Should the government tax goods that are unhealthy In recent decades the rate of obesity across the world has risen. As of 2014, 13% of the world’s population is obese caused by the overconsumption of unhealthy goods. Obesity is estimated to cost the UK over £6 billion/year in direct healthcare costs (1). Furthermore smoking costs the United States $600 billion each year(2). Unhealthy goods not only burden health services unnecessarily but also decrease productivity and quality of life. Goods found to be detrimental to health are demerit goods and have negative consumption externalities. They are demerit goods as consumers in the market for unhealthy goods do not have complete or accurate information to the negative consequences associated with the good. Unhealthy goods have negative consumption externalities as when they are consumed third parties like the NHS have costs imposed on them due to the resulting increased disease/obesity. One way to correct this is with a per unit tax on the market for goods deemed to be unhealthy. The demand and supply graph shows the market for goods that the government deems unhealthy. The curve D optimal shows the demand if all consumers had perfect information about the consequences of unhealthy food. The curve D real shows the demand curve currently present. This highlights the root cause of this market failure as unhealthy foods are demerit goods. The supply curve S1 shifts to S2 after the per unit tax. This causes a shift in the equilibrium point from Q1,P1 to Q2,P2. This equilibrium point is at a higher price point but its quantity is closer to the optimal social consumption. This reduces the market failure and increases quality of life for the consumers in the market. However, the success of this intervention is dependant on many factors, one factor being that if the price elasticity of demand is inelastic the per unit tax will have to be larger to produce a similar effect. The graph also shows the tax incidence of the per unit tax with the pink area being equal to revenue paid by consumer possibly and the yellow area being equal to revenue paid by the producer. The proportion of these depend on the price elasticity of the demand curve with more being paid by the consumer if the demand is inelastic. For some goods in the market that are addictive or are consumed habitually like cigarettes there is always a chance that consumers keep consuming at high levels and pay the per unit tax leading to a significantly higher price level and increase in inflation. For example, in Denmark a tax was levied on foods containing more than 2.3% saturated fat in 2011. This tax was however heavily criticised and was abolished after a year as it led to inflated food prices. Per unit taxes are also always regressive meaning that consumers with lower income pay a larger proportion of their income towards the tax which is inequitable and contributes to the inequitable distribution of income. This tax has also led to some unintended consequences like the reformulation of drinks to contain substances which are not as well studied to be substituted in the place of the substance deemed unhealthy. This has occurred in the UK soft drinks market as a result of the sugar tax with glycerol being the substitute. This unintended consequence is an example of government failure due to the law of unintended consequences. Governments are also prone to information failure and goods may be deemed unhealthy incorrectly. Any policy would have to be well studied as consequences related to substitutes and complements would likely be unforeseen and could negate any health improvements References: (1) McKinsey Global Institute (2014) Overcoming Obesity: An Initial Economic Analysis. (2) Costs and Expenditures (cdc.gov)