Instructor’s Manual Microeconomics Third edition Hugh Gravelle Ray Rees For further instructor material please visit: www.pearsoned.co.uk/gravelle ISBN-13: 978-0-273-65892-4 / ISBN-10: 0-273-65892-1 Pearson Education Limited 2007 Lecturers adopting the main text are permitted to download and photocopy the manual as required. Pearson Education Limited Edinburgh Gate Harlow Essex CM20 2JE England and Associated Companies around the world Visit us on the World Wide Web at: http://www.pearsoned.co.uk ----------------------------------Third edition 2007 © Pearson Education Limited 2007 The rights of Hugh Gravelle and Ray Rees to be identified as authors of this Work has been asserted by him/her/them in accordance with the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988. ISBN-13: 978-0-273-65892-4 ISBN-10: 0-273-65892-1 All rights reserved. Permission is hereby given for the material in this publication to be reproduced for OHP transparencies and student handouts, without express permission of the Publishers, for educational purposes only. In all other cases, no part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise without either the prior written permission of the Publishers or a licence permitting restricted copying in the United Kingdom issued by the Copyright Licensing Agency Ltd., 90 Tottenham Court Road, London W1T 4LP. This book may not be lent, resold, hired out or otherwise disposed of by way of trade in any form of binding or cover other than that in which is it is published, without the prior consent of the Publishers. Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Contents Chapter 2 The Theory of the Consumer 1 Chapter 3 Consumer Theory: Duality 21 Chapter 4 Further Models of Consumer Behaviour 39 Chapter 5 Production 60 Chapter 6 Cost 69 Chapter 7 Supply and Firm Objectives 83 Chapter 8 The Theory of a Competitive Market 100 Chapter 9 Monopoly 112 Chapter 10 Input Markets 130 Chapter 11 Capital Markets 145 Chapter 12 General Equilibrium 154 Chapter 13 Welfare Economics 160 Chapter 14 Market Failure and Government Failure 167 Chapter 15 Game Theory 178 Chapter 16 Oligopoly 196 Chapter 17 Choice under Uncertainty 207 Chapter 18 Production under Uncertainty 221 Chapter 19 Insurance, Risk Spreading and Pooling 226 Chapter 20 Agency, Contract Theory and the Firm 242 Chapter 21 General Equilibrium under Uncertainty and Incomplete Markets 255 Appendices 277 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 1 Chapter 2 The Theory of the Consumer Exercise 2A 1. Suppose two indifference curves intersect at a point x0, as shown in Fig. 2A.1. Then there exist bundles x′, x″ such that x′ ~ x0 and x0 ~ x″ but x′ > x″ which violates transitivity. Note that we do not require the non-satiation axiom for this. The same result would follow if x″ > x′. 2. The answer is given by diagrams in Fig. 2A.2 (examples are used to label the axes). 3. The assumption of non-satiation rules out the possibility of bliss points (refer to the answer to question 4 of Exercise F). It ensures that consumers will always want to consume more goods than are available given the resources the economy possesses. As a result, we have relative scarcity and the need for the allocation of scarce resources among competing uses. Thus the usefulness of microeconomics rests upon some kind of non-satiation assumption. 4. See Fig. 2A.3. 4. (a) The utility function is quasi-concave but not strictly quasi-concave. Blue and red matches are perfect substitutes (we assume the consumer cares only about incendiary properties and not colour). Therefore utility depends only on the total number of matches: reducing the number of blue matches by one is fully compensated by increasing the number of red matches by one. MRS21 is therefore constant and equal to one. 4. (b) Assuming the consumer has the usual configuration of legs, right and left shoes of the same style, colour, quality, size, etc. are perfect complements. Utility depends on the number of pairs of shoes the consumer possesses. Thus the consumer would be indifferent between two pairs of shoes and two pairs of shoes plus one left shoe. Thus the indifference curves take the extreme kinked shape shown here. We would say that right and left shoes have to be consumed in fixed proportions, here one-to-one. The utility function is concave but not strictly concave. MRS21 = −dx2/dx1 is zero along a horizontal segment of an indifference curve and undefined along a vertical segment (and conversely for MRS12). 5. The correct answer here is (c), as may perhaps have been guessed from the fact that it is the most complicated answer. (a) is wrong because it refers to total rather than marginal valuations. (b) is wrong in a more subtle way. Strict convexity does not refer to absolute amounts of the marginal variations in the two goods required to stay on an indifference curve, but only on how the ratio of these amounts varies © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 1 2 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 2A.1 Fig. 2A.2 as we move along an indifference curve. It is quite consistent with strict convexity that, at a bundle consisting of a lot of water and a few diamonds, the consumer would give up very little water for an extra diamond. In water-diamond space the indifference curves could be everywhere very steep. The point is that at a bundle with more water and fewer diamonds, he would give up more water for an extra diamond. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 3 Fig. 2A.3 Exercise 2B 1. Suppose that p1 = p1(x1), with p1′ > 0, but that p2 is constant. Then, we can write the consumer’s budget constraint as x2 = (M − p1(x1)x1)/p2 ≡ B(x1) and we have B′(x1) = − 1 (p + x1 p1′ ) < 0. p2 1 Thus again we have a negatively-sloped budget constraint. We could interpret p1 + x1 p1′ as the marginal price or marginal cost of x1 to the consumer, since it is the derivative d[p1(x1)x1]/dx1, where p1(x1)x1 is the total cost of buying x1. Thus the slope of the budget line, or curve, at a point is the ratio of the marginal cost of x1 to the price (= marginal cost) of x2. If we want the budget set still to be a convex set, we require B(x1) to be a concave function, i.e. we require B″(x1) = − 1 ( 2 p1′ + x1 p1′′) < 0 p2 or 2 p1′ + x1 p1′′ > 0. This cannot be guaranteed without further restrictions on the function p(x1). If this function is convex, so that p1′′ ≥ 0, then we have immediately that B″(x1) < 0 and the budget set is a convex set. If, on the other hand, p1(x1) is non-convex, then we require 2 p1′( x1 ) > − x1 p1′′( x1 ) at all x1 in the interval [0, I1], where I1 satisfies p1(I1)I1 = M. If this condition does not hold then we may have non-convexity of the budget set which, as we saw in Appendix D, can cause local optima to be non-unique or, worse, nonglobal. Accordingly, a point satisfying the Lagrange multiplier conditions may not then be a true solution to the constrained problem. In the case where the condition is satisfied, Fig. 2B.1 illustrates the budget set. Choose the unit of measurement for x2 such that its price is p2 = 1. Then, in the figure, the slope at B(x1) at a point such as x0 measures the marginal cost or price © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 4 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 2B.1 Fig. 2B.2 B′ ( x10 ), while the slope of the line from x′ to M gives the average cost or price p( x10 ). To see the latter, note that if p2 = 1 expenditure on good 2 is x20 and so expenditure on good 1 is M − x20 = p1 ( x10 ) x10 , while the slope of the line is (M − x20 ) / x10 . Thus marginal exceeds average cost or price. 2. Denote the connection charge by C, let p0 be the price of the first n units of electricity and let p1 be the price of the remainder, with p0 > p1. Let the price of the consumption good be normalized at 1. Then Fig. 2B.2 shows the consumer’s budget constraint on the assumption that her income M is large enough that she is able to buy more than n units of electricity if she wants to. If she buys no electricity then she spends M on the consumption good. If she wants to buy any positive quantity of electricity she pays C. Denoting the consumption good by c and electricity demand by e the function defining the budget constraint is © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 5 Fig. 2B.3 c = M for e = 0, c = M − C − p0e c = M − C − p0n − p1(e − n) = M − C − (p0 − p1)n − p1e for 0 < e ≤ n, for n < e. Since p1 < p0 the second segment of the budget constraint is flatter than the first. The intercept on the e-axis is B= M − C − ( p0 − p1 ) n p1 The marginal price of electricity is p0 for 0 < e ≤ n and p1 for e > n. The average price of electricity is F0 = C + p0 e F1 = C + ( p0 − p1 ) n + p1 e for 0 < e ≤ n, for n < e. In each case therefore the average price falls with e but is always above the marginal price. The effects of changes in the connection charge and in prices are shown in Fig. 2B.3. If, say, C falls to C′ then the budget constraint shifts to B′. If with the fixed charge at C, p0 increases to p0′ then the budget constraint becomes B″. Finally, if with C and p0 fixed, p1 falls to p1′ then the constraint becomes B′″. Supplementary questions (i) On the budget constraint of Fig. 2B.2, superimpose indifference curves appropriate to each of the following types of consumer: © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 6 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 2B.4 (a) one who buys no electricity; (b) one who buys between zero and n units of electricity; (c) one who buys more than n units (ii) Is the consumer’s feasible set convex? Ilustrate some problems that may arise. 3. Let g be the amount of garbage removed, so that the amount retained by the consumer is x = G − g, with G the total amount produced. Let p be the cost per unit of garbage removed. Finally, let y be the consumption good, with price set at 1, and M the consumer’s income. Then the budget constraint is y + pg = M or y − px = M − pG. The budget constraint in (x, y)-space is graphed in Fig. 2B.4, on the assumption that pG < M. The slope of the line is p. Supplementary questions (i) Show the effects on the budget constraint of a rise in M; a fall in c; and increase in *. (ii) Superimpose the indifference curves for each of the following types of consumer: (a) one who has all her garbage removed; (b) one who has some but not all garbage removed; (c) one who has no garbage removed. What happens to the first type of consumer if c* > M? Exercise 2C 1. Given a budget constraint as in Fig. 2B.2, the conditions of the Existence Theorem are satisfied (given that the utility function is continuous) since the feasible set is nonempty, closed and bounded. It is not, however, convex, and so we may have multiple global optima (an indifference curve could be tangent to both linear segments) and local optima that are not global (two indifference curves each tangent to one linear segment). © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 7 Fig. 2C.1 2. We can use the Kuhn-Tucker conditions as a general framework within which to organize the answer to this question. Thus suppose we want to solve max u(x1, x2) x1 ,x2 s.t. p1x1 + p2 x2 ≤ M, x1, x2 ≥ 0, where u is quasi-concave. The Kuhn-Tucker conditions, which are both necessary and sufficient for an optimum are, ui − λ*pi ≤ 0 xi* ≥ 0 xi* [ui − λ*pi] = 0 p1 x1* + p2 x2* − M ≤ 0 λ* ≥ 0 λ*[ p1 x1* + p2 x2* − M ] = 0 i = 1, 2, Now take two cases: (a) One of the goods, say x1, is a bad, i.e. u1 < 0. From the Kuhn-Tucker conditions we see that if x1* > 0, then u1 = λ*p1 at the optimum. This tells us that a necessary condition for positive consumption of a bad at the optimum is that its price is negative – one must be paid for consuming it. If p1 > 0 then the condition can only be satisfied with u1 < λp1 implying x1* = 0. If you have to pay to consume a bad then you choose a zero quantity. (b) Suppose that the consumer is satiated with x1 when she reaches a consumption I1; i.e. u1 > 0 for x1 < I1 and u1 = 0 for x1 ≥ I1, for any consumption x2. We now show that, if u2 > 0 everywhere in the feasible set, and both prices are positive, the consumer is always at an equilibrium at which x1* < I1, so that u1 ( x1* , x2* ) > 0. Thus for i = 2, the Kuhn-Tucker condition gives u2 = λ*p2 > 0 and so λ* > 0, and the budget constraint must be binding. For i = 1, if x1* ≥ I1 > 0 we must have u1 = 0 < λ*p1, which then implies x1* = 0, which is a contradiction. x1* > 0 implies u1 = λ*p1 > 0 implying in turn x1* < I1. Fig. 2C.1 illustrates the solution. (c) Now let (I1, I2) be the bliss point, so that xi < Ii ⇒ ui > 0 and xi ≥ Ii ⇒ ui = 0. If the feasible set does not contain the bliss point, then we can show, as in ( b), that x i* < Ii, or neither good is consumed to satiation. On the other hand, if (I1, I2) is feasible then it satisfies the Kuhn-Tucker conditions. Thus, if (I1, I2) is not feasible, © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 8 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 2C.2 setting, say x1* = I1 must imply x2* < I2. But then, just as before, u2 = λ*p2 > 0 ⇒ λ* > 0 and so x1* = I1 > 0 is inconsistent with the Kuhn-Tucker conditions. On the other hand, if (I1, I2) is feasible and the consumer chooses it then u1 = u2 = 0 and so λ* = 0 and the budget constraint is not binding (though it may pass through (I1, I2)). Fig. 2C.2 illustrates. (d) If Ii is defined as the value of xi at which i changes from being a good to a bad, then in effect (I1, I2) is a bliss point and given that both prices are positive the analysis is just as in case (c). Turning now to question 4 of Exercise 2A, first recall that in the case of red and blue matches we have MRS21 = u1/u2 = 1. We can then distinguish three cases: (i) x1* > 0, x2* > 0. From the Kuhn-Tucker conditions this implies ui = λ*pi or u1/u2 = p1/p2 = 1. Thus a necessary condition for this solution possibility is that p1 = p2: both types of matches will be bought only if they have the same price. (ii) x1* > 0, x2* = 0, implying u1 = λ*p1, u2 ≤ λ*p2 or (u1/u2) ≥ p1/p2. Thus a necessary condition for this case is p1 ≤ p2: we have a solution in which, say only red matches are bought only if their price is no higher than that of blue matches. (iii) Similarly x1* = 0, x2* > 0 implies p1 ≥ p2. Thus we see that the solution depends essentially on the relative prices of the perfect substitutes as Fig. 2C.3 shows. In the case of left and right shoes the Kuhn-Tucker conditions cannot be used because the utility function is not everywhere differentiable. Fig. 2C.4 however illustrates the solution, which must always occur at a kink of an indifference curve if both prices are positive, whatever their price ratio. It will never be optimal to buy superfluous shoes. 3. (a) If ui > 0, a consumer always increases utility by moving from a point below the budget line to a point on it. So a utility maximizing consumer will always choose a point on his budget line. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 9 Fig. 2C.3 Fig. 2C.4 3. (b) At point x′ in text Fig. 2.8 the consumer can achieve higher indifference curves by moving rightward along the budget line, thus feasible consumption bundles exist which yield higher utility and x′ would not be chosen. 4. Let t be the amount of the transactions cost. (a) Lump sum transactions cost. The consumer can at most buy xi0 = (M − t)/pi. The budget constraint simply shifts inward in a parallel fashion. The transactions cost is equivalent to a reduction in income. (b) Proportional to price. If ti = ki pi, then the budget constraint becomes simply ∑(1 + ki)pi xi ≤ M, and we have a perfectly standard problem with effective prices (1 + ki)pi. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 10 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn (c) Decreasing with quantity bought. If ti = ti(xi) with ti′ < 0, the budget constraint is ∑(pi + ti(xi))xi ≤ M. In the 2-good case we then have that the slope of the budget constraint is given by dx2 ( p + t + x1t1′) =− 1 1 0 dx1 ( p2 + t2 + x2t2′ ) In this case we cannot say whether the budget constraint has a positive or negative slope at any point, without further specification of the functions ti(xi). (Note the contrast with the case in which ti′ > 0, i = 1, 2.) 5. The marginal utility of income is not uniquely defined, but rather changes with any positive monotonic transformation of the utility function. Thus if v = T[u], then ∂v ∂u = T′ ∂M ∂M where T′ > 0. This also implies that in ordinal utility theory we cannot talk of the “diminishing marginal utility of income” since ∂2 v ∂ 2 u ∂u = + T ′′ T ′ ∂M 2 ∂M 2 ∂M and so even if ∂2u/∂M 2 < 0, we can always choose a transformation T[.] with T″ > 0 sufficiently to make ∂2v/∂M 2 > 0. Exercise 2D 1. We keep the notation used in answering question 3 of Exercise 2B. Fig. 2D.1 carries out the analysis in terms of g, the amount of garbage removed. Note that ∂u/∂x = −∂u/∂g and so if x is a bad, with negative marginal utility, g is a good. In the analysis we assume that g is not a Giffen good, and we take a rise in the price of garbage removal. 2. We keep the notation used in the answer to question 2 of Exercise 2B. Fig. 2D.2 gives the answer, for a change in C and p0. Note that the effect of a change in C is zero if the consumer does not buy e, and is equivalent to an income effect if she does. A change in p0 affects demand both where e* < n and where e* > n. Supplementary question (i) Analyze the effect of a change in p1. Is this always zero if e* < n? 3. (a) In the case of red and blue matches, Fig. 2D.3 illustrates the Marshallian and Hicksian demands. With p2 given, the Marshallian demand curve for x1 is the vertical axis for p1 > p2, any value in [0, x10 ] for p1 = p2, and then the rectangular hyperbola given by x1 = M/p1, for p1 < p2. The Hicksian ‘demand curve’ on the other hand is a stepped function given by the vertical axis for p1 > p2, any value in [0, x10 ] for p1 = p2, and the vertical line corresponding to demand at x10 for p1 < p2. To see this, note that any budget line flatter than some indifference curve I0 which makes I0 the highest attainable indifference curve must touch it at x10 . Thus the substitution effect is zero for p1 > p2, © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 2D.1 Fig. 2D.2 Fig. 2D.3 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 11 12 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 2D.4 undefined at p1 = p2 and zero at p1 < p2. This implies that for p1 < p2, any increase in demand for x1 resulting from a fall in p1 is due solely to an income effect (the horizontal distance between the Marshallian and Hicksian demand curves). 3. (b) In the case of left and right shoes, Fig. 2D.4 illustrates the Marshallian and Hicksian demands. At all prices p1 with given p2 the Hicksian demand curve is vertical, indicating a zero substitution effect. Changing relative prices with the requirement that the consumer remains on the same indifference curve always results in the solution at the kink of the indifference curve. On the other hand the Marshallian demand curve has a negative slope, and so the entire demand increase for x1 following a fall in p1 is due to the income effect. 4. According to Hicks, real income is based on the achievable level of utility while for Slutsky real income is based on the bundle of goods that can be bought. An advantage of the Slutsky definition is that it is based on something observable (see also the theory of revealed preference in section 4A). In text Fig. 2.15, because of the convexity of the indifference curve, the reduction in money income required to cancel out the increase in real income in the Hicksian sense must be larger than that required to cancel out the increase in real income in Slutsky’s sense. Hence, if the good x1 is a normal good, the income effect is greater in the Hicksian case than in Slutsky’s case, and the Hicksian demand curve will lie further inside the Marshallian demand curve than does the Slutsky demand curve. Supplementary question (i) Carry out the analysis for text Fig. 2.15 in the case in which x1 is an inferior (though not Giffen) good. 5. We decompose the price effect into income and substitution effects because we want to be more precise about the circumstances under which the Marshallian demand curve will have a negative slope. Before this analysis, all we can say is that this slope may be positive, negative or zero. It appears that the theory has no predictive or explanatory © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 13 content and cannot be refuted because it is consistent with anything we might observe. After the analysis we can say that the theory predicts that normal goods will certainly have negatively sloped Marshallian demands, but that inferior goods may or may not have. The analysis also classifies the determinants of the steepness of the demand curve in terms of the closeness of substitutes and the strength of income effects. Finally it gives an explanation of the existence of Giffen goods, whose Marshallian demand curves have positive slopes. In the next chapter we consider a more precise statement of income and substitution effects in the form of the Slutsky equation, which is one of the most important equations in economic theory. 6. (a) Applying Lagrange’s method to the problem max u(x) s.t. px = M, where u(x) is the Cobb-Douglas function and p is a price vector, gives the n + 1 first-order conditions α i x1α . . . xiα −1 . . . x nα − λpi = 0 ∑pi xi − M = 0 1 i n i = 1, . . . , n Take any of the first n conditions, say the first, and divide through the remaining n − 1 to obtain α i x1α . . . xiα −1 . . . xnα p = i α 1 x1α −1 . . . xiα . . . xnα p1 1 i 1 n i i = 2, . . . , n, n and cancelling terms gives simply α i x1 pi = α 1 xi p1 i = 2, . . . , n α i p1 x1 α 1 pi i = 2, . . . , n. or xi = Then substituting into the budget constraint gives n α p αi pi i 1 x1 = p1 x1 1 + = M. α 1 pi i= 2 i= 2 α 1 n p1x1 + ∑ ∑ But n αi αi 1 = = ∑ ∑ α1 i= 2 α 1 i=1 α 1 n 1+ and so we have the Marshallian demand function x1 = α1M p1 . © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 14 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn But since the choice of x1 was completely arbitrary, we can write any demand function as xi = α i M , pi i = 1, . . . , n. The main properties of these demand functions are: (i) expenditure on each good, pixi, is a constant proportion of income, αiM, at all prices; (ii) the Marshallian demand curve is therefore a rectangular hyperbola with slope − a i M / pi2 and elasticity −1; (iii) the Engel curves are rays through the origin with slopes ∂xi /∂M = αi /pi and income elasticities (∂xi /∂M)(M/xi) = 1. There are no inferior goods; (iv) ∂xi /∂pj = 0, i ≠ j, and demands depend only on their own prices. Therefore there are no (Marshallian) substitutes and complements. Supplementary questions (i) Sketch a typical Marshallian demand curve and Engel curve for this case. (ii) On an indifference curve diagram, show what property (iv) must imply about the way in which an optimal point changes when the price of a good falls. 6. (b) Define Vi = xi − ki, i = 1, . . . , n. If we then define ? ≡ M − ∑ ni =1 piki (> 0 by assumption, otherwise no solution exists), we can then formulate the problem as max V1α V2α . . . Vnα s. t. 1 2 n Vi n ∑pV = ? i i i=1 which is identical in form to the problem for the Cobb-Douglas case. Thus, we can write the solution as Vi = αi?/pi, implying the Marshallian demand functions for the xi, xi = = n M − p j k j + ki pi j =1 αi ∑ (1 − αi)ki + α iM pi − αi ∑p k . pi j ≠ i j j The properties of these functions are then: (i) they are downward-sloping, since ∂xi /∂pi = −αi(M − ∑ j ≠ i p j k j )/ pi2 < 0. However, they are no longer rectangular hyperbolas with unit elasticity since we have pi xi = pi (1 − α i ) ki + α i M − pj kj , j≠i ∑ and so expenditure on xi is a linear increasing function of pi, and elasticity varies with pi; © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 15 (ii) Engel curves are again linear, since ∂xi /∂M = αi /pi, but they now have non-zero intercepts [(1 − αi)piki − αi∑j≠i pjkj]/pi. Moreover, in general these intercepts vary with i. There are still, however, no inferior goods, αi /pi > 0. (iii) We now have ∂xi /∂pj = −αikj /pi < 0, i, j = 1, . . . , n, i ≠ j. Thus all goods are (Marshallian) complements. Though this may be thought an improvement on the Cobb-Douglas case, where cross-effects are zero, restricting all goods to be complements is still not very reasonable. The constants ki are typically interpreted as subsistence level requirements for the goods. Thus Vi could be thought of as demand net of the subsistence requirement, ∑ ni =1 piki the expenditure required to buy the “subsistence bundle”, and ? is a kind of “discretionary income”, i.e. income over and above that required to buy the subsistence bundle. We can then interpret the cross-price elasticities ∂xi /∂pj as follows. An increase in pj causes an increase in the expenditure required to provide the subsistence level of good j, which in turn reduces discretionary income ? and so, since every good is normal, we have a reduction in demand for good i. If we totally differentiate the above expression for pixi we obtain d(pixi) = −αikjdpj i, j = 1, . . . , n, i ≠ j Thus expenditure on good i falls by the proportion αi of the amount by which ? falls, −kjdpj. With pi fixed, this implies the partial derivative given above. Supplementary question (i) Obtain an expression for the price elasticity of demand for this demand function and comment on its properties. 6. (c) Setting up the utility maximization problem as a Lagrangean yields the first-order conditions fi′( xi* ) − λpi = 0 i = 1, . . . , n n − ∑ p x* + M i i = 0. i=1 The precise forms of the Marshallian demand functions will of course depend on the functions fi(.), which we have not specified. However, we can carry out a general qualitative analysis of the properties of these functions quite easily. To do so, we use the comparative statics methods of Appendix I rather than the simpler duality methods of chapter 3. Also to simplify notation we assume just two goods, n = 2. Then, totally differentiating through the above first-order conditions and using Cramer’s Rule to solve for the demand derivatives gives ∂x1 − λp22 + x1 p1 f2′′ = ∂p1 D λp1 p2 + x2 p1 f2′′ ∂x1 = ∂p2 D © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 16 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn − p1 f2′′ ∂x1 = ∂M D − λp12 + x2 p2 f1′′ ∂x2 = D ∂p2 λp1 p2 + x1 p2 f1′′ ∂x2 = D ∂p1 ∂x2 − p2 f1′′ = ∂M D where D = −( p12 f2′′+ p22 f1′′) > 0 from the second-order conditions. From these three equations we can write the Slutsky equations λp2j ∂xi ∂x = − − xi i , ∂M D ∂pi ∂xi λp1 p2 ∂x = − xj i , ∂p j D ∂M i, j = 1, 2, i ≠ j. The first term in each of these equations is the substitution effect of a change in the corresponding price, the second term is the income effect. One interesting result of this functional form is that since λp1p2/D > 0, the goods must be what we call later Hicksian substitutes – the possibility of their being Hicksian complements is ruled out. Next note that if the fi′′ < 0, then each good is a normal good and must have a negatively sloped Marshallian demand. This assumption is that there is “diminishing marginal utility” for each good. Thus this assumption together with the additively separable form, implies that there are no inferior goods and so no Giffen goods. This was in fact the structure that underlay Marshall’s theory of demand, which ordinal utility theory supplanted. We cannot, however, make the assumption fi′′ < 0 in an ordinal theory, since it cannot survive a positive monotonic transformation of the utility function. What we can note is that the assumption that the utility function be strictly quasi-concave implies (see question 7 of Appendix B) that ( f1′)2 f2′′+ ( f2′)2 f1′′< 0 (since the cross-partial derivatives fij = 0 in the additively separable case). Indeed, this can be seen in precisely the condition that D > 0, if we substitute fi′ = λpi from the firstorder conditions. Now, the above condition does not imply fi′′ < 0, i = 1, 2. It would be possible to construct examples in which, say f1′′ < 0 and f2′′ > 0 were consistent with the condition. For this we would have to restrict the relative variations in f1′ and f2′, since the above condition implies 2 f ′ f1′′< − 1 f2′′ f2′ and this would have to hold over the whole domain of the function. Ruling out such cases and taking fi′′ < 0, i = 1, 2, we have that both goods are normal and so their Marshallian demands have negative slopes. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 17 Supplementary question (i) A consumer is said to have strongly or additively separable preferences if her utility function can be written u(x) = F fi ( xi ) i ∑ where F is any increasing function. Show that the Cobb-Douglas, Stone-Geary, and additively separable utility functions are all examples of strongly separable preferences. Exercise 2E 1. In (a) of Fig. 2E.1, the horizontal axis is at the level of the consumer’s initial endowment of x2, and she is a net seller of x1 and buyer of x2. In (b) of the figure the vertical axis is at the level of the consumer’s initial endowment of x1, and she is a net buyer of x1 and seller of x2. In each case we take an increase in p1 relative to p2, so that the budget constraint rotates clockwise through the initial endowment point. We also assume that each good is a normal good. Then we see that in case (b), the consumer’s net demand for x1 certainly falls, and the figure decomposes the overall change into an income and substitution effect as before. The analysis here is exactly similar to the case in which the consumer has money income. In (a) however, we see that the consumer’s net supply of x1 could increase or decrease, depending on the relative strengths of the income and substitution effects. Thus we have an ambiguous response to the price change in this case even though x1 is a normal good. The reason for the difference in the two cases is that the income effect of a price change depends on whether the consumer is a buyer or seller of the good. If she is a buyer, an increase in price reduces her real income, and so if the good is normal the income effect reinforces the substitution effect. On the other hand, if the consumer is a seller of the good, an increase in its price increases her real income, and so if the good is normal this will lead her to increase her consumption of it (reduce net supply). This income effect therefore goes in the opposite direction to the substitution effect, which is to reduce consumption of x1 (increase net supply) following the price increase. Supplementary questions (i) Work through the analysis of Fig. 2E.1 for the case of a price fall. (ii) Analyze the effects of a rise in price p1 when x1 is an inferior good. 2. The slope of the consumer’s offer curve at a point shows the consumer’s subjective marginal rate of exchange between the two goods. Thus a point on the curve, such as x′, shows that the consumer is prepared to exchange I1 − x1′ of x1 for x2′ − I2 of x2, to give an average rate of exchange of ( x2′ − I2)/(I1 − x1′ ). The slope of the offer curve at, say, x′, shows the relation between the extra bit of x1 she is prepared to trade for an extra bit of x2 given that she holds ( x1′, x2′ ) of the goods. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 18 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 2E.1 3. The offer curve is the locus of tangency points between a budget line, reflecting a particular price ratio, and an indifference curve. That is, it shows the (x1, x2)-pairs at each of these tangency points, since it shows the trades the consumer wishes to make. 4. (a) In a world of complete certainty, the model would be appropriate for a market in stocks and shares. Each participant in the market has given initial holdings of shares. Given the prices of shares, investors will adjust their portfolios, selling some stocks and buying others, until equilibrium is reached: a set of prices is achieved at which each investor is content to hold her particular portfolio and no further trades take place. However, the assumption of complete certainty is a very restrictive one and rules out many of the aspects of stock markets, for example, speculation and portfolio diversification, that we would really want to study. For analysis of this, see chapters 19, 21. 4. (b) A market in secondhand cars is again one which it is apt to treat as an “initial endowments” model. Consumers are initially endowed with a stock of used cars of varying vintages, qualities, types, etc., there is a flow of old cars out of the market and a flow of new cars onto the market. At various prices consumers could be buyers of used cars, sellers of used cars and buyers of new cars. In equilibrium, a set of prices prevails at which the total stock of new and used cars is held by consumers with no-one wishing to make further trades. However, such a static equilibrium is likely to last for only a short time, because of depreciation (change in quality) of used cars and the continual flow of new cars with changes in style, design, performance etc. Thus trading in the car market is likely to be a virtually continuous activity. 4. (c) This is a special case of the general model in which the endowment of one good, bread, is zero while that of the other is positive. Thus the consumer will almost certainly be a buyer in the market for bread and a “seller of leisure time”, or to put it more conventionally, a supplier of labour. The price of leisure time is the wage rate, since taking an hour of leisure means giving up the hourly wage that could have been earned by working instead. If (contrary to general usage) we measure x2 on the horizontal axis and x1 on the vertical axis, and define the price ratio as w/p1, where w is the wage rate © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 19 and p1 is the price of bread, then Fig. 2E.1 analyzes the supply of labour (I2 − x2) in exchange for bread, and shows the ambiguous effect of an increase in the wage rate. A much fuller analysis of this model is carried out in section 4C below. Supplementary question (i) Explain why the analysis of Fig. 2E.1 implies that the supply of labour may increase or decrease as the real wage increases. Exercise A1 1. Let I2 be the subsistence level for x2. Then the consumer’s demand functions are now: x1 = (M − p2I2)/p1; x2 = I2. That is, the consumer with lexicographic preferences will buy only the minimum amount of x2 he needs for subsistence and will spend the rest of his income on x1. 2. Suppose now there are no minimum subsistence levels but there is a satiation level for x1 denoted V1. Then, assuming M/p1 > V1, his demand functions are: x1 = V1; x2 = (M − p1V1)/p2, a vertical line and a rectangular hyperbola respectively. (Incidentally, we should not really have referred to the “marginal utility of x2” in this question since the utility function does not exist for this ordering.) 3. For n goods, the statement of the lexicographic ordering is for any two unequal bundles x′ = ( x1′, . . . , xn′ ), x″ = ( x1′′, . . . , xn′′): x1′ > x1′′ ⇒ x′ Ɑ x″ x1′ = x1′′ and x2′ > x2′′ ⇒ x′ Ɑ x″ ... ... ... x1′ = x1′′, x2′ = x2′′, . . . , xn′ −1 = xn′′−1 and xn′ > xn′′ ... ... ⇒ x′ Ɑ x″. Without subsistence and satiation levels, the demand functions would be: x1 = M/p1; x2 = . . . = xn = 0. The consumer spends all his income on the first good. With subsistence but without satiation levels, the demand functions would be: x1 = (M − ∑ in=1 piIi)/p1; xi = Ii, i = 2, . . . , n, where Ii is the subsistence level for good i. Without subsistence but with satiation levels the demand functions would be: xi = Vi, i = 1, . . . , k − 1; xk = (M − ∑ ik=−11 piVi)/pk, k = 1, . . . , n. Here, Vi is the subsistence level for good i and k is the first value of i such that ∑ ik=1 piVi ≥ M. 4. We have to confess that we find lexicographic preferences implausible as a general formulation of preferences both for individual goods and for groups of goods. The reasonable observation that one must have minimum levels of water, food, sleep (“leisure”) and shelter to survive can be handled by introducing subsistence levels into the standard framework set out in this chapter. That is, we define a consumer’s consumption set C as the set of consumption bundles it is physically (as opposed to economically) feasible for the consumer to choose, and we could then define C = {x ∈ R+n | x ≥ I} © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 20 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn where I = (I1, . . . , In) is a subsistence vector. Consumer theory can only then apply to those people whose consumption sets have a non-empty intersection with their budget sets, i.e. who can literally afford to live. On the other hand lexicographic preferences together with subsistence levels are appropriate for those individuals with strong addictions – say to alcohol or hard drugs. Otherwise evidence suggests that consumers have preferences which allow them to trade off among goods. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 21 Chapter 3 Consumer Theory: Duality Exercise 3A 1. Let x1* and x2* be the Hicksian demand functions, then xi* , i = 1, 2, are the solutions to the maximization problem min p1x1 + p2x2 x1 , x 2 s.t. E = x1a x2b , a + b = 1. With λ as the Lagrange multiplier, the Lagrange function is L = p1x1 + p2x2 + λ(E − x1a x2b ) and so the first-order conditions are Lx = p1 − λax1a −1 x2b = 0, (3.1) Lx = p2 − λbx1a x2b−1 = 0, (3.2) Lλ = E − x1a x2b = 0. (3.3) 1 2 (3.1) and (3.2) give p1 ax2 = p2 bx1 ⇒ x2 = p1 b x1 p2 a (3.4) substitute (3.4) into (3.3) p b E = x 1 x1 p2 a b a 1 b p b = 1 x1 p2 a −b p b ⇒ x1* = E 1 p2 a −b and by symmetry, −a −a p a x2* = E 2 . p1 b (3.5) © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 21 22 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Let m(p1, p2, u) be the expenditure function; m(p1, p2, u) = p1 x1* + p2 x2* p −a a −a p −b a b 1 = p1 E + p2 E 2 p1 b p2 b b a a = Ep11−b p2b + Ep21−a p1a b b b a a = Ep1a p2b + Ep2b p1a b b −a −a a b a − a a b = + p1 p2 E b b Now v = u2 = ( x1a x2b )2 = x12a x22b . min ∑pixi H = x12a x22b , s.t. a+b=1 L = p1x1 + p2x2 + λ ( H − x12a x22b ) Lx = p1 − 2aλ x12a −1 x22b = 0 (3.6) Lx = p2 − 2bλ x12a x22b−1 = 0 (3.7) Lλ = H − x12a x22b = 0 (3.8) 1 2 Dividing (3.6) by (3.7) gives p1 ax2 = p2 bx1 ⇒ x2 = p1 b x1 p2 a just as in (3.4) above. Substitute (3.4) in (3.8) 2b p b H = x 1 x12b p2 a 2a 1 2b p b = 1 x12 p2 a since a + b = 1 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 23 −2 b p x12 = H 1 b p2 a , −b p b x1* = H 1 . p2 a 1 2 By symmetry, p a x2* = H 2 p1 b −a 1 2 Substituting in the expenditure function yields p b m(p1, p2, v) = p1 H 1 p2 a 1 2 −b p a + p2 H 2 p1 b −a 1 2 Simplifying yields a b a − a m(p1, p2, v)* = + H p1a p2b b b 1 2 Now substituting for H = u gives 1 2 a b a − a m(p1, p2, v)* = + up1a p2b b b as before. Then we have the derivatives: a b a − a a b ∂m( p1 , p2 , u) = + p1 p2 ∂u b b −a b 1 a a ∂m( p1 , p2 , u) − = + p1a p2b v 2 b b ∂v 1 2 Thus although the values of the expenditure function and the Hicksian demands are unaffected by the transformation of the utility function, the measure of the ‘marginal cost of utility’, ∂m/∂u, which is the reciprocal of the marginal utility of income, ∂u/∂m, does depend on the specific utility function used. You should confirm for the transformation used here that: ∂m ∂m dv . = ∂u ∂v du 2. For perfect complements, the indifference curves take the form shown in Fig. 3A.1. As the figure shows x1* = x2* . The equilibrium must satisfy the budget constraint p1 x1* + p2 x2* = M and so M = x1* = x2* = u. p1 + p2 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 24 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 3A.1 Hence, u* = M p1 + p2 is the indirect utility function. Inverting the indirect utility function gives the expenditure function m(p, u) = (p1 + p2)u. In the perfect substitute case, u = ax1 + bx2. As the figure shows, in maximizing utility we have two main cases determined by the relative slopes of the budget line and the linear indifference curves (where these slopes are equal the solution is at any point on the budget constraint). (a) a b a p1 or equivalently . > > b p2 p1 p2 Then we have a corner solution with x1 = M/p1, x2 = 0. Then u = aM/p1 > bM/p2. (b) b a p1 a . > or equivalently > p2 b p2 p1 Then we have a corner solution with x2 = M/p2, x1 = 0. Then u = bM/p2 > aM/p1. These results allow us to write the indirect utility function as aM bM a b , u = max = M. max , . p1 p2 p1 p2 Inverting this gives the expenditure function p p M = u min 1 , 2 a b © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 25 Supplementary question (i) Obtain the above result on the expenditure function in the case of perfect substitutes by solving the expenditure minimization problem. [Hint: use Fig. 3A.1 and obtain the values for M in cases (a) and (b).] 3. (a) If u(x) is strictly quasi-concave, there is a unique solution x* to the problem max u(x) s.t. px = m, and we assume at this solution every xi* > 0. Moreover, there is a unique solution V to the problem min px s.t. u(x) = u*, and we also have that u(x*) = u* = u(V). Suppose that x* ≠ V. Then px* ≠ pV. Either px* > pV. But given the strict quasi-concavity of u, this implies there exists I = kx* + (1 − k)V, k ∈ (0, 1) such that u(I) > u(x*) and pI < px* = M, thus contradicting the optimality of x*. Or px* < pV. But this immediately contradicts the optimality of V since u(x*) = u* and so x* is feasible for the expenditure minimization problem. Thus the assumption x* ≠ V leads to a contradiction and we have x* = V. 3. (b) The first-order conditions for the utility maximization and expenditure minimization problems are, respectively ui(x*) − λ*pi = 0 px* = M i = 1, . . . , n pi − µ*ui(V) = 0 u(V) = u i = 1, . . . , n. But we just saw that if u(V) = u(x*), then V = x*, and so: λ* = ui(x*)/pi, µ* = pi/ui(x*), ⇒ λ* = 1/µ*. 4. First define: Vi ≡ xi − ci, i = 1, 2. Then note that M = p1x1 + p2x2 = p1V1 + p2V2 + p1c1 + p2c2 We can then write the problem as min p1V1 + p2V2 + p1c1 + p2c2 V1, V 2 s.t. V1a V 2b = u This gives the first-order conditions p1 − aµ V1a −1 V2b = 0 p2 − bµ V1a V 2b−1 = 0 V1a V 2b = u and Hicksian demand functions: V1 = (a/b)b(p1/p2)−bu V2 = (a/b)−a(p2/p1)−au or © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 26 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn x1 = (a/b)b(p1/p2)−bu + c1 x2 = (a/b)−a(p2/p1)−au + c2 Substituting into the expression for M gives the expenditure function: M = [(a/b)b + (a/b)−a] p1a p2b u + p1c1 + p2c2. The difference to the expenditure function in question one is the term p1c1 + p2c2, which can be interpreted as the cost of the required subsistence bundle, a kind of ‘fixed cost of survival’. 5. Suppose that the optimal bundle has positive consumption of both goods. The Lagrangean is f(x1) + x2 + µ[u − p1x1 − p2x2] and the first order conditions on x1 and x2 are f′(x1) − µp1 = 0 1 − µp2 = 0 From the condition on x2 we can substitute 1/p2 for µ to write the condition on x2 as f′(x1) = p1/p2. Thus the Hicksian demand for good 1 depends only on relative prices and not on the required utility level: x1 = h1(p1/p2). Any increase in the required utility level is met entirely by an increase in x2. Using the constraint, the Hicksian demand for good 2 is x2 = u − f(h1(p1/p2)) = h2(u, p1/p2). The expenditure function is m(u, p) = p1h1(p1/p2) + p2[u − f(h1(p1/p2))] The slope of an indifference curve is dx2 = −f′(x1) dx1 so that the indifference curves have the same slope along vertical lines in (x1, x2) space. Supplementary question (i) After reading section 3B, derive the indirect utility function and the Marshallian demands and show that good 1 has a zero income elasticity of demand so that all additional income is spent on good 2. Exercise 3B 1. The Hicksian demand function is derived from the problem min ∑px i i s.t. u(x1, x2, . . . , xn) = E i yielding the first-order conditions: © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn pi ui ( x*) = pn un ( x*) 27 i = 1, 2, . . . , n − 1, u(x*) = E. If the price vector is multiplied by k > 0, the conditions become kpi u ( x*) = i kpn un ( x*) which clearly will leave the solution unchanged. Thus, xi* = Hi(p1, . . . , pn, u) = Hi(kp1, . . . , kpn, u) and the Hicksian demand function is homogeneous of degree zero in prices. Identifying Hi with the function f in Euler’s Theorem and pj with xi we have n ∂H i j =1 j ∑ ∂p p = 0. j 2. From question 6(a) of Exercise 2D we have that the consumer’s Marshallian demands are: x1 = aM/p1; x2 = (1 − a)M/p2. Substituting into the utility function gives a aM (1 − a ) M u= p2 p1 1− a = a a (1 − a )1−a p1− a p2− (1−a ) M Roy’s Identity says that in general: ∂u = −λxi. ∂pi Then, (a) ∂ [a a (1 − a )1−a p1− a p2− (1−a ) M ] = − a 1+a (1 − a )1−a p1− (1+a ) p2− (1−a ) M ∂p1 (b) From the first-order conditions we find λ = ax1a −1 x21 − a / p1 So, −λx1 = − ax1a x21−a / p1 . (c) Given the indirect utility function, we can use (a) to write: ∂u au =− ∂p1 p1 and given the direct utility function we can use (b) to write −λx1 = − au p1 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 28 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 3. u = a a (1 − a )1−a p1− a p2− (1−a ) M . Inverting this gives the expenditure function Alternatively, solving the expenditure-minimization problem gives: M = m(p, u) = a−a(1 − a)−(1−a) p1a p2(1−a ) v p x1 = 1 p2 − ( 1− a ) a 1− a 1− a u −a a p a x2 = 1 u p2 1 − a and so we have the expenditure function: m(p, u) = p1x1 + p2x2 p = p1 1 p2 − ( 1− a ) a 1− a 1− a a −a p a u + p2 1 u p2 1 − a a 1−a a − a = p p u + . 1 − a 1 − a a 1 1− a 2 We therefore need to show that: a 1 − a 1− a a + 1 − a −a = a−a(1 − a)a−1 Now: −a a a + 1 = a−a(1 − a)a(1 − a)−1 1 − a 1 − a = a−a(1 − a)a−1 as required. 4. (a) Given the Marshallian demand functions xi = Di(p, M) i = 1, . . . , n. the adding up property implies ∑ p D (p, M) = M. i i (3.9) i Allowing pj to change with M constant, differentiating through (3.9) gives Dj(p, M) + ∂Di ∑ p ∂p = 0 j = 1, . . . , n. i i (3.10) j as required. Differentiating through (3.9) with respect to M holding prices constant gives ∂Di ∑ p ∂M = 1 i i as required. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 (3.11) Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 29 4. (b) Multiply through the jth equation in (3.10) by pj /M, and each term pi∂Di /∂pj by xi /xi (= 1) to obtain p ∂Di p j D j ( p, M ) si e ij = 0 pi xi j + = sj + xi ∂p j M i i ∑ ∑ as required. Multiply through (3.11) by xiM/xiM to obtain M ∂Di ∑ p x x ∂M = ∑ s η = 1 i i i i i i i as required. 4. (c) Euler’s Theorem states that for a function f(x1, . . . , xn), if f is homogeneous of degree zero then ∑ f x = 0. i i i We know that the Marshallian demand functions are homogeneous of degree zero in prices and income, so p1 ∂Di ∂Di ∂Di ∂Di + p2 + . . . + pn + M =0 ∂p1 ∂p2 ∂pn ∂M or ∂Di n ∂Di ∑ p ∂p + ∂M M = 0 i = 1, . . . , n. j j =1 j Dividing through by xi gives ∑e + η = 0 ij i j as required. 4. (d) From the symmetry property we derive immediately: ∂D j ∂pi ∂D j ∂Di ∂Di + xj − xi . ∂p j ∂M ∂M = Multiplying through by pi and summing over i gives ∂D j ∂Di ∂Di ∂D j ∑ p ∂p = ∑ p ∂p + x ∑ p ∂M − ∂M ∑ p x . i i i j i i i i i j i i Using the Engel aggregation result, homogeneity and the fact that ∑i pi xi = M gives ∂D j ∂D j ∂Di ∂D j ∑ p ∂p = ∑ p ∂p + x − M ∂M = − M ∂M i i i i i j j © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 30 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn and so we have the Cournot aggregation result ∂Di ∑ p ∂p + x = 0. i j i j 5. The Slutsky equations for goods i and j are ∂Di ∂H i ∂Di = − xj ∂p j ∂p j ∂M ∂D j ∂pi = ∂H j − xi ∂pi ∂D j ∂M where ∂Hi/∂pj = ∂Hj/∂pi by symmetry. Call this term S. Then if ∂Di/∂pj < 0 (complements) and ∂Dj/∂pi > 0 (substitutes), we must have xi ∂D j ∂M < S < xj ∂Di ∂M as the necessary and sufficient condition for this to happen. If S < 0 (Hicksian complements) then good j must be inferior, good i could be normal or, if inferior, have a sufficiently smaller (in absolute value) income effect than j. If S > 0 (Hicksian substitutes) then i must be normal and j could be inferior or normal with a sufficiently smaller income effect. Exercise 3C 1. In Fig. 3.6 of the text, simply interpret B as the initial equilibrium and A as the postprice change equilibrium. Then EV in the figure becomes CV and CV becomes EV. We make the same reinterpretation of the areas under the Hicksian demand curves in Fig. 3.6(b). If u1 is now the initial level of utility, and u0 the final level, with p1 = ( p11 , p2 , . . . , pn ) the initial price vector and p0 = ( p10 , p2 , . . . , pn ) the final price vector, we now have p ∂m dp1 = H1 ( p, u1 )dp1 p ∂p p 1 p10 ∫ EV = m(p0, u0) − m(p1, u0) = p ∂m dp1 = H1 ( p, u0 )dp1 p ∂p p 1 ∫ 1 1 p10 1 1 ∫ 0 1 CV = m(p0, u1) − m(p1, u1) = ∫ 1 1 0 1 1 1 In terms of the expression of CV and EV in terms of indirect utilities, we now have that they must respectively satisfy u*(p1, M0) = u*(p0, M0 + CV) = u1 u*(p1, M0 − EV) = u*(p0, M0) = u0 (compare these to [C.1] and [C.2] in the text). Note that here, because we wish to stress the relation between CV or EV and the area under the Hicksian demand curve, we have defined them so that they are always positive, regardless of the direction of the price change. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 31 2. (a) A contour of the utility function is defined by E = f(x1) + x2 Differentiating totally gives f′(x1)dx1 + dx2 = 0 ⇒ dx2 = −f′(x1). dx1 Thus the slope of the indifference curve depends only on x1. For given x1, every indifference curve has the same slope for all values of x2. 2. (b) Solving max f(x1) + x2 x1 , x 2 s.t. p1x1 + p2x2 = M gives the first-order conditions f′(x1) − λp1 = 0 1 − λp2 = 0 p1x1 + p2x2 − M = 0 For x1 we have f′(x1) = p1/p2 ⇒ x1 = f′−1(p1/p2) ≡ φ(p1/p2). Then substituting into the budget constraint we have x2 = M/p2 − φ(p1/p2)/p2 This gives the indirect utility function u = f[φ(p1/p2)] + M/p2 − φ(p1/p2)/p2 and the expenditure function M = φ(p1/p2) + p2[u − f[φ(p1/p2)]]. Differentiating gives the Hicksian demand function for x1 ∂M = φ′/p2 − f′φ′ = H1(p1, p2). ∂p1 Note that this Hicksian demand function is independent of the utility level. For given p2 (which could always be set equal to 1) there is only one Hicksian demand curve, whatever the utility level. 2. (c) Since the demand function x1 = φ(p1/p2) does not contain M as an argument, we must have ∂x1/∂M = 0 and so x1 has zero income elasticity. To show that CV and EV are identical for any price change from p10 to p11 we can use the expenditure function just derived to write: © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 32 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn CV = φ ( p10 / p2 ) + p2 [u 0 − f [φ ( p10 / p2 )]] − φ ( p11 / p2 ) − p2 [u0 − f [φ(p1/p2)]] EV = φ ( p10 / p2 ) + p2 [u1 − f [φ ( p10 / p2 )]] − φ ( p11 / p2 ) − p2 [u1 − f [φ(p1/p2)]] which are identical when the terms in u have been cancelled. In other words since there is only one Hicksian demand curve whatever the level of utility the area under it between two prices will be the same whatever the level of utility. 2. (d) From the first order conditions we have the marginal utility of income λ = 1/p2, and so ∂λ/∂p1 = 0. Thus condition [C.8] of the text is satisfied and the Marshallian consumer surplus is an appropriate money measure of a utility change. In fact, as we may expect from the result in 2(c), the Hicksian and Marshallian demand functions for x1 are identical in this case. To show this we can use Roy’s Identity, which gives ∂u φ ( p1 / p2 ) . = λx1 = − p2 ∂p1 Differentiating the indirect utility function gives ∂u = f′φ ′/p2 − φ ′/ p22 = −φ/p2 ∂p1 Then, multiplying this through by −p2 gives φ′/p2 − f′φ ′ = φ which, recalling the expression for H1 in (c) above, gives the result. 3. From our earlier results on the Cobb-Douglas case (question 6(a) of exercise 2D) we have the demand functions x1 = M 2 p1 and x2 = M 2 p2 Hence the indirect utility function is 1/ 2 M M v* = 2 p1 2 p2 = 1/ 2 1 −1/ 2 −1/ 2 p1 p2 M 2 So, v0 = 1 (1)−1/2(1)−1/2100 2 = 50 −1 / 2 1 1 v = (1)−1/2100 2 4 1 = (2)(100) = 100 2 1 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 33 The expenditure function is M = 2vp11 / 2 p21 / 2 and CV = m(p0, v0) − m(p1, v0) = 2v0 [( p10 )1 / 2 p21 / 2 − ( p11 )1 / 2 p21 / 2 ] = 50 EV = m(p0, v1) − m(p1, v1) = 2v1 [( p10 )1 / 2 p21 / 2 − ( p11 )1 / 2 p21 / 2 ] = 100. The first-order conditions in this example yield λ= x2 x1 = . p1 p2 So, ∂λ/∂p1 = − x2 / p12 ≠ 0; ∂λ/∂p2 = − x1 / p22 ≠ 0 and so condition [C.8] is not satisfied. Thus the Marshallian consumer surplus is not a valid (exact) measure of the change in utility for these preferences. 4. (a) Using the Slutsky equation, the requirement that the Marshallian cross-price effects are equal can be written as ∂D j ∂Di = Hij − Dj DiM = Hji − Di DjM = ∂p j ∂pi where Hij, Hji are the cross-substitution effects and DiM, DjM the effect of income on demand. Since cross-substitution effects are equal, equality of Marshallian cross-price effects implies Dj DiM = Di DjM ⇒ DiM M D jM M = Di Dj so that all goods must have the same income elasticity of demand: η1 = . . . = ηn = η. But from the Engel aggregation property of Marshallian demands (question 4(b) of Exercise 3B) 1= ∑ s η = ∑ s η = η∑ s = η. i i i i i i i 4. (b) The expression for CV and EV in terms of the expenditure function in [C.3] and [C.5] are well-defined since the expenditure function is well-defined. Alternatively, the condition for path-independence of the integrals in [C.3] and [C.5] when more than one price changes is that the cross-effects of prices on the Hicksian demands are equal and this is ensured by the equality of cross-substitution effects. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 34 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Exercise 3D 1. To simplify notation assume only 3 commodities, x1, x2, x3 and that p2 = kp20 , p3 = kp30 , so that p2/p3 = p20 / p30 , a constant. k itself may vary. We choose as our composite commodity xc = p20 x2 + p30 x3 and the price of this commodity is k. The idea is that we can analyze demands x1, xc in terms of p1 and k. Consider the expenditure function m(p1, p2, p3, u) derived in the usual way. Since pi = kpi0 , i = 2, 3, we can re-write this as m(p1, p2, p3, u) ≡ m(p1, kp20 , kp30 , u) ≡ µ(p1, k, u) and we can work with µ as the expenditure function for the composite commodity case. Thus we have ∂µ ∂m ∂p2 ∂m ∂p3 = p20 x2 + p30 x3 = xc = + ∂k ∂p2 ∂k ∂p3 ∂k using Shephard’s Lemma. Thus xc is the composite commodity corresponding to price k. The expenditure function µ can be taken as fully describing preferences in the case where we treat x2 and x3 as a composite commodity. To show that µ has the properties of an expenditure function (we just showed that it satisfies Shephard’s lemma) first note that it is concave in p1, k. To see this, let L = λk′ + (1 − λ)k″ 0≤λ≤1 for values k′, k″ of k, and let pi′ = k′pi0 , pi′′ = k′′pi0 i = 1, 2. Now concavity of the expenditure function m implies m(F1, F2, F3, u) ≥ λm( p1′, p2′ , p3′ , u) + (1 − λ ) m( p1′′, p2′′, p3′′, u) where Fi = λpi′ + (1 − λ ) p1′′, i = 1, 2, 3. Then for i = 2, 3, Fi = λki′ pi0 + (1 − λ) k′′pi0 = Lpi0 . Thus m(F1, Lp20 , Lp30 , u) ≥ λm( p1′, k ′p20 , k ′p30 , u) + (1 − λ ) m( p1′′, k′′p20 , k′′p30 , u) implying, given the definition of µ: µ(F1, L, u) ≥ λµ( p1′, k ′, u) + (1 − λ ) µ( p1′′, k′′, u) and so µ is concave. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 35 To show that ∂µ/∂k ≥ 0, we note simply ∂µ ∂m 0 ∂m 0 = p2 + p3 ≥ 0 ∂k ∂p2 ∂p3 by the properties of the expenditure function m. Finally, µ is clearly homogeneous of degree one in p1, k, since for α > 0 u(α p1, α k, u) ≡ m(α p1, α kp20 , α kp30 , u) ≡ m(α p1, α p2, α p3, u) and so the result follows from the linear homogeneity in prices of the expenditure function m. 2. This function is the constant elasticity of substitution (CES) function, which is also widely used as a production function. In that context it is analyzed quite fully in questions 6, 7 and 8 of Exercise 5A. Here we note that it is a homothetic function: in fact, it is the basic form for the class of homothetic functions which have constant elasticity of substitution (and which contains the Cobb-Douglas function as a special case). Recall from [D.10] of the text the definition of a homothetic function: any positive monotonic transformation of a linear homogeneous function is homothetic. Then note that: − β1 f(x1, x2) = [α 1 x1− β + α 2 x2− β ] is linear homogeneous, since for k > 0, − β1 f(kx1, kx2) = [α1(kx1)−β + α2(kx2)−β ] − β1 = [k−β (α 1 x1− β + α 2 x2− β )] = k (α 1 x1− β + αx2− β ) − β1 = kf(x1, x2) Since the function is linear homogeneous then trivially it is homothetic, but then by defining any differentable transformation − β1 T [(α 1 x1− β + α 2 x2− β ) ] with T′ > 0 we obtain the entire family of homothetic utility functions with constant elasticity of substitution. 3. From the solution to question 4 of Exercise 3A we have the expenditure function for the Stone-Geary utility function as m(p1, p2, u) = Ap1α p21 −α u − p1c1 − p2c2 where A ≡ ((α /(1 − α))1−α + (α /(1 − α))−α). Then simply define b(p) ≡ Ap1α p21−α and a(p) ≡ −(p1c1 + p2c2). 4. We shall answer this question for the case in which the utility function is written u = u1(x1) + u2(x2) + . . . + un(xn) ui′ > 0, ui′′ < 0, all i © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 36 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn (for the more general but complicated case of any positive monotonic transformation of this function see A. Deaton and J. Muellbauer, Economics and Consumer Behaviour, Cambridge, 1980, Chapter 5). Maximizing u subject to the constraint ∑pixi = m gives the first-order conditions ui′( xi* ) = λpi i = 1, . . . , n m − ∑ pi xi* = 0. Write the Slutsky equation for this model as: ∂x ∂xi = sij − x j i ∂p j ∂m i, j = 1, . . . , n where sij is the Hicksian or compensated demand derivative. The first step in the proof is to show that sij = µ ∂xi ∂x j ∂m ∂m i, j = 1, . . . , n, i≠j for some given µ > 0 independent of i and j. If we then show that ∂xi/∂m > 0 for all i, this immediately establishes that sij > 0 for all i, j, implying that all pairs of goods are Hicksian substitutes. First, differentiate through the first-order conditions for the ith good with respect to m and to pj, to obtain: ui′′ ∂xi ∂λ = pi ∂m ∂m ui′′ ∂xi ∂λ = pi ∂p j ∂p j i = 1, . . . , n. Use the second equation to solve for ui′′/ pi and substitute into the first to obtain ∂λ ∂λ /∂p j ∂xi = ∂m ∂xi /∂p j ∂m i = 1, . . . , n. Since an exactly similar equation holds for good j, we have ∂λ /∂p j ∂xi ∂λ ∂λ /∂pi ∂x j = = ∂m ∂x j /∂pi ∂m ∂xi /∂p j ∂m i, j = 1, . . . , n, Thus, we can write ∂x j ∂λ ∂xi ∂xi ∂λ ∂x j = ∂p j ∂pi ∂m ∂pi ∂p j ∂m i, j = 1, . . . , n, i ≠ j. We now make use of the following facts: ∂2 u ∂2 u ∂ ∂λ = = = ( − λxi ) ∂pi ∂m ∂m∂pi ∂m ∂pi ∂λ ∂x = − λ i + xi ∂m ∂m i = 1, . . . , n, © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 i ≠ j. Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 37 and similarly for ∂λ/∂pj. Then, using the Slutsky equations to substitute for ∂xi /∂pj and ∂xj /∂pi, and the above fact to substitute for ∂λ/∂pi and ∂λ/∂pj, we obtain ∂x ∂λ ∂x ∂x ∂xi ∂λ ∂x ∂x + λ i j = s ji − xi j x j +λ j i . sij − x j xi ∂m ∂m ∂m ∂m ∂m ∂m ∂m ∂m We leave it to the reader to check the tedious details of expanding the brackets, cancelling terms and regrouping, but if you do this correctly you will obtain: sij ∂x ∂λ x j ∂x ∂x ∂x ∂x j − x j i = −λ xi j − x j i i xi ∂m ∂m ∂m ∂m ∂m ∂m ∂m (remember sij = sji) and so, defining µ ≡ −λ/(∂λ/∂m) we have ∂xi ∂x j ∂m ∂m sij = µ i, j = 1, . . . , n, i≠j as required. Note that we require that ∂λ/∂m(= ∂2u/∂m2) < 0, which cannot hold for ordinal utility functions in general, but does follow from the special form of the utility function taken here, since from the first-order conditions we have ui′′ = pi∂λ/∂m and ui′′ < 0 by the assumed form of the utility function. Next, we need to make use of Euler’s Theorem. This states that if the function f(x1, . . . , xn) is homogeneous of degree zero, then ∑ fi xi = 0. Now the Hicksian demand functions Hi(p, u) are homogeneous of degree zero in prices, and so we have the n equations ∑ (∂H /∂p )p = ∑ s p = 0 i j j ij j j i, j = 1, . . . , n. j Using the expression derived earlier for sij (i ≠ j) and writing out this equation for any one i gives sii pi + ∂xi ∂x j ∂x j ∂xi ∑ µ ∂m ∂m = s p + µ ∂m ∑ ∂m ii i j≠i j≠i = sii pi + µ ∂xi ∂xi 1 − pi ∂m ∂m =0 where we have used pi ∂x ∂xi pj j = 1 + ∂m j ≠ i ∂m ∑ from the budget constraint. Then we can solve for sii = − µ ∂xi ∂xi 1 − pi pi ∂m ∂m © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 38 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Now we know that sii < 0 and µ > 0. But this then rules out the possibility that ∂xi/∂m < 0, since if that were true the above would give sii > 0. Thus for this special utility function only normal goods are possible. In that case of course every sij > 0 (i ≠ j), and only Hicksian substitutes are possible. Note another implication of this special functional form: the Hicksian demand derivatives sii, sij (i ≠ j), as well as the Marshallian demand derivatives, can all be estimated simply from knowledge of the income derivatives ∂xi /∂m. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 39 Chapter 4 Further Models of Consumer Behaviour Exercise 4A 1. The preference assumptions of section 2A are: Completeness Transitivity Reflexivity Non-satiation Continuity Strict convexity Non-satiation will imply the first behavioural assumption that the consumer spends all her income. The second behavioural assumption is that only one commodity bundle x is chosen by the consumer for each price and income situation. This implies there cannot be straight stretches of indifference curves, which is ensured by the assumption of strict convexity. The third behavioural assumption is that there exists one and only one price and income combination at which each bundle is chosen. This rules out kinked indifference curves or curves that are not continuous. The fourth behavioural assumption, that of consistency, is implied by transitivity of preferences. 2. If MI = p1 x1 p1 x 0 < = LP p0 x 0 p0 x 0 this means that at prices in the current period the bundle x1 is cheaper than the bundle x0. We know the consumer spends all her income. The fact that she chose x1 in the current period merely reveals that she could not afford x0, it does not say anything about her preferences. Similarly, MI = p1 x1 p1 x1 > = PP p 0 x 0 p 0 x1 implies that 1/(p0x0) > 1/(p0x1) or p0x0 < p0x1. The fact that an individual chose x0 at prices p0 is an indication that she cannot afford x1 at the base period prices. Again, we © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 39 40 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 4A.1 Fig. 4A.2 learn nothing about her preferences over x0 and x1. In Fig. 4A.1 the consumer is observed to choose x1 when the budget line is NN which represents income M1 and prices p1. This tells us nothing about whether the bundle x1 is preferred to x0 as x0 is not affordable at prices p1 and income M1. In this case p1x1 < p1x0 so that MI = p1 x 1 p1 x 0 < = LP. p0 x 0 p0 x 0 In Fig. 4A.2 the individual chooses x0 on budget line MM which represents prices p0 and income M0. Since x1 is not affordable we do not know what her preferences are for x1 versus x0. Since p0x0 < p0x1 then MI = p1 x1 p1 x1 > = PP p 0 x 0 p 0 x1 and we know nothing about which bundle is preferred. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 41 3. The MI and LP indices are calculated using average consumption bundles for the group of consumers, p1 n MI = 0 p n ∑x s1 ∑x s0 1 ∑x s0 ∑x s0 p n LP = 0 p n s s s s Here, n is the number of consumers in the group. The n’s can be cancelled so that this weighting scheme is no different than using the sum of consumption bundles. Conditions (a) or (b) given in the text must hold for MI > LP to imply that all consumers are better off. 4. The Paasche price index for one consumer is PP = p1 x1 . p 0 x1 For a group of individuals we can use the sum of consumption bundles, PP = p1 ∑ s x s1 p 0 ∑ s x s1 MI = p1 ∑ s x s1 . p0 ∑ s x s 0 Assume MI < PP and divide both sides by p1 ∑s xs1 to give 1/(p0 ∑sxs0) < 1/(p0 ∑s xs1) or p0 ∑s xs0 > p0 ∑s xs1. Taking the case of two consumers a and b, we can write p0xa0 + p0xb0 ≥ p0xa1 + p0xb1. (4.1) This condition implies that at least one of p0xa0 > p0xa1 or p0xb0 > p0xb1 holds, but both inequalities do not necessarily hold. We cannot infer that both consumers are worse off in the current period, only that at least one of them is. Assume that the bundles bought by the consumers at given prices are proportional, i.e. xa1 = kxb1 and xa0 = kxb0. We can rewrite (4.1) as p0kxb0 + p0xb0 > p0kxb1 + p0xb1 or (1 + k)p0xb0 > (1 + k)p0xb1. This implies p0xb0 > p0xb1 so that individual b is worse off in the current period. Similarly, we can show that p0xa0 > p0xa1; both individuals are worse off. As discussed in the text, for consumers to have equiproportionate expenditure patterns for all price vectors we must have either identical consumers with identical income or consumers with identical © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 42 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn homothetic preferences. These remarks hold whether we use average or total consumption bundles in the price indices. 5. PQ = p1 x1 p1 x 0 If PQ ≤ 1 then p1x1 ≤ p1x0 implying that the bundle chosen in the current period, x1 is cheaper at current prices than x0. Thus we do not know whether x1 is actually preferred to x0 because x0 cannot be purchased at p1 given income M1(= p1x1). LQ = p0 x1 p0 x 0 If LQ ≥ 1, then p0x1 ≥ p0x0 and again we do not know if x0 is preferred to x1 because x1 cannot be purchased at income M0 (= p0x0) and prices p0. If we cannot tell if one individual is better or worse off we certainly cannot say whether a group of consumers have a better or worse standard of living. 6. For an individual pensioner to be better off we must have MI = p1 x1 p1 x 0 ≥ = LP p0 x 0 p0 x 0 or p1 x 0 p1 x1 ≥ p0 x 0 0 0 . px The government increases individual pensioner’s income in proportion to the rise in LP. Thus, p1 ∑ x s1 p1 x1 = p0 x 0 0 s s 0 p ∑s x where the Laspeyres index is assumed to be calculated by the sum of consumption bundles. However, we cannot tell whether this government scheme will leave an individual pensioner better off. If the individual’s LP measure rose by more than the total index, i.e., p1 x 0 p1 ∑ s x s1 > p0 x 0 p0 ∑ s x s 0 then for the individual MI might be less than LP and we cannot say whether the individual has been made better off in the current period compared to the base period. We may note that total pensioners’ money income will increase by the rise in the total LP index, so that p1 ∑ s x s1 = p 0 p1 ∑ x s 0 x s0 0 s s0 . p ∑s x s ∑ © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 43 From this we can conclude that at least some pensioners are made better off. If the government raised pensioners’ income by the increase in the Paasche index then total money income in the current period would be as follows p1 ∑ x s1 = p 0 s p1 ∑ x1 x s0 0 s 1 p ∑s x s ∑ or p1 ∑ s x s1 p1 ∑ s x1 = p0 ∑ s x s 0 p0 ∑ s x1 or MI = PP. As for the preceeding example, we cannot infer whether individual pensioners are better or worse off. But we do know that for some individuals at least MI = PP, so that some pensioners are definitely worse off. If prices fell, the reverse scheme would be to reduce pensioner’s income proportionally to the fall in prices. Our previous conclusions hold for a price increase or decrease. Exercise 4B 1. (a) In Fig. 4B.1, the upper boundary of the feasible set is defined by the wage line R M1 which plots income as a function of labour supplied M1 = R + w1z, given the wage rate w1. 1. (a) (i) A fixed proportional income tax (t) would change the wage line: M2 = R + w1(1 − t)z The slope of the line is reduced to w1(1 − t) lowering the boundary of the feasible set (wage line R M2). 1. (a) (ii) Overtime payments imply that a higher wage rate w′ is paid for hours in excess of a certain value z*. The constraint is then given by the relation M = R + wz z ≤ z* M = R + wz* + w′(z − z*) z > z*. This is graphed in Fig. 4B.2. Note that the feasible set is no longer convex and two local optima (one of which may not be global) are possible. 1. (a) (iii) Unemployment benefit is paid when z = 0, but is not paid if z > 0. This introduces a discontinuity in the relation between M and z, and a nonconvexity in the budget constraint. Thus in Fig. 4B.3, M = R + u for z = 0 and M = M + wz for z > 0, where u is unemployment benefit. This implies that a local optimum may not be global (for example, a tangency point in the interior of the diagram may involve a lower indifference curve than that passing through R + u). © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 44 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 4B.1 Fig. 4B.2 Fig. 4B.3 1. (a) (iv) Fixed hours of work reduce the feasible set to two points: z = K, the fixed number of hours, or z = 0. 1. (b) (i) If the labour supply curve is expressed as a relation between hours worked and the gross wage, then imposition of a proportional tax shifts the labour supply curve upward by the amount of the tax (compare the standard analysis of a tax on a good produced in a competitive market). However, it is more usual to regard the gross wage as an exogenous constant and to take hours worked as a function of the net of © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 45 Fig. 4B.4 tax wage U = (1 − t)w. Then variations in the rate of tax t cause movements along the labour supply curve rather than a shift in it. 1. (b) (ii) Labour supply now becomes a function of two wage rates, the standard wage w and the overtime wage w′. Some care must then be taken in discussing the labour supply curve. Fig. 4B.4 illustrates some possibilities. In (a) of the figure the individual is initially in equilibrium earning the standard wage and increases in this cause straightforward reductions in labour supply. In (b), on the other hand, an increase in the standard wage, with the overtime wage unchanged (αβ is parallel to α ′β ′), causes a jump in labour supply to an equilibrium at the overtime wage. In (c), increases in the standard wage cause reductions in labour supply, with the overtime wage unchanged, because of an income effect. Finally, in (d), increases in the overtime wage reduce labour supply and a jump to an equilibrium at the standard wage cannot take place (for an increase in the overtime wage: a jump could occur for a decrease). 1. (b) (iii) The effect of unemployment benefit is to introduce a discontinuity into the labour supply function. Fig. 4B.5 illustrates. The indifference curve I0 passes through the point R + u, and at a wage rate of w0 the individual would be just indifferent between setting z = 0 and receiving u and setting z = z0 and receiving R + w0z0. At higher wage rates she will work, at lower wage rates she chooses unemployment. 1. (b) (iv) With fixed hours of work the individual will in general be at a wage-hours pair that is off her labour supply curve – only by chance will the wage and fixed hours of work correspond to a point of tangency in the indifference curve in the diagram. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 46 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 4B.5 2. Two interpretations of “the same tax revenue” are possible: (a) the same tax revenue if the same amount of labour is supplied or (b) the same tax revenue at the new amount of labour supplied. Interpretation (a) gives an unambiguous answer if the individual has no non-labour income, as Fig. 4B.6 shows. In the figure, 0M1 is the pre-tax budget constraint and 0M2 the budget constraint with a proportional income tax. With the proportional tax the initial point chosen is A and the amount of tax paid is equal to the vertical distance between 0M2 and 0M1 at ZA. All points along the line TT yield the same tax revenue for the government. With a progressive tax the marginal rate of tax increases with income and therefore with the amount of labour supplied. Hence the slope of the after-tax budget constraint must decrease with z. If the progressive tax schedule is to yield the same tax revenue at a constant labour supply it must be of the form 0M3 which cuts 0M2 from above at A. Hence the new optimum choice must be to the left of A, at B say. With the second interpretation of “unchanged” tax revenue the progressive tax schedules which yield the same tax revenue at the new amount of labour could be like 0M4 or 0M5 depending on the individual’s preferences. With 0M4 labour supply is reduced at the new optimum where I4 is tangent to 0M4 at C. With different preferences a constant tax revenue might require a tax schedule like 0M5 in which case labour supply is reduced at D where the indifference curve Î5 is tangent to 0M5. Note that the second interpretation of an unchanged tax revenue is less sensible since it requires that tax authorities have detailed knowledge of preferences. 3. In Fig. 4B.7, MT represents the target income. The individual is indifferent between points that achieve the target income, thus the indifference ‘curve’ is a horizontal line. The ‘target income’ hypothesis gives insufficient information to allow any other indifference curves to be drawn. Since the individual supplies just enough labour to meet the target income the higher the wage rate the less will be the labour supplied. The labour supply curve is negatively sloped, and, since wz = MT = constant, it is in fact a rectangular hyperbola. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 47 Fig. 4B.6 Fig. 4B.7 4. (a) If all prices increase by a factor k the constraint on the labour supply decision in problem [B.5] in the text is kpy = wz + R. This is equivalent to the constraint py = (w/k)z + R/k. Thus the effect of the price change is equivalent to a reduction in the real wage rate and of real unearned income by a factor 1/k. In terms of text Fig. 4.2(a) the intercept of the wage line is shifted down to R/k and its slope is reduced. If leisure is a normal good the effect of the increase in consumer prices on labour supply is ambiguous: the substitution effect of the reduction in the real wage rate will reduce labour supply but the income effect of the reduction in the real wage and the reduction in real unearned income will tend to increase it. 4. (b) If all prices and the money wage rate increase by a factor k the constraint on the labour supply decision is kpy = kwz + R which is equivalent to py = wz + R/k. In Fig. 4.2(a) the effect is to shift the intercept of the wage line downwards but there is no change in the real wage and hence no change in the slope of the wage line. Labour supply is increased or reduced depending on whether leisure is a normal good or an inferior good. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 48 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 5. When preferences are weakly separable between all goods and leisure the utility function [C.1] can be written u = u(x, L) = g(r(x), L) where r(x) is the sub-utility function for the vector of consumption goods. For a given L utility is maximized subject to the budget constraint px + wL ≤ R + wT ≡ F only if r(x) is maximized subject to px ≤ F − wL. The Lagrangean for this first-stage problem is r(x) + λ(F − wL − px) and the first-order conditions on the n consumption goods, assuming a non-corner solution for simplicity are ri(x) − λpi, i = 1, . . . , n where ri = ∂r/∂xi. The optimal Marshallian demands are xi* ( p, F − wL) and the indirect sub-utility function is R(p, F − wL) = r(x*(p, F − wL)). Note that the amount of leisure L affects the optimal demand for the consumption goods only via its effect on the amount of income available to be spent on them. The indirect sub-utility function R(p, F − wL) has all the properties of the indirect utility functions of section 3B. In particular Roy’s Identity holds: ∂R( p, F − wL ) = − R F ( p, F − wL) xi* ( p, F − wL ) ∂pi which yields a result we will use below: * R p F = R Fp = − R FF xi* − R F xiF i i (4.2) The second stage of the utility maximization problem is to choose L so as to maximize g(R(p, F − wL), L) = u(x*(p, F − wL), L) = G(L; p, F, w) and the first-order condition is GL(L; p, F, w) = −gr(R, L)wRF + gL(R, L) = 0 (4.3) and the optimal demand for leisure is L*(p, F, w). Consider first the effect on the demand for leisure of an increase in F. Using the simple comparative-static procedure on (4.3) we get ∂L* − GLF g rr R F wR F + g r wR FF − g Lr R F = = ∂F GLL GLL (4.4) Now using the same procedure for the effect of an increase in the price of the i’th consumption good, we have, using (4.3), © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 49 * − g Lr R F xi* GLp = g rr R F wR F xi* + g r wR FF xi* + g r wR F xiF (4.5) i * = xi*[w( grr RF RF + gr RFF ) − g Lr RF ] + gr wRF xiF * = − xi*GLF + g r wRF xiF Using the first-order condition (4.3) to substitute in the last term, the Slutsky equation is ∂L* − GLp ∂L* g L = = − xi* + xiF ∂pi GLL ∂F GLL i (4.6) The first part of (4.6) is the income effect of a change in the price of the i’th consumption good, showing the effect of the reduction in real income or purchasing power on the demand for leisure. The second term is the substitution effect. The assumption of weak separability means that the substitution effect of a change in the price of the consumption good arises via the change in the total expenditure on consumption goods. If the i’th good is normal then the cross-substitution effect leads to a reduction in the demand for leisure (remember GLL is negative from the second-order condition). Thus whether leisure and the i’th consumption good are Hicksian complements or substitutes depends on whether the i’th consumption good is normal or inferior. Exercise 4C 1. (a) For the two good case the absolute value of the slope of the full budget constraint (F) is s≡− dx2 ( p1 + wt1 ) = dx1 ( p2 + wt2 ) We want to know what happens to s when w increases. Taking its derivative with respect to w: ∂s t1 ( p2 + wt2 ) − ( p1 + wt1 )t2 = ∂w ( p2 + wt2 )2 = t1 p2 − t2 p1 ( p2 + wt2 )2 This derivative will be less than zero if t1p2 < t2p1 or, t1 p1 < t2 p2 as in [C.5] of the text. Hence if good 1 is less time intensive than good 2, an increase in the wage rate will reduce the absolute value of the slope of the full budget line, i.e. it will become flatter. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 50 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 1. (b) Since w influences all the full prices (ρi = pi + wti) and the full income (F = R + wT) its effects are more complicated than a change in income or a single price. Consider first the effect of w on the consumer’s maximized utility. Allowing for its effects on the full prices and full income the partial derivative of the indirect utility function [C.9] with respect to w is ∂v( ρ, F ) = ∂w ∂v ∂ρ i ∂v ∂F ∑ ∂ρ ∂w + ∂F ∂w = −∑v x t + v T = v [T − ∑t x ] = v z F i i F F i i F i where we have used Roy’s identity for the effects of the full prices on v : vi = ∂v(ρ, F)/∂ρi = −vFxi(ρ, F). This is just another version of Roy’s identity: the effect on utility of an increase in the price of a commodity (labour) that the individual sells is the quantity sold (z = T − ∑tixi), which is the rate at which income increases with price, times the marginal utility from additional income. The effect of w on the consumer’s demand for goods is also complicated because w alters all full prices and full incomes. Recall from section 3B that the Marshallian and Hicksian demands are equal if the required utility level in the full cost minimization problem is set at the maximized utility achieved in the utility maximization problem: xi(ρ, F) = hi(ρ, v(ρ, F)) Hence the effect of full income on the Marshallian demand for good i is xiF(ρ, F) = hiuvF and the effect of w on xi is ∂xi ( ρ, F ) = ∂w ∂hi ∂ρ j ∂v ∑ ∂ρ ∂w + h ∂w = ∑ h t + h v z = ∑ h t + zx iv j j ij j iu F j ij j iF (4.7) j where hij = ∂hi/∂ρj is the cross substitution effect of the full price ρj on the constant utility (Hicksian) demand for good i. The effect of w on the demand for good i has been decomposed into an income effect (zxiF) and the sum of n substitution effects. In general, the effect of an increase in the wage on the demand for goods is ambiguous for two reasons. First, the good may be normal or inferior so that the increase in real income or utility caused by the increase in the wage rate may increase or reduce demand. Second, the change in the wage rate alters all the relative full prices and so leads to n substitution effects, rather than just one as in the case of change in a single price. If we assume that there are just two goods we can get some insight into the substitution effects of the wage increase. Condsider the sum of the substitution effect terms in (4.7) in the case of good 1: h11t1 + h12t2 (4.8) The Hicksian demand functions are homogeneous of degree zero (see section 3A) so that we can use Euler’s Theorem (see section 5C) to establish h11ρ1 + h12 ρ2 = 0 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 51 This enables us to substitute −h11ρ1/ρ2 for h12 in (4.8) to get h11t1 − h11 t t ρ1 t2 = h11 1 − 2 ρ 1 ρ2 ρ1 ρ 2 (4.9) Since the own full price substitution effect h11 is always negative, the wage substitution effect is also negative if good 1 has a greater time intensity than good 2 (recall our discussion of [C.6]). (4.9) indicates that in the two-good case the wage substitution effect on good 1 is proportional to the own full price substitution effect on good 1. The full price of good 2 falls relative to the full price of good 1 when w increases if good 1 is more time intensive than good 2 and so the wage substitution effect is in the same direction as the own full price substitution effect, leading to a decrease in demand for good 1. If good 1 is less time intensive than good 2 an increase in w is equivalent to reduction in the relative full price of good 1 and so the wage substitution effect would increase the demand for good 1. For good 2 the substitution effect would be h21t1 + h22t2 From Euler’s Theorem we have h21ρ1 + h22 ρ2 = 0 or ρ2 ρ1 h21 = h22 Substituting this into the substitution effect: h22t2 − h22 t t ρ2 t1 = h22 2 − 1 ρ 2 ρ1 ρ 2 ρ1 We know that h22 < 0 and with good 1 more time intensive than good 2 t2 ρ2 − t1 ρ1 <0 The substitution effect is positive. An increase in the wage rate causes more of good 2 to be consumed at a constant utility. The effect of an increase in the wage rate on labour supply is given by the Slutsky equation ∂z( p, F ) =− ∂w i ∑ ∑ t h t + z( ρ, F )z ( ρ, F ) i ij j F j The last term is the income effect and its sign is ambiguous. The first term is the ownsubstitution effect which for the two-good case can be written t1h11t1 + t1h12t2 + t2h21t1+ t2h22t2 = t12 h11 + 2h12t1t2 + t22 h22 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 52 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 4C.1 Fig. 4C.2 since we know h12 = h21. For a strictly concave utility function h(p, u) is strictly concave in prices and the above quadratic form is negative definite. This means the own wage substitution effect is positive. 2. (a) The equation of the full budget line F is R − wT p + wt1 x2 = − 1 x1 p2 + wt2 p2 + wt2 If unearned income increases F will shift out in a parallel fashion. In Fig. 4C.1 the optimal bundle changes from A to B, but we cannot in general determine whether consumption of x1 or x2 will increase or decrease. This depends on whether they are normal or inferior goods. 2. (b) If p1 increases the slope of F becomes steeper (F1) in Fig. 4C.2 (a). If p2 increases the slope of F becomes less steep and its intercept on the x2 axis falls, as in Fig. 4C.2 (b). In both cases the change in the optimal bundle is ambiguous and depends on preferences. 2. (c) An increase in t1 will have the same impact on the feasible set as an increase in p1. Likewise a change in t2 is comparable to a change in p2. Again, the impact on the optimal bundle depends on the structure of the indifference curves. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 53 3. This question can be answered simply by noting that ∂ρ i = 1; ∂pi ∂ρ i = w, ∂ti where ρi is the full price of good i. Putting the problem in the standard form max u(x) s.t. ρx = F yields the indirect utility function v(ρ, F), the expenditure function F = f(ρ, u), the Marshallian demands xi = Di(ρ, F) and the Hicksian demands xi = Hi(ρ, u). Then we have ∂v ∂v ∂ρ i = = − λxi ∂pi ∂ρ i ∂pi where λ is the marginal utility of full income; ∂v ∂v ∂ρ i = = − λwxi . ∂ti ∂ρ i ∂ti From the Slutsky equation ∂Di ∂H i ∂Di = − xi ∂ρ i ∂ρ i ∂F we have ∂Di ∂Di ∂ρ i ∂Di = = ∂pi ∂ρ i ∂pi ∂ρ i and the Slutsky equation is unchanged. We then have ∂Di ∂Di ∂ρ i ∂H i ∂Di = =w − wxi . ∂ti ∂ρ i ∂ti ∂ρ i ∂F 4. Since ρi = pi + wti the effect of an increase in the money price on the demand for good i is ∂xi ( ρ, F ) ∂xi ( ρ, F ) ∂ρ i ∂xi ( ρ, F ) = = ∂pi ∂ρ i ∂pi ∂ρ i and so the elasticity of demand for good i with respect to its money price is ep = i ∂xi pi ∂xi ρ i pi p = = eρ i . ∂pi xi ∂ρ i xi ρ i ρi i Thus if two individuals have the same full price demand elasticity the individual with the greater wage rate will have the smaller money price demand elasticity since ρi/pi will be smaller for her. 5. The model in section 4C of the text does not consider the time spent travelling to work explicitly. One approach might be to regard ‘travelling to work’ as one of the consumption goods xi, and so a reduction in its ti causes a fall in its full price ρi. We could then consider compensating and equivalent variations associated with this fall. However, a more realistic approach is to take time spent travelling to work as some © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 54 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn fixed value tz > 0 (given that z > 0) and so the time constraint in the problem could be written ∑tI xi + z = T − tz = }. The model could be analyzed as before, with } taking the place of T. Thus full income now takes the value | = R + w}. We then have the indirect utility function v( ρ, | ), where ∂v/∂| = λ is the marginal utility of full income. It follows that the effect of a change in tz on utility is given by: ∂v ∂v ∂ | = = − λw. ∂tz ∂ | ∂tz If then tz falls from some initial level tz0 to some new level tz1 , we can define CV and EV measures by v(ρ, | 0) = v(ρ, | 1 − CV) v(ρ, | 1) = v(ρ, | 0 + EV). But then obviously CV = EV = | 1 − | 0 = w(tz0 − tz1 ) and so we simply have to value the fall in commuting time at the individual’s wage rate (as long as this does not change). Exercise 4D 1. (a) Let xo denote the market good used as an input in domestic production and write the household production function as y = h(t1, t2, xo) The budget constraint must be rewritten as 2 ∑ i=1 2 xi + px o = ∑ w (T − t ) i i i=1 where p is the price of xo. The rest of the model is as before. The optimality condition with respect to xo can be written as ρh3(t1, t2, xo) = p so xo is used to the point at which its marginal value product in household production equals its market price. The rest of the model is as before. 1. (b) Let Li denote i’s leisure, the direct consumption of own time. The utility functions are rewritten as ui = ui(xi, yi, Li), i = 1, 2 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 55 It is useful now to introduce zi as i’s market labour supply and to write the individual time constraints explictly as ti + zi + Li ≤ T, i = 1, 2 In the Lagrange function in [D.4], replace the previous utility functions with the new, write income as wizi so that the budget constraint is ∑iwizi − ∑ixi, and add the term ∑ τ (T − t − z − L ) i i i i i where τi are Lagrange multipliers. We consider only the possibility that the secondary earner may supply no market labour, so we assume all variables other than possibly z2 are stictly positive at the optimum. The first order conditions on the x, y, L, t and z are now u1x = λ = σ ux2 uy1 = µ = σ uy2 u1L = τ 1 σ uL2 = τ 2 µhi (t1, t2) = τi, i = 1, 2 λw1 = τ1 λw2 ≤ τ2, z2 ≥ 0, z2(λw2 − τ2) = 0 If z2 > 0 at the optimum, nothing much changes, we just have some additional conditions uLi = wi uxi uLi wi = uyi ρ which are just standard equalities of marginal rates of substitution and price ratios (remember the price of x is 1). The price of leisure in this case is the wage. However, more interesting is the case of a corner solution where z2 = 0, since then we have uLi = ρh2 (t1 , t2 ) ≥ w2 uxi uLi w = h2 (t1 , t2 ) ≥ 2 uyi ρ In this case, the opportunity cost of leisure may no longer be the wage, if the secondary earner is not supplying market labour, but rather is in general given by the marginal value of time spent in household production. The second condition says that the © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 56 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn marginal rate of substitution between leisure and the domestic good is equated to the secondary earner’s marginal product of time spent in producing the domestic good. 1. (c) This is largely a matter of notation. Write x = [x1, . . . xn] as a vector of market goods, y = [y1, . . . , ym] as a vector of household goods, and H(y, t1, t2) as the household’s transformation function, giving the technological possibilities of producing the household goods with time. There will now be a vector of implicit prices of household goods ρ = (ρ1, . . . , ρm) and we also need the vector of prices of market goods p = (p1, . . . , pm). If we assume that the transformation function can be represented by the m production functions yj = hj(t1j, t2j) i.e. there is no joint production, then the model is essentially as before. However, there is in general the possibility of joint production, where a given time input produces more than one good (e.g. looking after the baby while cooking dinner). 2. Note that, given positive market labour supplies of both household members, an alternative way of solving the model is to derive the cost function for the household good by solving min C = ti ∑w t i i s.t. y ≤ h(t1, t2) i for given y. This results in a cost function C(w1, w2, y) and it is a standard result (see section 6B) that if h(., .) is homogeneous of degree 1, this can always be written as C(w1, w2, y) = c(w1, w2)y where c(w1, w2) is the cost of producing 1 unit of y. Thus we set ρ = c(w1, w2). 3. If the market and domestic goods are perfect substitutes, we can rewrite the utility functions as ui(xi + yi) and solve just as before. We obtain from the first order conditions the condition ρ= wi =1 hi (t1 , t2 ) i = 1, 2 Recall that the price of the market good is 1. Thus the implicit price of the domestic good at the optimum is always equal to that of the market good. The household produces the domestic good up to the point at which its marginal cost is equal to the market price. If this is less than it wants to consume at that price, it buys the rest in, if more, it sells the surplus on the market. This illustrates nicely that the household in this model can be thought of as a small economy. What we have just described is precisely the optimum of a small country in international trade producing and consuming a good which is available on the world market at an exogenously given price. Suppose that the bought in domestic labour d is a perfect substitute for the secondary earner’s domestic labour. Then the production function becomes © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 57 h(t1, t2 + d). The price of d is w < w2. Intuitively we would expect that the secondary earner will supply no domestic labour if a perfect substitute is available at a lower wage, and this is confirmed by the relevant first order conditions, which are µh2(t1, t2 + d) ≤ λw2, t2 ≥ 0, t2[µh2(t1, t2 + d) − λw2] = 0 µh2(t1, t2 + d) − λw = 0 Thus if w < w2 we must have t2 = 0. However if the two forms of labour are less than perfect substitutes then we would write the production function as h(t1, t2, d) and it is quite possible to have all three types of labour input positive at the optimum. 4. The value of household production in this model is ρy. Unfortunately, the implicit price of the household good is usually unobservable, since we do not have data on domestic output (time use studies give detailed data on domestic inputs). However, consider the budget constaint in [D12]. This implies that ρy = T ∑ wi + π − ∑ xi i i If we are able to observe the household’s wages and value of consumption of market goods, which seems reasonable, we could take the difference between the value of the household’s time endowment and its consumption as a measure of the value of household production. This could involve an error. There are three possible cases: (a) The household production function has constant returns to scale. In that case it is straightforward to show that π = 0. Thus there is no error. (b) Household production has diminishing returns to scale. In that case π > 0 and the measure would understate the true value of household production. (c) Household production has increasing returns to scale. In that case π < 0 and the measure would overstate the true value of household production. If we are prepared to accept that in practice returns to scale in household production are roughly constant, then we have quite a simple practical measure of the value of household production, at least in this simple model. 5. If the households face the same wage rates and have identical preferences then there are only 2 possible reasons for the difference in labour supply of the secondary earner: differences in distributional preferences; and differences in the household production function. For example, if the secondary earner’s leisure is a normal good and she obtains a higher income share in one household than another, then that household could show a lower secondary earner labour supply. However, we focus here on the difference in production functions. For simplicity, assume the primary earner in each household supplies labour only to the market, and that the household production functions are simply yh = khth h = 1, 2 with k1 > k2 and th the secondary earner labour supply to domestic production in household h. Here we can think of the kh as productivity parameters which reflect the © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 58 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn physical and human capital available to the household. It follows that the implicit price of the household good is ρh = w2 kh which is the opportunity cost of the time needed to produce 1 unit of the domestic good. The household budget constraint can be written as ∑x + ρ y = T∑w ih i h h i h = 1, 2 i This tells us immediately that household 1, with the higher domestic productivity, must have the higher utility possibilities, since its budget constraint lies everywhere above that of household 2 except at the point yh = 0. The slopes of the budget constraints in (x, y)-space are respectively 1/ρ1 > 1/ρ2. An income measure of the difference in their welfares would be the compensating or equivalent variations defined by the achieved utility levels of the two households: how much income could we take away from household 1 to put its members on the same utility levels as those reached at the optimum of household 2; or how much income must we give household 2 to put its members on the same utility levels as those in household 1? Note that we could not use the difference in their money incomes from market labour supply as a measure of the difference in welfare, for the simple reason that the secondary earner’s labour supply, and therefore market income, in household 1 could be greater or less than the secondary earner’s labour supply and income in household 2. To see why, note the we can write market labour supply of the secondary earner as lh = T − th = T − yh(ρh)/kh That is, market labour supply is total time minus the amount of time required to meet the household’s demand for the domestic good, which is a function of the relative price of that good. Differentiating with respect to kh gives ∂lh yh ρ ∂y y = (1 + h h ) = h (1 − eh ) ⱀ 0 ∂kh kh yh ∂ρ h kh where eh is the price elasticity of demand for the domestic good. This shows the two opposing effects of, say, an increase in the household’s domestic productivity. The time input required to produce a given amount of the domestic good would fall, and this would increase the time allocated to the market. But the fall in the opportunity cost of the domestic good would (normally) increase the demand for it, and this would tend to increase time spent in domestic production and reduce market labour supply. Thus if demand for the domestic good is inelastic (eh < 1), the former effect dominates, while if this demand is elastic (eh > 1) the latter effect dominates. The important consequence of this simple demonstration is that a household’s total market income may be a poor indicator of its welfare relative to another household when household production is taken into account and secondary earner labour supply varies across households. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 59 6. If the domestic good is a household public good, we can write the utility functions as ui = ui(xi, y) i = 1, 2 where y is the output of the public good. The production function is as before. The relevant optimality condition will now become, with the same notation as before uy1 + σ uy2 = λρ This corresponds to the usual condition of equality between the sum of marginal utilities of the public good to its marginal cost (see Section 13B). Note that the overall demand and total output of the good, and hence the allocation of time, will depend, if tastes differ, also on the utility distribution with in the household, as expressed by the value of the shadow price of the utility constraint, σ. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 60 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Chapter 5 Production Exercise 5A 1. The casual system was clearly ‘co-ordination by the market’ in that the employment contract extended over the period of just one job – the unloading of a ship – and new contracts were entered into each time a ‘job’ appeared. It existed in the ports industry because of the day to day variability in the flow of jobs which depended on the rate at which ships arrived to be unloaded and reloaded, and on the non-storability of output. 2. If each individual contracts with every other individual the required number of contracts is n! n( n − 1)( n − 2)! n( n − 1) = = ( n − 2)!( 2 !) ( n − 2)!( 2 !) 2 If there is coordination by a central coordinator only n contracts are required. 3. (a) The small size of the group and the artistic nature of the work might well make the producers’ cooperative more effective than the conventional firm. Shirking would be discouraged through peer pressure and the presence of shirking would be easy to detect. Individuals could be rewarded by receiving the profits on their own sales. Each member of the cooperative would benefit from access to a central studio and potterymaking supplies. A disadvantage might be difficulties in agreeing on how to divide up the costs of operation and generally deciding on the level of investment to make in a studio and equipment. The conventional firm might be less effective because artists on a fixed wage would have less incentive to be productive. However, the firm would have no difficulty planning the scale of operation and the level of investment to be made. 3. (b) A producers’ cooperative would be difficult to organize. Workers could be paid according to the number of motor cycle parts produced, but the quality control might be a major problem. Unlike the pottery workers in (a) workers could not easily identify their own output so that ‘pride of work’ would be diminished. Workers would have an incentive to shirk if there were little chance of being detected. A penalty scheme could presumably be devised whereby a person’s pay would be docked if she were discovered to be making defective products. Major problems would be likely to exist in getting any agreement on production plans. The conventional firm has the advantage of being able to make decisions quickly, but also suffers from the problem of quality control. A centrally controlled firm is perhaps in a better position to design penalty schemes to discourage shirking. 60 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 61 3. (c) A producers’ cooperative would have the same problems described in (b). The coordination of production decisions would be very difficult without the central authority of a firm. Typically, a manager would be appointed to run the cooperative subject to some sort of democratic oversight by the workers. The problem here is to trade off the manager’s accountability to the workforce against the need for effective decision-taking. Exercise 5B 1. Production is output-efficient when the output produced is the maximum possible from the input combination. Production is technically efficient when it is impossible to reduce the use of any input without reducing output. Output-efficiency is necessary for technical efficiency since, if the firm is not producing the maximum possible output from an input combination, it can reduce the use of one or both inputs without reducing output. If the firm is output-efficient it is on an isoquant. If the firm is operating on the upward sloping segment of an isoquant (see Fig. 5.2 in the text), then it is output efficient but not technically efficient since it could move ‘south-west’ down the isoquant, reducing the use of both inputs and producing the same output. 2. The contours of a function f(z1, z2) have the slope dz2/dz1 = −f1/f2 which is positive only if the partial derivatives f1, f2 are of opposite sign. We did not rule out the possibility that marginal product could be negative so that isoquants could be positively sloped. In chapters 2 to 4 we assumed that marginal utilities were always positive so that indifference curves were always negatively sloped. 3. If a firm’s technology is represented by a production function y = f(z1, z2), then the only permissible transformation of the production function is proportional: a change of units in which the output or the inputs are measured. Such transformations cannot alter the sign of marginal product, only its magnitude. The utility function used in chapters 2 to 4 is an ordinal function, unique only up to a positive monotonic transformation. Thus any statement about diminishing marginal utility is meaningless since it is always possible to find another numerical representation of preferences which contradicts it. 4. (a) Fixed Proportions Technology (Leontief). The isoquant map for the single process fixed proportions production function: y = min(z1/β11, z2/β12) is shown in Fig. 5B.1. The economic region is the ray from the origin through the corners of the isoquants: all points off this ray are technically inefficient since it is possible produce the same output after reducing the use of one input and holding the use of the other constant. 4. (b) Process 2 is technically inefficient if β11 < β21 and β12 < β22 so that process 2 requires more of both inputs to produce any specified output. Fig. 5B.2 shows the isoquants for both production processes for one unit of output. The input vector zi © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 62 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 5B.1 Fig. 5B.2 produces one unit of output when used in process i (i = 1, 2). The vector za = kz1 (0 ≤ k ≤ 1) will therefore produce k units of output and similarly zb = (1 − k)z2 will produce (1 − k) units of output. Hence the input combination zc which is just the sum of za and zb can produce one unit of output and is on the unit isoquant. Varying k traces the negatively sloped portion of the unit isoquant. 4. (c) Fig. 5B.3 illustrates the unit isoquant and input requirement set with four technically efficient production processes. Processes whose input vectors for producing one unit of output lie inside the unit output input requirement set generated by combinations of other production processes are not technically efficient. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 63 Fig. 5B.3 5. Partially differentiating the Cobb-Douglas production function y = z1α z2β with respect to z1 and z2 yields MP1 = α z1α −1 z2β = α z1α z2β / z1 = αy/z1 MP2 = β z1α z2β −1 = β z1α z2β / z2 = βy/z2 Thus MRTS 21 = MP1 α z2 = MP2 β z1 so that the marginal rate of technical substitution is independent of the output level and varies only with the input proportions. The isoquants have the same slope along rays from the origin and the Cobb-Douglas production function is homothetic. 6. Write the Constant Elasticity of Substitution production function as y = f(g(z1, z2)) where g = δ 1 z1α + δ 2 z2α and f = Ag1/α. Partially differentiating with the respect to input i and using the function of a function rule gives ∂y ∂g A −1 = f′ = g αδ i ziα −1 ∂zi ∂zi α 1 α = Aα δ i A1−α ( g 1/α )1−α ziα −1 = Aα δ i y1−α ziα −1 y = Aα δ i zi 1−α Hence MRTS 21 = MP1 δ 1 z2 = MP2 δ 2 z1 1−α and so MRTS is independent of output and depends only on the input proportions. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 64 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 7. (a) First note that using the implicit function rule on y − f(z1, z1r) = 0 yields dz1 fz = g ′( r ) = − 2 1 < 0 dr f1 + f2 r dz2 dz1 r f1 z1 = = z1 + g ′( r ) z1 = >0 dr dr f1 + f2 r Now write MRTS as m(z1, z2) to get dm dz dz ( m2 f1 − m1 f2 ) z1 = m1 1 + m2 2 = dr dr dr f1 + f2 r Hence σ= dr m dm r = ( f1 z1 + f2 z2 ) f1 ( m2 f1 − m1 f2 ) z1 z2 f2 = ( f1 z1 + f2 z2 ) f1 f2 ( m2 f1 − m1 f2 ) z1 z2 f 22 Finally, substituting in the denominator for the partial derivatives of m with respect to z1 and z2: m1 = ( f2 f11 − f1 f21 ) , f 22 m2 = ( f2 f12 − f1 f22 ) f 22 yields the required expression for the elasticity of substitution. 7. (b)(i) The marginal rate of substitution of the Leontief fixed proportions production function of question 4(a) is zero for r < : ≡ β12/β11, undefined at r = : and infinite for r > :. Hence the elasticity of substitution is not defined for the Leontief production function. However, looking ahead to chapter 6, we can use another definition of the elasticity of substitution in terms of the change in the cost minimizing input ratio to changes in the input price ratio: σ= % change in z2 / z1 d( z2 / z1 ) ( p1 / p2 ) = % change in p1 / p2 d( p1 / p2 ) ( z2 / z1 ) (5.1) where p1/p2 is the input price ratio. (Compare [B.8].) As we show in chapter 6, if the production function is differentiable, a non-corner solution to the problem of minimizing the cost of producing a given output will have p1/p2 = f1/f2. In such cases the two definitions of the elasticity of substitution are equivalent. In the Leontief case the cost minimizing input ratio is always :, provided both input prices are positive. Hence the elasticity of substitution in (5.1) is zero. 7. (b)(ii) The log of the MRTS for the Cobb-Douglas production function is ln m = ln α z2 /β z1 = ln α /β + ln r © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 65 so that σ= dr m dr m d ln r = = =1 dm r r dm d ln m 7. (b)(iii) The log of the MRTS for the CES production function is (see question 6) ln m = ln δ1/δ2 + (1 − α) ln r and so σ = 1/(1 − α) 7. (c) The marginal products of the linear production function are constant: MPi = ai, (i = 1, 2). Hence the isoquants are straight lines with slope −a1/a2 and MRTS is constant at all input ratios: dm/dr = 0, implying that σ = (dr/dm)(r/m) is infinite. 8. (a) With α = 1 the CES production function in question 6 reduces to y = A(δ1z1 + δ2z2) (5.2) which is the same form as the linear production function in question 7(c) with ai = Aδi. The alert reader will notice that in the definition of the CES production function in question 6 we required that δ1 + δ2 = 1, so that the coefficients have the same dimension. However, in (5.2) the coefficients Aδi appear to have the dimension of [output]/[input i]. The answer to this difficulty is that the CES production function could be written as y = A[δ1(k1z1)α + δ2(k2z2)α]1/α = Ag1/α (5.3) where the coefficients ki have the dimension [output]/[input i]. The production function is now explicitly dimensionally homogeneous. In the definition in question 6 we tacitly chose the units in which the inputs are measured so that the coefficients ki = 1 and do not appear explicitly in the production function. 8. (b) Choose units so that ki = 1, (i = 1, 2) in (5.3). Take the log of the CES form, with g = δ 1 z1α + δ 2 z2α , to get ln y = ln A + (1/α) ln g which is undefined at α = 0. However, we can use L’Hôpital’s Rule: lim α →0 ln g α = limα →0 d ln g /α limα →0 dα /dα = lim α →0 1 dg g dα Since lim dg /dα = lim(δ 1 z1α ln z1 + δ 2 z2α ln z2 ) = δ 1 ln z1 + δ 2 ln z2 α →0 α →0 and limα→0 g = δ1 + δ2 = 1 we have lim ln y = ln A + δ1 ln z1 + δ2 ln z2 α →0 which is the log of a Cobb-Douglas production function. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 66 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 8. (c) Let us use the definition (5.3). Consider an input bundle where k1z1 ≤ k2z2 Since limα→−∞ δ 1/α = 1, there exists an < < 0 such that α<<⇒ δ 11/α Ak1 z1 ≤ δ 12/α Ak2 z2 ⇒ δ1(Ak1z1)α ≥ δ2(Ak2z2)α ⇒ 2δ1(Ak1z1)α ≥ δ1(Ak1z1)α + δ2(Ak2z2)α = Aαg ⇒ (2δ1)1/αAk1z1 ≤ Ag1/α = y Hence lim ( 2δ 1 )1/α Ak1 z1 = Ak1 z1 ≤ lim y α → −∞ α → −∞ (5.4) Next, notice that when α < 0 δ1(Ak1z1)α ≤ δ1(Ak1z1)α + δ2(Ak2z2)α = Aαg which implies δ 1/1 α Ak1z1 ≥ Ag1/α = y and so lim δ 11/α Ak1 z1 = Ak1 z1 ≥ lim y α → −∞ α → −∞ (5.5) Hence (5.4) and (5.5) together imply limα→−∞ y = Ak1z1. Repeating the analysis for the case in which k2z2 ≤ k1z1 we conclude that lim A[δ1(k1z1)α + δ2(k2z2)α] = A min(k1z1, k2z2) α → −∞ where the right hand term is the Leontief production function of question 4(a) with βi1 = 1/Aki. Notice that since the elasticity of substitution of the CES form is 1/(1 − α) and limα→−∞1/(1 − α) = 0 we have confirmed the results in question 7 that σ = 0 for the Leontief production function. Exercise 5C 1. (a) If y = f(z) is homogeneous of degree t, we have f(sz) = stf(z) and differentiating both sides partially with respect to zi gives fi(sz)s = stfi(z) so that fi(sz) = st−1fi(z) (5.6) so that the marginal products are homogeneous of degree t − 1 and vary with the scale of production unless f(z) is linear homogeneous (t = 1). © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 67 1. (b) Since MRTS is just the ratio of the marginal products (5.6) implies that, for homogeneous functions, MRTS is independent of the scale of production. The isoquants have constant slopes along rays from the origin. Compare the discussion of homothetic preferences in chapter 3. 2. (a) Multiplying all inputs by s > 0 gives a1sz1 + a2sz2 = s(a1z1 + a2z2) = sf(z) so that the linear production function has constant returns. 2. (b) The Leontief production function also has constant returns min(sz1/β1, sz2/β2) = s min(z1/β1, z2/β2) = sf(z) 2. (c) But with the Cobb-Douglas production function (sz1)α(sz2)β = sα + β z1α z2β = sα+βf(z) so that there are increasing, constant or decreasing returns as α + β is greater than, equal to or less than 1. 2. (d) The CES production function has constant returns: A[δ1(sz1)α + δ2(sz2)α]1/α = A[(δ 1 z1α + δ 2 z2α ) sα ]1/α = A[δ 1 z1α + δ 2 z2α ]1/α s = sf(z) 3. Suppose that f(z) is homogeneous of degree t. We must show that there is a linear homogeneous function ᐉ(z) and an increasing transformation G(ᐉ) such that G(ᐉ(z)) = f(z). Suppose that we define ᐉ(z) ≡ [f(z)]1/t. Then ᐉ(z) is linear homogeneous: ᐉ(sz) = [f(sz)]1/t = [stf(z)]1/t = s[f(z)]1/t = sᐉ(z) Hence if we also define G(ᐉ) ≡ ᐉt we have Gᐉ(z) = ([f(z)]1/t)t = f(z) and f(z) is indeed a homothetic function. An example of a homothetic but non-homogeneous function is y = A(δ 0 + δ 1 z1α + δ 2 z 2α ) 1 /α (5.7) which is the general form of the CES with an additional constant term δ0. Supplementary Questions (i) Show that (5.7) is not homogeneous. (ii) Show that (5.7) is an increasing transformation of a linear homogeneous function of z. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 68 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 4. Since f(z) is linear homogeneous Euler’s Theorem [C.4] implies that f1z1 + f2z2 = y so the numerator in σ= f1 f2 ( f1 z1 + f2 z2 ) z1 z2 [2 f12 f1 f2 − f11 ( f2 )2 − f22 ( f1 )2 ] (5.8) is f1 f2y. The partial derivatives of a linear homogeneous function are homogeneous of degree zero (see [C.3]) and so, applying Euler’s Theorem again, f11z1 + f12z2 = 0 ⇒ f11 = −f12z2/z1 f21z1 + f22z2 = 0 ⇒ f22 = −f12z1/z2 (remember that f12 = f21). Hence the denominator in (5.8) can be written z1z2[2f12 f1 f2 + z2 f12( f2)2/z1 + z1 f12( f1)2/z2] which can be rearranged to give f12[ f1z1( f1z1 + f2z2) + f2z2( f1z1 + f2z2)] = f12( f1z1 + f2z2)2 = f12y2 and so σ= f1 f2 f12y Exercise 5D 1. For z2 = z20 output is maximized when the variable input is at the level z1* . Any further increase in z1 will place the firm on a lower isoquant and so reduce output. Hence z1* is on the ridge line R1 which is the boundary of the economic region. Since output is maximized at z1* the marginal product of z1 must be zero. 2. Average product decreases with z1 up to z10 and then increases, so that AP1 has a local minimum at z10 for given z2. Hence its derivative [D.3] is zero at this point and AP2 = MP1. Supplementary Question (i) Why must the MP1 curve cut the AP2 curve from below at z10 and from above at z1′ ? © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructur’s Manual, 3rd edn 69 Chapter 6 Cost Exercise 6A 1. Assume first that there are no transactions costs and suppose that the market price of the asset is p0 now at date 0 and p1 and p1 one year later at date 1. To use the asset for one year the firm must buy it at date 0 and resell it at date 1. By purchasing the asset at date 0 and reselling it at date 1 the firm reduces its income stream at date 0 by −p0 at date 0 and increases it by p1 at date 1. The cost to the firm is p0 − p1 1+ r since £1 of income at date 1 has a present value of 1/(1 + r). If the price of the asset is constant, p0 = p1, the cost of using the asset for a year is p0r/(1 + r). The asset’s infinite durability is not sufficient to ensure that its price is constant over time. We would need to assume that there is no technical progress or change in the value of the output produced by the asset. The implication of the asset having a finite life is that its price will decline over time so that p1 < p0. If the firm already owns the asset at date 0 it could sell it for p0 and lend out the proceeds for one year at the interest rate r, giving an income stream of 0, p0(1 + r). If it uses the asset for a year and then sells it at date 1 its income stream from this transaction is 0, p1. Hence the difference in its income stream from using the asset for a year is 0, p0(1 + r) − p1 which has the same present value as the case in which the firm does not own the asset at date 0. If there is no second-hand market the cost of using the asset from date 0 to date 1 is just p0. If the firm already owns the asset at date 0 its opportunity cost is zero. If there are transactions costs of t per transaction and the firm buys the asset at date 0 and resells at date 1 the opportunity cost is (assuming that the transactions costs are incurred by the purchaser, so that the market prices are net of transactions costs) p0 + t − p1 . 1+r Exercise 6B 1. The isoquants for the single process Leontief technology are rectangular, so that the cost minimizing input bundles are always at the ‘corner’ of the relevant isoquant, where the minimum amounts of the two inputs are used to produce the required output level. Hence the cost minimizing conditional input demands are zi = βiy, (i = 1, 2) and the cost function is C(p, y) = (p1β1 + p2β2)y The cost function is linear in output, yielding © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 69 70 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructur’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 6B.1 Fig. 6B.2 the total cost curve in part (b) of Fig. 6B.1 and the horizontal marginal and average cost curves in part (c). As part (a) shows, changes in relative input prices (changes in the slope of the isocost lines) have no effect on the optimal bundle. The conditional input demands do not vary with the input prices, only with output. 2. In Fig. 6B.2 the isoquant I is a straight line with slope −α1/α2 since marginal products are constant: MPi = αi. If the isocost lines are steeper than I (p1/p2 < α1/α2), as in the figure, cost is minimized by using only input 1 to produce output. Hence when p1/α1 < p2/α2 the conditional input demands are z1 = y/α1, z2 = 0 and total cost is C = p1y/α1 Conversely when the isocost lines are flatter than the isoquants cost is minimized when only z2 is used. Thus p1/α1 > p2/α2 implies conditional input demands z1 = y/α1, z2 = 0 total cost is C = p1y/α1. The cost function is therefore C(p, y) = y min(p1/α1, p2/α2) and the cost curves have the same form as those of parts (b) and (c) of Fig. 6B.1. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructur’s Manual, 3rd edn 71 Supplementary Questions (i) What is the interpretation of pi /αi? (ii) What is the cost function and the conditional input demands when the isocost lines have the same slope as the isoquants? 3. Note that since there is strict essentiality no output is produced if either input is zero. Hence the solution to the cost minimization problem must have positive amounts of all inputs. Forming the Lagrangean L( z, λ ) = ∑ pi zi + λ ( y − Az1α z21−α ) the first order conditions are p1 − λαAz1α −1 z21−α = 0 (6.1) p2 − λ (1 − α ) Az1α z2−α = 0 (6.2) y − Az1α z21 −α = 0 (6.3) From (6.1) and (6.2) we have the usual condition for cost minimization that the input price ratio equals the ratio of marginal products: p1 α z2 = p2 1 − α z1 which implies z2 = p1 1 − α z1 p2 α (6.4) Substituting (6.4) in the constraint (6.3) gives p 1−α y = Az1 1 z1 p2 α 1 −α α p 1−α = Az1 1 p2 α 1 −α and so the conditional demand for input 1 is y p 1−α z1 = 1 A p2 α α −1 (6.5) Substituting (6.5) into (6.4) gives the conditional demand for input 2 as p 1 − α y p1 1 − α z2 = 1 p2 α A p2 α α −1 y p 1−α = 1 A p2 α α (6.6) Note that, since 0 < α < 1 the conditional input demand for zi is decreasing in pi and increasing in pj. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 72 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructur’s Manual, 3rd edn z2 slope −p1s /p2 EP I2 I1 I0 slope −p1b /p2 z1 z01 Fig. 6B.3 Using (6.5) and (6.6), the cost function is y p 1−α C ( p, y) = p1 1 A p2 α = α −1 y p 1−α + p2 1 A p2 α y α −1 1−α 1 − α p1 p1 p2 α A α −1 α 1−α + p2 p2−α p1α α α 1 − α α −1 1 − α α 1 = yp1α p21−α + α A α Since the production function has constant returns, the cost function is linear in the output and the cost curves are of the same form as those in parts (b) and (c) of Fig. 6B.1. 4. The isocost lines will be kinked at z1 = z10 , as in Fig. 6B.3. When z1 < z10 its marginal opportunity cost is the selling price p1s and when z1 > z10 it is the price at which more of the input can be bought: p1b > p1s. Hence the isocost lines are steeper to the right of z10 than to the left. The cost minimizing solutions for different output levels are shown in Fig. 6B.3 and EP is the expansion path. Note that at the output y1 the optimal input combination is at the kink in the isocost line C1 and so changes in p1s, p1b or p2 may have no effect on the cost minimizing input combination at this output. The cost function is kinked at the output (y1 in Fig. 6B.3) at which the cost minimizing demand for input 1 is z10 because the marginal opportunity cost of z1 jumps from p1s to p1b. Fig. 6B.4 shows the total, average and marginal cost curves for a simple case in which the technology has constant returns to scale. Recalling the expression for long run marginal cost [B.8], long run marginal cost jumps from p1s/f1 to p1b/f1 at output y1. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructur’s Manual, 3rd edn 73 Fig. 6B.4 Supplementary questions (i) Show the effect on EP of small increases in p1s, p1b and p2. (ii) Explain the shape of the average cost curve in part (b) of Fig. 6B.4. 5. (a) Homogeneity implies that the slope of isoquants is constant along rays from the origin. Hence the expansion path defined by the tangency of isoquants and isocost lines is also a ray from the origin and the cost minimizing input ratio is independent of the required output. Let X = (z1(p, 1), z2(p, 1)) be the cost minimizing input combination for producing an arbitrary reference output level of W. Hence C(p, W) = pX. Because f(z) is homogeneous of degree n, the input vector s1/nX will produce sW units of output: f(s1/nX) = (s1/n)nf(X) = sf(X) = sW since f(X) = W. Further, s1/nX will also be the cost minimizing vector for producing y = sW units since it is on the same ray from the origin as X and therefore on the expansion path. Hence the minimum cost of producing sW is C(p, sW) = s1/npX = s1/nC(p, W) and the cost of producing y = sW is y C(p, y) = C(p, sW) = W 1/ n C(p, W) = y1/nC(p, W)W−1/n = y1/nb(p) as required since the arbitrary reference output W is constant. 5. (b) Since X is cost minimizing for W, the cost minimizing bundle for y is s(y)X and C(p, y) = s(y)C(p, W) (6.7) The factor of proportionality s(y) is defined by F(f(s(y)X) = F(s(y)f(X)) = y © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 (6.8) 74 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructur’s Manual, 3rd edn (where we have written the homothetic production function as an increasing transformation F of a linear homogeneous production function f). We can invert (6.8) to get s(y)f(X) = F −1(y) ⇒ s(y) = F −1 f ( X) (6.9) Using (6.7) and (6.9), marginal cost is Cy(p, y) = s′(y)C(p, W) = C(p, W)/F ′f(X) and so the elasticity of cost with respect to output is Eyc = = Cyy s′( y)C ( p, W) F = C ( p, y) s( y)C ( p, W) F F ( f ( s( y) X )) = F ′f ( X ) s( y) F ′f ( s( y) X ) where the last expression is the reciprocal of the scale elasticity of a homothetic function (see text, page 104). 6. Denote the input price ratio p1 /p2 by ρ and the cost minimizing input ratio z2 /z1 by r = r(ρ), so that relative exenditure is ρ/r and dρ / r 1 dr 1 ρ dr 1 = 2 r − ρ = 1 − = (1 − σ ) dρ r dρ r r dρ r (where the last follows from the definition of the elasticity of substitution and the fact that cost-minimization implies that ρ = f1/f2). Thus if the relative price of input 1 increases, relative expenditure on it increases only if the elasiticity of substitution is less than 1. Supplementary question (i) How do relative expenditures vary with ρ in the case of a Cobb-Douglas production function? 7. Since it is not cost minimizing to use more of the input than necessary, total cost is a step function of output, as in part (a) of Fig. 6B.5. Over the range y ∈ (0, J] average cost is p/y, so the average cost curve is a rectangular hyperbola over this range, with lim y→0 C /y = ∞ and lim y→ J C /y = p/J. For y ∈ (J, 2J] average cost is 2p/y with lim y→ J C /y = 2p/J and lim y→2 J C /y = p/J. Generally, for y ∈ (nJ, (n + 1)J], (n = 1, 2 . . .) we have lim C/y = np/(n + 1)J y→ nJ and lim C/y = p/J y→( n +1 ) J © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructur’s Manual, 3rd edn 75 Fig. 6B.5 Hence the average cost curve is a set of discontinuous ‘scalloped’ segments as part (b) of the figure. As output becomes large relative to the capacity J of the indivisible input, the average cost curve tends to a horizontal line with height p/J. The derivative of total cost with respect to output is zero for y ∈ (nJ, (n + 1)J) and is undefined for y = nJ. Hence the marginal cost curve is the horizontal axis in part (b) for the open intervals (nJ, (n + 1)J) and undefined at y = nJ. Although marginal cost is not defined at nJ, the additional cost incurred in increasing output by some discrete amount is well defined. The increase in cost from producing ∆ ∈ (0, y < J] is p. Exercise 6C 1. The isoquants for a firm with four fixed proportions processes is shown in Fig. 6C.1. The Leontief production function for process i is z z y = min 1 , 2 β 1i β 2i and we have assumed that β11 > β12 > β13 > β14. With input 2 fixed at z20 , and assuming that input 2 has a marginal opportunity cost of zero, the short run expansion path is the horizontal line at z20 . The firm will minimize cost by using as little as possible of the costly input 1 to produce the required output. Thus its expansion path is the horizontal line abcd for output of y1 (corresponding to isoquant I1) or more. For output of less than y1, such as y0 corresponding to isoquant I0, the firm’s cost is the same at all points on the vertical segment ef of the isoquant I0. Thus for output y ∈ (0, y1) all non-negatively sloped curves from the vertical axis to point a are expansion paths, including the horizontal line z20 fa. The firm’s cost curves are shown in Fig. 6C.2. For y ∈ [0, y1) additional output is produced by using process 1 only and requires only β11 additional units of z1 to produce an extra unit of output. Hence marginal cost over this range of output is p1β11. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 76 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructur’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 6C.1 Fig. 6C.2 For y ∈ [y1, y2) a mixture of process 1 and process 2 is required to produce more output given that the maximum amount of input 2 is fixed. Extra output is produced by increasing the use of process 2 and reducing the use of process 1. Similarly to produce extra output when y ∈ [y2, y3), the firm substitutes process 3 for process 2. The firm substitutes processes which require larger amounts of input 1 to produce an additional unit of output for those which require smaller amounts as its output increases. As it moves along abcd from segment ab to segment bc to segment cd it requires larger amounts of z1 to produce more output. Its variable cost curve is shown in part (a) of Fig. 6C.2 and its marginal cost curve as an increasing step function in part (b). At y4 no more output can be produced given the constraint on z2: further increases in z1 do not increase output and the shout run marginal cost curve is vertical. Average variable cost for any output is the slope of a line from the origin to the variable cost curve in part (a). Hence for output up to y1 the SMC and AVC curves in part (b) coincide, but for y > y1 the AVC curve lies below SMC. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructur’s Manual, 3rd edn 77 Fig. 6C.3 2. The short run total cost curves are shown in part (a) of Fig. 6C.3 and the marginal and average curves in part (b). Since marginal product is always positive with a CobbDouglas production function y = z1α z2β the firm will always wish to use all the fixed input available to minimize the amount of the costly variable input required. Thus we can invert the production function at the level of the fixed input X2 to get the cost minimizing level of the variable input as z1 = ( yX2− β ) = y k 1 1 α α −α where k = X . Hence variable cost is β 1 α p1y k and short run marginal cost 1−α SMC = p1y kα −1 α which is increasing in y if α ∈ (0, 1). Since the marginal product of input 1 is never zero, no matter what the required output, the SMC curve never becomes vertical. 3. See the ridge line R in Fig. 5.2. of the text. The firm would never choose to operate above such a ridge line since it could always reduce the amount of the variable input required by moving back down the positively sloped section of the isoquant. Hence the expansion path would be the ridge line up to z2 = z20 and the horizontal line at z20 thereafter. 4. The isocost lines in Fig. 6C.4 are negatively sloped for z ≥ z20 , since the marginal opportunity cost of input 2 is p2 for z ≥ z20 . For z ≤ z20 input 2 has zero marginal opportunity cost and the isocost lines are vertical. Assuming that MP2 is positive, the © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructur’s Manual, 3rd edn 78 Fig. 6C.4 firm will always use all its contracted-for workers (who have zero opportunity cost to it). It will hire more workers if their marginal product is sufficiently large that the isoquants are flatter at z20 than the isocost line. (Recall the interpretation of the shadow value (µj) of the fixed input on page 132 of the text.) The expansion path in Fig. 6C.4 is the horizontal line at z20 up to the isoquant I0 and the positively sloped curve EP thereafter. The STC curve lies above LTC up to y0 and coincides with LTC thereafter. 5. Refer to page 117 of the text for the properties of the long run cost function. Property (a): Short run cost is increasing in y if more of the variable inputs are required to produce more output and the prices of variable inputs are positive. Increases in any input price must increase total cost if a positive amount of that input is used. Property (b): The solution (zv(p, y, zk0 ), zk(p, y, zk0 )) to the short run cost minimization problem at prices p is also the solution at prices tp since S(p, y, zk0 ) = pvzv(p, y, zk0 ) + pkzk(p, y, zk0 ) ≤ pvzv + pkzk, all feasible (zv, zk) implies that tpvzv(p, y, zk0 ) + tpkzk(p, y, zk0 ) ≤ tpvzv + tpkzk, all feasible (zv, zk) Hence S(tp, y, zk0 ) = tS(p, y, zk0 ). Property (c): For continuity see Takayama (1985, pp253–254). For concavity, let ( zvi , zki ) be cost minimizing at prices pi. Then tS ( p1 , y, zk0 ) = tp1v z1v + tp1k z1k ≤ tpv3 zv3 + tpk3 zk3 (1 − t) S ( p2 , y, zk0 ) = (1 − t ) pv2 zv2 + (1 − t) pk2 zk2 ≤ (1 − t) pv3 zv3 + (1 − t) pk3 zk3 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructur’s Manual, 3rd edn 79 and adding the left hand sides of these expressions and the right hand sides gives tS ( p1 , y, zk0 ) + (1 − t) S ( p2 , y, zk0 ) ≤ [tp1v + (1 − t) pv2 ]zv3 + [tp1k + (1 − t ) pk2 ]zk3 Defining p3 = ( pv3 , pk3 ) = (tp1v + (1 − t) pv2 , tp1k + (1 − t) pk2 ) we have tS ( p1 , y, zk0 ) + (1 − t) S ( p2 , y, zk0 ) ≤ S ( p3 , y, zk0 ) which establishes that the short run cost function is concave in prices. Property (d): Define the function g( p, p0 , y, zk0 ) = S ( p, y, zk0 ) − pv zv ( p, y, zk0 ) − pk zk ( p, y, zk0 ) Now compare g with G on page 117 of the text and apply exactly the same argument to establish ∂g ∂S = − zl ( p0 , y, zk0 ) = 0, ∂pl p = p ∂pl p = p l 0 l l ᐉ = v, k 0 l which is Shephard’s Lemma for the short run cost function. Exercise 6D 1. Suppose that there are two inputs (physical plant and fuel), with each plant having a fixed proportions technology z z y = max 1 , 2 β 1i β 2i and the fixed input level z20i . The maximum output from plant i is yi0 = z20i /β 2 i and its constant short run marginal cost up to this capacity is p1β1i. Labelling the plants so that β11 < β12 . . . < β1n, the firm’s short run marginal cost curve is shown in Fig. 6D.1. The firm uses plant 1 to produce output of y10 or less, plants 1 and 2 to produce y ∈ ( y10 , y10 + y20 ) and so on. 2. (a) The Kuhn-Tucker conditions are necessary and sufficient in this cost minimization problem if the objective function in [D.1] is convex. (See Appendix H.) This requires that C(y) is convex in y. But C(ty + (1 − t)0) = C(ty) = F + vtαyα and tC(y) + (1 − t)C(0) = tC(y) = tF + tvyα where t ∈ (0, 1). Hence, when α ∈ (0, 1] the cost function is concave for all output levels since C(ty + (1 − t)0) > tC(y) + (1 − t)C(0). When α > 1, the cost function is concave for small enough t (small enough output) since limt→0 C(ty) = F > limt→0 tC(y) = 0 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 80 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructur’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 6D.1 Hence the Kuhn-Tucker conditions cannot be used to identify the optimal least cost plant allocation: when the plant cost functions are concave it may be less costly to allocate all output to one plant so as to incur only one fixed cost. 2. (b) When α = 1, C(y) = F + vy and average cost is v + F/y which declines with y. Hence there are economies of scale for all output levels. When α > 1 the cost function is of the form shown in Fig. 6.14 in the text. There are economies of scale (declining average cost) up to W, defined by the equality of marginal and average cost: F + vWα−1 = αvWα−1 W and we can solve for 1 F F W= = 2v v(α − 1) α 1 3 when α = 3. 2. (c) When α = 1, so that C = F + vy, marginal cost is constant and equal in the two plants. It is never cost minimizing to use both plants and incur two fixed costs. When α > 1 it is cost minimizing to use two plants for sufficiently large total output because the saving in variable costs will more than offset the additional fixed cost. The critical total output J above which it is cheaper to use two plants is defined by J F + vJα = 2F + 2v 2 α and solving we have 1 F 4F = J= 1−α 3v v(1 − 2 ) α 1 3 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructur’s Manual, 3rd edn 81 Thus, since W < J, there is a range of output over which there is subadditivity and diseconomies of scale. Exercise 6E 1. (a) Recall from Appendix I of the text that a function is concave if the principal minors of its Hessian alternate in sign, with the first prinipal minor being negative. The second derivatives of C are 1 − 1 − 1 − C ii = − yi − yi y j = − yi (1 + y j ) 4 4 4 3 2 3 2 1 2 3 2 1 2 1 − yi y j 4 1 2 C ij = 1 2 Since Cii < 0 the first principal minor is negative. The second principal minor is C11C22 − C122 = [ 1 − ( y1y2 ) (1 + y1 )(1 + y2 ) − ( y1y2 ) −1 16 3 2 1 2 1 2 ] which is positive since the first term in square brackets is − 32 − 32 1 2 1 2 ( y1y2 ) + ( y1y2 ) −1 + ( y1y2 ) ( y1 + y2 ) which is greater than the second term. Hence C is concave in (y1, y2). 1. (b) Refer to the text definition [E.5] of multi-product economies of scale. We have, at t = 1, Etc = ∑ C C = ∑ 2 y (1 + y ) C 1 yit i = − 12 i i 1 2 yi j i [ 1 y1 + 2( y1y2 ) + y2 2C 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 ( y + y2 ) + ( y1y2 ) = 2 1 ( y1 + y2 ) + ( y1y2 ) 1 2 1 2 ] 1 2 1 2 < 1 This holds for all output vectors, so there are global economies of scale. 1. (c) There are economies of scope over y ∈ [0, y0] if [E.7] holds over this interval. Since 1 2 C(y1, 0, p) = y1 1 2 C(0, y2, p) = y2 and we have 1 2 1 2 C(y1, 0, p) + C(0, y2, p) = y1 + y2 1 2 1 2 < y1 + y2 + ( y1y2 ) = C(y1, y2, p) © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 1 2 82 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructur’s Manual, 3rd edn Thus C does not exhibit economies of scope: separate production of the two goods is less costly. 1. (d) Since Cij = 14 ( y1y2 ) − 12 > 0, the cost function does not have cost complementarity. 1. (e) To see that C is not globally subadditive it suffices to show that there is some pair of output vectors y′ = ( y1′ , y2′ ), y ′′( y1′′, y2′′) such that C(y′ + y″, p) < C(y′, p) + C(y″, p) Setting y′ = (y1, 0) and y″ = (0, y2), we see that the inequality in part (c) above establishes that the cost function is not globally subadditive. Hence economies of scope are necessary for subadditivity. The example in the text ([E.9]) shows that they are not sufficient. Supplementary question (i) Sketch the contours of C in output space. Is it quasi-convex or quasi-concave? Use the contours to illustrate the various concepts in parts (a) to (e). 2. (a) In the definition of cost complementarity [E.10], choose output vectors y1 = 0, y2 = y, y3 = y, so that [E.10] implies C(2y, p) − C(y, p) < C(y, p) − C(0, p) = C(y, p) or C(2y, p) < 2C(y, p) Hence costs increase less than proportionately with output: there are economies of scale. 2. (b) Now let y1 = (0, 0), y2 = (y1, 0), y3 = (0, y2) and apply [E.10] to get C(y1 + y2, p) − C(y1, 0, p) < C(0, y2, p) which implies [E.7] so that there are economies of scope. Supplementary question (i) Over what, if any, ranges of outputs do the following functions exhibit economies of scale, economies of scope; subadditivity? 1 4 1 4 C = y1 + y2 − ( y1y2 ) 1 4 C = 1 + (y1 + y2)2 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 83 Chapter 7 Supply and Firm Objectives Exercise 7A 1. Assuming that both inputs are used at the optimum, the first order conditions are pfi − pi = 0, i = 1, 2 These conditions can be rearranged to yield f1 p1 = f2 p2 p= p1 p2 = f1 f2 the first of which is the usual cost minimization condition that the slope of the isoquant equals the slope of the isocost line (see [B.4] in chapter 6). Recalling the discussion of LMC in section 6B, we see that the second of these conditions is the requirement that the firm adjust its inputs (and hence its output) until price equals marginal cost. 2. (a),(b) The firm will plan to produce where p = LMC and p ≥ LAC. The LAC and LMC curves for firms with diminishing returns to scale (diseconomies of scale) and constant returns to scale are shown in parts (a) and (b) of Fig. 7A.1. 2. (c) A firm with increasing returns to scale will have LMC < LAC and planning to produce where p = LMC would be planning to produce at a loss. It could do better by closing down and avoiding the loss. 3. (a) C(y, p) increases with pi if input i is used by the firm and so average cost increases at all output levels, including that for which LAC is minimized. 3. (b) The output W at which LAC is minimized satisfies LAC = LMC or C(W, p) − Cy(W, p)W = 0 Using the implicit function rule gives −( C p − C yp W) C p − C yp W ∂W = = ∂pi C y − C yy W − C y C yy W i i i i © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 83 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 84 Fig. 7A.1 Fig. 7A.2 Since LMC cuts LAC from below at W, Cyy(W, p) > 0. The numerator can be rearranged, using Shephard’s lemma, to get Cp − Cyp W = zi − i i ∂zi W = zi(1 − ez y) ∂y i where ez y is the elasticity of demand for input i with respect to output. Thus W increases or decreases with pi as the demand for input i decreases or increases more than in proportion with output. i 2. (c) Since Cyp = ∂zi/∂y, LMC increases or decreases with pi as zi is normal or regressive. In Fig. 7A.2(a) we have assumed ez y = 1. In part (b) note that the fact the input is regressive implies both that the LMC curve shifts down and that the output at which LAC is minimized increases. i i Supplementary question (i) What is the effect of input prices on W if the production function is Cobb-Douglas, CES or Leontief? © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 85 Fig. 7B.1 Exercise 7B 1. In part (a) of Fig. 7B.1 the firm wrongly forecast a price of pwf and installed plant which gave it the SMCw curve through w. The actual price is pa > pwf. Given its mistaken forecast and actual SMCw curve the firm maximises profit with output ya. The firm’s total cost at ya is the area under LMC up to output yw plus the area under SMCw between yw and ya. (Remember that at output yw short and long run cost are equal since the installed plant was designed to produce yw.) Hence its profit given its wrong forecast is the area gawh. If its forecast had been right it would have installed plant which gave it the SMCr and produced and output of yr. Its profit would then have been the area grwh. Thus its wrong forecast reduces its profit by the area war. The firm loses from a wrong forecast because it finds itself with the inappropriate plant size. This reduces its profit in two ways: it has a higher marginal cost and therefore earns less profit over the output range yw to ya and it produces a different (smaller) output. Part (b) of the figure illustrates the case in which the wrongly forecast price exceeds the actual price: pwf > pa. The firm’s cost given its actual wrongly chosen plant size is the area under its LMC up to yw less the area under its SMCw curve between yw and ya. Hence its profit is the area grwh less the area war. If it had correctly forecast that price would pa it would have installed plant such that it faced the SMCr curve and produced output yr. Its profit with a correct forecast would have been the area grwh. Hence its reduction in profit from the wrong forecast is the area war. 2. Comparing the size of the areas war in parts (a) and (b) of Fig. 7B.1 it is apparent that the answer depends on the precise curvature of the long and short run marginal cost curves. The firm could be better or worse off being overly optimistic compared with being overly pessimistic. 3. At each date the firm will make two decisions. Given its fixed input, the price of output and the actual price of the variable input it chooses its output level. It also makes a forecast of the prices of the variable input, the fixed input and its output and chooses a plant size such that its forecast LMC is equal to the forecast output price. The firm’s actual output decision is made by comparing current output price with © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 86 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 7B.2 actual short run marginal cost (determined by the actual variable input price and the amount of the fixed plant chosen last period). The firm’s forecast prices are relevant for its plant size decision but have no direct influence on its actual output in any period, which is determined by equating actual short run marginal cost and actual output price. Supplementary question (i) Illustrate the firm’s decisions over output and plant size in a diagram analogous to Fig. 7.3 in the text. 4. See Fig. 7B.2. The discussion of the relationship between short and long run cost functions in section 6B of the text explained why the short run total cost curve is tangent to the long run total cost curve from above and hence why SMC cuts LMC from leads it to install below at the tangency output. In Fig. 7B.2 the firm’s forecast of pt+1 f 1 a plant which gives rise to the SMC curve in period t + 1. When the actual price turns out to be pat+1 it produces the output yat+1 . It correctly forecasts that the price in period t + 2 will be the same as the actual period t + 1 price: p tf+ 2 = pat+ 2 = pat+1 and chooses its plant for period t + 2 so that LMC = ptf+2 . In period t + 2 it faces the SMC 2 curve and produces yat+2 . Hence its long run supply response is greater than its short run response. This must always be the case for small output price variations since for small output variations around the planned output the SMC curve is always steeper than the LMC curve. The cost curves in Fig. 6.11 in the text are an example where the relationship between long and short run responses to a large price change would be the same as to a small price change. Fig. 7B.3 gives an example where the long run response would be smaller than the short run response for a large price change like that from p′ to p″. Exercise 7C 1. (a) Refer to the definition of separability in production (text page 110). Since production is separable the firm’s cost function for the output vector (y1, . . . , yn) is C(y1, . . . , yn) = ∑ C (y ) i i i © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 87 Fig. 7B.3 where C i(yi) is the cost function resulting from minimizing wzi to produce yi subject to the production function yi = f i(zi) for product i. The profit function if production is separable can be written π = ∑ ( piyi − C i ( yi )) i and the first order conditions on output i for maximization of π are pi − C yi (yi) = 0 i = 1, . . . , n If each product division was told to maximize its own profits π i = piyi − C i(yi) it would also choose an output satisfying pi = C yi (yi). Hence separate maximization of division profits implies maximization of total firm profits. The actions of a division (input and output choices) do not affect the profit of any other division. Note that, in addition to separability in production (which implies that the cost function of the firm is separable), this result requires that there is no interdependence in the firm’s markets, so that changes in input or output decisions have no effect on the prices faced by any other division. 1. (b) Suppose that the firm’s cost function is C(y1, y2) = C 0 + C 1(y1) + C 2(y2) © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 88 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn where C0 is a fixed administrative cost which must be incurred to produce any output but which does not vary with the output of either good. The rule for allocating the fixed cost is that division i is debited with kiC0, ∑ki = 1, ki ≥ 0. Hence the profit of division i is piyi − C i(yi) − kiC 0 i = 1, 2 and separate profit maxization leads to pi − C yi ( yi ) − C 0 dk i =0 dyi (7.1) This is only compatible with firm profit maximization if dki/dyi = 0 and for the three allocation rules we have ki = p1a1 p1a1 + p2a2 ⇒ dk i =0 dyi ki = p1y1 p1y1 + p2y2 ⇒ dk i >0 dyi ⇒ dk i >0 dyi C1 k = 1 C + C2 i Thus only the first of these allocation rules leads to profit maximization for the firm as a whole. Since the firm operates in competitive markets the product prices, and thus the shares ki, are not affected by output changes. If any of the firm’s goods were sold in monopolized markets then even this first allocation rule would not lead to profit maximization for the firm as a whole. Note that in the specification of the first allocation rule we need some dimensionality constants so that the prices of different goods can sensibly be added and the share ki is not affected by arbitrary changes in the units in which the goods are measured. 1. (c) No. Consider the following case, in which for simplicity the cost allocation shares are independent of the division outputs and the output levels chosen maximize the firm’s profit. Suppose that at these output levels p1y1 − C1 − k1C 0 < 0 p2y2 − C 2 − k2C 0 > 0 p2y2 − C 2 − C 0 < 0 ∑( pi y i − C i − k i C 0 ) = ∑( pi y i − C i ) − C 0 > 0 The firm would first be led to close down the “unprofitable” division 1. It would then find that after attributing all the central administrative costs to the remaining division 2 that division 2 now makes a loss and should also be shut down. Thus the firm would cease production despite the fact that it makes a positive profit by operating both divisions. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 89 1. (d) A sufficient condition for shutting down a division is that its separate contribution to any central costs is negative: piyi − Ci < 0 (7.2) Clearly, shutting down a single division which makes a non-negative contribution cannot increase overall profit. However, it is possible that after closing all divisions which satisfy (7.2) the firm will find that even though all its remaining divisions have piyi − C i ≥ 0 it may be better off closing down entirely because ∑(piyi − C i) − C 0 < 0 where the sum is over the divisions which make positive contributions. Supplementary question (i) Would separate maximization of division profits imply maximization of firm profits if (a) the firm was a monopolist for some of its products? (b) was a monopsonist for some its inputs? (c) if some of its products were substitutes? Exercise 7D 1. Part (a) of Fig. 7D.1 shows a production possibility set with the property that for some relative prices the firm’s optimal netput vector is not unique and over some ranges of relative prices the optimal netput does not vary with relative prices. Part (b) plots the resulting supply function for the output (positive netput) y2 against the price ratio r = p1/p2. The firm’s optimal netput is not unique at price ratio r′ since at this price ratio the slope of the isoprofit lines is equal to the slope of the upper boundary of the production possibility set between a and b. The kink at a means that for all r ∈ [r″, r′] the firm chooses the same netput a. Similarly for all r ∈ [r′, r′″] the firm chooses b. Thus we get the vertical segments of the supply function in part (b). Note that at the price ratio r′ the supply function is drawn as a horizontal line: strictly speaking there is a supply correspondence at this price ratio since r′ does not map into a unique netput. Supplementary questions (i) Is the supply function continous if PS is convex, or if strictly convex, or if concave? (ii) What are the implications of the PS in Fig. 7D.1 for the firm’s demand for its input (netput 1)? 2. Let prices of the output and the inputs increase from (p, w) at date 0, when the firm makes its production plan and purchases its inputs, to (kp, kw), k ≥ 1 at date 1, when production takes place, the output is sold and the firm is taxed. Its recorded profit at date 1 for tax purposes is kpy − wz so that it pays tax of t(kpy − wz). At date 0 the firm correctly anticipates the price changes and makes its input decision to maximize its after tax profit k(py − wz) − t(kpy − wz) = (1 − t)kpy − (k − t)wz © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 90 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 7D.1 subject to its production function. Equivalently, the firm chooses its output to maximize )(y, k, t) = (1 − t)kpy − (k − t)C(y, w) (The firm would choose the same input mix to produce output y at prices w and at prices (k − t)w and so its cost function, allowing for the tax and the change in prices, is C(y, (k − t)w) = (k − t)C(y, w).) The first order condition for maximization of ) is )y = (1 − t)kp − (k − t)Cy(y, w) = 0 (7.3) k−t Cy(y, w) ≥ Cy(y, w) k(1 − t) (7.4) which implies p= Hence the combined effect of the tax on recorded profit and inflation is to make the firm act as if it faced a marginal cost curve which has been shifted upward. It will therefore produce a smaller output than it would if either there was no inflation (k = 1) or no tax (t = 0). More formally, we can apply the simple comparative static method (text, Appendix I, page 699) to examine the effect of an increase in the tax. Partially differentiating (7.3) with respect to t gives )yt = −(kp − Cy) ≤ 0 which is negative when k > 1 (see (7.4)). Supplementary question (i) Show that increases in the rate of inflation reduce the firm’s output when t > 0. What happens if there is a correctly anticipated deflation? © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 91 Exercise 7E 1. If the entrepreneur has an initial endowment of income J the intercepts of the P(E) and I0 curves in text Fig. 7.8 shift up by this amount, but otherwise the analysis is unchanged. The point of this question is to say that the absence of endowed income in the analysis in the text does not really matter. 2. We know for the quasi-linear utility function that indifference curves in (E, y)-space are vertical displacements of each other (see question 2, Exercise 3C), and so this utility function gives the type of preferences for which utility maximization and profit maximization (in the absence of a market in entrepreneurial input) are equivalent. Quite simply, for any contour G(E) + y = E we have that dy = − G′( E ) dE and so since this slope depends only on E and not on y indifference curves have the same slopes along any vertical line. We leave to the reader the details of working through the model, as in [E.2] to [E.7], with this utility function. 3. This question is exploring a little more deeply the factors underlying the P(E) function in the model, and is concerned more with comparative-statics than whether the firm is profit-maximizing. A general outline of the analysis is given in Fig. 7E.1. Essentially, an increase in output price p or a fall in input price pz can be expected to change the P(E) curve in the way shown. The location of the new equilibrium is ambiguous, for the familiar reason that both income and substitution effects are involved. The substitution effect of the kind of change shown would always increase the entrepreneur’s effort supply, since the marginal return to effort has increased. However, at any level of E the entrepreneur is now better off, and if leisure is normal this will tend to reduce effort supply. Of course, we know that in the quasi-linear case of question 2, income effects are absent and effort supply will increase. Given that the effects of the change on E are ambiguous in the general case, we should not be surprised if the effects on q and z are also ambiguous, as can be confirmed by carrying out the comparative-statics. Of more interest is the question: suppose the entrepreneur’s preferences correspond to the case in which she maximizes profits, so that the introduction of these preferences makes no difference to the equilibrium choice; then could it be the case that the comparative-statics responses might still differ? To explore this question we adopt the quasi-linear preferences of question 2 and set up the following model. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 92 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 7E.1 The entrepreneur seeks to solve max g(E) + y s.t. y = pq − pzz q = f(E, z) g(E) + y ≥ u0 where u0 is her reservation utility. We assume, as illustrated in Fig. 7.8 of the text, that at the equilibrium the constraint is non-binding. We can use the constraints to simplify the problem to max g(E) + pf(E, z) − pzz E ,z with first-order conditions g′(E*) + pfE(E*, z*) = 0 pfz(E*, z*) − pz = 0. Clearly, the condition on employment of z is exactly that which would be satisfied for a profit-maximizing firm (and this is true also for a more general utility function), while the first condition essentially expresses the tangency solution of Fig. 7.8. For the comparative-statics, differentiating through totally gives the system g ′′ + pf EE pf zE pf Ez dE − f E dp = pfzz dz dpz − fz dp From the second-order conditions the matrix, denoted D, has determinant D > 0. We obtain the comparative-statics effects ∂E p( fz f Ez − f E fzz ) = >0 ∂p D ∂E − pf Ez = <0 ∂pz D © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 93 ∂z pf E fzE − fz ( g ′′ + pf EE ) = >0 ∂p D ∂z g ′′ + pf EE = <0 ∂pz D The signs are unambiguous if we assume, reasonably, that g″, fzz and fEE are all negative and that fzE > 0 (the inputs are “cooperant”). For these assumptions a straightforward profit-maximizing model would give the same results, and so we can confirm that if the special assumptions on preferences hold under which an entrepreneur chooses a profitmaximizing equilibrium, her comparative-statics responses will also be those predicted by a profit-maximizing model, at least qualitatively. If there is free entry into the industry, we expect it to take place until the “marginal entrepreneur”, for whom entry is just worthwhile, is earning just about her reservation utility. Any entrepreneurs with lower opportunity costs or who are more productive than this will therefore be earning rents in long-run equilibrium. If all entrepreneurs are identical then long-run equilibrium occurs at the point of tangency between P(E) and I0 in Fig. 7.8 of the text. 4. If the entrepreneur prefers to work for herself than for someone else, even though work of any kind creates a disutility, we can model this by distinguishing two kinds of effort: Eo is the work for herself; Em is work supplied to the market. The utility function is then u(Eo, Em, y), with uo < 0, um < 0, uy > 0, in an obvious notation. The idea that work for herself is preferable could be expressed by restricting − dE m uo = >1 dEo um implying that an hour’s work on the market trades off for less than an hour’s work for oneself, at any given income level. We also specify of course that u is strictly quasiconcave. We can then formulate the entrepreneur’s problem as max u(Eo, Em, y) s.t. y = P(Eo + EB) + wEm − wEB, Eo + Em = T, Eo , Em , EB ≥ 0 where EB is the entrepreneurial input bought in from the market at wage rate w. Note that we assume that bought-in input is just as productive as the entrepreneur’s own input. It is also also necessary to specify non-negativity conditions explicitly, since corner solutions are quite possible. Substituting for y in the utility function, we obtain first-order conditions u0 + uyP′ − λ ≤ 0, Eo ≥ 0, Eo[u0 + uyP′ − λ] = 0 uy(P′ − w) ≤ 0, EB ≥ 0, EB[uyP′ − w] = 0 um + uyw − λ ≤ 0, Em ≥ 0, Em[um + uyw − λ] = 0. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 94 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn The first result we can establish is that if working for oneself is always preferable to working in the market, we cannot have simultaneously Eo > 0, Em > 0 and EB > 0. For suppose this is true. Then the first-order conditions are strict equalities. Then w = P ′, and eliminating λ gives uo + uyw = um + uyw ⇒ uo = um or uo =1 um which we have assumed cannot be true. In fact there are two possible cases: 1. Eo > 0, EB > 0, Em = 0. In that case it is straightforward to show that we have an equilibrium given by conditions [E.11]–[E.13] of the text. 2. Eo > 0, Em > 0, EB = 0. From the second condition we have (non-trivially) P ′ < w, and so Eo is extended beyond the point at which a wage line is tangent to the P(E ) curve. The extent of this difference is determined by the condition uo um = + ( w − P ′) uy uy so that the lower return for work within the firm than for work outside simply reflects the stronger preference for the former. 5. Arranging private patients in order of fee per minute gives, we assume, a function P(E) (ignore the discreteness of the real world and assume this is differentiable). The fee per unit time offered by the health service is equivalent to the wage rate w in the model of the entrepreneurial input market. Thus we can represent the physician’s choice of time allocation by this model, and his possible equilibria are described by Fig. 7.9 of the text (assuming he can also hire other physicians to work for him at the health service fee, and that he has no preference for working for himself). Thus he will work both for the health service and for himself if he is at the equilibrium γ shown in Fig. 7.9. If he is now forced to choose either to work for himself or for the health service, then we have to find (a) the point of tangency of an indifference curve with P(E); (b) the point of tangency of an indifference curve with the wage line 0w; and compare the utility levels achieved in each case. As Fig. 7.9 is drawn, the physician will choose to work for himself, since the point in (a) will certainly be above the point in (b). However, it is quite possible to construct a figure which gives the result that he would choose the health service (Hint: 0w must intersect P(E)). If he was previously at a point such as γ, then the introduction of the forced choice will certainly reduce his income and utility, though the effects on his effort are ambiguous, this could rise or fall. In the case drawn in Fig. 7.9 effort must fall, but again cases can be constructed in which effort would increase. Finally, return to the case where he can supply effort both to the health service and private practice. A tax on private earnings shifts the P(E) curve in Fig. 7.9 downward while leaving 0w unchanged. If, as we might expect, the new curve is flatter at every E (the tax reduces the marginal return to effort supplied to private practice) then effort supplied to private practice will certainly fall, while that supplied to the health service © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 95 could rise, fall or remain unchanged depending on the size of the income effect of the tax (suppose the new overall equilibrium is somewhere along UU in Fig. 7.9 of the text). Exercise 7F 1. With F = 0, [F.3] of the text becomes pfN = pf(N*)/N* The comparative-statics now become f p f pfNNdN + f N − dp + pf N* − p = 0 N N N But the second and third terms are zero by the first-order condition, and so we must have dN = 0. Diagrammatically, both fN and f/N increase by the same amount at N*, and so the employment level is unchanged. Thus a fixed cost is required to achieve the strong form of Ward’s result. At the same time, the result that an increase in output price leads to no increase in output and employment is still very striking. 2. Let NO denote outside workers so that the total labour force is NI + NO. The production function is f(NI + NO), and the market wage is w. Then the inside workers seek to maximize yI = [pf(NI + NO) − wNO]/NI. We assume that at the equilibrium, NO > 0. Then the first-order condition is: ∂y I = (pf′ − w)/NI = 0 ⇒ pf′ = w ∂N O Note there is no condition with respect to NI because we assume there is a fixed number of inside workers. Thus the firm acts just like a profit-maximizer in choosing its aggregate employment level and hence the number of outside workers. The comparative-statics will also be identical. 3. The income of the representative worker is again y = [pf(Nl, N) − F]/N where F is the fixed cost of capital. First, proceed by solving max u = v[(pf(Nl, N) − F)/N] − l l, N giving first-order conditions: v′pf1 − 1 = 0 ⇒ pf1 = 1/v′ v′ (pf1l* − (pf − F)/N*) = 0 ⇒ pf1l* = (pf − F)/N* N © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 96 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn where f1 is the marginal product of labour. The first condition says that given the optimal number of workers N* (note that N is treated as a real number rather than an integer), the amount of time each works, l*, is set so that the marginal revenue product of labour is just equal to the worker’s marginal rate of substitution between income and effort, 1/v′. This can be thought of as the worker’s supply price. The second condition says that the number of workers (each working the optimal time l*) is adjusted to the point at which an additional worker adds just as much to revenue ( pf ′l*) as she is paid (( pf − F)/N*), just as in the Ward-Vanek model. The notation in the comparative-statics will be simplified if we denote ( pf − F )/N by y and its partial derivatives by yj, j = l, N, p. Moreover, note that yN = 0 from the first-order condition. Then differentiating through the first-order conditions gives the system: v′′yl pf1 + v′pf11 N pf + pf lN − y 11 l 1 v′pf11l dl − v′f1 = dp pf11l 2 dN y p − f1l Then solving for dl gives ∂l − y p v′pf11l = >0 |D | ∂p The sign on this derivative follows from the facts that f11 < 0 because of the strict concavity of the production function, and |D| > 0 from the second-order condition (D is the square matrix in the above system). Thus an increase in price, since it increases the marginal value product of work, increases each worker’s labour supply. The lack of ambiguity in this case arises because income effects are excluded by the special form of utility function. Solving for dN gives ∂N f = v′′( pf1 )2 − f1l + f11 Nl /| D | < 0 N ∂p To explain this result, note that we again have f11 < 0, |D| > 0. The first term in the numerator is also negative if f/N > f1l (since v″ < 0 and recall yl = pf1). This is assured because f is strictly concave in Nl. Thus, although this model is in many respects less special and more ‘reasonable’ than the simple Ward-Vanek model, we still have the result that the number of workers falls when output price increases. This is because of the sharing rule, y = ( pf − F )/N: an increase in price increases the cost of the marginal worker by more than she adds to revenue, so she is fired. 4. (a) When choosing her consumption level consumer-owner i will take the price set by her firm as given. She will however realise that she will receive a proportion θi of any change in profit generated by her purchase and will take this into account in choosing her consumption of the firm’s product. Thus she realises that the firm’s profit π is defined implicitly by p ∑ xj(p, Jj + θjπ) − c(x) − π = 0 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 (7.1) Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 97 where xj(p, Jj + θjπ) is the demand by j. In general an increase in purchases by i changes profit directly by altering revenue and costs and indirectly because the change in firm profit alters the demand by all owners. Hence, using the implicit function rule dπ p − c ′( x) = dxi 1 − [ p − c ′( x)] ∑ i≠ j x jJθ j (7.2) where x jJ is the change in demand induced by an increase in j ’s income. Fortunately we have assumed that changes in income have no effect on demand by any owner ( x jJ = 0, ∀j) and so (7.2) simplifies to dπ = p − c′(x) dxi The Lagrangean for the consumer-owner’s choice of xi is L = ui(xi, yi) + λ[Ji + θiπ − yi − pxi] (7.3) and the first order conditions are dπ Lx = uxi + λ θ i − p = uxi − λ[p − θi(p − c′(x))] = 0 dxi (7.4) Ly = uyi − λ = 0 (7.5) i i plus the budget constraint. Thus i acts as if she faced a price of Yi = p − θi[p − c′(x)]. 4. (b) An increase in the price p has two effects on i: as a consumer she is worse off but as a part-owner she may be better or worse off depending on whether the firm’s profit is increased. Using the implicit function rule on (7.1) and remembering our assumption that the income elasticity of demand is zero for all owners, we have x + [ p − c ′( x)]x p dπ = = x + [p − c′(x)]xp dp 1 − [ p − c ′( x)] ∑ x jJθ j where xp = ∑∂xj /∂p. From the envelope theorem (Appendix J) the marginal effect of an increases in p on i, given that she has chosen xi optimally, is the partial derivative of her Lagrangean (7.3) with respect to p dπ ∂L = λ θ i − xi ∂p dp = λ{θi[x + (p − c′)xP] − xi} ( p − c ′ ) x p p xi = λx θ i 1 + − p x x ( p − c ′) = λx θ i 1 + e − δ i p © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 (7.6) 98 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Setting this expression equal to zero and rearranging gives the optimal price – marginal cost margin in the question. Note that the weights attached to the conflicting interests of i as shareholder and consumer are shown by her share of the profit θi and of total consumption δi. If she does not consume any of the product she will wish the firm to maximize profit. If she owns a smaller proportion of the firm than her share in its output θi < δi she will wish the firm to price below marginal cost. Since the price which is optimal for i varies with θi and δi shareholders will disagree about the price the firm should set unless θi/δi is the same for all shareholders. Supplementary question (i) Many companies offer their shareholders the opportunity to buy their products at prices below those offered to non-shareholders. For example British Home Stores gives shareholders vouchers entitling them to 10% off the marked price of goods sold in their stores. Why do firms use this form of price discrimination? What are the optimal discriminatory prices at which goods would be sold to shareholders and to nonshareholders? 5. The proportional rate of income tax satisfies the public sector budget constraint G = π + tJ and so t= G−π J Hence we can write the Lagrangean for the i’th consumer-taxpayer’s consumption decision as L = ui(xi, yi) + λ[(1 − t)Ji − yi − pxi] ( J + π − G) = ui(xi, yi) + λ Ji − yi − pxi J J J = ui(xi, yi) + λ i ( J − G) + i π − yi − pxi J J Thus apart from the first term, this is identical in form to the Lagrangean (7.3) in question 1 with Ji /J replacing θi. For the purposes of this problem we can therefore think of i as the “owner” of a proportion of the public sector firm. Hence the price which each “owner” prefers the public firm to set will depend on their income relative to total income and their share in total consumption. Thus we would expect individuals with higher incomes to favour a price closer to the profit maximizing level. The analogy between ownership of shares in a private firm quoted on the stock exchange and “ownership” of a public sector firm via the taxation system can be helpful but it should not be taken too far. In particular the two situations are certainly not equivalent in respect of the ability of the individual to cease being an “owner”. The taxpayer “owner” of a public firm can only vary her share of the firm by changing her income relative to total income and can only divest herself completely by emigrating. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 99 She does not have one crucial ownership right: the ability to sell her share in the firm’s profits or losses. 6. The i’th consumer’s budget constraint is Ji + px x π − yi − pxi = Ji + i (px − c(x)) − yi − pxi pxi x = Ji − c( x ) xi − yi x Denoting average cost by A(x) ≡ c(x)/x the Lagrangean is L = ui(xi, yi) + λ[Ji − A(x)xi − yi] and since x = ∑xj the first order condition on the choice of xi is uxi − λ[A(x) + A′(x)xi] = 0 Thus the individual acts as if faced with a price, equal to average cost, which may vary with the amount bought. If average cost is constant then A = c′ and she acts as if facing a perfectly competitive firm which sells at a price equal to marginal cost. The price paid has no effect on the individual’s budget constraint since any payment made is returned to her via the cooperative dividend and she bears only a proportion xi /x of the total cost of the firm. Hence the nominal price is irrelevant. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 100 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Chapter 8 The Theory of a Competitive Market Exercise 8A 1. For the firm the effective supply function is (from [A.4] of the text): yj = sj(p, w(z(y(p)))) = sj(p) dy j dp = s jp + s jw w′( z) z ′( y) dy = s ′j ( p) > 0 dp because sjp > 0, w′(z) < 0 (pecuniary economies), sjw < 0, z′(y) > 0, dy/dp > 0. For the market y= ∑ y = ∑ s ( p) = s( p) j j j j ∑ j s jp dy = 0 dp 1 − w′( z) z ′( y) ∑ j s jw With pecuniary external economies w′(z) < 0. This ensures that the supply function for the individual firm slopes upward, but we now have ambiguity regarding the sign of the slope of the market supply function. External pecuniary economies might result if input suppliers had production processes with increasing returns to scale. If labour is the variable input one could imagine circumstances in which the expansion of output in a given industry in a particular city would encourage skilled workers to locate in that region, thereby reducing an individual firm’s cost of hiring in terms of training expenses or actual wages paid. 2. yj = sj(p, a) diseconomies. sjp > 0 sja < 0. We are not including any possible pecuniary external a = a(y(p)) ay > 0 yj = sj(p, a(y(p))) dy j dp = s jp + s ja a ′( y) dy 0 dp where sjp > 0, sja < 0, a′(y) > 0 and dy/dp > 0. Thus the effective supply of a firm could have a positive, negative, or zero slope. 100 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 101 Fig. 8A.1 The change in industry supply as a result of an increase in p is dy = dp dy j ∑ dp = ∑ s + a ′(y) dp ∑ s dy jp j ja j ∑ j s jp dy = >0 dp 1 − a ′( y) ∑ j s ja because a′(y) > 0 and ∑jsja < 0. The effective industry supply is positively sloped. 3. If the supply function is continuous and non-decreasing only for p > p0, then we may have the case shown in Fig. 8.2 (b) of the text, in which an equilibrium does not exist. If the supply function must be continuous and non-decreasing for all p ≥ 0, then three cases are possible: 1. D(p0) = s(p0), in which case p0 is obviously an equilibrium. 2. D(p0) > s(p0). Then under the given assumptions an equilibrium must exist, since for a sufficiently high price p1, we have D(p1) < s(p1) and the conditions for existence are met. 3. D(p0) < s(p0). In that case it is possible that s(p0) > D(p0) at all p ≥ 0, in which case we have an equilibrium at p = 0 as long as the excess supply of the good can be disposed of costlessly (see Fig. 12.1 (d) of the text). 4. In Fig. 8A.1 the labour demand curve is continuous and strictly decreasing, the labour supply curve is backward-bending. There is no equilibrium in this market. 5. (a) A per unit tax of amount t is applied. The pre-tax equilibrium is at p0 and q0 in Fig. 8A.2. If the producer pays the tax we can consider the tax as an increase in production costs which shifts the supply curve up vertically by t. The intersection of S′ and D shows what consumers will pay (pc). Producers remit t to the government and thus receive ps (= pc − t). © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 102 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 8A.2 If the consumer pays the tax we may create a net-of-tax demand curve D′ which is vertically below D by the amount t. The intersection of S with D′ shows what producers will receive in the marketplace. This is ps as before. The consumer remits t to the government and receives pc(= ps + t). Q′ is traded as before. Hence pc, ps, and the quantity traded are independent of who pays the tax to the government formally. The incidence of the tax refers to the way in which the actual prices paid by buyers and received by sellers change. As compared to the initial equilibrium price p0, the price to buyers rises by pc − p0, and the price received by sellers falls by p0 − ps, and these two amounts (which sum to t) give the incidence of the tax. Then, we note that since the post-tax equilibrium is independent of who formally pays the tax, so is the incidence of the tax. 5. (b) Assume that the maximum price pmax is below the initial equilibrium (otherwise it is not binding). If sellers pay the tax, the supply curve in (a) of Fig. 8A.3 shifts to S′. The price consumers pay remains at pmax while the price sellers receive falls to pmax − t, where t is the amount of the tax. Thus the entire incidence of the tax falls on sellers. If buyers pay the tax, then the demand curve shifts down to D′ in (b) of Fig. 8A.3. However, this simply reduces the amount of excess demand at pmax. The price sellers receive remains at pmax, and buyers pay the price pmax + t. Thus in this case the entire incidence of the tax falls on buyers. Supplementary question. What happens if, in (b) of Fig. 8A.3, the tax paid by buyers is so large that D′ intersects S at a price below pmax? 5. (c) If there is a minimum price above the initial (no-tax) equilibrium, and sellers pay the tax, then the supply curve may shift as in (a) of Fig. 8A.4. Buyers continue to pay pmax, sellers now receive pmax − t, and so they bear the entire incidence of the tax. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 103 Fig. 8A.3 Fig. 8A.4 Supplementary question: What happens if, in (a) of Fig. 8A.4, the tax paid by sellers is so large that S′ intersects D at a price above pmax? If buyers pay the tax, then the demand curve shifts to D′ in (b) of Fig. 8A.4, the price sellers receive remains at pmin, excess supply increases, and buyers pay the price pmin + t, and so they bear the entire incidence of the tax. Exercise 8B 1. In (a) of Fig. 8B.1 the supply curve is steeper than the demand curve. Marshall’s process is stable. Below y* the demand price is above the supply price so that sellers will expand production. Likewise when y is greater than y* the supply price exceeds the demand price and sellers contract output. The Walrasian TP is unstable as excess demand increases with price. In (b) of Fig. 8B.1 the demand curve is steeper than the supply curve. As the arrows indicate Marshall’s process will now be unstable. The Walrasian TP is stable as excess demand decreases as price increases. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 104 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 8B.1 2. Cobweb cycles are more likely in the market for coffee because of the delay between planting and harvesting. Lettuce grows very rapidly so that farmers’ planting plans would be based on expectations only a few weeks into the future. There is less chance of errors in forecasting which could cause cobweb cycles. In the case of the market for lawyers, if it were competitive there is every reason to expect a cobweb phenomenon. There is quite a long supply lag, since it takes around five years to qualify as a lawyer. Moreover, young people embarking on a law degeree tend to observe current earnings of lawyers rather than to form rational expectations. However, the market for lawyers is not competitive, in that entry is controlled by the legal profession, and so we do not observe fluctuations in earnings which characterize the cobweb. 3. (a) In equilibrium we have z( p, a) = 0 = D( p, a) − s( p) Totally differentiate to get Da( p, a)da + Dp( p, a)dp − s′( p)dp = 0 Rearrange to get Da ( p, a ) dp =− da D p ( p, a ) − s ′( p) We are interested in the conditions that make dp/da > 0. We have assumed Da( p, a) is positive; for the overall expression to be positive we require Dp( p, a) − s′( p) < 0 or Dp( p, a) < s′( p). © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 105 Fig. 8B.2 Fig. 8B.3 3. (c) Consider Fig. 8B.2 where the initial excess demand function is Z( p, a0) and there are three possible initial equilibria at α0, β0 and γ0. α0 and γ0 are stable under Walrasian TP, whereas β0 is unstable. After a increases to a1 the excess demand function shifts to the right and there are again three equilibria at α1, β1 and γ1. Since under Walrasian TP it is impossible for an unstable equilibrium to be reached the new equilibrium after the shift in Z must be at one of the new stable equilibria: α1 or γ1. If the initial equilibrium was the unstable one at β0 then the new equilibrium will be at α1. After the demand shift there is positive excess demand at the original equilibrium price and under Walrasian TP the price will be driven up. 3. (d) The previous result does not hold under the Marshallian adjustment process as Fig. 8B.3 shows. The ( peculiar) demand and supply functions generate an excess demand function which has the same form as in Fig. 8B.2 but now the stable equilibrium is at β0 and the other two equilibria are unstable. If the initial equilibrium is at α0 a © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 106 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn rightward shift in the demand curve leads to price and quantity decreasing to a new equilibrium at β1. After the demand shift the demand price is less than the supply price at the initial quantity and so price and quantity must fall under the Marshallian process. If the initial equilibrium was at γ1 the same argument shows that the price and quantity will fall and no equilibrium will be established. Finally, if the initial equilibrium was at β0 the Marshallian process will drive price and quantity up to a new equilibrium at β1. 4. Adaptive expectations: We set up the linear model yt = a + bpte (the supply function) xt = α − βpt (the demand function) pte − pte−1 = k( pt −1 − pte−1 ) (0 < k < 1) Setting yt = xt for equilibrium at each t gives: a + bpte = α − βpt. Solving for pte : pte = α − βpt − a b and pte−1 = α − βpt −1 − a b Substituting gives α − βpt − a b + α − βpt −1 − a b ( k − 1) − kpt −1 = 0 Rearranging, we have the first order linear difference equation pt = k(α − a ) β bk + 1 − k − pt −1 . β Given the initial condition p0 = F, the solution to this equation is bk pt = p* + (F − p*) 1 − k − β t where p* = (α − a)/(b + β) is the equilibrium price. Then we see that as t → ∞, pt → p* if −1 < 1 − k − bk β <1 that is if 2 b >1+ > 0 k β © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 107 Fig. 8C.1 Fig. 8C.2 If b and β are both positive (demand and supply curves have the usual slopes) the right hand inequality is satisified. Then the actual price will not diverge monotonically from equilibrium. However, it could diverge with oscillations of increasing amplitude if k and b/β are sufficiently large so as to violate the left hand inequality. Exercise 8C 1. (a) As in Fig. 8C.1, each firm’s long run average cost and long run marginal cost curves will be horizontal as firms can expand output with no change in average cost. The long run market supply curve will also be horizontal at the constant long run average cost. The equilibrium output of each firm and the number of firms in the industry are indeterminate. 1. (b) As in Fig. 8C.2, each firm’s long run average and marginal cost curves are everywhere upward sloping. p* is the only long run equilibrium price where profits are zero. In the long run we would have a very large number of firms producing an infinitesimally small amount at price p*. The long run supply curve is horizontal at p*. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 108 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 8C.3 Fig. 8C.4 1. (c) As in (a) but with input prices increasing as market output increases. Although a firm could individually expand output at constant long run average cost, when all firms expand output average cost will increase. The long run market supply curve will therefore be upward sloping. 2. In Fig. 8C.3 we have an equilibrium price of p0 with a very large number of firms each producing an infinitesimal amount. If demand increases to D′(p) market output will expand via entry of new firms. Input prices will drop causing the LAC and LMC curves of the typical firm to shift down to LAC′ and LMC′. The equilibrium price drops to p1. The intersection of p1 and p0 and D′(p) are two points on the long run market supply curve S(p). In the case in which each firm has an increasing returns production function there is no determinate equilibrium. Long-run average and marginal costs are falling (see Fig. 8C.4), and so if price is taken as given – the firm’s perceived demand curve is horizontal – there is no profit-maximizing output for the firm. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 109 Fig. 8C.5 The output at which p = MC is a profit minimum, not a maximum (what is the sign of the second derivative of the profit function at that point?). In other words, the firm would seek to expand output indefinitely beyond this point. If increasing returns to scale exist over a range of outputs which is large relative to market output, we would expect the structure of the market to become imperfectly competitive. 3. (a) Naive expectations: The initial market equilibrium is at (y0, p0) in Fig. 8C.5. Firms will be making zero profits. The actual number of firms and their output are indeterminate. In year 1 demand increases to D′. Output can only expand along the short run supply function which reflects a fixed number of firms. Price in year 1 rises to p1 which must imply the firms are making positive profits. If firms expect p1 to prevail in year 2 new firms will enter the market and existing firms will expand production. However, the model as it stands tells us nothing about this process – truly naive firms would seek to expand by an infinite amount since if they really believe price will remain at p1 then every scale of output yields positive profits. Rational expectations: Under rational expectations the year 1 short run equilibrium is (p1, y1) as before. However, firms know that in year 2 p0 is the only price at which planned outputs which maximize profits at that price can actually be sold. Existing firms will expand capacity and new firms will enter to expand market output to y2. The market moves to its full long run equilibrium in year 2. Note, however, there is still something of an indeterminacy in the theory. How does each firm know by how much to expand so that aggregate output from existing and new sellers just equals the new equilibrium y2? What makes all these expansion decisions consistent? In fact there is nothing in the theory which explains this, and so the best conclusion is that even in the rational expectations case the perfectly competitive adjustment process under constant returns to scale is indeterminate. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 110 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 8C.6 3. (b) Naive expectations: The initial equilibrium is at (y0, p*) in Fig. 8C.6. Demand increases to D′(p) in year 1 and output expands along the short run supply curve s′(p) to y1 for the market (W for the firm). Firms plan for year 2 as though p1 would be the price forever. Existing firms will expand output to W2 where long run marginal cost (LMC) intersects p1. But firms are making positive profits at p1 which entices new firms to enter the market. Each new firm, given that it has identical costs to existing firms, would want to enter at a scale W2. But again the theory does not tell us anything about the number of new firms that will enter the market and so again the adjustment process is left unspecified. Rational expectations: Under rational expectations we would expect price to jump to p1 initially in year 1 (assuming the increase in demand was unanticipated). In year 2 firms would expect p* to prevail and would produce an ‘infinitesimally small’ amount with total market supply at y2. 3. (c) Naive expectations: The initial equilibrium in the market is at (y0, p0) in Fig. 8C.7. Individual firm production is indeterminate, but we assume it is at W0. Demand increases to D′(p) in year 1. Output expands along s(p); price in year 1 will be p1. Firms plan for year 2 assuming p1 will prevail. Output will expand along long run supply S(p) to y2. Individual firms’ long run average cost curves will shift up to p1 as input prices rise. Market output y2 can only be sold for price p2. At price p2 planned market output for year 3 will be determined by the long run supply curve S(p). This process will continue until the final new market equilibrium of (y*, p*) is attained. Individual firms’ long run average costs will shift as market output changes, coming to rest at p*. Rational expectations: We move directly from (y1, p1) in year 1 to (y*, p*) in year 2. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 111 Fig. 8C.7 Fig. 8C.8 4. The initial equilibrium is (y0, p0) in Fig. 8C.8 with each firm producing W0. Demand increases to D′(p). Market output expands along the short run supply curve and price in year 1 rises to p1. Existing firms expand output to W1 and make positive profits. New firms will enter the market and drive profits to zero. Since input prices are constant and all firms have identical costs, the long run supply curve must be horizontal at p0, the minimum long run average cost for all firms. Assuming rational expectations firms will be aware that p0 is the only profit maximizing price where their sales expectations will be met. Thus in year 2 all firms will again produce W0. Total market supply will have increased to y2 with the increase over y0 met entirely by an increase in the number of firms serving the market. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 112 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Chapter 9 Monopoly Exercise 9B 1. Let q = f(z1, z2) be the monopolist’s production function (with the standard properties), wi the price of input zi, i = 1, 2, p = D0(q) the inverse demand function in the current period (the short run) and p = D1(q) that in the next period (the long run). Note that the next period demand function is assumed to be known with certainty. In the current period the firm’s choices are subject to the constraint z2 ≤ z20 , while next period both inputs are unconstrained. The firm’s problems are therefore: this period (the short run): max q 0 , z1 D0(q0)q0 − w1z1 − w2 z20 s.t. q0 = f(z1, z20 ) planning for next period (the long run): max q1 , z1 , z2 D1(q1)q1 − ∑wizi s.t. q1 = f(z1, z2) Note in the short run problem we use the previous idea that the firm will find it optimal to set z2 = z20 , given that associated with the fixed input is a fixed cost. Then, from the first-order conditions for the first problem we obtain p0 + q0 D0′ = w1 / f1 ( z1 , z20 ) which is the marginal revenue = marginal cost condition (recall that marginal cost = input price / marginal product). From the first-order condition for the second problem we obtain: p1 + q1 D1′ = w1 / f1 ( z1* , z2* ) = w2 / f2 ( z1* , z2* ). Since z1* and z2* are chosen without constraint, the wi/fi ratios in this case are long-run marginal cost. Note that if we set z2 = z2* , then short-run marginal cost in the next period is w1 / f1 ( z1 , z2* ). It is straightforward to show that the z1* obtained as a solution to the long-run problem also solves the short-run problem next period, of max q1 , z1 D1(q1)q1 − w1z1 − w2z2* s.t. q1 = f ( z1 , z2* ) 112 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 113 Fig. 9B.1 For suppose there exists some X1 ≠ z1* such that D1(f(X1, z2* )) f ( X1 , z2* ) − w1X1 − w2 z2* > D1 ( f ( z1* , z2* )) f ( z1* , z2* )) − w1 z1* − w2 z2* Then this contradicts the fact that ( z1* , z2* ) solves the long-run maximization problem. 2. In Fig. 9B.1 we show the monopoly’s profit-maximizing equilibrium for the case in which there are increasing returns to scale. Note that the second-order condition is satisfied. Supplementary question: Draw figures illustrating the case of increasing returns to scale in which the monopoly’s second-order conditions are not satisfied. 3. (a) Let the monopolist’s revenue function be R(q, a), with Ra > 0, Rqa > 0, so that increases in a increase both total and marginal revenue at each output. Then the monopoly’s first-order condition on optimal output q* is Rq(q*, a) − C′(q*) = 0. Differentiating totally and rearranging gives Rqa dq * =− da Rqq − C ′′ where we require that Rqq ≠ C″. Since we normally assume R is strictly concave in q, Rqq < 0, and if C″ ≥ 0 (non-decreasing marginal cost) then we immediately have dq*/da > 0. However, if C″ < 0 and is sufficiently large relative to Rqq that Rqq − C″ > 0, then we may have dq*/da < 0. Note, however, that the second-order condition for a maximum is that Rqq − C″ < 0, and so if q* is a true maximum we have that increasing a increases output. For the effect on price, write the demand function as q = D(p, a), Dp < 0, Da > 0, and write the profit function as π(p, a) = pD(p, a) − C(D(p, a)). © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 114 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Then the first-order condition is πp = D + pDp − C′Dp = 0 and the second-order condition is πpp = 2Dp + pDpp − C ′′D p2 − C′Dpp < 0. From now on we assume the second-order condition (which is essentially equivalent to the condition Rqq − C″ < 0) is satisfied. Now totally differentiating through the first-order condition gives πppdp + [Da − C″DpDa +(p − C′)Dpa] da = 0 and so rearranging gives [ D a − C ′′D p D a + ( p − C ′) D pa dp =− da π pp ] Since πpp < 0 the sign of dp/da will be that of the bracketed expression in the numerator, which of course is πpa. Since Dp < 0, and since we know that p > C′ at the equilibrium, it is sufficient for this expression to be positive that Da > 0 and Dpa, C″ ≥ 0. However, perverse results are possible, even with πpp < 0, if Dpa < 0 and C″ < 0. 3. (b) In this case the monopolist’s profit function becomes C(q) + tq where t is the tax per unit of output. In effect the monopolist’s marginal cost curve shifts up by the amount of the tax. The first-order condition is now R′(q) − C′(q) − t = 0 and the second-order condition is unchanged. The comparative-statics effect on output is dq 1 = <0 dt R ′′ − C ′′ where the sign follows from the second-order condition. Since the demand function is unchanged, we have the effect on price as simply dp /dq dp dp dq = = >0 dt dq dt R ′′ − C ′′ since the demand function has a negative slope. 3. (c) After tax profits are defined as ) = (1 − τ)(R(q) − C(q)) where τ is the profit tax rate. From the first-order condition (1 − τ)[R′ − C′] = 0 we see that the profit tax leaves the equilibrium unaffected. Overall, we see that the comparative-statics effects are broadly similar to those for the competitive firm, except © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 115 that in the case of a demand shift there is greater scope for ambiguity of results under monopoly. 4. We assume that you, the regulator, have full knowledge of the cost and demand functions of the monopoly and are free to choose any instrument. Then four possible methods are: 1. Set a maximum price F = D(Z) = C′(Z). The monopolist will then produce output Z because this maximizes its profit at this maximum price: in effect it is confronted with a horizontal demand curve at F for outputs q < Z, and so none of these outputs yields higher profit than Z. 2. Set a minimum output Z. The monopolist will then maximize its profit by producing Z, since any larger output makes less profit and lower outputs are not feasible. 3. Pay a subsidy to the monopolist of å, where this satisfies R′(Z) = C′(Z) − å. Diagrammatically, the subsidy shifts the monopolist’s marginal cost curve downward until it intersects the marginal revenue curve at Z (note that for this we may need å > C′(Z)). Then the monopolist’s profit maximizing output given this subsidy is Z. 4. Pay consumers a subsidy per unit of s*, where s* satisfies R′(Z) + s* = C′(Z). Diagrammatically, the subsidy shifts the demand and marginal revenue curves of the monopolist upward until the marginal revenue curve cuts the marginal cost curve at Z. Other possible policies would be to tax substitutes or subsidise complements for the monopoly output (thus shifting its demand and marginal revenue curves upward) or subsidising its inputs (shifting its marginal cost curve downward). However, such indirect methods are ‘second best’ (see section 14C of the text) because they create resource allocation distortions in the market concerned. For the rest of this answer we consider only the four measures given above. A problem with policies 3 and 4 is that they greatly increase the profit of the monopoly and are a cost to the public purse. Both these problems can be met by simultaneously imposing a lump-sum profit tax on the monopoly. This leaves profitmaximizing output unchanged at Z, reduces the monopoly profit and finances the subsidy. With this addition, there is nothing on resource allocation grounds to differentiate between the four measures. Choice among them would require information on the administrative costs and political feasibility of each. In reality the main problem is that the regulator is unlikely to possess exact information on the cost function, and possibly the demand function, of the monopoly, and furthermore policies must be © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 116 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn formulated in light of the fact that costs and demands change over time in a way which may well be influenced by the type of policy adopted. 5. (a) A supply curve is a relationship between price and quantity supplied. For a firm in a competitive market we derive it by taking the first-order condition on output p = C′(q) and inverting it to obtain output as a function of price q = C′−1(p) = S(p). In the case of a monopoly, the first-order condition R′(q) = C′(q) cannot be solved to give output as a function of price: in choosing output (price) the monopoly simultaneously chooses price (output). 5. (b) If the monopolist buys an input in a competitive market then it can be said to have a demand function for that input. Thus we can represent the monopoly’s input choice problem as: max p[ f(z1, z2)] f(z1, z2) − w1z1 − w2z2 where p[.] is its inverse demand function and f(. , .) its production function. Then its first-order conditions are (p + fp′)fi = wi i = 1, 2 where the left hand side is its marginal revenue product (MRPi) (marginal revenue × marginal physical product) of input i. These equations can be solved to give zi = zi(w1, w2), the input demand functions. Note that the left hand side can be written pfi + fp′fi. Since p′ < 0, while pfi is the marginal value product (MVPi), this shows that MRPi < MVPi, and so a monopoly uses less of the inputs than would be the case if the competitive market condition MVPi = wi prevailed. This is, of course, another way of expressing the point that the monopoly distorts the allocation of resources by restricting output of the monopoly good. Note, finally, that from the above condition we obtain f1/f2 = w1/w2, indicating that the monopoly produces its (restricted) output in a cost-minimizing way. 6. We assume throughout that the bidding for the monopoly franchise is competitive and that all bidders would be equally efficient in production. Then (a) Price and output will be set at the profit-maximizing (monopoly) levels, and the winning bid will equal the monopoly profit. (b) Price and output will be at the point of intersection of the demand and long-run average cost curves, since this gives the lowest break-even price. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 117 (c) Let å < 1 be the share of revenue paid to the government. Then, given å the monopolist will seek to maximize (1 − å)R(q) − C(q) implying the output that satisfies the condition R′(Z) = C′(Z)/(1 − å). Since 1 − å < 1, this implies that output is lower and price higher than in either of cases (a) and (b). The value of å that will win the franchise is that which satisfies: (1 − å)R(Z) − C(Z) = 0 since that just exhausts monopoly profit. Then, these two equations jointly determine Z and å. Supplementary question: Show that in the case of linear demand p = a − bq and costs C = cq, a > c > 0, we have å = 1 − (c/a). 7. The firm’s demand functions are pi = Di(q1, q2), i = 1, 2, and so its revenue function is R( q1 , q2 ) = ∑ q D (q , q ). i i 1 2 i Its profit function is π(q1, q2) = R(q1, q2) − C1(q1) − C2(q2), where we assume separability of costs. Then the first-order conditions for maximum profit are Ri − Ci′ = 0 i = 1, 2, where Ri = pi + qi ∂D j ∂Di , + qj ∂qi ∂qi i, j = 1, 2, i ≠ j is ‘total marginal reveue’ (TMR) of good i. The TMR takes account of the demand interdependence between the outputs, and exceeds the partial MR pi + qi(∂Di/∂qi) if the goods are complements, and is less if they are substitutes. As the second-order condition for this problem (see p. 700 of the text), we require R11 − C1′ < 0 and R11 − C 1′′ R12 > 0. R 21 R 22 − C 2′′ The second condition, ( R11 − C1′′)( R22 − C 2′′) > R12 R21 can be thought of as placing restrictions on the demand functions for the two goods to ensure a well-behaved problem. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 118 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 8. The monopoly’s profit function is q1−α − cq and its first-order condition is 1 (1 − α )q −α (1 − α ) =c⇒q= . c α For this to be well-behaved we clearly require 0 < α < 1. Since α is the inverse of the (constant) elasticity of demand in this case we require demand elasticity to exceed unity. The intuition for this is as follows. Suppose demand elasticity equals (is less than) unity. Then reductions in output and increases in price leave total revenue unchanged (increase it) while reducing total costs and so profit must increase. Thus the firm will want to set output as close to zero as possible, selling this at an infinitely high price. But there is no solution to this problem since profit can always be increased by reducing output. The non-existence is created by a discontinuity in the firm’s profit function at q = 0. Supplementary question: Graph the firm’s profit function for the cases in which α ≥ 1. 9. A monopolist with zero marginal costs maximizes profit by maximizing revenue, implying that marginal revenue is zero. But 1 MR = p 1 + = 0 ⇒ e = −1. e The value of the Lerner index at this point is obviously unity. Exercise 9C 1. We would expect that institutions have a lower demand elasticity for journals than individual academics, who in turn have a lower demand elasticity than students. Thus we predict subscription rates to be highest for institutions and lowest for students, which is in fact the case. To compare the pricing policies of profit maximizing publishers and learned societies we need to specify an objective function for the letter. Let us assume they want to maximize the total number of subscriptions. For simplicity, we assume just two groups of subscribers, with subscriptions x1 and x2 respectively. The inverse demand functions are p1(x1), p2(x2), and the cost function is C(x1 + x2). Thus the profit maximizing publisher wishes to max π = p1(x1)x1 + p2(x2)x2 − C(x1 + x2) x1 , x 2 while the learned society wishes to maximize x1 + x2 s.t. p1(x1)x1 + p2(x2)x2 − C(x1 + x2) ≥ B © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 119 where we impose a break-even constraint on the learned society’s activities. The firstorder conditions for the latter are 1 + λ[MRi − MC] = 0 ∑pixi − C(x1 + x2) − B ≥ 0 i = 1, 2 λ≥0 λ[∑pixi − C(x1 + x2) − B] = 0 We must have λ ≠ 0 and so the break-even constraint is binding. From the first two conditions we have MR1 − MC = MR2 − MC = −1/λ < 0 which in turn implies MR1 = MR2. Thus, just as the profit-maximizing publisher, the learned society equalizes marginal revenues and so will set a higher subscription rate in the market with the less elastic demand. The main difference is that its subscription rates overall will be lower (MRi < MC) and subscription volume higher, because it is simply concerned with meeting its profit constraint (this is assumed to be for less than maximum profit). 2. We would expect the car manufacturers’ demand for sparking plugs to be far more elastic than that of individual consumers. The manufacturers can shop around for alternatives to any one supplier, on a worldwide scale, or indeed could set up manufacture of the plugs themselves. Individual consumers, on the other hand, have sparking plugs in their cars replaced as part of an overall service, and typically accept what the garage gives them. 3. In general, we could take house price as an indicator of the income and wealth of the indiviual purchaser. The higher the purchaser’s income the greater her willingness to pay and the smaller, it would be assumed, her price elasticity of demand. Thus relating fees to house price is a way of approximating price discrimination according to demand elasticity. 4. This is a clear example of second-degree price discrimination. The low demand types will choose 1 unit at 50p, the high demand types 2 units at 90p. In terms of the analysis of this section we have: x1* = 1, F1* = 50p; x2c = 2, F2* = 90p. 5. The buyer faced with a full-line force has a choice of not buying the monopolized good and buying the complementary good on a competitive market, or buying the monopolized good and the complementary good at a price above the competitive level. She will do this if the excess paid on the complementary good is less than her consumer surplus on the monopolized good. Thus the full-line force can be seen as a way of scooping out some consumer surplus on the monopoly good, in conditions where nonlinear pricing may not be feasible. It may also have the longer-run effect of eliminating competition in the market for the complementary good and extending its monopoly to that market. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 120 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 6. (i) Let R1(q1) be the revenue function for the good in the US and R2(q2) that in Japan, expressed in dollars and yen respectively. Also let: q11 be the amount produced and consumed in the US q12 the amount produced in the US and shipped to Japan q21 the amount produced in Japan and shipped to the US q22 the amount produced and consumed in Japan. Intuitively we would not expect both q12 and q21 to be positive at the optimum, but it is useful to see how that emerges out of the mathematics. The production cost functions are C1(q11 + q12) in the US, in dollars, and C2(q21 + q22) in Japan, in yen, with Ci″ > 0, i = 1, 2. Suppose that transport cost per unit is $t, regardless of whether the good is shipped from Japan to the US or conversely. Finally, the exchange rate, in dollars per yen, is y. Then the firm’s profit in dollars is π = R1(q1) − C1(q11 + q12) + y[R2(q2) − C2(q21 + q22)] − t(q12 + q21) and the firm seeks to maximize this subject to the constraints: q1 ≤ q11 + q21 q2 ≤ q12 + q22 qij ≥ 0, i, j, = 1, 2 (we assume qi > 0, i = 1, 2, at the optimum, (i.e. some output is sold in both markets). The first-order conditions are: R1′ − λ 1 = 0 yR′2 − λ 2 = 0 − C1′ + λ 1 ≤ 0 q11* ≥ 0 q11* ( λ 1 − C1′) = 0 − C1′ − t + λ2 ≤ 0 q12* ≥ 0 q12* (λ2 − C1′ − t) = 0 − yC 2′ + λ2 ≤ 0 * ≥0 q22 * (λ2 − yC 2′ ) = 0 q22 − yC 2′ − t + λ2 ≤ 0 * ≥0 q21 * (λ1 − yC 2′ − t) = 0 q21 together with the functional constraints, which, given Ri′ > 0 at the optimum, will be binding, i.e. λi > 0. We now consider the main solution possibilities. * > 0, λ 2 < C 1′ + t, λ 1 < yC 2′ + t 1. q11* > 0, q 22 In this case q12 = q21 = 0, production and sales take place in each country separately. From the first four conditions we see that this implies R i′ = C i′ , i = 1, 2, the straightforward monopoly solution. At the optimum, we see that it would not be worth producing additional output in the country with the lower marginal cost (there is nothing to say that these marginal costs – or the marginal revenues – must be equal across countries at the optimum) because adding transport cost brings the “marginal delivered cost” in the other country above the marginal revenue in that country. Fig. 9C.1 illustrates this solution, with the US as the country with the lower marginal revenue = marginal cost solution. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 121 Fig. 9C.1 Fig. 9C.2 * > 0, q12* > 0, λ 1 < yC 2′ + t. 2. q11* > 0, q 22 In this case some US production is exported to Japan. We have as conditions: R1′ = C 1′ ; yR2′ = yC 2′ = C 1′ + t Fig. 9C.2 illustrates this solution. The intuition is as follows. If marginal revenue in the US differed form marginal costs there, it would be possible to increase profit by varying sales and production in the US alone, regardless of exports. If marginal revenue in Japan (in dollar terms) differed from the marginal cost of producing and transporting a unit of US output, it would be possible to increase profit by varying exports. Finally, if the marginal cost of producing a unit of output in Japan differed from that of producing and shipping a unit from the US it would be possible to increase profit by substituting between US and Japanese output. * > 0, q12* > 0, q 21 * > 0. 3. q11* > 0, q 22 We shall show that this case is impossible: we would not simultaneously observe exports from the US to Japan and conversely. The first-order conditions in this case yield: © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 122 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig 9C.3 R1′ = C 1′ = yC 2′ + t yR 2′ = yC 2′ = C 1′ + t The first line gives C 1′ − yC 2′ = t, the second gives C 1′ − yC 2′ = −t, which is a contradiction given that t > 0. 4. q11* > 0, q12* > 0, λ 2 < yC 2′, λ 1 < yC 2′ + t. In this case sales in both the US and Japan are supplied by US production, with * = q21 * = 0. From the first-order conditions we obtain: q22 R1′ = C1′, yR′2 = C1′ + t which are self-explanatory. Essentially, it is cheaper to supply Japan entirely from the US, implying the Japanese marginal cost function is everywhere above the US marginal cost plus transport cost function over the relevant range of outputs. Fig. 9C.3 illustrates. Clearly nothing much would be added by considering cases in which Japan is the exporting country. 6. (ii) The comparative-statics effects depend on which is the initial equilibrium. Let us take case (1), in which there is production in both countries and the US exports to Japan. Substituting to eliminate the constraints gives the first-order conditions: R1′( q11* ) − C1′( q11* + q12* ) = 0 * + q12* ) − C1′( q11* + q12* ) − t = 0 yR2′( q22 * + q12* ) − C 2′( q22 *) = 0 R2′( q22 * . Note that the first-order conditions are the in the three non-zero unknowns q11* , q12* , q22 same whether the firm is US- or Japanese-owned. A Japanese firm would presumably want to maximize profit expressed in yen, but multiplying through the firm’s profit function by 1/y would leave the solution unchanged. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 123 We use the standard comparative-statics methods of Chapter 2 to find the effects of a change in the exchange rate y: C ′′( R ′′ − C 2′′) R 2′ dq11* = − 1 2 <0 dy D R ′( R ′′− C1′′)( R2′′− C 2′′) dq12* = − 2 1 >0 dy D * dq22 R ′ R ′′( R ′′− C1′′) <0 = 2 2 1 dy D where D is the 3 × 3 Hessian determinant and from the second-order conditions D < 0. The signs on these comparative-statics effects reflect the assumptions that C1′′ > 0, Ri′′ < 0 and Ri′ > 0. The intuitive explanation is as follows. If the dollar devalues against the yen, y increases. This increases the marginal revenue of exports from the US to Japan in dollar terms, which is why q12* increases. However, in yen terms the marginal revenue curve for Japanese sales does not shift, and so the increased exports reduce marginal revenue in yen, causing a corresponding fall in Japanese production. However, since * R2′C 2′′( R1′′− C1′′) dq12* dq22 + = >0 dy dy D there is still an overall expansion in total Japanese sales. There is a fall in US sales because the increased exports raise marginal cost in the US, thus requiring an increase in marginal revenue of domestic sales. Again, however, there is a net increase in US production since dq11* dq12* R ′( R ′′− C 2′′) R1′′ + =− 2 2 >0 dy dy D In a similar way one can carry out the comparative-statics analysis for the other cases. 7. If we impose the constraint that, in the model of first-degree price discrimination the fixed charges must be zero, we have third-degree price discrimination: the monopolist can identify each buyer’s type and prevent arbitrage between them. Then, if we take conditions [C.14]–[C.16] in the text, Fi = 0 implies that we can delete [C.15], since the Fi are no longer choice variables. [C.16] becomes vi(pi, 0) ≥ Ei βi ≥ 0 βi[vi − Ei] = 0 i = 1, 2. Now if this constraint is non-binding βi = 0 and so [C.14] becomes pi + xi /xi′ = c i = 1, 2, which is precisely the condition that MR1 = MR2 = c, as derived earlier in the section. But we know that, since Ei = vi ( pi0 , 0), we must have βi = 0 for any pi < pi0 . Thus provided [C.14] has a solution with xi > 0, i = 1, 2, we must have pi < pi0 and the rest goes through. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 124 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 8. In the model with linear demands and constant marginal cost, as long as ai > c, i = 1, 2 we can without loss of generality set c = 0 (given each ai > c, this is simply a change of origin for measuring the constant terms in the demand functions). Then under thirddegree price discrimination with linear demands we maximize the total profit (revenue) function π ∑( a iqi − biqi2 ) The first-order conditions yield qi* = ai /2bi i = 1, 2, implying prices and profits pi* = ai /2, i = 1, 2, π * = ∑ a i2 /4bi . Note also that the sum of outputs is a b + a2b1 . q1* + q2* = 1 2 2b1b2 Where a uniform price must be charged, we can add to the above maximization problem the constraint p1 = p2, i.e. a1 − b1q1 − a2 + b2q2 = 0. With λ as the Lagrange multiplier on this constraint the first-order conditions become: a1 − 2b1q1 − b1λ = 0, a2 − 2b2q2 + b2λ = 0, a1 − a2 − b1q1 + b2q2 = 0. This is a linear system in the three unknowns q1, q2 and λ. Solving this system gives a 2 b1 b2 − 2a 1 b1 b2 − a 1 b22 Z1 = , −( 2b1 b22 + 2b2 b12 ) Z2 = a 1 b1 b2 − 2a 2 b1 b2 − a 2 b12 . −( 2b1 b22 + 2b2 b12 ) The interesting thing now is that if we take the sum Z1 + Z2 we obtain: Z1 + Z2 = ( a 1 b22 + a 1 b1 b2 ) + ( a 2 b1 b2 + a 2 b12 ) 2( b1 b22 + b12 b2 ) = ( a 1 b2 + a 2 b1 )( b1 + b2 ) 2b1 b2 ( b1 + b2 ) = a 1 b2 + a 2 b1 = q1* + q 2* . 2b1 b2 Thus, total market output is the same with or without price discrimination. What differs is the division of this total output between the two markets. Fig. 9C.4 illustrates. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 125 Fig. 9C.4 In both price discrimination and non-discrimination cases total output is set where its marginal revenue is zero (= marginal cost). Under price discrimination, the price of the less elastic good is higher and that of the more elastic good lower than under price uniformity. Profits are lower in the latter case because marginal revenues in the two sub-markets are not equalized. Supplementary question: Now allow c > 0 and suppose that a1 > c > a2. What do you think happens to the profit maximizing solution under both price discrimination and uniformity? Illustrate diagrammatically. 9. To show that under second degree price discrimination both types will be offered separate contracts, suppose to the contrary that they are offered the same contract (x0, F 0). The argument in the text establishes that (x0, F 0) must lie on E1, and we can never have x0 > x1 (refer to the text for notation) and so x0 < x1* . Consider the type 2 indifference curve passing through (x0, F 0). Since at x* on this curve dF/dx = −1, x0 < x* and the strict convexity of the indifference curve implies that at (x0, F 0) we must have that the indifference curve is steeper at x0 than at x*. At x* the slope of the indifference curve dF/dx = −c and so if at x0 dF/dx < −c, we have that dF > cdx, and so a small movement along the curve will increase the firm’s profit on a type 2 contract. Thus, since such a move would not violate self-selection, (x0, F 0) cannot be optimal. 10. Self-selection by quality difference This is answered simply by redefining the variable x. Let each consumer now demand one unit of the good, and x now measures the quality of the good. The cost parameter c now measures the production cost of a ‘unit of quality’. Then, assuming two types of buyers with utility functions Ui(xi), defined on quality, the analysis goes through just as before. The fact that the seller makes a profit on sales to type 2 buyers can be interpreted as the result, stated in the question, that the differential between the charges for the two types of quality exceeds the extra cost of producing that quality. This can be easily shown by rearranging condition [C.28] in the text: F *2 − F 1* = U 2 ( x2* ) − U 2 ( x1* ) © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 126 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 9C.5 Then, as Fig. 9C.5 shows, at the second-best equilibrium the right hand side of the above equation must exceed c( x2* − x1* ), the cost of the additional quality of the unit of the good sold to type 2 buyers. Exercise 9D 1. (a) Let the inverse demand function be p(x) = a − bx so that revenue is R(x) = ax − 2bx2. With constant marginal cost of c and zero fixed cost, profit is R(x) − cx and the profit maximising quantity satisfies R′(x) − c = a − 2bx − c = 0 and is x* = a−c 2b Profit maximising price is p* = a − bx* = a+c 2 and maximised profit is π* = (p* − c)x* Welfare is measured as the area under the demand curve (willingness to pay) minus the area under the marginal cost curve (total cost) and hence is maximised at the output where marginal cost curve (height c) cuts the demand curve (height p(x)). Thus the welfare maximising price po and quantity xo are defined by po = p(xo) = a − bxo = c © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 127 so that welfare maximising quantity is twice the monopoly profit maximising quantity: xo = a−c = 2x* b When the demand curve is linear and marginal cost is constant the expression in the text for the monopoly welfare loss (MWL) on the right hand side of [D.1] is exact: MWL = 1 ( p* − p o )( x o − x*) 2 and so subsitituting for po and xo MWL = 1 1 1 ( p* − c )( 2x* − x*) = ( p* − c ) x* = π * 2 2 2 Supplementary question (i) How would the answer change if the firm had a fixed cost? 1. (b) With the constant elasticity demand function x(p) = kp−α, the inverse demand function is p(x) = (k/x)−1/α, and revenue is R(x) = k1/αx(α−1)/α. The elasticity of demand is −α and we assume that α > 1 so that demand is inelastic. Profit is maximised when α − 1 1/α −1/α R′(x) − c = k x −c=0 α and the profit maximising quantity and price are α − 1 x* = k αc p* = α αc α −1 Welfare maximising price is po = c and welfare maximising quantity is xo = kc−α Monopoly welfare loss is the area between the demand curve and marginal cost curve between x* and xo: MWL = ∫ xo x* = k1/α [ p( x) − c]dx = α (α − 1) xo ∫ [k x x* 1 /α −1 / α − c]dx [(xo)(α−1)/α − (x*)(α−1)/α] − c(xo − x*) = ∆WTP − ∆C © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 128 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn The first term can be written as ∆WTP = k 1/α ( α −1 )/ α a ( kc −α )(α −1)/α − k α − 1 α (α − 1) c α 1/α = k k = kc 1−α ( α −1 )/ α 1−α α − 1 a −1 1−α c − c α (α − 1) α α − 1 a −1 1 − (α − 1) α α and the second as a 1−α α − 1 a 1−α α − 1 −α ∆C = c ( kc ) − k = k c − c α α c = kc 1−α α − 1 a 1 − α Total expenditure at the monopoly price is α α − 1 α c α − 1 k R(x*) = p*x* = = k α −1 αc αc α − 1 = kc1−α α and thus α −1 [ ][ − 1−( α ) MWL ∆WTP − ∆C (α −1 ) 1 − ( α ) = = α −1 R R ( αα−1 ) α α − 1 = α −α α − 1 − α α −1 −1 α −1 a −1 α − 1 − α 1−α α −1 a ] α − 1 + α which depends only on the demand elasticity. You should plot MWL/R against α > 1 and show that it declines monotonically to zero as α increases (demand becomes more elastic). 2. (a) Assume that marginal costs do not vary with output whether or not there is Xinefficiency and that the demand curve is linear. In Fig. 9D.1 the marginal cost curve with no X-inefficiency is at c0 and with X-inefficiency is at c1. Given the marginal cost curve at c1 the monopolist sets a price of p* and output is x*. If costs were minimised the welfare maximising output would be at xo where the marginal cost curve c0 cuts the demand curve and consumers pay a price equal to the marginal cost of production. If output was increased to xo consumers would be willing to pay the area under the demand curve between x* and xo for the additional output. The additional cost of this © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 129 Fig. 9D.1 output, with no X-inefficiency would be the area under the c0 marginal cost curve. The difference between the consumers’ willingness to pay and the additional costs is the area acd. With production with no X-inefficiency there would also be a cost saving on the initial x* output equal to the area c1edc0. Thus the total welfare loss from an Xinefficient monopolist is the sum of the areas acd and c1edc0. 2. (b) If the X-efficient marginal cost curve was at c1 the welfare loss would be the sum of the usual triangle abe plus the increase in the fixed costs. 2. (c) This part of the question is designed to remind you that the calculations of welfare loss made so far rest on the assumption that £1 has the same marginal social value whether it accrues to the owners of the firm, their employees, or consumers. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 130 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Chapter 10 Input Markets Exercise 10A 1. In Fig. 10A.1 the curves D(p1, p2, p, z20 ) plot the market demand for input 1 against its price, holding the level of the fixed input 2 (and thus the number of firms), the price of input 2 and output price constant. The curves are just the horizontal sums of the MRP curves of the individual firms, as shown in text Fig. 10.1 with z2 held constant at its initial level. When the price of input 1 falls from p10 to p11 firms find that their SMC has fallen and they increase their output. If the increased output has no effect on p all firms world move down their MRP curve generated by the initial output price p0. But if the increase in the output of firms leads to a reduction in the price of output, say to p1, then their MRP curves are shifted down. Aggregating these new lower MRP curves across all firms gives D(p1, p2, p1, z20 ). Thus when the reduction in the price of input 1 induces a reduction in the price of output the increase in demand (z10 to z11 ) is less than would be indicated by the constant output price demand curve D(p1, p2, p0, z20 ). The short run industry demand curve, allowing for the induced change in output price is shown by D(p1, p2, z20 ). To compare the long and short run industry responses to a change in the price of input 1 we consider a simple case in which all firms have identical linear homogeneous quasi-concave production functions f(z1, z2). Linear homogeneity implies that we can treat the industry as if it were composed of a single firm which takes the output price as given when it chooses its inputs. Since we are interested in industry demand for inputs rather individual firm demands the fact that the size of individual firms is indeterminate under the assumption of linear homogeneity does not matter. The long run equilibrium will be characterised by profit maximizing choices of the two inputs pfi(z1, z2) − pi = 0, i = 1, 2 (10.1) and the market clearing condition p = p(f(z)) where p(f) is the inverse demand function for the industry’s output. Note that we do not impose a zero profit condition to determine the number of firms since linear homogeneity implies that LMC = LAC and LMC = pi/fi = p from the profit maximization conditions. Substituting the inverse output demand function into (10.1) and totally differentiating with respect to the input price p1 gives p ′ f12 + pf11 p ′ f1 f 2 + pf12 ∂z1 /∂p1 1 = 2 p ′ f 2 f1 + pf 21 p ′ f 2 + pf 22 ∂z 2 /∂p1 0 130 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 (10.2) Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 131 Fig. 10A.1 Using Cramer’s rule gives the long run effect on industry demand for input 1 of an increase in its price: ∂z1 ( p1 , p2 ) p ′ f22 + pf22 = <0 ∂p1 ∆ (10.3) where ∆ = ( p ′ f12 + pf11 )( p ′ f 22 + pf22) − (p′f1f2 + pf12)2 > 0 by the second order conditions on the profit maximization problem and the downward sloping demand curve for the industry’s output: p′ < 0. In the short run, input z2 cannot be varied and so profit maximization with the output price taken as given requires that the choice of the variable input z1 satisfies pf1(z1, z20 ) − p1 = 0 (10.4) (so that p = SMC). The other requirement for short run equilibrium is that the product market clears and p − p(f(z1, z20 )) = 0. Substituting the market clearing condition into (10.4) and differentiating with respect to p1 gives ∂z1 ( p1 , p2 , z 20 ) 1 = <0 2 ∂p1 p ′ f1 + pf11 (10.5) To compare the long and short run responses set the fixed input in (10.5) at its long run level. Then multiply (10.3) and (10.5) by ∆ ( p′ f12 + pf11) < 0 and note that since ∆ < ( p ′ f12 + pf11 )( p ′ f 22 + pf22) we have established that ∂z1 ( p1 , p2 ) ∂z1 ( p1 , p2 , z 20 ) < ∂p1 ∂p1 Thus the long run reduction in demand for an input as a result of an increase in its price is greater than the short run reduction. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 132 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 2. Let us suppose that the market for input 2 is stable in the Marshallian and Walrasian sense (recall section 8B) and has an upward sloping supply function for input 2. Let z2 = z2(p2), z2′ > 0 be supply function for input 2 and Di(p1, p2), (i = 1, 2) be the demand functions for the two inputs. We are interested in the effect of an increase in the price of input 1 on the demand for input 1 given that changes in p1 shift the demand curve in the market for input 2 and hence cause a change in p2, which then shifts the demand curve for input 1. Equilibrium in the market for input 2 requires z2(p2) − D2(p1, p2) = 0 which implicitly defines the equilibrium price of input 2 as a function of the price of input 1: p2 = p2e ( p1 ) with dp2e D 21 = dp1 z 2′ − D 22 (10.6) where D2i denotes the partial derivative of D2 with respect to pi. Since we know that ceteris paribus increases in the price of an input reduce the demand for it (Dii < 0) the equilibrium price of input 2 increases or decreases with p1 if the inputs are substitutes (D21 > 0) or complements (D21 < 0). (If the inputs are substitutes an increase in p1 shifts the demand curve for input 2 to the right and hence increases its equilibrium price.) Now consider the effect of an increase in p1 on the demand for input 1, allowing for the induced change in the price of input 2: dD1 ( p1 , p2e ( p1 )) dpe = D11 + D12 2 > D11 dp1 dp1 Since we can usually assume (see question 10A.4) that the cross-price effects on input demands are equal the last term in this expression must be positive (see (10.6)). Hence the implication of the interaction of the two markets is that the demand curve for input 1 allowing for induced changes in p2 is less steep than the ceteris paribus demand curve. The reason is that the induced changes in p2 counteract the direct effects of p1. 3. In choosing her input levels a monopolist takes account of the fact that she faces a downward sloping demand curve for her product. Thus monopolist m’s demand function for an input zim ( p1 , p2) does not depend on the price of her output and the total demand for input i by all the monopolists is just ∑m zim ( p1 , p2). The market demand curve for input i in the rather unusual case where all the firms are monopolists is the horizontal sum of their individual demand curves. 4. Recall the discussion of the firm’s profit maximizing input choices zk(p1, p2) and its maximum profit function π *(p1, p2) (text pages 211–213). The profit maximizing input demands are, using Hotelling’s Lemma, zi(p1, p2) = − ∂π * ( p1 , p2 ) ∂pi so that © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 133 Fig. 10B.1 ∂z i ∂ 2π* = ∂p j ∂p i ∂p j But, by Young’s Theorem, if the partial derivatives of a function are differentiable the cross partial derivatives are equal. The profit function π* has continuous partials with respect to input prices if the production possibility set is strictly convex so that there are no jumps in the profit maximizing net output as result of small changes in relative prices. Hence if the firm has a strictly convex production possibility set the second order cross partials will be equal and input k is a substitute for input i if and only if input i is a substitute for input k. Exercise 10B 1. Fig. 10B.1 shows how shifts in the supply curve for the input can lead to the same quantity being demanded at two different prices (part (a)) and different quantities at the same price (part (b)). In a competitive input market such supply shifts would trace out the market demand curve with higher prices being associated with a smaller quantity. 2. Suppose that the firm is a monopsonist in the market for input 1 but buys input 2 in a competitive market. The Lagrangean for the problem of minimizing the expenditure necessary to produce a required output level is p1(z1)z1 + p2z2 + λ[y − f(z1, z2)] where p1(z1) is the inverse supply function for input 1. The first order conditions are p1′ (z1)z1 + p1 − λf1 = 0 p2 − λf2 = 0 plus the constraint. Rearranging we get © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 134 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 10B.2 f1 p1′ z1 + p1 p1 = > f2 p2 p2 (10.7) so that cost minimization implies that the marginal rate of technical substitution is greater than the input price ratio. Since the marginal cost of input 1 to the firm exceeds its price, the firm minimizes its cost by using less of z1 and more of z2 to produce a given output than it would if it treated the price of input 1 as unaffected by its action. Fig. 10B.2 illustrates for a simple case in which the production function is homothetic and p2′′ ≥ 0. The slope of the firm’s isoquants is constant along rays from the origin. The firm’s isocost curves reflect the fact that the price of input 1 increases as the firm buys more of it: dz2 p ′ z + p1 =− 1 1 dz1 p2 and d 2 z2 p′′z + 2 p1′ =− 1 1 <0 2 dz1 p2 As the reader should confirm the assumption p2′′ ≥ 0 implies that ∑pizi is strictly convex and so has quasi-convex contours, as shown in the figure. The isoquants become more steeply sloped as the amount of z1 increases. Hence the expansion path is not a ray from the origin (as would be the case if the firm treated p1 as a parameter) but the curve EP. The firm’s cost function can be derived in the usual way from its expansion path. Supplementary question (i) Show that the assumption p1′′ ≥ 0 implies that expenditure is a strictly convex function of (z1, z2). Is the assumption plausible? What would be the consequences if p1′ > 0 but p1′′ < 0? © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 135 Fig. 10B.3 3. In Fig. 10B.3 we assume that the market demand curve under competition is identical to the monopsonist’s MRP curve under monopoly. Without a minimum wage the competitive equilibrium is a wage of wc and employment of zc. Imposing a minimum wage of w1 > wc raises the market wage to w1, creating an excess supply of labour since supply at this wage exceeds demand. Under monopsony the initial equilibrium without a minimum wage is a wage wm and employment of zm. With a minimum wage of w0 > wm the firm faces an effective marginal buyer cost of w0 for z < X0. However for z ≥ X0 the firm must increase the wage above w0 along the supply curve to generate an increase in supply. Hence for z ≥ X0 its marginal buyer cost curve is the segment of MBC to the right of X0. Faced with a marginal buyer cost curve which is discontinous at X0 the firm will choose to employ X0 > zm workers at a wage of w0 > wm. Thus a minimum wage which does not exceed the competitive wage will increase employment in a monopsonized labour market. A higher minimum wage, such as w1 will generate a marginal buyer cost curve which is the minimum wage line up to X1 and the MBC curve thereafter. The firm’s optimum employment level will then be at z1 at the minimum wage of w1. At this wage there is an excess supply of labour but the level of employment is greater than without a minimum wage. If the minimum wage is w2 there will be an excess supply and the level of employment is reduced. Thus, under monopsony, imposing a binding minimum wage increases employment if it is less than U. 4. In Fig. 10B.4 we assume that the supply functions of the two groups are linear. Recall the discussion of third degree monopoly price discrimination (text pages 195–196). The firm will buy small amounts of the input (up to z0) from group 1 since over this range the marginal buyer cost of input 1 MBC1(z1) is less than MBC2(0). For larger amounts the firm will allocate its purchases between the two groups so as to equate the marginal buyer costs. Hence the firm’s overall marginal buyer cost curve MBC in part (c) of the figure is the MBC1(z1) curve up to z0 and the horizontal sum of the MBCi(zi) curves © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 136 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 10B.4 thereafter. The profit maximizing input level is z* where the MBC curve cuts the firm’s marginal revenue product curve MRP. The firm buys zi* of input i at price pi* , equating the marginal buyer costs but paying a higher price to group 1 which has a more elastic supply. (Recall from text page 218 that MBCi = pi(1 + 1/e is ).) It is best to model the effect of legislation which forbids paying different wages to the two groups by examining the solution to the firm’s problem of maximizing R(z1 + z2) − ∑pi(zi)zi subject to the constraint p1 − p2 ≤ δ. The two groups supply an identical input and so the firm’s output and thus its revenue depends only total employment. We assume that revenue is an increasing but concave function of total employment: R′ > 0, R″ < 0. We assume that group 1 has the more elastic supply function and would be offered a higher price if discrimination was legal. When discrimination is illegal we set δ = 0. If discrimination is legal the firm’s prices are not constrained and we can capture this by making δ sufficiently large that the constraint p1 − p2 ≤ δ does not bind. To ensure a well behaved problem we assume that expenditure on the inputs is a convex function of (z1, z2). ( pi′′ ≤ 0, i = 1, 2 is sufficient but not necessary for convexity – see question 2 above.) The Lagrangean for the legally restrained monopsonist is R(z1 + z2) − ∑pi(zi)zi + λ[p1 − p2 − δ ] and the first order conditions in the case in which the constraint is binding and both groups are employed are R′ − p1′ z1 − p1 + λp1′ = 0 R′ − p2′ z2 − p2 − λp2′ = 0 p1 − p2 − δ = 0 Now totally differentiate the first order conditions with respect to δ to get R ′′ − p1′′( z12 − λ ) − p1′ R ′′ p1′ R ′′ R ′′ − p2′′( z + λ ) − p2′ 2 2 − p2′ p1′ ∂z1 /∂δ 0 − p2′ ∂z 2 /∂δ = 0 0 ∂λ /∂δ 1 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 137 Cramer’s rule yields ∂z1 = [a + ( z22 + λ ) p1′ p2′′]∆−1 ∂δ (10.8) ∂z2 = −[a + ( z12 − λ ) p2′ p1′′]∆−1 ∂δ (10.9) where a = p1′ p2′ − ( p1′ + p2′ ) R ′′ > 0 and ∆ is the bordered Hessian of the system and is positive by virtue of the second order conditions (see Appendix I). In general the effects of forbidding monopsonistic discrimination depend on rather fine details of the groups’ supply functions and the firm’s revenue function. If we assume (as in Fig. 10B.4) that the supply functions are linear ( pi′′ = 0) then we see from (10.8) and (10.9) that relaxing the legal constraint (increasing δ) will increase z1 and reduce z2. This accords with intuition: the legal constraint forces the firm to reduce w1 and increase w2 compared with the situation in which it is unconstrained. In the linear case the changes in employment of two groups are exactly offsetting and so total employment is unchanged. When the firm is not allowed to discriminate it pays both groups the same wage and therefore faces a supply function S which is the horizontal sum of S1 and S2. This curve plots the average cost of labour to the firm and gives rise to the discontinous marginal buyer cost curve abcde. Since the discrimination and no discrimination marginal buyer cost curves coincide for total employment greater than X there is no difference in the profit maximizing total employment. The firm is obviously worse off if it is not allowed to discriminate since it is subject to an additional binding constraint. The difference in profit is shown in diagram by the area bcd which is the difference in the firm’s input cost (the difference in the areas under the discrimination and no discrimination marginal buyer cost curves.) Supplementary question (i) Under what circumstances will forbidding discrimination lead to the paradoxical result that the wage employment of group 1 falls and the employment of group 2 increases? What happens to prices in this case? 5. For given (z1, p1) the firm chooses (z2, . . . , zn) to maximize ) = R(f(z1, z2, . . . , zn)) − p1z1 − n ∑ p z = )(z , z , . . . , z , p , p , . . . , p ) i i 1 2 n 1 2 n i=2 The optimal (z2, . . . , zn) depend on the input prices (p2, . . . , pn) and on (p1, z1): Xi = Xi(p1, z1, p2, . . . , pn), i = 2, . . . , n. The maximum profit function for given (p1, z1) is π = π(p1, z1, p2, . . . , pn) = )(z1, X2, . . . , Xn, p1, p2, . . . , pn) © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 138 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 10B.5 The marginal effects of increases in p1 and z1 are n ∂π ∂) ∂ ) ∂X i ∂) = + = = − z1 ∂p1 ∂p1 i = 2 ∂z i ∂p1 ∂p1 ∑ n ∂π ∂) ∂ ) ∂Xi ∂ ) = + = = R ′f1 − p1 ∂z1 ∂z1 i=2 ∂zi ∂z1 ∂z1 ∑ (Remember ∂)/∂zi = 0, i = 2, . . . , n.) Hence the slope of indifference curves in (p1, z1) space, after allowing for the fact that changes in (p1, z1) induce changes in (z2, . . . , zn), is dp1 π R ′f1 − p1 = − z1 = dz1 dπ = 0 π p1 z1 Since π is decreasing in p, lower indifference curves in Fig. 10B.5 correspond to higher profit: the firm is better off on I1 than on I0. The firm will maximize profit by choosing the (p1, z1) combination which gets it onto the lowest feasible indifference curve. What (p1, z1) combinations are feasible depend on the input market conditions which the firm faces. If the firm was a competitive buyer of the input it would treat p1 as a parameter: it would be constrained to choose a (p1, z1) combination on the horizontal line with height equal to the given p1. For example, if p1 = p10 it would maximize profit by choosing an input level of z10 where its indifference curve I0 is tangent to the horizontal line p10 p10 . Hence the slope of its indifference curve at the profit maximizing (p1, z1) combination would be zero and so R′f1 ( z10 ) = p10 . Similarly, if the firm acted as if the input price was a parameter equal to p11 , it would choose the profit maximizing input level z11 , where I1 is tangent to the horizontal line p11 p11 and its marginal revenue product is equal to the © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 139 input price. The firm’s demand curve for the input is the locus of such points of tangency, i.e. its MRP1 curve. Notice that to the left of the MRP1 curve the firm’s indifference curves are positively sloped and to the right of it they are negatively sloped. This follows from the fact that to the left of MRP1 increases in z1 at given p1 increase profit and to the right of it they reduce profit. When the firm acts as a monopsonist it is constrained by the supply curve of the competitive input suppliers. It therefore maximizes profit by choosing the (p1, z1) combination on S1 which yields the highest profit. This is at ( p1* , z1* ) where the indifference curve I* is tangent to S1. Since the supply curve is positively sloped the point of tangency between I* and S1 must also occur where I* is positively sloped and R′f1 ( z1* ) > p1* The monopsonist will maximize profit by demanding less of the input than would a firm which treated the input price as a parameter. 6. To focus on the welfare loss from monopsony consider an isolated labour market where the single employer of z uses it to produce an output x = f(z) which is sold on a competitive product market at a price of p which is unaffected by the monopsonist’s employment and output level. There are many workers in the isolated labour market and each supplies one unit of labour. The inverse labour supply function is w(z) which shows the wage that workers in this isolated labour market must be paid to induce them to supply z. Thus w(z) is the height of the supply curve S in Fig. 10B.6. The monopsonist chooses to employ z* workers at a wage of w* where its marginal buyer cost MBC equals the value of the marginal product pf′(z). Because the labour supply curve slopes upward infra marginal workers receive an economic rent since the wage they get exceeds the wage they require to supply labour (see text page 220). The total economic rent is the area between the wage line and the supply curve: area w*ce. (Compare the consumer surplus in section 4C when there is no income effect.) The monopsonist’s revenue is pf(z) which is the area under the value of the marginal product curve VMP. Thus monopsonist profit is the area under VMP minus the cost of labour w(z)z: area dacw*. Refresh your memory of the discussion of the monopoly welfare loss (section 9D). Assuming that £1 has the same marginal social value whether it accrues to workers or to the monopsonist, welfare is the sum of the economic rent of workers and the profit of the monopsonist. (Because the product market is competitive the price of the product is unaffected by the monopsonist’s output and so we can ignore the welfare of consumers.) Welfare is thus the area under the VMP curve minus wz (monopsonist profit) plus wz minus the area under the labour supply curve (economic rent). Welfare is maximised at z0 where the area under the VMP curve minus the area under the labour supply curve is maximised. Alternatively, welfare is the value of output minus the cost of labour: W(z) = pf(z) − ∫ w( z)dz z 0 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 140 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 10B.6 which is maximised when W′(z) = pf′(z) − w(z) = 0 The welfare loss from monopsony is W(z0) − W(z*) = p[f(z0) − f(z*)] − zo ∫ w( z) dz z* or the difference between the area under VMP curve and the labour supply curve between z* and z0. In Fig. 10B.6 in moving from the welfare maximising (w0, z0) to the monopsony profit maximising (w*, z*) the monopsonist gains by an amount equal to the area w0fcw* minus the area afb. The workers lose economic rent equal to the area w0fcw* plus the area cfb. Thus the welfare loss is the area abc, which is the sum of areas afb and cfb. Exercise 10C 1. The rent maximizing union chooses (w, z) to maximize [C.1] subject to the inverse industry demand function w = wd(z) which gives the maxmimum per unit wage wd that can be charged for a supply of z ie the height of D in text Fig. 10.5. Substituting wd(z) for w in [C.1] the union maximand is wd(z)z − ∫ ω ( 0) d 0 z 0 (remember ω (z) is the reservation wage – the lowest per unit wage at which z will be supplied). The first order condition when the optimal z is positive is wd′ ( z) z + wd(z) − ω (z) = 0 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 141 which can be rearranged to give wd ( z) − ω ( z) = wd′ ( z) z the left hand side of which is the slope of the union’s indifference curve (see [C.2]) and the right hand side is the slope of the industry demand curve. Hence the union chooses (w*, z*) where the union indifference curve is tangent to the industry demand curve. 2. Since the union will not force members to work at wage w when u(w) < û(U), U is defined only for u(w) ≥ û(U). The slope of the indifference curve U(w, z) in [C.5] is dw [u( w) − û( U)] =− ≤0 dz U zu ′( w) (10.10) The curvature of the union indifference curves is established by differentiating (10.10) with respect to z: dw d2w −1 dw − ( u − û) u ′′z + u ′ u ′zu ′ = 2 2 dz dz dz U ( zu ′) Hence the indifference curves have the usual quasi-concave shape if the marginal utility of income is non-increasing: u″ ≤ 0. Partially differentiating (10.10) with respect to w and z gives ∂( dw/dz) −1 = {u′zu′ − ( u − û) u′′z} ∂w ( zu′)2 ∂( dw/dz) u − û = ∂z ( zu′)2 which shows that the indifference curves get flatter as z increases for given w and, if u″ ≤ 0, steeper as w increases for given z. The preferences represented by [C.6] are a special case of those represented by [C.5] with u(w) = û(U) for w = U and u′ = û′ = 1, so that dw ( w − U) =− dz U z Hence, as text page 223 suggested, the indifference curves are rectangular hyperbolas with horizontal axis at w = U. The assumption (a) that u(w) > û(U) at w = U means that union members prefer to be in work rather than unemployed at the same wage. Assumption (b) that du/dw > dû/dU at w = U means that union members get greater utility from an extra £1 when employed than when they are unemployed at the same wage. Assumption (a) implies that unemployment per se has a cost to union members (loss of self esteem, say). This would mean that U is defined for some w < U and that the indifference curves extend below the horizontal line at U. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 142 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 10D.1 Exercise 10D 1. The contract curve in (w, z) space is defined by (a) the tangency of the indifference curves of the firm and the union (so that the agreement is efficient) and (b) by the individual rationality constraints that both parties will not accept an agreement which makes them worse off than without an agreement. With U given by [C.1] and (hence indifference curves by [C.2]) the contract curve must satisfy the tangency condition R ′f ′ − w w−ω =− z z which is equivalent to R′(f(z))f′(z) − ω (z) = 0 Since w does not appear in this equation (ω (z) is the reservation wage, whereas w is the actual wage paid) the contract curve is a vertical line in (w, z) space at z* determined by the intersection of the supply curve (plotting ω (z)) and the MRP (plotting R′f′). The individual rationality requirements imply that in Fig. 10D.1 the union will not accept a wage less than ω (z*) and the firm will not pay a wage greater than pAP(z*). Thus the contract curve is the vertical line c1c1. With U given by [C.3] the tangency condition is R ′f ′ − w w =− z z which implies R′(f(z))f′(z) = 0 The contract curve in Fig. 10D.1 is now the vertical line c2c2 at z** where MRP is zero. The firm will not pay more than pAP(z**) and the union will accept only non-negative wages. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 143 2. (a) The tangency condition for the contract curve is R ′f ′ − w u( w) − û( U) =− <0 z z (10.11) (See the answer to question 10C.2 for the union’s indifference curve.) Note that since the union gets ûX in the absence of any agreement it will only make an agreement which gives u(w) > û(U) and so the indifference curves must have negative slope at the contract curve. Rearranging the tangency condition gives the implicit function of the contract curve: F(w, z) = (R′f′ − w)u′(w) + u(w) − û = 0 with partial derivatives Fw = −u′ + (R′f′ − w)u″ + u′ = (R′f′ − w)u″ > 0 Fz = (R′f″ + R″f′f′)u′ < 0 The sign of Fw follows from the assumption that u″ < 0 and the fact that the firm’s indifference curves are tangent to the negatively sloped union indifference curves, which implies that R′f′ − w < 0. The sign of Fz arises from the fact that MRP declines with z. Thus the slope of the contract curve is F dw ( R ′f ′′ + R ′′f ′f ′) u ′ =− z =− >0 dz Fw ( R ′f ′ − w) u ′′ 2. (b) (i) Neither the firm nor the union will wish to increase effective labour n beyond n0 for any given w: union members get the same utility when employed whether working or playing cards and the revenue to be shared between union and firm would be reduced by increasing n beyond n0. Conversely if n < n0 making idle employed union members work effectively would increase revenue and leave their utility unchanged. Hence for n ≤ n0 all union members who are employed will be used effectively: z = n and ᐉ = 0. The union and firm indifference curves will be as in (10.11) and the contract curve will be positively sloped in (w, z) space up to z = n0. Beyond z = n0 any additional union members who are employed play cards and the firm’s profit is R(f(n0)) − (n0 + ᐉ)w = R(f(n0)) − wz Its indifference curves therefore have slope dw/dz = −w/z. Since union members are indifferent when employed between working effectively and being idle, the form of the union objective function is the same for all levels of z. Hence the tangency condition for contract curve for the region where z ≥ n0 is − w u−û =− z zu ′ which yields the implicit equation F(w, z) = u(w) − û − u′(w)w = 0 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 144 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 10D.2 Since this equation does not depend on z the contract curve is horizontal for z ≥ n0. In Fig. 10D.2 we assume that members have the same utility function whether employed or not. Hence the union will never make an agreement with a wage less than U. The contract curve is abc. If the actual bargain is along the horizontal segment bc, say at d, the agreement has zd workers employed at a wage of w0 of whom n0 are productively employed and zd − n0 are idle in the firm. (ii) Let the revenue function of the firm be R(f, α) where increases in the shift parameter α increase revenue for a given output and increase the marginal revenue product of labour: Rα > 0, Rfα > 0. The positively sloped segment of the contract curve now satisfies F(w, z, α) = (Rf f′ − w)u′(w) + u(w) − û = 0 Since Fα = Rf α f′u′ > 0, we see that ∂w F = − α < 0, ∂α Fw F ∂z =− α >0 ∂α Fz Increases in the demand shift parameter α shift the positively sloped segment of the contract curve down and to the right. An increase in α also increases the output at which marginal revenue Rf is zero. Hence n0 also increases with α. However, the equation for the horizontal segment of the contract curve is unaffected by α and so w0 does not change. If the actual bargain is shifted along the horizontal segment as a result of the change in α the demand shift would have no effect on the wage rate. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 145 Chapter 11 Capital Markets Exercise 11B 1. (a) Expenditure on consumption cannot be negative. In the case where A > 0 (borrowing), consumption in period 0 cannot exceed endowed income plus borrowing and consumption in period 1 cannot exceed endowed income less the repayment of the loan. 1. (b) Redraw Fig. 11.2 with the point of tangency between the indifference curve and the wealth line (i) above and to the left of the endowment point, (ii) at the endowment point. 1. (c) The consumer would have no consumption in one period. 1. (d) The consumer would have linear indifference curves and would choose to spend all her wealth on consumption in only one of the periods. 1. (e) ρ is the subjective rate of interest: the consumer is willing to accept 1 + ρ additional consumption in period 1 in exchange for one unit less consumption in period 0. Thus with the stated values of ρ she is willing give up one unit in period 0 in exchange for 0.8, 1 and 1.2 units of consumption in period 1 respectively. 2. The Lagrangean for the intertemporal utility maximization problem is L = M 0α M11−α + λ[V0 − M0 − M1/(1 + r)] The problem is formally identical to the standard utility maximization problem of chapter 2, except for the notational changes: p0 = 1, p1 = 1/(1 + r), M = V0. We can draw on the results from question 2D.6 to write the demand functions for current and future consumption as M 0* = V0α M1* = V0(1 − α)(1 + r) 3. No. δ = u1/u0 > 1 implies that the consumer values £1 in the future more highly than £1 now (corresponding to ρ = 1 − (u1/u0) < 1). The market determined discount factor µ = 1/(1 + r) is the present value of £1 received in period 1. The consumer is in equilibrium when her indifference curve is tangent to her wealth line: −u0/u1 = −1/δ = −(1 + r) = −1/µ ⇒ δ = µ © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 145 146 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 11B.1 4. Let the interest rates for borrowing and lending be rb > rl. The slope of the budget or wealth line to the left of the endowment point, where the consumer lends, is −(1 + rᐉ). To the right of the endowment point R the consumer borrows, so the slope of the wealth line is −(1 + rb). Thus the budget line is kinked at R in Fig. 11B.1, where three possible solutions are shown. When the consumer does not borrow or lend ρ(R0, R1) ∈ [rb, rᐉ]. Exercise 11C 1. (a) From [C.3], [C.4] and the envelope theorem, the slope of PP is dD1 dD1 /dK 1 ∂D1 /∂K 1 p f ( L* , K 1 ) = =− 1 K 1 = − pK pK dD0 dD0 /dK 1 (11.1) where L*1 = L*1 ( p1 , w, K 1 ). It is apparent that an increase in pK flattens PP. Applying the usual comparative static procedure to the first order condition p1 fL − w = 0 on L1 shows that −1 f f ∂( dD1 /dD0 ) −1 ∂L* = f K + p1 f KL 1 = f K − KL L ∂p1 dp1 pK f LL pK As the reader should check by partially differentiating fK/fL with respect to L, this expression is negative (PP becomes steeper as p1 increases) if L is a normal input. (See text Fig. 6.4.) Similarly ∂dD1 /dD0 p ∂L* p f = − 1 f KL 1 = − 1 KL pK pK f LL ∂w ∂w and so an increase in w flattens or steepens PP as fLK is negative or positive. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 147 1. (b) An increase in the depreciation rate means that less capital is available next period for a given expenditure this period. Hence D1 is smaller for given D0 and PP pivots down about its intercept on the D0 axis. 1. (c) If disinvestment is impossible and there is no depreciation then K1 ≥ K0 and the maximum D0 is p0 f ( L*0 , K 0 ) − wL*0 . PP is discontinuous, dropping to the horizontal axis at this level of D0. 2. Total differentiation of the first order conditions [C.11] to [C.13] gives p0 f L L 0 0 ∂L*0 /∂α −VL α p1 f L K (1 + r ) −1 ∂L*1 /∂α = −VL α p1 f K K (1 + r ) −1 ∂K 1* /∂α −VK α 0 0 0 0 p1 f L L 1 1 p1 f L K (1 + r ) −1 1 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 where α = p0, p1, pK, w. Using Cramer’s rule we get ∂K 1* = ∂α p0 f L L 0 −VL α 0 p1 f L L −VL α 0 p1 f L K (1 + r ) −1 −VK α 0 0 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 ∆ 2 Making the appropriate substitutions and using the second order conditions which imply ∆ < 0; VL L < 0, (t = 0, 1), yields t t ∂K 1* = p0 f L L p1 f L L (1 + r ) −1 ∆−1 < 0 ∂pK 0 0 1 1 ∂K 1* = p0 f L L p1 (1 + r ) −2 [ f L f L K − f L L f K ]∆−1 > 0 if K1 normal ∂p1 0 0 1 1 1 1 1 ∂K 1* = p0 f L L p1 (1 + r ) −2 f L K ∆−1 ∂w1 0 0 1 1 Referring back to question 1 we see that if the parameter change makes the PP curve flatter for given K1 then the optimal period 1 capital stock is smaller. 3. (a) Draw the wealth line tangent to PP at Ç, so that p1 f K ( L*1 , K0)/pK = (1 + r) 1 3. (b) Draw a very flat wealth line so that PP is everywhere steeper than the wealth line and the optimum has D0 = 0 and p1 f K ( L*1 , Ñ1)/pK > (1 + r) 1 at Ñ1 = [p0 f(L0, K0) − wL0 + pKK0]/pK. 4. Just use [B.9] and [C.8]. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 148 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 5. Let the amount which the firm borrows be B. Then the present value of the cash flows available to the shareholders is V = V(L0, L1, K1, B) = D0 + D1 1+ r = p0 f(L0, K0) − wL0 − pK(K1 − K0) + B + 1 [p1 f(L1, K1) − wL1 − B(1 + r)] (1 + r ) (11.2) Then clearly variations in B have no effect on the value of the firm to its owners: ∂V/∂B = 1 − (1 + r)/(1 + r) = 0. The shareholders will not care about the way in which the investment plan is financed because they have access to the capital market on exactly the same terms as the firm: they can therefore nullify the effects of B on their period 0 and period 1 incomes by suitable lending or borrowing on their own account. They care only about the present value of the cash flows, not their timing. 6. (a) When interest payments are tax deductible the present value of the firm’s cash flows after payment of a tax at the rate t on its dividends is V = D0 + D1 1+ r = [p0 f(L0, K0) − wL0 − pK(K1 − K0) + B](1 − t) 1 [p1 f(L1, K1) − wL1 − B(1 + r)](1 − t) + (1 + r ) (11.3) We see that (11.3) is just (11.2) multiplied by 1 − t. The tax shifts PP radially inwards, without altering its slope at given K1. It will therefore have no effect on the firm’s optimal decisions: V ( L*0 , L*1 , K 1* , B * ) ≥ V(L0, L1, K1, B) ⇒ (1 − t)V ( L*0 , L*1 , K 1* , B * ) ≥ (1 − t)V(L0, L1, K1, B) Note again that since ∂(1 − t)V/∂B = (1 − t)[1 − (1 + r)/(1 + r)] = 0 the level of borrowing by the firm has no effect on its present value. 6. (b) With interest payments not tax deductible the present value of the firm’s cash flows is V = D0 + D1 1+ r = [p0 f(L0, K0) − wL0 − pK(K1 − K0) + B](1 − t) 1 {[p1 f(L1, K1) − wL1 − B](1 − t) − rB} + (1 + r ) © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 (11.4) Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 149 The effect of additional borrowing (holding all other decision variables constant) on the wealth of the shareholders is ∂V 1−t − rt = (1 − t) − −1+ r = ∂B 1+ r 1+ r and so the firm will reduce its borrowing to zero if possible and finance its investment by reducing D0. If the firm is forced for some reason to finance additional investment by borrowing, so that B = pKK1 then the first order condition on K1 becomes p1 f K rt dV =0 − pK − = (1 − t) dK 1 1+ r 1+ r 1 instead of [C.13]. The other first order conditions on L0, L1 are essentially unchanged by the tax. Totally differentiating the first order conditions with respect to t and applying Cramer’s rule gives p1 f K r 1 ∂K 1* + pK − = (1 − t)2 p0 f L L p1 f L L − <0 ∂t 1+ r ∆ 1+ r 1 0 0 1 1 since the first order condition on K1 implies that the penultimate term must be negative. 7. The monopolist’s first order conditions are similar to [C.11]–[C.15] except that marginal revenue MRt replaces price pt. For example, [C.15] becomes r= MR1 f K pK 1 −1 The marginal rate of return on investment is still equated to the interest rate. However the average rate of return is D1 − pK K 1 >r pK K 1 since there is no competition to drive the average return down to equal the market rate of interest. 8. Remembering that variations in K1 alter the optimal labour input in period 1, the rate of change of the slope of PP is d[− p1 f K ( L*1 , K 1 )/ pK ] 1 dK 1 = − p1 dL* f KL 1 + f KK pK dK 1 Using the earlier comparative static result (question 1) that dL*1 f = − LK dK 1 f LL © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 (11.5) 150 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 11C.1 the bracketed term in (11.5) can be rearranged as (fLL fKK − fKL fKL) 1 f LL which is negative if the production function is concave. (See Appendix I.) Hence the slope of PP becomes flatter as K1 increases if the production function is concave. 9. Assume that the borrowing rate is greater than the lending rate: rb > rl. With a single owner there are three possible optimal production and consumption decisions, illustrated in Fig. 11C.1. In case (i) the owner will prefer the production plan a and will then lend to achieve her optimal consumption. Since she wishes to lend, the relevant rate of interest for evaluating changes in the firm’s cash flows is the lending rate. Hence a is at the tangency between PP and a wealth line with slope −(1 + rᐉ). If she wishes to lend this is the optimal production plan. In case (ii) the owner’s optimal consumption plan involves borrowing and she prefers the production plan b. At b the value of the firm at the interest rate rb is maximized where the wealth line with slope −(1 + rb) is tangent to PP. If she wishes to borrow this is the optimal production plan. In case (iii) the owner does not borrow or lend on the capital market and consumes the firm’s cash flows. Thus her optimal consumption and production plans coincide. The owner’s efficient feasible consumption plans available by production and transactions in the capital market when borrowing and lending rates differ are those along the budget curve cabd. The optimal production plan a, b or an intermediate point, cannot be determined without knowledge of the owner’s preferences. Separation of production and consumption decisions is not possible if the interest rate the owner faces depends on his consumption decision. Even worse problems arise if there is more than one owner. It is possible that some owners wish to borrow and would therefore prefer production plan b, whilst others wish to lend and prefer production plan a. Under these circumstances it is not clear what is the firm’s objective function. A similar © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 151 difficulty arises under uncertainty when the incompleteness or imperfection of markets means that owners could evaluate production decisions differently. See section 21F. 10. The dividend payable would be increased by the proceeds from selling the assets after production is complete. If the assets had not depreciated: D1 = p1 f(L1, K1) − wL1 + pKK1 The PP curve would be shifted upward and would have a steeper slope p1 f K + pK dD0 =− dD1 pK 1 The level of investment would be increased. 11. (a) The present value of the firm’s cash flows (shareholders’ wealth) without the project is V 0 = ∑Dt(1 + r)−t and with it is V 1 = ∑[Dt + Rt](1 + r)−t = ∑Dt(1 + r)−t + ∑Rt(1 + r)−t = V 0 + NPV Thus accepting projects with a positive net present value will increase shareholder wealth. 11. (b) In many types of projects NPV(r) is monotone decreasing with r. (One example is a project in which there is a sequence of negative cash flows followed by a sequence of positive cash flows.) If NPV(r) is monotone decreasing with r then NPV(r) > 0 ⇔ i > r and the two criteria are equivalent. 11. (c) (i) NPV(i) = 0 is a polynomial equation in i which has T – 1 roots for a project with T cash flows. Only if the cash flows satisfy certain conditions will it be the case that there is a single positive real root with NPV decreasing at this root. In general there may be multiple roots, in which case it is not clear which of the roots should be compared with the market rate of interest. (ii) If the market rate of interest differs in different periods NPV can still be easily calculated but there is no obvious market rate with which the internal rate of return can be compared. (iii) The internal rate of return criterion can also be misleading for mutually exclusive projects. Consider project A with cash flows −10, 15 which has an internal rate of return of 50% and project B with cash flows −100, 120 and internal rate of return 20%. Project A has a smaller NPV at a rate of interest of 10%. Thus choosing the project with the larger internal rate of return could lead to wealth not being maximized. Supplementary questions (i) Show that increases in r always reduce NPV if the project consists of a sequence of negative cash flows followed by a sequence of positive cash flows. (ii) What is the formula for NPV when the market rate of interest differs in different time periods? (iii) Construct a project with two positive internal rates of return. (iv) How could you adapt the internal rate of return criterion so that it could be used to decide between mutually exclusive projects? © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 152 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 11D.1 Exercise 11D 1. (a) A simple example has the consumer with utility function u = min(M0/α0, M1/α1) and endowment (R0, R1), with R1/R0 < α1/α0. The indifference curves are rectangular and have corners on the ray with slope α1/α0. The consumer will never borrow. (Draw the diagram.) 1. (b) Same preferences as in (a) but with R1/R0 > α1/α0. 1. (c) In Fig. 11D.1 a reduction in r shifts the consumer from a to b so that c0 is reduced and borrowing is reduced. The wealth effect bc outweighs the substitution effect ac. Since increases in r can make the consumer better or worse off, depending on whether he is a lender or borrower, to guarantee that Ac is negatively sloped we must assume that the substitution effect is always larger than the absolute value of the wealth effect. 2. The precise effects depend on the consumer preferences and the changes in the feasible set. The latter are the same for all consumers. 2. (a) The consumer’s wealth line is shifted out and his endowment point shifted vertically upward. If M0 is a normal good he will increase M0 and since R0 is unchanged his borrowing is increased (or lending is reduced). 2. (b) A tax on endowed income shifts the endowment point inward along the ray with slope R1/R0. 2. (c) The budget constraint is kinked at the endowment point with a slope −(1 + r) to the right for borrowing and −(1 + r(1 − t)) to the left for lending. 3. and 4. The implications of the changes depend on whether the horizontal sum of the individual Ac curves is shifted up or down. This depends on the particular assumptions about preferences and endowments of the different consumers. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 153 Fig. 11D.2 5. In Fig. 11D.2 aM* is the substitution effect, ab is the wealth effect and bM** the production effect. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 154 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Chapter 12 General Equilibrium Exercise 12B 1. With the βhi (individual shareholdings) taken as exogenously given, substituting from [B.5] in the text into [B.2] allows us to write the consumer’s wealth as Wh = ∑β ∑ p S (p , p ,..., p ) hi i j ij 1 2 n j Since the Sij are homogeneous of degree 0 in prices, W h is homogeneous of degree 1 in prices, i.e. Wh ( kp10 , kp20 , . . . , kpn0 ) = kW h ( p10 , p20 , . . . , pn0 ) (Note we have supressed the βhi in the function W h because they are assumed not to change). When we solve the problem max uh s.t. ∑p V j hj ≤ Wh = W h(p1, p2, . . . , pn) j the parameters of the problem (excluding initial endowments of goods and shares) are simply the prices pj and so the consumer’s net demands can be written as functions of these alone. Since both sides of the budget constraint are homogeneous of degree 1 in prices, demands will be unaffected by an equiproportional increase in prices and so the net demand functions are homogeneous of degree zero. 2. As the price of a good falls to zero, the demand for it could go to infinity, i.e. its demand curve has no quantity intercept (for example a Cobb-Douglas utility function has this feature). The simple form of the non-satiation axiom implies this: more of any one good is always preferred to less. The solution is to modify this axiom to one of local non-satiation: for any one good taken individually there is always a satiation point, beyond which more is indifferent to less, but we assume that every consumer is always in the region of the consumption space at which she is non-satiated in at least one good. She will always be on her budget constraint. The reason for being concerned with this problem is that if, at some points in the set of price-vectors, the consumer’s demand for a good goes to infinity, we cannot assume the continuity of the mapping from prices to excess demands, which plays such an important role in the existence proof. It does seem reasonable to restrict attention to economies in which resources overall are relatively scarce, even if consumers can be satiated in particular commodities. 154 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 155 3. It is clear enough that if supply cannot meet demand some consumption plans cannot be realized. If supply exceeds demand then suppliers cannot sell all they planned but if unsold output is costless to dispose of then there are no resource implications for having excess supply and so no modification needs to be made to supply functions themselves in situations of excess supply. Firms will however prefer to sell output at a positive price if they can, rather than throw it away, and this of course underlies the process by which excess supply results in bidding down prices. Exercise 12C 1. Zero degree homogeneity allows the normalization of the price vectors to make the price set closed and bounded as well as convex. This, and the continuity of the excess demand functions then allows Brouwer’s Theorem to be used to establish existence of a fixed point. Walras’ Law is important in defining the mapping back from the set of excess demands to the set of price vectors. First, it is used (see question 6 of this Exercise) to establish that the denominator in [C.20] is non-zero and so the renormalization can be applied. It is then used repeatedly in establishing that the fixed point of the composite mapping really is an equilibrium. 2. In Fig. 12.3 of the text, point d is to the right of point c because point c generates the point γ in excess demand space, where z1 > 0 and z2 < 0. Thus, under the rule defining the reverse mapping k, p1 must be raised and p2 lowered, implying a rightward move along the line ab. The reason f is to the left of e follows similarly. 3. (a) The mapping is essentially based on the linear functions p′j + kj zj, where p′j ≥ 0 and kj > 0 are constants. Thus any sequence of zj-values tending to a limit, say z 0j will cause p′j + kj zj to tend to the limit p ′j + k j z 0j . The max(.,.) introduces a kink in this function, at that z 0j = − p′j / k j , but no discontinuity there, since lim z →z p′j + kj zj = 0 = p′j + k j z 0j in this case also. Then the denominator is the sum of continuous functions and is itself therefore continuous, while, as we show below, its value is also bounded away from zero, so the domain of the mapping is in effect restricted to z-vectors which do not create difficulties due to the unboundedness of pj. j 0 j 3. (b) If zj is a linear function of p′j we have zj = aj + bj p′j aj ≥ 0 and so pj = max(0, p′j + kj(aj + b j p′j )) = max(0, ajkj + (1 + b j k j ) p′j ) If bj < 0 (which we tend to assume intuitively even though Giffen goods may exist) and bj kj < −1, then the graph in question will, for aj > 0, be a negatively-sloped line until it hits the p′j axis, at which it then coincides with the axis; or, if aj = 0, it is simply the axis. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 156 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 4. If p′ and p″ are such that ∑ p ′j = ∑ p ′′j = 1 and F = kp′ + (1 − k)p″, 0 ≤ k ≤ 1, then Fj = kp′j + (1 − k) p′′j and ∑Fj = k ∑ p′j + (1 − k) ∑ p′′j = 1 as required. 5. This is simply a plane with vertices at (1, 0, 0), (0, 1, 0), (0, 0, 1). 6. Suppose to the contrary that max[0, p′j + kjzj(p′)] = 0 for every j. Since kj > 0 for all j while p′j > 0 for at least one j, this implies that zj(p′) ≤ 0 for all j and zj(p′) < 0 for at least that one j. But then we cannot have ∑ p′j z j (p′) = 0 as required by Walras’ Law, since at least one term of the sum is strictly negative and there are no positive terms to cancel it out. So, Walras’ Law ensures the mapping in [C.16] is well-defined. Exercise 12D 1. The essential answer to the question can be given algebraically, the sketch of the figure is left to the reader. We have two excess demand functions z1(p1, p2), z2(p1, p2). Normalizing prices by setting p2 = 1 and letting p1 now denote the relative price p1/p2, we note that gross substitutability implies ∂z2/∂p1 > 0. Also, Walras’ Law states p1z1(p1) + z2(p1) = 0 If p1* is the equilibrium relative price, Walras’ Law holds at this point too, with, also z1 ( p1* ) = z2 ( p2* ) = 0 Now let p1* fall. By gross substitutability, z2 must fall also – becoming negative – while therefore, from Walras’ Law, z1 must increase – becoming positive. The converse follows from increasing p1 from p1* . Thus, graphed against p1, z1(p) is negatively-sloped and z2(p) is positively-sloped. It follows that if we begin with p10 > p1* and reduce p1 we move toward equilibrium and if p10 < p1* and we increase p1 we again move toward equilibrium. Thus the tatonnement process would be stable in this case. If Y1 > p1* and Y2 < p2* then gross-substitutability implies z1(Y1, Y2) < 0, z2(Y1, Y2) > 0 Then we must have ( p1* − Y1)z1(Y1, Y2) + ( p2* − Y1)z2(Y1, Y2) > 0 which again gives © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 157 p1* z1(Y1, Y2) + p2* z2(Y1, Y2) > Y1z1(Y1, Y2) + Y2z2(Y1, Y2) = 0 as required. 3. Gross-substitutability refers to the effects of price changes on excess demands zj(p) = Dj(p) − Sj(p) Since ∂z j ∂pk = ∂d j ∂pk − ∂S j ∂p k >0j≠k goods could be (Marshallian) complements in demand as long as they were sufficiently strong substitutes in supply, or conversely and still satisfy this assumption. Using the Slutsky equation we have ∂z j ∂pk = s ik − D k ∂d j ∂pk − ∂S j ∂pk >0j≠k where sik > 0 if the goods are Hicksian substitutes and sik < 0 if they are Hicksian complements. Both cases are clearly consistent with gross substitutability given that the other two terms in the expression can take either sign. Exercise 12E 1. (a) If two consumers are at different points in an Edgeworth box then the sum of their consumptions of at least one good is not equal to the total amount available. 1. (b) If 1 is at a point southwest of 2, the sum of the consumptions of both goods is less than their total supply. If 1 is northeast of 2 then the sum of consumptions of each good exceeds the available supply. 1. (c) At a single point on a vertical side of the box, the consumers are both consuming x2 but one of them is consuming all of x1. At a single point on the horizontal side we have the reverse. 1. (d) Rotate the figure for consumer 2 until its origin is diagonally opposite 1’s origin, and superimpose 2’s figure on 1’s, ensuring that the lengths of the sides reflect available quantities of goods. 1. (e) The bottom right hand corner of the box 2’s origin. 1. (f) This is somewhat ambiguous, since scales could be chosen for measuring quantities of the goods such that the box is always square. However, assuming the same distance on each axis is chosen for ‘one unit’ of each good, the box is square if there are equal numbers of units of the goods. A sufficient condition for no trade to take place would be that the consumers’ marginal rates of substitution are equal at the initial endowment point (indifference curves are tangent there). If this is not the case (indifference curves intersect) some mutually beneficial trade can always be found. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 158 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn I2 02 I1 α C I2M M l R2 I1 01 Fig. 12F.1 2. The contract curve would lie along a side of the box if there is a corner solution to the exchange problem, with one consumer receiving the entire amount of one of the goods in equilibrium (see (c) of the previous question). At such a point it need no longer be the case that the consumers’ marginal rates of substitution are equal. We have the following cases, where MRS12i is consumer i’s marginal rate of substitution between the goods: (i) if the equilibrium is on the lower horizontal side (2 consumes all the y) then MRS121 ≥ MRS122 : 2 would not be prepared to compensate 1 at the rate required to move into the interior of the box (1’s indifference curve is at least as steep as 2’s at the equilibrium point; (ii) if on the left hand vertical side then MRS121 ≤ MRS122 at the equilibrium; (iii) if on the upper horizontal side then MRS121 ≤ MRS122 ; (iv) if on the right hand vertical side then MRS121 ≥ MRS122 . The reader should now take Fig. 12.5 of the text and sketch each of these cases. 3. Here, if each consumer’s indifference curves had linear segments then a ‘tangency’ could take the form of the coincidence of these segments for the consumers. Exercise 12F 1. Essentially 1 should find the allocation which maximizes her utility subject to the constraint that 2 be on his offer curve. In Fig. 12F.1 (which is based on Fig. 12.7) if 1 offers 2 the price ratio implied by the line α l, 2 will choose point M which makes 1 better off than any other point on 2’s offer curve, including the competitive equilibrium E. However, this point is not in the core (and cannot be, because it can never be an intersection point of offer curves) and so can be improved upon. For example, 1 could be made still better off, and 2 no worse off if they traded along I 2M to point C. Note, however that point C could not be reached if there were a constraint on the nature of the trading process, which ruled out any form of exchange except that in which 1 must offer 2 a given price at which all units are to be traded. Diagrammatically, 1 can only offer 2 a given line from the initial endowment point. This constraint then makes M the best point for 1. This example relates closely to the discussion of the welfare effects © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 159 of monopoly and price discrimination in Chapter 14. As a link between the two, note that if the initial endowment point were such that 1 owned all of one of the goods, then the above analysis would go through essentially unchanged but would explain why, when a monopolist is contrained to sell all units of his good at the same price, there is an economic inefficiency in the sense that the resulting allocation is not in the core of the economy. To reach a point in the core other than a competitive equilibrium, ‘price discrimination’ or ‘non-linear pricing’ must be feasible, under which different units of the good are sold at different prices. 2. If x* is chosen at price p* and x′ is strictly preferred to x* then it must cost more, i.e. p*x′ > p*x*, otherwise it would have been chosen. If x′ and x* are indifferent, but x* is chosen at point p*, then strict convexity of preferences again implies that px′ > p*x* (review the discussion of the expenditure function in Chapter 3). 3. Just go through equations [F.1] to [F.11] for this 4-consumer case. 4. Since consumers of the same type have identical preferences and initial endowments they solve exactly the same optimization problem. If preferences are strictly convex, the solution to the problem is unique and so they all consume the same bundle in equilibrium. 5. Simply set xB′ 1 = xB′ 2 and y B′ 1 = y B′ 2 in [F.15] and [F.16] of the text and note that the proof goes through just as before, noting that B1 would be indifferent to the trade (therefore why not make it?) while A1 will be strictly better off. 6. All we need to do is let A2 drop his deal with B2 and return to the initial endowment point. He can then trade with A1 to reach c0 in text Fig. 12.9. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 160 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Chapter 13 Welfare Economics Exercise 13B 1. Rewrite the Lagrangean [B.5] interchanging the two individuals so that the first two terms are u2(x21, x22, z2) + λ[E1 − u1(x11, x12, z1)]. The first order conditions are identical in form to [B.6] to [B.11] except that u1i , u1z are interchanged with ui2 , u z2 . The tangency conditions are also identical in form since the Lagrange multiplier λ on the utility constraint cancels out. In terms of text Fig. 13.1, it does not matter whether we determine FF by maximizing u1 for given u2 or vice versa. 2. (a) It is sufficient to assume strictly quasi-concave utility functions and strictly concave production functions. 2. (b) The endowment constraint zh ≤ Kh binds if individual h’s marginal rate of substitution between the input and one of the goods it produces (the marginal cost of his input in terms of that good) is less than the marginal product of his input in producing that good. If we interpret zh as labour then the marginal cost of labour can be plausibly assumed to become arbitrarily large as zh tends to Kh, so that the constraint will not bind when the input is labour. 2. (c) The tangency conditions are replaced by suitable inequalities (as for example in the consumer optimization example in section 2C). 2. (d) The multipliers measure the rate at which the maximized value of the objective function changes as there is a marginal change in the relevant constraint parameter. Thus λ is the rate at which u1 falls as E2 increases (it is the reciprocal of the slope of FF in Fig. 13.1). ρi is the rate at which u1 increases if the material balance constraint xi ≥ ∑xhi is relaxed to xi + ∆i ≥ ∑xhi where ∆i is a small endowment of good i. ωi is the value of relaxing [B.3] by increasing the endowment of input h. µi is the rate at which u1 increases if the output produced by (zi1, zi2) is increased from f i(zi1, zi2) to f i(zil, zi2) + ∆i. Note that µi = ρi: relaxations in [B.1] and [B.2] are equally valuable. Exercise 13C 1. (a) The Lagrangean is L = W(u1, u2, . . . , uH) + ∑ ρ [x − ∑ x ] i i ih i + ∑ ω [z − ∑ z ] + ∑ µ [f (z , . . . , z ) − x ] i h h 160 h h ih i i i1 i © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 iH i Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 161 Fig. 13C.1 with first order conditions for a non-corner solution ∂L ∂x ih = Wh uih − ρi = 0, h = 1, . . . , H; ∂L ∂zh = Wh uzh + ωi = 0, h = 1, . . . , H ∂L ∂zih = −ωh − µ i f hi = 0, h = 1, . . . , H; ∂L ∂xi = ρi − µi = 0, i = 1, . . . , n i = 1, . . . , n i = 1, . . . , n plus the constraints. 1. (b) The Wh terms can be cancelled out by suitable rearrangement to give a set of tangency conditions which are identical in form to the efficiency conditions of section B. For example write the conditions on xih and xjh as Wh uih = ρi, Wh u hj = ρj and divide one equation by the other to give u ih ρi = , u hj ρ j h = 1, . . . , H; i, j = 1, . . . , n; i≠j 2. See Fig. 13C.1. The welfare contours are right angled about the 45° line in (u1, u2) space. Only if the FF curve was upward sloping as it crossed the 45° line would the Rawlsian optimum not be at the 45° line where the individuals have equal utility. For example, it may be necessary to give one of the individuals a larger income than the other if that individual is very productive and cannot be induced to provide large output in any other way: there is a trade off between equity and total output. Note that the Rawlsian optimum is always Pareto efficient. 3. The swf contours of a utilitarian are straight lines with slope −1, as in Fig. 13C.1. The optimal allocation will not in general have equal utilities. If FF is symmetric about the © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 162 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 13C.2 45° line the utilitarian and Rawlsian optima coincide. This requires that the individuals have identical preferences and productivities. 4. The slope of the contours of W in (x1h, x2h) space if W = W(u1, u2) are dx 2 h Wh u1h u1h = = dx1 h Wh u2h u2h which depends only on the bundle consumed by h. A non-paternal swf is weakly separable in the individual consumption bundles. 5. In Fig. 13C.2 a is measured horizontally and, without any loss in generality, we have set a1 = 0 (no restriction) and a2 = 1 (say a complete ban). OS is the origin for the smoker, who prefers a larger income yS and smaller a (less restrictive law). ON is the origin for the non-smoker who prefers more income yN and a more restrictive law. The vertical side of the box measures the total income of the two parties. The initial position is at b. After the ban the new position is at c. N is better off at c than b and could pay up to ce and still be better off as a result of the change from a1 to a2. Thus CV12N = ce. S is worse off and would have to be compensated with cd additional income: CV12S = −cd. The ban passes the Hicks-Kaldor compensation test since ∑i CV12i = de > 0 A move from a2 to a1 (c to b) makes N worse off ( CV21N = −bf) and S better off ( CV21S = bg). Since ∑i CV21i = gf > 0 removing the ban also passes the Hicks-Kaldor compensation test. A paradox requires CV12S + CV12N > 0 and CV21S + CV21N > 0 which implies ( CV12N + CV21N ) + ( CV12S + CV21S ) > 0 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 (13.1) Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 163 Fig. 13C.3 If a is a normal good for N, then, since he is better off at c than b, the amount he is willing to pay for the increase in a is less than the amount she would have to be paid in compensation for the decrease: CV12N < − CV21N or CV12N + CV21N < 0. If a is a normal good for S then the amount she must be paid in compensation for the increase in a is greater than the amount which she would be willing to pay for the reduction in a: − CV12S > CV21S or CV12S + CV21S < 0. Hence if a is normal for both parties (13.1) cannot be satisfied and so the paradox cannot arise. Equivalently: a necessary condition for a paradox is that a is an inferior good for at least one of the parties. 6. In Fig. 13C.3 a2 passes the Scitovsky test relative to a1 and a3 passes the Scitovsky test relative to a2. But a1 passes the Scitovsky test relative to a3. 7. From the definition of the compensating variation vh(yh − CV h, p1) = vh(yh, p0) and so the change in W as p changes from p0 to p1 is W(v1(y1, p1), v2(y2, p1)) − W(v1(y1 − CV 1, p1), v2(y2 − CV 2, p1)) = ∑∫ 0 h =σ CV h ∑∫ h Wh vyh ( yh − CV h − Sh, p1)dSh CV h 0 dSh = σ ∑ CV h h if Wh vyh = σ, h = 1, 2, so that the social marginal utility of income is constant and equal across all consumers. Exercise 13D 1. If there is no market in one of the goods we must specify how its level is determined at the equilibrium of the economy. An obvious assumption is that the individuals have © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 164 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn an endowment of this good (say good 0) and since they cannot trade it or firms produce it, they are forced to consume their endowment of the good 0. For goods for which there are markets consumers will adjust their consumption until uih = λhpi where λh is consumer h’s marginal utility of income and pi the market price of good i. The marginal rate of substitution between good i and the unmarketed good 0 is therefore u0h u0h = u ih λ h p i and since there is no market in which consumers can adjust their consumption of good 0 until u0h = λhp0 their marginal rates of substitution between the unmarketed good and the marketed goods will not be equalised. 2. Let xih be the net demand for good i by individual h (the difference between consumption and endowment). Then from the budget constraints x1h + px2h = 0, we can write uh(x1h, x2h) = uh(−px2h, x2h) where p is the price of good 2 in terms of good 1. Individual 2 treats p as a parameter and announces her true utility maximizing demand x22(p) at p where x22(p) satisfies du2/dx22 = − u12 p + u22 = 0 and we assume for simplicity that x22 ′ ( p) < 0. The Walrasian equilibrium p is determined by the equilibrium condition for market 2: x21 + x22(p) = 0 (13.2) (remember Walras Law implies that with both individuals’ budget constraints binding equilibrium in n − 1 markets implies that there is equilibrium in the remaining market). Individual 1 realises that (13.2) implies that p depends on his announced demand: p = p(x21) with p′(x21) = −1/ x22 ′ ( p) > 0. He therefore chooses x21 to maximize u1 = u1(−p(x21)x21, x21) so that the first order condition is −[p + x21p′(x21)] u11 + u21 = 0 Hence the equilibrium satisfies u21 1 1 u22 = ≠ = u11 p + x 21 p ′ p u12 and is not Pareto efficient. See Fig. 13D.1 (and compare Fig. 12.7). Individual 1 realises that individual 2 will always announce a demand on her offer curve αR2 through her endowment α. By announcing a demand of V21 individual 1 can ensure an equilibrium price of Y and get to β where his utility is maximized along αR2. Compared with the Walrasian equilibrium price p* at E, individual 1 has restricted his supply of the good he is selling and driven up its relative price, making himself better off and individual 2 worse off. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 165 Fig. 13D.1 Exercise 13E 1. Let ti be the per unit tax on good i, so that firms get the net price pi and consumers pay pi + ti. Since all consumers face the same relative gross of tax price ratios (pi + ti)/(pj + tj) for goods consumed, their MRS for these goods are equal. The budget constraint for consumer h is ∑ ( p + t )x − wz − ∑ β π = 0 k i i hi hk h k Consumers’ MRSiz between consumption of good i and supply of the input is set equal to the relative price ratio w/(pi + ti). But firms adjust their use of the input in production of good i until the net of tax value of the increase in the output of good i equals the price of the input : piMPi = w. Hence MPi = w/pi > MRSiz. Consumers and firms place different marginal values on the input in terms of good i, thus violating [B.7]. An equal rate proportional purchase tax at the rate t would also violate [B.7] and would be equivalent to an income tax at the rate θ = t/(1 + t) since ∑ p (1 + t)x − wz − ∑ β π = 0 k i hi hk h k and ∑ p x − w(1 − θ)z − (1 − θ) ∑ β π = 0 k i hi hk h k are equivalent constraints. 2. Since potential tax payers can always emigrate we cannot think of any non-distorting tax or subsidy. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 166 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Exercise 13F 1. One example is (a, b, c)1, (a, c, b)2, (b, c, a)3 which yields [a, b], [b, c], [a, c]. 3. See text page 310. To demonstrate that acyclicity is less demanding consider the preference orderings (a, b, c)1, (a, b, c)2, (c, a, b)3, (b, c, a)4 with a majority voting rule which ranks two alternatives as indifferent if they have the same number of votes. Then [a, b], [b, c] but a and c are indifferent. Hence transitivity is violated but acyclicity is not. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 167 Chapter 14 Market Failure and Government Failure Exercise 14B 1. (a) A lump sum or proportional profits tax has no effect on monopoly output but transfers income from the owners of the monopoly to the beneficiaries of the government expenditure or reductions in other taxation financed with the proceeds. 1. (b) The inefficiency is worsened: a tax on sales reduces output because marginal revenue is reduced. 1. (c) Since marginal revenue with a per unit subsidy of s is d(p + s)x/dx = p + s + p′x, setting s = −p′x leads the monopolist to produce where p = MC. 1. (d) Setting pmax = p* where p* is defined by the intersection of the demand and marginal cost curves induces an efficient output. 1. (e) Competition for the right to be a monopolist will lead the highest bidder to make a bid equal to the maximum profit that the monopoly could earn. The successful bidder will then choose a profit maximizing output. The bidding regime merely appropriates the monopoly profit for the government. 1. (f) Competition amongst bidders will drive the profit from the monopoly to zero and the bid price down to average cost, not to marginal cost. Supplementary question (i) Draw diagrams to show that a price equal to average cost could be better or worse than the profit maximizing price. 2. (a) First degree price discrimination. Type i consumers have quasi-linear utility Ui(xi) + yi and their marginal rates of substitution between the monopolised good and the composite commodity are MRS i = dyi U ′( x ) = − i i = −U i′( xi ) dxi 1 The marginal rate of transformation between the composite commodity and the monopolised good is the marginal cost of the monopolised good: the amount of the composite commodity that must be given up to produce one additional unit of the monopolised good. The monopoly sets a price to type i equal to marginal cost: pi = c and each type chooses xi so that U 1′ (x1) = p1 = c = p2 = U 2′ (x2) © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 167 168 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Hence marginal rates of substitution are equal for the two types and equal to the marginal rate of transformation. Thus the necessary conditions for Pareto Efficiency are satisfied. (There are no changes in the allocation which will make either type of consumer or the monopolist better off without making someone else worse off.) 2. (b) Second degree price discrimination. Recall from page 202 that type 2 consumers who place a higher marginal value on the good (have a higher marginal rate of substitution) face a price equal to marginal cost, so that MRS2 = p2 = c. But type 1 consumers face a price above marginal cost because the monopolist does not observe consumer types and has to offer a menu of prices and fixed charges which induces the consumers to reveal their types honestly. Thus MRS1 = p1 > c. If type 2 consumers could trade with type 1 consumers they could offer to buy some of the type 1’s consumption at a price which is above marginal cost and below the price that the type 2 consumers are paying. Both types would be better off. The monopolist would be no worse off, provided that both types continued to buy the same amount from the monopolist, so that the arbitrage merely redistributed consumption between purchasers. 2. (c) Third degree price discrimination. The consumers in the separated markets face different prices (and both prices are above marginal cost) so that marginal rates of substitution are not equalised and are greater than the marginal rate of transformation. Consumers buying in the low price market could resell the good to consumers in the high price market at a price between the low and high prices set by the monopolist and both types of consumers would be better off. The monopolist would be no worse off provided that the amounts sold by the monopolist to the two markets did not alter. 3. Let p = p(x, q) be the inverse demand function relating the price (consumers’ marginal willingness to pay) to output x and quality q, with px < 0, pq > 0. Let c(x, q), cx > 0, cq > 0 be the cost function. Using willingness to pay (the area under the demand curve) less cost as the measure of social benefit from the good, the marginal benefit from quality improvement is ∫ p ( 8, q)d8 − c (x, q) x 0 q q whereas the marginal effect on profit is pq(x, q)x − cq(x, q) In general the marginal social benefit and the marginal private benefit to the monopolist from quality changes will not be equal. In Fig. 14B.1 for example, increasing q from q0 to q1 increases revenue by the rectangle (p1 − p0)x, whereas the benefit to consumers increases by the shaded area abcd. Since the firm’s reward for increasing quality differs from the social benefit it will choose the wrong quality. In the example in the figure it will choose too low a quality. The fact that quality is a public good for consumers increases the difficulty of forming a coalition to share the costs of bribing the firm to vary its quality level. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 169 Fig. 14B.1 Fig. 14B.2 Supplementary questions (i) Draw a diagram in which the monopolist has too great an incentive to improve quality. (ii) What restrictions on p(x, q) ensure that the monopolist’s quality choice is welfare maximizing at any given quantity? 4. (a) Assume that the welfare function is W = −x − π (x)L so that P and D have equal weight. The socially optimal care level x* minimizes the sum of the cost of care and expected accident costs and satisfies Wx = −1 − π ′(x*)L = 0 See Fig. 14B.2. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 170 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 4. (b) With the three legal regimes D’s objective function u(x) is No liability Strict liability Negligence u = −x u = −x − π(x)L u = −x − π(x)L u = −x if x < x0 if x ≥ x0 where x0 is the due care standard set by the courts: the defendant is held to be negligent if care is less than the due care standard. No liability leads to no care and strict liability to efficient care. See Fig. 14B.2 for the negligence regime. Under such a regime D’s objective function is discontinuous at the due care level x0: her expected costs are shown by the upper curve plotting x + π(x)L up to x0 and by the 450 line beyond x0. Consider the level of care V defined by x* + π(x*)L = V. When x0 < V the optimal care level for D is x = x0 and when x0 > V her optimal care is x*. Hence if the due care standard is x0 = x* or x0 > V D will take an efficient amount of care. Note that a high enough due care standard is equivalent to strict liability and induces efficiency. 4. (c) The welfare function is now W = −x − y − π(x, y)L and the efficient care levels satisfy Wx = −1 − πx(x*, y*)L = 0 Wy = −1 − πy(x*, y*)L = 0 If D is not liable she sets x = 0. However P’s care is efficient (for given x) since he bears the full cost of the accident and so chooses y to minimize y + π(x, y)L. If D is strictly liable she takes an efficient level of care (for given y) but P takes no care. Since he never bears any of the accident costs he has no incentive to take care. Under a negligence regime if D takes due care (x = x0), she will not be liable and P will bear the full accident cost and will be motivated to take efficient care (for given x). Hence if the due care standard is set at x0 = x* both parties will take efficient care. 5. (a) and (b) The equilibrium input level is determined by the breakeven condition (p − t)f(L) = (w + θ)L where t, θ are taxes on output and the input respectively. Hence the equilibrium input is Ö = Ö((p − t)/(w + θ)). Since Ö′ > 0 increases in either tax will reduce the equilibrium input and output, the efficient input level L* can be achieved by setting suitable taxes so that Ö((p − t)/(w + θ)) = L*. Since the equilibrium depends on the relative price ratio the optimal taxes are not unique. 5. (c) A firm with monopoly power over output would choose L to maximize p(f(L))f(L) − wL. There would be no over exploitation since the resource is no longer free access but the firm would choose an inefficiently small input level. 6. Fig. 14B.3 plots the value of the average and marginal product curves. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 171 Fig. 14B.3 Invert the production function to get the input requirement function L(q). Average cost is wL(q) so that the breakeven condition is pq = wL(q) or pq/w − L(q) = rq − L(q) = 0 where r = p/w. Hence the supply function is dq −q −q = = dr r − L ′( q) ( p/ w) − (1 f ′) Since pf′ < w at the equilibrium, dq/dr > 0 when f′ > 0 and dq/dr < 0 when f′ < 0. Hence the backward bending supply curve in Fig. 14B.4. With r = r0 the equilibrium is at q0. Let a(q), a′ > 0 be the cost to a driver of making a trip along a road where q is the number of drivers making the trip. (The cost includes the value of the time taken over the trip. As the number of drivers increases the time each takes increases and so the cost of the trip for each driver increases.) Each driver decides to make the trip if the benefit from it exceeds its cost. If we rank the drivers in decreasing order of the size of their benefits we can derive a function b(q), b′ < 0 which gives the benefit to the marginal driver when there are q drivers. The equilibrium number of drivers is determined by b(q) = a(q). However the social cost of q trips is qa(q) so that the marginal social cost of an additional trip is a(q) + qa′(q) > a(q) Each driver takes account only of the cost of a trip to them (a) and ignores the fact that their journey increases the costs of all other drivers making the trip. Thus the private marginal cost is the average social cost. The difference between private and social marginal cost is the congestions cost qa′(q). We can illustrate this in Fig. 14B.4 if we let the horizontal axis measure the number of trips and the vertical axis measure b and a. The equilibrium number of trips is q0 where the demand curve for trips b(q) cuts the marginal private cost curve a(q). The efficient number of trips is q** where marginal social benefit and marginal social cost of trips are equal. This could be achieved by levying a toll of t = q**a′(q**) per trip. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 172 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 14B.4 7. The material balance constraints are yi ≥ ∑hxhi, i = 1, . . . , n; q ≥ q1 = . . . = qH, where yi is the net output of commodity i (yi < 0 if commodity i is an input), xhi is the net consumption (consumption less endowment) of commodity i by individual h, q is the output of the public good, qh is individual h’s consumption of the public good. The production function constraint is written implicitly (see section 5E) as g(y1, . . . , yn, q) ≤ 0. The Lagrangean for the welfare maximization problem is L = W(u1, . . . , uH) + ∑ ρ (y − ∑ x ) − µg(y , . . . , y , q) i i i hi 1 n (14.1) h where uh(xh1, . . . , xhn, qh) is h’s utility function defined in terms of net consumption (see section 2E). We assume that all the constraints bind so that we can substitute q for qh. With a non-corner solution the first order conditions are ∂L = Whuih − ρ i = 0, ∂xhi ∂L = ρi − µgi = 0, ∂yi ∂L ∂q = h = 1, . . . , H; i = 1, . . . , n i = 1, . . . , n ∑ u − µg = 0 h q q h plus the constraints. Use the conditions on the xhi to substitute pi / uih for Wh in the condition on q, substitute µgi for pi and rearrange to get − uqh ∑u h h i =− gq gi The left hand side is the sum of consumers’ marginal rates of substitution between the public good and commodity i and the right hand side is the marginal rate of © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 173 substitution between q and i. Thus efficiency requires that consumers’ summed marginal valuations of the public good in terms of commodity i should be equal to its marginal cost in terms of commodity i. If the public good was optional (e.g. a broadcast) the material balance constraint on the public good becomes q ≥ qh, h = 1, . . . , H. Adding ∑hλh(q − qh) to (14.1) yields first order conditions which are very similar to those previously derived except for ∂L = − µg q + λh = 0 ∂q h ∑ ∂L = Wh uqh − λ h = 0, h ∂q h = 1, . . . , H Substituting for λh gives the same efficiency conditions as before. 9. Suppose ∑j≠i Tj > 0. Then i gets Ti + if vi ∑T > 0 j j≠i and −Ti = − ∑T if j Ti + j≠i ∑T ≤ 0 j j≠i Hence if vi ≥ − ∑j≠i Tj then i should announce Ti ≥ vi and get a payoff of vi. On the other hand if vi < − ∑j≠i Tj then i should announce Ti ≤ vi and get a payoff of −Ti = −∑j≠i Tj Conversely suppose ∑j≠i Tj ≤ 0. Then i gets vi − Ti = vi + ∑T j if Ti + j≠i ∑T > 0 j j≠i and 0 if Ti + ∑T ≤ 0 j j≠i Hence if vi + ∑j≠i Tj ≥ 0 then i should announce Ti ≥ vi ≥ −∑j≠i Tj and get a payoff of vi − Ti = vi + ∑j≠i Tj. On the other hand if vi + ∑j≠i Tj < 0 then i should announce Ti ≤ vi ≤ − ∑j≠i Tj and get a payoff of 0. Thus if i knows all the other announcements he cannot do better than announce Ti = vi ie tell the truth whatever the strategies of the other players. 9. (b) Individuals 3 and 4 are better off without the project but will not individually misrepresent their preferences to prevent it given that all other individuals tell the truth because each would have to pay the tax ∑ j ≠ i v j . Suppose that they both agree to report Ti < −25, i = 3, 4. Then since T4 + v1 + v2 < 0 individual 3 can report T3 < −25 and not have to bear the tax because her report does not alter the decision. Similarly, since T3 + v1 + v2 < 0 individual 4 can report T4 < −25 and also not have to bear the tax because his report does not alter the decision either. Since such reports stop the project and do not lead to either of them bearing the tax, individuals 3 and 4 have an incentive to collude. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 174 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Exercise 14C 1. (a) Monopoly i has the profit function πi(p1, p2) = piDi(p1, p2) − ci(Di(p1, p2)) The private sector monopoly 2 chooses p2 to maximize its profit, so that π22(p1, p2) = D2 + (p2 − c2′ ) D22 = 0 (14.2) holds. This first order condition implicitly defines the profit maximizing price as a function of the price of the public monopoly: p2 = f(p1). The welfare criterion is the sum of consumer surplus and firm profit: W= ∑ ∫ D dp + ∑ π = W ( p , p ) ∞ i pi i i i 1 2 i and Wi = −Di + πii = (pi − ci′) Dii (We assume that income effects are zero so that Dij = Dji and the sum of consumer surpluses does not depend on the path over which prices vary.) The welfare maximizing p1 given that p2 = f(p1) satisfies dp dW = W1 + W2 2 = ( p1 − c1′ ) D11 + ( p2 − c 2′ ) f ′( p1 ) = 0 dp1 dp1 and suitable manipulation and division by p1, p2, D1, D2 gives the expression in the text. 1. (b) Partial differentiation of π22 with respect to p1 gives π221 = D21 + (p2 − c2′ ) D221 − c 2′′D22 D12 Now if the demand function for good 2 is of the form D2 = a(p1) − bp2, a > 0, b > 0 and firm 2 has constant marginal cost ( c 2′′ = 0) then the usual comparative static analysis establishes that sign f ′(p1) = sign π221 = sign D21 Thus if the goods are substitutes (Dij < 0) the optimal second best price of good 1 exceeds its marginal cost. Exercise 14D 1. (a) There are always majorities for increasing q from qi to qi+1 if i < M = (n + 1)/2. Conversely for reducing q from qi to qi−1 if i > M. At qM a majority will vote against an increase or a decrease. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 175 Fig. 14D.1 1. (b) At qM we have B M′ (qM) = c′(qM)/n, whereas the condition for efficiency in public good supply is ∑ Bi′ (q*) = c′(q*). Thus the median voter’s preferred supply is efficient only if BM ′ (q) = ∑ Bi′ (q)/n ie the median voter’s marginal benefit equals the mean marginal benefit. If tastes ( Bi′) are symmetrically distributed then q* = qM. 2. (a) Suppose we ignore the preferences of bureaucrats and define an efficient allocation as one which maximizes the benefit to consumers less expenditure: B(q) − C(q) − w. Then the efficient allocation has B′(q*) = C′(q*) and w = 0. 2. (b) The bureau wishes to maximize its total allocation which is equal to its actual expenditure A = E(q) = C(q) + w. Politicians know q and B(q) but cannot tell how much of actual expenditure is wasted. They are willing to allocate up to the value of the total benefits: A = kB(q), k ∈ [0, 1]. The bureaucrats will always set k = 1 for given q ie they will extract the maximum amount that politicians are willing to pay for q. Thus the bureaucrats’ problem is to choose q and w to maximize C(q) + w subject to C(q) + w = B(q). Depending on the benefit and cost functions there are two types of solution, illustrated in Fig. 14D.1. (i) If C = C1(q), the bureau will maximize A at q1, where C1(q1) = B(q1). There is no waste since w = 0. Note that the efficient output is q* < q1. (ii) If C = C2(q) the bureau will set q = q2 where B′(q2) = 0 since any larger q reduces B and therefore A. Since B(q2) > C2(q2) and the bureaucrats wish to maximize total expenditure they set w = B(q2) − C2(q2), again giving a total expenditure equal to the benefit. 3. (a) The welfare function is W= ∞ ∫ D( 6)d 6 + pD(p) − C(D(p)) p which is maximized when dW/dp = −D(p) + D(p) + [p − C(p)]D′(p) = 0 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 176 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn so that the optimal price is marginal cost. In what follows it is easier to have output x rather than price as the choice variable. Invert the demand function to get p = p(x) which is the height of the demand curve or consumers’ marginal willingness to pay for the good. We can write the welfare function equivalently as the difference between consumers’ total willingness to pay for the good less cost of production: W= ∫ p( 8 )d 8 − C(x) x 0 which is maximized when dW/dx = p(x*) − C′(x*) = 0 3. (b) Assume that the mark up pricing constraint is binding in that at the unregulated profit maximizing output level x0 we have p(x0) > (1 + k)C(x0)/x0. Since the firm is on its demand curve and faces a binding markup constraint its output is determined by p(x)x − (1 + k)[C(x) + w] = R(x) − (1 + k)[C(x) + w] = 0 (14.3) Thus its only degree of freedom is the amount of waste w and (14.3) implicitly defines output as a function of waste: x = x(w). By increasing w the firm increases its recorded average cost [C(x) + w]/x and so can move up its demand curve, increasing its price and reducing its output. From (14.3) dx 1+k = <0 dw R ′( x) − (1 + k)C ′( x) (remember R′ < C′ since the pricing constraint forces the firm to increase output beyond the profit maximizing level where R(x0) = C′(x0)). The regulated firm’s profit function is Π(w) = R(x(w)) − C(x(w)) − w and Π′(w) = (R′ − C′) dx kR ′ −1= dw R ′ − (1 + k)C ′ (14.4) There are two types of profit maximizing solution. (i) If Π′(0) > 0 the firm sets w > 0. Since the numerator in (14.4) is negative, Π′(0) > 0 requires R′(x(0)) < 0. In this case the price constraint increases the firm’s output beyond the point at which marginal revenue is zero. The firm will therefore choose to produce wastefully in order to increase recorded average cost to push up price and reduce output until revenue is maximized: R′(x(w)) = 0. (ii) If Π′(0) ≤ 0 the firm sets w = 0 and output and price are x(0) and p(x(0)). The price constraint means that profit is proportional to revenue: Π=R−c−w=R− px k = R( x( w)) 1+k 1+k © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 177 Thus it will choose w (and hence x) to maximize revenue. Since x′(w) < 0 it sets w = 0 if R′(x(0)) > 0. 3. (c) Yes. If the firm has increasing average cost the output at which average cost equals price could be worse than the output determined by marginal revenue equals marginal cost. This is true whether waste is positive or zero. (Draw a diagram.) Supplementary questions (i) Draw diagrams to illustrate these two solution types. (ii) Can markup regulation reduce welfare if the firm has decreasing average cost? © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 178 Chapter 15 Game Theory Exercise 15B 1. The payoff matrix for this game is C NC C 2, 2 5, 0 NC 0, 5 1, 1 where C denotes confess and NC not confess. Since the numbers in the table represent prison sentences, the smaller the number the better. Thus regardless of what the other does, it is a dominant strategy to confess, but then each receives a longer sentence than if both did not confess. The idea that the logical pursuit of self interest can make everyone worse off than if they did not behave in this way, contrary to the results of neoclassical welfare economics, in which self seeking behaviour leads to a Pareto efficient outcome (see Chapter 13), is considered to be a very important lesson of this game. It suggests the need for rules, norms or social conditioning which could lead people to choose the socially preferable outcome rather than the individually rational one. Note of course that “society” in this case means the players of the game. 2. Firm B’s profit function is vB = 40qB − qAqB − qB2 and so maximising gives qB = 40 − q A 2 which is B’s reaction function. Firm A’s problem is then max v A = 40q A − q AqB − q 2A qA s. t. qB = 40 − q A 2 The simplest way to solve is just to substitute for qB in A’s profit function, to give 1 max v A = 20q A − q 2A q 2 A yielding qA = 20. This yields a Nash equilibrium because A is maximising its profit given B’s optimal choice, and B is doing the same thing. The outputs (20, 10) are mutually best replies. 178 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 179 3. Here we have to find the Cournot or Cournot-Nash equilibrium. We just saw that B’s reaction function is qB = 40 − qA 2 Proceeding in exactly the same way with A we find that its reaction function is qA = 40 − qB 2 A Nash equilibrium is a point ( q AN , qBN ) which satisfies both reaction functions, since then these outputs are mutually best responses. This gives the pair of linear equations 1 q AN + qBN = 20 2 1 N 1 N q A + qB = 20 2 2 Solving these then gives q AN = qBN = 13 13 . 4. In a game with no proper subgames, the only subgame is the entire game itself. Thus a Nash equilibrium of the entire game is subgame perfect. 5. (Outline) The game tree begins with a node at which B can choose either to enter or not. If not, the payoffs are zero for B and the monopoly profit for A. If it moves along the branch corresponding to entry, we then have a subgame corresponding to the Cournot game analysed in question 3. A, let us say, has the choice of any output level. All these therefore lie in B’s information set. Corresponding to each possible output of A, B can choose any possible output level. We have just seen that the Nash equilibrium of this subgame is (13 13 , 13 13 ). Replacing this subgame by its payoffs (177, 177), clearly A will prefer to enter than not enter. Thus we have the same solution as before. 6. Consider the fifth city. Since there are no cities left in which to deter entry, the incumbent will certainly accept entry rather than incur a loss to deter it. But then in the fourth city, the entrant knows that entry is going to take place in the fifth city, and so there is no gain to the incumbent in fighting to deter entry in city four, and so entry will take place and the incumbent will not fight it. But then the same is true in the third, second and finally the first city. Thus it never pays to fight entry. The only subgame perfect strategy is to accept entry in each city. This is thought of as a paradox, because one might have thought that for a cost of only −1 in the first city, the incumbent could fight entry, thus deterring entry in all remaining cities and preserving its monopoly profit. The backward induction argument shows that this cannot be an equilibrium. 7. Recall that each player at the beginning of the second period is assumed to know what action the other chose in the first period. It follows that a strategy in the repeated game must specifiy an action for the first period, and an action for the second period © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 180 contingent on what the other player chose in the first. The game is symmetrical, and we can list player i = A, B’s strategies as follows: s1i = (10, 10, 10) s2i = (10, 10, 12) s3i = (10, 12, 10) s4i = (10, 12, 12) s5i = (12, 10, 10) s6i = (12, 10, 12) s7i = (12, 12, 10) s8i = (12, 12, 12) where the first number is the output chosen in the first period, the second is output in the second period if the other player chose 10 in the first period, and the third is output in the second period if the other chose 12 in the first period. Using Fig. 15.9 in the text (and rounding where necessary) we have the payoff matrix s1A s2A s3A s4A s5A s6A s7A s8A s1B s2B s3B s4B s5B s6B s7B s8B 380, 380 380, 380 394, 362 394, 362 396, 360 396, 360 410, 342 410, 342 380, 380 380, 380 394, 362 394, 362 378, 374 378, 374 389, 353 389, 353 362, 394 362, 394 373, 373 373, 373 396, 360 396, 360 410, 342 410, 342 362, 394 362, 394 373, 373 373, 373 378, 374 378, 374 389, 353 389, 353 360, 396 374, 378 360, 396 374, 378 372, 372 386, 354 372, 372 386, 354 360, 396 374, 378 360, 396 374, 378 354, 386 365, 365 354, 386 365, 365 342, 410 353, 389 342, 410 353, 389 372, 372 386, 354 372, 372 386, 354 342, 410 353, 389 342, 410 353, 389 354, 386 365, 365 354, 386 365, 365 For example consider the strategy pair s3A = (10, 12, 10) and s7B = (12, 12, 10). A chooses 10 in the first period and B chooses 12. A responds in the second period by choosing 10 and B responds to A’s choice of 10 in the first period by choosing 12. From Fig. 15.9, this leads to the payoffs (342, 410). The payoffs for A that are highest in their columns, and the payoffs for B that are highest in their rows, are shown in bold. We see that there is a unique Nash equilibrium at the strategy pair ( s8A , s8B ), and this is again worse for both players than the cooperative strategies such as ( s1A , s1B ). In this game however there are no strictly dominant strategies. 8. We take the Stackelberg game shown in Fig. 15.3 and suppose it is now infinitely repeated. The choice of 13 13 by A and 10 by B gives payoffs of 222 for A and 167 for B, which are therefore better than the one-period Nash equilibrium payoffs for both firms. Consider the following trigger strategies: © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 181 A will produce 13 13 in periods t, t + 2, t + 4, . . . . as long as B produces 10 in periods t + 1, t + 3, . . . . If however B deviates in any period t + j by producing 13 13 , A will produce 20 in every period t + j + 1, t + j + 3, . . . thereafter. Consider now the payoff to B from deviating. He makes an immediate profit gain of 10, but then loses 67 in every period thereafter. Thus it does not pay to deviate if 10 ≤ 67/r or r ≤ 6.7 where r is the one period interest rate. If this condition is satisfied he will never deviate. Obviously also it never pays A to deviate, given that B will not deviate. Thus the cooperative solution can be supported by the trigger strategy as long as the interest rate is less than 670%. Exercise 15C 1. Since B knows its own type, it could use the information in Fig. 15.11 to calculate the probabilities of A being of each type. However, it does not need to do this since it can observe A’s output decision before it has to choose its own output. It knows that if A is type A1, it will optimally produce 20.4, knowing that B2’s reaction function then leads it to produce 9.3, and B0’s reaction function will lead it to produce 10.3. It will in that case set the probability that A is of type A1 to 1. Likewise, if A produces 20.9, B knows that A is type A0 and sets the probability of this to 1. It then makes the optimal response, given its own type, as correctly predicted by A. 2. If the incumbent is uncertain about the entrant’s costs, we have a Bayesian game. For concreteness, suppose that B’s costs are £1 per unit with probability π and £2 per unit with probability 1 − π. In the post-entry duopoly game, the incumbent will have a reaction function derived from maximising its expected profit (recall its cost per unit is £1 with certainty) HA = (41 − qA − π qB1 − (1 − π)qB2)qA − qA yielding the reaction function qA = 40 − π qB 1 − (1 − π )qB 2 2 The type B1 entrant will maximise HB1 = (41 − qA − qB1)qB1 − qB1 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 182 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn giving the reaction function qB 1 = 40 − qA 2 while type B2 maximises HB2 = (41 − qA − qB2)qB2 − 2qB2 to give the reaction function qB 2 = 39 − q A 2 Substituting for qB1 and qB2 in A’s reaction function and solving for qA gives q ABN = 4 (10.25 − 0.25π) 3 Thus for example if we assume π = 0.5, the PBE of the post entry duopoly game is q ABN = 13.5 q BBN1 = 13.25 q BBN2 = 12.75 At this post entry equilibrium each type of firm B finds it profitable to enter and will do so. We could, as in the text, suppose that the incumbent could make the threat of producing an output of 27 32 which, if believed, would deter entry by each type of firm B, but this cannot be a PBE because it is not optimal for A in the continuation game beginning at the node following B’s entry, given its probability beliefs about B’s type. 3. (a) This really just repeats the discussion of the Finitely Repeated Prisoner’s Dilemma in the text, with a different payoff matrix. Thus the PBE paths are A BR BN t=1 C C C t=2 C C C t=3 C R C t=4 R R C and we have to find the critical value of π at which, for the payoffs in the question, A would not wish to deviate from this equilibrium. Using the notation in the text, the value to A of the equilibrium path is 7 VA1 ( C , C , C , R ) = 1 + π 2 found by assuming that both types of B play these equilibrium strategies. The possible deviating paths for A, and their associated payoffs, found just as shown in the text, are as follows © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 183 3 VA1 ( C , C , R, R ) = 2 + π 2 VA1 ( R, C , R, R ) = 1 3 + π 2 2 VA1 ( R, R, R, R ) = 3 2 VA1 ( C , R, R, R ) = 5 2 VA1 ( C , R, C , R ) = 3 3 + π 2 2 VA1 ( R, R, C , R ) = 1 3 + π 2 2 VA1 ( R, C , C , R ) = 3 3 + π 2 2 There are 23 = 8 possible paths because all candidate paths must end in R. The condition under which the first deviation is not preferable to the equilibrium is 7 3 1 1+ π ≥ 2+ π ⇔π ≥ 2 2 2 It is easy to see that if this is satisfied so will be all the other non-deviation conditions, and so π = 12 is the critical probability. 3. (b) There is a typo in the text. The question should read: “Let the number of repetitions be n > k, and show that, as n increases, the minimum value of π such that the rational B will play tit-for-tat for the first n − k periods, with k depending on π but not on n, will decrease.” The answer is drawn from the paper by Kreps et al (1982). There they show that in a game with n periods, in any Pareto-undominated PBE (they use the sequential equilibrium concept, which is equivalent in this context) both players choose C in each period for sure as long as there are at least k periods left in the game, where, in our example, k = 2+ 8 π This does not rule out that both will both play C later than this, but the complexity of the analysis is such that only this rather loose upper bound on the number of periods at the end of the game in which R will be played can be placed. Thus for example we just saw that for π ≥ 0.5 in our four period game R would be played by some player only in the last two stages, while for π = 0.5 we have k = 18, which is greater than the number of stages in that example. Bearing this in mind, it is still true that, since k varies inversely © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 184 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn with π, the larger is n, the smaller is the minimum value of π consistent with n − k > 0. Exercise 15D 1. The strategic form game matrix is Player A H T Player B H T 2,0 0,2 0,2 2,0 There is no Nash Equilibrium in pure strategies: for each cell (pure strategy combination) one of the players can do better by changing their strategy. Since each player only has two pure strategies their mixed strategy is uniquely defined by the probability that they play a particular strategy. Denote player A’s mixed strategy as the probability pA that she plays H and B’s mixed strategy by the probability pB that he plays H. The expected payoffs are VA(pA) = 2pApB + 2(1 − pA)(1 − pB) VB(pB) = 2pA(1 − pB) + 2(1 − pA)pB The marginal payoffs are VA′ (pA) = 4pB − 2 VB′ (pB) = 2 − 4pA We know there is no pure strategy Nash equilibrium so that these marginal payoffs must be zero and the mixed strategy equilibrium is pA = 1/2, pB = 1/2. A is willing to randomise (choose a probability of H which is strictly greater than zero and less than 1) if pB = 1/2 and similarly B is willing to randomise if pA = 1/2. Thus pA = 1/2, pB = 1/2 are a Nash Equilibrium in mixed strategies in that neither can do better by deviating if other does not. If we now change the game so that A gets £3 when the coins match (draw the strategic form matrix of payoffs) her expected payoff changes to VA(pA) = 3pApB + 3(1 − pB)(1 − pB) and her marginal payoff to VA′ (pA) = 6pB − 3 Hence if pB = 1/2 then pA = 1/2 is still a best reply by A and the unique Nash equilibrium in mixed strategies is the same as before. The change in payoffs does not alter relative to the payoffs from the pure strategy combinations and so she has no incentive to alter her mixed strategy. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 185 2. The payoff matrix for scissors, paper, stone is Player A Scissors Paper Stone Scissors 0,0 0,1 1,0 Player B Paper 1,0 0,0 0,1 Stone 0,1 1,0 0,0 There are no pure strategy Nash equilibria: whatever the pair of strategies (cells) at least of the players does better by deviating to another strategy given the strategy of the other player. Denote the probabilities that player A chooses scissors by pA1 and the probability that he chooses paper by pA2 and analogously for player B. The expected payoffs (since the probability of A choosing stone is 1 − pA1 − pA2) are VA = pA1pB2 + pA2(1 − pB1 − pB2) + (1 − pA1 − pA2)pB1 VB = pB1pA2 + pB2(1 − pA1 − pA2) + (1 − pB1 − pB2)pA1 The marginal payoffs for A are ∂VA/∂pA1 = pB2 − pB1 ∂VA/∂pA2 = (1 − pB2 − pB1) − pB1 and analogously for player B. We know that there is no pure strategy Nash equilibrium so that 0 < pik < 1 for all strategies k = 1, 2, 3 for both players i = A, B. Hence the marginal payoffs from pA1 and pA2 (and the analogous payoffs for player B) must be zero. Thus pB1 = pB2 and pB2 − 2pB1 = 1 implying pB1 = pB2 = pB3 = 31 Similarly for player A’s probabilities. Thus the unique mixed strategy has both players choosing scissors, paper, and stone with equal probabilities and getting expected payoffs of zero. 3. The payoff matrix is Firm A 1 2 Firm B 1 2 10,5 0,0 0,0 5,10 There are two pure strategy Nash equilibria in which the firms choose the same location. There is also a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium. Letting pA, pB be the probabilities that players A,B choose location 1, the expected payoffs are VA(pA) = 10pApB + 5(1 − pA)(1 − pB) VB(pB) = 5pApB + 10(1 − pA)(1 − pB) and the marginal payoffs are VA′ (pA) = 10pB − 5(1 − pB) = 15pB − 5 VB′ (pB) = 5pA − 10(1 − pA) = 15pA − 10 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 186 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Hence the mixed strategies pA = 2/3, pB = 1/3 constitute a Nash equilibrium in that neither player would gain by deviating if the other did not. Notice that at the pure strategy equilibrium where both choose location 1 which can be characterised as pA = 1, pB = 1, the constant marginal payoffs are both positive (VA′ (pH) = 10, VB′ (pH) = 5) so that neither player wishes to randomise (reduce their probability of choosing location 1). Similarly at the pure strategy equilibrium where both choose location 2 the marginal payoffs are negative (VA′ (pH) = −5, VB′ (pH) = −10), so neither player wishes to increase their probability of choosing location 1 from zero. The expected payoffs for the players at the three equilbria are VA 10 5 3 13 (pA = 1, pB = 1) pA = 0, pB = 0) pA = 2/3, pB = 1/3 VB 5 10 3 13 VA + VB 15 15 6 32 The mixed strategy equilibrium leads to a smaller total payoff because the probability of the firms choosing the same location and getting the total payoff of 15 is pApB + (1 − pA)(1 − pB) = 4/9, so that the expected total payoff from the mixed strategy equilibrium is 15 × ( 49 ) = 6 32 . The mixed strategy equilibrium is also Pareto inefficient in terms of expected payoffs: both players would be better off moving to either of the pure strategy equilibria. But since this is a non-cooperative game they have no means of doing so. Supplementary question (i) If the game is cooperative so that binding agreements are possible what bargain would the two firms make if no side payments are possible and the game is played once only? Exercise 15E 1. Consider any two agreements a′ and a″ in P. If the parties agree to use a randomizing device which selects a′ with probability t and a″ with probability (1 − t), individual i will get expected utility of tui(a′) + (1 − t)ui(a″). Thus even if there is no agreement â in P such that u(â) = tui(a′) + (1 − t)ui(a″), i = 1, 2 they can always choose a randomizing device which is equivalent in expected utility terms to this agreement. Hence the set of feasible utility combinations is convex whatever the characteristics of the set A of physical agreements. In Fig. 15E.1 the set of physical agreements without any randomization maps into the set U′. Randomization over the set of physical agreements convexifies the set of utility outcomes. For example, an agreement to choose a′ and a″ each with probability 12 , enables the parties to achieve the point û, even though the physical agreement â which would yield this outcome is not feasible. Thus all outcomes in the area R are © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 187 u2 â u′ R u u″ a″ U′ a′ P u1 Fig. 15E.1 Fig. 15E.2 achievable by a suitable randomization and the utility payoff set U is the union of U′ and R. (U is the convex hull of U′.) 2. (a) In part (a) of Fig. 15E.2 the individuals have initial wealth yi. An agreement gives xi − yi to i. The set P of feasible agreements is the triangle satisfying ∑xi − ∑yi ≤ 1, xi − yi ≥ 0. In part (b) U is the set of utility outcomes derived from the agreements in P. Along the upper boundary of U the agreements satisfy ∑xi − ∑yi = 1. This boundary is strictly convex: changing the agreement to give more to individual 1 increases her utility but reduces the utility of individual 2. Since marginal utility declines with wealth ( ui′′ = −1/xi < 0) the rate of increase of individual 1’s utility declines and the rate of decrease of individual 2’s increases as the agreement shifts them down ab from left to right. The set U′ is also derived from P but with u1 = (1/2)logx1 − logy2, u2 = 2logx2. 2. (b) Let s = x1 − y1 be the amount of the $1 given to individual 1. Since both individuals have positive marginal utility from wealth and the Nash solution satisfies E the agreement generated by the Nash solution must have ∑xi − ∑yi = 1 so that x2 − y2 = 1 − s. Hence the Nash product to be maximized by s is © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 188 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn N(s; y1, y2) = [u1(y1 + s) − u1(y1)][u2(y2 + 1 − s) − u2(y2)] Now Ns = u1′ ( y1 + s)[u2(y2 + 1 − s) − u2(y2)] − u2′ ( y2 + 1 − s)[u1(y1 + s) − u1(y1)] so that Ns(0, y1, y2) = u1′ ( y1 )[u2 ( y2 + 1) − u2(y2)] > 0 Ns(1, y1, y2) = − u2′ ( y2 )[u1 ( y1 + 1) − u1(y1)] < 0 Hence the Nash bargain must have s ∈ (0, 1) and both parties share in the gain from the agreement. With the particular preferences assumed the Nash product is maximized when N s ( s, y1 , y2 ) = y + 1 − s y + s 1 1 log 2 log 1 − =0 y1 + s y2 y2 + 1 − s y1 2. (c) Consider the sign of N s (1/2, y1 , y2 ) = y + s y + s 1 1 log 2 log 1 − y1 + s y2 y2 + s y1 (15.1) If the sign depends only whether y1 is larger or smaller than y2 then, since Ns is decreasing in s, we can make a definite conclusion about whether the richer or poorer individual gets a larger or smaller share. Multiplying (15.1) by (y1 + s)(y2 + s) we see that the sign of (15.1) is the sign of y + s y + s ( y2 + s)log 2 − ( y1 + s)log 1 y2 y1 (15.2) Obviously at y1 = y2 this expression is zero and the Nash bargain has s = 1/2. Now consider the derivative y + s y + s d y+s + log ( y + s)log =1− y y dy y (15.3) Readers should sketch the graphs of the terms in (15.3) to convince themselves that the derivative is negative for all finite positive y. Thus if y1 > y2 the second term in (15.2) is smaller than the first term and so (15.2) is positive, which implies that (15.1) is also positive. Hence we have established that a larger share is given to the richer of the two individuals. The result does not hold for all utility functions. It is apparent from the first order condition for maximizing the Nash product that the solution depends on the ratios ui′ /[( ui ( xi ) − ui(yi)]. When the utility function is concave an increase in endowed income yi will reduce marginal utility but is will also reduce the denominator since ui′( xi ) − ui′( yi ) < 0. Thus the effect of a change in endowed income depends on the magnitude of the first and second derivatives of the utility function. You may like to think about this again after reading the discussion of risk aversion in section 17E. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 189 Supplementary question (i) Compare two “divide a dollar” bargaining problems which are identical except that in one of them individual 1 has utility u1(x1) and in the other she has preferences represented by g(x1) = G(u1(x1)), G′(u1) > 0, G″(u1) < 0, G(u1(y1)) = 0 Thus in the second problem her utility function is a concave transformation of her utility function in the first problem. (She is more risk averse in the second problem – see section 17E.) Show that individual 1 will get a smaller share at the Nash solution in the second problem compared with the first. 3. If there is no agreement no union members are employed by the firm. When there is no employment the union and the firm are unaffected by w, so that we can, with no loss in generality, assume that the disagreement wage is U. The disagreement event in (z, w) space is (0, U) and yields utilities π(0, U) = 0, U(0, U) = Uz0. In Fig. 10.7 the set of agreements P is the triangle bounded by the pAP and UU curves and the vertical axis. Since P is closed and bounded and contains the disagreement event, and the utility functions are continuous, the set of utility payoffs U is closed, bounded and contains π(0, U), U(0, U). It is not necessary to assume that randomization is possible to show that U is convex. Remember that efficient bargains have z = z* (where pAP(z*) = U), so that movements along the upper right boundary of U can occur only through changes in w. Hence the slope of the upper boundary of U in (π, U) space is dπ/dU = πw/Uw = −1. Since all points along pAP give π = 0 and all points along UU give U = Uz0, the set U in (π, U) space is the triangle with vertices (0, Uz0), (0, (pAP − U)z* + Uz0), ((pAP − U)z*, Uz0). The Nash product is N = [R(f(z)) − wz][(w − U)z] which is maximized when Nz = (R′f′ − w)(w − U)z + (w − U)(R − wz) = 0 (15.4) Nw = −z(w − U)z + (R − wz)z = 0 (15.5) Using (15.5) to substitute for R − wz in (15.4) gives 0 = (R′f′ − w)z + (w − U)z = (R′f′ − U)z implying (R′f′ = U, which is the text equation [10D.6]. Employment is z* which maximizes the total surplus R − Uz. The wage w* determines how this maximized total surplus is shared. From (15.5) we get w*z* = [R(f(z*)) − Uz*]/2, so that the wage w* = (pAP − U) is halfway along the contract curve CC in Fig. 10.7. The reader should subsitute this wage into the firm and union utility functions and note that π(z*, w*) − π(0, U) = (R − Uz*)/2 U(z*, w*) − U(0, U) = (R − Uz*)/2 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 190 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn so that the Nash solution splits the gain from trade equally between the firm and the union. 4. The first order conditions for maximization of the asymmetric Nash product N = π α[(w − U)z]1−α are Nz = α (R′f ′ − w)π α−1[(w − U)z]1−α + (1 − α)π α[(w − U)z]−α(w − U) = 0 (15.6) Nw = −α zπ α−1[(w − U)z]1−α + (1 − α)π α[(w − U)z]−αz = 0 (15.7) Rearranging (15.7) to get π α[(w − U)z]−α = α 1−α π α−1[(w − U)z]1−α (15.8) substituting in (15.6) and cancelling terms gives R′f ′ − w + (w − U) = R′f ′ − U = 0 and so the level of employment is not affected by the degree of asymmetry in the bargaining solution. The agreement will maximize the total surplus. We can manipulate (15.8) to get ( w* − U) z* 1 − α = π ( z*, w*) α The greater is α the smaller is the right hand side of this equation and so the left hand side must be reduced by reducing w* which reduces the numerator and increases the denominator. Thus the greater is the weight on the firm’s utility in the Nash product the greater its share of the gain from trade. Exercise 15F 1. The dates at which offers can be made are 0, 1, 2, . . . , T − 1, T. Suppose that the number of dates (T + 1) is odd, so that player A makes the last offer at date T. The subgame beginning at that date consists of her making an offer and player B deciding to reject or accept it. The Nash equilibrium is an offer xT = 1 by A which is accepted by B: rTb = 0. At date T – 1 player B makes an offer. Since A will get 1 (her payoff from the period T game) if there is no agreement at T − 1, she will reject all period T − 1 offers which give her less than the discounted value of her period T payoff: δaxT = δa. Given his rational anticipation of what will happen in the period T game, B’s optimal period T − 1 offer is yT−1 = 1 − δa. At period T − 2 A knows that B will get a payoff of 1 − δa if there is no agreement in period T − 2 and so her optimal offer is xT−2 = 1 − δbyT−1 = 1 − δb(1 − δa) = 1 − δb + δaδb which B would accept since he is indifferent between δbyT−1 at date T − 2 and yT−1 at date T − 1. At date T − 3 B’s optimal offer is yT−3 = 1 − δaxT−2. Similarly at date T − 4 A will make the just acceptable offer © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 191 xT−4 = 1 − δbyT−3 = 1 − δb + δaδb − δbδaδb + (δaδb)2 Repeated application of the same arguments shows that at date 0 her offer (and payoff) is T /2 x0 = (1 − δb) ∑ (δ δ ) + (δ δ ) i a b (T/2)+1 a b i= 0 Taking the limit as T → ∞ player A gets the payoff from the game of x0 = 1−δb 1 − δ aδ b which is identical to her payoff from the infinite horizon game of the text. Now consider a version of the finite horizon game in which the number of periods is even, so that player B makes the last offer, although player A makes the first offer. The optimal offers are now yT = 1, xT−1 = 1 − δb, yT−2 = 1 − δa(1 − δb) and so on. The reader should be able to show that T /2 x0 = (1 − δb) ∑ (δ δ ) + (δ δ ) i a b a b i= 0 (T/2)+1 xT−1 which as T → ∞ has the same limit as in the game in which A has the last move, since the differences in the last terms in the relevant equations for x0 vanish as T → ∞. Thus in the limit of the finite horizon game what matters is which player makes the first offer, not who makes the last offer. 2. (a) and (b) A’s strategy in the T + 1 period game is a sequence of offers (x0, . . . , xT) and B’s is a sequence of rejection rules (r0, . . . , rT). Let βt be the minimum payoff that B can get from the SPE of the game starting at date t. Then at date t − 1 A’s optimal offer, which is accepted by B, is δbβt. Hence B’s minimum payoff from the SPE of the game starting at period t − 1 is βt−1 = δβt. Thus the date 0 optimal offer by A is δ TβT . But at date T B will accept any non-negative offer, since he gets 0 if there is no agreement. Hence A’s optimal offer at date T is xT = 1 and βT = 0. Thus the SPE strategies are xt = 1, rt = 0, t = 0, . . . , T. 2. (c) B’s rejection rules are credible only if rt ≤ rt+1, which implies that rt+k ≥ rtδ b− k , k > 1 (15.9) But, since the equilibrium rejection rules must also satisfy rt ≤ 1 and δb ∈ (0, 1), (15.9) can be satisfied for large k only if rt = 0, t = 0, 1, . . . . Hence A’s SPE strategy is xt = 0, t = 1, . . . . Supplementary question (i) Suppose there is only one period and A and B make simultaneous offers x ≥ 0, y ≥ 0, which they get only if x + y ≤ 1. What are the Nash equilibria? © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 192 3. A’s SPE offer and payoff when the day is split into n periods is x*( n ) = 1 − δ bn 1 − δ 1b/n = 1 − δ anδ bn 1 − (δ a δ b )1/n Now lim n →∞ δ 1i / n = δ 0i = 1, so we must use L’Hôpital’s rule to evaluate the limit of the above ratio: d(1 − δ 1b/n )/dn n →∞ d (1 − (δ δ )1/ n )/dn a b lim x*( n ) = lim n →∞ Now dδ 1i/n δ 1/n log δ =− i 2 i dn n and so δ b n −2 log δ b log δ b = / − 1 2 n n→∞ (δ δ ) n log δ aδ b log(δ aδ b ) a b lim x*( n ) = lim n→∞ Differentiation of this expression for x* shows that A’s payoff is increasing in δa and decreasing in δb. (Remember logδi < 0). Exercise 15G 1. Let F(b) be the distribution function for b. B will buy if b ≥ p so that the probability of a sale is 1 − F(p). S gets zero benefit from the asset if it is not sold and will therefore set the price p to maximize her expected revenue R(p) = [1 − F(p)]p. As we can see from Table 15G.1 it is never optimal to have p < ᐉ or p ≥ h. Since marginal revenue is discontinuous at ᐉ there are two types of solution. (i) If h < 2ᐉ marginal revenue is negative for p > ᐉ and positive for p < ᐉ, hence p* = ᐉ. (ii) When h > 2ᐉ marginal revenue is positive at ᐉ and so p* = h/2. In case (i) the expected gain from trade is Eb = (h + ᐉ)/2. Since p* = ᐉ trade is certain to take place. Thus the seller’s monopoly power creates no inefficiency. In case (ii) the expected gain from trade is h 1 3h 2 bdb = < Eb 4( h − l) h−l p ∫ Some potential gains from trade are lost because with probability F(h/2) > 0 the realised benefit is less than the price and B does not buy. p ∈ (0, ᐉ) p=ᐉ p ∈ (ᐉ, h) p=h p>h F(p) R(p) 1 p 1 p (h − p)/(h − ᐉ) p(h − p)/(h − ᐉ) 0 0 0 0 Table 15G.1 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 R′(p) 1 (h − 2p)/(h − ᐉ) 0 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 193 Supplementary questions (i) Illustrate the two solution types in a diagram. Show that in case (ii) variations in ᐉ have no effect on the solution. (ii) How is the answer affected if S places the value c ∈ (ᐉ, h) on the asset or if she must incur c to produce the asset after promising to sell it to B? 2. If q < G = h/ᐉ, S sets p = ᐉ. Trade takes place whatever B’s actual type and the expected gain from trade is maximized. The outcome is efficient. If q > G, S sets p = h. There is no trade with probability (1 − q). A fully informed regulator R could effect a Pareto improvement by ordering S to set p ∈ [0, ᐉ] if R observes b = ᐉ. This outcome is not feasible if b is not observed by R. Whether R can make a Pareto improvement then depends on whether R can intervene before or after B learns his type. (i) Suppose R can intervene before B observes b. R could order B to pay p0 to S before B learns b and p1 = ᐉ when the asset is exchanged. Since B would otherwise get an expected benefit of zero he is better off if q(h − p1) + (1 − q)(ᐉ − p1 − p0) = q(h − ᐉ) − p0 > 0 S would otherwise get q(h − ᐉ) and is better off if p0 + p1 = p0 + ᐉ > qh Both parties can be made better off if p0 ∈ (qh − ᐉ, q(h − ᐉ)). Note that if the parties can sign a binding contract fixing (p0, p1) before b is revealed the regulator is unnecessary. (ii) If R can intervene only after b is revealed to B no Pareto improvement is possible. In order to increase the total gains from trade the price p1 to a buyer with a value of ᐉ must be reduced to ᐉ. To make the seller no worse off she must be compensated with at least p0 = q(h − ᐉ) > 0. But then the type ᐉ buyer has an expected value of −p0 and is worse off. There is no set of feasible payments which will ensure that trade always takes place and that all individuals (the seller, the high value buyer and the low value buyer) are no worse off. In case (i) there are only two individuals: the seller and the buyer who does not yet know his type. In case (i) all individuals would be willing to accept the regulator’s intervention. In case (ii) at least one of the parties would always veto it. Supplementary question (i) Show that when p0 is chosen before b is revealed the suggested regulatory mechanism also works if b is distributed uniformly over (ᐉ, h). 3. We can show that if q < G there is no equilibrium with p0 ∈ (60, h). Such a p0 is rejected by type ᐉ. We know that a0(p0, h) = 1 for p0 ∈ (60, h] cannot be part of a PBE (see text pages 396–397). Nor is a strictly mixed strategy for type h part of a PBE since this would require a0 = A0 [G.11], which is impossible since q < G < 1. Thus only a0 = 0 can be part of a PBE for p0 ∈ (60, h]. But then, since both types reject such p0, q1(p0) = q and the optimal p1 = ᐉ. Since setting p0 ∈ (60, h) and p1 = ᐉ gives an expected payoff to S © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 194 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 15G.1 of δᐉ, she would be better off setting p0 = 60, p1 = ᐉ and getting an expected payoff of qh(1 − δ) + δᐉ. The two candidates for a PBE therefore have S playing p0 = 60, p1 = ᐉ or p0 = ᐉ, p1 = ᐉ. But since q < G, S gets a higher payoff from the low price strategy. 4. If the union knew the firm’s type i it would make the take or leave it offer (zi, wi) which maximizes U (z, w) subject to the firm breaking even: iR(d(zi)) − wizi ≥ 0. Since the pAP curve for a type h firm lies outside that for a type ᐉ firm it must be true that hR(f(zᐉ)) − wᐉzᐉ > 0. Thus the union will either set (zᐉ, wᐉ) and get U(zᐉ, wᐉ) for sure, or it will set (zh, wh) and get an expected payoff of qU(zh, wh). The critical value G = U(zᐉ, wᐉ)/U(zh, wh) determines the type of solution. 5. When S can commit herself to her offers we do not have to impose the requirement that whenever it is her turn to move her strategy should be optimal from that point on given the information she has acquired. This requirement need only be imposed at the start of the game when S commits herself to a strategy for the whole game. Her strategy is defined by (p0, λ). Fig. 15G.1 shows the possible strategies. We consider how the equilibrium is derived for the case of a strong seller: q > G = ᐉ/h. At p0 = 60(λ) = h(1 − δλ) + δλᐉ (15.10) the type h buyer is indifferent between accepting p0 and rejecting it and facing the probability λ of p1 = ᐉ next period. The line 60 in the figure plots (15.10). There are four types of strategies which the seller can adopt. (i) She can set p0 ∈ [0, ᐉ] which yields a certain payoff of p0 whatever the value of λ. Clearly the best such strategy is p0 = ᐉ which yields v1 = ᐉ. (ii) Strategies in the region ii with p0 ∈ (ᐉ, 60) result in the type h accepting the first period offer and the type ᐉ accepting the second period offer if it is ᐉ. These strategies yield qp0 + (1 − q)λδᐉ. This function is increasing in p0 and λ and, because q > ᐉ/h, its contours are flatter than the 60 line. The supremum of the payoff function in this region is v2 = qh which is the limit of qp0 + (1 − q)λδ ᐉ as p0 → h, λ → 0. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 195 (iii) The payoff along the curve 60 is q60 + (1 − q)λδᐉ = qh(1 − λδ) + λδᐉ and the optimal strategy in this region is λ = 0, 60(0) = h with payoff v3 = qh. (iv) The region iv has p0 ∈ (60, h]. Neither buyer type buys in the first period so the payoff is δ [λᐉ + (1 − λ)qh]. Since q > ᐉ/h the supremum of the payoff function is v4 = δ h which is achieved as p0 → h, λ → 0. Comparison of the payoffs from the different types of strategies shows that the optimum strategy when the seller is strong is to set p0 = h, λ = 0 which yields exactly the same payoff to the seller as in the single period model. You should now be able to use similar reasoning in the weak seller case to establish that the optimum strategy has p0 = ᐉ. 6. (a) Denote the offer in the second period by the type b buyer as pb1. At date 1 S’s optimal strategy is accept any offer pb1 ≥ 0 so that the optimal offer by the buyers at that date are ph1 = pᐉ1 = 0. At date 0 S realises that a type b buyer will refuse any offer p0 by her such that b − p0 < δ b since the buyer will get a discounted payoff of δ b by refusing p0 and making his optimal offer in period 1. Thus an offer p0 = (1 − δ )ᐉ is certain to be accepted and an offer p0 = (1 − δ )h will be accepted with probability q. Thus S will set p0 = (1 − δ )h if q > ᐉ/h and p0 = (1 − δ ) ᐉ if q < ᐉ/h. • 6. (b) At date 1 S has observed B’s offer p0 and has updated her belief from q to q1(p0). She will then choose λ by reference to [G.5]. Consider the case in which q < ᐉ/h. The equilibrium has both types of buyer making the same offer p0(ᐉ) = p0(h) = δ ᐉ and being willing to accept any period 1 offer from S which satisfies p1(p0) ≤ b. The seller will accept any p0 ≥ δ ᐉ and will set p1(p0) = ᐉ. This is an equilibrium because at date 1 S has received no information from the period 0 offer which is the same for both types of buyer. Since q < ᐉ/h her optimal period 1 offer is ᐉ, which would yield her ᐉ at date 1. Thus she would accept any offer p0 ≥ δ ᐉ from B at date 0 and reject all other offers. If a type b buyer makes the just acceptable offer at date 0 he gets b − δ ᐉ. The type b buyer will not set a lower price since this would not be accepted and the would face p1 = ᐉ next period. This would yield 0 < ᐉ(1 − δ ) to a type ᐉ and δ (h − ᐉ) < h − δ ᐉ to a type h. Note that the seller sets p1 = ᐉ even if she receives an out of equilibrium offer p0 ≠ δ ᐉ. We assume that such offers convey no information about the buyer’s type. The case where q > ᐉ/h is much more complicated and the reader should consult the discussion of a similar model in David Canning, “Bargaining theory”, in F. Hahn (ed.), The Economics of Missing Markets, Information and Games, Oxford University Press, 1990. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 196 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Chapter 16 Oligopoly Exercise 16B 1. Write the inverse demand functions in [B.2] of the text as the linear system: β1q1 + γ q2 = α1 − p1 γ q1 + β2q2 = α2 − p2 Then using Cramer’s Rule, we have, q1 = α 1 − p1 γ α 2 − p2 β 2 β1 γ γ β2 = β 2 (α 1 − p1 ) − γ (α 2 − p2 ) β 1β 2 − γ 2 = α 1 β 2 − α 2γ β 2 p1 γ p2 − + 2 2 β 1β 2 − γ β 1β 2 − γ β 1β 2 − γ 2 and the solution of q2 follows similarly. We require βjαi − γ αj > 0 because this is the value of qi when p1 = p2 = 0. For the above solution to be possible we require β1β2 ≠ γ 2, but for qi to vary negatively with pi we require the stronger condition that β1β2 > γ 2. 2. Inspection of the relevant rows of Table 16.1 shows that qiM = 1/2Zi. 3. The individual outputs qiM and Zi are indeterminate in the homogeneous goods case because the firms’ marginal costs are identical and constant, so that the firms’ outputs are perfect substitutes in supply. There is nothing in the models that allows us to solve for individual outputs. For example, the joint profit function in the monopoly case is Π(q1 + q2) = α (q1 + q2) − γ (q1 + q2)2 − c(q1 + q2). Maximizing this first with respect to q1 then q2 gives α −c = q1 + q2 2γ α −c = q1 + q2 2γ which, of course, are the same condition, and so we can only solve for total output. 196 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 197 4. In general terms the joint-profit-maximizing problem is max Π1(q1, q2) + Π2(q1, q2) yielding the first-order conditions Π ii ( q1M , q2M ) + Π ij ( q1M , q2M ) = 0 i, j = 1, 2, i ≠ j. Now if, as is the case in this model, Π ij ( q1M , q2M ) < 0, then Π ii ( q1M , q2M ) > 0, i.e. an increase in qi, with qj held fixed at q Mj , will increase profit. Since qiR maximizes Πi(qi, q Mj ), we must therefore have qiR > qiM as required (recall that Πi is strictly concave in qi). 5. We have that Âi ≡ (ai + bici)/2bi; Åi ≡ φ / 2bi. Then, simply using the definitions of ai, bi and φ from question 1 gives: Âi = ( β jα i − γα j ) + β j ci 2β j and this must be positive by virtue of the assumption that βjαi > γαj. We then have Åi Åj = φ2 4bi b j = γ2 4β i β j and since γ 2 < βi βj we certainly have 0 < 1 − Åi Åj < 1. It follows that the pair of simultaneous linear equations (derived from [B.24] of the text) p1 − Å1 p2 = Â1 −Å2 p1 + p2 = Â2 has a solution (since 1 − Å1Å2 ≠ 0) and that this solution, given in [B.25] of the text, implies positive prices. 6. It will simplify the algebra without losing real generality if we set ci = cj = 0 in the model. Then the Bertrand equilibrium prices can be written (using the definitions given in question 1): piB = 2β i ( β jα i − γα j ) + γ ( β iα j − γα i ) 4β i β j − γ 2 . If we can show that piB > 0 then the Bertrand equilibrium is profitable. The term 4βiβj − γ 2 > 0. We can re-write the numerator as αi(βiβj − γ 2) + βi(βjαi − γ αj) and each of these terms is positive given the assumptions explained in question 1. The Cournot-Nash equilibrium will be more profitable than the Bertrand if i’s price piC > piB , i = 1, 2. To obtain piC substitute the expressions for qiC , q Cj into i’s inverse demand function to obtain © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 198 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn α i ( 4 β 1 β 2 − γ 2 ) − β i ( 2β j α i − γα i ) − γ ( 2β iα j − γα i ) p = 4β 1 β 2 − γ 2 C i Then piC − piB = γ 2αi > 0 where the details of the algebra are left to the reader. 7. In the discussion of the Stackelberg model (see p. 407 of the text) we sketched the profit contours for firm 1 as strictly concave relative to the q1-axis and, since lower q2 implies higher profits for firm 1, this is equivalent to asserting that the firm’s profit function is strictly quasi-concave. To prove this, write, say firm 1’s profit contour as (α1 − c1 − γ q2)q1 − β 1 q12 = Π 10 where Π10 > 0 is some given (feasible) profit level. We can solve this explicitly for q2 as a function of q1: q2 = α 1 − c1 β 1 Π0 − q1 − 1 γ γ γ q1 Differentiating gives dq2 β Π0 = − 1 + 12 dq1 γ γ q1 Note that by setting this derivative to zero we obtain the value of q1 at which the contour is at its maximum, as Π0 q1 = 1 β1 1/ 2 implying that the higher is Π1, the larger is the output at the peak of the profit contour, as Fig. 16.2 of the text illustrates. To confirm the concavity of the contour, differentiate again to get d 2 q2 2Π 10 = − < 0. γ q13 dq12 8. In case (a) of the Edgeworth model, each firm’s capacity is at least sufficient to supply the entire market at a zero price, i.e. G ≥ α /γ. This means that if firm i sets pi > 0, firm j captures the entire market by setting pj = pi − ε, and it certainly has enough capacity to supply this. Then repeat the reasoning underlying the Bertrand result for the homogeneous output case to rationalize the Nash equilibrium at p1 = p2 = 0. Exercise 16C 1. The joint-profit maximum is found by solving max[100 − (q1 + q2)](q1 + q2) − q12 − 2q22 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 199 First-order conditions are 100 − 4q1 − 2q2 = 0 100 − 2q1 − 6q2 = 0 yielding outputs, prices and profits: q1M = 20; q2M = 10; pM = 70; Π1M = 1000; Π 2M = 5000. To derive the Cournot-Nash equilibrium we obtain the reaction functions by solving: max q1 (100 − (q1 + q2))q1 − q12 max q2 (100 − (q1 + q2))q2 − 2q22 giving q1C = 100 − q2 ; 4 q2C = 100 − q1 . 6 This results in the Cournot-Nash equilibrium q1C = 21.74; q2C = 13.04; pC = 65.22; Π 1C = 945.25; Π C2 = 510.39. Then we see that firm 2’s profit at the Cournot-Nash equilibrium, at 510.39, is higher than its profit at the joint-profit maximum, 500. One way of explaining this is to note that at the joint profit maximum the firms’ marginal costs must be equalized, while at the Cournot-Nash equilibrium there is nothing to bring about this result. It follows that the firm with the higher marginal cost function (here firm 2) may produce lower output at the joint-profit-maximizing position and, in the absence of side-payments, this gives it lower profit. 2. Though in principle the profit frontier is derived by solving max Πi (q1, q2) s.t. Πj (q1, q2) ≥ Π j , in practice it is easier to solve by introducing the parameter λ ∈ (0, 1) and formulating the problem as max λΠ1(q1, q2) + (1 − λ)Π2(q1, q2) the profit functions in this case being Π1 = 100q1 − (q1 + q2)q1 − q12 Π2 = 100q2 − (q1 + q2)q2 − 2q22 . From the first-order conditions we obtain 100λ − λ4q1 − q2 = 0 100(1 − λ) − q1 − (1 − λ)6q2 = 0. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 200 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Solving for q1 and q2 by Cramer’s Rule gives q1 = 600λ (1 − λ ) − 100(1 − λ ) 24λ (1 − λ ) − 1 q2 = 400λ (1 − λ ) − 100λ . 24λ (1 − λ ) − 1 Since we must have q1 ≥ 0, q2 ≥ 0, this implies λ ∈ [1/6, 3/4] (just set qi = 0 and solve for λ in each case). Then the following table gives the values for q1, q2, Π1, Π2 as λ varies over this interval. λ q1 0.167 0.300 0.400 0.500 0.600 0.700 0.75 0 13.86 17.65 20.00 21.85 23.76 25.00 q2 16.65 13.37 11.76 10.00 7.56 3.47 0 Π1 0 816.49 934.39 1000.00 1064.97 1164.48 1250.00 Π2 833.33 615.42 553.54 500.00 419.35 228.43 0 Note that joint profits are maximized at λ = 0.5. At the outputs q1 = 20, q2 = 10, the firms’ marginal costs are equalized, since, C1′ = 2q1 = 40 C 2′ = 4q2 = 40 As the firms move around the profit frontier, they redistribute profit by redistributing outputs, and this leads to a violation of the cost-minimization condition of equality of marginal costs. For example, at λ = 0.7 we have C1′ = 2q1 = 47.52; C 2′ = 4q2 = 13.88 and so overall profit could be increased by expanding q2 and contracting q1. Note that, because costs are increased, the sum of firms’ outputs falls as they move away from the joint-profit-maximizing position. If we replace the cost functions in the above model by C1 = q1, C2 = 2q2, the analysis becomes considerably simpler. Note that now firm 1’s marginal cost, 1, is always below that of firm 2, which is 2. So, joint-profit-maximization involves firm 1 producing the entire output, so we solve max 100q12 − q1 q1 giving the solution q1* = 49.5, Π1* = 2450.25. 3. We can treat this as a straightforward problem in comparative-statics. Given the problem in [C.6] of the text, we have the first-order conditions © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 201 Π21 + λΠ11 = 0 Π22 + λΠ12 = 0 Π1 − Π10 = 0 We are interested in the sign of ∂λ /∂Π10 , since (as in [C.9]) we have that ∂Π 2 /∂Π 10 = −λ. Differentiating the first-order conditions totally gives the system Π 211 + λΠ 111 Π + λΠ 121 221 Π 11 Π 212 + λΠ 112 Π 222 + λΠ 122 Π 12 Π 11 dq1 0 Π 12 dq2 = 0 0 dλ dΠ 10 Call the determinant of the 3 × 3 matrix D, and note that the second-order conditions imply D > 0 (see Appendix I, and note here we have a case where n = 2, m = 1). Then applying the standard comparative-statics procedure gives ∂λ = {(Π211 + λΠ111)(Π222 + λΠ122) − (Π221 + λΠ121)(Π212 + λΠ112)}/D ∂Π 10 and so it remains to evaluate the bracketed terms. Recall the profit functions Πi(q1, q2) = (αi − ci − γ qj)qi − β i qi2 i, j = 1, 2, i ≠ j It follows that we have Π211 = Π122 = 0 Π111 = −2β1; Π222 = −2β2 Π112 = Π121 = Π212 = Π221 = −γ We then have 4λβ 1 β 2 − (1 + λ ) 2 γ 2 ∂λ = D ∂Π 10 Note that at the joint-profit-maximizing point λ = 1, and so we have ∂λ 4 2 = (β1β2 − γ ) > 0 0 ∂Π1 D Since λ is the absolute value of the slope of the profit frontier, this tells us that the frontier is certainly strictly concave in a neighbourhood of that point. To construct the profit frontier for the homogeneous output example, note that in this example the firms have identical marginal costs. It follows that the profit frontier is a line with slope −1 through the joint-profit-maximizing point (recall the discussion surrounding [C.3] of the text). From Table 16.2 we have that maximum joint profit is 20.25, and so the equation for the profit frontier is Π 2M = 20.25 − Π1M Π1M , Π 2M ≥ 0. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 202 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn This is graphed in Fig. 16.11 of the text. Since it is linear, it is concave. 4. In the case of homogeneous products the (inverse) market demand function is p = 100 − (q1 + q2) and the firms have identical constant marginal costs of 1. It is immediate that firm j minimaximizes firm i by setting q jX to satisfy 100 − q jX = 1 since in that case market price equals marginal cost, and i cannot make a positive profit at any output: minimax profit is zero. 5. The reason a price-setting duopoly can sustain a wider set of collusive allocations than a quantity-setting duopoly is evident from Fig. 16.9. The one-shot Nash equilibrium involves a lower profit in the price-setting than in the quantity-setting case, and so larger punishments can be threatened in the former case. 6. The example used in the chapter has the demand function p = 10 − (q1 + q2) and the firms’ cost functions are Ci = qi, i = 1, 2. From question 3 we have that the profit frontier in this case is given by Π2 = 20.25 − Π1 (16.1) To find the set of weakly renegotiation-proof (WRP) profit pairs, we proceed by finding the equations of the curves defining the boundaries of the set (refer to Fig. 16.11 of the text). Suppose that the given profit pair is ( Π1* , Π *2 ), which is to be sustained by a pair of punishment outputs ( q1P , q2P ). If ( Π1* , Π *2 ) is WRP, there must exist a punishment output q2P (start by taking firm 1 as the cheat) that satisfies max{Π 1 ( q1 , q2P )} ≤ Π 1* . q1 (16.2) That is, q2P must be such as to make firm 1’s punishment profit no greater than the collusive profit, even if it makes its best response to 2’s punishment output (in general q1P will give firm 1 less profit than this). To translate (16.2) into a condition involving only q2P and Π1* , solve max Π1 ( q1 , q2P ) = max(10 − ( q1 + q2P ))q1 − q1 q1 q1 to obtain Z1 = (9 − q2P )/2 and then rewrite (16.1) as 1 Π1(Z1, q2P ) = ( 9 − q2P ) 2 ≤ Π 1* 4 (16.3) (we leave the substitution for Z1 and rearrangement of terms to the reader). Thus if q2P satisfies (16.3), firm 1 can never do better when it is punished than when it colludes. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 203 To induce firm 2 to carry out the punishment rather than renegotiate back to the original agreement, we require Π2 ( q1P , q2P ) = (10 − ( q1P + q2P ))q2P − q2P ≥ Π *2 . (16.4) Since we want to determine the upper boundary of the WRP set, we can choose q1P to be the most favourable to firm 2, which means setting q1P = 0. This gives us the condition Π2 (0, q2P ) = (9 − q2P )q2P ≥ Π *2 . (16.5) Thus (16.3) and (16.5) give a pair of conditions with which to solve for the upper boundary of the WRP set. We can derive an equation for this by first solving (16.3) as an equality to obtain q2P = 9 − 2 Π 1* and then substituting into (16.5) and rearranging to get 18 Π 1* − 4Π 1* ≥ Π *2 . (16.6) Taking the equality in (16.6) gives the function which is graphed as the upper boundary of the WRP set in Fig. 16.11 of the text. Given the symmetry of the model, it is easy to see that the lower boundary is obtained by exchanging subscripts in (16.6). We can locate the points at which the boundary curves meet the profit frontier by, of course, solving (16.1) and (16.5) simultaneously. We obtain from them the quadratic 3Π 1* − 18 Π 1* + 20.25 = 0 and so solving and discarding the infeasible root gives Π1* = 2.25. This then gives Π *2 = 18. Note that in all this nothing has been said about discount rates, we have simply found the set of profit pairs which can be sustained by punishments involving less profit for one firm and more for the other. Implicit in all this is the idea that if the firm being punished reneges in the punishment phase the punishment will be reimposed from the beginning (as with Abreu’s simple penal code). Fudenberg and Maskin (1986) showed that there always exists some range of discount rates for which cheating can be deterred, and so implicit in the above discussion is also the assumption that the discount rate falls in that range. Moving on to strong renegotiation proofness (SRP), this criterion restricts attention to WRP profit pairs that are Pareto-undominated, i.e. that lie along the profit frontier. This means that as well as having to satisfy conditions (16.3) and (16.4), the punishment outputs q1P and q2P must generate profit pairs along the profit frontier. We know that these profit pairs satisfy the condition q2P = 4.5 − q1P (refer to Table 16.2 of the text). Again, to define the boundary points of the SRP set take the worst possible punishment for, say, firm 1, as q1P = 0, which then gives q2P = 4.5. But clearly then, since the left hand side takes the value 20.25, this condition is satisfied for © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 204 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn any Π *2 on the profit frontier, and so places no constraint on the solution. The only constraints is (16.3). With q2P = 4.5, this becomes Π 1* ≥ 5.06. Thus the upper boundary point of the SRP set is (5.06, 15.19). By symmetry, the lower boundary point is (15.19, 5.06). It is easy to see why (5.06, 15.19) cannot be in the SRP set. If this were chosen as an allocation, there is no value of q1P (since it cannot be negative) that could be used to punish a deviation by firm 1 from the punishment pair (0, 4.5). On the other hand, for any point to the right of (5.06, 15.19) (and to the left of (15.19, 5.06)) on the profit frontier, it is always possible to find a point to its left which both is an effective punishment point for a deviation, and which is itself capable of being enforced by threat of a further move to the left. This is why the SRP set is an open set (a similar argument can be used to explain why the WRP set is also open). Exercise 16D 1. If there is a constant marginal cost of output in each firm, then all that happens is that in Fig. 16.14 of the text, the reaction functions shift leftward by amounts that depend on the value of the marginal cost, their slopes unchanged. This can be seen by introducing a term, say cx1, into the expression for firm 1’s profit in [D.3] of the text, where c is the constant marginal cost, and nothing that in [D.4] the constant term in the reaction function then becomes (35 − c/2). The same can be shown for [D.6]. Of course, we require c not to be “too large”, otherwise no output would be profitable. 2. This question requires us to work through the model taking c, rather than F, as the parameter that will determine the various possible cases. Since we know that capacity never exceeds output we shall let xi denote both output and capacity for firm i. The counterparts of [D.3] and [D.5] are max[100 − c − (x1 + x2)]x1 x1 and max[100 − c − (x1 + x2)]x2 x2 yielding reaction functions x1 = (100 − c − x2)/2; x2 = (100 − c − x1)/2 and the Cournot-Nash outputs become functions of c: x1c = (100 − c)/3; x2c = (100 − c)/3. Thus the lower is c the higher the Cournot-Nash outputs. In Fig. 16.14 of the text, reducing c shifts R1 and R2 out parallel to themselves, so that point c moves in a northeasterly direction along a 45° line. At the same time O1 is unchanged because it does not depend on c (capacity is a sunk cost). Thus the range of outputs within which the incumbent will choose to precommit capacity certainly shrinks as c increases. The intersection of O1 and R2 is now given by the solution of © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 205 x1 = 50 − 0.5x2 x2 = (100 − c − x1)/2 yielding x1 = (100 + c)/3, x2 = 2(50 − c)/3. Thus the incumbent will choose capacity in the interval [(100 − c)/3, (100 + c)/3] which is clearly wider than a point if and only if c > 0, and the width of the interval increases with c. At the Cournot-Nash point ( x1c , x2c ) the firms’ profits are π 1c = (100 − 2c)2/9; π c2 = (100 − c)2/9 − F With F = 300, entry will certainly not take place if π c2 ≤ 0, or equivalently if c ≥ 48. We therefore assume in what follows that c < 48. As in the text example, there are two cases in general. 1. The point of intersection of O1 and R2 is profitable for the entrant. Since at this point x1 = (100 + c)/3, x2 = 2(50 − c)/3, this corresponds to π2 = [2(50 − c)]2/9 − 300 > 0 or c < 24. It follows that for 0 < c < 24, any capacity choice the incumbent makes in the interval [(100 − c)/3, (100 + c)/3] will be profitable for the entrant, and the best the incumbent can do is maximize his profit given that entry will take place. The Stackelberg leadership problem in this case is max[100 − c − (x1 + (100 − c − x1)/2)]x1 x1 with solution x1s = (100 − c)/2. In the text, we had c = 30 and so xs = 35. This solution shows that the output of the incumbent, and therefore the resulting profit, falls as c increases. Note that as in the text example, the Stackelberg solution always happens to coincide with the monopoly solution. The entrant’s corresponding output is x2s = (100 − c)/4 and so the entrant’s post-entry output and profits also fall as c increases. Note that the ratio of x1s to x2s is constant whatever the value of c. 2. If c lies in the interval 24 ≤ c < 48, then the entrant’s profit becomes zero somewhere in the interval [(100 − c)/3, (100 + c)/3]. The significance of the output level V1 (notation as in the text) is that if the incumbent sets capacity at or above this level he can deter entry. For given F it is of interest to see how V1 varies with c. With F = 300, V1 must satisfy π2 = [100 − c − (x1 + x2)]x2 − 300 = 0 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 206 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn where x2 is given by the reaction function x2 = (100 − c − x1)/2. Substituting into the expression for π2 and solving for x1 gives V1 = 100 − c1 ± 34.64. Clearly then the higher is the marginal capacity cost the lower will be the output at which entry is just profitable and so the lower the capacity level to which the incumbent must precommit if he wants to deter entry. The discussion of the possible sub-cases in the text then applies directly. 3. Let v < 30 be the price at which the incumbent could sell off capacity post-entry, while 30 is the cost of expanding capacity pre- and post-entry. The effect of introducing v is to change the form of the incumbent’s post-entry reaction function, O1. Given a capacity commitment L1, the incumbent’s post-entry reaction function is found by solving max π 1 = [100 − v − (x1 + x2)]x1 x1 s.t. x1 ≤ L1 yielding the reaction function (100 − v − x2 )/2 for x1 < L1 x1 = otherwise L1 This reaction function has the same slope as R1 and O1 in Fig. 16.14 of the text, but lies between them (for 0 < v < 30). The analysis then goes through exactly as before, but with respect to this reaction function. Nothing in the results changes qualitatively, but quantitatively the profitability and the effectiveness of capacity precommitment will be reduced. Intuitively, capacity is less of a sunk cost and this reduces its precommitment value. 4. If in this model F = 0, the entrant certainly makes a profit at the intersection of O1 and R2 in Fig. 16.14 of the text. Then the only case possible is that where the incumbent acts as a Stackelberg leader, choosing a capacity L*1 = 35, and allowing entry. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 207 Chapter 17 Choice under Uncertainty Exercise 17C 1. (a) and (b) The largest amount p that an individual with initial income y and the utility function u = √y will pay for the prospect which yields either 900 or 400 with equal probabilities is defined by 0.5√(y + 900 − p) + 0.5√(y + 400 − p) = √y (17.1) After some tedious manipulation it is possible to solve this equation for p = 650 − 15625 y (Start by multiplying through by 2, square both sides, rearrange, square both sides again . . . ) The individual will never be willing to pay the expected value of the prospect but the amount he would pay increases with his initial income. 2. (a) Instead of (17.1) we have 0.5a(y + 900 − p) + 0.5a(y + 400 − p) = ay which solves for p = 650. 2. (b) Instead of (17.1) we have 0.5(y + 900 − p)2 + 0.5(y + 400 − p)2 = y2 (17.2) which solves for p = 650 ± 1 √(4y2 − 5002) 2 and we are interested only in the positive root of the second term. (If we take the negative root p will be zero for y ≈ 696.42 and (17.2) will be violated.) The prospect becomes more valuable to the individual the greater his initial income. 3. Daniel Bernoulli suggested that the gamble is not infinitely valuable because individuals are concerned with expected utility rather than expected income. Specifically he proposed the utility function u(y) = log y so that © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 207 208 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Eu = ∞ ∞ ∑ π s u(ys ) = ∑ 2− s log 2s 1 1 = s2− s log 2 1 ∞ ∑ = 2 log 2 Diminishing marginal utility is not sufficient to ensure that prospects with arbitrarily small probabilities of arbitrarily large payoffs have a finite expected utility. Consider a utility function u(y) and a prospect with payoffs (y1, y2, . . . ) with probabilities πs = 2−s such that u(ys) ≥ 2s. For the individual with the utility function u this prospect has an infinite expected utility: Eu = ∞ ∞ ∑ π u(y ) ≥ ∑ 2 2 = ∞ s 1 −s s s 1 To avoid this kind of difficulty it is necessary to assume that the utility function is bounded. See K J Arrow, Essays in Risk Bearing, North Holland, 1970. 4. Let πi be the probability that the punter’s horse wins in race i, bi be the bet placed on the race i and wi = kibi be the amount won if the horse wins race i. If the punter wins on race 1, b2 = w2 = k1b1; if the punter then wins on race 2, b3 = w2 = k2b2 = k2k1b1 and, if the last race is also won, w3 = k3b3 = k3k2k1b1. The prospect of the bet on the third race is P 3 = (π3, 1 − π3; k3k2k1b1, −b1). The second race is a prospect whose prizes are the prospect of the third race with probability π2 and the loss of the original stake with complementary probability: P 2 = (π2, 1 − π2; P 3, −b1). The first race is a prospect with prizes of P 2 with probability π1 and −b1 with complementary probability: P 1 = (π1, 1 − π1; P 2, −b1). The rational equivalent of the compound prospect P 1 is the prospect P = (π1π2π3, 1 − π1π2π3; k3k2k1b1, −b1). Betting in each race separately gives three simple prospects P si = (πi, 1 − πi; kibi, −bi). Exercise 17D 1. (a) This is inconsistent with the version of expected utility theory set out in section C: utility depends on whether she has gambled as well as on her income. It is possible to describe her preferences over income by two utility functions ui(y), i = g, n where the subscript indicates whether she has gambled or not. If we assume that ug(y) = −∞ she would never gamble because her expected utility from any gamble would always be less than her expected utility without the gamble. 1. (b) If she believes (wrongly) that the probability of winning is zero then her reasons for rejecting the gamble are consistent with expected utility theory. 1. (c) This is consistent: she has declining marginal utility. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 209 Fig. 17D.1 1. (d) This is consistent if we interpret “cannot afford” as placing a very high value on income lost relative to income gained. It is a statement about the shape of her utility function. 1. (e) This is consistent: she is better off with some other gamble. 1. (f) This is consistent: the rationale for not accepting the gamble relates to feasibility, not her preferences. 2. One example is when income varies with health and health directly affects preferences. This is ruled out by axiom 3 (equivalent standard prospects). The value of v1 at which y1 is equivalent to (v1; yu, yL) will not be unique if the individual also cares about health. 3. The apparent contradiction arises because the purchase of unfair insurance implies risk aversion and acceptance of an unfair bet implies risk preference. One obvious, though not necessarily satisfactory, explanation for such behaviour is that preferences are state dependent. (One buys unfair health insurance because health state affects the marginal utility of income. See section 19B.) Another possibility, suggested by Friedman and Savage (Journal of Political Economy, 56, 1948, 297–304) is that the utility function has both concave and convex segments, as in Fig. 17D.1. Suppose that the individual initially faces the prospect P a = (πa; y1, y2) with expected income J a and buys an insurance policy with a premium of ra leaving him with a certain income of yca = J a − ra. If he is now offered the unfair gamble of the risky prospect P b = (πb; y3, y4) with expected income J b < yca he would accept it. Yet a third explanation is that one obtains pleasure from gambling of certain kinds, e.g. on horse racing, but not of others, e.g. on falling sick. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 210 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 4. From the definition of a concave function [D.6] tg(y1) + (1 − t)g(y2) = t[a + bv(y1)] + (1 − t)[a + bv(y2)] = a + b[tv(y1) + (1 − t)v2)] ≤ a + bv(ty1 + (1 − t)y2) = g(ty1 + (1 − t)y2), t ∈ [0, 1] (where the concavity of v is used at the third step in the argument). Hence g(y) is concave. Define ys = tys1 + (1 − t)ys2, t ∈ [0, 1] and use the definition of concavity vs(ys) ≥ tvs(ys1) + (1 − t)vs(ys2) which implies πsvs(tys1 + (1 − t)ys2) ≥ tπsvs(ys1) + (1 − t)πsvs(ys2) Hence H(y1, . . . , yS) = ∑ π v (y ) s s s s ≥t ∑ π v (y ) + (1 − t)∑ π v (y ) s s s1 s s s s2 s = tH(y11, . . . , yS1) + (1 − t)H(y12, . . . , yS2) which establishes the concavity of the expected utility function in (y1, . . . , yS) space. Hence the contours of the expected utility function are quasi-concave if the utility of income function v(y) is concave. 5. Reducing yL to yL′ means that the probability of getting the better outcome yu must be increased if the individual is to be indifferent between y and the standard prospect. Conversely in Fig. 17.2(b). 6. Herrman has diminishing marginal utility. 7. Let P 1 = (π ; y, y) be a certain prospect and P 2 = (π ; y + g, y − ᐉ) be a risky prospect with π g − (1 − π)ᐉ = 0. Let ua = √y and ub = [ua(y)]4 = y2, so that ub is an increasing monotone transformation of ua. Since ua is a concave function P 1 is preferred to P 2 if u = ua(y), but ub is a convex function and P 2 is preferred to P 1 if u = ub(y). To be more specific try y = 100, g = 30, ᐉ = 15, π = 1/3. 8. Let ycu , ycg be the certainty equivalents under the two utility functions. Then u( ycu ) = Eu(y) ⇒ a + bu( ycu ) = a + bEu(y) and since g(y) = a + bu(y) we have g( ycu ) = Eg(y) © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 211 and so ycu = ycg . Since the risk premium is defined as expected income less certainty equivalent income we have also established that the risk premium is unaffected by a positive linear transformation of the utility function: ru = Ey − ycu = Ey − ycg = r g. 9. Let Ag, Av be the coefficients of absolute risk aversion for the two utility functions. Since g′(y) = f ′(v)v′(y) and g″(y) = f ′(v)v″(y) + f ″(v)v′v′ we have Ag = − g ′′ − f ′v′′ − f ′′v′v′ = g′ f ′v′ = − v ′′ f ′′ − v′ v′ f′ = Av − f ′′ v′ > A v f′ since f ″ < 0. Inserting this result in the approximation for the risk premium shows that for ‘small’ gambles the risk premium is larger for the utility function g. More generally, we can use the definition of certainty equivalent income [D.2]. Apply Jensen’s inequality (the expected value of a concave function of a variable is less than the value of the function evaluated at the expected value of the variable) to note that Eg = Ef(v) < f(Ev) (17.3) From the definition of certainty equivalent income g( ycg ) = Eg(y) and v( ycv ) = Ev(y) we see that (17.3) implies g( ycg ) < f ( v( ycv )) = g( ycv ) and so ycg < ycv since g is increasing in y. Hence rg = Ey − ycg > Ey − ycv = rv 10. Differentiation gives Table 17D.1. Constant absolute risk aversion. Integrating − u′′ d log u′ =− =A u′ dy v a − be−Ay a + b 1y− R a + b log y 1− R v′ Abe−Ay by−R by−1 v″ A = −v″/v′ 2 −Ay −A be A −R−1 −bRy Ry−1 −by−2 y−1 Table 17D.1 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 R = −v″y/v′ Ay R 1 212 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn gives −log u′ = Ay + k0 when A is a constant. Hence log u′ = −k0 − Ay and so u′ = K0e−Ay where log K0 = −k0. Integrating again gives u = K1 − K0e−Ay as required. Constant relative risk aversion. Assume that R ≠ 1. Integrating − u′′y − d log u′ = =R u′ d log y gives log u′ = −R log y − k0 and so u′ = K0y−R where log K0 = −k0. Integrating again gives u = K1 + K 0 y 1− R 1− R Supplementary question (i) What is the form of the utility function when the constant relative risk aversion is unity: R = 1? 11. (a) For risk aversion we require v″ = 2c < 0 which implies c < 0. Marginal utility will be positive if v′ = b + 2cy > 0 which requires b > 0 and y < −b/2c. 11. (b) Expected utility is Ev = a + bEy + cEy2 = a + bEy + c[σ 2 + (Ey)2] where σ 2 = Ey2 − (Ey)2 is the variance. The slope of indifference curves in (σ 2, Ey) space is dσ 2 b + 2cEy =− dEy c which is negative for Ey < −b/2c so that the indifference map is as shown in Fig. 17D.2. For Ey < −b/2c the slope of the indifference curve is positive, declining with Ey and unaffected by σ 2. In Fig. 17D.2 we have drawn the indifference curves with Ey on the vertical axis and σ 2 on the horizontal axis, as is conventional in finance theory. Thus © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 213 σ Fig. 17D.2 each indifference curve now become steeper as Ey increases. The amount of additional expected income required to compensate for an increase in risk is increasing: risk aversion is increasing with mean income. Exercise 17E 1. Differentiating the slope of the indifference curve [E.3] with respect to y1, remembering that around the indifference curve y2 is a function of y1, gives dy −π 1 d( dy 2 / dy1 ) v ′( y 2 ) v ′( y1 ) − v ′( y1 ) v ′′( y 2 ) 2 = 2 dy1 dy1 π 2 v ′( y 2 ) = −π 1 π v ′( y1 ) v ′( y 2 ) v ′( y1 ) + v ′( y1 ) v ′′( y 2 ) 1 >0 2 π 2 v ′( y 2 ) π 2 v ′( y 2 ) So indifference curves get flatter as y1 increases if the individual is risk averse (v″ < 0). More formally, expected utility is a weighted sum of concave functions and is therefore also concave and so has quasi-concave contours. If the individual is risk preferring (v″ > 0) indifference curves are concave to the origin. 2. A risk neutral individual has v(y) = a + by, (b > 0) and so using [E.3] dy2 π v ′( y1 ) π =− 1 =− 1 dy1 π 2 v ′( y2 ) π2 so that indifference curves are negatively sloped straight lines which show combinations of income (prospects) with the same mean. 3. From [E.3], an increase in π1 makes the indifference curves steeper. Intuitively: a larger increase in y2 is required to compensate for a unit reduction in y1 if the probability of state 1 has increased. 4. Use of [E.14] shows that decreasing absolute risk aversion implies that the slope of the indifference curves will decrease along lines parallel to and below (y1 > y2) the 45° line and increase along lines parallel to and above (y2 > y1) the 45° line. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 214 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 17E.1 5. (a) From question 17C.10 we know that constant absolute risk aversion implies that v′ = bAe−Ay and so the slope of the indifference curve [E.3] is dy 2 π bAe − Ay π =− 1 = − 1 e − A( y − y ) − Ay dy1 π2 π 2 bAe 1 1 2 2 so that the slope is constant along lines parallel with the 45° line where y1 − y2 is constant. Attitude to risk depends on the absolute difference between the two payoffs. 5. (b) Since constant relative risk aversion (not equal to 1) implies v′(y) = by−R (when R ≠ 1) the slope of the indifference curve is dy2 π by − R π y = − 1 1− R = − 1 1 dy1 π 2 by2 π 2 y2 −R which is constant if along rays from the origin where y1/y2 is constant. Attitude to risk depends on the relative size of the two payoffs. 6. Since g′(y) = f ′(v(y))v′(y) the slope of the indifference curves when preferences are represented by g is dy2 π f ′( v( y1 )) v ′( y1 ) =− 1 dy1 π 2 f ′( v( y2 )) v ′( y2 ) Now f ″ < 0 implies f ′(v(y1)) < (>) f ′(v(y2)) if y1 > (<) y2, so that the indifference curves are flatter below the 45° line and steeper above it. Fig. 17E.1 shows the effect of the transformation on the indifference curves and the certainty equivalent income and risk premium. (Refer to question 17D.9 for a proof that the transformation reduces certainty equivalent income and increases the risk premium.) © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 215 The endowment point is E. The indifference curve I Eg is more “bowed in” than the indifference curve I v and cuts the certainty line lower down than the I Ev indifference curve through the same endowment point. Certainty equivalent income for the risky income at E with preferences g(y) is ycg and with preferences v(y) is ycv . The respective risk premia are r g, rv. 7. (a) Indifference curves in (y1, y2) space are rectangular about the 45° line. (Compare the isoquants for the Leontief production function.) 7. (b) Differentiation gives f ′(u) = α u−α−1 > 0 and f ″(u) = −α 2u−α−2 < 0. 7. (c) The argument is very similar to that in question 8(c) in section 5B where the relationship between the Leontief and CES production functions was examined. An individual who ranks prospects by reference to the expected utility V = ∑πsus would also be willing to rank them by any increasing monotone transformation H = H(V), (H′ > 0) of expected utility. Thus H is an equivalent representation of his preferences towards risky prospects. In particular prospects can be ranked by V = − ∑ π s us−α and by H = −V −1/α which is an increasing transformation of V for α > 0. Let us = u(ys). Suppose for a particular prospect that u1 = min(u1, . . . , uS), so that −u1 = max(−u1, . . . , −uS) Now limα→∞ π −s 1/α = 1, so that there exists an < > 0 such that for α > < ⇒ −π 1−1/α u1 = max( −π 1−1/α u1 , . . . ,−π −S1/α uS ) ⇒ −π 1 u1−α = min( −π 1 u1−α , . . . ,−π S uS−α ) ⇒ − Sπ 1 u1−α ≤ ∑ −π u = V −α s s ⇒ −(Sπ1)−1/αu1 ≥ V−1/α = −H ⇒ lim( Sπ 1 ) −1/α u1 = u1 ≤ lim H α →∞ α →∞ (17.4) Next note that, since we can always choose the original utility function so that us > 0, −π 1 u1−α ≥ ∑ −π u = V s −α s implying π 1 u1−α ≤ −V ⇒ π 1−1/α u1 ≥ −V −1/α = H ⇒ lim π1−1/αu1 = u1 ≥ lim H α →∞ α →∞ (17.5) Hence from (17.4) and (17.5) lim H = u1 α →∞ Repeating the argument for the instances in which us, s = 2, . . . , S is the minimum utility level we see that lim H = min(u1, . . . , uS) α →∞ Hence projects are ranked by their minimum utility level or, equivalently, by their minimum income level. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 216 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Exercise 17F 1. Differentiate g(y) = (y − J)2 twice with respect to y to get g″ = 2 > 0. Hence g(y) is a convex function of y and E(g(y)) (the variance of y) is increased by a mean preserving spread in the distribution. 2. Write the two prospects as P a = (.75, 0, .25, 0; 10, 22.727, 100, 1000) P b = (0, .99, 0, .01; 10, 22.727, 100, 1000) Then γ1 = 0.75, γ2 = −.99, γ3 = .25, γ4 = −.01 so that, although ∑γsys = 0 (requirement (a)), requirement (b) is not satisfied. It is possible to write P a equivalently as P a = (0, .75, .25, 0; 3 13 , 10, 100, 120) and to construct a mean preserving spread of P a P c = (0.7, 0, 0, 0.25; 3 13 , 10, 100, 120) Calculation shows that the variance of P c is 2552.08 and with u = √y, Eu = 4.1079. With u = log y, the expected utilities of P a, P c are 2.8782 and 2.0999 respectively. 3. The change from F1 to F2 is a mean preserving spread if and only if it reduces the expected value of a concave function of y. (See text pages 481–482). But since y1 and y2 differ only in location and scale and in fact have the same mean, we know from text page 476 that all risk averters are made worse off if and only if σ2 > σ1. Hence F2 is a mean preserving spread of F1. Supplementary question (i) Prove that sign Cov(h(y), y) = sign dh/dy to put the plausible assertion on text page 476 that Cov(v′, y) < 0 if v is concave ([F.9]) on a more rigorous footing. 4. Since y(γ) is a linear function of y, the random variables y(γ) are all members of a class differing only in location and scale (text page 475). The distribution function of y(γ) is G = Prob[9(γ) ≤ y] = Prob[γ (9 − J) + J ≤ y] y − (1 − γ ) J = Prob[9 ≤ (y − (1 − γ))J/γ) = F γ = G(y, γ) © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 217 Since y − (1 − γ ) J y − J Gγ (y, γ) = − f 2 γ γ we have −1 y′ 9 − (1 − γ ) J ( y − J )d 9 γ y′ ∫ G ( 9, γ )d 9 = γ ∫ f 0 γ 2 0 (17.6) Now Ey(γ) = Eγ (y − J) + J = J so that variations in γ do not alter the mean. Hence (recall [F.19]) ∫G = 0 1 0 γ Next note that the derivative of (17.6) with respect to y′ is −f(⋅)(y′ − J)γ−2 which is nondecreasing for y′ ∈ (0, J) and non-increasing for y′ ∈ (J, 1). Since (17.6) is zero at y′ = 0 and at y′ = 1 it must therefore be non-negative for all y′ ∈ (0, 1). Because both conditions [F.18] and [F.19] are satisfied, increases in γ constitute a mean preserving spread. To show that an increase in γ makes all risk averters worse off differentiate Ev(y(γ)) with respect to γ : d Ev(γ (y − J) + J) = Ev′(y(γ))(y − J) dγ = Ev′E(y − J) + Cov(v′, y) = Cov(v′, y) and Cov(v′, y) < 0 if v″ < 0. Exercise 17G 1. The rate of change of prudence is dP ( y) d − v ′′′( y) −1 [v″″v″ − (v′″)2] = = dy dy v ′′( y) ( v ′′)2 which has the same sign as −[v″″v″ − (v′″)2] = [(v′″)2 − v″″v″]. Hence, since the first term is positive and risk aversion is equivalent to v″ < 0, an individual has decreasing prudence only if the fourth derivative of the utility function is negative: v″″ < 0. 2. The table has the derivatives of the three functions from Question 10, Exercise 17D. v v′ v″ v′″ P = −v′″/v″ P′ a − be−Ay Abe−Ay −A2be−Ay A3be−Ay A 0 a + by1−R/(1 − R) by−R −Rby−(1+R) (1 + R)Rby−(2+R) (1 + R)y−1 – a + bln y by−1 −by−2 by−3 y−1 – © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 218 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Supplementary questions (i) From the answer to Question 8, Exercise 17E, show that the rate of change of absolute risk aversion has the same sign as A(y) − P(y) and then compare A and P for the three utility functions in the table to confirm your answers to Question 10, Exercise 17E about the sign of A′(y). (ii) We can define relative prudence as Py by analogy with relative risk aversion (Ay). Is relative prudence increasing, decreasing or constant for the three utility functions in the table? 3. Expected utility is E = v(y0 − a) + Ev(J1 + z + (1 + i)a) where random period 1 income y1 = J1 + z is written as the sum of its mean J1 and a random component z with zero mean (Ez = 0). The first order condition on the choice of saving is Ea = −v′(y0 − a) + (1 + i)Ev′(J1 + z + (1 + i)a) = 0 so that the marginal utility of consumption in the first period equals discounted second period expected utility of consumption. Or: the marginal rate of substitution between first and second period consumption is equal to rate at which consumption can be transferred between periods by saving: Ev′(J1 + z + (1 + i)a)/v′(y0 − a) = 1/(1 + i) (recall the savings decision under certainty from chapter 11B). 3. (a) Recalling the method of simple comparative statics for problem with a single choice variable (Appendix I) Eay ∂a* [− v′′( y0 − a )] =− =− >0 ∂y0 Eaa Eaa 0 (remember that Eaa < 0 for a maximum and the individual is risk averse). Intuitively, since first period income is higher, marginal utility in the first period is smaller, and the individual responds by reducing consumption in the first period by saving more, thereby increasing future consumption and reducing expected marginal utility in the second period. 3. (b) The marginal effect of an increase in expected future income is EaJ ∂a* [(1 + i) Ev ′′( J1 + z + (1 + i)a )] =− =− <0 Eaa Eaa ∂J1 1 An increase in expected future income reduces the expected marginal utility of consumption in the second period and so first period consumption must be increased by a reduction in saving. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 219 3. (c) The effect of an increase in the rate of interest is ∂a* E [Ev ′( J1 + z + (1 + i)a )] + a[Ev ′′( J1 + z + (1 + i)a )] = − ai = − Eaa Eaa ∂i =− [Ev ′( J1 + z + (1 + i)a )] a[Ev ′′( J1 + z + (1 + i)a )] − Eaa Eaa =− [Ev′( J1 + z + (1 + i)a )] ∂a* +a ∂J1 Eaa The first term is the substitution effect and is positive: an increase in the rate of interest increases the opportunity cost of current consumption and so, holding expected utility constant, saving will increase. However, an increase in i increases future consumption at any given level of savings and increases in future consumption make saving less valuable. The “income” or more precisely, wealth effect has a definite sign (unlike the wealth effects examined in chapter 10B) because we have had to make more restrictive assumptions about preferences under uncertainty in order to represent them by an expected utility function. But the income and substitution effects are of opposite sign so that the overall effect of an increase in the price of current consumption on saving is ambiguous without further restrictions on preferences. 3. (d) We can write ∂a * E E[v ′( y1 ) + a(1 + i) v ′′( y1 )] = − ai = − ∂i Eaa Eaa =− v′′ v′′ 1 1 E 1 + a(1 + i) v′ = − E 1 + [y1 + a(1 + i) − y1 ] v′ v′ v′ Eaa Eaa =− v′′ v′′ 1 E 1 + y1 v′ − [y1 − a(1 + i)] v′ v′ v′ Eaa =− 1 E[[1 − R(y1)]v′ + [(y1 − a(1 + i))]A(y1)v′] Eaa Since y1 > a, A > 0, and v′ > 0, then if relative risk aversion is less than 1 (R < 1) increases in the rate of interest increases saving. 4. The first order condition is now written Ea = −v′(y0 − a) + (1 + i)Ev′(J1 + βz + (1 + i)a) = 0 and so Eaβ = (1 + i)E[zv″(J1 + βz + (1 + i)a)] = 0 Since by construction Ez = 0 E[zv″(J1 + βz + (1 + i)a)] = EzEv″ + Cov(z, v″) = Cov(z, v″(J1 + βz + (1 + i)a)) © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 220 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Now increases in z will lead to increases in consumption and so to increases or decreases in v″ depending on whether v′″ is positive or negative. Thus a Sandmo increase in risk increases saving if prudence (−v′″/v″) is positive. Moreover, recall Question 8, Exercise 17E, we see that a sufficient condition for a Sandmo increase in risk to increase saving is that absolute risk aversion is increasing which implies that v′″ > 0. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 221 Chapter 18 Production under Uncertainty Section 18B 1. Suppose that there is only output price uncertainty. The effect of an increase in B on the marginal value of output is, from [B.3], ∂Vx = Ev″(psx* − c(x*) + B)[ps − c′(x*)] ∂B Define p0 ≡ c′(x*) and y0 ≡ p0x* − c(x*). Since ys is increasing in ps ps ≥ p0 ⇒ A(ys) ≤ A(y0) ⇒ −v″(ys) ≤ A(y0)v′(ys) ⇒ −v″(ys)[ps − c′(x*)] ≤ A(y0)v′(ys)[ps − c′(x*)] (18.1) Similarly, ps < p0 ⇒ A(ys) > A(y0) ⇒ −v″(ys) > A(y0)v′(ys) ⇒ −v″(ys)[ps − c′(x*)] < A(y0)v′(ys)[ps − c′(x*)] (18.2) (the last inequality follows because ps ≤ p0 = c′(x*)). Since (18.1) and (18.2) cover all possible values of ps we can multiply each inequality through by −πs < 0 and sum over s to get Ev″(ys)[ps − c′(x*)] > −A(y0)Ev′(ys)[ps − c′(x*)] = 0 where the last equality follows from the first order condition [B.3] on x. Hence when there is diminishing absolute risk aversion an increase in lump sum income reduces the marginal value of output and so reduces the output level chosen. Supplementary questions (i) Repeat the above procedure to establish that an increase in lump sum income increases the input level if there technological uncertainty and diminishing absolute risk aversion. (ii) Show that when there is price and technological uncertainty the assumption of diminishing absolute risk aversion is not sufficient to determine the effect of lump sum income on the input level. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 221 222 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 2. The variance of income [B.1] is Var(ys) = Var(psx) = x2Var(ps) which is increasing in output. A risk averse firm with quadratic utility v = a + bys + cys2 has expected utility V = a + bEys + cEys2 = a + bEys + c(Eys)2 + cVar(ys) with c < 0, Eys < −b/2c. (See question 11, exercise 17D.) The marginal value of output is dys dVar( y s ) +c Vx = (b + 2cEys) dx dx At the output at which expected income is maximized, we have dEys/dx = 0 and so Vx = cdVar(ys)/dx < 0. Hence the firm with a quadratic utility function chooses a smaller output than a firm which is risk neutral and maximizes expected income. 3. (a) In state s the producer chooses output xs* to maximize v(ys). Since utility is increasing in income (v′(ys) > 0) this implies maximization of ys and the first order condition on output in state s is dys = ps − c ′( xs* ) = 0 dxs (18.3) and the optimal state s output is xs* = g(ps). Note that, since the cost function is not state dependent, the supply function determining output in each state s is state independent. 3. (b) The maximized utility in state s is v( ys* ) = v(psg(ps) − c(g(ps)) + B) and expected utility is Ev(ys) = Ev(psg(ps) − c(g(ps)) + B) 3. (c) Intuitively: the firm cannot be worse off if it chooses output after observing ps rather than before, since it has the option of setting xs = x* where x* maximizes Ev(psx − c(x) + B). More formally, since xs* = g(ps) maximizes ys, v(psg(ps) − c(g(ps)) + B) ≥ v(psx* − c(x*) + B) which implies Ev(psg(ps) − c(g(ps)) + B) ≥ Ev(psx* − c(x*) + B) 3. (d) The firm is better (worse) off a result of a mean preserving contraction in the distribution of ps if its maximized state s utility v(psg(ps) − c(g(ps)) + B) is concave (convex) in ps. (See the discussion of mean preserving spreads in section 17F.) The derivative of v( ys* ) with respect to ps is, using the envelope theorem, dv( ys* ) dy * ∂y * = v ′( ys* ) s = v ′( ys* ) s = v ′( ys* ) g( ps ) dps dps ∂ps Differentiating again with respect to ps we have © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 223 dg( p s ) v ′′ dg ps g( ps ) v ′ v ′′( y s* ) g( ps ) 2 + v ′( y s* ) = p s g( p s ) + dp s dps g( ps ) ps v′ p g( p s ) g( p s ) v ′ = ε ps − R( y s* ) s (18.4) ps * y s where εps is the elasticity of supply with respect to ps and R = −v″ys/v′ is relative risk aversion. It is obvious from the first order condition (18.3) on state s output that the supply elasticity is positive. Hence if risk aversion is “small” or B is “large” relative to profit psg(ps) − c(g(ps)), (18.4) is positive and v( ys* ) is convex in ps. In these circumstances the owner of the firm is worse off as a result of a price stabilization scheme which is a mean preserving contraction of the price distribution. Thus the timing of decisions is crucial in evaluating the gains and losses from price stabilization. 4. There is diminishing absolute risk aversion if d( − v′′( y)/ v′( y)) 1 =− (v′″v′ − v″v″) < 0 dy ( v′)2 Hence v′″ < 0 is sufficient, but not necessary, for diminishing absolute risk aversion. Supplementary question (i) Use a Taylor’s series expansion on v(ys) about Eys to get an expression for Ev(ys) which shows that v′″ < 0 can be interpreted as a dislike of positive skewness in the distribution of ys. 5. Partially differentiate the first order condition [B.34] on z with respect to w to get Vzw = − Ev ′′( ys ) z[ pfs′( z) − w] − Ev′(ys) (18.5) Hence if the firm is risk neutral (v″ = 0), the firm reduces the demand for the input when its price increases because Vzw = −Ev′ < 0 Differentiate [B.34] partially with respect to B to get VzB = Ev″(ys) ( pfs′ − w) and substitute this into (18.5), yielding ∂z V V Ev ′ = − zw = zB z + ∂w Vzz Vzz Vzz =− ∂z Ev ′ z+ ∂B Vzz The second term is the substitution effect which is always negative since Vzz < 0. The first term is the ambiguous income effect. The increase in w makes the firm worse off and if there is declining absolute risk aversion the income effect reinforces the substitution effect. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 224 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 6. When the market demand has constant elasticity of ε the demand function is q = pε and so log q = ε log p and Var(log q) = ε 2 Var(log p) Hence Var(log pq) = Var((1 + ε) log p) = (1 + ε)2Var(log p) and the variance of log pq is less than the variance of log q if and only if ε > − 12 . Exercise 18C 1. (a) If Eps = F < pf the expected profit from selling one unit forward and then buying a unit on the spot market (to deliver the promised unit) is positive. Hence arbitrarily large expected profits can be made by such selling forward and the market cannot be in equilibrium if there are any traders who care only about expected income. 1. (b) We can write the first order condition on the sale of futures contracts [C.3] (letting xf < 0 indicate purchases) as (pf − F)Ev′(ys) − Cov(v′(ys), ps) = 0 When pf > F the first term is positive so that Cov(v′, ps) > 0 is required under contango. If there is risk aversion contango implies that ys and ps are negatively correlated. But from [C.1] this requires that the ps(fs − xf) are negatively correlated. If production is not stochastic the ps(fs − xf) are negatively correlated only if the firm sells more forward than it produces (xf > f(z)), entering the spot market to make up the difference between its promised delivery and its output. 2. Let state 1 be fine weather and state 2 be wet weather. Denote the premium for cover q against wet weather by ρ. Incomes in the two states are y1 = p1 f1(z) − wz − ρ q + B y2 = p2 f2(z) − wz + (1 − ρ)q + B Assume that fine weather is preferable to wet weather (p1 f1(z) > p2 f2(z)). The firm’s choice of input and cover satisfy Vz = π1v′(y1) [ f1′( z) − w] + π2v′(y2) [ f2′( z) − w] = 0 (18.6) Vq = −π1v′(y1)ρ + π2v′(y2)(1 − ρ) = 0 (18.7) Since insurance is actuarially fair (ρ = π2), (18.7) implies v′(y1) = v′(y2) and cover is set at the level which equates the state contingent incomes: q* = p1 f1(z) − p2 f2(z) © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 225 Fig. 18C.1 The equality of marginal utilities of income across states means that we can also divide (18.6) through by v′ to get π 1 [ f1′( z) − w] + π 2 [ f2′( z) − w] = 0 so that the availability of actuarially fair insurance leads the insured producer to act as if risk neutral. Fig. 18C.1 illustrates (compare text Fig. 18.3). By increasing z the firm can move along the state contingent production possibility frontier FF. Since dys/dz = ps fs′( z) − w the frontier has the slope dy2 p1 f1′( z) − w = dy1 p2 f2′( z) − w Note that p1 f1(z) > p2 f2(z) implies that FF lies below the 45° line. If there is no insurance the risk averse producer chooses b0 where her indifference curve is tangent to FF. (Rearrange (18.6) to derive the tangency condition.) The lines a0b0, a*b* have slope −π1/π2 and are iso-expected income lines. A risk neutral producer would choose point b* where expected income is maximized. When insurance is available the risk averse producer could still choose a production plan at b0 and then insure to get to a0. However, she does even better by choosing to produce the state contingent incomes at b* and insuring to a*. Without insurance the owner of the firm can alter her state contingent incomes only by changing her input choice. The insurance market permits the exchange of state contingent incomes and allows the owner to separate production and consumption decisions. The production plan is made to maximize expected income and the resulting risk traded away via the insurance market to leave the owner with a risky income but certain consumption. Compare the separation of intertemporal consumption and investment in chapter 11. Note that since the introduction of insurance alters the production decisions it will have consequences for the input and output markets. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 226 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Chapter 19 Insurance, Risk Spreading and Pooling Exercise 19B 1. (a) The slope of the budget constraint [B.5] is −(1 − kπ2)/kπ2 > −(1 − π)/π. Increases in π flatten the budget constraint and reduce the slope of the indifference curves. (See question 4 for the effect on the demand for cover.) 1. (b) If the insurer incurs administrative costs of k0 + kq whether the accident occurs or not, the breakeven premium (in £) is P = π q + k0 + kq = k0 + (π + k)q for cover of q. Hence dy1/dq = −(π + k) and dy2/dq = 1 − (π + k). The budget line has slope dy2/dy1 = −[1 − (π + k)]/(π + k) and starts from a point (y − k0, y − L − k0) instead of (y, y − L). In Fig. 19B.1 contracts along bc, except b, break even. The feasible set is point a plus bc except for point c. 2. The marginal value of cover is (see [B.8]) Vq = −π 1 v1′ (y − pq)p + π 2 bv′1 (y − L + (1 − p)q)(1 − p) and so increases in a have no effect on the demand for insurance. Increases in b increase the marginal utility of income if there has been an accident and so increase the demand for cover. The state dependence of utility functions affects decisions which transfer income between states only if marginal utility depends on the state. Full cover would be bought if b ≥ π1p/π2(1 − p) since this implies that Vq(q, ⋅) > 0 at q < L. 3. With full cover, actuarially fair insurance the insured has expected utility of v(y − π2L) > π1v(y) + π2v(y − L) and would be willing to pay up to β, defined implicitly by v(y − π2L − β) = π1v(y) + π2v(y − L) over and above the fair premium π2L for such a policy. Thus the certainty equivalent income for no cover is yc = y − π2L − β. Since expected income is J = y − π2L we see that β = J − yc is the risk premium. 4. (a) Partially differentiate Vq with respect to π2, remembering that π1 = 1 − π2: Vqπ = v′(y − pq)p + v′(y − L + (1 − p)q)(1 − p) > 0 2 which implies that demand for cover increases with the accident probability. 226 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 (19.1) Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 227 Fig. 19B.1 4. (b) Since VqL = −π2v″(y − L + (1 − p)q)(1 − p) > 0 the demand for cover increases with the loss. 4. (c) Because p varies with π2, the effect of an increase in the accident probability on the marginal value of cover is, from (19.1) and [B.18], Vqπ + Vqp 2 dp = [v1′ p + v2′ (1 − p)] − [π 1 v1′ + π 2 v2′ ]k − kVqyq dπ 2 (19.2) where vs′ = v′(ys). Make use of the first order condition [B.8] to substitute π 1 v1′ p/π 2 for v2′ (1 − p) and π 1 v1′ p /(1 − p) for v2′π 2 and collect terms to write the first two terms of (19.2) as π π 2π 1 π p p v1′ p 1 + 1 − kπ 1 v1′ 1 + −π1 − 1 = v1′ k π 2 + 1 − p 1 − p π2 π2 = v1′ k [(1 − p) − π1(1 − p) − π1p] (1 − p) = v1′ k (1 − p − π1) 1− p = v1′ kπ 2 (1 − k) < 0 1− p Even though the substitution effect (the second term in (19.2)) outweighs the effect of the change in the slope of the indifference curves (the first term in (19.2)) the overall effect is ambiguous because of the income effect. However, if insurance is a normal good (so that the income effect of a rise in π2 and therefore in p reduces the demand for insurance) we see that the demand for cover will decrease when the accident probability increases. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 228 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Supplementary question (i) Illustrate these comparative static results in a series of diagrams. 5. The first order condition is Vq = [v(y − P) − v(y − q − P + q)]dF − P ′ + (1 − P ′) = −P′ ∫ v′(y − P (q))dF q 0 ∫ v′(y − L − P + q)dF L1 q ∫ v′(y − P )dF + (1 − P ′)∫ v′(y − L − P + q)dF = 0 q L1 0 q Partially differentiate with respect to y to get Vqy = − P ′ ∫ v′′(y − P )dF + (1 − P ′)∫ v′′(y − L − P + q)dF q L1 0 q and, using the definition of absolute risk aversion to replace v″ with −Av′, Vqy = P′ ∫ A(y − P)v′(y − P)dF q 0 − (1 − P′) ∫ A(y − L − P + q)v′(y − L − P + q)dF L1 q Now y − L − P + q < y − P when q < L. Hence, if A declines with income, A(y − L − P + q) > A(y − P) and so Vqy < P′ ∫ A(y − P)v′(y − P)dF − (1 − P′) ∫ A(y − P)v′(y − L − P + q)dF q L1 0 q = A(y − P)[P′ ∫ v′(y − P)dF − (1 − P′) ∫ v′(y − L − P + q)dF] q L1 0 q = A(y − P)[−Vq(q*, ⋅)] = 0 where q* is the optimal cover, so that Vq(q*, ⋅) = 0. Hence an increase in income reduces the demand for cover if and only if the insured has decreasing absolute risk aversion. Exercise 19C 1. If the small uninsurable risk is characterised (as in [C.1]) by a reduction in income in states 2 and 4 then clearly expected utility is reduced because an increase in D reduces income in these states with no offsetting increase in income in states 1 and 3: dEu dq dEu dEu = −f2u′(y2) − f4u′(y4) < 0 + = dq dD D = 0 dD D = 0 dD D = 0 (remember that insurance against the insurable risk is chosen optimally so that dEu/dq = 0). © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 229 More interesting is the effect of small uninsurable risk which is a fair bet ie has a zero expected value. To ensure this we can write the state contingent incomes as y1 = x + kD − pq, y2 = x − D − pq, y3 = x + kD − L + (1 − p)q, y4 = x − D − L + (1 − p)q with k = (f2 + f4)/(f1 + f3) = τ /(1 − τ). Now the effect of small uninsurable fair risk is dEu = f1 u1′k − f2 u2′ + f3 u3′ k − f4 u4′ dD D = 0 = ( f1 k − f 2 ) u2′ + ( f 3 k − f4 ) u4′ = [ f1( f2 + f4) − f2( f1 + f3)] = ( f1 f4 − f2 f3) u2′ u4′ + [ f3( f2 + f4) − f4( f1 + f3)] 1−τ 1−τ u2′ − u4′ 1−τ (19.3) (19.4) (where ui′ = u′(yi) and remember that with D = 0, y1 = y2, y3 = y4.) Consider a number of cases. (a) The insured faces an actuarially fair premium on the insurable risk, in which case she buys insurance until marginal utility is equal in all states. Hence (19.4) is zero: with fair insurance a small uninsurable fair bet makes the individual no worse off. Intuitively, since marginal utility is equalised across all states the insured is risk neutral towards small bets. (b) Insurance against the loss L is actuarially unfair so that u′(y2) < u′(y4). Now, as some simple manipulation shows, ( f1 f4 − f2 f3) is positive or negative if and only if f4/( f3 + f4) is greater or less than f2/( f2 + f4). But f4/( f3 + f4) is the conditional probability of the uninsurable loss ocurring given that the insured loss has ocurred and f2/( f2 + f4) is the conditional probability of the uninsurable loss occuring given that the insured loss has not ocurred. If the former exceeds the latter the losses are positively correlated. Hence with positively correlated losses a small uninsurable risk reduces expected utility. Conversely if the losses are negatively correlated expected utility is increased. Exercise 19D 1. (a) The project makes the individual worse off because utility without the project is V(0) = log 10000 = 9.210 and expected utility with the project is V(1) = 0.5 ln(20000) + 0.5 ln(1000) = 8.406 1. (b) With n individuals in a syndicate sharing the project proceeds each gets an expected utility of 10000 9000 V(n) = 0.5 ln 10000 + + 0.5 ln 10000 − n n The syndicate size which would leave the members no worse off with the project is defined by V(0) = V(n) or 10000 9000 ln(10000) = 0.5 ln 10000 + + 0.5 ln 10000 − n n © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 (19.5) 230 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Multiplying through by 2 and anti-logging gives 100002 = (10000 + 10000/n)(10000 − 9000/n) which solves for the unique breakeven { = 9. 1. (c) Assume for the moment that n is a continuous variable. Then a necessary condition for the expected utility of syndicate members to be maximized with respect to n is V′(n) = 0. Equivalently, since multiplying the maximand by a positive constant (2) does not affect the solution, the optimal size for syndicate members satisfies 0 = 2V′(n) = = −10000 n −2 90000 n −2 − ((10000 n + 10000)/ n ) ((10000 n − 9000)/ n ) −10 n −1 9 n −1 − 10 n + 10 10 n − 9 Multiplying through by n and rearranging gives the unique solution n* = 18. 1. (d) The compensating variation p(n) for a syndicate member is defined by 10000 9000 0.5 ln 10000 + − p( n) + 0.5 ln 10000 − − p( n ) = ln 10000 n n It is the maximum amount that would be paid for membership of the syndicate. With N identical individuals, all counting equally in social welfare, we can use the sum of compensating variations as the welfare measure. (The N − n non-members have a compensating variation of zero.) Using [D.8], the welfare measure is W = np(n) = 500 − nᐉ(1/n), where ᐉ is the risk loading. We know that limn→∞ nᐉ(1/n) = 0, so that provided N is large the socially optimal syndicate size is n** = N. 1. (e) If the owner gives away the fraction λ of the project his expected utility is V = 0.5 ln(10000 + (1 − λ)10000) + 0.5 ln(10000 − (1 − λ)9000) Using the answer to part (c), this is maximized when λ = (n* − 1)/n* = 17/18. 1. (f ) Assume that there are no competing projects. Since the owner is a monopolist and knows all potential buyers’ utility functions, it is plausible that he will price shares in the project so that buyers are just indifferent between buying and not buying. He sells a proportion λ of the project to n individuals at a price p. Adopting a more general notation, let the utility function of the owner and the buyers be u, ub respectively, the income without the project of the owner and the buyers be y, yb respectively, their incomes with the project in state s be ys, ybs respectively and the project payoff in state s be zs. Then p satisfies Eub(ybs) = Eub(yb + λzs/n − p) = Eub(yb + ᐉ(n, λ) + λes/n) = u(y) (19.6) where es = zs − Ezs = zs − K. (See [D.6].) Again using the definition of the risk loading (ᐉ = λX/n − p), the total revenue from share sales is np = λK − nᐉ(n, λ) which is maximized for given λ by making n as large as possible: n = N − 1. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 231 With given λ, the owner gets V = Eu(ys) = Eu(y + pn + (1 − λ)zs) = Eu(y + λK − (N − 1)ᐉ + (1 − λ)zs) = Eu(y + K − (N − 1)ᐉ(n, λ) + (1 − λ)es) The effect of an increase in the proportion of the project sold off is dV dy dl = Eu′( ys ) s = Eu′( ys ) − es − ( N − 1) dλ dλ dλ = −Eu′(ys)Ees − Cov(u′(ys), es) − Eu′(ys) (N − 1) = −Cov(u′(ys), es) + Eu′( ys )Cov( ub′ ( ybs ), es ) Eub′ ( ybs ) dl dλ (19.7) where we have used the definition of the risk loading (19.6) to get − Eub′ ( ybs )e s − Cov( ub′ , e s ) dl = = dλ ( N − 1) Eub′ ( ybs ) ( N − 1) Eub′ ( ybs ) (Remember Ees = 0.) At λ = 0 the second term in (19.6) is zero because Cov( ub′ ( ybs , e s )) = 0 since ybs = yb if the owner does not sell any of the project. At λ = 1 the first term is zero. (Cov(u′(ys), es) = 0 because ys is non-stochastic if the owner sells all the project. Hence, remembering that the Cov terms are negative if there is risk aversion, the optimal λ is positive but less than 1. The owner will not sell all of the project. As λ increases more risk is borne by buyers and less by the seller. This makes the owner more willing to bear risk and eventually reduces the proceeds from sales to risk averse buyers. Exercise 19E 1. (a) Denote the variance of the rates of return by σ 2, the random rate of return on security i by hi and the amount invested in security i by Di. The realised value of the portfolio is w = ∑1n Di(1 + h)i and the variance of the portfolio value is Var(w) = Var(∑ Di(1 + hi)) = ∑ Di2 Var(1 + hi) = σ 2 ∑ Di2 (The covariances are zero since the rates of return are independently distributed.) Since Var(w) is convex and symmetric in (D1, . . . , Dn), it is minimized when D1 = . . . = Dn = y/n. 1. (b) The minimized portfolio variance is Var(w) = σ 2∑y2/n2 = σ 2y2/n which vanishes as n → ∞. Exercise 19F 1. A proof is constructed along the following lines: we know that the self-selection constraint for high-risk types, [F.9], must be imposed, and so the discussion of [F.9] goes through as before and the equilibrium contract for high-risk types is (πhL, L). If © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 232 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn constraint [F.9] is binding for low-risk types then they are on the low-risk type indifference curve passing through this point – Ah in Fig. 19.8 of the text. But since the low-risk indifference curve is steeper than the high-risk indifference curve at this point (draw in a low-risk indifference curve in Fig. 19.8), it is obviously always possible to increase the low-risk types’ expected utility while still breaking even and continuing to satisfy [F.9], i.e. by moving along the Ih indifference curve through Ah. But this then means that constraint [F.9] is no longer binding for low-risk types. 2. We leave the reader to construct the figures from the more formal analysis given in the answer for question 3. 3. Differentiating totally through [F.11] of the text and rearranging gives [π l (1 − π h ) vl′1 − π h (1 − π l ) vl′2 ]dZl = π h vh′ [vh′ − vl′2 ]dL + [vh′ L + ( v( yl 2 ) − v( yl 1 )]dπ h − Zl [(1 − π h ) vl′1 + π h vl′2 ]dπ l where vl1′ and vl′2 are low-risk types’ marginal utilities at their state 1 and 2 incomes yl1 and yl2 respectively, and vh′ is a high type’s marginal utility (the same across states). It can quickly be established that the coefficient of dZl is negative, because πh > πl , (1 − πl ) > (1 − πh ), and vl′2 > vl1′ (since yl1 > yl2). We denote this term by δ < 0. Then comparativestatics effects are: (i) ∂Zl π h [vh′ − vl′2 ] = >0 δ ∂L An increase in the size of loss increases the coverage low-risk types can obtain. Note that if [F.11] is to hold we must have (since utility functions are identical): y − πl Zl > y − πh L > y − L + (1 − πl )Zl Then, since v″ < 0, this implies vl′2 > vh′ and the sign of ∂Zl /∂L follows from δ < 0. (ii) ∂Zl v ′ L + ( v( yl 2 ) − v( yl 1 )) 0 = h ∂π h δ The sign of this effect is ambiguous, since the term vh′ L > 0 while v(yl2) − v(yl1) < 0. A change in πh changes both sides of [F.11] in the same direction, and whether Zl will have to be increased or decreased (or left unchanged) to maintain the equality depends on the parameters of the problem. (iii) − Z [(1 − π h ) vl′1 + π h vl′2 ] ∂Zl = l >0 ∂π l δ An increase in the low risk type’s probability of loss increases the degree of coverage because it reduces the attractiveness of the low-risk contract to the high-risk types. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 233 4. If insurers could not observe how much insurance an individual buys in total, then the analysis falls apart, because a high-risk type could simply take out several low-risk type contracts, effectively moving upwards along the line Bly0 in Fig. 19.8 until he achieves the best point he can. Thus the separating equilibrium can only be sustained if buyers can be rationed to the total level of coverage Zl. 5. This is essentially explained by the answer to question 4. It may be costly to monitor every buyer of insurance to ensure that she is not taking out more total coverage than Zl at the low-risk premium. However, if every buyer knows that, in the event she makes a claim, the total coverage she will in fact receive will be restricted to Zl, then it is a waste of money to buy more coverage than this ex ante. Note, however, that sellers of insurance must still exchange information on the identity of claimants, but this involves lower costs than monitoring the identity of all buyers of insurance. 6. In Fig. 19.9, an increase in risk-aversion of low-risk types will increase the curvature of the indifference curve I d′ about its intersection point with the 45° line. Thus, to obtain a tangency point the line S* must rotate to the right. This widens the set of values of γ for which the separating equilibrium will exist. If risk aversion of high-risk types increases, this increases the curvature of the indifference curve I h in Fig. 19.9, thus shifting point d upwards along the line Bly0, implying that the I d′ indifference curve must also be higher. This again therefore widens the set of γ -values for which the separating equilibrium exists. 7. The tax paid on each high risk contract is T so that the low risk breakeven line Sᐉ satisfies Pᐉ = πᐉqᐉ + T The proceeds of the tax per head of the total population of high and low risks are λT since the proportion of low risks is λ. The amount of subsidy per high risk contract is therefore λT/(1 − λ) and the high risk breakeven line Sh satisfies Ph = πhqh − λT (1 − λ ) At the intersection of Sᐉ and Sh the low and high risk contracts offer the same amount of cover qᐉ = qh = q. By offering this pair of contracts the insurer would have expected costs, after taxes and subsidies of λ[πᐉq + T] + (1 − λ) π h q − λT = λπᐉq + (1 − λ)πhq = èq (1 − λ ) The pooling contract breakeven line S satisfies Ü = [λπᐉ + (1 − λ)πh]q = èq Thus the intersection of the breakeven lines Sᐉ, Sh is also on the pooling contract breakeven line. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 234 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 19F.1 8. Fig. 19F.1 retains the assumption of Fig. 19.10 that there are equal numbers of high and low risks and illustrates the set of possible cross-subsidy contracts generated as the level of cross-subsidy T varies. Increasing T shifts the post-subsidy break-even line Äᐉ for the low risk contract down and the post-subsidy break-even line Äh for the high risk contract up. Hence the high risks’ contract Ãh moves up the 45° line. The low risks’ contract ã is defined by the intersection of the high risk indifference curve Éh through Ãh with the post-subsidy low risk break-even line Äl. Hence as T increases the low risk contract shifts to the left, tracing out the locus dã. In the text the cross-subsidy arose from government intervention. However there can also be a Wilson anticipatory equilibrium in which competing firms offer crosssubsidising contracts without the need for government imposed taxes and subsidies. In Fig. 19F.1 competition amongst firms for low risk customers ensures that if they offer cross-subsidising separating contracts the only possible candidate for an equilibrium is the pair Ãh, ã where the expected utility of low risks is maximized given the selfselection and break-even constraints. This pair of contracts is clearly not a RothschildStiglitz Nash equilibrium since some firm could make a profit by offering only the contract ã which attracts only low risks if all other firms continue to offer the pair Ãh, ã. But if a firm offers only the contract ã and attracts only low risks the other firms will have a higher ratio of bad to low risks and will make a loss on their cross-subsidising pair of contracts. These will be withdrawn and all risks will buy ã which will make a loss. Hence the cross-subsidy pair Ãh, ã is an anticipatory equilibrium. Note that since the locus dã lies above the fair odds pooling line except at d the pooling contract a cannot be an anticipatory equilibrium if cross-subsidy is feasible. If the indifference curves of the low risks are sufficiently steeply sloped the best contract for them will be at d where there is no cross-subsidy. Hence with the anticipatory equilibrium concept and feasible cross-subsidy an equilibrium will always exist and it will be separating. The anticipatory cross-subsidy equilibrium is also constrained Pareto efficient in that any intervention by a planner who is subject to the same informational constraints as © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 235 the firms can only make one type better off by making the other type worse off. The anticipatory cross-subsidy equilibrium maximizes the expected utility of the low risk types subject to the constraints that firms break even over the pair of contracts offered and that insureds self-select. A planner would be subject to exactly the same constraints and could not make any Pareto improvement using tax and subsidy instruments. For a fuller discussion see K. Crocker and A. Snow, “The efficiency of competitive equilibrium in insurance markets with asymmetric information”, Journal of Public Economics, 26, 1985, 207–219. Exercise 19G 1. (a) With the insured paying a lump sum tax T and receiving a proportionate subsidy s on her care expenditure, her expected utility is V(a, P, T, y, q, L, s) = [1 − π(a)]v1(y1) + π(a)v2(y2) (19.8) where y1 = y − P − T − (1 − s)a and y2 = y − L − P − T − (1 − s)a + q. Since the insurer cannot observe a the insurance contract terms P, q cannot be made conditional on a and so in choosing her care level the insured takes the insurance contract as given. Assuming that the optimal amount of care is positive, her care choice satisfies the first order condition Va = π ′(a)[v2(y2) − v1(y2)] − (1 − s)[(1 − π ) v1′( y1 ) + π v2′ ( y2 )] = 0 (19.9) and the second derivative with respect to a is Vaa = π ″(a)[v2 − v1] − 2π ′( a )[v2′ − v1′](1 − s) + Evi′′ (19.10) where vi′ is marginal utility in state i. The second term in (19.9) is the expected marginal utility of income times the “price” (1 − s) of care or the utility cost of increased care expenditure. The first term is the gain from increased expenditure on care which reduces the probability of state 2. Note that the insured will only take care if this first term is positive, which requires that her utility in state 2 is smaller than in state 1. Thus if she is sufficiently well compensated for the accident that v2 ≥ v1 she will take no care at all. Note also that the plausible assumptions of risk aversion ( vi′′ < 0) and diminishing returns to care (π ″ > 0) are not sufficient to ensure that V is concave in a. We must place stronger restrictions on preferences and the technology for Vaa < 0. If the insured has less than full compensation for accident v2 < v1 the first term is negative. The last term is negative by risk aversion. However the middle term could be positive or negative. For example if marginal utility of income does not depend directly on the state and y2 < y1 then v2′ > v1′ and it is possible that Vaa > 0. 1. (b) The optimal care level is a*(P, T, y, q, L, s). Inspection of Va shows that second order cross partial derivatives satisfy VaP = VaT = −Vay and Vaq = −VaL, so that a *P = aT* = − ay* and aq* = − a L* . We will therefore just derive the effects of P and q on the amount of care. (Note that an increase in P reduces income in both states, an increase © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 236 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn in q increases income in state 2 only.) For future use we will also derive the effect of a change in the subsidy of care s. Partially differentiating Va with respect to P, q and s gives VaP = VaT = −Vay = −π ′[v2′ − v1′] + (1 − s) Evi′′ (19.11) Vaq = −VaL = π ′v2′ − (1 − s)π v2′′ (19.12) Vas = π ′[v2′ − v1′]a + Evi′ − (1 − s) Evi′′a = Evi′ + aVay (19.13) The comparative static responses are in general ambiguous without further assumptions. Thus consider the effect of an increase in cover q. Intuitively one would expect that if income in the accident state is increased, thus increasing utility in that state, this would lead to a reduction in care because the marginal benefit of care π ′[v2 − v1] is reduced. As (19.12) shows this neglects the effect of an increase in q on the marginal cost of care. Because income in state 2 is greater, marginal utility is smaller so that the marginal cost of care is reduced. Hence the optimal amount of care could increase or fall with q. Rearranging Vaq we see that care is reduced only if −π ′ − v ′′ > 2 (1 − s)π v2′ (19.14) where the right hand side is the coefficient of absolute risk aversion in state 2. Hence if the insured is not too risk averse an increase in cover will reduce care. Using (19.13) we can also derive a Slutsky equation for an increase in the subsidy rate: a s* = −Vas − Evi′ Vay − Evi′ = − = + a *a y* Vaa Vaa Vaa Vaa (19.15) The first term is the positive substitution effect (remember an increase in s corresponds to a reduction in the price of care) and the second is an ambiguous income effect. Referring to −Vay = VaP in (19.11) shows that risk aversion (which implies Evi′′ < 0) is insufficient to ensure that care is normal good. Supplementary question Suppose that the insured has state dependent constant absolute risk aversion preferences with vi = Ki − ki exp(−α yi). What is the interpretation of the coefficients Ki, ki i = 1, 2? What restrictions must be placed on them to yield a sensible specification with intuitively plausible comparative static properties? 2. Competition ensures that the insurer has zero expected profit M = P − qπ. The insurer is also constrained by the fact that care cannot be made an explicit term of an enforceable contract. Hence insurers realise that care is chosen to maximize the insured’s expected utility given the premium and the cover: a = a*(P, T, y, q, L, s) and that their expected profit constraint must be written M = P − qπ(a*(P, T, y, q, L, s)) = 0 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 (19.16) Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 237 which defines the premium implicitly as a function of the cover (and y, L, T, s): P = P(q, T, y, L, s) (19.17) Using the implicit function rule on (19.16) gives Pq = − Mq MP = π + qπ ′( a*)aq* 1 − qπ ′( a*)a *P (19.18) The assumption that care is an inferior good ay* = − a *P < 0 is sufficient, though not necessary, to ensure that an increase in the premium with cover held constant increases expected profit: M P = 1 − qπ ′a *P > 0. This, coupled with the assumption that care is reduced by an increase in cover, implies that Pq > π, since Pq > π ⇔ qπ ′a q* + π > π (1 − qπ ′a *P ) ⇔ [π a *P + a q* ]qπ ′ > 0 Hence, under these assumptions, insurers will set a premium which increases more than in proportion to the cover since they know that an increase in cover increases the accident risk. Competition amongst insurers means that the insurance contract will maximize the insured’s expected utility subject to the insurer breaking even (the insurer’s participation constraint) and to the insured’s choice of care taking no account of its effect on the insurer’s expected profit (the insured’s incentive compatibility constraint). Both constraints are embodied in (19.16). Using (19.16) to substitute for P in (19.17), the marginal value of cover is dV = Va [a q* + a *P Pq ] + Vq + VPPq = Vq + VPPq dq = π v2′ − Evi′ Pq (19.19) (Remember that a is chosen so that Va = 0.) From (19.19) we see that dV = π v2′ − Evi′π = π (1 − π )( v2′ − v1′ ) dq q=0 which is positive if marginal utility is state independent since then y1 > y2 implies v2′ > v1′. 3. The equilibrium in the insurance market has the insured choosing an optimal care level given the insurer’s break even constraint and the information asymmetry which prevents care being directly controlled by the contract. Assuming that the optimal cover is positive, it is defined by dV/dq = 0 and depends on the parameters which the insurer and insured take as exogenous: q = q**(y, T, L, s). Substituting for a and q, the per capita public sector budget constraint can be written as T − sa*(P(T, y, q**, L, s), T, y, q**, L, s) = 0 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 238 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn defining the lump sum tax implicitly as function of the subsidy rate and the other exogenous variables: T = }(y, L, s) (19.20) Using the implicit function rule we see that } s s=0 = a* + s dads* = a* * 1 − s da dT (19.21) With identical individuals treated identically the social planner’s problem is to choose s, T, a, q, P to maximize V subject to (a) the per capita public sector budget constraint, (b) the insured’s choice of care, (c) the break even constraint on the insurance contract and (d) the insured’s choice of cover. Using (19.20) and (19.21) we can use the four constraints to substitute for T, a, q, P to reduce the planner’s problem to choosing the single policy instrument s to maximize V(a*, P(}, y, q**, L, s), }, y, q**, L, s) (19.22) The derivative of V with respect to s is dV da* da* dV dq** dq** = Va + }s + + }s ds dT ds dT dq ds + VP [Ps + PT}s] + VT}s + Vs = VP [Ps + PT}s] + VT}s + Vs (19.23) where we have used the fact that Va = 0 and dV/dq = 0. Using (19.23) and the implicit function rule on (19.22) we get qπ ′a s* + qπ ′aT* } s dV = VP − Evi′a* + Evi′a* ds s=0 1 − qπ ′a P* = VP qπ ′ a s* + aT*a* 1 − qπ ′a *P a * − a y*a* = − Evi′qπ ′ s >0 1 − qπ ′a *P (19.24) From (19.24) we see that the numerator in the fraction in (19.24) is the substitution effect on care of an increase in the subsidy and is positive. Hence, since π ′ < 0, we have established that introducing a small subsidy for care improves on the competitive insurance market equilibrium even though the insurance contract mitigates the moral hazard produced by the insurer’s inability to control the level of care directly via the insurance contract and the subsidy must be financed by a tax on the insured. The market is not constrained efficient because the planner has an instrument (the subsidy) which is not available to the insured and insurer. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 239 4. To derive the full information first best allocation suppose that the government can observe a and control it directly. Hence it has no need of tax and subsidy instruments and its budget constraint is P − π(a)q = 0. The Lagrangean for its problem is L = [(1 − π(a)]v1(y − P − a) + π(a)v2(y − L − P − a + q) + λ[P − π(a)q] and the first best premium, cover and care satisfy LP = − Evi′( yi ) + λ = 0 Lq = π v2′ ( y2 ) − λπ = 0 La = π ′(a)[v2 − v1] − Evi′( yi ) − λπ ′(a)q = 0 (19.25) The first two conditions imply that λ = v2′ = Evi′ = v1′ so that there is perfect insurance in that the marginal utility of income is equalised. Rearranging the condition on the amount of care gives v − v1 − q = 1 Evi′ π ′( a ) 2 where the left hand side is the social marginal benefit of care taking account of its effect on the expected utility of the insured and the expected costs of the insurer which fall at the rate q as the accident probability is reduced. When the government cannot directly control a it must rely on the care subsidy to influence it indirectly. The government budget constraint is now P + T + sa − π q = 0. Since the effect of P and T on the budget constraint and the insured’s utility are identical we can set T = 0 and let the premium be set both to finance the care subsidy and the cost of cover. The government is subject to its budget constraint and to the constraint that the insured will choose her care solely for its effect on her expected utility, ignoring its effect on the government budget constraint. Despite this it is possible to induce a first best solution. The insured’s choice of care satisfies (if it is positive) π ′(a)(v2 − v1) − (1 − s) Evi′ = 0 (19.26) However the first best choice of care satisfies (19.25). If the government chooses the subsidy so that s=− π ′( a )q Evi′ then (19.26) will imply that (19.25) holds. Hence by also setting P and q, subject to the government budget constraint, to ensure that there is perfect insurance, the first best can be achieved. The only difficultly with this argument arises if utility is state independent. Then perfect insurance ( v1′ = v2′ ) implies v1 = v2 in which case the insured has no incentive to take any care and will set a = 0. However if insurance is only slightly less than perfect so that v2 − v1 = −ε < 0 with ε “small” then the allocation can be made as close as desired to the first best. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 240 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Exercise 19H 1. (a) Separating equilibrium. Refer to Figure 19.14 of the text, and let s2 and s3 respectively denote the s-values at which the indifference curves I1 and I2 cut a horizontal line drawn from ”. Then if s* ∈ [s2, s3] we have a separating ICE. If type 1 chooses s = 0, it receives θ1, and if type 2 chooses s ≥ s* ∈ [s2, s3] it will receive ”. Type 1 is in fact indifferent between (0, θ1) and (s2, ”), and if it chooses the latter this is still consistent with P’s beliefs. (b) Pooling Equilibrium. There is also a pooling equilibrium with s* = 0. It is impossible to choose s < 0, so no type receives θ1, everyone chooses s = 0 and receives ”. This is also consistent with P’s beliefs. 2. Take P’s beliefs to be as given on page 548 of the text. Applying the arguments underlying [H.1] and [H.2] in the text results in the inequalities s* ≥ θ 2 − θ1 c1 ; s* ≤ θ 2 − θ1 c2 (19.27) But if c2 > c1 these inequalities cannot both be satisfied and there is no separating ICE with signalling. 3. (a) We obtain a result as in the lemons model if r2 > ”. Then no type 2 worker would accept the pooling contract, and only type 1 workers are employed at wage θ1. (b) If r2 < θ1, then we have essentially the same results as before. If θ2 > r2 > θ1 then there are two possible cases. Refer to Figure 19.14 in the text. The point s0 continues to have the interpretation that type 1 will never choose s to the right of this in order to receive θ2. However s1 is no longer relevant as the upper bound of possible equilibrium values of s, since if r2 > θ1 this violates the participation constraint for type 2 that θ2 − c2s* ≥ r2 (19.28) In fact this defines a new upper bound of the interval given by s1′ = θ 2 − r2 c2 < s1 (19.29) Then as long as s1′ ≥ s0 , we have that separating ICE in which type 1 chooses s = 0 and receives θ1 and type 2 chooses s* ∈ [s0, s1′ ] and receives θ2 exist. However, if r2 is sufficiently high that s1′ < s0 , then no amount of s acceptable to type 2 can achieve separation, since they would allow type 1 to signal s1′ , receive θ2 and be better off than at (0, θ1). Then if r2 ≤ ” only a pooling equilibrium is possible, while if r2 > ” we have the lemons case as in (a). 4. In a pooling equilibrium, either (i) P would offer r2 so both types would work and her profit is πθ2 + (1 − π)θ1 − r2 or (ii) P would offer 0, so only type 1 would work and her profit is (1 − π)θ1. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 (19.30) Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 241 If πθ2 − r2 > 0 therefore she chooses (i), if πθ2 − r2 < 0 she chooses (ii). In any separating equilibrium, P will be able just to pay the reservation values r2 and 0, and so her profit is π (θ2 − r2) + (1 − π)θ1. (19.31) Thus in the case of a pooling equilibrium (i) the difference in profit is π (θ2 − r2) + (1 − π)θ1 − [πθ2 + (1 − π)θ1 − r2] = (1 − π)r2 > 0 (19.32) while in the case of pooling equilibrium (ii) the difference is πθ2 + (1 − π)θ1 − π r2 − (1 − π)θ1 = π (θ2 − r2) > 0 In each case the separating equilibrium yields a higher profit. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 (19.33) 242 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Chapter 20 Agency, Contract Theory and the Firm Exercise 20B 1. If instead of [B.7] of the text we set up the problem as: max πhv(y1) + (1 − πh)v(y2) − ah s.t. Kh ≥ z0 where z0 is the reservation expected utility for P, then the first-order conditions [B.8], [B.9] will be the same, except for being multiplied through by the Lagrange multiplier µ = 1/λ. Condition [B.10] will be replaced by the condition Kh = z0. The interpretation of the second-best solution and its comparison with the first-best remains unchanged. The only difference is that P receives her reservation utility in both first- and second-best, and it is actually A, the manager, who is made worse off by the asymmetry of information. 2. It may not be possible to find a J that satisfies [B.4]. For example, if π is very large then J will have to be small to offset the fact that the “punishment state” is unlikely to happen. There may be a lower-bound on J, i.e. a limit to the extent to which P can punish A, which then makes it impossible to find a sufficiently small J. In that case, P would have to devise an incentive-compatible contract of the second-best kind we analyze in section 20D of the text. 3. If P wants to enforce the low-effort contract, she would solve the problem: max Kl = πl(x1 − y1) + (1 − πl)(x2 − y2) s.t. πlv(y1) + (1 − πl)v(y2) − al ≥ H0. As in the high-effort case, the risk-neutrality of P means that y1* = y2* and A is fully insured, with π l v( y1* ) + (1 − π l ) v( y2* ) − al = H 0 . It is then obvious that there is no incentive-compatibility problem; A would clearly not choose ah > al if offered this contract since it would make him worse-off. Thus P would have no problem in achieving the low effort level if that was optimal for her. 4. This question reinforces the point that it is P’s risk-neutrality that leads her to offer A a certain payment in the first-best case. If P is risk-neutral, the first-best contract (for the high-effort case) is found by solving: max áH = πhU(x1 − y1) + (1 − πh)U(x2 − y2) s.t. πhv(y1) + (1 − πh)v(y2) − ah ≥ v0 242 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 243 yielding the conditions πhU′(x1 − y1* ) + λπhv′ ( y1* ) = 0 −(1 − πh)U′(x2 − y2* ) + λ(1 − πh)v′ ( y2* ) = 0 together with the constraint. These yield the conditions U ′( x1 − y1* ) U ′( x2 − y2* ) = v ′( y1* ) v ′( y2* ) which implies a tangency point of indifference curves in (y1, y2)-space; again we have a Pareto-efficient risk-sharing solution. Now suppose y1* = y2* . They v ′( y1* ) = v ′( y2* ) and the right-hand side of the equation is 1. But if x1 ≠ x2, we would then have x1 − y1* ≠ x2 − y2* , and the left-hand side is unequal to 1, a contradiction. Thus we must have y1* ≠ y2* . 5. If µ = 0, from [B.13] and [B.14] we have 1 1 =λ= v′( W1 ) v′( W2 ) implying W1 = W2 as in the first-best case. But then, in the constraint [B.12], with W1 = W2 = W we have ah ≤ al, which is false, and so we must have µ > 0. This is another reflection of the fact that a constant payment cannot be incentive-compatible. If λ = 0, the in [B.14] we have 1 µ (π h − π l ) =− (1 − π h ) v′( W2) The right hand side is negative since πh > πl and we just saw that µ > 0. But the left hand side cannot be negative, since v′ > 0. Thus we have a contradiction and we must have λ > 0. 6. Comparative-statics of contracts. We note that [B.15] and [B.16] “solve for” W1 and W2, since ah, al are given: we have two equations in two unknowns. The parameters of the model are the effort levels ah, al and probabilities πh, πl. Totally differentiating [B.15] and [B.16] gives the system: (1 − π h ) v2′ dy1 da h − [v( W1 ) − v( W2 )]dπ h π h v1′ (π − π ) v − (π − π ) v dy = da − da − [v( W ) − v( W )][dπ − dπ ]. l 1′ h l 2′ 2 l 1 2 h l h h We derive just one comparative-statics result here, leaving the remainder to the reader. Solving for ∂y1/∂π l gives ∂y1 −(1 − π h ) v2′[v( W1 ) − v( W2 )] = > 0. ∂π l −(π h − π l ) v1′v2′ © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 244 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn To explain this sign; vi′ = v ′( Wi ), and so v1′, v2′ > 0. Since W1 > W2 and πh > πl, the rest of the argument follows immediately. The intuitive argument is that if the probability of the high outcome in the low effort state increases, this increases the relative attractiveness to A of choosing low effort, and so to maintain incentive-compatibiltiy it is necessary to increase the payoff in the better state. It can also be shown that this change reduces W2. But then, in Fig. 13.4, this rightward move from β along I h0 must put P on a lower (straight line) indifference curve, that is, the agency cost has increased. An even simpler version of the comparative-statics can be undertaken using condition [B.21]. We could rewrite this as ∆v = ∆a/∆π where ∆v is the difference in utility at incomes y1 and y2. Then, this utility difference must clearly increase (y1 and y2 must increasingly diverge) the greater the difference in effort levels and the smaller the difference in probabilities of the better state at each effort level. Exercise 20C 1. From [C.12] of the text, we have dy* rP = =1 dx rP + rA if A is risk-neutral since then rA = 0. Thus the first best contract has y*(x) = x − k with k the constant of integration chosen to satisfy the agent’s reservation utility constraint: ∫ ( x − k) f(x, a*)dx = V + a* x1 0 x0 where a* is A’s first best optimal a. In effect, A is fully insuring P, or equivalently, A is buying the production opportunity from P at a price k. If P cannot observe a, she nevertheless still knows what k is, and so she simply gives the first best payment function y*(x) = x − k. Now in fact, as long as she receives k, P does not really care what a is chosen by A, but the interesting thing is that A will choose the first best optimal a*. To see this, note that the first term in condition [C.8] of the text becomes k ∫ f ( x, a)dx = 0 x1 x0 a since the integral in this expression is always zero. Thus the condition becomes ∫ ( x − k) f (x, a)d − 1 = 0 x1 a x0 x But this is precisely what we would get if we solved A’s maximization problem: max a ∫ ( x − k) f(x, a)dx − a x1 x0 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 245 and we know of course that x − k and a* satisfy A’s reservation constraint. Thus, the first-best solution is available under asymmetric information when A is risk-neutral. 2. We can again use [C.12] of the text to good effect. We have dy* rP = dx rP + rA Where rP = −u″/u′ and rA = −v″/v′. Evaluating the relevant derivatives from the given utility functions, we have (1 − kp )( x − y − d p ) −1 dy* = >0 dx (1 − kp )( x − y − d p ) −1 + (1 − kA )( y + d A ) −1 Thus y* increases monotonically with x given that ki ∈ (0, 1), i = P, A. For further restrictions, revert to the simpler notation of [C.12] and differentiate totally: 1 dy* d = {(rP + rA)drP − rP(drP + drA)} 2 dx [rP + rA ] = 1 rP ( drP + drA ) drP − rP + rA rP + rA = 1 dy dy drA 1 − drP + rP + rA dx dx Thus d 2y* 1 dy drP dy drA + = 1 − 2 dx rP + rA dx dx dx dx Evaluating the total derivatives drP /dx, drA/dx, we have dy drP = −(1 − kp)(x − y − dp)−2 + (1 − kp)(x − y − d p ) −2 dx dx dy = − 1 − (1 − kp)(x − y − dp)−2 < 0 dx dy drA = −(1 − kA)(y + d A ) −2 <0 dx dx Thus since dy/dx ∈ (0, 1) we have from the above expression that d2y*/dx2 < 0. Thus the optimal payment function y*(x) is a strictly increasing strictly concave function. 3. Note from the first-order conditon [C.18] in the text ∂Eu ∂ 2 EV = −é >0 ∂a ∂a 2 since on the given assumptions EV is strictly concave in a. This implies that at the second-best solution P would always want more a than is in fact supplied – her © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 246 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn expected utility at the second best solution is increasing in a. The answer to the question however follows simply from A’s reservation constraint. In the first best this is ∫ v(y* ( x)) f ( x, a*)dx = a* = V x1 0 x0 and in the second best ∫ vW( x)) f ( x, â )dx = â + V x1 0 x0 Suppose â = a*. We know that in the second best, because of the departure from the optimal risk-sharing, W(x) yields a distribution of utilities which, at probabilities f(x, a*) gives less expected utility than y*(x), and so the second reservation constraint could not be satisfied with â = a*. We must therefore have â < a* − to accommodate a lower expected utility of income A has to be given lower effort. 4. The treatment of this example is set out quite fully in Holmstrom (1979), to which the reader is referred. 5. Denote the density and distribution functions for the state of the world parameter θ by h(θ) > 0 and H(θ). Hence F(x, a) = Pr[g(a) + θ ≤ x] = Pr[θ ≤ x − g(a)] = H(x − g(a)) For first degree stochastic dominance we require Fa(x, a) = −h(x − g(a))g′(a) ≤ 0 and so a positive marginal product of effort ensures stochastic dominance. CDFC requires Faa(x, a) = h′g′g′ − hg″ ≥ 0 Hence the simple assumption of a uniform distribution of states (h′ = 0) and a declining marginal product of effort g″ < 0 guarantee CDFC. However if the marginal product of effort is constant and the distribution of states is negative exponential we have Faa > 0. Note that a triangular distribution would not satisfy CDFC without further assumptions about the rate of decline of the marginal product of effort. The MLRC is ∂( fa / f ) 1 = 2 (fax f − fa fx) ∂x f = 1 g ′h ′h h ′ h ′′ (−hh″g′ + h′h′g′) = − 2 h2 h h′ h = −g′ ∂ 2 log h ≥0 ∂θ 2 since f = Fx = h(x − g(a)), fx = h′(x − g(a)), fa = −h′(x − g(a))g′(a), fax = −h″g′. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 (20.1) Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 247 Clearly, even with the assumption that the marginal product of effort is positive but decreasing and the simplest possible form of uncertainty (additive) strong additional assumptions on the distribution of states is required to generate the plausible result that the payment schedule is increasing in the outcome (see [C.21]). For example, the assumption that the distribution is uniform implies that MLRC is satisfied but (20.1) is zero so that the payment schedule is determined solely by the risk aversion of the Principal and the Agent with incentives playing no part in influencing its slope. With a uniform distribution higher output is no more or less likely to arise from greater effort and so there is no need to include an incentive term in the reward schedule. 6. First we find an equivalent but more convenient way of representing the preferences of A and P. Define z = y − 12 a 2 as the “net income” of A and note that Ez = E(y − 12 a 2 ) = δ0 + δ1Ex + δ2Em − 12 a 2 = δ0 + δ1(ka + µ) − 12 a 2 (20.2) σ 2z = Var(y − 12 a 2 ) = Var(y) = δ 12 Var ( x) + δ 22 Var ( m) + 2δ1δ2Cov(x, m) = δ 12σ 2 + δ 22ψ 2 + 2δ1δ2σψρ (20.3) Effort affects mean net income but has no effect on the variance of net income. This simplifies the results considerably. Since z is normally distributed (it is a linear combination of normally distributed variables θ and m) and A has an exponential utility function, his expected utility can be written as a function of the mean and variance of net income z. (Those familiar with probability theory will recognise the similarities with derivation of the moment generating function for linear combinations of normally distributed random variables.) We get Ev(z) = − Ee −α z = − e E ( −α z)+ Var ( −αz ) = − e 1 2 − α Ez + 12 α 2σ 2z = − e −αV (20.4) Since (20.4) is increasing in V = Ez − 12 ασ 2z (dv/dV = αe −αV > 0), maximizing Ev(z) is equivalent to maximizing V(a; δ0, δ1, δ2) = δ0 + δ1(ka + µ) − 12 a 2 − α2 [δ 12σ 2 + δ 22ψ 2 + 2δ 1δ 2σψρ] (20.5) Since x − y = x − δ0 − δ1x − δ2m = (1 − δ1)x − δ2m − δ0 is normally distributed with E(x − y) = (1 − δ1)(ka + µ) − δ0 (20.6) Var(x − y) = (1 − δ1)2σ 2 + δ 22ψ 2 − 2(1 − δ1)δ2σψρ (20.7) the same argument as above means that maximizing P’s expected utility Eu(x − y) is equivalent to maximizing U(a; δ0, δ1, δ2) = (1 − δ1)(ka + µ) − δ0 − β2 [(1 − δ 1 ) 2 σ 2 + δ 22ψ 2 − 2(1 − δ1)δ2σψρ] (20.8) Given the incentive scheme A chooses a to maximize (20.5). The first order condition is Va = δ1k − a = 0, so that a = δ1k © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 (20.9) 248 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn The principal designs the contract to maximize her objective function (20.8) subject to the participation constraint that A will accept the contract and to the incentive compatibility constraint that A’s effort satisfies (20.9). Hence the Lagrangean is L = U(a; δ0, δ1, δ2) + λ[V(a; δ0, δ1, δ2) − V0] + γ [kδ1 − a] (20.10) where V0 is the minimum level of V which A will accept. (Alternatively we could substitute kδ1 for a to get the equivalent problem of choosing δ0, δ1, δ2 to maximize U(kδ1, δ0, δ1, δ2) subject only to the participation constraint V(kδ1, δ0, δ1, δ2) ≥ V 0.) The first order conditions are (remembering that Va = 0 from the first order condition on A’s choice of a) Ua + λVa − γ = Ua − γ = (1 − δ1)k − γ = 0 (20.11) Uδ 0 + λVδ 0 = −1 + λ = 0 (20.12) Uδ 1 + λVδ 1 + γ k = −(ka + µ) + β (1 − δ1)σ 2 − βδ2σψρ + λ[(ka + µ) − αδ1σ 2 − αδ2σψρ] + γ k = 0 (20.13) Uδ 2 + λVδ 2 = −βδ2ψ 2 + β (1 − δ1)σψρ + λ[−αδ2ψ 2 − αδ1σψρ] = 0 (20.14) plus the constraints. Use (20.11) and (20.12) to substitute (1 − δ1)k for γ and 1 for λ in (20.13) and (20.14). Now solve (20.14) for δ2 = σρ[β (1 − δ 1 ) − αδ 1 ] ψ (α + β ) (20.15) and substitute for δ2 in (20.13) and solve for δ1. We get δ1 = k 2 + σ 2 β (1 − ρ 2 ) k 2 + σ 2 (α + β )(1 − ρ 2 ) (20.16) δ2 = −σρα k 2 ψ (α + β )[k 2 + σ 2 (α + β )(1 − ρ 2 )] (20.17) (δ0 is determined by substituting for δ1, δ2 in the participation constraint.) The intuition behind these results can be brought out by examining the effects of varying the parameters (differentiate (20.16) and (20.17) with respect to the parameters). Alternatively consider some special cases. First best: If P can observe a, (20.9) is no longer a constraint and γ ≡ 0. The first order condition on a will be Ua + λVa = (1 − δ1)k + δ1k − a = 0. P will direct A to set a = k where the marginal cost of effort to A is equal to the value of the marginal product of effort. With γ = 0 (20.13) and (20.14) together imply that δ2 = 0 and δ1 = β /(α + β). Incentives and risk sharing can be separated because P can control a directly and use the contract to share risks efficiently. Pure risk sharing: k = 0. Since A’s effort does not affect output, the contract is purely for risk sharing and δ1 = β /(α + β), δ2 = 0. Note (i) that since linking A’s reward to the © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 249 message increases the variances of P and A’s incomes, risk is minimised by setting δ2 = 0; if P is risk neutral she cares only about her mean income (20.6) which in the current setting is equivalent to assuming that her preferences are represented by (20.8) with β = 0. She will then optimally bear all the risk. Compare the first best contract. Perfectly informative message: ρ = 1. The message is perfectly correlated with the state: m = t0 + t1θ. Hence Em = t0 + t1µ = 0, Var(m) = ψ 2 = t12σ 2 and t0 = −ψµ/σ, t1 = ψ/σ, so m = ψ(θ − µ)/σ. Observing the message is equivalent to observing the state, and hence since output is also observed, to observing the agent’s effort a = (xt1 − m − t0)/t1k. P can therefore direct A to supply the first best effort a = k. The reward schedule is y = δ0 + x − σα α m = δ 0 + ka + θ − (θ − µ ) ψ (α + β ) (α + β ) = δ0 + ka + µα + θβ α +β Risk neutral agent: α = 0. Since A is risk neutral setting δ1 = 1, δ2 = 0 leads to optimal incentives for effort and there is no need to worry about efficient risk sharing since the risk neutral party (A) bears all the risk. In effect A buys the firm from P who receives a fixed payment −δ0. 7. Suppose that the contract reduces the agent’s income by δ when there is low profit and the principal receives the signal that the agent’s effort was low. The agent now has three income levels: with probability πi profit is high and he gets y1; with probability (1 − πi)(1 − ri) profit is low but the signal indicates high effort and he gets y2; with probability (1 − πi)ri profit is low and the signal indicates low effort so that he is punished and gets y2 − δ. We can show that the optimal contract will make the agent’s reward depend on profit and the signal by showing that the owner’s expected income is increased by increasing δ from zero and adjusting the other terms of the contract y1, y2 to keep the binding participation and incentive compatibility constraints satisfied. We do this by using the Envelope Theorem (Appendix J). For a given δ the optimised value of the Lagrangean for the principal’s problem is, Ö = πh(P1 − W1) + (1 − πh)(P2 − W2 + rhδ ) + λ{πhv(W1) + (1 − πh)[(1 − rh)v(W2) + rhv(W2 − δ )] − Eh − E0} + µ{πhv(W1) + (1 − πh)[(1 − rh)v(W2) + rhv(W2 − δ )] − Eh − πᐉv(W1) + (1 − πᐉ)[(1 − rᐉ)v(W2) + rᐉv(W2) − δ )] − Eᐉ} where W1 and W2 are the optimal payments to the agent. Using the Envelope Theorem the marginal value of an increase in δ is ∂Ö = (1 − πh)rh − λ(1 − πh)rhv′(W2 − δ) ∂δ δ =0 − µ(1 − πh)rhv′(W2 − δ ) + µ(1 − πᐉ)rᐉv′(W2 − δ ) = (1 − πh)rh − v′(W2)[(λ + µ)(1 − πh)rh − µ(1 − πᐉ)rᐉ] © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 (20.18) 250 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Using the first order condition on W2 (rearrange [20B.4]) we can substitute 1 − πh = v′(W2)[(λ + µ)(1 − πh)rh − µ(1 − πᐉ)] for (1 − πh) in the first term in (20.18) to get ∂Ö = v′(W2){[(λ + µ)(1− πh)rh − µ(1 − πᐉ)]rh ∂δ δ =0 − [(λ + µ)(1 − πh)rh − µ(1 − πᐉ)rᐉ]} = v′(W2)(rᐉ − rh)(1 − πᐉ)µ > 0 (remember that µ > 0 because the incentive compatibility constraint binds and that rᐉ > rh because the signal is more likely to correctly indicate low effort if low effort was supplied). We see that the ability to imperfectly monitor effort is more valuable to the principal as: (a) the signal is better able to discriminate between low and high effort (rᐉ − rh increases); (b) the likelihood of low profit given low effort (1 − πᐉ) increases; (c) the value of relaxing the incentive compatiblility constraint increases and (d) the marginal utility of income increases. The intuition behind (d) is that if marginal utility of income is greater then the “cost” of punishment is greater for the agent and the punishment is more effective in inducing high effort. Exercise 20D 1. Given dyi ψ x ( x,θ i ) = dxi v ′( yi ) partially differentiating with respect to θi gives ∂ dyi v ′ψ xθ ψ xθ = = ∂θ i dxi ( v ′)2 v′ From [D.7] we have ψxθ < 0. Thus we have condition [D.13] of the text. What it means is that if we fix a point (xi, yi), and increase θi, then the slope of the indifference curve decreases. Intuitively, a given increase in output requires a smaller income increase as the agent’s productivity increases, because he can achieve the output increase with a smaller effort increase. 2. If A is risk-neutral his utility function can be written as v = yi − ai. Then, when we substitute ai = ψ(xi, θi) we obtain the quasi-linear form: v = yi − ψ(xi, θi) It follows that the slope of the indifference curve dyi 1 =ψ x = dxi xa ( a , θ i ) © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 251 which is independent of yi. Thus in this case his indifference curves are vertical displacements of each other. If he is risk-averse then from [D.12] of the text we have dyi ψ x ( x,θ i ) = dxi v ′( yi ) and ∂ dyi ψ x v ′′ >0 =− ∂yi dxi v′ since ψx > 0, v′ > 0 and v″ < 0. Thus for fixed xi as yi increases the slopes of successive indifference curves increase. 3. The model of adverse selection is essentially identical to the model of second-degree price discrimination in section 9C and the answers to questions (i) and (ii) are given therefore on pages 200–204 of the text. Then we have: (iii) If the agent is risk-neutral the slopes of indifference curves for a given type are equal along a vertical line in (xi, yi)-space. Consequently, the ‘no distortion at the top’ result, that x2* and V2 satisfy the same tangency condition, means that the slopes of the indifference curves have to be the same, and so in the risk-neutral case we must have x2* = V2. (iv) To show that >2 > é2 use condition [D.19] of the text to obtain >2 − é2 = π v ′( W1 ) >0 We can give these multipliers their ‘shadow price’ interpretation: the loss of expected utility to the principal from a small tightening of the low productivity type’s reservation utility constraint is greater than the loss of utility to P from a small increase in the lower type’s utility at his optimal contract (V1, W1). 4. As the discussion surrounding Fig. 20.12 of the text makes clear, the higher is π the smaller the distortion in the type 1 contract, and so in Fig. 20.12 the higher the Î2 indifference curve must be to maintain self-selection, and so the higher must be W2. If the indifference curves rise very sharply then we could find that the W2 required to achieve self-selection exceeds the x2 produced. Thus the constraints yi ≤ xi should be imposed. If the constraint was binding for i = 2, that would mean that there is a larger distortion away from first best in the type 1 contract as well as a distortion from the first best condition in the solution for x2. 5. The analysis is essentially as in the two-agent case, with distortions in the types 1 and 2 contracts but with the ‘no distortion at the top’ result holding. However, only the lowest-productivity type can be held to his reservation utility. We now also have the possibility that types 1 and 2 may be offered the same contract. 6. The Lagrangean for the problem of maximizing the expected value of the welfare function subject to the participation and incentive compatibility constraints is © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 252 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn L = ∑πi[B(xi) − θixi − kTi] + ∑λi[(p(xi) −θi)xi + Ti] + µ1[(p(x1) − θ1)x1 + T1 − (p(x2) − θ1)x2 − T2] + µ2[(p(x2) − θ2)x2 + T2 − (p(x1) − θ2)x1 − T1] where pi = p(xi) is the inverse demand function of consumers generated by p = B′(xi). The first order conditions for a non-corner solution are LT = −πik+ λi + µi − µj = 0 (20.19) Lx = (πi + λi + µi − µj)(pi − θi) + (λi + µi − µj)p′(xi)xi − µ2(θi − θj) = 0 (20.20) i i for i = 1, 2; i ≠ j, plus complementary slackness conditions on the participation and incentive compatibility constraints. Notice that the participation constraint on the low cost firm never binds: 0 ≤ (p1 − θ1)x1 + T1 < (p1 − θ2)x1 + T1 ≤ (p2 − θ2)x2 + T2 where the first inequality follows from the participation constraint on firm 1, the second from θ2 < θ1 and the third from the incentive compatibility constraint on firm 2. Hence λ2 = 0. Suppose first that the transfers have no social cost (k = 0). In this case the first best allocation in which both types of firms price at marginal cost pi = θi is achievable. If the regulator also sets T1 = 0 and T2 = (θ1 − θ2)x1 then firm 1 breaks even and firm 2 is just indifferent between producing x1 at price p1 = θ1 and getting T1 = 0 and producing x2 at price p2 = θ2 and getting T2. In fact any transfers which satisfy T2 − T1 ≥ (θ1 − θ2)x1 will satisfy all the constraints. Because there are no costs to the transfers the regulator can use them to satisfy the incentive compatibility constraints without the need to adjust prices away from their first best levels. When transfers have a social cost the regulator will wish to balance the cost of the distortions introduced by prices diverging from marginal cost against the cost of the transfers. Using the conditions on the Ti to substitute πik for λi + µi − µj, remembering from the discussion in the text that the incentive compatibility constraint on the type 1 firm will not bind, and rearranging the conditions on the outputs gives p1 − θ 1 = µ 2 (θ 1 − θ 2 ) − π 1 kp′( x1 ) x1 >0 (1 + k)π 1 p2 − θ 2 = −π 2 kp′( x2 ) x2 >0 (1 + k)π 2 Thus we see that because transfers are costly the price set for the low cost firm exceeds marginal cost. The low cost firm is induced to choose its output and transfer pair by being offered a more profitable output and a smaller transfer than in the first best solution achievable when transfers are costless. 7. Consider condition [D.53] in the text and note that if we were to let πh get arbitrarily small, there is nothing to stop the right hand side becoming negative. But this would then present a problem, because the derivative on the left hand side is supposed always © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 253 to be positive. The problem arises because we have implicitly assumed that we always obtain an interior solution with sH > 0. It is possible however that we could have a corner solution in which sH = 0. We should in fact formulate the problem with the explicit constraint sH ≥ 0. We will now show that doing this resolves the mathematical difficulty we just pointed out, and also has an interesting intuitive explanation. Thus if we add to the problem defined in [D.46], [D.47] and [D.48] the condition sH ≥ 0, we have to replace [D.50] with the Kuhn-Tucker condition −λπH + γ − µ ≤ 0 sH ≥ 0 sH(−λπH + γ − µ) = 0 The case examined in the text assumes sH > 0, so γ = µ + λπH, and then substituting into [D.52] and rearranging gives [D.53]. Suppose however we have sH = 0 at the optimum. Then γ ≤ µ +λπH and using this in [D.52] gives instead of [D.53] the condition ψ ′(θH – àH) ≥ 1 − λ πL [ψ ′(θ H − àH ) − ψ ′(θ L − àH )] (1 + λ ) π H This fixes up the mathematics, since the right hand side can be negative without violating the condition. For the economic intuition, refer again to Fig. 20.17 in the text. As we slide rightward along the H type’s indifference curve away from point H* we are trading off two effects. On the one hand we are incurring a cost from distorting the equilibrium of the H type, causing it to supply less effort and incur higher costs, but at the same time we are receiving a benefit by reducing the rent that has to be paid to the L type. We stop at the optimum when the marginal cost of the first is just equal to the marginal benefit of the second. However, suppose πH is very small. Then the expected marginal cost of the distortion is small relative to the expected marginal benefit of the rent reduction, and so it could pay to go on increasing the distortion until we can go no further, i.e. until sH = 0. This then implies from [D.47] that aH = ψ(aH) = 0, so the H type supplies no cost reducing effort. This could imply that its costs are so high as to exceed u, so that it would not be required to produce. This would imply offering the H type a contract that induces it not to produce at all. The regulator knows then that the only firm in the market would be the L type, and so she can offer it the first best contract, leaving it with a zero rent. 8. Let (åL, åH, àL, àH) be the optimal solution to the single period problem as found on page 596 of the text. The proposition is that offering these in both periods is optimal, given that the regulator can commit to doing this in the second period, which implies ignoring the information on the firm’s type she has gained in the first period. The proof is by contradiction. We suppose that there are alternative menus ( sL′ 1 , sH′ 1 , c L′ 1 , c H′ 1 ) in period 1 and ( sL′ 2 , sH′ 2 , cL′ 2 , cH′ 2 ) in period 2 that yield a better solution to the two-period problem. We then show that in the single period problem, a mixed strategy involving these two menus with appropriately chosen probabilities must in that case yield a better solution for the regulator than (åL, åH, àL, àH). This contradicts the optimality of the latter. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 254 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Thus if ( sL′ 1 , sH′ 1 , c L′ 1 , c H′ 1 ) and ( sL′ 2 , sH′ 2 , c L′ 2 , c H′ 2 ) are optimal in the two-period problem they must satisfy the constraints for that problem. Again it suffices to consider only the participation constraint of the high cost type and the incentive compatibility constraint of the low cost type. In the two period case these are respectively sH′ 1 − ψ (θ H − c H′ 1 ) + δ [sH′ 2 − ψ (θ H − c H′ 2 )] ≥ 0 i.e. the present value of profit over the two periods must be non-negative, with δ the discount factor, and sL′ 1 − ψ (θ L − c L′ 1 ) + δ [sL′ 2 − ψ (θ L − c L′ 2 )] ≥ sH′ 1 − ψ (θ L − c H′ 1 ) + δ [sH′ 2 − ψ (θ L − c H′ 2 )] i.e. it cannot pay the low cost firm to claim to be high cost. Next, note that these inequalities continue to hold if we divide through each by 1 + δ. But this then implies that in the single period problem, choosing ( sL′ 1 , sH′ 1 , c L′ 1 , c H′ 1 ) with probability 1/(1 + δ ) and ( sL′ 2 , sH′ 2 , c L′ 2 , c H′ 2 ) with probability δ /(1 + δ ) must be feasible since it satisfies these constraints in that problem. Moreover, if in the two-period problem (1 + δ ) u − ∑ π [λs′ − (1 + λ )c ′ − ψ (θ − c ′ )] +δ ∑ π [λs′ − (1 + λ )c ′ − ψ (θ − c ′ )] i i1 i1 i i1 i2 i i= L , H i2 i i2 i= L , H > (1 + δ ){u − ∑ π [λå − (1 + λ )à − ψ (θ − à )]} i i i i i i= L , H then offering ( sL′ 1 , sH′ 1 , c L′ 1 , c H′ 1 ) and ( sL′ 2 , sH′ 2 , c L′ 2 , c H′ 2 ) with probabilities 1/(1 + δ ) and δ /(1 + δ ) respectively must yield higher expected utility to the regulator than offering (åL, åH, àL, àH) for certain (just divide through by 1 + δ ). This gives the contradiction. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 255 Chapter 21 General Equilibrium under Uncertainty and Incomplete Markets Exercise 21B 1. Given that the individuals are risk averse and therefore have convex-to-the-origin indifference curves, a contract curve outside the 45° line can only arise if (a) the individuals have different probability beliefs, or (b) if at least one of them has state dependent marginal utility. As Fig. 21B.1 shows, if the individuals have identical probability beliefs and state independent marginal utility their indifference curves have slope −π1/π2 at their 45° lines. Hence they can only be tangent between the 45° lines. They both share in any social risk in that both have incomes which are positively correlated with total income. 2. (a) and (b). When probability beliefs are identical the contract curve is defined by va′ 1 ( ya 1 ) vb′1 ( y1 − ya 1 ) = va′ 2 ( ya 2 ) vb′2 ( y2 − ya 2 ) (21.1) Now consider the different types of LRT (text page 609). (i) With the quadratic type (21.1) is ρ a − ya 1 ρ b − y1 + ya 1 = ρ a − ya 2 ρ b − y2 + ya 2 which solves for the equation of the contract curve as ya 2 = ρ a ( y2 − y1 ) ρ a + ρ b − y2 + ya 1 ρ a + ρ b − y1 ρ a + ρ b − y1 Note that for economically sensible results we assume that neither individual would be satiated if given the total income ys available in any state: ρi > ys, i = a, b; s = 1, 2. The contract curve is an upward sloping straight line. (ii) With the exponential form (21.1) is exp( − ya 1 / ρ a ) exp[−( y1 − ya 1 )/ ρ b ] = exp( − ya 2 / ρ a ) exp[− y2 − ya 2 )/ ρ b ] or exp[(ya1 − ya2)/ρa] = exp[−(y1 − ya1 − y2 + ya2)/ρb] © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 255 256 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 21B.1 Taking logs and rearranging gives ya 2 = ρ a ( y2 − y1 ) + ya 1 ρa + ρb The contract curve is parallel to and between the 45° lines. (iii) For the logarithmic type (21.1) is ρ a + ya 2 ρ b + y2 − ya 2 = ρ a + ya 1 ρ b + y1 − ya 1 so that ya 2 = ρ a ( y2 − y1 ) ρ a + ρ b + y2 + y ρ a − ρ b − y1 ρ a + ρ b + y1 a 1 When ρa = ρb = 0, so that u = log yis, the contract curve is the diagonal of the Edgeworth Box. (iv) Finally, with the power form (21.1) is ρ a + τ a ya 1 ρ a + τ a ya 2 −1/τ a ρ + τ b ( y1 − ya 1 ) = b ρ b + τ b ( y2 − ya 2 ) −1/τ b This yields ya2 as a linear function of ya1 only if τa = τb = τ, so that we can raise both sides to the power −τ and then solve for ya 2 = ρ a ( y2 − y1 ) ρ a + ρ b + τ y2 + y ρ a + ρ b + τ y1 ρ a + ρ b + τ y1 a 1 1. (c) With one risk averse individual (say individual b) and identical probability beliefs, the contract curve is defined by va′ 1 ( ya 1 ) =1 ua′ 2 ( ya 2 ) (since vbs′ is a positive constant). Hence if the marginal utility of income is state independent, the contract curve is the 45° line for individual a where ya1 = ya2. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 257 Supplementary questions (i) Draw the contract curves for the various cases in parts (a) and (b) of the question. What are the effects of increases in: the difference between the total state contingent incomes; ρa? (ii) What does the contract curve look like in part (c) if a has state independent marginal utility or different probability beliefs to b? 3. (a) Write the first order condition [B.7] as an implicit equation to get dyas π bs vbs′ <0 = π as vas′′ + λπ bs vbs′′ dλ An increase in the distributional weight on b reduces a’s income in all states. 3. (b) Similarly dyas − vas ′ = >0 dπ as π as vas ′′ + λπ bs vbs′′ 4. Since v ′′ d log v ′ = = − ( ρ + τ y ) −1 v′ dy integrating, when τ ≠ 0, gives log v′ = K − τ −1log(ρ + τ y) = log[k1(ρ + τ y)−1/τ] (21.2) where K = log k1. Hence v′ = k1(ρ + τ y)−1/τ (21.3) Now if τ = 1 we have v′ = k1(ρ + y)−1 and integration gives v = k0 + k1 log(ρ + y) Since utility functions representing preferences satisfying the axioms of expected utility theory are unique up to linear transformations we can choose k0 = 0, k1 = 1 to yield the logarithmic type of LRT. If τ ≠ −1, τ ≠ 0 integrating (21.3) gives v = k0 + k1 1 (ρ + τ y)(τ−1)/τ τ −1 which is identical to the power form after setting k0 = 0, k1 = 1. With τ = −1 the power form becomes 1 v = − (ρ − y)2 2 and multiplying by 2 gives the quadratic form on text page 609. Finally, if τ = 0 we have d log v ′ 1 =− dy ρ © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 258 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn so that log v′ = K − y/ρ and v′ = k1 exp(−y/ρ) where K = log k1. Hence v = k0 − k1 exp(−y/ρ), and k0 = 0, k1 = 1 gives the exponential form. Since we have considered all possible values of τ and placed no restrictions on ρ, the four types derived above are the only possible utility functions with LRT. 5. (a) With exponential utility functions the sharing rule [B.7] is given by πas exp(−yas/ρa) = λπbs exp[−(ys − yas)/ρb] which implies log π as − yas ρa = log λπ bs − ys − yas ρb Collecting terms in yas and dividing through by ρ a−1 + ρ b−1 gives the result. 5. (b) With logarithmic utility functions, [B.7] is π as ρ a + yas = λπ bs ρ b + ys − yas which implies ρb + ys − yas = >(ρa + yas) which rearranges to give the result. 6. Differentiate the sharing rule in question 5(a) with respect to ωa ω dyas ys 1 1 log a + =− − 2 (ω a + ω b ) dω a λω b (ω a + ω b )ω a (ω a + ω b )2 = 1 1 − yas + ωa + ωb ωa which is positive if ωayas < 1 where ωayas is the coefficient of relative risk aversion. Note that an increase in ωa reduces a’s marginal share of the income in state s: the variability of yas is reduced. 7. (a) Yes, numerous studies show that most individuals are very bad at assessing probabilities. 7. (b) When the individuals have the same probability beliefs and marginal utility is state independent, the sharing rules do not depend on the probability beliefs. Hence the allocation in each state is the same whether beliefs are correct or not. Only if it is possible to transfer total income between states will it matter that the individuals’ unanimous beliefs are incorrect. 7. (c) From question 3(b) we know that an increase in πas will increase yas. Thus compared with the allocation in which individuals have the same correct beliefs, the allocation with a having incorrect beliefs will have yas larger (and therefore ybs smaller) when a incorrectly believes πas to be larger than it actually is. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 259 8. (a) and (b). The analysis here is very similar to that of sections 2E and 11B in which the individual financed consumption by selling endowments. Fig. 11.1 shows the effect (with suitable relabelling) of changing the relative price of state contingent incomes and of increasing the endowment of state 1 income. 8. (c) We can write the consumer’s budget constraint as wi − ∑s ps yis ≥ 0 where wi = ∑s ps Wis is wealth or the market value of endowed state contingent incomes. The utility maximization problem now has the same mathematical form as that of chapter 2, although the interpretation of the choice variables and the budget constraint differs. The utility maximizing demands depend on prices and wealth: Dis(p, wi). The demand for yis, s = 1, . . . , S will increase with w because of the additive separability of preferences over state contingent incomes. The first order conditions imply π i1 vi′1 ( yi1 ) p1 = ... = π iS viS′ ( yiS ) pS Since marginal utility is positive an increase in wi must be used to buy more of at least one of the state contingent incomes, say yi1. But since vis′′ < 0 the increase in yi1 reduces the ratio π i1 vi′1 / p1 and, if the first order conditions are to continue to hold, all the other ratios π is vis′ / ps must also be reduced, which requires that the other yis must increase. Hence all state contingent incomes are normal goods and if an increase in ps makes the individual worse off the wealth effect will reinforce the substitution effect. From Roy’s Identity the effect of an increase in ps on expected utility is θi(Dis − Wis). Thus the statement in the question is in fact correct only for states of the world for which the individual has a positive net demand. 9. (a) If a has no information on what state of the world has occurred his income and utility functions must be the same in all states, otherwise he can infer the state from yas or vas. In the Edgeworth Box in Fig. 21B.2 the initial allocation must be on a’s 45° line and the slope of his indifference curves at the 45° line is −πa1/πa2. 9. (b) Suppose that the individuals wrote a contract which purports to shift them from the initial endowment at c0 to the allocation at c1. The contract requires a to give up income if state 2 occurs in exchange for additional income if state 1 occurs. If b is selfish and rational she will always tell a that state 2 has occurred, irrespective of the true state. Hence the contract will actually generate the allocation c2. Similarly a contract which purports to move them to c3 will actually move them to c4. 9. (c) The set of allocations which are feasible via contracts between the parties is the rectangular line through c4c0c2. The only point on this curve which satisfies the individual rationality constraints that it leaves both individuals no worse off than at the no contract point is the original endowment point c0. Thus the core is the single allocation c0. 10. See Fig. 21B.3. Without the information device the individual has a budget line through his endowment point W with slope −p1/p2 and initial wealth w = ∑spsWs. His © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 260 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 21B.2 Fig. 21B.3 optimal state contingent consumption plan is y*. His maximized expected utility is V(p, W) = ∑ vs ( ys* ). When he acquires the information device he knows what the state will be before trading starts on the markets in state contingent claims. On acquiring the correct information that state s will occur he spends his entire wealth to buy claims to y s* * = w/ps of income in state s and gets utility of vs(w/ps). Hence his vector of state contingent consumption is (w/p1, . . . , w/pS) at y**. His expected utility is now ∑sπsvs(w/ps) and he is on the indifference curve I** through y**. The maximum he would be willing to pay for such a device (the value of the information) is δ defined by ∑sπsvs(w/ps − δ ) = ∑ vs ( ys* ). In terms of the figure, δ is measured by the vertical or horizontal distance from y** on I** to a on I*. If there is public information before the markets for state contingent claims open that state s will occur, the price of claims to state s income will be 1 and the price to claims in income in all other states will be zero. No trade will take place on the markets since no one will be willing to buy claims to states which will not occur. All individuals will be forced to consume their endowments if there is public information about the state before the markets open. Thus no individual is better off, © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 261 and some will be worse off, compared with a situation in which there is no information device. In Fig. 21B.3 the public information shifts the individual from I* to Î. Exercise 21C 1. Refer to text page 103 and note that a function which is homogeneous of degree k has partial derivatives which are homogeneous of degree k − 1. Hence, although doubling all prices and income does not alter utility, it halves the gain in utility from an extra £1. Since marginal utility of income is homogeneous of degree −1 ∑ vyp pi + vyyy = −vy i (dropping the s subscript to save notation). This equation shows that assumptions about the marginal utility of income can have surprisingly strong implications about the pattern of consumption. For example, if we assume that the marginal utility of income is constant with respect to prices (vyp = 0, i = 1, . . . , n) we are also assuming that i − vyy y yy =1 so that there is constant relative aversion to income risk, of unity. The indirect utility function must have the form v(p, y) = α (p) + log y. But this implies that preferences are homothetic and that the income elasticity of demand for all goods is unity. (See text pages 68–70 and note that taking the log of [D.13] there gives the above form with α (p) = −log a(p)). 2. If u(xs) is concave then v(ps, ys) is concave in ys (text page 622). Denoting ∑πsCVs by ä we can write v( ps2 , ys − CVs) = v( ps2 , ys − ä) + vy ( ps2 , y1 − ä)(ä − CVs) + vyy ( ps2 , 9s )( ä − CVs )2 /2 for some 9s ∈ (ys − ä, ys − CVs). Hence Ev( ps2 , ys − CVs) − Ev( ps2 , ys − ä) = Evy ( ps2 , ys − ä)(ä − CVs) + Evyy ( ps2 , 9s)(ä − CVs)2/2 = Cov(vy ( ps2 , ys − ä), ä − CVs) + Evyy ( ps2 , 9s)(ä − CVs)2/2 (21.4) Although we have assumed that the marginal utility of income does not vary directly with the state of the world this is not sufficient for the Cov term to be zero. The Cov term will be zero if we also assume that marginal utility of income is not affected by the prices which vary across states of the world. If we make these assumptions (21.4) will be negative (since vyy < 0) and the expected ex post compensating variation is less than the ex ante compensating variation (see [C.45]). 3. The demand for good i is Di(p, y) = − v p ( p, y)/vy(p, y) so that o ∂Di 1 [v p y vy − v p vyy ] =− ∂y ( vy )2 i i © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 262 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Thus vyy = 0 is neither necessary nor sufficient for demand for good i to be unaffected by income. 4. Since good 1 is chosen before the state of the world is known xs1 = x1, s = 1, . . . , S. In state s the other goods are chosen to maximize u(x1, xs2, . . . , xsn) subject to ∑ 2n psi xsi ≤ ys − ps1x1. The Lagrangean for the state s problem is Ls = u(x1, xs2, . . . , xsn) + λs[ys − ps1x1 − n ∑p x ] si si (21.5) 2 Her demand for xsi, i = 2, . . . , n is Dsi(ps2, . . . , psn, ys − ps1 − x1) and her state s indirect utility function is vs = v(x1, ps2, . . . , psn, ys − ps1 − x1). Before the state of the world is known she chooses x1 to maximize the expected value of the indirect utility function, so that her choice of x1 satisfies Evs1(x1, ps2, . . . , psn, ys − ps1 − x1) − Evsy(x1, ps2, . . . , psn, ys − ps1 − x1)ps1 = Eu1(x1, xs2, . . . , xsn) − Eλs ps1 = 0 where we have used the envelope function on the Lagrangeans (21.5). Note that the demand for good 1 (D1) depends on the anticipated incomes and prices of all the goods in all states. The maximized expected indirect utility is V = Evs(D1, ps2, . . . , psn, y2 − ps1 − x1). The consumer is made better or worse off by a mean preserving contraction in the price of good 1 if Evs is increased or decreased. The derivative of vs with respect to ps1 is, using the envelope theorem on (21.5), vsp = s1 ∂Ls = −λsx1 = −vsyx1 ∂ps1 Partially differentiating again with respect to ps1 vsp p = s1 s1 − ∂( vsy x1 ) ∂ps1 = vsyy x12 Thus if she is averse to income risks vsyy < 0 her state s indirect utility function is concave in ps1 and hence its expected value is increased by a mean preserving contraction in the distribution of ps1. (See section 17F.) Exercise 21D 1. The Pareto efficiency conditions are derived by maximizing the expected utility of, say, the producer subject to (i) the consumer getting at least a specified level of expected utility (Ec ); (ii) the production function constraints: xsc ≤ fs(z), s = 1, . . . , S and (iii) the constraints on the availability of the composite commodity: ys + ysc ≤ Ws + Wsc ≡ Ws, s = 1, . . . , S. Since both individuals have positive marginal utility and the marginal product fs′ is also positive, all the constraints bind and we can substitute fs(z) for xsc and Ws − ys for ysc to write the Lagrangean as L = Evs(ys, z) + λ[Eusc ( Ws − ys, fs(z)) − Ec )] © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 263 The first order conditions are c fs′( z) = 0 Lz = Evsz + λEusx c = 0, Ly = πsvsy − λπ s usy (21.6) s = 1, . . . , S s (21.7) plus the expected utility constraint on the consumer. Rearranging (21.7) gives π s vsy π s usyc = π l vly π l ulcy (21.8) which is the usual condition for efficient risk bearing that marginal rates of substitution c , we across states are equalized for different individuals. Since, from (21.7), vsy = λusy c c can divide each vsz term in (21.6) by vsy and each usx term by λusy to write the condition for efficient production as uc v E sx fs′ = E sz c usy vsy The left hand side is the expected marginal value product of the input in terms of income and the left hand side is its expected marginal cost in terms of income. 1. (a) With a market in state contingent income claims the producer can buy (qs > 0) or sell (qs < 0) claims to income in state s at price psy, subject to the budget constraint that the total value of sales and purchases must be non-positive: ∑p q ≤0 sy (21.9) s s Given her trades in the state contingent income markets and her correct expectations about the spot price of her output, she correctly anticipates that her state s income will be ys = ps fs(z) + qs + Ws Her Lagrangean for her choice of input and state contingent income trades is L = Evs(ps fs(z) + qs + Ws) − µ ∑p q sy s s with first order conditions Lz = Evsz + Evsy ps fs′( z) = 0 Lq = πsvsy − µpsy = 0, s s = 1, . . . , S (21.10) (21.11) plus the budget constraint. Her optimal input choice is z*(W, p, π, py) and her net or market demand for state s income is Qs(W, p, π, py). The consumer also buys ( qsc > 0) or sells ( qsc < 0) claims to state contingent income at prices psy, subject to a budget constraint: ∑ s psy qsc ≤ 0, yielding the state s budget constraint © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 264 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn y sc + ps x sc = Wsc + qsc His demand for xsc = Ds ( ps , Wsc + qsc ) maximizes his state s direct utility usc ( ysc , xsc ) with the first order condition c c usx − usy ps = 0 (21.12) to give state s indirect utility vsc ( ps , Wsc + qsc ) = usc ( Wsc + qsc − ps Ds , Ds ) Before the state is revealed he chooses his state contingent income trades and the Lagrangean for this problem is Lc = Evsc ( ps , Wsc + qsc ) − µ c ∑p q c sy s s and the first order conditions are c c Lcq = π s vsy − µ c psy = π s usy − µ c psy = 0, s = 1, . . . , S c s (21.13) (Note that the assumption of rational expectations means that the correct spot prices are used in the indirect utility functions when the state contingent income trades are chosen before the state is revealed.) The consumer’s net demand function for state s contingent income is Qsc (Wc, p, π, py). The economy is in equilibrium when the markets for state contingent incomes clear: Qs(W, p, π, py) + Qsc ( W c , p, π, py) = 0, s = 1, . . . , S and the spot markets for the producer’s output clear: fs(z*) − Ds(ps, Wsc + Qsc ) = 0, s = 1, . . . , S Since all agents face the same prices for state contingent income trades, (21.11) and (21.13) imply πsvsy/µ = psy = π s vsyc / µ c = π s usyc / µ c and dividing this through by the analogous condition for another state ᐉ shows that the conditions for Pareto efficient risk bearing (21.8) are satisfied. From (21.11) we can write (21.10) as Evsz + ∑ π v p f ′ = Ev + µ ∑ ρ p f ′ s sy s s sz sy s s s (21.14) s From (21.12) and (21.13) we have ps = c c c usx usx usx π = = c c usy vsy µ c psy s and substituting in (21.14) gives Evsz + ( µ / µ c ) ∑π u f ′ = 0 s c sx s s Since for some choice of Ec in the Pareto efficiency problem we will have λ = µ/µ c, we see that there is efficient production. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 265 1. (b) With markets for the state contingent delivery of the producer’s output both parties can contract at prices psx for delivery of one unit of x if and only if state s occurs. The producer can sell (buy) (ζs > (<)0 claims at prices psx to get a certain wealth from production of ∑s psxζs. Her wealth or budget constraint for trading in state contingent income claims is now ∑p ζ −∑p q ≥0 sx s s sy sy s and her state s income is ys = Ws + qs + ps[fs(z) − ζs] + B The following arbitrage condition must hold: psy ps = psx, s = 1, . . . , S in equilibrium. Suppose it did not for some s and, in particular, that psy ps > psx. If the producer reduced her sales of output on the state contingent commodity market by one unit her wealth would fall by psx and her state s income increase by ps. If she simultaneously sold claims to ps of state s income on the state contingent income market her state s income would fall by ps and her wealth would increase by psy ps. The net effect of these transactions would be to leave her state s income unchanged but to increase her wealth by psy ps − psx > 0. Analogous arguments apply when psy ps < psx. The arbitrage condition means that transactions in state contingent income claims and state contingent commodities are equivalent means of transferring income across states via market exchanges. Thus define the net transfer to state s via market exchanges as δs ≡ qs − psζs = qs − psxζs/psy so that we could write state s income as ys = Ws + psfs + δs + B and the budget constraint as ∑ p ζ − ∑ p q = −∑ δ ≥ 0 sx s sy s sy s s s Since what matters is the net transfer we could cast the analysis in terms of choice of the δs. Equivalently we can set arbitrary values for the ζs (or the qs) and let the producer choose the qs (or the ζs). It is simplest to assume that the producer always sets ζs = fs(z) so that state s income is ys = Ws + qs + B and the budget constraint is ∑ p f ( z) − ∑ p q ≥ 0 sx s sy s sy s With this formulation the Lagrangean for the producer’s problem is ∑ p f ( z) − ∑ p q ] L = Evs(Ws + qs + B, z) + µ[ sx s s © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 sy s sy 266 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn The first order conditions are Lz = Evsz + µ ∑ psx f s′ = 0 Lq = πsvsy − µpsy = 0, (21.15) s = 1, . . . , S s (21.16) plus the budget constraint. The consumer chooses the xsc and the qsc via contracts on the markets for the state contingent commodity and state contingent income. We assume that the consumer buys all her requirements of x on the state contingent commodity markets and does not enter the spot market for the commodity when the state is revealed. (It is easy to show that the arbitrage condition implies that the consumer is indifferent as to the mix of spot and state contingent commodity market transactions which yield a given consumption level xsc .) In this economy the spot markets do not operate because the producer sells all her output on the contingent commodity markets and the consumer buys all his requirements on the contingent commodity markets. The consumer’s budget constraint is ∑p q +∑p x ≤0 sy c s sx s c s s and his Lagrangean is ∑p q +∑p x ] Lc = Eusc ( Wsc + qsc , xsc ) − µ c [ sy c s s sx c s s The first order conditions are c Lcq = π s usy − µ c psy = 0, s = 1, . . . , S (21.17) c Lcx = π s usx − µ c psx = 0, s = 1, . . . , S (21.18) c s c s plus the budget constraint. It is apparent from (21.16) and (21.18) that the market in state contingent income claims again leads to efficient risk bearing because the parties face the same relative c /µ c prices of claims to state contingent incomes. Using (21.17) to substitute psx = π s usx in (21.15) shows that the producer’s choice of input satisfies Evsz + ( µ / µ c ) ∑π u f ′ = 0 s c sx s s and is therefore Pareto efficient. 2. Writing the first order condition in the question as Evsy ps f s′ + Evsz − tEvsy f s′ = 0 Comparing this with [D.17] (after setting psa = ps since there are rational expectations), we see that setting t=− c ) Ds psz E ( vsy − λvsy Evsy f s′ ensures that the producer’s choice implies ∂W/∂z = 0. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 267 Note that the partial derivative of the first order condition on z with respect to t (holding z constant but remembering tfs = Hs) is ∂ dEvs ∂y = ( Evsyy + Evszy ) s − Evsy fs′ = − Evsy fs′ < 0 ∂t dz ∂t since ∂ys/∂t = 0. Hence the producer’s input level can be reduced by increasing t or vice versa. 3. Drop the s subscript to save notation and recall that unity elasticity of demand with respect to price implies −1 = ∂ log D ∂ log p Integrating and using Roy’s Identity, −vc log D = log c p = −log p + K(y) vy c = 0 implies that vc is additively separable in y and p and can be written vc(p, y) = But vyp a(p) + k1g(y). Hence − a ′( p) log D = log = −log p + K(y) k1 g ′( y) so that a ′( p) = − k( y) k1 g ′( y) p where log k(y) = K(y). Hence a(p) = −k(y)k1g′(y) log p + m and since a is not a function of y we must have k(y)k1g′(y) = constant = k0. Since the utility function is unique up to linear transformations we can always set m = 0 to give [D.19]. 4. The producer’s state s income is given by [D.20] and her forward sales satisfy [D.21]. However, because she does not choose z, her optimal forward sale is xf(W, p, pf , π, z). The consumer’s optimal forward and spot demands are still given by Df(Wc, p, pf , π) and Ds(ps, Wsc + (ps − pf)Df). Hence equilibrium of the forward and spot markets requires xf(W, p, pf , π, z) − Df(Wc, p, pf , π) = 0 fs(z) − Ds(ps, Wsc + (ps − pf)Df) = 0, s = 1, 2, 3 instead of [D.24] and [D.25]. The equilibrium forward and spot prices thus depend on the level of z: pf = pf(z, ⋅), ps = ps(z, ⋅), s = 1, 2, 3 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 268 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Proceeding as on text pages 629–631, the marginal social value of z is ∂p f ∂p f ∂W ∂p c c ∂ps xf = Evsy ps fs′ + Evsz + Evsy ( f s − x f ) s + x f + λEvsy − Df ∂z ∂z ∂z ∂z ∂z ∂p ∂p ∂p c = Evsy ps fs′ + Evsz + E ( vsy − λvsy ) Ds s + D f f − s ∂z ∂z ∂z (Use the market clearing conditions and Roy’s Identity.) At the level of z chosen by the producer the first two terms sum to zero and so ∂p ∂p ∂W ∂p c ) Ds s + D f f − s = E ( vsy − λvsy ∂z ∂z ∂z ∂z (21.19) As in the case where there are no futures markets the input choice of the producer is not in general constrained Pareto efficient because she neglects the effect of her changes in z on the market clearing prices and the consequent transfers of income across states. Since there are no markets in state contingent income claims there is in general inefficient risk bearing so that changes in forward and spot prices which alter state contingent incomes have efficiency implications. Unfortunately, as total differentiation of the market clearing conditions with respect to z shows, the effect of z on the equilibrium prices is extremely complicated. Exercise 21E 1. (a) The slope of the budget line AB in text Fig. 21.3 is given by [E.4] and does not depend on the initial holdings. A reduction in the initial holding in firm 1 shifts the point â1Y 1 inward along the ray 0Y 1. The value of the initial holdings is reduced but since the prices of shares is unchanged the budget line slope is unaltered. 1. (b) Write δ for the denominator of [E.4] and differentiate [E.4] with respect to M1: Y Y −2 d( dy2 /dy1 ) 1 Y21 Y11 −2 = 2 − M1 Y12 − 22 − 12 M1 Y11 dM1 δ M 2 M1 M 2 M1 =− = = Y M − Y12 M 2 1 Y21 M1 − Y11 M 2 Y12 − 22 1 Y11 2 δ M1 M1 M 2 M1 M 2 2 1 δ 2 M12 M 2 (Y12Y21 − Y11Y22 ) Y11Y21 Y12 Y22 − <0 δ 2 M12 M 2 Y11 Y21 The inequality follows from inspection of Fig. 21.3 where the slope of 0Y 1 (Y12/Y11) is less than the slope of 0Y 2 (Y22/Y21). © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 269 Fig. 21E.1 An increase in the price of shares in firm 1 therefore makes the budget line steeper: acquiring additional state 1 income by trading in the stock market becomes relatively more expensive. Firm 1 yields relatively more income in state 1 than firm 2 and so an increase in the price of its shares makes it more expensive to acquire claims to state 1 income: the budget line becomes steeper. Since the individual can always choose not to trade in the markets for shares the endowment point W is always feasible. Hence the budget line pivots through W. 1. (c) The denominator in [E.4] is negative since m1Y11 > m2Y21. Hence an increase in Y11 makes the absolute value of [E.4] smaller. The budget line AB becomes flatter because the point A moves horizontally to the right. The budget line also becomes flatter when Y12 increases because this shifts the point A vertically upwards. 2. The rate of return on firm j shares is hj2 = Yjs/Mj − 1 (see [E.5]). Consider Fig. 21E.1 in which point a at (1 + h11, 1 + h12) is the state contingent income vector attainable by spending £1 on buying shares in firm 1. Point b is similarly the state contingent income vector obtainable by spending £1 on buying shares in firm 2. By suitable choice of (λ1, λ2), λj ≥ 0, ∑λj = 1 it is possible to achieve any point on ab. Such a mixture of shares is an asset with random rates of return hs = ∑λj hjs. In particular the point c where income is the same in both states is attainable. The composite security or portfolio corresponding to c has a certain rate of return h0. If the rates of return in the firms are such that both points a and b are on the same side of the 45° line a point on the 45° line is attainable if short sales are permitted ie if the restriction λj ≥ 0 is lifted. (See the discussion in the text.) There are two circumstances in which it will not be possible to achieve a certain rate of return when there are as many firms as states. (i) The first is when two of the firms have the same rates of return. In the two state, two firm case h1s = h2s, s = 1, 2 implies that the line ab collapses to a single point and no change in the state distribution of incomes is possible by exchanging shares in the two firms. (ii) The second case in which a certain rate of return is not possible is when the line ab has a slope of 1 and is parallel to the 45° line, as for example if firm 2’s rates of return generated point b′ in the © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 270 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn figure. In this case the line ab′, no matter how extended, does not cut the 45° and there is no composite asset with a certain rate of return. The second case is not economically sensible since firm 1 yields a larger rate of return in all states of the world. Clearly there would be no demand for shares in firm 2 and its market price M2 would fall. This would increase its rate of return (see [E.5]) and the point b′ would be shifted out along the ray 0b′ until its rates of return are not dominated by firm 1. Depending on investors’ preferences the market price would adjust until the markets clear and a point like b″ is attainable by spending £1 on firm 2 shares. But now suitable purchases and (short) sales will make all points along ab″ and its extension feasible, including a point on the 45° line. More formally: it is possible to achieve a certain rate of return by a suitable mixture of shares in the two firm, two state case if the following equations can be solved for λ1, λ2, h0: λ1h11 + λ2h21 = h0 λ1h12 + λ2h22 = h0 λ1 + λ2 = 1 or, in matrix form, h11 h21 h 12 h22 −1 −1 −1 λ 1 0 −1 λ 2 = 0 0 h0 −1 These equations can be solved for λ1, λ2, h0 only if the determinant ∆ of the system is non-zero. Since the determinant is ∆ = (h21 − h11) − (h22 − h12) the system has a solution only if one firm’s rate of return does not exceed that of the other by the same amount in both states. This rules out a configuration like a, b′ in Fig. 21E.1. If the determinant of the system is non-zero we can use Cramer’s rule to solve for h h0 = − 11 h12 h21 h22 If the vectors of the firms’s rates of return are linearly independent we can solve for a non-zero certain rate of return achievable by a suitable combination of the shares. This is the spanning condition. Note that if the vectors are linearly dependent the solution has h0 = 0. This is not economically sensible. Linear dependence means that ab is ray from the origin, so that a certain rate of return of zero is obtainable at the origin. But if ab is a ray from the origin one firm’s rates of return are larger than the other’s in every state. The price of the dominated firm’s shares would adjust until the rates of return were equal and ab would collapse to a single point. But then ∆ = 0 and the system would have no solution: a certain rate of return is not obtainable. Hence, allowing for the adjustment of share prices, we see that the spanning condition is a necessary and sufficient condition for the construction of a composite security with a certain rate of return. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 271 Fig. 21E.2 3. Fig. 21E.2 shows the effect of the various changes on the budget constraint. The initial budget constraint is AB and is constructed as in text Fig. 21.5. and has slope (h2 − h0)/(h1 − h0). 3. (a) An increase in wealth w shifts the budget line outward to A′B′ with no change in slope. The demand for the risky asset is unaffected if there is constant relative risk aversion which implies that the slope of indifference curves is constant along rays from the origin. 3. (b) Let the return on the risky asset increase from hs to hs + k. The budget line is now BA″: the income attainable from investing only in the risky asset is larger in both states whilst the certain income attainable from investing only in the safe asset is unaffected. More formally: the right hand side negative numerator in [E.11] is reduced and the positive denominator increased, thus reducing the absolute value of [E.11]. The effect on demand will depend on risk aversion: if the individual has decreasing absolute (relative) risk aversion the wealth effect of the increase in the risky returns increases the amount (proportion) of initial wealth invested in the risky asset, thus reinforcing the substitution effect. 3. (c) An increase in the return on the safe asset pivots the budget line to B″A making it steeper. If there is diminishing risk aversion the substitution and wealth effects will work in opposite directions. 3. (d) An increase in the probability of the high return state 1 has no effect on the budget constraint which is defined solely by initial wealth and the rates of return on safe and risky assets. An increase in π1 makes the indifference curves steeper and hence leads to an increase in the demand for the risky asset. 3. (e) With only two states a mean preserving spread requires a change in the state contingent rates of return as well possibly as a change in probabilities. The simplest case to analyse is a change in the rats of return with constant probabilities. Expected income is constant along lines with a slope of −π1/π2 (the slope of the indifference © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 272 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. 21E.3 curves at the 45° line). Thus a movement down the constant expected income line through A away from the 45° line holds expected income constant but is clearly riskier: the rate of return in state 1 has increased whilst that in state 2 has fallen. The effect is to steepen the budget line to BA′″. The individual is worse off and, if there is diminishing risk aversion, the wealth effect now reinforces the substitution effect and the demand for the risky asset is reduced. 4. (a) With a proportional tax at the rate t on final wealth we have ys = [w(1 + h0) + D(hs − h0)](1 − t) instead of [E.6]. The budget constraint in Fig. 21E.3 is shifted inward but its slope is unchanged. If the individual has constant relative risk aversion investment in the risky asset is unchanged: B′C′/B′A′ is equal to BC/BA so that the proportion of initial wealth invested in the risky asset is unchanged. Since D/w is unchanged and the tax does not alter w the demand D for the risky asset is also unchanged if there is constant relative risk aversion. 4. (b) With a tax at the rate θ on the income from investments we have ys = (w − D)[1 + h0(1 − θ)] + D[1 + hs(1 − θ)] = w[1 + h0(1 − θ)] + D(hs − h0)(1 − θ) instead of [E.6]. Using the equation for y1 to solve for D and substituting in the equation for y2 gives the equation for the budget line as y2 = w[1 + h0(1 − θ)] + y1 − w[1 + h0 (1 − θ )] ( h2 − h0 ) ( h1 − h0 )(1 − θ ) so that the slope of the budget line is unaffected by the tax. The effect of the tax is to shrink the budget line from BA to B′A″, reducing the final wealth achievable by investing entirely in the safe or the risky asset. When θ = 1 and all investment income is taxed away the budget line collapses to the point (w, w) on the 45° line. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 273 If there is constant relative risk aversion the tax shifts the individual from C to C′, increasing the proportion of initial wealth invested in the risky asset from BC/BA to B′C′/B′A″. In this case taxation increases risk taking (measured by the demand for the risky asset). 5. The effect on the slope of the indifference curve of movement along a straight line in (y1, y2) space defined by y2 = a + by1 is given by d( −π 1 v ′y1 ) /π 2 v ′( y2 ) −π 1 [v″(y1)v′(a + by1) − v′(y1)v″(a + by1)b] = dy1 π 2 ( v ′( y2 ))2 v′( a + by1 ) v′( y1 ) − = −γ b v′′( a + by1 ) v′′( y1 ) (21.20) = γ [T(a + by1) − bT(y1)] (21.21) where γ = π1v″(y1)v″(y2)/π2(v′(y2))2 and T(y) = −v′(y)/v″(y) is risk tolerance. Thus indifference curves have constant slope along a straight line if and only if T (a + by1) = bT(y1) (21.22) for all y1. Now (21.22) implies dT (a + by1 ) = T ′(a + by1)b = bT ′(y1) dy1 or T ′(a + by1) = T ′(y1). Hence (21.22) implies that T(y) is linear: T = α + βy, so that T ′ = β is constant. Conversely if T is linear the “income consumption curve” is also linear since it is always possible to find constants a, b such that T(a + by1) = α + β (a + by1) = b(α + βy1) = bT(y1) implying that (21.21) is zero. 6. Let the proportion of initial wealth invested in the certain asset be δ0 so that c = δ0w, and the amount invested in risky asset j be δj(w − c) = δj(1 − δ0)w. Hence ys = w[δ0(1 + h0) + (1 − δ0) J ∑ δ (1 + h )] j js 1 = w[δ0(1 + h0) + (1 − δ0)(1 + hJs + J −1 ∑ δ (h − h ))] j js Js 1 = wzs(δ ) (21.23) remembering that ∑1J δ j = 1. Note that zs depends on the investment decision but not on w. Marginal utility in state s is v′(ys) = (ρ + τys)−1/τ (with τ = 1 for the logarithmic utility function). In the case in which ρ = 0 marginal utility can be written v′(ys) = (τ ys)−1/τ = w−1/τ(τ zs)−1/τ © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 274 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn so that the first order conditions are Ev′(wzs(δ )) w ∂zs ∂z = w−1/τ E[τ zs(δ )]−1/τ w s = 0, i = 0, . . . , J − 1 ∂δ i ∂δ i (21.24) Dividing each of the first order conditions by w1−1/τ leaves a set of conditions determining the optimal δ0, . . . , δJ−1 which do not depend on w. Hence the proportion of wealth invested in each asset, including the safe asset, is independent of wealth. Now consider the case in which ρ ≠ 0 and denote the investment in the safe and risky assets as c = α + δ0(w − α) Dj = δj(1 − δ0)(w − α) (Note that c + ∑ Dj = w). Choice of the δj completely determines investment in the safe and risky assets: by setting δ0 = (c − α)/(w − α) and δj = Dj/(w − α), j = 1, . . . , J and investment plan (c, D1, . . . , DJ) with c + ∑ Dj = w can be achieved whatever the value of α . With this reformulation of the investment problem, write state s wealth as ys = α (1 + h0) + (w − α)[δ0(1 + h0) + (1 − δ0)[1 + hJs + J −1 ∑ δ ( h − h )]] j js Js 1 = α (1 + h0) + (w − α)zs(δ ) (21.25) For given α , the optimal investment plan satisfies the first order conditions on δ0, . . . , δJ−1: Ev′(α (1 + h0) + (w − α)zs(δ ))(w − α) ∂zs ∂δ i = E{ρ + τ [α (1 + h0) + (w − α)zs(δ )]}−1/τ(w − α) ∂zs ∂δ i = E{ρ + τα (1 + h0) + τ (w − α)zs(δ )}−1/τ(w − α) ∂zs =0 ∂δ i (21.26) With different α different δ0, . . . , δJ−1 would satisfy these conditions but the optimal portfolio c, D1, . . . , DJ would be unchanged. Suppose we set α = −ρ/τ(1 + h0) Then the conditions (21.26) simplify to E[τ(w − α)zs(δ )]−1/τ(w − α) = (w − α)−1/τE[τ zs(δ )]−1/τ(w − α) ∂zs ∂δ i ∂zs = 0, i = 0, . . . , J − 1 ∂δ i (21.27) Dividing these conditions through by (w − α)1−1/τ gives a set of equations which determine δ0, . . . , δJ−1 but do not depend on w − α. Hence the proportion of wealth in © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 275 Fig. 21E.4 excess of α invested in the assets is independent of w − α. Thus setting α = −ρ/τ(1 + h0) and then choosing the δ0, . . . , δJ−1 determined by (21.26) yields an optimal portfolio. Moreover since δi, i = 1, . . . , J − 1 does not vary with w − α the share of the risky part of the portfolio invested in each risky asset is independent of w: Di δ (1 − δ 0 )( w − α ) δ = Ji = Ji J ∑1 D j ∑1 δ j (1 − δ 0 )( w − α ) ∑1 δ j 7. (a) Before the state is revealed the price p of a share in the firm entitling the holder to income Ys/N in state s and the price of a call option entitling the holder to buy one share at a price of p0 is c. An individual with initial wealth w can buy n shares and q call options subject to the budget constraint w = np + qc. Given these transactions the state contingent incomes are y1 = n Y1 Y Y q + q 1 − qp0 = n 1 + (Y1 − p0 N ) N N N N (21.28) y2 = n Y2 N (21.29) Using the budget constraint to substitute for n = (w − qc)/p in (21.28) and then using the resulting equation for y1 to substitute for q in (21.29) gives the equation for the budget line in (y1, y2) space as ( Npy1 − wY1 ) Y2 y2 = w − c Y1 ( p − c ) − p0 Np pN The slope of the budget line is − cY2 dy2 = dy1 Y1 ( p − c ) − p0 Np © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 (21.30) 276 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn In Fig. 21E.4 purchases of the call option enable all points along the budget line from B where q = 0 to A where q = w/c to be reached. Since the option is only worth exercising if state 1 occurs, purchases of the option transfer are a means of transferring income between states by reducing income in both states by c and increasing income in state 1 by Y1/N − p0. By selling call options (q < 0) it is possible to reduce income in state 1 and increase state 2 income. Hence all points along BA and its extension are achievable via the share and option markets. Adding a market in options which are only worth exercising if state 1 occurs is equivalent to creating a market in an artificial firm with a payoff vector (Y1 − Np0, 0), so that together the payoff vectors of the original and the artificial firm satisfy the spanning condition. 7. (b) The total number of securities (firm shares and options) must be at least equal to the number of states and there must be a subset of S of them with linearly independent payoff vectors. One firm could be sufficient if there were S − 1 options each with different exercise prices p0i such that Y1/N > p01 > Y2/N > p02 > . . . > p0S −1 > YS/N. Exercise 21F 1. In the case in which each firm’s output in one state is a linear combination of its outputs in the other two states, constrained Pareto efficiency is possible because the number of states is now effectively the same as the number of firms, and firms will be able to deduce (effective) shareholders’ discount rates from market data. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 277 Appendices Exercise A 1. (a) We can represent the choice variables as x1, x2, x3, where x1 = 1 if you go home on foot and zero otherwise; x2 = 1 if you go home by bus, and zero otherwise; and x3 = 1 if you go home by train, and zero otherwise. The feasible set is the set of triples S = {(x1, x2, x3)} = {(1, 0, 0), (0, 1, 0), (0, 0, 1)}. If ti denotes how long it takes to get home by mode i = 1, 2, 3, and ci denotes the money cost of mode i, then time taken is 3 T= ∑t x i i i =1 and money cost is 3 C= ∑c x i i i =1 We can postulate that you have an objective function V(T, C) which expresses your preferences over time-cost combinations. For example, suppose that this takes the linear form V = wT + C, w > 0. Note that we expect the ‘best’ way of getting home to minimize V. Thus the problem is to minimize V by choosing one of the triplets in S. A more direct approach to the problem would define the feasible set S′ = {(t1, c1), (t2, c2), (t3, c3)} i.e. in terms of the time-cost pairs corresponding to each mode. You must still have some function such as V, however, which places a relative valuation on time and money. Fig. A.1 then illustrates a solution. (We assume walking is costless, so we ignore depreciation on shoes etc.) Clearly, each mode could be optimal for some value of w. We take the case in which the bus is best: time is too valuable to you to go on foot, but not so valuable that you take the train. Note that minimizing V means getting onto the lowest possible line. Supplementary questions (i) What observable economic variable could you take as an estimate of w, if you wanted to construct the function V? (ii) Draw lines which yield first (0, t1), then (c3, t3) as solutions and interpret what they imply about w. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 277 278 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. A.1 (iii) Assume now that your objective is to minimize time spent travelling, subject to not spending more than a given amount of ". Use Fig. A.1 to reconsider the solution possibilities. (iv) Now do the same assuming the objective is to minimize cost subject to not taking longer to get home than a specified time Q. (v) Suppose you were indifferent between taking the bus or the train. What does that tell us about your value of w? 1. (b) Let xi, i = 1, . . . , n denote the quantity of foodstuff i, and x0 the calorie-free, expensive, all-vitamin tablet. Let pi, ci and vij be respectively the price, calorie count and the content of vitamin j = 1, . . . , m, in foodstuff i. Let Pj denote the minimum amount of vitamin j you require, " your minimum possible calorie consumption, and M your maximum possible expenditure on food. Then your problem is n minimize C = ∑c x i i i =1 subject to : n ∑c x i ≥ ", ≤ M, i ≥ Pj j = 1, . . . , m, xi ≥ 0 i = 0, 1, . . . , n. i i =1 n ∑px i i i=0 n ∑v x ij i=0 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 279 Supplementary questions (i) Suppose the calorie-free tablet does not exist, there are only two foodstuffs, one vitamin, and the parameter values are p1 = 4, c1 = 40, v1= 20, " = 1200, p2 = 2.5, c2 = 40, v2 = 10, M = 100. P = 400, Graph the constraints and identify the feasible set. Then find a feasible, calorieminimizing pair of quantities ( x1* , x2* ). (ii) Suppose now that the calorie-free tablet also exists, it contains 50 of the vitamin, and costs 10 per unit. What is the optimal solution in this case? 1. (c) The price of each good sold at market B is less than the corresponding price at market A. Then either the consumer will do all his shopping at market A, or all at market B. The choice variables are xiA , xiB , i = 1, . . . , n, the quantities of each good bought at supermarket A or B respectively. The corresponding prices are piA , piB , i = 1, . . . , n, with piA > piB , all i, by assumption. Let M be available income, and C the extra cost incurred by shopping at market B rather than at market A. Then, if he shops at market A his feasible set is determined by the constraint, n ∑p x ≤M A i A i xiA ≥ 0 i = 1, . . . , n, i =1 and if at market B by n ∑p x ≤ M −C B i B i xiB ≥ 0 i = 1, . . . , n. i =1 If he shops at market A he will choose the optimal consumption vector VA = ( V1A , . . . , V nA ), and if he shops at B, he will choose the optimal consumption vector VB = ( V1B , . . . , V nB ). Then, in general, all we can say is that his choice of market depends on whether or not he prefers VA to VB. Supplementary questions (i) Suppose piA = kpiB , k > 1. Also assume that whichever market he shops in the consumer spends all available income. Find a condition under which the consumer will certainly shop at B. (The condition does not involve the optimal vectors VA, VB.) (ii) You know the vectors VA, VB, all the prices, M and C. Can you frame conditions under which: the consumer certainly buys at A; he certainly buys at B? Is this information enough to allow you to predict his choice in all cases? 2. The answers are given by Fig. A.2. Exercise B 1. (a) Let f(x*) ≥ f(x) all x ∈ S, so that x* is a global maximum (f is the objective function, S the feasible set, and x* ∈ S). Take a small neighbourhood of points around © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 280 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. A.2 x*, and take any point x′ both in this neighbourhood and in S (if there is no such point then the proposition is trivially true). Then f(x*) ≥ f(x) all x ∈ S and x′ ∈ S ⇒ f(x*) ≥ f(x′) and so x* is also a local maximum. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 281 Fig. B.1 1. (b) Let x* and x′ be global maxima of f over the set S with x* ≠ x′. Then by definition f(x*) ≥ f(x′), all x ∈ S, and f(x′) ≥ f(x), all x ∈ S. In particular, f(x*) ≥ f(x′) and f(x′) ≥ f(x*), which then implies f(x*) = f(x′). 1. (c) For a linear function, f(I) = kf(x′) + (1 − k) f(x″) for I = kx′ + (1 − k)x″, 0 ≤ k ≤ 1. Comparison with the definitions of concavity and convexity then gives the result. 2. The answers are given by the Fig. B.1. 3. The function is quasi-concave if B′ is a convex set, and strictly concave if B′ is a strictly convex set. 4. If f is concave then f(I) ≥ kf(x′) + (1 − k)f(x″) 0≤k≤1 for all x′, x″ ∈ X, the domain of the function. It follows that if we choose x′, x″ such that f(x′) = f(x″), then the above inequality must hold for these. This implies quasi-concavity from the definition. An example of a quasi-concave, non-concave function is y = x12 x22 . Supplementary question (i) Use the answer to question 7 below to show that this function is (strictly) quasiconcave. Use the definition of a concave function, and the points (0, 0), (1, 1), with k = 1/2, to show that this function is not concave. Sketch the function in three dimensions (or get a computer to do so). © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 282 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 5. (a) This feasible set is non-empty, closed, unbounded and convex. (b) This feasible set is non-empty, not closed, bounded and convex. (c) This feasible set is non-empty, closed, bounded and convex. (d) This feasible set consists of the single point (3, −2) and so is non-empty, closed, bounded and convex. (e) This feasible set is empty. (f) This feasible set is non-empty, closed, unbounded and non-convex. (g) This feasible set is non-empty, closed, unbounded and non-convex. (h) This feasible set is non-empty, closed, bounded and non-convex. (i) This feasible set is non-empty, closed, bounded and convex. (j) This feasible set consists of two points (1, 3), (2, 0) and is non-empty, closed, bounded and non-convex. Supplementary question (i) Explain the above answers. 6. A set is closed if it contains whatever boundary points it has, but it can still be unbounded if its boundaries do not fully enclose it, for example, the set of numbers x ≥ 0. A set is not closed if it does not contain all its boundary points, for example the set of numbers satisfying 0 ≤ x < 1. 7. We have dx2 f (x , x ) =− 1 1 2 . dx1 f 2 ( x1 , x 2 ) Hence: d dx2 d f1 ( x1 , x2 ) =− dx1 dx1 dx1 f 2 ( x1 , x2 ) =− dx dx 1 f f + f12 2 − f1 f 21 + f 22 2 2 2 11 f 2 dx1 dx1 where we use the fact that x2 is implicitly a function of x1. Then substituting dx2/dx1 = −f1/f2 gives d 2 x2 f 1 = − 2 f 2 f11 − f12 f1 − f1 f 21 + f 12 22 2 dx1 f2 f2 =− 1 { f12 f 22 − 2 f1 f 2 f12 + f 22 f11 } 3 f2 Where we use Young’s Theorem, f12 = f21. Since, for strict quasi-concavity d 2 x2 /dx12 > 0, multiplying through by −1 gives the required result. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 283 Fig. C.1 Supplementary question (i) Explain why it is neither necessary nor sufficient for strict quasi-concavity that fi > 0, fii < 0, i = 1, 2. Exercise C 1. From Fig. C.1 we see that it is possible to have existence of a solution when the conditions of the theorem are not met. Existence of a solution therefore does not imply that the conditions are met, and so they are not necessary conditions for existence. They do however guarantee that a solution does exist (they rule out cases in which a solution does not exist) and so they are sufficient. 2. If a solution exists then there must exist a feasible point, i.e. the feasible set is nonempty. Therefore non-emptiness is a necessary condition for existence. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 284 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. D.1 Exercise D 1. (a) See Fig. D.1. 1. (b) It has been assumed that f1, f2 > 0, and so increasing x1 and x2 in text Fig. D.2 must increase the value of the objective function. Thus points along the contour c yield the same value of the objective function as points along ab, and points above the contour, since they involve higher x1 and x2, yield higher values of the function. 2. If the feasible set S in text Fig. D.2 is not closed, in that it does not contain the points on the segment ab, then no solution exists. Between any point in S and a point on ab we can always find another point yielding a higher value of the function. Thus no maximum exists. 3. A local minimum is a global minimum if: (a) the objective function is quasi-convex, and (b) the feasible set is convex. The proof is precisely as given in the text, if we note that minimizing f(x1, x2) is equivalent to maximizing −f(x1, x2), and that if f(x1, x2) is quasi-convex, then −f(x1, x2) is quasi-concave. Supplementary question (i) Draw the counterpart of text Fig. D.2 for a minimization problem in which the origin (a) is, and (b) is not a solution. 4. This question anticipates the discussion of the next appendix. If B is strictly convex then the solution will be a unique point of tangency rather than the set of points along ab (see text Fig. E.1 (c) for an illustration). © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 285 Exercise E 1. See Fig. D.1. 2. Given a minimization problem in which the feasible set is convex and the objective function is non-constant and quasi-convex, a solution is unique if (a) the feasible set is strictly convex or (b) the objective function is strictly quasi-convex (or both). The proof follows that in the text exactly, if we again note that minimizing f(x) is equivalent to maximizing −f(x), and f(x) (strictly) quasi-convex implies −f(x) (strictly) quasi-concave. 3. In text Fig. E.1 (a), the feasible set is not strictly convex because its two lower boundaries, the x1- and x2-axes are linear. Its upper boundary is defined as U B = {x ∈ S|x is a boundary point of S and x′ Ⰷ x ⇒ x′ ∉ S} It is easy to show that if we are maximizing f(x1, x2) over S, with f1, f2 > 0, then a solution must be in U B. Suppose there are two such solutions, x* and x**, both in U B. Then, if S is strictly upper convex then I = kx* + (1 − k)x**, 0 < k < 1 lies in the interior of S and the rest of the proof goes through as before. Supplementary question (i) Show that if we are maximizing a function f(x) with fi > 0, i = 1, . . . , n, over a nonempty, closed, bounded convex set S, then any solution must lie on the upper boundary of S. Exercise F 1. See Fig. F.1. 2. Without further specification, a satisfactory point could be anywhere in the feasible set, and may or may not be affected by a change in the boundaries of the set. “Satisficing” is not a solution principle, while optimizing is. 3. We assume that the objective function is strictly quasi-concave. The feasible set is the line ab in text Fig. F.1 (a). The diagrams in Fig. F.2 answer the question. 4. Recall that one of the fundamental concepts in microeconomics is relative scarcity. People always want to consume more commodities than can be made available with the resources an economy possesses. This creates a need for allocation, and microeconomics is concerned with the way a market economy solves this allocation problem. Now if everyone in the economy possesses a bliss point, and resources and technology were such that everyone could attain their bliss point, then relative scarcity would disappear, and so too would the microeconomic problem. Production and distribution would simply have to be organized so as to give each person the © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 286 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. F.1 Fig. F.2 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 287 Fig. G.1 consumption vector corresponding to the bliss point. We would not need a price mechanism to help allocate scarce resources among competing ends. We would have reached Utopia. On the other hand, if people have bliss points but the total amounts of commodities required to reach them all are beyond the capacity of the economy to produce, then we again have relative scarcity and microeconomics is a relevant – indeed essential – field of study. In other words people may have bliss points, but this is not very important if they are locally non-satiated at levels of output feasible for the economy. Exercise G 1. See Fig. G.1. In case (a) f ′(x*) > 0, and in case (b) fi(x*) > 0 at the optimal point. 2. If for this constrained minimization problem we form the Lagrange function L(x, λ) = f(x) − m ∑ λ [g (x) − b ] j j j j =1 and minimize this function with respect to x and λ, then we obtain precisely conditions [G.15] and [G.16]. This is simply the familiar point that an unconstrained maximum or minimum must occur at a point at which all partial derivatives are zero. 3. (a) The Lagrange multiplier associated with the constraint on the balance of payments deficit is often called the “shadow price of foreign exchange”. It shows by how much GNP in the economy could be increased if the constraint on the deficit were relaxed slightly, for example by an exogenous increase in foreign exchange reserves. The Lagrange multiplier on the skilled labour constraint would be called the shadow wage of skilled labour, since it shows by how much GNP would increase for a marginal increase in the amount of skilled labour. This may well differ from the actual wage rate in the economy, hence the term “shadow”. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 288 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. G.2 3. (b) The Lagrange multiplier in this case is simply the marginal rate of return to investment in the firm. The firm should compare it to the cost of borrowing, since if this is lower, investment should be expanded; and also compared to the return of lending outside the firm, since if this is higher, investment should be contracted. 4. (a) See Fig. G.2. There are five solution possibilities: (i) point α, where x1 = 0, x2 > 0. In this case the b1 constraint is non-binding, (ii) a point along αγ, such as β, where x1, x2 > 0, while the b1 constraint is again nonbinding (iii) point γ, where x1, x2 > 0 and both constraints bind, (iv) a point along γ ε such as δ, where x1, x2 > 0, while the b2 constraint is non-binding, (v) point ε, where x1 > 0, x2 = 0, and the b2 constraint is non-binding. 4. (b) λ*1 is the shadow price of the b1-constraint. It shows the rate at which the optimized value of the objective function changes when b1 changes. If λ*1 = 0, this must imply that a (very small) change in b1 leaves the solution unaffected. Thus b1 must be non-binding at the optimum, and we have either case (i) or case (ii) above. Exercise H 1. We may have both x2* = 0 and L2 = f2 − λ*a2 = 0, since this does not violate [H.20]. Therefore we cannot say that x2* = 0 ⇒ L2 < 0. In terms of text Fig. H.4, we can interpret the case in which x2* = 0 and f2 = λ*a2 as being that in which the contour c1 and the constraint line are just tangent at ( x1*, 0), since then we have: a1 f ( x *, 0) = 1 1 . a2 f ( x *, 0) 2 1 © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 289 In terms of the original discussion of non-negativity conditions in text Fig. H.1, this is like the case illustrated in Fig. H.1 (c). It so happens that the necessary condition for the case without negativity conditions holds at the point x2* = 0. This is clearly something of a special case, but, all the same, you should always resist the temptation to conclude that Li < 0 when x i* = 0. 2. In text Fig. H.4, a1 and a2 would be the prices of goods 1 and 2 respectively, and the contours c0, c1, c2 would be indifference curves. Then we have the case in which the consumer spends all her income on good 1. Though this may seem rather special in the 2-good case, in reality a consumer buys positive amounts of a small subset of all the commodities that are in fact available – corner solutions are perfectly typical. 3. Given the problem max f(x) s.t. xi ≥ bi, i = 1, . . . , n (for simplicity ignore functional constraints) we can proceed in either of two ways: (a) Define Vi = xi − bi, and write the problem as max f(V1 + b1, . . . , Vn + bn) Vi ≥ 0 s.t. i = 1, . . . , n. Note that ∂f/∂xi ≡ ∂f/∂Vi since the bi are constants. Thus applying [H.4] we have fi ≤ 0, Vi* ≥ 0, Vi* fi = 0. But Vi* = x i* − bi, so this becomes fi ≤ 0, x i* ≥ bi , ( xi* − bi ) fi = 0. Thus, if we have an interior solution, with xi* > bi, we must have fi = 0, while at a corner solution with xi* = bi we have fi ≤ 0. We can extend this to take account of functional constraints just as before. (b) Define the Lagrange function L(x, λ) = f(x) + ∑ λ ( x − b ). i i i i Then the Kuhn-Tucker conditions are Li = fi + λ*i = 0 Lλ i = xi* − bi ≥ 0, λ*i ≥ 0, λ*i ( x i* − bi) = 0. Then: if λ*i > 0, fi = − λ*i < 0 and xi* = bi if xi − bi > 0, λ*i = 0 and fi = 0 if λ*i = ( x i* − bi) = 0, then fi = 0. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 290 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn Fig. H.1 Supplementary questions (i) Develop necessary conditions for the problem max f(x) s.t. xi ≤ bi, i = 1, . . . , n. (ii) Suppose f(x1, x2) is a strictly quasi-concave utility function, a consumer has a standard budget constraint, and must consume at least minimum subsistence levels s1, s2 of the two goods. Apply one of the above procedures and interpret the solution diagrammatically. (iii) Interpret the Lagrange multipliers in approach (b). 4. Detailed answers depend on exactly how the new constraint relates to the two initial constraints. Suppose it enters as illustrated in Fig. H.1. Then, clearly the α and β solutions are still possible (as are corner solutions on the original two constraints) but solutions at γ are ruled out. Instead, we have three new solution possibilities, at δ, at ε, or at a point like φ along δε. The Lagrange function is now 2 2 2 f ( x1 , x2 ) − λ 1 a i x i − b1 − λ 2 c i x i − b2 − λ 3 e i x i − b3 . i =1 i =1 i =1 ∑ ∑ ∑ The Kuhn-Tucker conditions are now Li = fi − λ*1 a i − λ*2 c i − λ*3 e i ≤ 0 xi* ≥ 0 xi* Li = 0 i = 1, 2, Lλ 1 = ∑ a i xi* − b1 ≤ 0, λ*1 ≥ 0 λ*1 Lλ = 0, Lλ 2 = ∑ c i xi* − b2 ≤ 0, λ*2 ≥ 0 λ*2 Lλ = 0, Lλ 3 = ∑ e i xi* − b3 ≤ 0, λ*3 ≥ 0 λ*3 Lλ = 0. 1 2 3 Then, at α, set λ*2 = λ*3 = 0; at β, set λ*1 = λ*3 = 0; at φ, set λ*1 = λ*2 = 0; at δ, set λ*2 = 0; at ε, set λ*1 =0. Then, for each of these cases the Kuhn-Tucker conditions can be used to © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 291 Fig. H.2 characterize the optimal pair ( x1* , x2* ), (which are both positive at all these points – again you should also add the cases ( x1* , 0) and (0, x2* )). Essentially, then, the KuhnTucker conditions allow a systematic working through of solution possibilities. 5. In this problem, for one unit of good i the consumer must pay ai units of money and ci ration points. If ration points cannot be exchanged for money, the two constraints must be imposed separately. Then, in Fig. H.2, at an α-type solution the consumer is spending all her endowment of money but is left with surplus ration coupons (since α is below the b2 constraint). In other words her preferences are such that she wants to buy relatively more of good x2, whose money price is relatively higher than its points price ((a2/a1) > (c2/c1)). A β-type on the other hand has preferences such that his optimal consumption bundle requires all his ration points but leaves him with money left over. Only a solution at γ involves spending exactly all of both money and points endowments. As the figure shows, there is no reason in general why everyone would be at a point such as γ – if preferences vary over individuals, the other solution types are also perfectly possible. Thus, there will be people with “spare” ration points, and also people with “spare” money. In microeconomics we regard it as a basic fact of human nature that in such a situation people will want to trade (if, for some reason, the rationing authority has declared this illegal, then there will be a “black market” in ration points). The important point is that such trade makes everyone better off. To see this, let p be the money price of a ration that is established in the market for points. Then the two constraints can be collapsed into one, since multiplying through the ration constraint by p and summing we have (a1 + pc1)x1 + (a2 + pc2)x2 ≤ b1 + pb2. This is a valid operation because p is in dimensions £/points, and so multiplying through the points constraint puts it in the dimension of money. Intuitively, we could think of a consumer selling her entire points endowment b2 for pb2. Then, to buy a unit of xi she must pay ai as the price, and then pci as the money cost of ration points she © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 292 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn needs for the purchase. Thus we could think of (ai + pci) as the “full price” of a unit of xi and b1 + pb2 as her “full income”. What can we say about the new single budget constraint? Diagrammatically, we can say that it passes through the point γ in Fig. H.2, and has a slope intermediate between those of the two separate constraints. But this then means that the feasible set expands, as in the figure. Thus both α and β types are made strictly better off, as we would expect. But in general γ -types will also be better off unless it so happened that their marginal rate of substitution at ( x1γ , x2γ ) was exactly equal to (a1 + pc1)/ (a2 + pc2). To establish the result illustrated in the above figure, note first that at ( x1γ , x2γ ) we have, since it is an intersection point a1 x1γ + a2 x2γ = b1 c1 x1γ + c2 x2γ = b2 and so it must follow that (a1 + pc1 ) x1γ + (a2 + pc2 ) x2γ = b1 + pb2, so the new constraint must pass through point γ. Next, we have a1 c1 < ⇒ a1 c2 < a 2 c1 a 2 c2 ⇒ a1a2 + a1pc2 < a1a2 + a2pc1 ⇒ a1(a2 + pc2) < a2(a1 + pc1) ⇒ a1 a 1 + pc1 < a 2 a 2 + pc 2 In a similar way we can show that (a1 + pc1)/(a2 + pc2) < (c1/c2). Thus the slope of the single budget constraint lies between that of the initial constraints. (Note that a similar result could be established if we initially assumed (a1/a2) > (c1/c2).) Thus trade in ration points in general makes everyone better off. We have not yet discussed how the price p is determined. Essentially, this will be by the demand and supply of ration coupons. Intuitively, the more α-type people there are relative to β-types, the greater will be the amount of “excess coupons” relative to “excess money”, and so the lower is p, the money price of coupons. In turn, the lower is p the flatter will be the single budget constraint in the figure and the larger is the gain of those with “excess money” (the β-types) and the smaller that of those with “excess coupons” (the α-types). Supplementary question (i) Suppose that instead of being given an endowment of generalized ration points, with each good having a given points price, rationing is effected by giving the consumer endowments of coupons which can only be spent on a particular good, i.e. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn 293 Fig. H.3 x1-ration coupons and x2-ration coupons. There is still of course a money budget constraint. Carry out an analysis, along the above lines, for this type of rationing. When will markets in coupons exist? Should trade in coupons be permitted? 6. Assume for concreteness that (a1/a2) < (c1/c2). Then, a1 c1 < ⇒ a1 c2 < a 2 c1 a 2 c2 ⇒ λ*1 a1a2 + λ*2 a1c2 < λ*1 a1a2 + λ*2 a2c1 ⇒ a1( λ*1 a2 + λ*1 c2) < a2( λ*1 a1 + λ*2 c1) ⇒ a1 λ*1 a1 + λ*2 c1 < . a 2 λ* a + λ* c 1 2 2 2 The other inequality is established in a similar way, as are the two corresponding inequalities for the case (a1/a2) > (c1/c2). 7. If, at γ in text Fig. H.5, we have that the contour is tangent to the b1 constraint, then we must have f1 a 1 = . f2 a 2 From conditions [H.27], [H.28] we see that this must imply that λ*2 = 0. Thus in [H.30] we have in this case both that λ*2 = 0 and c1 x1* + c2 x2* − b2 = 0, since the solution is on the b2 constraint line at γ. This suggests that the b2-constraint is in some sense nonbinding. We illustrate this in Fig. H.3, where the contour is tangent to the b1 constraint. Suppose the b2-constraint shifts outward to the dashed line. Then the solution is unaffected: point γ is still both feasible and optimal. Thus for a relaxation of the constraint or an increase in b2, the optimized value of the objective function will be unchanged: dV/db2 = 0, where V = f ( x1* , x2* ) , at γ. On the other hand, if the b2-constraint shifts inward to the dotted line, point γ is no longer feasible, the solution must change, © Pearson Education Ltd 2007 294 Gravelle and Rees: Microeconomics Instructor’s Manual, 3rd edn and the optimized value of the objective function must fall. Since this resulted from a decrease in b2 we have dV/db2 > 0. That is, at γ the derivative of V with respect to b2 is in this case not unique: viewed as a function of b2, it has a discontinuity at that value of b2 at which the b2-constraint passes through the point of tangency of the objective function contour with the b1-constraint. In such cases, the Kuhn-Tucker conditions are made to yield the correct answer by choosing λ*2 = 0. Note that in this kind of case, if we were carrying out the comparative-statics analysis with respect to the b2-constraint, we would have to specify the direction of change in the constraint, because of this discontinuity. Exercise I 1. From [I.7] we have ∂x1 (α u − α 2 u12 ) λ* α 22 =− + x1* 1 22 ∂α 1 D D =− λ* α 22 D ∂x1 − x1* ∂α 3 as required. From the second-order conditions we have that D > 0. The first term − λ* α 22 / D < 0, since λ* > 0. However, if we have no restrictions on the signs or relative magnitudes of u12, u22 (or of α1, α2) then we cannot sign the term (a1u22 − α2u12). Thus neither ∂x1/∂α1 nor ∂x1/∂α3 can be signed unambiguously. If u is a utility function, α1, α2 prices, and α3 income then the above gives the Slutsky equation for good x1. The first term is the substitution effect and we see that this is negative. The second term is the income effect, and because its sign is ambiguous so is that of the derivative ∂x1/∂α1, the slope of the Marshallian demand curve. 2. We wish to solve min f(x1, x2) s.t. g(x1, x2) = b, with fi > 0, i = 1, 2. In text Fig. I.2, interchange f and g: the contour of f now becomes the one that is more concave or less convex to the origin. The idea is that moving away from the optimal point x* along the constraint contour always increases the value function, i.e. gives points on contours further away from the origin. Thus the counterpart of [I.18] is dx d dx 2 − 2 <0 dx1 dx1 f dx1 g at x = x*. The rest of the analysis proceeds just as before, except that in [I.19] we set φ ′′( x1* ) > 0 as the second-order condition for a minimum. © Pearson Education Ltd 2007