Uploaded by Mcglynn Rolland

10.1177 04866134231175177

advertisement
1175177
research-article2023
RRPXXX10.1177/04866134231175177Review of Radical Political EconomicsOssa
Article
Gender Wage Gap,
Wage-Productivity Decoupling,
and the Rate of Profit
Review of Radical Political Economics
2024, Vol. 56(1) 51­–69
© 2023 Union for Radical
Political Economics
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
https://doi.org/10.1177/04866134231175177
DOI: 10.1177/04866134231175177
rrpe.sagepub.com
Daniel Ossa1
Abstract
The declining gender wage gap (GWG) and the wage-productivity decoupling (WPD) are two
emerging phenomena for the United States since the 1980s. This article proposes an extension
to the usual decomposition method of the profit rate to account for both the GWG and
the WPD on aggregate income distribution. It then uses this framework to study the US
manufacturing sector from 1960 to 2017. It suggests that gender wage inequality was a source
of profitability, especially before 1986, but which was slowly petered out. Since 2001, increases
in the profit share have mostly been due to the WPD. These results highlight the relevance of
gender-based inequality in the more traditional analysis of the profit rate dynamics.
JEL Classification: B51, E11, E25, J16
Keywords
rate of profit, gender wage gap, wage-productivity decoupling, income distribution
1. Introduction
Two crucial phenomena related to wage growth have been observed in the United States persistently since the 1980s, both of them having impacts on income distribution between capital and
labor, and the rate of profit. On the one hand, the gender wage gap (GWG) has been declining,
possibly negatively affecting capital profitability. Elveren, Marr, and Renard (2017) find evidence that higher women’s labor force participation rates, in the presence of a GWG, leads to
higher profit rates. Since women get paid less than men, capital could benefit by hiring women
and reducing unit labor costs. On the other hand, wages stopped increasing at the growth rate of
labor productivity since the 1970s but consistently since the 1980s, reducing output’s wage share.
This wage-productivity decoupling (WPD) has been a topic of discussion since the 1990s when
it was first observed that real wages stopped growing at the same pace as labor productivity
during the two previous decades (Ferguson 1996; Zavodny 1999). Taken together, these two
1
Department of Economics, University of Denver, Denver, CO, USA
Date received: October 18, 2021
Date accepted: April 25, 2023
Corresponding Author:
Daniel Ossa, Department of Economics, University of Denver, 2000 E. Asbury Ave., Denver, CO 80208, USA.
Email: daniel.ossa@du.edu
52
Review of Radical Political Economics 56(1)
phenomena are associated with contradictory impacts on income distribution: the declining of the
GWG has been associated with a burden of capital profitability, whereas the WPD has been associated with a boost of profits. Given the worthwhileness of asking about the contradictory impacts
of these two wage phenomena, what has been their overall effect on profits during the neoliberal
era in the United States?
This article proposes an extension to the usual decomposition method of the profit rate by
including the GWG into the analysis. With it, I attempt to shed some light on how the combination of changes in both the GWG and the WPD has shaped the two aggregate outcomes relevant
for the proposed discussion: the wage share and the rate of profit.
This analysis focuses on the US manufacturing business sector for the period 1960–2017
because of data availability. It applies this extended decomposition method to the rate of profit
and income shares by gender and between capital and labor. Using this perspective, this article
approaches the impact of the narrowing of the GWG and the WPD on both the rate of profit and
the distribution of income in this sector. A plausible hypothesis is that the increase of the WPD
has been a counterweight to the decline in the GWG. In other words, as the catch-up of female
workers to their male counterparts is harmful to capital in terms of its profitability, the WPD
could be understood as a response to maintaining a profitability level.
One of the main objectives of this analysis is to emphasize the relevance of gender inequalities
when studying the rate of profit. The more traditional decomposition method considers the
dynamics of labor productivity, average wage, and capital/labor ratio (Basu 2017: 1375).
However, wage differences among workers also play an essential role in the tendencies of the
profit rate, as in the case of gender inequalities. As Seguino (2019) points out, incorporating different gender variables into macroeconomic models improves the relevance of the theory and the
policy results.
The rest of the article is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews the discussions around the
factors behind the GWG and its implications on profitability and income distribution. Section 3
presents a review of the debates on WPD and the different approaches to measuring it. Section 4
exposes the extension to the traditional decomposition method that includes the GWG. Section 5
presents the data sources. Section 6 applies the decomposition method to analyze the impacts of
the GWG and WPD in the rate of profit and the functional income distribution within the US
manufacturing sector. Finally, section 7 concludes that there are three main periods identified in
which the GWG and the WPD influenced the rate of profit of the manufacturing sector: 1960–
1986, where the increasing female share of employment and a relatively stagnant GWG might
have contributed to the rate of profit, 1986–2001, where this source of extra profitability was
depleted by a closing of the GWG and lower participation of female workers in the sector, and
from 2001–2017 where the WPD in the average workers’ total compensation helped to sustain
the rate of profit.
2. The Gender Wage Gap
The GWG is the measure of the average differences in income between female and male workers.
It has been associated with labor market discrimination, which “exists when two equally qualified individuals are treated differently in the labor market solely on the basis of their gender
(race, ethnicity, age, disability, sexual orientation, etc.)” (Blau and Winkler 2018: 264). However,
the reasons behind the GWG are complex.
Some economists argue that the GWG reflects differences in productivity and not labor market discrimination. Several empirical studies have controlled for different variables as the level
of education, experience, and other differences in qualifications that could explain the disparities
in wages by gender but that are not necessarily related to discrimination in the labor market.
However, even when controlling for these factors seems to account for a portion of the wage differential, a significant share of the gap appears to respond to nonqualification variables such as
Ossa
53
unionization, race, and industry, while most of the gap remains unexplained. Different authors
associate this unexplained portion with labor market discrimination (Blau and Kahn 2017: 831).
In other words, some of the nonqualification variables plus the unexplained part of the gap suggest that females and their male counterparts are developing a similar job but having the former
earning less than the latter. The following paragraphs take a closer look at each of these factors.
Differences in the unionization rates across genders used to have some explanatory power in
the GWG. Blau and Kahn (2017) find that unionization explained around 6.2 percent of the GWG
in 1980, but this factor has lost importance through time. By 2010 it completely lost its explanatory power. This finding makes sense considering the continuous decline in unionization rates in
the United States, at least since the 1960s (Zavodny 1999), and the decrease in collective-bargaining coverage. As it was more common for men to be in a union (Schur and Kruse 1992), they
had a higher bargaining power than women. However, these differences in unionization rates
have declined to the point that by 2015 the union membership rate in the United States was higher
for women than men (Card, Lemieux, and Riddell 2020), and therefore losing its explanatory
power over the gap. In sum, this dynamic of unionization rates across gender is one of the reasons
to explain the closing of the GWG.
Blau and Kahn (2017) also present some other nonqualification factors that help to explain the
GWG and that are relevant for the analysis in the following sections. First, race increased its
explanatory power in the gap, from 1.6 to 6.6 percent when comparing 1980 to 2010. Second, the
wage gap also varies across industries (Fields and Wolf 1995; Horrace and Oaxaca 2001). Given
these differences, industry explains around 17.6 percent of the aggregate GWG by 2010. Third, it
is also crucial to notice which groups of workers have led the GWG to close. For the period
1980–2010, the GWG has closed mainly among the low- and middle-income workers.
Considering the factors associated with the GWG, the question is, What are its effects on the
income distribution between capital and labor, and also on the rate of profit? Different studies
have associated the presence of gender income inequality with a source of either extra benefits
for capital or as a means to cut unit labor costs and be more competitive in the market.1 For
example, Seguino (2000) finds evidence that women’s lower relative wages were a stimulus to
investment, exports, and rapid economic growth experienced by several Asian economies during
the period from 1975 to 1990. One of the key ideas is that investment is positively linked to gender wage inequality due to higher capital return rates.
There are contradictory approaches to analyze the effect of the GWG on the profitability of
capital theoretically. Seguino (2019) points out that investment is positively related to both profits and demand. This is similar to the post-Keynesian approach dealing with two different accumulation regimes: profit-led or wage-led regimes (Lavoie and Stockhammer 2013). In the first
regime, a wider GWG would boost profits because of the lower unit labor costs. In the second
kind of regime, a wider gender wage inequality could imply lower profits because of the shortage
of aggregate demand. Therefore, the net effect is theoretically ambiguous. Nevertheless, Seguino
(2019) notes that there is little evidence in the literature that the demand effect dominates the
profitability effect.
Theoretical developments have also provided insights into these questions. For example, Hein
(2020) proposes a neo-Kalekian distribution and growth model for advanced capitalist economies where a GWG is introduced. The model suggests that for a closed economy, narrowing the
GWG will not affect income distribution between profits and wages but only improve the female
wage share at the expense of the male wage share, in the case when factors that determine the
firms’ mark-ups remain constant. In an open economy, the model shows that narrowing the GWG
1
See, e.g., Ertürk and Çağatay (1995: 1971) referring to the substitution hypothesis. They mention that this
hypothesis “is based on the observation that women become substituted for men workers during downswings as a cost-saving measure because of a gender gap in wages and the low level of union activism and
organization among women.”
54
Review of Radical Political Economics 56(1)
reduces the profit share. The reason is the higher costs and loss in competitiveness associated
with higher female wages.
Several empirical studies have also shed light on the relationship between gender wage
inequality and the aggregate income distribution between capital and labor. Finnoff and Jayadev
(2006) find a negative correlation between the increase in the females’ share of employment and
the wage share of national income in the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development (OECD) countries for 1975–2000. In contrast, Zacharias and Mahoney (2009) find
that women’s participation rates contributed to offset the wage share loss in the US case during
the period 1982–1997. The idea is that the decline in the GWG during this period prevented the
decline in the aggregate wage share. They use a decomposition methodology to separate the
effects of the trends in women’s employment and wages on the labor share and the rate of profit.
Tescari and Vaona (2014) perform a similar decomposition analysis to Zacharias and Mahoney
(2009) of the wage share and rate of profit for the Italian economy for 1994–2005 and find similar patterns. Finally, Elveren, Marr, and Renard (2017), using panel data for twenty-one OECD
countries from 1970–2008, find evidence supporting the idea that higher women’s labor force
participation rates and GWG lead to higher profit rates. Their intuition is that lower unit labor
costs, given the unequal pays by gender, helps to boost profits.
However, these empirical studies mentioned in the previous paragraph have a limitation,
given the aggregate nature of the data: they do not control for the qualification variables as level
of education or experience that affect the GWG. These studies, therefore, implicitly assume that
the GWG comes mainly from discrimination in the labor market, and thus capital could save unit
labor costs by hiring female workers.2 However, as covered above, nonqualification factors such
as race, unionization, the level of income, plus the unexplained portion of the gap represent most
of the GWG, supporting the idea that companies could replace males with female workers and
saving in unit labor costs as a result. Thus, these empirical studies should be understood as an
approximation to the problem but not as precise measures, as in the case of this study.
3. The Wage-Productivity Decoupling
Since the early 1970s, wages stopped growing at the same rate as labor productivity in some
industries in the United States. The WPD is a tendency that can also be seen in some of the major
economies worldwide (ILO 2018; OECD 2018).
For the mainstream theory, this is a result of technical factors since it expects that each factor
of production gets paid according to their contribution to the output. Cobb and Douglas (1928)
tested the neoclassical theory of income distribution for the first time, and reported evidence in
favor of the idea that wages are paid according to labor’s marginal productivity. However, following works have shown that neoclassical theory of income distribution has no strong empirical
support since the neoclassical production functions are a transformation of an accounting identity, which make their good apparent empirical results to be due a tautology (Phelps Brown 1957;
Shaikh 1974; Felipe and McCombie 2014). Other schools of thought (including the Classical,
Marxist, and post-Keynesian) understand income distribution as a result of a class dispute and
power relations, and not as technical market result (Cakmakli, Cantillon, and Ucal 2020). For
2
E.g., the most recent one, Elveren, Marr, and Renard (2017), runs a panel regression of the rate of profit
of OECD countries against their respective GWG, under the idea of testing the hypothesis that capital
saves in unit labor costs by hiring women. In their empirical exercise, they do not consider the different
reasons behind the GWG. Implicitly they assume that with the existence of the GWG, capital can save in
unit labor costs, the case when there is labor market discrimination (same productivity, different wages).
Also, Zacharias and Mahoney (2009) perform a counterfactual analysis, which inspired the present study,
and analyses the wage share assuming constant GWG. This means, implicitly they assume the decline in the
GWG responds to changes in discrimination, as this study does because of data limitations.
Ossa
55
these schools of thought, the WPD has to do with the weakening of trade unions, loss of collective bargaining power, and poor labor conditions that came along with neoliberalism (Arestis
2020; Cauvel and Pacitti 2022).
This section presents a literature review about the WPD in the US economy and the discussions about its measurement. Works, such as Cantillon and Ucal (2019), have shown that its size
depends heavily on the variables used to measure it, as the use of average or medium compensation, as well as the deflator used for wages. The idea is to go in this direction and cover all the
possible variables that affects its size and their implications. With the literature review, it is clear
why there are misconceptions about the WPD and why some authors, such as Škare and Škare
(2017) and Pessoa and Reenen (2013), find no decoupling between wages and productivity in
most of the major economies in the world, and why they underestimate it for the US economy.
The aim is to set the ground for the analysis in the following sections.
Ferguson (1996) presents one of the first papers that point out the increasing gap between
wages and labor productivity in the United States. Considering wages for production and nonsupervisory workers for 320 nonagricultural and nongovernment industries, he finds that the
wage-productivity gap between 1981 and 1988 increased by 8.24 percent. The author associates
this gap with the fall in the bargaining power of workers. He uses linear regression to test this
idea using variables such as unionization, unemployment, and import penetration.
Later, Zavodny (1999) found that the gap between real hourly earnings and productivity in the
nonfarm business sector has widened since the early 1970s. However, “increases in real compensation per hour have more closely matched productivity gains than have wages and salaries
alone, but compensation increases have lagged behind productivity gains since the mid-1980s”
(Zavodny 1999: 46). Zavodny also takes a look at this gap across industries. The author finds that
the cumulative difference between productivity and compensation growth between 1977–1996
differs across sectors. While the gap increases in mining, manufacturing, transportation, communication and public utilities, and wholesale and retail trade, she does not find the same tendency for finance and services industries. Her findings suggest that the WPD is smaller in
industries with higher initial unionization rates, an idea aligned with Ferguson (1996).
In this same vein, Levy and Temin (2007) construct a bargaining power index using the wageproductivity gap. As in Ferguson (1996) and Zavodny (1999), the idea is that wages not growing
at the rate of labor productivity reflects workers’ bargaining conditions. According to the estimations of this gap for 1945–2005, the decoupling began in the 1970s and accelerated in the 1980s.
They use median annual earnings of full-time workers and the value of estimated fringe benefits,
and the labor productivity in hours for nonfarm businesses.
Other works have also presented estimations of the WPD for the aggregate economy or specific sectors. Here are some relevant examples. From the Economic Policy Institute, Bivens et al.
(2014) use productivity in terms of output per hour and the real hourly compensation for production and nonsupervisory workers. Using data for the period 1948–2013, they show that the gap
began to increase since the mid-1970s and increased consistently since 1979. Another report by
the Economic Policy Institute, Gould (2019), finds that while productivity has increased 69.6 percent for 1979–2018, the hourly pay has risen just 11.6 percent during the same period. Finally,
Shaikh (2016: 60) presents that the gap between labor productivity and real compensation per
production worker has increased since 1979 in the manufacturing sector for the US economy.
The most intriguing fact of his work is that he presents data for this sector from 1889–2010,
showing that workers’ compensation and productivity increased closely during 1889–1979 and
began to diverge only since then.
Nevertheless, some authors sub-estimate the size of this gap pointing out to discussions around
its measurement. There are two main critics in the literature about the measurement. The first one
is about taking wages instead of total compensation of workers. As already pointed out by
Zavodny (1999), the gap is much higher when it is measured using wages instead of total compensation. This difference in the patterns between wages and total labor compensation is at the
center of the discussions about the WPD, as presented by the Global Wage Report 2014/15 (ILO
56
Review of Radical Political Economics 56(1)
2015). This is a point that some authors, for example, Feldstein (2008), use to disesteem the
WPD. The second one, argued in Pessoa and Reenen (2013), posits how different the decoupling
conclusions are if the worker’s compensation is not deflated by using the Consumer Price Index
(CPI) but the GDP deflator. In the case of the United States, they show how using the CPI as a
deflator for wages, the gap for the period 1972–2010 is around 80 percent, but when using the
GDP deflator, the gap is only about 13 percent. They call the former “gross decoupling” and the
latter “net decoupling.” The authors argue that the latter is the relevant measure since this is the
one that accounts for changes in the wage share of output. The Global Wage Report 2014/15 follows this idea but finds that the differences are less dramatic. The wage-productivity gap for
1999–2013 is almost half when the GDP deflator is used instead of the CPI (ILO 2015).
Additionally, the Economic Policy Institute (2021) measures the gap for the US economy using
GDP deflator and still finds it has been persistent when other variables in the measurement, different from the ones used by Škare and Škare (2017) and Pessoa and Reenen (2013), are used.
The magnitude of the gap is affected by the group of workers included into the measurement
of the gap, a difference not considered by the mainstream literature. The wages and compensations of workers with managerial positions tend to be higher and evolve differently compared to
nonsupervisory workers (Duménil and Lévy 2011; Elsby, Hobijn, and Sahin 2013; Giovannoni
2014). This point could be addressed using two different approaches. The first one is by directly
including into the data only nonsupervisory workers. The Economic Policy Institute (2021)
shows that the wage-productivity gap is dramatically higher when accounting only for nonsupervisory workers. This group of workers is the one that has suffered more from losing the fruits of
economic growth. By taking into account the evolution of the compensation of workers as a
whole, you miss the increasing inequality within companies in the United States. A second
approach is to use median labor compensations, instead of the average. These two measurements
depend on the concentrations of income among workers. The use of average compensation
underestimates the gap with productivity compared to the median compensation. With this distinction, the Schwellnus, Kappeler, and Pionnier (2017) find that for the period 1995–2013, for
24 OECD countries, the gap of real median compensation is significatively broader than when
using the average.
Finally, Baker (2019) points out the relevance of the measurement of output considered for
productivity changes. Because GDP does not account for capital depreciation, it is more precise
to measure productivity using NDP. Also, he discusses the point made by Pessoa and Reenen
(2013) about the different deflators for wages. He recognizes that the CPI generally shows a
higher inflation rate than the output deflator (GDP or NDP). However, he points out that part of
the reason is how the deflators are constructed. While the CPI is a fixed-weight index, the NDP
deflator is a chained index. This difference tends to make the former larger than the latter, even
if they are including the same basket of goods and services. A second factor that accounts for that
difference is they include a different mix of goods and services. The NDP deflator includes
investment goods, which price has grown less rapidly compared to consumer goods.
Table 1 summarizes the different measurements that could be used for each variable to estimate the WPD. As revealed by the literature review, the conclusions about the magnitude of the
decoupling change according to the chosen measurements for the variables. First of all, considering all workers, instead of only nonsupervisory workers, underestimated the gap
(Economic Policy Institute 2021). In the case of workers’ income, the productivity gap is usually higher when using wages instead of total compensation (Zavodny 1999; Feldstein 2008;
ILO 2015). Taking the average income instead of the median underestimates the gap
(Schwellnus, Kappeler, and Pionnier 2017). For the deflator for workers’ income, the use of
CPI shows a much wider gap than using one of the output deflators (Pessoa and Reenen 2013;
ILO 2015; Baker 2019; Economic Policy Institute 2021). Finally, no relevant differences in the
gap seem to be reported when measuring productivity per hour or per worker.
Ossa
57
Table 1. Different Measurements to Estimate the Wage-Productivity Gap.
Variables
Measurements
Group of workers
Workers' income
All workers
Wages
Deflator for workers' income
Output
Productivity
CPI
Gross domestic product
Per hour worked
Average
Median
Nonsupervisory workers
Total compensation
Average
Median
GDP or NDP deflator
Net domestic product
Per worker
4. Decomposition Method
Basu (2017: 1375) presents a literature review about the quantitative empirical research in
Marxist political economy. In the section dedicated to decomposition analysis, there is a subsection dedicated to medium-run decomposition analysis. He mentions that to study the drivers of
profitability over a medium-run time scale, the usual analysis is done using a decomposition of
the profit rate into the share of profit and the output/capital ratio (see, e.g., Shaikh 1992; Duménil
and Lévy 2002; Bakir and Campbell 2006; Basu and Vasudevan 2013). Additionally, the author
presents that the decomposition is sometimes taken further from these two components into subcomponents. From here, a more detailed analysis of the profit rate tendencies is usually done by
decomposing it on the labor productivity  Y  , average wage ( w ), and capital/labor ratio  K  , as
L
L
in equation 1:
Y
−w
r= L
K
L
(1)
This approach is the more general framework to analyze the rate of profit in particular and the
disputes for income distribution in general. As it is, it does not account for differences in wages
among workers. The proposal here is to disaggregate wages by gender. With this, it could be possible to account for gender wage discrimination and differences in labor shares of employment
by gender.
It is possible to redefine equation 1 by including the average wage for females w f and the
average wage for males wm . Also, by including the female and male shares of employment,
where the number of female workers is defined by L f and the number of male workers by Lm ,
having L = L f + Lm . The rate of profit is therefore equal to:
( )
( )
Y L f f Lm m
w
w −
−
L
r= L L
K
L
(2)
The GWG (σ) is defined as one less the gender wage ratio (the ratio of the average wage for
females and the average wage for males). Therefore, the variable σ falls between 0 and 1. As the
literature points out, the gap has been persistently higher than 0 for the aggregate economy. Having
σ = 0 implies that there is no GWG:
σ = 1−
wf
wm
(3)
58
Review of Radical Political Economics 56(1)
It is also possible to define the female share of employment ( α ) as the ratio of employed
female workers over total labor employed. By definition, α falls between 0 and 1 too:
α=
Lf
L
(4)
Replacing σ and α in equation 2 and reorganizing terms, the rate of profit is equal to:
Y
− wm (1 − ασ )
L
r=
K
L
(5)
Equation 5 shows that with an absence of a GWG, when σ = 0, the term (1 − ασ ) = 1 .
Therefore, equation 5 becomes the same as equation 1, where the gender variables are no longer
relevant for determining the profit rate.
However, in the presence of a GWG, it is known that 0 < (1 − ασ ) < 1. This implies that, in a
classical framework, having a GWG that responds to gender wage discrimination benefits the
capitalists through a higher rate of profit. Also, the higher this gap, the more benefits the capitalists get. Nevertheless, the impact of this gap on the rate of profit depends on the female share of
employment—the higher the α, the higher is the rate of profit, ceteris paribus. The intuition is
that the capital could save on unit labor costs by employing female workers since their wages are
lower than those of their male coworkers.
This approach can also be used to decompose the wage share, taking into account gender wage
differences. It allows analyzing the impacts of the GWG and the female share of employment on
the wage share. Besides, it is also possible to account for the dynamics of wages and productivity.
Both need to increase at the same rate in order to keep the wage share constant. An increasing
wage-productivity gap means that a higher portion of the output goes to profits:
m
W w (1 − ασ )
=
Y
Y 
L
 
(6)
Finally, this approach makes it possible to analyze the decoupling of labor productivity and
wages by gender. This decoupling in part reflects that the share of the total output is received by
female and male workers separately as in equations 7 and 8, respectively. They provide information about the distribution of income, not only by class but also by gender:
Wf
wf
=
Y
Y 
L
 
(7)
Wm
wm
=
Y
Y 
L
 
(8)
5. Data Sources
Data are restricted to the period 1960–2017 for the US manufacturing sector. This includes corporate and noncorporate manufacturing businesses. Data on the GWG comes from two different
Ossa
59
sources. The Comparative Family Policy Database has a series of wages by gender in the US
manufacturing sector from 1960 to 2008 (Gauthier 2010). An estimate for the period 2009–2017
is done by using data from the US Department of Labor on median annual earnings by sex.3 Data
on the number of workers in the manufacturing sector by gender comes from the US Bureau of
Labor Statistics. The CPI comes from the Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED).
The rest of the data comes from the Bureau of Economic Analysis National Income and
Produce Accounts (BEA-NIPA) tables. The level of output comes from table 6.1: National
Income Without Capital Consumption Adjustment by Industry (B, C, and D). The capital stock
comes from table 3.1: ESI Current-Cost Net Stock of Private Fixed Assets by Industry. On wages,
there are two possible approaches: either using total compensation of employees, which includes
wages and salaries, and supplements to wages and salaries, or only wages and salaries. Because
this article aims to approach the rate of profit in its broader sense (output minus labor compensation), the analysis is done using the total compensation of employees. The data used comes from
table 6.2 (B, C, and D). The output deflator for nonfarm business comes from table 1.9.4: Price
Indexes for Net Value Added by sector. To control for part-time and full-time workers, I use table
6.5: Full-Time Equivalent Employees by Industry.
6. Decomposition Analysis
The evolution of the GWG is presented in figure 1. Four main periods seem relevant in the movement of this variable. Between 1960 and 1980, the gap was relatively stagnant. From 1981 to
2000, the GWG gap declined. For the period 2001–2012, it was relatively stagnant again, and
then began to continue falling since 2013. A significant part of the decline in the GWG is
explained by the increasing level of schooling and years of experience in the aggregate economy,
as Blau and Kahn (2017) find. However, as their article also points out, even when controlling for
qualification variables, there is still a decline in the GWG associated with changes in nonqualification factors as the evolution of the unionization rates across genders.
The second central variable for the analysis is the share of female workers in the total number
of employees in the manufacturing sector. As shown in figure 2, it presents an inverted-U shape
for most of the period. The share of female workers increases steadily from 1960 to the beginning
of the 1990s. Since then, its share began to fall up to 2013, where it started to grow again up to
the most recent data in 2021.
With the data on the GWG ( σ ) and the female share of employment ( α ), it is possible to ask,
What has been the combined effects of these two variables over the rate of profit in the period
examined? To do so, it is possible to measure the actual rate of profit of the manufacturing
sector and compare it to a counterfactual measure under an absence of gender wage discrimination. Given that there is no precise data for the level of such discrimination, I am using the
totality of the GWG assuming that its totality responds to it. Then, the counterfactual rate of
profit is measured taking the value of the GWG equal to zero ( σ = 0 ) and using equation 5 it
is. This counterfactual analysis is inspired by Shaikh (2016: 730–32).
3
The reason to use two different data sets for the GWG is that the data in the Comparative Family Policy
Database includes average hourly wage by gender, but is only available up to 2008. The data from the US
Department of Labor does not include the hourly wage, and it is not disaggregated by sectors, but presents
data on the GWG that covers more recent data points. The GWG from both are located at different levels.
The GWG is higher for the overall economy, from the US Department of Labor, compared to the manufacturing sector of the Comparative Family Policy Database. Nevertheless, both data sets share very similar
trends for the period 1960–2008. For this reason, I extend the manufacturing sector GWG assuming it has
the same rate of growth as the rest of the economy.
60
Review of Radical Political Economics 56(1)
Figure 1. Gender wage gap: US manufacturing sector, 1960–2017.
Source: Author’s elaboration based on Comparative Family Policy Database and US Department of Labor.
Figure 2. Female share of employment: US manufacturing sector, 1960–2021.
Source: Author’s elaboration based on US Bureau of Labor Statistics.
Figure 3 suggests that gender wage discrimination might have provided additional benefits to
the rate of profit throughout the entire period. However, those extra benefits, the difference
between the actual and counterfactual profit rates, have been getting lost over time as the GWG
have been closing. Some caution should go into interpreting these results. As discussed in section
2, the GWG responds to multiple factors, including, at least partially, differences in qualifications. This means that for capital it is not always possible to replace a male worker with a female
counterpart and save the total amount of the GWG on average. Nevertheless, the nonqualification
factors explain an even more significant portion of the GWG. First of all, this article focuses only
on the manufacturing sector, which sets aside a portion of the gap explained by industry. Second,
part of the gap and its decline is explained by the drop in the differences in unionization rates by
gender. Third, discrimination based on race also has an important role. Finally, most of the gap
remains unexplained, something associated with labor market discrimination. Therefore, this
analysis should be taken as an approximation and not as an exact measure of the problem,
Ossa
61
Figure 3. Actual and counterfactual rates of profit: US manufacturing sector, 1960–2017.
Source: Author’s own calculations based on Bureau of Economic Analysis National Income and Produce Accounts
tables 3.1 ESI, 6.1, 6.2, 6.5, Comparative Family Policy Database, and US Bureau of Labor Statistics.
Figure 4. Ratio of the difference between actual and counterfactual rates of profit over the actual: US
manufacturing sector, 1960–2017.
Source: Author’s own calculations based on Bureau of Economic Analysis National Income and Produce Accounts
tables 3.1 ESI, 6.1, 6.2, and 6.5; Comparative Family Policy Database; and US Bureau of Labor Statistics.
considering the limitations of the data. The consequence of this exercise is a possible overestimation of the extra benefits obtained by capital coming from the gender wage discrimination.
Figure 4 presents a clearer picture of the patterns in the ratio of the difference between the
factual and counterfactual rates of profit, which I am calling extra benefits. From 1960 to 1986,
the extra benefits increased. This was the same period when the GWG was stagnant, and the
female labor share of employment rose. The combination of these two effects might have
increased the additional benefits by reducing unit labor costs. The additional gains began to fall
afterward as the GWG narrowed, and the female labor share of employment began to decline.
The combination of these two phenomena might have decreased the extra benefit for capital
coming from the gender wage discrimination.
62
Review of Radical Political Economics 56(1)
Figure 5. Wage-productivity gap: US manufacturing sector, 1960–2017. Output is deflated using the
Net Output Deflator, and labor’s total compensation is deflated using Consumer Price Index and Net
Output Deflator.
Source: Author’s own calculations based on Bureau of Economic Analysis National Income and Produce Accounts
tables 1.9.4, 6.1, 6.2, and 6.5 and Consumer Price Index from Federal Reserve Economic Data.
Taking a look at the WPD also provides important insights. As covered in section 3, the dimension of the decoupling depends on the different measurements for each the variables to be considered. The present analysis uses the following measurements. I consider all workers, that is, supervisory
and nonsupervisory. For worker’s income, I use the average of the total labor compensation. For the
deflator of worker’s income, I present the results of using the CPI and the net output deflator, considering the debate proposed by Pessoa and Reenen (2013) and the response by Baker (2019). For
output, I use net output instead of gross. And finally, productivity is measured as output per worker,
and because I am using full-time equivalent employees, it is equal to the productivity per hour.
There is a limitation with this approach. As said before, taking the totality of workers, instead of
nonsupervisory workers, and the use of average worker’s income instead of the median underestimates the WPD. Different authors have pointed out that the compensation of low- and middle-income
workers has been stagnant while high managerial salaries have had a significant increase (Duménil
and Lévy 2011; Elsby, Hobijn, and Sahin 2013; Giovannoni 2014; Economic Policy Institute 2021).
This leads to an overestimation of the labor share for the immense majority of workers. However,
given the available data, it is not possible to control for these factors in the present work.
Figure 5 compares the evolution of workers’ compensation with labor productivity using two
different deflators: the CPI and the Net Output Deflator. In the first case, the decoupling began in
the 1970s and has grown in a sustained path since then, a result coherent with Shaikh (2016: 60).
In the second case, the decoupling started in 2001. Though the data are not presented in this
article, it is worth pointing out that the decoupling is higher in both cases when only wages and
salaries are used instead of workers’ total compensation, which is in line with Zavodny (1999).
Using wages and salaries, the decoupling began in 1970 using the CPI and in 1986 using the
output deflator.
The wage share, measured as the portion of workers’ total compensation in the net output, is
presented in figure 6. It can be seen that the share began to decline drastically after 2001. The
reason is that this was the point at which the total compensation of workers stopped increasing
along with productivity, as seen in figure 5 in the case of the Net Output Deflator. As Pessoa and
Reenen (2013) point out, a fall in the wage share can only be observed when the WPD is measured using the same deflator for both wages and output.
After analyzing the WPD and its impacts on the wage share, it is worth asking about the gender aspect of this issue. More specifically, the GWG and the female share of employment provide
Ossa
63
Figure 6. Total compensation of employees as a share of net output: US manufacturing sector,
1960–2017.
Source: Author’s own calculations based on Bureau of Economic Analysis National Income and Produce Accounts
tables 6.1 and 6.2.
Figure 7. Wage-productivity gap: US manufacturing sector, 1960–2017. Labor’s total compensation is
deflated using Consumer Price Index.
Source: Author’s own calculations based on Bureau of Economic Analysis National Income and Produce Accounts
tables 6.1, 6.2, and 6.5; Federal Reserve Economic Data Consumer Price Index; Comparative Family Policy Database;
and US Bureau of Labor Statistics.
a new angle to understand the problem. Figure 7 shows the real total compensation of workers by
gender. It can be seen how total female compensation grew along with productivity up to 2002,
while male compensation was relatively stagnant (which is especially true when looking at wages
instead of total compensation). This suggests that the decline in the GWG followed roughly the
rhythm of increasing labor productivity up to 2002.
Some interesting patterns can be seen regarding the share of output received by female and
male workers using equations 7 and 8. The female wage share, shown in figure 8, closely follows
the inverted-U shape of the female share of employment. On the other hand, the male wage share
has declined since the 1970s. The reason is mainly the increasing participation of female labor in
the manufacturing sector and the stagnation of male wages relative to labor productivity.
64
Review of Radical Political Economics 56(1)
Figure 8. Total compensation of female and male workers as a share of net output: US manufacturing
sector 1960–2017.
Source: Author’s own calculations based on Bureau of Economic Analysis National Income and Produce Accounts
tables 6.1, 6.2, and 6.5; Comparative Family Policy Database; and US Bureau of Labor Statistics.
Figure 9. Actual and counterfactual wage shares using total compensation of employees and net
output: US manufacturing sector, 1960–2017.
Source: Author’s own calculations based on Bureau of Economic Analysis National Income and Produce Accounts
tables 6.1, 6.2, and 6.5; Comparative Family Policy Database; and US Bureau of Labor Statistics.
It is possible to apply the same counterfactual exercise to analyze the wage share using equation 6. Figure 9 shows that assuming the absence of the GWG ( σ = 0 ), the wage share would have
been higher during the entire period (Counterfactual Wage Share). As in the case of the rate of
profit, as the GWG falls, the difference between the actual and the counterfactual diminishes. It
is important to notice that while in the actual wage share, the fall began in 2001, in the counterfactual one, it started in 1986. This result suggests that narrowing the GWG could have played a
significant role in maintaining the total wage share roughly constant up to 2001. In other
words, the fact that female wages were catching up with male wages helped to prevent the fall in
Ossa
65
Figure 10. Actual and counterfactual rates of profit. US manufacturing sector 1960–2017.
Source: Author’s own calculations based on Bureau of Economic Analysis National Income and Produce Accounts
tables 3.1 ESI, 6.1, 6.2, and 6.5; Comparative Family Policy Database; and US Bureau of Labor Statistics.
the wage share in the manufacturing sector during 1986–2001, a similar finding as in Zacharias
and Mahoney (2009).
By now, the isolated effects of the GWG and the WPD in the level of profitability and income
distribution have been covered. The first phenomenon might have helped sustain profits by saving in unit labor costs by hiring female workers during 1960–1986 as more women entered as
workers in this sector. Nevertheless, these extra benefits began to disappear as the female wages
got closer to their male counterparts. It was also shown that the WPD began to gain relevance in
sustaining the profit rate after 2001. With these two processes in mind, it is possible to create a
second counterfactual rate of profit that combines both effects.
Figure 10 combines the assumptions of absence in the GWG and wages growing along with
productivity (constant wage share after 2001). The graph suggests that the US manufacturing
sector might have gotten extra benefits from these two sources. During 1960–2000, these additional benefits came mainly from the gender wage discrimination and afterward from the WPD.
This means that part of the fall in the profit rate experienced before the new millennia could be
associated with closing the GWG. After this period, the extra benefits come mainly from the
decoupling between wages and productivity, despite the persistence of gender income inequality.
In sum, the results suggest that the US manufacturing sector might have transited from getting
extra benefits by exploiting cheap female labor to a period of constraining labor compensation by
providing increments below the productivity growth and therefore reducing the wage share.
Table 2 presents a summary of the results.
7. Conclusions
The narrowing of the GWG and the WPD are two relevant phenomena to understand the struggle
for income distribution in the US economy. The GWG has been associated in the literature with
higher profitability, investment, and competitiveness due to the lower unit labor costs. The WPD
has also been associated with a way to maintain or boost profitability.
This article proposes an extension to the usual decomposition method of the profit rate that
takes into account labor productivity, average wage, and capital/labor ratio (Basu 2017: 1375).
66
Review of Radical Political Economics 56(1)
Table 2. Summary of the Results.
Period
1960–1986
1986–2001
2001–2017
Observations
Relatively constant GWG and increasing female share of labor participation might
become a source of extra benefits for capital, reflected in a higher rate of profit.
The closing of the GWG and the decline of the female share of employment might have
implied a loss of extra benefits for capital, reducing the rate of profit.
The GWG stop closing. The rate of profit is sustained thanks to the WPD, which can
be seen in the average worker's total compensation.
It introduces the GWG and the female share of employment into the equation. It then applies
this method to analyze the possible effects of the evolution of this wage discrepancy across
genders and the WPD in the profitability and income distribution of the US manufacturing
sector.
The results suggest that three consecutive periods could be defined for the US manufacturing sector. The first one, 1960–1986, in which the combined effects of gender wage discrimination and the increasing participation of female workers in this sector might have become a
source of extra benefits for capital. In the second period, 1986–2001, the combined effects of
narrowing the GWG and female workers leaving the sector reduced the extra benefits that
capital could have gotten by hiring cheaper labor. This might have pushed capital to change the
strategy to maintain profits. In consequence, the third period, after 2001, is when the WPD
gained more relevance to sustain profits, suppressing the wage share of output. One of the
main takeaways from this analysis is the relevance of including gender inequalities when
studying the dynamics and tendencies of the rate of profit.
There are several caveats and shortcomings to the analysis as the nature of available data sets
some limitations. First, I analyze the entire manufacturing sector, which includes corporate and
noncorporate businesses. However, the analysis of the profit rate is generally more relevant for
only the corporate sector since it is the one whose primary motivation is profitability. Second, as
discussed above, the factors behind the GWG are complex. And given the nature and availability
of these data, it is not possible to control for the qualification variables that explain part of the gap
in order to obtain cleaner results. In consequence, the analysis of the extra benefits coming from
gender wage discrimination could be overestimated. Third, given that I considered the average
labor compensation of all workers in the sector instead of focusing on nonsupervisory workers,
the results could be underestimating the impacts of both the GWG and the WPD in the functional
income distribution and the rate of profit.
The present article also opens possibilities for future research. I focus here on the manufacturing sector. However, it is well known in the literature that the dynamics of the GWG and the
WPD vary across sectors. Therefore, further research could shed light on the interaction between
these two variables in the rest of the economy. Additionally, given the availability of new data
sets, it could be possible to have better estimations of the impacts of the GWG and the WPD on
the income distribution between capital and labor.
Author Note
Daniel Ossa is now affiliated with Department of Economics, University of Denver, Denver, CO, USA.
Acknowledgment
I am grateful to Kristin Munro, Sara Cantillon, and Aaron Pacitti for their valuable comments and suggestions on previous visions of this article. Any remaining errors are my own responsibility.
Ossa
67
Declaration of Conflicting Interests
The author declared no potential conflicts of interest with respect to the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article.
Funding
The author received no financial support for the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article.
ORCID iD
Daniel Ossa
https://orcid.org/0000-0001-5435-5120
References
Arestis, Philip. 2020. Productivity and inequality in the UK: A political economy perspective. Review of
Evolutionary Political Economy 1 (2): 183–97.
Baker, Dean. 2019. The Productivity to Paycheck Gap: 2019 Update. CEPR Report. Washington, DC:
Center for Economic and Policy Research. Accessed at: https://cepr.net/report/the-productivity-topaycheck-gap-2019-update/.
Bakir, Erdogan, and Al Campbell. 2006. The effect of neoliberalism on the fall in the rate of profit in business cycles. Review of Radical Political Economics 38 (3): 365–73.
Basu, Deepankar. 2017. Quantitative empirical research in Marxist political economy: A selective review.
Journal of Economic Surveys 31 (5): 1359–86.
Basu, Deepankar, and Ramaa Vasudevan. 2013. Technology, distribution, and the rate of profit in the US
economy: Understanding the current crisis. Cambridge Journal of Economics 37 (1): 57–89.
Bivens, Josh, Elise Gould, Lawrence Mishel, and Heidi Shierholz. 2014. Raising America’s Pay: Why It’s
Our Central Economic Policy Challenge. EPI Briefing Paper no. 378. Washington, DC: Economic
Policy Institute. Accessed at: https://www.epi.org/publication/raising-americas-pay/.
Blau, Francine D., and Lawrence M. Kahn. 2017. The gender wage gap: Extent, trends, and explanations.
Journal of Economic Literature 55 (3): 789–865.
Blau, Francine D., and Anne E. Winkler. 2018. The Economics of Women, Men, and Work. 8th ed. New
York: Oxford University Press.
Cakmakli, Selim, Sara Cantillon, and Lutfi Ucal. 2020. The Pay and Productivity Dilemma: A Critical
Theoretical Review and Empirical Analysis for the UK Economy. Research Paper. Sheffield, UK:
Productivity Insights Network. Accessed at: https://www.researchgate.net/publication/347472437_
The_Pay_and_Productivity_Dilemma_A_Critical_Theoretical_Review_and_Empirical_Analysis_
for_the_UK_Economy.
Cantillon, Sara, and Lutfi Ucal. 2019. The Divergence of Pay and Productivity? Institutional Structural and
Cyclical Factors. Research Paper. Sheffield, UK: Productivity Insights Network. Accessed at: https://
productivityinsightsnetwork.co.uk/publications-project-reports/.
Card, David, Thomas Lemieux, and W. Craig Riddell. 2020. Unions and wage inequality: The roles of
gender, skill, and public sector employment. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue Canadienne
d’économique 53 (1): 140–73.
Cauvel, Michael, and Aaron Pacitti. 2022. Bargaining power, structural change, and the falling US labor
share. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 60: 512–30.
Cobb, Charles W., and Paul H. Douglas. 1928. A theory of production. The American Economic Review
18 (1): 139–65.
Duménil, Gérard, and Dominique Lévy. 2002. The profit rate: Where and how much did it fall? Did it
recover? (USA 1948–2000). Review of Radical Political Economics 34 (4): 437–61.
———. 2011. The Crisis of Neoliberalism. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Economic Policy Institute. 2021. The Productivity–Pay Gap. EPI blog. Washington, DC: Economic Policy
Institute. Accessed at: https://www.epi.org/productivity-pay-gap/.
Elsby, Michael, Bart Hobijn, and Ayseful Sahin. 2013. The decline of the U.S. labor share. Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity 44 (2): 1–63.
Elveren, Adem Y., Christa Marr, and Yvonne Renard. 2017. Feminization of labour and profit rates:
Evidence from OECD countries. Applied Economics Letters 24 (7): 481–84.
68
Review of Radical Political Economics 56(1)
Ertürk, Korkut, and Nilüfer Çağatay. 1995. Macroeconomic consequences of cyclical and secular changes
in feminization: An experiment at gendered macromodeling. World Development 23 (11): 1969–77.
Feldstein, Martin. 2008. Did wages reflect growth in productivity? Journal of Policy Modeling 30 (4):
591–94.
Felipe, Jesus, and John S. L. McCombie. 2014. The aggregate production function: “Not even wrong.”
Review of Political Economy 26 (1): 60–84.
Ferguson, William. 1996. Explaining the rising wage-productivity gap of the 1980s: Effects of declining
employment and unionization. Review of Radical Political Economics 28 (2): 77–115.
Fields, Judith, and Edward N. Wolff. 1995. Interindustry wage differentials and the gender wage gap. ILR
Review 49 (1): 105–20.
Finnoff, Kade, and Arjun Jayadev. 2006. Feminization and the Labor Share. Working Paper no. 06–4. Salt
Lake City, UT: International Working Group on Gender.
Gauthier, Anne H. 2010. Comparative Family Policy Database, version 3. Netherlands Interdisciplinary
Demographic Institute and Max Planck Institute for Demographic Research. Accessed at: https://www.
demogr.mpg.de/cgi-bin/databases/fampoldb/index.plx.
Giovannoni, Olivier. 2014. What Do We Know about the Labor Share and the Profit Share? Part III:
Measures and Structural Factors. Economics Working Paper Archive, Levy Economics Institute.
Accessed at: https://econpapers.repec.org/paper/levwrkpap/wp_5f805.htm.
Gould, Elise. 2019. State of Working America Wages 2018: Wage Inequality Marches On—And Is Even
Threatening Data Reliability. Washington, DC: Economic Policy Institute. Accessed at: https://www.
epi.org/publication/state-of-american-wages-2018/.
Hein, Eckhard. 2020. Gender issues in Kaleckian distribution and growth models: On the macroeconomics
of the gender wage gap. Review of Political Economy 32 (4): 640–64.
Horrace, William C., and Ronald L. Oaxaca. 2001. Inter-industry wage differentials and the gender wage
gap: An identification problem. ILR Review 54 (3): 611–18.
ILO (International Labour Organization). 2015. Global Wage Report 2014/15—Wages and Income
Inequality. Global Wage Report. Geneva: International Labour Organization. Accessed at: https://
www.ilo.org/global/research/global-reports/global-wage-report/2014/lang--en/index.htm.
———. 2018. Global Wage Report 2018/19—What Lies behind Gender Pay Gaps. Global Wage Report.
Geneva: International Labour Organization. Accessed at: https://www.ilo.org/global/research/globalreports/global-wage-report/2018/lang--en/index.htm.
Lavoie, Marc, and Engelbert Stockhammer, eds. 2013. Wage-Led Growth. London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Levy, Frank S., and Peter Temin. 2007. Inequality and Institutions in 20th Century America. SSRN
Scholarly Paper ID 984330. Rochester, NY: Social Science Research Network. Accessed at: https://
papers.ssrn.com/abstract=984330.
OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). 2018. OECD Economic Outlook,
volume 2018. OECD Publishing. Accessed at: https://www.oecd.org/economy/decoupling-of-wagesfrom-productivity/.
Pessoa, Joao Paulo, and John Van Reenen. 2013. Decoupling of Wage Growth and Productivity Growth?
Myth and Reality. CEP Discussion Paper no. 1246. London: Centre for Economic Performance, LSE.
Accessed at: https://ideas.repec.org/p/cep/cepdps/dp1246.html.
Phelps Brown, Ernest H. 1957. The meaning of the fitted Cobb-Douglas function. The Quarterly Journal
of Economics 71 (4): 546–60.
Schur, Lisa A., and Douglas L. Kruse. 1992. Gender differences in attitudes toward unions. Industrial and
Labor Relations Review 46 (1): 89–102.
Schwellnus, Cyrille, Andreas Kappeler, and Pierre-Alain Pionnier. 2017. Decoupling of Wages from
Productivity: Macro-Level Facts. OECD Economics Department Working Paper no. 1373. Paris:
OECD Publishing. Accessed at: https://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/economics/decoupling-of-wages-fromproductivity_d4764493-en.
Seguino, Stephanie. 2000. Accounting for gender in Asian economic growth. Feminist Economics 6: 27–58.
———. 2019. Engendering macroeconomic theory and policy. Feminist Economics 26 (2): 27–61.
Shaikh, Anwar. 1974. Laws of production and laws of algebra: The humbug production function. The
Review of Economics and Statistics 56 (1): 115–20.
Ossa
69
———. 1992. The falling rate of profit as the cause of long waves: Theory and empirical evidence. In New
Findings in Long-Wave Research, eds. Alfred Kleinknecht, Ernest Mandel, and Immanuel Wallerstein,
174–202. London: Palgrave Macmillan.
———. 2016. Capitalism: Competition, Conflict, Crises. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Škare, Marinko, and Damian Škare. 2017. Is the great decoupling real? Journal of Business Economics and
Management 18 (3): 451–67.
Tescari, Alice, and Andrea Vaona. 2014. Gender employment disparities, financialization, and profitability
dynamics on the eve of Italy’s post-2008 crisis. Feminist Economics 20 (3): 191–209.
Zacharias, Ajit, and Melissa Mahoney. 2009. Do gender disparities in employment increase profitability?
Evidence from the United States. Feminist Economics 15: 133–61.
Zavodny, Madeline. 1999. Unions and the wage-productivity gap. Economic Review 84 (Q2): 44–53.
Author Biography
Daniel Ossa received his PhD in Economics from the University of Utah in 2023. He is joining the
University of Denver as a Teaching Assistant Professor in Economics. His research focuses on political
economy and macroeconomics.
Download