for the sale of a fixed quantity of commodity for delivery at a specific time in the future for a price fixed by reference to the futures price for a particular month on the futures exchange.99 This determination of the purchase price on the basis of a quotation at a futures exchange is one of the hedging or speculative features of HTAs that distinguishes them from the traditional forwards. Even though the purchase price is fixed by reference to the price of a futures contract, HTAs do not fundamentally alter the parties’ underlying obligations to exchange the commodity for funds.100 Their users are mainly farmers who sell the future year’s crop.101 This right granted to the seller is one of the primary reasons for the buyer of a futures contract to close it out prior to the delivery month. Otherwise the buyer would be obligated to accept a commodity of any quality within the designated range, even if it did not meet her requirements. The Delivery Requirement: An Illusory Bar to Regulation of Manipulation in Commodity Exchanges, 73(1) YALE L. J. 171, 173 (1963). 96 BAER & SAXON, supra note 20, at 135. 97 CFTC v. CO Petro Marketing Group, Inc., 680 F.2d 573, 580 (9th Cir. 1982). 98 Charles F. Reid, Note: Risky Business: HTAs, the Cash Forward Exclusion and Top of Iowa Cooperative v. Schewe, 44 VILL. L. REV. 125, 134 (1999). 99 Lachmund v. ADM, 191 F.3d 777, 779 (7th Cir. 1999). 100 In re Rawlin L. Stovall, CFTC Docket No. 75-7 *3 (1979). 101 Edward M. Mansfield, Textualism Gone Astray: A Reply to Norris, Davison, and May on Hedge to Arrive Contracts, 47 DRAKE L. REV. 745, 747 (1999). 95 186 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts Swaps are agreements that may also create a right to delivery of a commodity. While futures contracts on crude oil and heating oil have been traded on commodity exchanges for decades, futures contracts on jet fuel are not yet publicly tradable, which has an impact on the business of airlines operators.102 Airlines thus manage the risk of rising market price for jet fuel by entering into a commodity swap. Despite the establishment of many clearinghouses for the clearance of OTC swaps, they are not held in commodity accounts maintained by intermediaries of the kind studied in this book and thus will not be discussed further.103 102 See CFTC Staff Report on Commodity Swap Dealers & Index Traders with Commission Recommendations, 11 (September 2008), available at http:// www.loe.org/images/content/080919/cftcstaffreportonswapdealers09.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013). 103 One of the first such clearinghouses – the Clearing Corp. – was sponsored by a bank consortium that included Goldman Sachs, Deutsche Bank, Morgan Stanley and other financial institutions. Doug Cameron & Serena Ng, Bank Group to Start CDS Clearinghouse, Product Complex to Expand later; Exchanges’ Efforts, THE WALL STREET JOURNAL, C7 (Friday, 30 May 2008). For the regulation of clearing of OTC instruments see Council Regulation 648/2012 on OTC Derivatives, Central Counterparties and Trade Repositories, 2012, available at http://www.cssf. lu /fileadmin/files/Lois_reglements /Legislation/Reglements /Rdg_UE_648_2012_ EN.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013) [hereinafter EU Regulation 648/2012]. 10. Commodity account relationships The organization of back-end systems for the holding of commodity accounts is similar to that of securities and funds. All of them are pyramid-modeled with a central entity at the top and a network of relationships among intermediaries and account holders forming the lower tiers of the pyramid holding structure. However, a number of differences in terms of relationships and functions can be identified. For instance, clearing is an important function performed by central securities settlement systems yet it is less important in RTGS payment systems. The organization of central clearinghouses for commodity accounts systems is similar to that of securities settlement systems. Yet as examined below many differences exist between the two. RELATIONSHIPS At the top of the commodity accounts holding system sits a commodity clearinghouse. Similar to securities clearing and LVFTSs, only authorized intermediaries may access the commodity clearinghouse. Membership is a privilege and license1 that is typically non-transferable.2 Individual investors establish commodity accounts with intermediaries, which either directly or through other intermediaries, known as clearing brokers, have access to the clearinghouse.3 Accordingly, two types of intermediaries 1 Membership privileges may be withdrawn for cause at any time. See CME Rulebook (available at http://www.cmegroup.com/rulebook/CME/I/7/ 7.pdf) § 901. 2 Clearing licenses issued by Eurex, and the rights arising under them, may not be transferred in any way by clearing members. Clearing Conditions for Eurex Clearing AG § 2.1.6 (Eurex04e, 15 July 2013), available at https:// www.eurexchange.com/blob/exchange-en/3138-136778/238376/28/data/clearing_ conditions_en_ab_15_07_2013.pdf.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013) [hereinafter Eurex Clearing Conditions]. 3 At Argentina Clearing S.A., all brokers are required to enter into a broker registration agreement with a clearing member to gain access to the clearing services. The broker also acknowledges that the clearinghouse shall act as the counterparty to every contract. Argentina Clearing Rulebook (available at 187 188 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts participate in commodity accounts systems: 1) clearing members who have direct access to the clearinghouse and 2) non-clearing members who do not deal directly with the clearinghouse.4 Clearing members have an account relationship with the commodity clearinghouse.5 Non-clearing members may enter into a standard clearing agreement with a clearing member with whom they also have an account relationship. Applicants for a clearing license must satisfy various conditions including minimum operational and financial requirements.6 As a condition of receiving the clearing license, applicants must enter into a clearing agreement with the clearinghouse.7 Only once all the prescribed requirements have been complied with and the application for membership approved will the applicants be authorized to act as clearing members. Clearinghouses maintain commodity accounts for clearing members in which they hold the intermediaries’ commodity contracts and those of the intermediaries’ customers. Regulations governing operations of clearinghouses typically include a general definition of account. Rule 110 of the Mexican Asigna Internal Regulations defines account as ‘a set of transaction records that the Clearinghouse maintains for each Clearing Member, and on the basis of which clearing and settlement is carried out’. Authorized intermediaries may become eligible to clear both their own (proprietary) trades and those of their customers, or only their own, depending on the type of the clearing license they have received.8 This is similar to securities clearing intermediaries, who may clear their own trades only or who may also clear those of their customers. If clearing members are authorized to clear their own trades as well as those of their http://www.argentinaclearing.com.ar/English/legal_members/files.aspx) § 2.5.1. Similarly, commodity intermediaries that are not clearing members at Eurex must sign an agreement with an eligible clearing member to clear their trades with the clearinghouse. Eurex Clearing Conditions § 1.1.5. 4 For a definition of ‘clearing member’ see EU Regulation 648/2012, art. 2(14). 5 Argentina Clearing Rulebook § 1.2.22 defines clearing member as ‘the legal person authorized by the clearinghouse to register, clear and settle trades for proprietary account or for its customers’ accounts’. 6 Ibid., § 2.1.2. 7 Eurex Clearing AG shall grant a clearing license upon the conclusion of the appropriate clearing agreement in the form appended to its internal regulations. Eurex Clearing Conditions § 2.1.1(2). 8 Ibid., § 2.1.2. Commodity account relationships 189 customers9 they must have two types of commodity accounts with the clearinghouse – one for their proprietary positions and one for the positions of their customers. Accordingly, for each clearing member Eurex Clearing AG maintains a ‘principal’ account for the holding of contracts entered into by the clearing member and an ‘agent’ account for the customers’ contracts.10 The two accounts must be segregated from one another and customers’ positions may not be used to cover losses in the clearing member’s proprietary account.11 However, the clearinghouse does not establish and maintain customer accounts for each individual client of the clearing intermediary. Instead clearinghouses may maintain an ‘omnibus’ or ‘global’ account for clearing members with respect to their customers’ property.12 Mexican Asigna is authorized to maintain ‘global accounts’ for its clearing members’ customer contracts. A global account is defined in the Asigna Internal Regulations, Section 110, as ‘an account in which transactions for one or more clients are recorded …’. Clearing members then segregate non-proprietary contracts on their own books and maintain accounts for their individual customers. This type of holding by the clearinghouse in a non-segregated customer account is more costefficient than individualized customer holding. Commodity contracts acquired by clearing members for their proprietary and customer accounts are executory promises that may be enforced by demanding delivery. Futures contracts contemplate delivery and investors must be prepared to make/take delivery in case they fail to close out the outstanding futures contracts before the delivery month. After 9 Asigna, Internal Regulations, 202 provides that clearing members may enter into, clear and settle transactions as proprietary or for third parties, available at http://www.mexder.com.mx/wb3/wb/MEX/MEX_Repositorio/_vtp/ MEX/1eb9_reglamento_interior_asigna /_rid / 21/_mto /3/ Internal_Rules_Asigna. pdf (last visited 11 December 2013). 10 Eurex Clearing Conditions § 4.2.1. 11 17 Code of Federal Regulations (C.F.R.) §§ 1.20–1.30 (2012) and Argentina Clearing Rulebook § 3.3.1. 12 The omnibus account structure is commonly used to facilitate relationships among brokers, especially when operating in different jurisdictions. The omnibus account structure is an efficient way to bunch customer trading activity into a single account, saving money through economies of scale and allowing for trades executed by many brokers to be consolidated at a single global broker. In fact, a brokerage firm may establish an omnibus account with its own affiliate at a foreign exchange. Customers often prefer to have all of their trading conducted through a single account carried out at one firm, rather than at multiple affiliates of that firm. 190 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts clearing the clearinghouse will become the counterparty to delivery obligations under the futures contract. In order to protect itself against the risk of default the clearinghouse customarily requests the clearing members to post margins to assure the performance of their obligations to pay and to deliver. Clearing margins are posted in the form of cash, securities, letters of credit or a combination thereof.13 Typically the futures margin varies from 10 to 20 percent of the value of the relevant obligation under the futures contract. For the maintenance of margins clearinghouses establish collateral clearing accounts to which margin payments are deposited.14 Clearinghouses also maintain securities pledge accounts to which clearing members transfer securities for margin purposes.15 In addition to margins some clearinghouses have implemented other protections against clearing members’ default. The CME clearinghouse has the right, on default of a clearing member, to foreclose on such member’s security deposit,16 its performance bonds and even to sell its commodity exchange seat. The CME clearinghouse also holds a first priority security interest in the membership rights.17 Clearing members are bound by the provisions in the CME Rulebook to refrain from seeking a court order to stop the actions of the clearinghouse.18 Accordingly, a default of the exchange member may result in the loss of its exchange membership rights. Enforcement of these remedies will lead to JULIE COLLINS & MARK MELIN, THE CHICAGO BOARD OF TRADE HANDBOOK OF FUTURES & OPTIONS 65 (MCGRAW-HILL, NEW YORK, NY, 2006). The 13 Board of Directors of the Argentinian Rofex Clearinghouse reserves the right to approve assets, in addition to letters of credit, commercial bonds and other payment undertakings, as eligible for margin. Argentina Clearing Rulebook § 1.2.15. While various financial instruments may be posted to satisfy the initial margin, typically only cash is allowed to satisfy variation margin calls. DERMOT TURING, CLEARING AND SETTLEMENT IN EUROPE 363 (BLOOMSBURY PROFESSIONAL LTD., HAYWARDS HEATH, UK, 2012). 14 Eurex Clearing Conditions § 4.4. 15 Securities pledged by clearing members to cover margin calls issued by Eurex are transferred to a pledge account maintained by Clearstream Banking AG. Ibid., § 3.2.2(3). 16 A security deposit must be provided by every clearing member as security for its obligations. 17 CME Rulebook § 902.F. 18 Ibid., § 802.A. If any security deposits are used to cure the default, the clearing member must replenish the security deposit prior to the close of business on the next banking day. Commodity account relationships 191 the termination of the account relationship between the clearinghouse and the affected member. Clearinghouses are also connected to LVFTSs, through which they complete settlement of commodity contracts. In many systems clearinghouses have direct access to LVFTSs by virtue of deposit accounts maintained by the central bank. In other systems clearinghouses effectuate settlement through agent banks that are authorized to access the LVFTS.19 CLEARINGHOUSE AND CLEARING FUNCTIONS A clearinghouse is a critical component of the commodity accounts holding system. Originally commodity clearinghouses did not perform central counterparty services and functioned comparably to bank clearing houses.20 In that role they reconciled and recorded positions taken by counterparties and performed related administrative functions. Today, clearing functions typically performed by commodity clearinghouses are similar to central counterparty clearing in securities holding systems.21 Both holding systems rely on a clearinghouse that novates existing delivery obligations and inserts itself as the central counterparty. The definition of clearinghouse in Chapter II of the Rulebook of Argentina Clearing S.A. aptly summarizes the functions of a commodity clearinghouse. It defines clearinghouse as: ‘a limited liability company whose purpose is to register, clear and settle futures contracts, options contracts and other derivatives contracts, and to act as the counterparty in every trade executed on the futures exchange’. Central counterparty clearing significantly reduces the risk of default. The first clearinghouses supporting commodity markets were established at the end of the nineteenth century in Europe. The Liverpool Corn Trade Association formed its clearinghouse in 1883 and the Tea Clearing Peter Allsopp, Bruce Summers & John Veale, The Evolution of Real-Time Gross Settlement: Access, Liquidity and Credit, and Pricing, Financial Infrastructure Series: Payment Systems Policy and Research, 16 (The World Bank, 2009). 20 JIABIN HUANG, THE LAW AND REGULATION OF CENTRAL COUNTERPARTIES 49 (HART PUBLISHING LTD., PORTLAND, OR, 2010). 21 Some authors argued that CCPs play a much more significant role in derivatives markets than in the clearing of securities transactions. TINA P. HASENPUSCH, CLEARING SERVICES FOR GLOBAL MARKETS 12 (2009). 19 192 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts House was established in 1888.22 The US-based CBOT established its clearinghouse in the 1920s.23 Contemporary commodity accounts systems utilize a clearinghouse that may be organized either as a department within a commodity exchange or as an independent entity.24 The largest commodity exchanges in the world, the CBOT and the CME, implemented a common clearing link in November 2003, through which the CME began providing clearing services to the CBOT and, thus, the world’s largest clearing organization for futures contracts was created. Eurex operates Eurex Clearing AG, which is the central counterparty clearinghouse for its futures contracts and options.25 A similar organization has taken hold in developing countries. In Mexico, MexDer operates its clearinghouse Asigna, Compensación y Liquidación. The commodity clearinghouse becomes the counterparty to every contract entered into on the commodity exchange(s) for which it provides clearing services. As the CBOT Handbook of Futures & Options highlights, in central counterparty clearing financial obligations are not created between the parties, but rather vis-à-vis the clearinghouse.26 The central counterparty is used for clearing of futures as well as options contracts.27 As in securities markets, clearing is completed in several stages. Commodity account holders may instruct their intermediaries to execute trades on a commodity exchange. Once the trade has been executed, intermediaries for both the seller and buyer then submit trade details that typically include the type of contract, its expiration, price, etc. to the clearinghouse electronically.28 In systems such as that of Brazil where the 22 See Ross Cranston, Law Through Practice: London and Liverpool Commodity Markets c. 1820–1975, LSE Law, Society and Economy Working Papers 14/2007, at 16–17. 23 REFCO PRIVATE CLIENT GROUP, THE COMPLETE GUIDE TO FUTURES TRADING 2 (JOHN WILEY & SONS, INC., HOBOKEN, NJ, 2005). 24 DAVID LOADER, CLEARING AND SETTLEMENT OF DERIVATIVES 35 (ELSEVIER LTD., OXFORD, UK, 2005). 25 Eurex is jointly operated by Deutsche Börse AG and SIX Swiss Exchange. 26 COLLINS & MELIN, supra note 13, at 60. 27 See Eurex Clearing Conditions, Chapter II, Part 3, § 3.1(1), which provides: ‘Eurex Clearing AG shall be a contracting party to all deliveries and payments arising out of the exercise and assignments of Options contracts’. 28 Originally, trade details used to be submitted to the clearinghouse in duplicate on paper sheets printed in different colors; one in red ink listing sales for the day and the other in black or blue listing purchases for the day. Bibb v. Allen, 149 U.S. 481, 494 (1893). See also JULIUS B. BAER & OLIN G. SAXON, COMMODITY EXCHANGES AND FUTURES TRADING, PRINCIPLES AND OPERATING Commodity account relationships 193 trading and clearing systems are integrated, the trade details are automatically transmitted from the trading to the clearing platform.29 Once the contract details are submitted for clearing, the matching engine operated by the clearinghouse compares them. If the data does not match, the contract will not be cleared and the intermediaries must then reconcile the discrepancies.30 When the data has been successfully matched the commodity contract may proceed to the second stage of clearing, which involves its novation.31 Novation of commodity contracts is accomplished in two phases. First, the contract entered into by the intermediaries will be extinguished. Second, the clearinghouse will become the counterparty to the original contracting parties. This process results in two new contracts. Rule 804 of the CME Rulebook expressly provides that: ‘upon such substitution, each clearing member shall be deemed to have bought the contracts from or sold the contracts to the clearinghouse, as the case may be, and the clearinghouse shall have the rights and be subject to all the liabilities of such member with respect to such transaction’.32 The CME Rulebook thus clearly specifies the function and result of central counterparty METHODS 171 (1949). Clearing members of MexDer use access codes to log in to the electronic system. This form of electronic access to the clearinghouse is legally equivalent to a written signature under the Mexican law. MexDer, Internal Regulations (available at http://www.mexder.com.mx/wb3/wb/MEX/MEX_ Repositorio/_vtp/MEX/1ea7_reglamento_interior_mexder/_rid/21/_mto/3/MexDer _Internal_Regulations_Jan_21_2013.pdf) (last visited 11 December 2013) § 10006. 29 Best Brazil, Brazil Market Profile 87 (February 2012), available at http:// www.bestbrazil.org.br/media/Market%20Profile.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013). 30 At the CME, they must do so before the opening of the next trading day. CME Rulebook § 809. 31 In certain futures markets, the clearinghouse does not novate already concluded contracts and interpose itself between the two contracting parties. For instance, the Eurex Clearing AG becomes the immediate party to every exchange contract by making an open public offer that has a binding effect. Robert Bliss & Chryssa Papathanassiou, Derivatives Clearing, Central Counterparties and Novation: The Economic Implications 20 (8 March 2006), available at http:// www.ecb.int/events/pdf/conferences/ccp/BlissPapathanassiou_final.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013). See also TURING, supra note 13, at 26 who argues that open offer is simpler than novation because in the former system the parties are deemed to have never executed a contract that is subsequently novated. 32 Similarly, Argentina Clearing Rulebook § 2.4.1 provides that the clearinghouse acts as the counterparty in each contract and guarantees the performance of every trade that it has registered. 194 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts clearing. After novation is completed, the new contracts with the clearinghouse will have the same terms as the original one. COMMODITY ACCOUNT RELATIONSHIPS AT LOWER TIERS AND RIGHTS TO COMMODITIES Account relationships between intermediaries and their customers represent the lower tier of relationships in the commodity accounts holding structure. The structure of commodity accounts holding systems is similar to those for securities and funds. Only authorized intermediaries have access to the CSD, the commodity clearinghouse and the central payment system. These (participating) intermediaries in turn maintain accounts for other (non-clearing) intermediaries and individual investors. The relationship between an investor and his commodity intermediary is represented in a commodity account. This account-based relationship is similar to those present in securities and bank accounts holding systems. In all of the systems, intermediaries maintain accounts for their customers, to which they book securities, funds and commodity contracts. The establishment of a commodity account with an authorized intermediary is a typical requirement for participation in commodity markets.33 As part of execution of the account agreement the account holder must receive the necessary risk disclosure statements, such as the CFTC Risk Disclosure Statement for Futures and Options. Commodity account agreements typically include disclosures that highlight the risks inherent in commodity contracts, including their speculative nature that in turn does not render them a conservative investment. The standard commodity client account agreement with the Argentina Clearing S.A. includes the following warning: ‘Futures and options trades require constant supervision. They entail a high risk … A benefit can rapidly change into loss as a consequence of price variations. Operating with Futures and Options requires knowledge and good judgment.’34 A similar duty to provide full 33 Ibid., § 2.6.1 provides that clearing members shall require their clients to sign an account opening agreement according to the model form approved by the Clearinghouse. 34 Similarly, a typical commodity account agreement concluded with US intermediaries provides that: ‘Customer acknowledges that trading in commodity contracts is a speculative activity involving leverage and rapidly fluctuating markets. Despite such risks, customer is willing and able to assume the financial risks and other hazards of trading commodity contracts.’ Advantage Futures LLC Commodity Futures Customer Agreement, art. 4 (on file with author). Commodity account relationships 195 risk disclosures has been imposed by German courts on local financial intermediaries.35 In a commodity account agreement the customer typically authorizes the commodity intermediary to purchase and sell commodity contracts for the customer’s account. The intermediary also assumes responsibility for the execution, clearance and carrying out of actions that pertain to the settlement, acceptance and delivery of commodities. The customer is responsible to indemnify the intermediary for the satisfaction of its duties with respect to the customer’s orders.36 In the client account agreement with Argentina Clearing S.A., the client acknowledges that the broker shall act as the client’s agent. Some account agreements and relevant laws even defer to the general regulation of commission agents. In Slovakia the relationship between a commodity intermediary and its customers is subject to the contract governing commission agency included in §§ 577–590 of the Commercial Code.37 Commodity account agreements customarily include provisions that alert account holders to the fact that the clearinghouse will be the counterparty to all their commodity contracts. In addition to a commodity account agreement the relationship between the customer and its intermediary is also subject to the rules, usages and customs of the particular commodity market.38 Commodity account agreements typically contain a clause whereby the customer acknowledges that it will be bound by the regulations, rules and other circulars issued by the commodities exchange and its clearinghouse. In the Argentina Clearing S.A. standard commodity account agreement, the customer must acknowledge that he will be bound by the terms of the 35 The German intermediaries were then held liable for losses sustained by the ill-informed investors. See Norbert Horn, Germany, in EUROPEAN BANKING LAW: THE BANKER-CUSTOMER RELATIONSHIP 63, 75 (Ross Cranston ed., 2nd edn., ROUTLEDGE, UK, 1999). 36 RICHARD J. TEWELES, CHARLES V. HARLOW & HERBERT L. STONE, THE COMMODITY FUTURES GAME, WHO WINS?, WHO LOSES?, WHY? 54 (MCGRAWHILL, NEW YORK, NY, 1974). 37 See Slovakian Law on Commodity Exchange (Zákon o komoditnej burze), No. 92/2008 (14 February 2008), available at http://www.kbb.sk/files/92_ 2008.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013); art. 2(6). However, if the intermediary trades for its own account, it is not subject to the rules on commission agency. Rules of the Commodity Exchange Bratislava, Annex 8: Guarantee-Settling System KBB 1, § 5 (30 July 2010), available at http://www.kbb.sk/en/category/ index/exchange-rules/ (last visited 11 December 2013). 38 Perin v. Parker, 126 Ill. 201, 212 (1888). 196 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts agreement, rulebook of the clearinghouse, the exchange bylaws, resolutions promulgated by these entities and regulations issued by the National Securities Commission.39 In the United States the issue of whether or not investors are bound by the usage of the particular commodity market was subject to protracted litigation and ultimately resolved by the US Supreme Court in Bibb v. Allen in which the court held: It is settled by the weight of authority that where a principal sends an order to a broker engaged in an established market or trade, for a deal in that trade, he confers authority upon the broker to deal according to any well-established usage in such market or trade, especially when such usage is known to the principal, and is fair in itself, and does not change in any essential particular the contract between the principal and agent, or involves no departure from the instructions of the principal; provided, the transaction for which the broker is employed is legal in its character, and does not violate any rule of law, good morals, or public policy.40 RIGHTS IN COMMODITY CONTRACTS AND COMMODITY ACCOUNTS Commodity contracts are seldom settled by actual delivery of the underlying asset. This type of settlement is characteristic for forward contracts and spot sales. Forward and spot commodity contracts transfer property rights to identified or identifiable commodities. In contrast, on commodity exchanges title to commodities does not pass by acquiring or offsetting a futures or option contract. A futures contract conveys only a contractual right to demand delivery sometime in the future. This right to delivery does not materialize until the last month of the effectiveness of the futures contract and still may be terminated by set-off prior to its expiration.41 39 Law on Commodity Exchange (Slovk.); art. 29(1) expressly provides that parties involved in commodity trading are bound by the applicable laws, account agreements that they have entered into, rules of the exchange, any established practice and a code of ethics issued by the exchange. Article 6 also authorizes exchange operators to issue rules governing its operation that are subject to approval by the Ministry of Commerce. 40 Bibb v. Allen, 149 U.S. 481, 489–90 (1893). 41 Telford Taylor, Trading in Commodity Futures – A New Standard of Legality?, 43 YALE L. J. 63, 90 (1933). Commodity account relationships 197 In order for a property interest to arise for a commodity, the commodity must both exist and be identified in the contract.42 A promise to sell goods sometime in the future does not convey property rights to the buyer until the goods are identified. Prior to identification neither property rights nor risk passes to the buyer. Goods intended to be delivered under a futures contract are not identified as that of the buyer when the futures contract is acquired. Only when the commodity account holder decides to take delivery of the commodity under a futures contract may he acquire property rights. If, however, the futures contract is terminated before the commodity account holder becomes obligated to take delivery, no property rights will arise. Trading in futures contracts does not involve a transfer of warehouse receipts as a sign of identification when the futures contract is entered into. The warehouse receipt is not delivered to the buyer until he decides to take delivery during the delivery month. The commodity account holder’s rights arise as contractual and, customarily, terminate in the same form. He does not bear any risk of damage, loss or destruction of the commodity.43 Futures contracts transfer a different kind of risk, which is the risk that the price of commodities may rise or fall. This market or price risk is independent from the property-related risk. This distinction between contractual and property rights may also be demonstrated on the example of commodity contracts to the future delivery of securities. Acquisition of a bond issued by a corporation conveys a property right in the bond. The investor may be an owner, a co-owner or have a security entitlement, depending on the securities holding pattern. In contrast acquisition of a futures contract conveys only the promise that a buyer and seller will exchange property rights to the underlying security in the future.44 By dealing in futures contracts one is dealing not in the actual security but in claims to delivery of the security.45 Parties to commodity contracts for future delivery have both contractual rights and obligations to settle the contract by either offset or delivery. It should be recalled that commodity option holders have no similar obligation and may let their options expire. In other words, while 42 See UCC 2-105(1) (2003) and Andrew G. L. Nicol, The Passing of Property in Part of a Bulk, 42(2) MODERN L. REV. 129 (1979). 43 Taylor, supra note 41, at 90. 44 REFCO PRIVATE CLIENT GROUP, supra note 23, at 5–6. 45 GEORGE WRIGHT HOFFMAN, FUTURE TRADING UPON ORGANIZED COMMODITY MARKETS IN THE UNITED STATES 111 (UNIVERSITY OF PENNSYLVANIA PRESS, PHILADELPHIA, PA, 1932). 198 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts an affirmative action is required to settle a futures contract, inaction by the option holder will terminate his rights under the option. Like a futures contract an option holder does not acquire any property interest in the underlying asset. Rights of the option holder are merely contractual and the writers of options are not required to hold the asset that the option references. The characterization of rights under commodity contracts held in accounts with intermediaries as contractual is evident in the case of insolvency of a commodity account holder. The claim of the clearinghouse, which is its counterparty, shall be classified as an executory contract rather than a proprietary or secured claim. Similarly, goods that may be acquired under a futures contract may not be attached by a creditor of the commodity account holder because he has no property interest in the goods. The creditor may serve its attachment order only against the contract and not against the goods. PROTECTIONS OF COMMODITY ACCOUNTS HOLDERS Commodity account holders acquire contractual rights under futures and options contracts. Unlike securities account holders, they do not acquire any property rights to the underlying commodities until they exercise the right to take delivery.46 Accordingly, their rights are similar to those of bank account holders. Neither of these account holders has any property rights to the funds or commodities. Consequently, property law protects only the rights of securities account holders. The rights of securities and bank account holders against their intermediaries are protected by mandatory insurance. In the case that a securities intermediary or a bank is declared insolvent, claims of their account holders, up to a certain cap, will be paid out from insurance funds typically administered by governmental agencies. In contrast, claims of commodity account holders are not covered by a similar mandatory insurance scheme. In the United States proposals to create an insurance mechanism for the protection of commodity account holders were studied extensively in the 1970s. At that time the CFTC concluded that insurance is not necessary due to ‘the high level of public confidence 46 If the account holder has deposited specifically identifiable assets with an insolvent intermediary, such as a warehouse receipt to be delivered in settlement of a futures contract, the account holder may be entitled to its return and such asset does not become subject to the pro-rata sharing rule. Commodity account relationships 199 in the safety of funds and the cost-inefficiency of insurance coverage’.47 Furthermore, insolvencies of commodity intermediaries are not as common as insolvencies of securities intermediaries and banks. However, the calls for a possible insurance protection recently resurfaced in the aftermath of the insolvencies of some major commodity intermediaries such as MF Global. In December 2012 a number of stakeholders, including the CME Group, launched a study on the feasibility of adopting an insurance framework for the US futures industry.48 The CME also voluntarily implemented the Family Farmer and Rancher Protection Fund, which provides coverage of up to US$ 25 000 to individual farmers for the losses incurred by a failure of their intermediaries.49 In the absence of insurance customers may be tempted to argue that their property is held in a securities account and that they are entitled to the protections available to customers of failed securities intermediaries, including a claim against an insurance fund.50 Although losses incurred by commodity account holders are not insured, commodity exchanges may impose a requirement to take out insurance for general damages caused by intermediaries. For instance, the Slovakian Bratislava Commodity Exchange requires every intermediary to take out insurance as a condition of issuing a trading authorization.51 However, such insurance may not be sufficient to cover all losses resulting from insolvency. Private insurance is not a replacement for mandatory insurance schemes along the lines that have been established for bank account holders. Recent insolvencies prove that some form of insurance may be necessary to protect commodity account holders. Commodity account holders’ assets, which include commodity contracts as well as funds and other property provided as margin, are 47 Jack M. Platt, Legislative Proposal, Commodity Futures Account Protection, 6 HOFSTRA L. REV. 173, 183 (1977). 48 Joanne Morrison, Futures Industry Moves Forward with Enhanced Customer Protections, 23(1) FUTURES INDUSTRY 39 (2013). 49 CME Group, Family Farmer and Rancher Protection Fund, available at http://www.cmegroup.com/clearing/family-farmer-fund.html (last visited 11 December 2013). 50 In re MF Global Inc., 2013 Bankr. LEXIS 1578 (S.D.N.Y. Bkrt. 2013). In this case, one customer of MF Global argued that palladium certificates held in a commodity account constitute securities entitled to protections under SIPA. Ibid., *5. The critical element that distinguishes between a customer of a securities intermediary and that of a futures commission merchant is the entrustment of cash or securities for the purposes of trading securities. In re Madoff Inv. Sec. LLC, 708 F.3d at 426 (2d Cir. 2013). 51 Law on Commodity Exchange art. 26(5) (Slovk.). 200 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts protected against insolvency of their intermediaries by the requirement of intermediaries to segregate their proprietary assets from customer accounts.52 Similarly, in the securities holding system the intermediary must segregate its own proprietary securities account from the securities accounts of its customers. In the commodity intermediary’s insolvency, the account holders have the highest priority and are entitled to the return of customer property.53 Even if the intermediary failed to segregate some property belonging to account holders such assets shall be treated as customer property subject to the highest priority.54 Funds of commodity account holders of the same intermediary may be commingled and held in a single account at a bank or similar authorized institution.55 Individual customer-by-customer segregation would be operationally cumbersome and expensive to implement.56 Intermediaries may be required to obtain an acknowledgment of the depository institution that the funds deposited with it by the intermediary belong to its customers.57 It is important for regulatory agencies to verify that such funds have in fact been deposited and that the amount corresponds to the amount owed by the intermediary to its customers. When the customer property is insufficient to satisfy the claims of account holders in full, recourse may be had to other estate property.58 As a reaction to the recent failures of commodity intermediaries in the United States, regulators and self-regulating agencies have been studying proposals to institute measures that would allow for more efficient monitoring of the commodity account holders’ assets held by intermediaries. The US-based National Futures Association has partnered with 52 US commodity intermediaries must hold customer assets, including funds, separate from their own house property. 17 C.F.R. § 1.20 (2012). Joanne Morrison, An LSOC Tutorial: A New Customer Protection Model for Cleared Swaps Begins, 23(1) FUTURES INDUS. 32 (2012). 53 US Bankruptcy Code, 11 U.S.C. § 766 (2013) and the CFTC Rules implementing the Commodity Exchange Act, 17 C.F.R. § 190.01-10 (2012). The term ‘customer property’ is defined in the 11 U.S.C. § 761(10) (2013). CFTC Rules further identify fifteen different categories of customer property. 54 Brief of the CFTC Pursuant to the Court’s 17 November 2011 Order, In re MF Global, Case No. 11-2790 (MG) SIPA, at 4. 55 Futures Industry Association, Protection of Customer Funds, Frequently Asked Question, Version 2.0, 3 (June 2012). 56 Ibid., at 7. 57 National Futures Association, NFA Regulatory Requirements 3 (May 2013), available at https://www.nfa.futures.org/NFA-compliance/publicationlibrary/regulatory-requirements-guide.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013). 58 C.F.R. § 190.08(a)(1) (2012). Commodity account relationships 201 the CME Group to create an automated system that would allow for the daily monitoring of all customer segregated funds held by commodity intermediaries.59 Segregation of customer assets coupled with efficient monitoring of those assets, are the two essential protective measures of the rights of commodity account holders.60 With the increasing number of insolvencies and losses sustained by customers of failed intermediaries, the pressure on instituting some minimal insurance coverage will increase. Morrison, supra note 48, at 38. Authorization to act as a commodities intermediary may also require submission of an operational plan for maintaining segregation. 59 60 11. Commodity transfers, finality and security interests Assets such as funds and securities circulate in the marketplace and between accounts. Funds have relatively unlimited longevity and their existence is not terminated when they are transferred between bank accounts. Such transfers cause only a modification in the claims of depositors. Securities also have a relatively long life-span. Bonds may have limited maturities (e.g., a 5-year bond) but shares may exist indefinitely until the company goes bankrupt, decides to repurchase them or transforms into a privately held company. Transfers do not terminate securities and, like funds transfers, they only modify rights of account holders against their intermediaries. Accordingly, both funds and securities do not cease to exist when they are transferred from one account to another. In contrast to funds and securities, commodity contracts have limited longevity. The life of a futures contract essentially involves only two phases: 1) when an investor enters into a futures contract and the intermediary credits his commodity account; and 2) when the investor acquires another futures contract that offsets the original futures contract. The second stage thus terminates the existence of both futures contracts, which offset one another. This process of offsetting commodity contracts is also known as ‘close out’. The other form of settling a commodity contract is by delivery of the underlying commodity. Rules governing the operation of commodity exchanges and associated clearinghouses typically provide for the possibility to settle a commodity contract either in cash or by delivery.1 Commodity account holders, unlike their securities and bank account counterparts, do not transfer commodity contracts to one another. Instead they enforce their rights embedded in commodity contracts by acquiring offsetting positions or making/taking delivery of the underlying commodity. Accordingly, it would be misleading to refer to transferring commodity contracts within See Argentina Clearing Rulebook (available at http://www.argentina clearing.com.ar/English/legal_members/files.aspx) (last visited 11 December 2013) § 1.2.14. 1 202 Commodity transfers, finality and security interests 203 the commodity accounts holding system. While securities and bank account holders exercise their rights by ‘transferring away’ their interests in securities and claims against banks, commodity account holders exercise their rights by acquiring offsetting positions or enforcing delivery obligations. A transfer of securities and funds completed by a book entry is thus similar to the acquisition of an offsetting position or making/taking delivery of the underlying commodity. A holder of a commodity contract, whether written on an agricultural commodity, metals or financial assets, has two options: 1) to offset the commodity contract, or 2) to make/take delivery of the commodity. OFFSET Futures contracts have traditionally been settled by offset that does not involve delivery of a warehouse receipt or commodity. Instead offset of commodity contracts is effectuated by payment of price differences.2 Offset has been recognized as a legitimate and enforceable settlement mechanism since the beginning of the twentieth century, when the US Supreme Court rendered the decision in Christie.3 Since the Christie decision, offset has been deemed to have the same legal effects as actual delivery.4 The settlement of commodity contracts by offset is justifiable on a number of legal and practical grounds. Legal arguments revolve around the nature of commodity contracts as transactions in which parties deal with promises rather than commodities. A promise may not be physically delivered but only settled by some form of set-off that discharges the mutual obligations of the parties. Practice-oriented arguments allude to the facts that inadequate infrastructure in some markets simply does not allow efficient physical deliveries over long distances.5 The offset in commodity markets operates as follows. Suppose that Steve and Brian, through their intermediaries, Goldman Sachs and RJO This feature or ability to offset obligations distinguishes futures contracts from forwards and similar agreements. See CFTC v. Int’l Fin. Servs., 323 F Supp 2d 482 (S.D.N.Y. 2004). 3 Board of Trade v. Christie Grain & Stock Co., 198 U.S. 236, 248–50 (1905). 4 See also Lyons Milling Co. v. Goffe & Carkener, Inc., 46 F.2d 241, 247 (10th Cir. 1931). 5 Golaka C. Nath & Thulasamma Lingareddy, Commodity Derivative Market and its Impact on Spot Market 2, available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/ papers.cfm?abstract_id=1087904 (last visited 11 December 2013) (January 2008). 2 204 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts Futures, enter into a futures contract. Steve acquires rights to sell corn and Brian acquires a right to buy corn. Upon execution, of their respective orders, which are matched on a commodity exchange, the futures contract is cleared and two new contracts with the clearinghouse are established. As a result of clearing, Steve has the right to sell 100 kilos of corn for US$ 500 in six months and Brian has the right to buy 100 kilos of corn for US$ 500 in six months. The clearinghouse becomes the counterparty to both Steve and Brian on their respective contracts. Now suppose that Steve wants to close out his futures contract. He does not intend to make delivery of the corn, whether or not his futures contract is profitable. Suppose four months later, just before the delivery month, the same futures contract for delivery of 100 kilos of corn trades for US$ 450. Steve may acquire the same futures contract to buy 100 kilos of corn for the current market price of US$ 450. Once Steve acquires this second corn futures contract it will be again cleared and the clearinghouse becomes Steve’s counterparty. Now Steve is the seller under the first futures contract where he agreed to sell for US$ 500 to the clearinghouse. Steve is also the buyer of corn under the second futures contract where he agreed to buy from the clearinghouse for US$ 450. Steve and the clearinghouse have two offsetting contracts, whereby Steve agreed to sell for US$ 500 and buy for US$ 450. These two obligations offset one another with the result that Steve will collect US$ 50 from the clearinghouse and the two futures contracts will get closed out. However, the clearinghouse is not the party that ultimately bears the loss, i.e., by paying Steve his profit of US$ 50. As mentioned earlier, for every ‘long’ there is a ‘short’. With respect to the second contract that Steve acquired for US$ 450, there must be a seller. Suppose that Brian does not want to take delivery and decides to enter into a futures contract to sell 100 kilos of corn for the then market price of US$ 450. After clearing, Brian’s two contracts against the clearinghouse will be novated in a manner equivalent to Steve’s contracts. However in Brian’s case, he bought for US$ 500 and sold for US$ 450 so he owes US$ 50 to the clearinghouse. Settlement by offset is feasible only if the commodity market is sufficiently liquid. In an illiquid market with a few participants who trade only occasionally, the participants may be forced to make/take delivery if they are not able to acquire offsetting positions prior to the delivery month. Offset may also be difficult to achieve in OTC markets in which the contracts are customized by the parties. Offset is accomplished by the payment of price differences. In the previous illustration, Brian owes the clearinghouse US$ 50 and the clearinghouse owes US$ 50 to Steve. The clearinghouse will not send a Commodity transfers, finality and security interests 205 check to Steve or credit his bank account. Neither will it collect payment directly from Brian. Instead it will deal with Steve’s and Brian’s intermediaries, Goldman Sachs and RJO Futures, who are its clearing members. The clearinghouse will collect payments from and make payments to the clearing members for all commodity contracts that their customers offset. To complete such payments clearing members must maintain settlement bank accounts.6 Establishment of a settlement bank account with a financial institution approved by the clearinghouse is typically one of the requirements for granting a clearing license. The offset settlement could not be accomplished without the cooperation of banks.7 PHYSICAL DELIVERY Although exchange-traded commodity contracts are rarely settled by actual delivery, they all contemplate that the commodity account holder may be required to make or take delivery unless he closes out before the delivery month.8 The delivery month is the last month when the futures contract expires. The possibility to make/take delivery applies only to futures contracts. In contrast, option contracts holders do not have any obligation to make/take delivery and may let their options expire. The commodity account holder is alerted to the possibility of having to make/take delivery in the account agreement. Commodity account agreements regularly provide for the right of the account holder to submit 6 REFCO PRIVATE CLIENT GROUP, THE COMPLETE GUIDE TO FUTURES TRADING 6 (JOHN WILEY & SONS, INC., HOBOKEN, NJ, 2005). The Commodity Exchange Bratislava requires its participants to open deposit accounts at one of the authorized banks. The Rules of the exchange provide for three types of deposit accounts: 1) a type A account that is held by the exchange itself and to which participants post their margin payments; 2) a type B account that is held by a participant in order to effect payments for delivered commodities; and 3) a type C account that is held in order to receive payments for exchange transactions. Rules of the Commodity Exchange Bratislava, Annex 8: GuaranteeSettling System KBB 1, § 2 (30 July 2010), available at http://www.en.kbb.sk/ Guarantee%20systems/ (last visited 11 December 2013). 7 LEO MELAMED, ESCAPE TO THE FUTURES 185 (JOHN WILEY & SONS, INC., US, 1996). 8 H.S. Irwin, Legal Status of Trading in Futures, 32 ILL. L. REV. 157 (1937–1938) and RICHARD J. TEWELES, CHARLES V. HARLOW & HERBERT L. STONE, THE COMMODITY FUTURES GAME, WHO WINS?, WHO LOSES?, WHY? 61 (MCGRAW-HILL, NEW YORK, NY, 1974). 206 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts offsetting instructions to the intermediary with respect to the futures contracts that mature in the current month. Such instructions must be received by the intermediary a certain number of days prior to the last trading day.9 The delivery obligation is also reiterated in the confirmation that the intermediary sends to its customer after execution of an order to acquire a commodity contract. The possibility of settlement by actual delivery under futures contracts is the factor that connects commodity markets with the spot (cash) market.10 Otherwise, commodity contracts traded on exchanges would remain purely speculative instruments.11 The correlation between commodity contracts and the physical market was included as one of the guiding principles prepared by IOSCO, which were endorsed at the G20 Summit in November 2011.12 According to Principle 3, the commodity contract must be designed to reflect price conditions in the underlying market and facilitate the convergence of prices.13 As described above, futures contracts may be written on a variety of assets, including agricultural commodities and financial instruments. Delivery of corn is obviously completed in a different setting than the delivery of a security. For this reason commodity exchanges provide for various mechanisms to accomplish settlement by delivery depending on the nature of the underlying asset.14 To settle a contract by physical delivery, commodity exchanges and clearinghouses promulgate rules either as part of the Rulebook (Regulations) or in a special supplement. Argentina Clearing S.A. published ‘Instructions for Delivery of Goods’ which governs physical settlement. According to Article 1.1, the Instructions complement, but do not replace, the Rulebook. Advantage Futures LLC Commodity Futures Customer Agreement, art. 15 Liquidating Instructions (on file with author). 10 Irwin, supra note 8, at 156. 11 In Volkart Bros. Inc. v. Orville L. Freeman, 311 F.2d 52 (5th Cir. 1962), the US 5th Circuit court observed that: ‘The legality of every futures exchange rests on the obligation of the parties to the futures contract to deliver or take delivery of the commodity unless the contract has been liquidated by offset on the exchange.’ 12 IOSCO, Survey on the Principles for the Regulation and Supervision of Commodity Derivatives Markets, 6 (October 2012), available at http:// www.iosco.org/library/pubdocs/pdf/IOSCOPD393.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013). 13 Ibid., at 8. 14 See CME Rulebook, Chapter 7, Delivery Facilities and Delivery Procedures, available at http://www.cmegroup.com/rulebook/CME/I/7/7.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013). 9 Commodity transfers, finality and security interests 207 Recall the illustration where Steve acquired two futures contracts for delivery of 100 kilos of corn that offset one another. Failure to offset a futures contract will trigger the customer’s obligation to provide the intermediary with adequate instructions including a warehouse receipt to complete delivery. In the case that the customer becomes obligated to take delivery, the customer must provide sufficient funds to cover the purchase price. As part of their risk management, some commodity exchanges, such as the CME, authorize clearing members to assess their account holders’ ability to make/take delivery prior to the last day of trading in the particular contract. If the clearing member determines that the account holder may not be able to settle its commodity contract by physical delivery the clearing member may liquidate the contract by offset.15 Delivery under a futures contract is accomplished like delivery in spot and forward markets – by exchange of a warehouse receipt for funds. The process of actual delivery on the commodity exchange involves a number of steps. First, the account holder (Steve) submits delivery instructions to its intermediary who in turn notifies the clearinghouse as to the intention to make delivery. However, the clearinghouse does not make/take delivery and instead it identifies the buyer (the other side of the contract such as Brian) and notifies him of his duty to take delivery. Since the number of ‘sell’ futures contracts always matches the number of ‘buy’ contracts there will always be a buyer or seller ready to make/take delivery. The following paragraphs illustrate the settlement by delivery at the CME and Argentina Clearing S.A. To settle a commodity contract by delivery through the CME the seller must tender a standardized delivery notice to the clearinghouse.16 The notice must indicate the net invoice price that is calculated on the basis of the last settlement price of the commodity contract. Transferable notices reference a commodity or a warehouse receipt that is to be delivered by the seller.17 The transferable notice serves two functions: 1) to notify the Ibid. § 716. Ibid. § 713. 17 A transferable notice typically refers to the warehouse receipt that represents the commodity to be delivered under the futures contract and includes the following language: ‘We have on hand ready for delivery the following described Warehouse Receipts, and hereby make tender to you of the same, in fulfillment of our contract of sale.’ GEORGE WRIGHT HOFFMAN, FUTURE TRADING UPON ORGANIZED COMMODITY MARKETS IN THE UNITED STATES 194 (UNIVERSITY OF PENNSYLVANIA PRESS, PHILADELPHIA, PA, 1932). For similar language in the transferable notice see JULIUS B. BAER & OLIN GLENN SAXON, 15 16 208 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts buyer that the seller is ready to make delivery, and 2) to temporarily replace the warehouse receipt in the settlement of outstanding futures contracts so as to avoid its loss or destruction.18 The clearinghouse will then forward the delivery notice to the clearing member that holds the oldest contract to take delivery of the particular commodity. The buyer who received a delivery notice must then pay the invoice price. Submission and transmission of delivery notices is commonly done electronically. Similarly, Argentina Clearing S.A. requires sellers under commodity contracts to submit delivery notices for the outstanding futures contracts that they intend to settle by physical delivery between the first and fifteenth day of the last contract month.19 The clearinghouse shall then notify the buyer to whom it has assigned the delivery notice. Such buyers must submit an Application for Assignment of Delivery Notice to the clearinghouse.20 The notification shall be accomplished by transmitting a bill of sale for the goods.21 Clearinghouses may also charge reasonable fees for facilitating the delivery of underlying assets. The Argentina Clearing S.A. requires buyers to pay a fee of 1 percent of the invoice price.22 FINALITY The preceding Parts distinguished finality of transfer orders and finality of actual transfers. The first finality rule applies between the sender of an COMMODITY EXCHANGES AND FUTURES TRADING, PRINCIPLES AND OPERATING METHODS 183 (HARPER, NEW YORK, NY, 1949): ‘We pledge ourselves to deliver on the day specified for delivery, to the last acceptor thereof, documents upon written notice of the holding of this notice given to us by the last acceptor hereof before 4pm on the day this notice is issued. This notice is to be delivered to us simultaneously with our delivery of the documents to the last acceptor hereof.’ (Emphasis added.) See also H.J. Loman, Commodity Exchange Clearing Systems, in ANNALS OF THE AMERICAN ACADEMY OF POLITICAL AND SOCIAL SCIENCE, VOL. 155, PART 1: ORGANIZED COMMODITY MARKETS 100, 102 (AMERICAN ACADEMY OF POLITICAL AND SOCIAL SCIENCE, PHILADELPHIA, PA, 1931). 18 HOFFMAN, supra note 17, at 193. 19 Argentina Clearing S.A., Instructions for Delivery of Goods – Argentina Clearing, § 2.2 (2nd edn., 2008) (on file with the author). 20 Ibid. § 2.3. 21 Ibid. § 2.5. 22 Ibid. § 1.2. Commodity transfers, finality and security interests 209 order and its intermediary while the second applies between the beneficiary of the order and its intermediary. The first type of finality as it regards an order submitted by the account holder to his intermediary also applies in commodity accounts holding systems. However, the second type of finality applies in commodity accounts systems to a limited extent because commodity account holders do not transfer commodity contracts between each other. Accordingly, the finality of transfer will be limited to the acquisition of a commodity contract that is associated with a book entry made by a commodity intermediary to an account of its customers. Commodity intermediaries may specialize only in the execution of orders and rely on other intermediaries for clearing, or they may provide full services.23 When an intermediary receives an order from a customer it must time-stamp the order and indicate the account and order number.24 Generally an order may no longer be revoked after it has been executed by the intermediary. Transfers of securities and funds are accomplished by modification of the relationships between intermediaries and their account holders. Account holders may dispose of securities and funds by ordering their intermediaries to transfer them to designated transferees. The account balance of the transferor is then reduced and the account balance of the transferee is correspondingly increased. This is not the case with transfers of commodity contracts in which the acquisition of an offsetting futures contract effectively modifies only the relationship between the commodity account holder and his intermediary. There is no sequel of transfers when one closes out a futures contract. All actions are performed within the particular commodity account holder-intermediary relationship. Unlike in the case of securities and funds transfers in which third parties rely on the finality of preceding transfers, the finality of acquisitions and offsets of commodity contracts is internal to the particular commodity account relationship. Account agreements between commodity intermediaries and their customers establish when the customer acquires a futures contract and when the futures contract is considered closed out. Like securities and bank accounts, entries made by intermediaries to their customer accounts determine the finality of acquisitions and offsets. FIA, Order Handling Risk Management Recommendations for Executing Brokers, 4 (2012), available at http://www.futuresindustry.org/downloads/Order_ Handling-Ex_Brokers.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013). 24 National Futures Association, NFA Regulatory Requirements 2 (May 2013), available at https://www.nfa.futures.org/NFA-compliance/publicationlibrary/regulatory-requirements-guide.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013). 23 210 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts COMMODITY CONTRACTS AND COMMODITY ACCOUNTS AS COLLATERAL Commodity contracts, commodity accounts and actual commodities may all function as collateral under commercial loans. From the perspective of secured transactions laws the following assets should be distinguished: 1) exchange-traded commodity contracts (e.g., futures) and commodity accounts; OTC commodity contracts (e.g., forwards); and actual commodities and documents of title (e.g., warehouse receipts). 2) 3) All of these assets are subject to different rules under secured transactions laws. Whereas secured transactions laws in many jurisdictions have, for decades, recognized pledging of commodities and representative documents of title, the taking of security interests in commodity contracts and accounts remains largely ignored in statutes and in practice. The hedging function of commodity contracts provides protection against price fluctuations not only to the merchant but also to a secured creditor that finances the underlying asset or the entire business of the merchant. From the secured creditor’s perspective the value of its collateral may increase if the price risk has been hedged. Suppose that Steve, who grows corn, exports his crop. Steve’s business operations are financed by a revolving bank loan secured with growing and future crops, equipment and accounts receivable. The value of the crop may fluctuate in the absence of long-term contracts that fix the purchase price. Consequently, the creditor is exposed to a potential risk of deterioration in the market value of the collateral and may face the risk of the debtor’s default if the market price of the crop significantly decreases. To hedge against this risk the creditor may require Steve to enter into a futures contract to sell corn. The bank could then take a security interest in such a futures contract and thus protect the value of its collateral. Banks regularly provide credit at a reduced cost if the price of the commodity pledged as collateral has been hedged.25 According to some studies, banks lend up to 10 percent or even 20 percent more if the commodity provided as collateral is hedged.26 As one author noted, HOFFMAN, supra note 17, at 380–2. HAROLD S. IRWIN, EVOLUTION OF FUTURES TRADING 53 (MIMIR PUBLISHERS INC., MADISON, WI, 1954). 25 26 Commodity transfers, finality and security interests 211 ‘banks rely less on the word of mouth and more on the security implied in the hedge’.27 Consequently, the ability of the creditor to effectively manage and reduce risks should translate into a lower cost of credit for the borrower. It should be highlighted that the collateral value of a futures contract fluctuates and may be either profitable for the borrower and the creditor or at times, may turn negative when the market moves against the borrower. For instance, Steve entered into a futures contract to sell corn in six months for the price of US$ 100 but at the expiration of the contract the market price of corn increases to US$ 110. Steve will close out the futures contract and sustain a loss of US$ 10, but will be able to sell his corn for US$ 110 in the spot market. The collateral value of such futures contract will be zero. In contrast, if the market price of corn decreased to US$ 90 Steve would close out the futures contract, take the profit of US$ 10 and sell his corn for the market price of US$ 90. In this case a security interest in the futures contract and its cash proceeds is extremely valuable to the creditor. In both situations the collateral value is underpinned by either the increasing market price of corn in the spot market or by potential gains on the futures contract. In the United States, UCC Article 9 governs security interests in personal property including commodity contracts and commodity accounts. Official Comment 6 to UCC 9-102 explains that the most likely situation in which a creditor takes a security interest in a commodity contract is when it finances inventory of a commodity that is susceptible to price fluctuations. UCC 9 is one of the few laws that: 1) provides for security interests in commodity contracts or commodity accounts, and 2) draws a distinction between futures and forwards. UCC 9 classifies commodity futures contracts and commodity accounts within a broader collateral type of investment property, along with securities and financial assets, security entitlements and securities accounts.28 This broader classification of security and commodity assets under a single collateral type resulted from the pattern in which both these categories of investment property are held. Commodity contracts as well as securities are carried in their respective accounts with relevant intermediaries. However, only exchange-traded commodity contracts are carried in commodity accounts maintained by intermediaries and only this category of 27 Kenneth J. Lipartito, The New York Cotton Exchange and the Development of the Cotton Futures Market, 57(1) BUS. HIST. REV. 50, 50–1 (1983). 28 UCC 9-102(a)(49) (1999) and Saskatchewan, Personal Property Security Act,§ 2(1)(x.1) (1993) (SS) [hereinafter Saskatchewan PPSA]. 212 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts commodity contracts is classified as investment property under UCC 9.29 OTC commodity contracts fall under the residual category of ‘general intangibles’.30 Perfection by control is not available for commodity contracts and commodity accounts that do not qualify as investment property under UCC 9. In the jurisdictions where secured transactions laws do not expressly provide for the taking of security interests in commodity contracts, it is possible for creditors to take such security interests by complying with the rules on the creation and perfection of security interests in executory contracts. Many jurisdictions provide for a catch-all category of ‘rights’ or ‘claims’, or refer generally to ‘any rights’ that may be used as collateral. Such categorizations seem to be broad enough to include executory promises in the form of commodity contracts. Special provisions are provided in Chapters III and IV of the OAS Model Law for taking security interests in accounts receivable and non-monetary claims. Under the OAS Model Law a security interest in a forward contract may be created by complying with the rules on accounts receivable and non-monetary claims. A claim under a futures contract may also be used as collateral by complying with the rules on accounts receivable. The OAS Model Law and secured transactions laws in the vast majority of jurisdictions do not distinguish between futures and forwards. The EU Financial Collateral Directive applies to financial collateral that is defined in Article 2 to include cash and financial instruments. However, commodity contracts and accounts do not fall under the scope of the Directive. Article 1(k) of MiFID expressly excludes ‘persons whose main business consists of dealing on own account in commodities and/or commodity derivatives’ from its scope. Security interests in commodity contracts and commodity accounts are thus not covered.31 Accordingly, for regulation of security interests in commodity contracts/ accounts one must resort to the local law of EU Member States. None of the EU Member States has enacted legislation or specific rules that would 29 UCC 9-102 (1999) Official Comment 6 provides that the UCC Article 9 investment property covers only the category of contracts that fall under the jurisdiction of the CFTC. 30 This classification would most likely apply to rights to payment as well as to rights to delivery under OTC contracts. Mark A. Guinn & William L. Harvey, Taking OTC Derivative Contracts as Collateral, 57 BUS. LAW. 1127, 1140 (2002). 31 The EU Financial Collateral Directive provides for the perfection of security interests by control only for financial instruments and funds. Commodity transfers, finality and security interests 213 facilitate collateralization of commodity contracts and accounts. Typically, the laws of EU Member States provide that a security interest may be created over a thing, a right or other monetary asset, as long as it is transferable.32 Accordingly, a commodity contract may be used as collateral unless its transferability has been restricted. Generally, exchange-traded commodity contracts are not subject to any restrictions on transfer and OTC contracts may be transferred by assignment. Laws in many jurisdictions neither provide for a specific type of commodity property collateral nor do they provide for a special perfection mechanism for such security interests. Jurisdictions in which viable commodity exchanges have been established and where businesses regularly enter into contracts for future delivery of commodities should adopt more specific rules to encourage creditors to use commodity contracts and commodity accounts as collateral. International rules and recent legislative projects in the area of secured lending entirely exempt commodity contracts from their scope. Article 4(2) of the 2001 UN Convention on the Assignment of Receivables in International Trade exempts assignments of receivables that arise from contracts concluded on regulated exchanges, including spot, forward, future, option or swap agreements involving commodities.33 This category of exempted financial contracts has been carried over to the UNCITRAL Legislative Guide.34 Consequently, jurisdictions that contemplate a modernization of their secured transactions laws must seek guidance elsewhere. In this regard the legal framework adopted in UCC 9 may be a model. Perfection by Control After the creditor has adequately classified and described commodity contracts or accounts in the security agreement, the creditor should perfect its security interest in order to obtain protection against competing claimants. For security interests in commodity contracts and See CIV. C. art. 151(d) (Slovk.). United Nations Convention on the Assignment of Receivables in International Trade, 12 December 2001, G.A. Res. 56/81, 56th Sess., U.N. Doc. A/RES/56/81 (31 January 2002), available at http://www.uncitral.org/pdf/ english/texts/payments/receivables/ctc-assignment-convention-e.pdf (last visited 11 December 2013). 34 UNCITRAL Legislative Guide on Secured Transactions, UN Sales No. E.09.V.12 (2010), 20. 32 33 214 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts commodity accounts, two perfection mechanisms are generally available: 1) registration (filing) and 2) control.35 Under UCC 9 a security interest in commodity contracts and commodity accounts may be taken either by the intermediary that maintains the commodity account or by a third-party creditor. The UCC 9 rules for perfection by control vary depending on whether the creditor is the intermediary or a third party. The intermediary may perfect a security interest in its customer’s commodity contracts and commodity accounts automatically upon attachment.36 Under UCC 9 automatic perfection is also available to banks and securities intermediaries that maintain the relevant accounts. Upon opening a commodity account the customer typically grants a security interest to his intermediary in all assets carried in such account, including those to be acquired in the future. A security interest of a commodity intermediary may also cover funds that are used by the customer for the acquisition of commodity contracts. In addition to granting a security interest, the customer regularly acknowledges in the account agreement that the intermediary has the right of set-off against the customer’s property for margin, commissions and fees incurred by the customer. Securities intermediaries regularly provide margin loans to their customers to purchase securities. Margins are also used in the commodities industry but play a very different role. Melamed summarized the differences between the two markets with respect to margins as follows: Securities market margin is a direct measure of the creation of bank credit. It determines the proportion between the amount paid for securities and the amount borrowed for their purchase. There is no such relation in futures markets. In future markets, margin acts as a surety or security deposit.37 A futures contract margin is a sign of good faith functioning as an assurance against the risk of the customer’s insolvency.38 In contrast, a 35 UCC 9-313(a) and 9-314(a) (1999). Compare also Saskatchewan PPSA §§ 24–5. 36 Ibid., 9-309(11). 9-106(b)(1) provides that ‘a secured party has control of a commodity contract if the secured party is the commodity intermediary with which the commodity contract is carried’. 37 LEO MELAMED, ON THE MARKETS, TWENTY YEARS OF FINANCIAL HISTORY AS SEEN BY THE MAN WHO REVOLUTIONIZED THE MARKETS 112 (JOHN WILEY & SONS, INC., US, 1993). 38 PETER G. ZHANG, BARINGS INSOLVENCY AND FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES 52 (WORLD SCIENTIFIC PUBLISHING CO. PTE. LTD., SINGAPORE, 1995). Commodity transfers, finality and security interests 215 securities margin is an extension of credit corresponding to the proportion of the purchase price of a security. Securities margin conveys to the customer a right to the security – a property right – while a futures margin represents only a promise to acquire an asset in the future – a contractual right.39 Since the securities margin is a down payment and the outstanding balance is an extension of credit by the intermediary the customer pays interest on the amount owed. In contrast the futures margin is not a down payment and the intermediary does not extend credit for the remaining portion.40 Because commodity intermediaries do not extend margin loans to their customers they do not take purchase money security interests in their customers’ commodity contracts. Margins in commodity markets are significantly lower than those required in securities markets because they neither reflect a proportion of the purchase price nor are they considered extensions of credit.41 Typically, on US commodity exchanges margins range from 2 percent to 15 percent of the value of the commodity contract but the intermediary may demand a higher margin.42 In Slovakia the required minimum margin is 2 percent of the value of the commodity contract.43 Commodity margins are assessed on a daily basis and must be paid before the opening of the next trading day. A security interest in commodity contracts and commodity accounts may also be taken by a third party. However, automatic perfection is not available to non-intermediary creditors. Pursuant to UCC 9 a creditor may perfect its security interest in an exchange-traded commodity contract and/or a commodities account by having the intermediary, the debtor and itself execute a control agreement.44 The control agreement will obligate the commodity intermediary to follow instructions of the creditor regarding the application of any value distributed on account of Ray L. Ross, Financial Consequences of Trading Commodity Futures Contracts, 15(2) ILL. AGRI. ECON. 27 (1975). 40 In fact, commodity intermediaries (e.g., CME clearing members) are prohibited from providing loans to their customers to cover margin calls. CME Rulebook § 930.G. Equally, the clearinghouse is typically prohibited from providing any financing to the clearing members to cover their margin requirements. See Argentina Clearing Rulebook (available at http://www. argentinaclearing.com.ar/English/legal_members/files.aspx) § 5.1.4. 41 Futures margins may be compared to money held in escrow by a realtor on the sale of real estate. Ross, supra note 39, at 27. 42 REFCO PRIVATE CLIENT GROUP, supra note 6, at 7. 43 Rules of the Commodity Exchange Bratislava, supra note 6, at Annex 8, § 3. 44 UCC 9-106(b)(2) (1999) and Saskatchewan PPSA § 2(1)(1.1.c). 39 216 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts the collateral without further consent of the debtor. In a typical control agreement the commodity intermediary confirms that it will maintain a commodity account ‘number 123’ for the customer and covenants not to change the name or the account number without prior consent of the creditor. The intermediary also regularly covenants not to enter into other control agreements without the creditor’s consent. The control agreement will typically permit the commodity account holder to perform additional transactions with the encumbered commodity account. The trading authority thus remains with the commodity account holder while the creditor acquires the power to dispose (management rights) of the encumbered property. Upon concluding a control agreement the commodity intermediary will assume the duty to comply with all instructions received from the creditor to liquidate any commodity contracts without further consent of the account holder. Typically, the creditor will exercise its management rights with respect to the commodity collateral only when the debtor defaults. If the creditor has taken control over all commodity contracts held in the commodity account it will be deemed to be perfected with respect to the entire commodity account.45 In US practice, creditors take security interests over the entire commodity account rather than over individual commodity contracts credited to such account.46 As demonstrated in the preceding two Parts, some jurisdictions have traditionally refused to recognize perfection of a security interest via a control agreement. The criticism of control agreements and the concept of control in general mentioned in the context of securities accounts apply equally to commodity accounts. Control agreements permit the debtor to deal with the collateral until the creditor decides to exercise its control rights. In some jurisdictions with unreformed secured transactions laws, this division of rights between the debtor and creditor may be inconsistent with the requirement that the debtor be stripped of all indicia of ownership, possession and control over the collateral. Perfection by Filing Filing is the other perfection mechanism that is utilized by creditors to perfect their security interests in account-based rights. Many jurisdictions expressly allow filing for security interests in account-based securities and, by default in absence of rules to the contrary, also with respect to 45 46 UCC 9-106(c) (1999). Official Comment 6 to UCC 9-102 (1999). Commodity transfers, finality and security interests 217 deposit accounts. While many secured transactions laws and special laws provide for the perfection of security interests in account-based securities and funds credited to bank accounts, this is less common for commodity contracts and accounts. The UNCITRAL Legislative Guide recommends that security interests in commodity contracts and accounts be excluded from the scope of general secured transactions laws. If a jurisdiction implements this recommendation and has not otherwise regulated such security interests there will be a legal vacuum that may prevent creditors from utilizing commodity contracts and accounts as collateral. A contrary interpretation may lead to the conclusion that what is not expressly excluded falls under the scope of secured transactions laws. In these laws, such as those adopted in Colombia, Slovakia, etc., a security interest may arguably be created and perfected by complying with the rules for security interests in accounts receivable, monetary or non-monetary claims. Perfection of such security interests would require filing in the registry of security interests. Filing is also an alternative perfection mechanism for security interests in securities accounts and, in some jurisdictions, deposit accounts. UCC 9 has adopted a different approach and included specific rules on the perfection of security interests in investment property, including commodity contracts and accounts. Under UCC 9, perfection may be accomplished by both control and filing. However, the priority rules subordinate a security interest perfected by filing to a security interest perfected by control, irrespective of their respective time of perfection.47 Control is thus the superior perfection mechanism that overrides even the traditional first-in-time, first-in-right rule and primes an earlier security interest perfected by filing. A similar priority rule also applies to security interests in account-based securities. 47 UCC 9-328(1) (1999) and Saskatchewan PPSA § 35(2). 12. Summary of Part III Commodity contracts, commodity accounts and commodity exchanges have become important risk management tools. They are integrated within the business and legal infrastructure of a number of economies that have recognized the value of commodity markets and their positive influence on economic development. However, the contribution of commodity markets to economic growth is frequently underestimated and occasionally even altogether ignored. Although commercial entities should benefit from the presence of commodity markets by having access to a mechanism that enables them to effectively manage their risks, critics often blame commodity markets for price increases and throw them into the same category as gambling and betting. This criticism is driven by the misunderstanding of the nature of risks involved in commercial activity. Stakeholders in developing countries should become familiar with the functions of organized commodity markets in order to assess whether their establishment would support economic growth. Understandably, this area of commercial activity and law is not as noticeable as securities markets and payment systems. However, just as companies utilize securities markets to raise capital by issuing shares and bonds, commodity markets provide similar opportunities to hedge against risks and reduce the cost of capital. Commercial risks inherent in commercial activities became valuable and highly liquid assets. These risks were packaged into commodity contracts and began to be traded on organized commodity markets. Organization of efficient commodity markets requires understanding of the rights conveyed by commodity contracts. Unlike the traditional sale contracts with deferred delivery that are consummated by actual transfer of possession of the commodity, exchange-traded commodity contracts do not convey any property rights to the underlying commodity. They exist independently of property rights in actual commodities and they reside in accounts held by commodity intermediaries. Commodity contracts consist of an exchange of executory promises. Customarily parties to such contracts neither perform their obligations by delivery of the actual commodity nor transfer any property rights. 218 Summary of Part III 219 Such contractual promises have been standardized and are now commonly traded on commodity exchanges. It is important to distinguish between, on the one hand standardized exchange-traded commodity contracts, such as futures and options and, on the other hand, commodity contracts that are individualized and executed in OTC markets. Only the former should be made subject to special commodity laws. Regulation of the latter should be left to private agreements and contract law. However, the legislator should tread carefully so as not to exempt too many contracts or include those that should be excluded from commodity laws. The scope of commodity laws must remain flexible so as to include new commodity contracts and related instruments that frequently emerge from the industry practice. Commodity markets may be established to trade rights to future delivery of a variety of commodities and financial assets. Commodity markets originated as venues for exchanges and holding of rights to delivery of agricultural commodities. Due to de-regulation of various financial instruments (e.g., trading in currencies), commodity markets in financial assets have become the dominant force. Many commodity markets recently established in developing countries (e.g., Mexico) provide for futures and options contracts on financial assets, such as currencies and securities. The scope of commodity laws and the type of assets subject to centralized commodity trading significantly impacts the back-end infrastructure and particularly the tools necessary to complete settlement. The structure of organized commodity markets is largely uniform, with US exchanges and clearinghouses serving as the model for many systems. The critical component of every trading, as well as the holding, system for commodity contracts is the clearinghouse. The commodity clearinghouse performs functions similar to the clearinghouse in a securities settlement system. They both reduce the counterparty risks and facilitate the settlement of transactions. Unlike in the case of payment and securities settlement systems every commodity contract is subject to mandatory clearing at the clearinghouse. The clearinghouse becomes the central counterparty to all exchange-traded commodity contracts. As a result, it must be wellcapitalized and regulated. In practice, established and reputable clearinghouses provide clearing functions for multiple commodity markets. Although the clearinghouse is the central counterparty to every commodity contract, it does not deal directly with individual commodity account holders. Only authorized clearing intermediaries have access to the clearinghouse. Such clearing members clear their own, as well as their customers’, commodity contracts. 220 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts Since the rights of commodity account holders are of a contractual nature, certain mechanisms must be provided to assure their protection. It was demonstrated in the previous Part that the rights of bank account holders against their banks are similarly contractual and that the main tool to protect bank account holders is mandatory insurance. Rights of securities accounts holders are protected by property law as well as mandatory insurance. Insurance protection has not been provided for commodity account holders. The only protection of the rights of commodity account holders is strict segregation of their commodity contracts from the contracts entered into by the intermediary for its own account. However, whether this protection is adequate and whether some form of insurance should be mandated is being questioned in the aftermath of insolvencies of major commodity intermediaries. Commodity contracts and markets deal only with executory contractual promises. The vast majority of these promises are settled by offset. Participants in commodity markets acquire offsetting contracts and settle their obligations by the payment of differences. For such settlement to be successfully accomplished, adequate and efficient connections with the payment system must be provided. Many commodity exchanges trade contracts to delivery of securities. A proper mechanism for potential delivery of securities must also be provided. In the case of security futures, all three types of commercial systems for bank, commodity and securities accounts interact. The security futures contract is held in a commodity account and when the holder elects to exercise the right to take delivery, the security will be transferred between securities accounts in exchange for payment by credits and debits to bank accounts. For agricultural commodities and metals, exchanges must maintain adequate storage facilities that warehouse products ready for delivery under commodity contracts. Commodity contracts have become an important factor that affects the decision of creditors to provide credit. From its marginal role, the commodity contract developed into valuable collateral. Lenders routinely discount the actual market value of the collateral to account for the potential risks in price fluctuations. If this risk is eliminated the creditor may safely rely on the actual collateral value of the commodity. Commodity contracts effectively eliminate this risk and allow borrowers to access credit on more reasonable terms. Legislators should take note of the growing role of commodity contracts and provide for legal rules that would allow creditors to take security interests in commodity contracts and accounts at a reasonable cost. Control mechanisms that are increasingly used in the securities industry for perfecting security interests in account-based securities are easily adaptable to security interests in Summary of Part III 221 commodity rights held in accounts. Furthermore, an easily accessible registration system should also be established for the perfection of security interests, not only in commodity property, but in any personal property. Globalization of economies and dematerialization of trading in commodity contracts, and their holding in commodity accounts, broadened access for foreign investors. Even though cross-border transactions with commodity contracts do not pose challenges as serious as those of the cross-border holding of securities, international cooperation on a regulatory level may be desired. Regulators in different countries already cooperate on more general informational and oversight levels. Further cooperation, particularly with respect to the effort to harmonize rules on the perfection of security interests in commodity contracts and accounts, has the potential to broaden access to credit. Commodity exchanges may not function properly without adequate back-end functions. Robust trading activity requires modern hardware and software for holding and liquidating commodity contracts held in accounts. The main objective of this Part was to examine these back-end processes and highlight the necessary components of a modern organized commodity market. Conclusion This book attempted to explore and analyse the fundamental features and legal aspects of an emerging trend in commercial practice, which is the holding of assets in accounts with intermediaries. Such holding is a relatively new structural and legal phenomenon based on principles developed over the millennia. In the last couple of decades, the holding systems for rights to securities, funds and commodity contracts have become not only integrated within the commercial marketplace but have also overshadowed many other traditional areas of commercial law. Local and international legislators no longer attempt to modernize the law of negotiable instruments, payments by check, deposits, bailments or paperbased documents of title;1 instead their focus is gradually shifting to the law of account relationships.2 Traces of the emerging law of account relationships may be found in international instruments drafted by UNCITRAL, UNIDROIT and other international organizations. Reforms in other areas of commercial law inevitably touch on some aspects of accounts relationships, whether they be the reforms of secured transactions laws and their regulation of security interests in account-based rights or the reforms of insolvency laws and their protection of the rights of account holders in the case of an insolvency of the intermediary. Account-based rights have come to play a significant role in commercial transactions. Hence there is a need for examination of account-based systems, their functions and fundamental features in order to craft efficient rules that no longer rely on traditional concepts such as transfer by negotiation. The primary function of account-based systems is to facilitate clearing and transfers of executed transactions. Clearing, transfers, delivery and settlement are all back-end functions that result from a trade. Once an 1 Some experts have even called for the abolishment of the law on negotiable instruments. See JAMES STEVEN ROGERS, THE END OF NEGOTIABLE INSTRUMENTS, BRINGING PAYMENT SYSTEMS LAW OUT OF THE PAST xvii (OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS, NEW YORK, NY, 2012). 2 ‘In modern economies, the financial infrastructure rests largely on intermediaries …’ José M. Garrido, The Loss-sharing Rule in the Insolvency of Financial Intermediaries, 15(3-4) UNIF. L. REV. 779 (2010). 222 Conclusion 223 agreement to purchase a security or acquire a commodity contract for payment of a certain sum is reached, the financial asset (a security or a commodity contract) must be transferred to the buyer and payment provided to the seller. The agreement between the seller and buyer is a front-end function that is in the nature of a transaction. The transfer of assets in exchange for funds is in the nature of a relationship that involves intermediaries holding accounts for the seller and the buyer. This book examined only the back-end features and components that are embedded in accounts relationships between investors and their intermediaries. Accounts systems for the holding of securities, funds and commodity contracts have many common features but also differ in a number of aspects. While bank accounts holding systems have already been established in all jurisdictions, developing countries only recently began implementing new legal and technological structures for securities accounts systems. However, commodity accounts systems are still absent in many jurisdictions. Successful implementation and functioning of accounts systems requires that local stakeholders understand the differences and various functions performed by each of the three individual accounts systems. This book sought to highlight those functions and features, contrast them in the jurisdictions that have already established such systems and compare the three individual accounts systems with one another. The objective of the author was not to criticize, evaluate or recommend which system to adopt in particular jurisdictions, because there is no uniform one-size model that fits all requirements and local conditions. The objective instead was to analyse the existing systems, explain their individual components and suggest the basis for appropriate legal regulation. Exposure to and understanding of the contemporary accounts holding systems should facilitate modernization and possible harmonization of commercial laws, including those that govern the accounts holding systems. Although securities, bank and commodity accounts systems are regulated in different laws, they all address a set of common features and characteristics. The similarities outnumber differences and in the future could potentially lead to adoption of a law or code of commercial accounts. In the design, development and implementation of a system for the holding of assets in accounts with intermediaries, the features listed below should be adequately reflected. It is expected that in the near future the majority of jurisdictions will have implemented accounts systems for securities, funds and commodity contracts. This area of commercial practice is evolving fast and new products, procedures and mechanisms are constantly introduced. The law governing accounts 224 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts systems should be flexible enough to anticipate future developments and support innovation of both the hardware and software. FEATURE 1: RIGHTS TO SECURITIES, FUNDS AND COMMODITY CONTRACTS ARE INTANGIBLE Each of the three Parts included a section in the Introduction on the evolution of the particular type of asset and the relationships involved. It has been demonstrated that possession and ownership of tangible items, such as security certificates, banknotes and warehouse receipts transformed into intangible rights embedded in accounts. Securities, money and commodities no longer circulate in the marketplace exclusively as tangible objects. They have been supplemented and, to a large extent, already replaced with intangible claims and rights held in accounts maintained by intermediaries. For now the world of tangible securities, money and commodities co-exist with that represented by intangible rights held in accounts. It may be expected that in the future, securities and bank accounts will become the only and exclusive vehicle for the holding of rights to securities and funds. However, this cannot be the case of commodity accounts that may never entirely replace tangible commodities. While securities and bank accounts are the perfect substitute for security certificates and money, commodity accounts and contracts supplement actual commodities. Commodity accounts are the perfect substitute only for the risk management function. FEATURE 2: DIFFERENT LAWS APPLY TO TANGIBLE AND INTANGIBLE ASSETS It has been demonstrated in each Part that tangible objects and intangible rights to securities, money and commodities are covered by different legal rules. Part I distinguished between the direct holding systems, in which the rights to securities may be embedded in a tangible object, such as a bearer or certificated security, and intermediated holding systems, in which the rights are entirely intangible because they are embedded in securities accounts maintained by intermediaries. Part II distinguished between legal money such as coins and banknotes, in which the rights are derived from their possession, and bank money, in which intangible rights are embedded in deposit accounts maintained by banks for their customers. Finally, Part III distinguished between actual commodities, Conclusion 225 such as corn, and intangible rights to delivery of such commodities sometime in the future, which are held in commodity accounts. The law should reflect this distinction between tangible objects and intangible rights. On the one hand, legal rules applicable to directly held securities, legal money and actual commodities are and should remain based on absolute ownership, possession and other proprietary rights. On the other hand, legal rules applicable to indirectly held securities, bank money and commodity contracts held in accounts should be divorced from the traditional property concepts of ownership and possession. In the case of securities accounts, these rules should be based on special proprietary concepts, such as security entitlement and indirect co-ownership. For bank accounts that are contractual creditor-debtor relationships, the law of contract should be sufficient. Finally, property law is implicated in commodity contracts only when commodity accounts holders decide to exercise their rights to make/take delivery, which occurs rather infrequently under transactions executed at organized commodity exchanges. FEATURE 3: ACCOUNTS HOLDING SYSTEMS CONTRIBUTE TO ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT AND INCREASE LIQUIDITY All three accounts holding systems support critical functions of economies without which commercial and financial transactions could not be efficiently completed. Securities markets provide a forum for corporations, banks, governments, utilities and other issuers to raise capital. Without proper and efficient systems for the holding and transferring of securities, access to capital facilitated through securities markets would be significantly hampered.3 Commodity markets provide a forum for merchants, agricultural producers, banks and other investors to effectively manage commercial risks. Without these hedging mechanisms, the risks inherent in commercial activities would have to be borne by the involved parties. Absence of such hedging tools increases operational costs and impedes the ability of businesses and economies to grow. As in securities markets, commodity markets could not function properly without a See AUGUSTO DE LA TORRE & SERGIO L. SCHMUCKLER, EMERGING CAPITAL MARKETS AND GLOBALIZATION, THE LATIN AMERICAN EXPERIENCE 2 (STANFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS, PALO ALTO, CA, 2007). 3 226 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts modern and efficient system for the holding and transferring of commodity contracts through commodity accounts. Finally, the contribution of payment and bank accounts holding systems is the most evident. Practically no commercial transaction, save for barter, could be completed without an efficient payment system. Commercial activity would be considerably impeded if businesses could not satisfy their obligations to pay easily by instructing their banks to transfer funds to sellers and providers of services. Most transactions with securities, funds and commodity contracts involve the element of time that may render them speculative.4 Investors buy bonds maturing in years, enter into commodity contracts that convey the right to delivery of a commodity in months and undertake to pay for financial assets and other products sometime in the future. However, the speculative element of these systems is outweighed by their contribution to economic development. Former US President Theodore Roosevelt highlighted the positive impact of these systems back in 1934 in the aftermath of the Great Depression, when he said: ‘it is my belief that exchanges for dealing in securities and commodities are necessary and of definite value to our commercial and agricultural life’.5 Effective management of risks stimulates economic growth; however, only sufficiently liquid markets may achieve effective risk management. Securities or commodity markets with very few participants and transactions do not allow businesses to raise funds and hedge their risks. Such markets distort market prices because the fewer investors that participate in a market, the more market prices experience severe fluctuations. These markets are unpredictable and unreliable. For those markets to attract more investors, a particular organizational and legal infrastructure, identified in the following features, is needed. FEATURE 4: CLEARINGHOUSES SUPPORT MODERN ACCOUNTS HOLDING SYSTEMS Central entities at the top of accounts holding structures provide a number of critical services that include: the administrative comparison of Abbott Payson Usher, The Technique of Medieval and Modern Produce Markets, 23(4) J. POL. ECON. 365, 367 (1915). 5 President Roosevelt’s Message to Congress, 78 Cong. Rec. 2264 (1934). See also John V. Rainbolt II, Symposium on Commodity Futures Regulation, Regulating the Grain Gambler and his Successors, 6 HOFSTRA L. REV. 1, 9 (1977). 4 Conclusion 227 trade details, the act of becoming the counterparty to every contract, the netting of outstanding obligations and settlement.6 Central entities ensure that systems for the holding and transfers of securities, funds and commodity contracts operate smoothly and that they effectively manage and distribute risks. Bernanke assimilated the clearinghouse to a bank because they both facilitate trading and transfer procedures.7 The functions of central entities differ in the three accounts holding systems. A clearinghouse as such does not exist in RTGS systems for payments. Instead operators of such systems ensure that transfers of funds are completed almost instantaneously by credits and debits to the participants’ bank accounts but they neither compare any trade details nor become counterparties to any funds transfers. Clearing functions are performed only in those payment systems that are based on the net settlement model. In contrast, central entities in securities and commodity accounts holding structures perform additional functions. In securities accounts holding systems, the clearinghouse may calculate/net individual transfers of securities or become the central counterparty to every transfer. As a central counterparty the clearinghouse minimizes the risk of default in delivering securities/commodity contracts against funds. Not all securities markets are supported by a clearinghouse that provides central counterparty services. Particularly in developing countries, the clearinghouse provides only the administrative functions of comparing transfer details, aggregating individual transfer obligations and netting out mutual obligations to deliver. Commodity markets have, for over a century, relied on clearinghouses to provide central counterparty services. 6 Bernanke classified the functions of clearinghouses into two categories: 1) operational that involves trade entry, trade matching and trade clearance and 2) financial that involves the reduction of risk, establishment of capital requirements, collection of margins and provision of guarantees in case of failure of a clearing member. Ben S. Bernanke, Clearing and Settlement during the Crash, National Bureau of Economic Research Conference: Stock Market Volatility and the Crash, Dorado Beach (16–18 March 1989) in 3(1) REV. FIN. STUD., 1990, at 135–6. 7 Bernanke provided an analogy to the function of a bank that in the check collection process must identify the parties to the transaction and then debit/ credit the corresponding accounts. The clearinghouse engages in a similar activity where it identifies the transaction and records debits and credits. Ibid., at 140. 228 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts FEATURE 5: RELATIONSHIPS THAT CONSTITUTE ACCOUNTS SYSTEMS ARE STRUCTURED IN TIERS Accounts holding systems are organized as pyramids with multiple layers of relationships. Participation at a particular level of the pyramid may be restricted only to certain entities. For instance, only authorized intermediaries may access central entities. Restrictions on access are imposed to protect the integrity of the holding and transfer systems.8 Clearinghouses, CSDs and operators of LVFTSs deal only directly with wellcapitalized and regulated entities (intermediaries). Furthermore, arrangements they enter into with participating intermediaries are regularly collateralized and guaranteed. Those intermediaries that do not have direct access to central entities must enter into a clearing agreement with one of the participating intermediaries. Accordingly, three levels of relationships may exist in a holding system: 1) 2) 3) between the central entity and participating intermediaries; between the participating intermediary and non-participating intermediaries and other customers; and between the non-participating intermediary and its customers. FEATURE 6: ACCOUNT RELATIONSHIPS ARE INDEPENDENT Rights of account holders do not relate to any underlying tangible assets. Accordingly, the account holder may not claim a particular security, a banknote or a bag of corn stored in a warehouse as belonging to him. These intangible rights are appropriated to a specific asset only when the securities account holder requests the intermediary to replace a book entry with a security certificate, a bank account holder withdraws cash or the commodity account holder settles his futures contract by acquiring a warehouse receipt. However, none of these account holders may assert claims and enforce their account-based rights against other participants in the holding chain. Rights of individual account holders are enforceable solely against their intermediaries, that is to say, the entities that they have an account relationship with. 8 DERMOT TURING, CLEARING AND SETTLEMENT IN EUROPE 344 (BLOOMSBURY PROFESSIONAL LTD., HAYWARDS HEATH, UK, 2012). Conclusion 229 Securities accounts holders may enforce their rights only against the intermediary that maintains the relevant account and, in the case of transparent systems, also against the CSD which is the top-level intermediary. However, they may not claim that securities held by other intermediaries for their own customers belong to them and sue such intermediaries and their account holders. Similarly, bank account holders may not enforce their rights to funds against banks that do not maintain deposit accounts for them or against the operator of a LVFTS. Likewise, commodity account holders may not enforce their rights against entities other than their own intermediary. Such holders may not sue other commodity account holders or their intermediaries for non-performance. Such isolation of individual account relationships is an effective risk management tool that minimizes the systemic risk. If an intermediary becomes insolvent, its account holders should not be able to assert claims against other participants in the holding chain and potentially cause their failure. The risk should be contained within the relevant account relationship and losses borne equally (pro-rata) among the account holders. FEATURE 7: TRANSFERS REQUIRE EFFECTIVE AND LEGALLY BINDING SETTLEMENT MECHANISMS Settlement follows clearing and involves the actual transfer of assets. As a result of settlement account holders acquire some assets in exchange for funds. Only once the transfer has been completed does the transferee acquire rights to securities, funds or commodity contracts. Settlement of transactions with securities and funds differs from the settlement of transactions with commodity contracts. Unlike the settlement of securities transactions and payment obligations that actually involve transfers of assets, the settlement of commodity contracts does not result in a transfer of the underlying commodity from one party to another.9 Instead it is regularly completed by offset in which one contract position cancels out another. Accounts holding systems should be supported by modern and efficient infrastructure (the ‘hardware’) for the settlement of transactions. Such a settlement system does not rely on manual delivery of tangible assets but instead on electronic entries made by intermediaries to the accounts of their customers. Settlement systems providing support to securities, bank Robert R. Bliss & Robert S. Steigerwald, Derivatives Clearing and Settlement: A Comparison of Central Counterparties and Alternative Structures, 4Q ECON. PERSP. 22, 23 (2006). 9 230 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts and commodity accounts holding systems must be properly aligned to facilitate and allow for seamless transfers of securities against cash as well as offsets of commodity contracts against funds. Legal rules (the ‘software’) must ensure that settlement mechanisms effectively and irrevocably transfer rights to securities, funds and commodity contracts. FEATURE 8: BOOK ENTRIES TO ACCOUNTS EFFECTUATE TRANSFERS OF RIGHTS BY NOVATION Transfers of account-based rights are completed by credits and debits made by intermediaries to the accounts of their customers. Electronic entries have effectively replaced other traditional forms of transfer, such as the physical delivery of an object. Transferors and transferees no longer complete transfers directly between themselves but they instruct their intermediaries to deliver and receive rights on their behalf. This operational transformation of the form of transfer from manual to electronic also changed the legal nature of such transfers. The reduction (debit) and the resulting increase (credit) in two different account balances are characterized in law as novation.10 Rights do not get transferred between accounts by assignment or negotiation. For any rights to be assigned, a claim of the transferor must pass to the transferee. This is not the case of transfers between accounts. A transferee of securities or funds acquires rights that are different from the rights of the transferor because the transferor’s rights are enforceable only against his intermediary. For any rights to be negotiated, a writing that reifies the underlying rights must be passed from hand to hand. In this respect, Sommer observed: Negotiable instruments are similar to accounts, except that rights exist by virtue of possession of an authentic physical instrument, rather than being an account holder. The necessary communication is embedded in a unique piece of paper. But thanks to computers, we are generally shifting from negotiable instruments and other physical tokens to account-based systems of holding and transferring rights … These account-based systems all rely on authenticated messages to establish rights, and authenticated records to evidence the rights established by the messages.11 10 PHILIP R. WOOD, SET-OFF AND NETTING, DERIVATIVES, CLEARING SYSTEMS 270 (2nd edn., SWEET & MAXWELL LTD., LONDON, UK, 2007). 11 Joseph H. Sommer, International Securities Holding and Transfer Law, 18 ARIZ. J. INT’L & COMP. L. 685, 697 (2001). Conclusion 231 What negotiation achieves for transfers of abstract rights, demolishing the history of the rights, novation achieves for the transfer of accountbased rights. Both protect the transferee from the defenses and claims assertable against the transferor. FEATURE 9: BOOK ENTRIES ESTABLISH THE FINALITY OF TRANSFER One of the most critical aspects of account-based transfers is the finality of transfer. Transferees must be assured that the rights they acquire are irrevocable and that transferors may not later unwind the entire chain of transfers. However, finality is not as important a feature in commodity accounts holding systems as it is in the systems for the holding and transfer of securities and funds. Transfers of commodity contracts are typically accomplished by offsets that cause the commodity contract to be extinguished rather than passed from the transferor to the transferee. In other words, a commodity contract initially acquired and credited to a commodity account of a customer may not be later transferred by debit and credit to an account of another customer. This sequence of transfers is typical for securities and bank accounts systems. In a funds or securities transfer, balances of accounts holders are adjusted respectively by their intermediaries. Crediting the transferee’s account typically establishes the finality of transfer. Unlike provisional entries in the check collection system, credits transferring securities, funds and commodity contracts should be final. This finality system should be supplemented by effective remedies for erroneous and fraudulent transfers. However, such remedies should be enforced only outside the accounts holding system and not reverse any already executed entries. FEATURE 10: SECURITY INTERESTS IN COMMERCIAL ACCOUNTS AND THE RIGHTS HELD IN SUCH ACCOUNTS Account-based rights are highly liquid and their value may be easily established. These characteristics make them attractive collateral for lenders who may easily dispose of them in the case of a borrower’s default. Yet many secured transactions laws provide inadequate mechanisms for the taking and perfecting of security interests in account-based rights and accounts held by intermediaries. Some countries have already 232 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts enacted legal rules to facilitate collateralization of loans with accountbased securities. However, only very few provide similar rules for funds held in bank accounts and only a handful extend their scope to commodity contracts and commodity accounts. As a result of the inadequate regulation, or complete absence thereof, lenders must be creative in properly structuring loans secured with the account-type of collateral. Secured transactions laws should embrace the notion of control for the perfection of security interests in rights held in securities, bank and commodity accounts. Control must be flexible and in effect convey to the creditor ‘management rights’ that may be exercised either pre- or post-default. Control should not transfer securities, funds or commodity contracts absolutely to the creditor, as is characteristic for the possessory pledge. As with most other types of collateral, such as inventory and receivables, the borrower should be able to deal with it and re-use it in his business. While registration enables perfection of non-possessory security interests in inventory, receivables, equipment and other types of collateral, control achieves perfection for ‘non-possessory’ security interests in account-based rights. Publicity of security interests perfected by control is, at times, questioned on the basis of insufficient public notice. This concern may be ameliorated by the duty of intermediaries to provide information to third parties through the debtor about the nature of the arrangement. Creditors and bailees in possession of the collateral are subject to a similar duty to disclose relevant information. Index account omnibus 64–65, 189 operators 42, 66, 70–71 pledge 79, 144, 190 agricultural commodities 164–165, 170, 173–178, 203, 206, 219–20 bank account holder 7, 13, 40, 102, 124, 143, 154, 198–99, 203, 220, 228–9 and relationships 11, 92, 94, 101, 111, 113–32, 153–4, 156 bank money 88, 97, 99–102, 111–12, 124, 131, 153, 224–5 Bernanke, Ben 9, 17–18, 88, 227 Bolsa Mexicana de Valores (BMV) 28 Brazilian Clearing and Depository Corporation (CBLC) 28, 37, 53 Brazilian Mercantile and Futures Exchange (BM&F) 28 central counterparty (CCP) 10, 49–54, 103, 191–3, 219, 227 see also clearing and central counterparty Central de Depósito de Valores (CEDEVAL) 29, 47–9, 53, 66, 80 Central de Valores (CEVAL) 29, 37, 39 central payment system 90, 114–17, 133, 141–2, 154, 194 central securities depository (CSD) 6, 26–9, 36–42, 46–9, 53–6, 59–71, 75, 80–81, 115, 165, 172, 194, 228–9 Chicago Board Options Exchange (CBOE) 181 Chicago Board of Trade (CBOT) 162–4, 169–70, 192 Chicago Mercantile Exchange (CME) 2–3, 159, 164, 177–179, 190, 192, 199, 201, 207 and Rulebook 177, 187, 190, 193, 207 clearing and central counterparty clearing 50–54, 103, 191–2 and clearinghouse clearing 49–50 and settlement systems 9, 82, 187, 219, 229 clearinghouse 6–9, 50, 66, 154, 165, 170, 181–2, 185–96, 198, 202, 204–208, 219, 226–8 Clearing House Inter-Bank Payments System (CHIPS) 102, 107–8, 113–15, 138, 143 Clearstream 27, 38, 40, 54–5, 61–2 commodity accounts 3–8, 13, 15–17, 89, 159– 163, 165, 169, 171–3, 176, 180, 182–3, 186–203, 205, 209–16, 218–232 clearinghouse 7, 187–8, 191–194, 219 contracts 1–16, 87, 153, 159–66, 169–85, 188–91, 193–9, 202–3, 205–32 exchanges 1, 6, 159, 162–5, 168, 170–73, 177–9, 185–6, 190, 192, 196, 199, 202, 204, 206–8, 213, 215, 218–21, 225 intermediary 13, 194–5, 200, 209, 214–6 intermediary and insurance fund 198–9 laws 173, 181, 183–4, 219 233 234 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts market 159–65, 168–80, 191, 194–96, 203–204, 206, 215, 218–21, 225–7 trading 196, 219 Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC) 194, 198 control 73–9, 83, 115, 147–52, 156, 160, 175, 179, 212–17, 220, 232 and agreement 74, 76–9, 148–50, 152, 215–16 see also perfection co-ownership 12, 32, 57, 61–5, 82, 154, 225 delivery versus payment (DVP) 24, 55, 82 dematerialization and commodities 171–2, 221 and money 99–100 and securities 24, 33–5, 73 deposit and irregular 11, 32, 93–5, 97, 112, 119–120, 122–3, 145, 155 and regular 11, 93, 112, 119–23, 155 Depository Trust Company (DTC) 2, 27, 37–8, 48, 52–5, 60 Depository Trust & Clearing Corporation (DTCC) 38, 53 document of title 167 see also warehouse receipt EU Financial Collateral Directive 44, 77, 80, 145–6, 148, 152, 212 EU Regulation 648/2012 50, 186, 188 EU Settlement Finality Directive 114, 138, 141 Eurex 164, 192 and Clearing AG 187–9, 192–3 European Central Bank (ECB) 8, 52, 108, 110, 114, 171 European Central Counterparty Limited (EuroCCP) 53 Rules (EuroCCP Rules) 14, 66 fairs of Champagne 97, 166 Fedwire 10, 90, 104, 107, 113, 116, 133, 143 financial assets 2, 43–5, 57, 60–1, 64–5, 82, 100, 137, 153, 164–5, 172–4, 179, 203, 211, 219, 226 financial instruments 45, 100, 170, 179, 206, 212, 219 financing statement 80, 148 finality 70–72, 83, 104, 106–7, 131, 136–43, 155, 209, 231 of order 89, 114, 126, 129, 131, 137–43, 155, 208 rules 15, 83, 125, 138–9, 141–2, 155, 208 of transfer 15, 71–2, 83, 107, 137–9, 142–3, 155–6, 208–9, 231 forward contract 162–3, 183–5, 196, 212 futures commission merchant 1, 199 see also commodity intermediary contract 159–60, 162–3, 165, 169–70, 173, 175–6, 179–86, 189–92, 194, 196–9, 202–11, 214, 219–220, 228 exchange 6, 8, 159, 164, 171, 175, 177, 180–2, 185, 214 Geneva Securities Convention 23, 40, 42, 75, 77, 79, 84 German Banking Act 123 goldsmiths 5–6, 97–8, 109, 165 grading system 166, 168, 170–71, 176, 179 Hague Securities Convention 23 hedge-to-arrive (HTA) agreements 185 holding system indirect 42–4, 46, 58, 64, 82, 102, transparent 42, 65 immobilization 24, 33, 36, 39, 46, 100, 171 INDEVAL 28, 38, 45, 53, 64, 165 insurance 4, 13, 66–7, 174–5, 198–9, 220 Inter-American Development Bank (IADB) 24 Index International Monetary Fund (IMF) 28–9, 53, 102 International Organization of Securities Commissions (IOSCO) 206 investment property 211–12, 217 large-value funds transfer systems (LVFTS) 2, 7, 90, 101–105, 115, 117, 124–5, 153–4, 187, 191, 228–9 law of commercial accounts ix, 4, 17 lien 79 management rights 148, 156, 216, 232 margin 78, 163, 182, 184–5, 190, 199, 214–15 Mercado Mexicano de Derivados, S.A. de C.V (MexDer) 165, 175, 182, 192 Mexican Securities Market Law 37, 45, 64 MiFID 44, 212 National Securities Clearing Corporation (NSCC) 38, 52 negotiable instruments 87, 92, 97, 120, 122, 124–5, 134, 222, 230, net settlement (NS) 90–91, 102, 106, 115, 227 netting 49–51, 53, 82, 103, 106, 154, 227 non-clearing members 188 novation 9, 14–5, 50–1, 69–70, 82–3, 134–5, 155–6, 193–4, 230–31 NewYork Stock Exchange (NYSE) 2–3, 21, 26–7, 38, 78 offset 87, 106, 120, 160, 171, 179, 184–5, 196–7, 202–9, 220, 229–31 see also set-off options 182–3 Organization of American States (OAS) 147 Model Law 147, 151–2, 212 over-the-counter (OTC) 38, 161, 180–81, 183, 186, 204, 210, 212–3, 219 235 payment order 54, 68, 87, 89, 90, 95, 97, 99, 103–107, 115, 126–45, 154–6 Payment Services Directive (PSD) 114, 126 perfection by control 73–9, 147–51, 212, 214–16 see also control by filing and registration 79–80, 150–52, 216–17 of security interest 73, 83, 150–51, 216 pledge possessory 74, 149, 232 account 79, 144, 190 privity 39, 46, 59–60, 131 pro-rata claims 13, 57, 61, 63–5, 123, 108, 229 real-time gross settlement (RTGS) 90–91, 102, 104–7, 115, 118–19, 143, 153–4, 156, 187, 227 repo 72–3 Rosario Futures Exchange (ROFEX) 164–5 Salvadoran Law on Electronic Entries 34–5, 37, 40, 63 secured transactions law 77, 144, 146–8, 150, 152, 156, 210, 212–13, 216–17, 222, 231–2 securities directly-held 43 entitlement 79, 80, 84 holding system 9, 22, 25, 27–8, 31–2, 56, 81–2, 101, 154, 163, 165, 191, 200 intermediary 3, 44, 65, 141, 198 uncertificated 34–5, 43, 81 Securities Investor Protection Corporation (SIPC) 67 segregation 4, 13, 65–6, 78, 200–201, 220 set-off 120, 144–6, 148, 150, 196, 203, 214 settlement account 54, 115–17, 142, 229 236 The law of securities, commodities and bank accounts Sistema de Transferência de Fundos (SITRAF) 91, 102–3 Sistema de Transferência de Reservas (STR) 91 Sistema Especial de Liquidação e de Custódia (SELIC) 37 Sistema Nacional de Pagos Electrónicos (SINPE) 91, 117 Sistema de Pagos Electrónicos Interbancarios (SPEI) 91 speculators 160–61, 169, 176, 179 spot contract 159, 162 swap 4, 180, 186, 213 SWIFT 103, 115 systemic risk 8, 25, 88, 229 Trans-European Automated Real-time Gross Settlement Express Transfer (Target2) 90, 104, 114, 118–19, 139 transfer of funds 54, 90, 130, 132, 136 tulipomania 168 UN Convention on the Assignment of Receivables in International Trade 213 UNCITRAL Legislative Guide on Secured Transactions 148–52, 213, 217 UNCITRAL Model Law on International Credit Transfers 88, 128–9, 141 Uniform Commercial Code (UCC) Article 4A (UCC 4A) 113–14, 119, 124–31, 135–8, 140–41 Article 7 (UCC 7) 65 Article 8 (UCC 8) 15, 22, 25, 35–6, 41, 43–4, 47, 58–9, 141 Article 9 (UCC 9) 78, 80, 146, 148–50, 152, 211–17 warehouse receipt 75, 160, 162–3, 167, 171, 177, 197, 198, 203, 207–8, 210, 214, 228 electronic 160