The Cambridge international A Level Economics series consists of a Student Book, Boost eBook, Workbook and Teacher Resource Pack. Cambridge International AS & A Level Economics Second Edition 9781398308275 Cambridge International AS & A Level Economics Second Edition Boost eBook 9781398308244 Cambridge International AS & A Level Economics Workbook Cambridge International AS & A Level Economics Teacher Resource Pack 9781398308282 9781398308299 To explore the entire series, visit www.hoddereducation.com/cambridge-alevel-economics Practise and apply what you have studied and develop independent learning skills by answering a range of questions. ● Build confidence with extra practice to ensure that a topic is thoroughly understood before moving on. ● Fully explore and analyse international economies through data response questions based on real case studies. ● Keep track of your work with ready-to-go write-in exercises. Save time marking and get support for delivering the revised Cambridge International AS & A Level Economics syllabus (9708). Confidently deliver the revised syllabus with guidance from experienced teachers on the transition between IGCSE and A level, ESL guidance and the subject-specific skills students will need, including how to interpret quantitative data. ● Familiarise students with the command words they will face in exams and improve their confidence with answer guidance to the questions in the student book. ● Save time with pre-made class and homework activities, such as editable worksheets, additional case studies and quizzes online. king for ove or r ss sm WITH al E YEARS es on m bridge A 25 ducation Ca We are working with Cambridge Assessment International Education to gain endorsement for these forthcoming titles W ● ent Intern i at Cambridge International AS & A Level Economics Second edition Peter Smith with Adam Wilby and Mila Zasheva 1 308275_FM_CAM_IASAL ECO_001_006.indd 1 23/03/21 10:24 AM Cambridge International copyright material in this publication is reproduced under licence and remains the intellectual property of Cambridge Assessment International Education. Exam-style questions (and sample answers) have been written by the authors. In examinations, the way marks are awarded may be different. References to assessment and/or assessment preparation are the publisher’s interpretation of the syllabus requirements and may not fully reflect the approach of Cambridge Assessment International Education. Cambridge International recommends that teachers consider using a range of teaching and learning resources in preparing learners for assessment, based on their own professional judgement of their students’ needs. Every effort has been made to trace and acknowledge ownership of copyright. The publishers will be glad to make suitable arrangements with any copyright holders whom it has not been possible to contact. Photo credits: p.9: piyaset/Adobe; p.12: jeson/Adobe; p.28: Kumar Sriskandan/Alamy; p.36: patpitchaya/ Adobe; p.53: David Tipling Photo Library/Alamy; p.62: Lukas Godja/Adobe; p.63: Andrew Barker/Adobe; p.71: marc zakian/Alamy; p.82: fredcardoso/Adobe; p.99: xPACIFICA/Alamy; p.102: Alexandre/Adobe; p.113: Charlie Varley/Alamy; p.120: rh2010/Adobe; p.124: Imaginechina Limited/Alamy; p.157: Africa Studio/Adobe; p.167: Pat Behnke/Alamy; p.179: Putu Artana/Alamy; p.209: Granger Historial Picture Archive/Alamy; p.214: bokstaz/ Adobe; p.224: Herwin Bahar/Alamy; p.233: Helen Sessions/Alamy; p.242: qaphotos.com/Alamy; p.257: Kevin Galvin/Alamy; p.270: Nick Maslen/Alamy; p.291: Kovalenko 1/Adobe; p.293: Alistair Ruff/Alamy; p.302: WavebreakMediaMicro/Adobe; p.309: Dinodia Photos/Alamy; p.313: elcovalana/Adobe; p.328: jaochainoi/Adobe; p.366: EvrenKalinbacak/Adobe; p.382: Sean Sprague/Alamy; p.387: Matyas Rehak/Adobe; p.388: k/Adobe; p.409: Grecaud Paul/Adobe; p.442: Imaginechina Limited/Alamy; p.464: blickwinkel/Alamy; p.469: Agencja Fotograficzna Caro/Alamy; p.478: Radek Procyk/Alamy; p.485: Gorma Kuma/Adobe; p.488: Image Professionals GmbH/Alamy; p.493: William Barton/Alamy; p.504: rocketclips/Adobe Although every effort has been made to ensure that website addresses are correct at time of going to press, Hodder Education cannot be held responsible for the content of any website mentioned in this book. It is sometimes possible to find a relocated web page by typing in the address of the home page for a website in the URL window of your browser. Third-party websites and resources referred to in this publication have not been endorsed by Cambridge Assessment International Education. Hachette UK’s policy is to use papers that are natural, renewable and recyclable products and made from wood grown in well-managed forests and other controlled sources. The logging and manufacturing processes are expected to conform to the environmental regulations of the country of origin. Orders: please contact Hachette UK Distribution, Hely Hutchinson Centre, Milton Road, Didcot, Oxfordshire, OX11 7HH. Telephone: +44 (0)1235 827827. Email: education@hachette.co.uk. Lines are open from 9 a.m. to 5 p.m., Monday to Friday. You can also order through our website: www.hoddereducation.com. © Peter Smith, Adam Wilby, Mila Zasheva 2021 First published in 2014 This edition published in 2021 by Hodder Education, An Hachette UK Company Carmelite House 50 Victoria Embankment London EC4Y 0DZ www.hoddereducation.com Impression number Year 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 2025 2024 2023 2022 2021 All rights reserved. Apart from any use permitted under UK copyright law, no part of this publication may be reproduced or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic or mechanical, including photocopying and recording, or held within any information storage and retrieval system, without permission in writing from the publisher or under licence from the Copyright Licensing Agency Limited. Further details of such licences (for reprographic reproduction) may be obtained from the Copyright Licensing Agency Limited, www.cla.co.uk Cover photo © kanzilyou – stock.adobe.com Illustrations by Aptara Typeset in India Printed in Slovenia A catalogue record for this title is available from the British Library. ISBN: 978 1 3983 0827 5 308275_FM_CAM_IASAL ECO_001_006.indd 2 20/03/21 10:47 AM Contents Get the most from this book 5 How to use this book 6 AS LEVEL Part 1 Basic economic ideas and resource allocation 1 Introducing economics Part 2 The price system and the microeconomy 2 3 4 Demand and supply curves Elasticity Market equilibrium and the price system Part 3 Government microeconomic intervention 5 The government in the microeconomy Part 4 The macroeconomy 6 7 8 9 10 National income Aggregate demand and aggregate supply analysis Economic growth Unemployment Price stability 7 7 24 24 40 54 73 73 88 88 97 114 125 134 Part 5 Government macroeconomic intervention 146 11 Macroeconomic policy Part 6 International economic issues 12 13 International trade and protectionism The balance of payments and exchange rates 146 164 164 182 3 308275_FM_CAM_IASAL ECO_001_006.indd 3 17/02/21 10:44 AM Contents A LEVEL Part 7 The price system and the microeconomy 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Marginal utility and consumer choice Efficiency and market failure Private costs and benefits, externalities and social costs and benefits Types of cost, revenue and profit, short-run and long-run production Different market structures: perfect competition and monopoly Different market structures: monopolistic competition and oligopoly The growth and objectives of firms 197 197 208 218 234 256 276 292 Part 8 Government microeconomic intervention 310 21 22 23 Government policies to achieve efficient resource allocation 310 and correct market failure Equity and redistribution of income and wealth 329 Labour market forces and government intervention 337 Part 9 The macroeconomy 24 25 26 27 The circular flow of income and the multiplier Economic growth and sustainability Employment and unemployment Money and banking 362 362 376 392 407 Part 10 Government macroeconomic intervention 423 28 Macroeconomic policy Part 11 International economic issues 29 30 31 32 The balance of payments and exchange rates Economic and human development Relationships between countries Globalisation 423 446 446 462 489 503 Glossary 516 Index 527 4 308275_FM_CAM_IASAL ECO_001_006.indd 4 17/02/21 10:44 AM Get the most from this book This textbook has been tailored explicitly to cover the Cambridge International AS & A Level Economics syllabus (9708) for first examination from 2023. The text provides the foundation for studying this qualification, but you will no doubt wish to keep up to date by referring to additional topical sources of information about economic events. This can be done by reading serious newspapers, visiting key sites on the internet, and reading magazines such as Economic Review. The syllabus is built around key concepts – the essential ideas, theories, principles or mental tools that help learners to develop a deep understanding of the subject and make links between different topics. An icon indicates where each key concept is covered. Scarcity and choice The fundamental problem in economics is that resources are scarce and wants are unlimited, so there is always a choice required between competing uses for the resources, and an opportunity cost in making this choice. markets and governments are able to respond to these changes in different ways depending on the time frame. Some economic decisions have a time frame element – trading off a cost in the present for a benefit in the future, for example. The margin and decision making In economic theory, decision making by consumers, firms and governments is based on choices at the margin – for example, firms will produce up to the point where the revenue generated by an extra unit of output is equal to the cost of producing it. However, economic decision making can be based on facts, theory, effectiveness, priorities/ objectives and values/ethical judgements. Efficiency and inefficiency Individual markets and the economy as a whole can be both efficient and inefficient in different ways when using scarce resources. The role of government and the issues of equality and equity There is a trade-off between, on one side, freedom for firms and individuals in unregulated markets and, on the other side, greater social equality and equity through government regulation of individuals and markets. Equilibrium and disequilibrium Individual markets and the economy as a whole are always moving into and out of equilibrium, constantly altering the allocation of resources. Progress and development Economics studies how societies can progress in measurable money terms and develop in a wider, more normative sense regarding living standards, inclusivity and sustainability. Time Economic conditions change in different time periods, such as the short run and the long run. Individuals, firms, Special features A LEVEL Economics ★ the distinction between equity and equality ★ the difference between equity and efficiency ★ absolute poverty and relative poverty ★ policies that can be adopted towards equity and inequality ★ the poverty trap In all countries, there is inequality in the distribution of income and wealth. In this chapter, we explore ways in which a government can attempt to influence the way in which resources are allocated among different groups in society, particularly in response to the presence of poverty. 22.1 Equity and inequality Regulation, equality and equity KEY TERMS inequality: where different groups within society receive differing amounts of income and/ or wealth equity: where people in the same situation receive equal treatment Some degree of inequality in the distribution of income within a society is inevitable. Individuals have different innate talents and abilities, and choose to undertake different types and levels of education and training. This means that they acquire different sets of skills, which open up different income-earning opportunities. Inequality also arises because of the pattern of ownership of assets. In other words, complete equality of income in a society (whereby everyone receives the same amount of income and wealth) can never be achieved. Provide another example of how some groups receive unequal treatment compared with others in your country. Bulleted summaries of each topic can be used as a revision tool. there are problems in terms of logistical and political problems. » Transfers from rich to poor households in the form of monetary benefits or benefits in kind are one of the most important ways of tackling inequality. » Such benefits can be universal (provided to all) or means tested. » Proposals have been discussed whereby a guaranteed safety net would be provided in the form of a universal basic income (UBI) that would be paid to everyone. » Pilot schemes have been launched in a number of countries around the world. » Problems can arise if benefit levels are set so high that individuals have little incentive to work — this is known as ‘the poverty trap’. taxation needs to be handled carefully to ensure that the net effect on the income distribution is as desired. LEARNING LINK END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS End of chapter questions to help you prepare for examination. 1 Read the following extract and then answer the questions that follow. Universal basic income: old hat or new fashion? A separate issue is whether there can be equity in the way that people are treated. One aspect of this is whether individuals face equal opportunities, and whether identical people receive identical treatment in economic terms. Many people would acknowledge that people in identical circumstances and with identical skills, abilities and experience should receive identical income. There are situations in which such equal treatment is not achieved. One example is that male and female workers receive unequal treatment in many societies. 5 The idea of a universal basic income (UBI) is nothing new — the notion has been around since the sixteenth century. More recently, libertarian economist Milton Friedman surprisingly endorsed its use through a negative income tax system. Friedman realised that even if an economy achieves Pareto optimality, a tradeoff might be required between efficiency and equity in policy design. Other proponents of UBI argue it is the best way to end absolute and relative poverty: just give everyone money! Some also say it will help society cope with the coming automation-induced job losses. SUMMARY: EQUITY AND EQUALITY In 2017, the Finnish government decided to see what would happen if, in a trial, 10 it chose 2,000 unemployed citizens at random and gave them Ð560 ($635) every » Inequality in the distribution of income and wealth occurs in all societies. » This results from differences in talents, abilities and experience, and from month for 2 years. Participants were assured they would keep receiving the UBI if they got a job. The trial ended in 2018 and the results are still being debated. differences in the ownership of assets. » Equity is where people in the same situation receive equal treatment. » Equity is also present in societies to some degree. 12 Page_006.indd 6 22 7/9/20 8:03 PM KEY TERMS headcount ratio: a measure of the percentage of a country’s population living below a poverty line 22 Equity and rEdistribution of incomE and wEalth International Poverty Line: an agreed measure that defines the absolute poverty line based on international prices, set at PPP$1.90 from October 2015 persistent poverty: where a household is currently in relative income poverty and has also been in this state in at least 2 of the preceding 3 years STUDY TIP This distinction between absolute and relative poverty is an important one. Absolute poverty is almost entirely confined to the less developed countries, but relative poverty can exist in any society, even in the more developed nations. A common way of measuring the poverty rate in a country is to estimate the percentage of the population living below a poverty line, known as a headcount ratio. The poverty line in this context is an estimate of the income needed to ensure basic human survival. People living below this level are perceived to be in absolute poverty. To enable international comparisons of poverty levels, the World Bank has defined an International Poverty Line. This is based on 2011 prices, and from October 2015 it was set at $1.90. The line has to be reset every few years in line with changing prices over time. The World Bank estimated that around 736 million people worldwide were living beneath this level in 2015 (down from 1.9 billion in 1990). Some individual countries also set their own national poverty line to reflect local conditions. Progress has been made to reduce the number of people living in absolute poverty on this definition, except in sub-Saharan Africa, where the number continues to rise. However, there was concern that poverty remained a problem, with people living on incomes that were not significantly higher than the International Poverty Line. In October 2018 the World Bank launched additional poverty lines to reflect typical national poverty lines in lower- and upper-middle-income countries. It was estimated that in 2015, over a quarter of the world’s population was surviving on less than $2.20 per day, and almost a half on less than $5.50 per day. Figure 22.1 shows estimates of the poverty headcount ratio for a range of countries around the world. For most developed economies, the headcount ratio at this level is zero or close to it. Italy is unusual in appearing on this graph, as relatively few developed countries have poverty on this measure. China Sri Lanka Italy Pakistan Brazil Indonesia Bangladesh Nepal South Africa India Zimbabwe Tanzania Zambia Uzbekistan Madagascar Explain why it is necessary to recalibrate the poverty line on a regular basis. Test yourself 22.3 Calculate the median adjusted household disposable income level for the UK in 2017, based on the fact that the UK relative poverty threshold is 60% of the median. 10 20 7/9/20 8:04 PM Case studies to show economic concepts applied to real-world situations. CASE STUDY 3.1 Acommonproblem Fishing and fisheries have been contentious in many countries. Who should have the rights to catch fish in international waters? Or should the seas be open to all? And how about a stretch of inland water such as Lake Victoria, the largest freshwater lake in Africa, which shares borders with Uganda, Kenya and Tanzania. 30 40 50 60 Follow-upquestions 1 How would you expect a market to evolve if the good has these characteristics of being non-excludable but rivalrous? 2 Give another example of where this problem could arise. EXTENSION MATERIAL Profitmaximisation The profit-maximising condition can be written as: wage = marginal revenue × marginal physical product of labour which is the same as: marginal revenue = wage ÷ MPP L Extension points to stretch your understanding. Remember that capital input is fixed for the firm in the short run, so the wage divided by the MPPL is the firm’s cost per unit of output at the margin. This shows that the profit-maximising condition is the same as that derived for a profit-maximising firm in Chapter 17: in other words, profit is maximised where marginal revenue equals marginal cost. This is just another way of looking at the firm’s decision. QUANTITATIVE SKILLS 17.2 Table 17.2 provides an arithmetic example to illustrate the relationship between these different aspects of costs. The firm represented here faces fixed costs of £225 per week. The table shows the costs of production for up to 6,000 units of the firm’s product per week. Column 3 shows total variable costs of production: you can see that these rise quite steeply as the volume of production increases. Adding fixed and variable costs gives the total costs at each output level. This is shown in column 4, which is the sum of columns 2 and 3. 70 80 % of population Source: based on data from World Development Indicators ▼ Table 17.2Theshort-runrelationshipbetweenoutputandcosts(in£s) ▲ Figure 22.1 Poverty headcount ratio at $1.90 (% of population) (1) Output (000 units per week) In Europe (including the UK), estimates of poverty are based on a regular survey of households conducted in EU member states and some other selected countries. In 2017, the UK’s threshold for poverty was set at £12,597. This is based on adjustments for household size and composition. Households with income below this are described as being in relative income poverty (or being ‘at risk of poverty’); households that experience this in the current year and at least 2 of the 3 preceding years are said to be in persistent poverty. 1 2 Figure 22.2 presents some data for a range of European countries in 2017. The proportion of people below the relative poverty line varies substantially across these countries, from 11.5% in Finland to 23.6% in Romania. (2) Fixed costs (STFC) 225 225 (3) Total variable costs (STVC) 85 150 3 225 210 4 225 300 (4) Total costs (2) +(3) (STC) 310 375 (5) Average total cost (4)/(1) (SATC) 310 187.5 (6) Marginal cost ∆(4)/∆(1) (SMC) 65 60 435 145 525 131.25 175 5 225 475 700 140 395 6 225 870 1,095 182.5 90 (7) (8) Average Average variable fixed cost cost (3)/(1) (2)/(1) (SAVC) (SAFC) 85 225 75 112.5 70 75 75 56.25 95 145 Worked examples of quantitative skills that you will need to develop. 45 37.5 14 8 310445_22_Cambridge_006-014.indd 8 Page_012.indd 12 Therelationshipbetweenoutputandcosts 0 Test yourself 22.2 Test yourself: short questions designed to allow you to check your understanding of key concepts. treated: for example, through encouraging equal opportunities. » One approach to tackling inequality is to implement a negative income tax, but » The balance between (progressive) direct taxation and (regressive) indirect 6 Study tips: short pieces of advice to help you present your ideas effectively and avoid potential pitfalls. SUMMARY: POLICIES TOWARDS EQUITY AND INEQUALITY » Policy towards equity needs to promote fairness in the way that people are Chapter 5 introduced some key concepts related to inequality in the distribution of income in a society, and ways in which the degree of inequality can be measured. It also explained the distinction between income and wealth. Test yourself 22.1 Key terms: clear, concise definitions of essential key terms where they first appear. Imagine that you are the Minister for Poverty Alleviation in a country in which the (absolute) poverty line is set at $500. Of the people living below the poverty line, you know that there are two distinct groups, each made up of 50 individuals. The people in group 1 have an income of $450, whereas those in group 2 have only $250. Suppose that your budget for poverty alleviation is $2,500. a Your prime concern is with the most needy: how would you use your budget? b Suppose instead that your prime minister instructs you to reduce the percentage of people living below the poverty line: do you adopt the same strategy for using the funds? c How helpful is the poverty line as a strategic target of policy action? 22 EQUITY AND REDISTRIBUTION OF INCOME AND WEALTH What this chapter covers Exercises to provide active engagement with economic analysis. EXERCISE 22.1 Equity and redistribution of income and wealth 22 EQUITY AND REDISTRIBUTION OF INCOME AND WEALTH Learning links show the connections between themes and cross-reference further treatment of topics. 22 22 Equity and rEdistribution of incomE and wEalth A statement of the key topics covered in each chapter. 7/9/20 1:33 PM Page_014.indd 14 7/9/20 9:35 PM 5 308275_FM_CAM_IASAL ECO_001_006.indd 5 17/02/21 10:44 AM How to use this book How to use this book Welcome to economics – or, if you have previously studied this subject, welcome back. This book is designed to help you learn, revise, test yourself and practise your knowledge and skills application for the Cambridge International AS & A Level Economics 9708 syllabus for examination from 2023. Any subject or field of expertise requires a solid theoretical background, and economics is no exception. It is the application of skills in an unfamiliar context that defines where the static content of a textbook transits into the dynamic world of real economics. This textbook offers a clear progression through the topics to support students transitioning from previous study in economics as well as those studying economics for the first time: » We start with easing the way into the basic economic ideas – the building blocks of the course, for example the basic economic problem. » We then introduce the principles of micro- and macroeconomics, while studying the behaviour of economic agents and the consequences of government policies. » The concepts of international trade present the big picture of economic relations between countries in today’s sometimes turbulent world. During this journey, the skills acquired and honed will help you to learn, make links and discuss key relationships, dependencies, causes and effects of the above. This is underpinned by the seven key concepts introduced on page 5. They are the anchor points of your course and the tools an economist uses to study the behaviour of individuals, firms and governments, markets and national economies. Acknowledging the importance and role of these key concepts is a step towards putting together the different sections of this textbook into a coherent understanding of the principles of economics. The key concepts resurface in different topics across the textbook and are signposted to flag the relationships to look out for. The icons act as quick reminders to revisit the concepts and encourage you to take a more holistic approach to the subject. Going beyond the textbook As you progress through the course, you will find that there is far more to economics than what fits between the covers of any textbook. Our Cambridge International AS & A Level Economics Workbook from the same series is available to enhance your academic experience by providing guidance for developing and applying your skills and knowledge, for example by using diagrams and practising your quantitative skills, as well as engaging with a variety of multiple-choice, data response and essay-style questions that follow the order of this textbook. The series of publications also offers support for teachers – our Cambridge International AS & A Level Economics Teacher Resource Pack is aimed at both new and experienced teachers to help them deliver a structured and engaging economics course that encourages students to pursue the subject further and beyond the school classrooms. This textbook provides the foundation for studying this qualification, but you will no doubt wish to keep up to date by referring to additional topical sources of information about economic events. The team of authors wish you a successful and enjoyable journey as you discover the world of economics. Test yourself, exercises and case studies Answers to the test yourself questions and commentaries on the exercises and case study questions can be found at: hoddereducation.com/cambridgeextras End of chapter questions The practice questions in this book are designed to help you apply your knowledge and skills learnt throughout this course. They do not follow the exact formulation in the exam – for example, the number of parts in data response questions in this book may not always necessarily reflect the number that would appear in an exam. Guidance for answers to the end of chapter questions is available in our Cambridge International AS & A Level Economics Teacher Resource Pack. 6 308275_FM_CAM_IASAL ECO_001_006.indd 6 18/03/21 2:49 PM AS LEVEL PART 1 Basic economic ideas and resource allocation 1 Introducing economics 1 Introducing economics What this chapter covers ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ the fundamental economic problem scarcity, choice and opportunity cost decision making at the margin basic questions of resource allocation economics as a social science positive and normative statements the importance of the time period ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ factors of production the division of labour and specialisation the role of the entrepreneur resource allocation in different economic systems production possibility curves classification of goods and services: free goods, private goods, public goods, merit and demerit goods Welcome to economics. Many of you opening this book will be meeting economics for the first time, and you will want to know what is in store for you as you set out to study the subject. This opening chapter sets the scene by introducing you to some key ideas and identifying the scope of economic analysis. As you learn more of the subject, you will find that economics is a way of thinking that will broaden your perspective on the world around you. 1.1 Scarcity, choice and opportunity cost KEY TERM scarcity: a situation that arises because people have unlimited wants in the face of limited resources Test yourself 1.1 Thinking of yourself, give an example of a ‘want’ and a ‘need’. The fundamental economic problem faced by any society in the world is that of scarcity. For countries in sub-Saharan Africa or parts of South Asia, it seems obvious that there is scarcity. However, it is also true of relatively prosperous economies such as those of Switzerland, the USA and the UK. It is true in the sense that all societies have finite resources, but people have unlimited wants. A big claim? Not really. There is no country in the world in which all wants can be met, and this is clearly true at the global level. There is a difference between wants and needs. Everyone needs to breathe and to eat, so air and food are necessary for human life. However, people would like to consume goods that are not strictly essential to maintain life, such as ice cream or designer clothes. These are known as wants. Talking about scarcity in this sense is not the same as talking about poverty. Poverty might be seen as an extreme form of scarcity, in which individuals lack the basic necessities of life – whereas even relatively prosperous people face scarcity because resources are limited. Scarcity and choice The key issue that arises from the existence of scarcity is that it forces people, firms (businesses) and governments to make choices. Each individual must choose which goods and services to consume. In other words, everyone needs to prioritise the consumption of whatever commodities they need or would like to have, as they cannot satisfy all their wants. Firms need to make choices about what to produce, and what techniques of production to use. At the national level, governments have to make choices between alternative uses of resources. 7 308275_C01_CAM_IASAL ECO_007_023.indd 7 18/03/21 10:07 AM It is this need to choose that underlies the subject matter of economics. Economic analysis is about analysing those choices made by individual people, firms or governments. 1 The margin and decision making KEY TERMS AS LEVEL PART 1 BASIC ECONOMIC IDEAS AND RESOURCE ALLOCATION marginal principle: the idea that economic agents may take decisions by considering the effect of small changes from the existing situation microeconomics: the study of economic decisions taken by individual economic agents, including households and firms macroeconomics: the study of the interrelationships between economic variables at an aggregate (economywide) level LEARNING LINK The marginal approach is explored more fully in Chapter 14. Test yourself 1.2 Give examples of ways in which government spends its funds. The notion of ‘the margin’ is important in much of economic analysis. Decisionmakers – whether they be firms or consumers – are seen to take decisions with reference to small changes in behaviour. For example, a firm may decide whether to increase its output by an extra unit by checking whether the additional revenue that it would receive from selling the extra unit will compensate for the additional cost of producing it. A consumer may decide whether the extra benefit of consuming an additional can of cola is worth the price to be paid for it. This is known as the marginal principle. You will meet this approach to decision making in a variety of situations as you study economics. At the heart of much of economic analysis is the notion that economic agents have clear objectives, and that they take decisions that allow them to do the best that they can to achieve those objectives. For example, it is often assumed that consumers set out to gain as much satisfaction from consuming goods and services as they can. Their decisions can be analysed by looking at small changes from their current position, seeing whether a small (marginal) change can improve their satisfaction. Choices are made at different levels When we come to explain how choices are made, it is helpful to be aware that choices are taken by different sets of economic agents, and at different levels. Individuals (people or households) take decisions about what goods and services to consume, and about how much labour to supply. Firms (businesses) face choices about what to produce and how to produce it. Governments need to take decisions about their spending and taxation policies. Microeconomics and macroeconomics Economic thinking is applied in different ways, depending on whether the focus is on the decisions taken by individual agents in the economy or on the interaction between economic variables at the level of the whole economy. Microeconomics deals with individual decisions taken by households or firms, or in particular markets. Macroeconomics examines the interactions between economic variables at the level of the whole economy. For example, it might examine the effect of a change in income taxes on the level of unemployment, or of the interest rate on total demand and the rate of inflation. In some ways the division between the two types of analysis is artificial. The same sort of economic reasoning is applied in both types, but the focus is different. EXERCISE 1.1 Think about the following, and see whether you think each represents a macroeconomic or microeconomic phenomenon. a The overall level of prices in an economy b The price of ice cream c The overall rate of unemployment in an economy d The unemployment rate among catering workers in Karachi e The average wage paid to construction workers in Kuala Lumpur 8 308275_C01_CAM_IASAL ECO_007_023.indd 8 16/02/21 5:21 PM Opportunity cost KEY TERM opportunity cost: in decision making, the value of the next-best alternative forgone One of the most important concepts in all of economic analysis is the notion of opportunity cost. When an individual chooses to consume one good, he or she does so at the cost of the item that would have been next in their list of priorities. For example, suppose you have enough money in your pocket either for a can of cola or for a snack from a street vendor. If you choose the cola, the opportunity cost of the cola is the snack that you could have had instead. In other words, the opportunity cost is the value of the next-best alternative forgone. 1 1 Introducing economics EXERCISE 1.2 Abdul has just started his AS courses, and has chosen to take economics, mathematics and geography, plus either French or English. What is Abdul’s opportunity cost of choosing French? This important notion can be applied in many different contexts because whenever you make a decision, you reject an alternative in favour of your chosen option. You have chosen to read this book, when instead you could be out with your friends. ▲ Sweet potatoes Test yourself 1.3 Suppose your school or college wants to build a new sports hall. Identify possible elements of the opportunity cost of such a project. As you move further into studying economics, you will encounter the notion of opportunity cost again and again. For example, firms take decisions about the sort of economic activity in which to engage. A farmer with limited land available has to decide whether to plant onions or sweet potatoes; if they decide to grow onions, they have to forgo the opportunity to grow sweet potatoes. From the government’s point of view, if it decides to devote more resources to the provision of healthcare, it will have fewer resources available for, say, defence. STUDY TIP Opportunity cost is a key concept in economics, and will be important in a variety of contexts. In particular, it captures the way in which economists take decisions, which may be quite different from how non-economists approach choice. Make sure you understand it and watch for situations in which it is relevant. Basic questions of resource allocation The choices that are made by people, firms and governments influence the way in which a society allocates its resources, and this is at the heart of the subject matter of economics. The US economist Paul Samuelson (who won the Nobel Prize for Economic Sciences in 1970) identified three key questions that economics sets out to investigate: 1 What? What goods and services should be produced in a society from its scarce resources? In other words, how should resources be allocated among producing cars, potatoes, banking services and so on? 2 How? How should the productive resources of the economy be used to produce these various goods and services? 3 For whom? Having produced a range of goods and services, how should these be allocated among the population for consumption? EXERCISE 1.3 With which of Samuelson’s three questions (what, how, for whom) would you associate the following? a A firm chooses to switch from producing DVDs in order to increase its output of Blu-ray discs. b The government reduces the highest rate of income tax. c Faced with increased labour costs, a firm introduces labour-saving machinery. d There is an increase in social security benefits. e The owner of a curry house decides to close down and take a job in a local factory. 9 308275_C01_CAM_IASAL ECO_007_023.indd 9 16/02/21 5:21 PM AS LEVEL PART 1 BASIC ECONOMIC IDEAS AND RESOURCE ALLOCATION 1 SUMMARY: SCARCITY, CHOICE AND OPPORTUNITY COST » The fundamental problem faced by any society is scarcity, because resources are finite but wants are unlimited. As a result, choices need to be made. » Choices need to be made at all levels (individuals, households, firms, government). » Microeconomics deals with individual decisions made by consumers and producers, whereas macroeconomics analyses the interactions between economic variables in the economy as a whole – but both use similar ways of thinking. » Each choice has an opportunity cost – the value of the next-best alternative. » Economics deals with the questions of what should be produced, how it should be produced, and for whom. 1.2 Economic methodology Economics as a social science KEY TERM model: a simplified representation of reality used to provide insight into economic decisions and events Economics sets out to tackle some complex issues concerning what is a very complex real world. This complexity is such that it is essential to simplify reality in some way; otherwise the task would be overwhelming. Economists therefore work with models. These are simplified versions of reality that are more straightforward to analyse, allowing economists to focus on some key aspects of the world. In evaluating a model, it is always important to examine the assumptions that are made, and to ask what happens if these assumptions do not hold. Consumer behaviour is explored more fully in Chapter 14; the objectives of firms are discussed in Chapter 20. The use of models is one way in which economists try to approach their discipline in a ‘scientific’ manner. Much of economics is about human behaviour. This complicates matters because humans do not all act in the same way as each other – and may not even act the same on different days. This makes individual behaviour difficult to predict or explain. However, when we are dealing with large numbers of people, we can be reasonably sure about how they will behave on average. A key assumption made in mainstream economics is that economic agents act rationally. Consumers take decisions that will bring them as much satisfaction as possible, and firms take decisions that allow them to make as much profit as possible. The approach taken by economists justifies the claim that economics is a ‘social science’. KEY TERMS Positive and normative statements positive statement: a statement about what is, i.e. about facts Economics tries to be objective in analysis. However, some of its subject matter requires careful attention in order to avoid being subjective. In this connection, it is important to be clear about the difference between positive and normative statements. LEARNING LINK normative statement: a statement involving a value judgement that is about what ought to be value judgement: a statement based on your opinion or beliefs, rather than on facts STUDY TIP There are some words that betray normative statements, such as ‘should’ or ‘ought to’ – you should watch for these. In short, a positive statement is about facts. In contrast, a normative statement is about what ought to be. Another way of looking at this is that a statement becomes normative when it involves an opinion or value judgement. Suppose the government is considering raising the tax on cigarettes. It may legitimately consult economists to discover what effect a higher tobacco tax will have on the consumption of cigarettes and on government revenues. This would be a positive investigation, in that the economists are being asked to use economic analysis to forecast what will happen when the tax is increased. A very different situation will arise if the government asks whether it should raise the tax on cigarettes. This moves the economists beyond positive analysis because it involves a value judgement – so it is now a normative analysis. Most of this book is about positive economics. However, you should be aware that positive analysis is often called upon to inform normative judgements. If the aim of a policy is to stop people from smoking (which reflects a normative judgement about 10 308275_C01_CAM_IASAL ECO_007_023.indd 10 16/02/21 5:21 PM Test yourself 1.4 Is the following a normative or a positive statement? ‘The government ought to raise unemployment benefits.’ ceteris paribus: a Latin phrase meaning ‘other things being equal’; it is used in economics when we focus on changes in one variable while holding other influences constant Critics of economics often joke that economists always disagree with one another: for example, it has been said that if you put five economists in a room together, they will come up with at least six conflicting opinions. However, although economists may arrive at different value judgements, and thus have differences when it comes to normative issues, there is much greater agreement when it comes to positive analysis. Ceteris paribus Often models work by allowing them to focus on one thing at a time. A model almost always begins with assumptions that help economists to simplify their questions. These assumptions can then be gradually relaxed so that the effect of each one of them can be observed. In this way, economists can move towards a more complicated version of reality. A common example is where we want to focus on one particular aspect of an economic issue or variable, and assume that other things remain constant. This is captured by the Latin phrase ‘ceteris paribus’. 1 1 Introducing economics KEY TERM what ought to happen), then economic analysis may be used to highlight the strengths and weaknesses of alternative policy measures in a purely positive fashion. The importance of the time period LEARNING LINK We return to this issue at the end of section 1.3. Notice that the timescale over which decisions are made is important. Firms and consumers may not be able to adjust their behaviour very much in the short run, as they may be committed to decisions already made. In the long run, they may be able to be more flexible – for example, firms can hire more labour and install new capital. Consumers may need time to adjust to changing market conditions, or to change their buying habits. SUMMARY: ECONOMIC METHODOLOGY » Economists work with models that help to simplify reality. » Positive statements are about what is, whereas normative statements are about what ought to be. » The ceteris paribus assumption helps economists to focus on key issues, holding other things constant. » The time period over which decisions are taken has an important influence on the outcomes. 1.3 Factors of production People in a society play two quite different roles. On the one hand, they are the consumers, the ultimate beneficiaries of the process of production. On the other, they are a key part of the production process in that they are essential in producing goods and services. KEY TERM factors of production: resources used in the production process; inputs into production, including labour, capital, land and enterprise More generally, it is clear that both human resources and physical resources are required as part of the production process. These productive resources are known as the factors of production. The most obvious human resource is labour. Labour is a key input into production. Of course, there are many different types of labour, encompassing different skill levels and working in different ways. Enterprise (or ‘entrepreneurship’) is another human resource that is seen as increasingly important in the economy. An entrepreneur is someone who organises production and identifies potentially profitable projects to be undertaken. Management is also sometimes classified as a human resource, although it might be seen as a particular form of labour. 11 308275_C01_CAM_IASAL ECO_007_023.indd 11 16/02/21 5:21 PM Natural resources are also inputs into the production process. In particular, all economic activities require some use of land, and most use some raw materials. An important distinction here is between renewable resources such as forests, and non-renewable resources such as oil or coal. 1 AS LEVEL PART 1 BASIC ECONOMIC IDEAS AND RESOURCE ALLOCATION There are also produced resources – inputs that are the product of a previous manufacturing process. If you like, these can be regarded as a stock of past production used to aid current production. For example, machines are used in the production process; they are resources manufactured for the purpose of producing other goods. These inputs are referred to as fixed capital, which includes things like factory buildings and transport equipment as well as plant and machinery. Firms also need working capital, made up of goods that are used up during the production process. ▲ Fixed capital includes machinery The way in which these inputs are combined in order to produce output is another important part of the allocation of resources. Firms need to take decisions about the mix of inputs used in order to produce their output. Such decisions are required in whatever form of economic activity a firm is engaged. EXERCISE 1.4 Classify each of the following as human, natural (renewable or non-renewable) or produced resources: a Timber b Services of a window cleaner c Natural gas Test yourself 1.5 Give an example of each of the four factors of production. d Solar energy e A tractor f A computer programmer who sets up a company to market his software g A computer Rewards to the factors of production The factors of production need to be rewarded in return for the services that they provide. Labour When households supply their labour, they do so in return for wages and salaries. The wage is the reward for the labour services that households supply, for which they must give up their leisure time. 12 308275_C01_CAM_IASAL ECO_007_023.indd 12 16/02/21 5:21 PM Capital Interest is regarded as the return on the use of capital services. It is the return that the firm gains from using the capital goods in the production process. In doing this, the firm forgoes the interest that it could have gained from investing in a financial asset. 1 Enterprise Land In the case of land, it is the rental that constitutes the reward for the use of land in production. Division of labour and specialisation KEY TERM division of labour and specialisation: a process whereby the production procedure is broken down into a sequence of stages, and workers are assigned to specialise in particular stages according to their skills STUDY TIP Notice that a key difference between physical and human capital is that a firm owns its physical capital, but cannot own its workers. STUDY TIP Be careful to avoid confusing ‘production’ (the output of a good) with ‘productivity’ (the efficiency with which a good is produced). How many workers does it take to make a pin? The eighteenth-century British economist Adam Smith figured that ten was about the right number. He argued that when a worker was producing pins on his own, carrying out all the various stages involved in the production process, the maximum number of pins that could be produced in one day was 20 – given the technology of his day, of course. This would imply that ten workers could produce about 200 pins if they worked in the same way as the lone worker. However, if the pin production process were broken into ten separate stages, with one worker specialising in each stage, the maximum production for a day’s work would be a staggering 48,000. This is known as division of labour. 1 Introducing economics Profit is seen as the reward for enterprise. By recognising income-earning opportunities for the firm and by taking on the risk, the entrepreneur is able to make profit for the business. The division of labour is effective because individual workers become skilled at performing specialised tasks. By focusing on a particular stage, they can become highly adept, and thus more efficient, at carrying out that task. In any case, people are not all the same, so some are better at certain activities. Furthermore, this specialisation is more efficient because workers do not spend time moving from one activity to another. Specialisation may also enable firms to operate on a larger scale of production. You will see later that this may be advantageous. This can be seen in practice in many businesses today, where there is considerable specialisation of functions. Workers are hired for particular tasks and activities. You do not see your star striker putting on the goalkeeper’s jersey at half time because they fancy a change. Earlier in the chapter, it was argued that ‘labour’ is considered a factor of production. This idea will now be developed further by arguing that there are different types of labour, having different skills and functions. The stock of skills and expertise that contribute to a worker’s productivity is known as human capital. The amount of output produced per worker is known as labour productivity. Although we refer to the division of labour, we can extend these arguments to consider specialisation among firms, or even among nations. For example, consider car manufacturing. The process of mass producing cars does not all take place within a single firm. One firm may specialise in producing tyres; another may produce windscreens; another may focus on assembling the final product. Here again, specialisation enables efficiency gains to be made. At national level, specialisation again takes place, simply because some countries are better equipped to produce some products than others. For example, it would not make sense for the UK to go into commercial production of pineapples or mangoes. There are other countries with climatic conditions that are much more suitable for producing these products. Most Formula 1 racing teams have their headquarters in the UK, and there are benefits from this specialisation. 13 308275_C01_CAM_IASAL ECO_007_023.indd 13 16/02/21 5:21 PM The advantages and disadvantages of specialisation AS LEVEL PART 1 BASIC ECONOMIC IDEAS AND RESOURCE ALLOCATION 1 Everyone is different. Individuals have different natural talents and abilities that make them good at different things. Indeed, there are some lucky people who seem to be good at everything. From society’s point of view, specialisation allows the better use of limited resources, so that overall the economy can produce more. However, although there may be many advantages that flow from specialisation, it is also important to realise that there may be a downside if individuals, firms or countries overspecialise. If workers spend all of their time on repetitive tasks, they are likely to get bored, and begin to lose concentration and job satisfaction. In other words, the tedium of their tasks may lead them to become careless and inefficient. If a firm focuses on production of a very narrow range of products and then finds that demand is falling for those products, then it will face difficulties. It may thus be advisable to maintain some diversity in the output range, in the hope that demand will not fall for all products simultaneously. Complete specialisation may not always be the best way for a firm to become successful in the long run. Test yourself 1.6 Name a possible disadvantage of overspecialisation in production. Nations may also find problems if they overspecialise. For example, it could be argued that all nations should retain some agricultural activity for strategic reasons. If a nation were to be completely dependent on imported foodstuffs, and then became engaged in a war, this could leave the country in a very vulnerable position. Indeed, this was one of the motivations for the establishment of what would become the European Union. The role of the entrepreneur Test yourself 1.7 Give one reason why a household might not be able to change its spending behaviour in the short run. Enterprise provides dynamism and innovation in an economy, especially within the sector dominated by small and medium-sized firms. The role of the entrepreneur in contemporary economies is viewed as being especially important. An effective entrepreneur is able to identify potential income-earning opportunities for businesses and is willing to assess and bear the risk involved in embarking on new projects or start-ups. The entrepreneur is also responsible for organising the other factors of production in the most efficient and effective way. Defining time periods KEY TERMS short run: the period over which a firm is free to vary its input of one factor of production (labour), but faces fixed inputs of the other factors of production long run: the period over which the firm is able to vary the inputs of all its factors of production very long run: the period over which the firm is able to vary the inputs of all its factors of production and in which technological change may occur and the government policy environment may alter The way in which ‘time’ is treated in economics is important. In economic thinking, time is not seen in terms of a specific period, like a month, year or decade. Instead, time is important because decisions cannot be taken and implemented immediately. It takes time for a firm, consumer or government to change behaviour, and for those changes to take effect. Think about this from the viewpoint of a firm wanting to expand its production. In the short run, the firm may not be able to bring in new machinery, or rent more buildings, but it may be able to hire more workers, or persuade its current workforce to work longer hours. In other words, in the short run, labour may be flexible, but capital and other factors of production are likely to be fixed. In the long run, the firm may also be able to bring more capital into the production process. In the very long run, the firm may be able to adopt new technologies and adjust to changes in government policy and the external environment. LEARNING LINK The significance of time in affecting firms’ decisions is explored more carefully in Chapter 17. 14 308275_C01_CAM_IASAL ECO_007_023.indd 14 16/02/21 5:21 PM SUMMARY: FACTORS OF PRODUCTION » The amount of output produced in a period important in contemporary economies by identifying income-earning opportunities and being willing to bear risk. » Some factors of production are more readily varied in the short run, underlining the importance of the timescale of decision making. 1.4 Resource allocation in different economic systems With so many different individuals and organisations (consumers, firms, governments) all taking decisions, a major question is how it all comes together. How are all these separate decisions coordinated so that the overall allocation of resources in a society is coherent? In other words, how can it be ensured that firms produce the commodities that consumers wish to consume? And how can the distribution of these products be organised? These are some of the basic questions that economics sets out to answer. LEARNING LINK The way in which prices guide the allocation of resources is explained in Chapter 4; Chapter 21 discusses ways in which the government seeks to ensure that the price mechanism works effectively, and explains the importance of property rights. KEY TERMS market economy: market forces are allowed to guide the allocation of resources within a society centrally planned economy: decisions on resource allocation are guided by the state 1 1 Introducing economics depends on the inputs of factors of production: labour, capital, enterprise and land. » The factors of production are rewarded by wages and salaries, interest, profits and rents. » Adam Smith introduced the notion of division of labour, which suggests that workers can become more productive by specialising in stages of the production process. » Entrepreneurs are seen as being especially Market economies A market economy is one in which market forces are allowed to guide the allocation of resources within a society. Prices play the key role in this sort of system, providing signals and incentives to producers and consumers. Consumers express changes in their preferences by their decisions to buy (or not to buy) at the going price. This is then a signal to firms, which are able to respond to changes in consumer demand, given the incentive of profitability, which is related to price. The government’s role in a free-market economy is limited, but nonetheless important. The government needs to provide a stable and secure environment in which markets can work effectively. Households, firms and entrepreneurs need to have secure ownership rights if they are to face the right incentives to consume, produce and innovate. Within such a system, consumers try to maximise the satisfaction they gain from consuming a range of products, and firms seek to maximise their profits by responding to consumer demand through the medium of price signals. Centrally planned economies In contrast, a centrally planned economy is one in which the government undertakes the coordination role, planning and directing the allocation of resources. Given the complexity of modern economies, reliance on central planning poses enormous decision-making dilemmas. In order to achieve a satisfactory allocation of resources across the economy, the government needs to make decisions on thousands of individual matters. Micromanagement on this sort of scale is costly to implement administratively. The collapse of the Soviet bloc in the 1990s largely discredited this approach, although a small number of countries (such as North Korea and Cuba) continue to stick with central planning. China has moved away from pure central planning by allowing prices to be used as signals. 15 308275_C01_CAM_IASAL ECO_007_023.indd 15 16/02/21 5:21 PM AS LEVEL PART 1 BASIC ECONOMIC IDEAS AND RESOURCE ALLOCATION 1 EXTENSION MATERIAL An example of decision making under central planning An example of the sorts of issues that can arise under central planning comes from the experience in Russia after the 1917 revolution. Factories were given production targets to fit in with the overall plan for the development of the economy. These targets then had to be met by the factory managers, who faced strong incentives to meet those targets. Factories producing nails were given two sorts of targets. Some factories were given a target to produce a certain number of nails, whereas others were given targets in weight terms. The former responded by producing large numbers of very small nails; the latter produced a very small number of very big nails. Neither was what the planners had in mind! Mixed economies Almost every country in the world now operates a mixed economy system; even a country such as the USA, where market forces are relatively free, is a mixed economy. In such a system, prices provide signals to firms and consumers, but the government intervenes by providing market infrastructure and by influencing the allocation of resources through imposing taxes and undertaking expenditure and through regulation. As this course progresses, you will see a variety of ways in which such intervention takes place, and will come to understand the reasoning that underpins such intervention – especially in situations where the free market fails to produce the best possible allocation of resources. KEY TERMS mixed economy: resources are allocated partly through price signals and partly on the basis of direction by government transition economies: countries that moved from central planning to being a mixed economy The extent to which the state intervenes in resource allocation varies across countries. North Korea is an example of a country that operates in a way that most resembles a centrally planned economy. The USA is often quoted as an example of an economy in which the government does intervene in some areas but allows markets to have a strong influence on how resources are allocated. There is a spectrum of state involvement, with Cuba tending towards central planning and many European countries such as the UK and Germany have greater reliance on markets. Countries such as Russia and China come somewhere in between. It has been argued that any such state intervention should be market-friendly: in other words, when governments intervene in the economy, they should do so in a way that helps markets to work, rather than trying to have the government replace market forces. Transition economies Test yourself 1.8 Name an example of a mixed economy. LEARNING LINK The role of the entrepreneur was explained in the previous section. The transition from a centrally planned economy to a mixed economy can be painful. This was seen in the break-up of the Soviet bloc in the 1990s, when countries in eastern Europe went through a difficult time both economically and politically, facing impacts on employment, output and inflation. During the transition period, both firms and consumers need to become accustomed to the idea that they have increased freedom to make decisions, and that prices need to adjust and take a more active role in providing signals and incentives. People and firms need to get used to the idea that they need to take risk, rather than depending on the state to take decisions for them. Governments need to move away from trying to micro-manage economic decision making and allow market forces to take over the coordination role. The role of entrepreneurs in these transition economies was especially important. They were the ones who needed to recognise opportunities and be willing to take on risk. In the process, many of them were able to reap rewards in terms of profit. 16 308275_C01_CAM_IASAL ECO_007_023.indd 16 16/02/21 5:21 PM SUMMARY: RESOURCE ALLOCATION IN DIFFERENT ECONOMIC SYSTEMS » Resource allocation concerns the way in which a society deploys its productive assets among alternative uses. » Alternative choices about resource allocation have implications for the wellbeing of society. » Society faces a coordination problem in seeking to find a good pattern of resource allocation. » The coordination problem is tackled in different ways in market, centrally planned and mixed economies. production possibility curve (PPC): a curve showing the maximum combinations of goods or services that can be produced in a set period of time given available resources and the state of technology The nature and meaning of a production possibility curve Economists rely heavily on diagrams to help in their analysis and to interpret their models. In exploring the notion of opportunity cost, a helpful diagram is the production possibility curve (PPC ). This shows the maximum combinations of goods that can be produced with a given set of resources and technology. First consider a simple example. In Exercise 1.2, Abdul was studying for his AS. Suppose now that he has got behind with his homework. He has limited time available, and has five economics questions to answer and five maths exercises to do. An economics question takes the same time to answer as a maths exercise. 1 Introducing economics 1.5 Production possibility curves KEY TERM 1 Maths exercises What are the options? Suppose he knows that in the time available he can tackle either all of the maths and none of the economics, or all of the economics and none of the maths. Alternatively, he can try to keep both teachers happy by doing some of each. Figure 1.1 shows his options. 6 A 5 4 D C 3 2 E 1 0 B 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Economics problems ▲ Figure 1.1 The production possibility curve He can devote all of his efforts to maths, and leave the economics for another day. He will then be at point A in the figure. Alternatively, he can do all the economics exercises and no maths, and be at point B. The line joining these two extreme points shows the intermediate possibilities. For example, at C he does two economics exercises and three maths problems. The line shows the maximum combinations that Abdul can tackle – which is why it is sometimes called a ‘frontier’. There is no way he can manage to be beyond the frontier (for example, at point D), as he does not have the time (i.e. resources) to do so. However, he could end up inside the frontier, at a point such as E. This could happen if he gives up, and squanders his time by watching television; that would be an inefficient use of his resources – at least in terms of tackling his homework. Opportunity cost and the PPC As Abdul moves down the line from left to right in Figure 1.1, he is spending more time on economics and less on maths. The opportunity cost of tackling an additional economics question is an additional maths exercise forgone. The PPC in this case is a straight line because the opportunity cost of tackling an additional economics question is constant. 17 308275_C01_CAM_IASAL ECO_007_023.indd 17 16/02/21 5:21 PM Figure 1.2 shows how the PPC provides information about opportunity cost. Suppose we have a farmer with 10 hectares of land who is choosing between growing sweet potatoes and onions. The PPC shows the combinations of the two crops that could be produced. For example, if the farmer produces 300 tonnes of onions on part of the land, then 180 tonnes of sweet potatoes could be produced from the remaining land. In order to increase production of potatoes by 70 tonnes from 180 to 250, 50 tonnes of onions must be given up. Thus, the opportunity cost of 70 extra tonnes of sweet potatoes is seen to be 50 tonnes of onions. Onions (tonnes) 450 400 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 0 PPC 0 100 180 200 250 300 400 500 Sweet potatoes (tonnes) ▲ Figure 1.2 Opportunity cost and the production possibility curve KEY TERMS investment: expenditure undertaken by firms to add to the capital stock; an increase in the capital stock consumption: household spending on goods and services in the economy We can also imagine a production possibility curve for a whole economy, as long as we are prepared to simplify reality. Assume that an economy produces just two types of good: capital goods and consumer goods. Capital goods are goods that are to be used to increase the future capacity of the economy. For example, you might think of machinery, trucks or factory buildings that will be used to produce other goods in the future. Expenditure on such goods is known as investment. In contrast, consumer goods are for present use. They are goods that people consume, such as apples, televisions and private cars. This sort of expenditure is known as consumption. Figure 1.3 illustrates society’s options in a particular period. Given the resources available, society can produce any combination of capital and consumer goods along the PPC. Thus, point A represents one possible combination of outputs, in which the economy produces C1 consumer goods and K1 capital goods. Capital goods per period AS LEVEL PART 1 BASIC ECONOMIC IDEAS AND RESOURCE ALLOCATION 1 B A K1 C PPC 0 C1 Consumer goods per period ▲ Figure 1.3 Capital and consumer goods As with the simpler examples, if society were to move to the right along the PPC, it would produce more consumer goods – but at the expense of capital goods. So, the opportunity cost of producing consumer goods is measured in terms of forgone opportunities to produce capital goods. 18 308275_C01_CAM_IASAL ECO_007_023.indd 18 16/02/21 5:21 PM The shape of the PPC: constant and increasing opportunity costs LEARNING LINK The significance of a position within a PPC It is now possible to interpret points B and C. Point B is unreachable given present resources and technology, so the economy cannot produce that combination of goods. This applies to any point outside the PPC. On the other hand, at point C society is not using its resources efficiently. In this position there is unemployment of some resources in the economy. By making better use of the resources available, the economy can move towards the frontier, reducing unemployment in the process. 1 1 Introducing economics In some circumstances, a country may be able to consume beyond its PPC by engaging in international trade. This is explained in Chapter 12. Chapter 15 discusses what is meant by ‘efficiency’ in economic analysis. Notice that the PPC has been drawn as a curve instead of a straight line. This is because not all factors of production are equally suited to the production of both sorts of good. When the economy is well balanced, as at A, the factors can be allocated to the uses for which they are best equipped. However, as the economy moves towards complete specialisation in one of the types of good, factors are no longer being best used, and the opportunity cost changes. For example, if nearly all of the workers are engaged in producing consumer goods, it becomes more difficult to produce still more of these, whereas those workers producing machinery find they have too few resources with which to work. In other words, the more consumer goods are being produced, the higher is their opportunity cost. The causes and consequences of shifts in a PPC Capital goods per period Figure 1.3 focused on a single period. However, if the economy is producing capital goods, then in the following period its capacity to produce should increase, as it will have more resources available for production. How can this be shown on the diagram? An expansion in the available inputs suggests that in the next period the economy should be able to produce more of both goods. This is shown in Figure 1.4. PPC1 PPC0 Consumer goods per period KEY TERM ▲ Figure 1.4 Economic growth potential economic growth: an expansion in the productive capacity of the economy Suppose that in one year the production possibility curve was at PPC0. However, in the following year the increased availability of resources enables greater production, and the frontier moves to PPC1. This is a process of potential economic growth, an expansion of the economy’s productive capacity through the increased availability of inputs. Notice that the decision to produce more capital goods today means that fewer consumer goods will be produced today. People must choose between consuming more now or having more to consume in the future. LEARNING LINK The meaning and importance of economic growth is explored in Chapters 8 and 25. The PPC need not always shift in parallel to the original curve. If there is an improvement in technology that favours the production of only one of the goods, then the slope of the PPC would change as it shifts. For example, in Figure 1.5, an improvement in the technology used to produce consumer goods allows more consumer goods to be produced, and the production possibility curve shifts from PPC0 to PPC1. The opportunity cost of producing consumer goods in terms of capital goods has changed, and this is reflected in the change in the slope of the PPC. 19 308275_C01_CAM_IASAL ECO_007_023.indd 19 16/02/21 5:21 PM Suppose that a firm devises a new and more cost-effective production method. How would this affect the PPC? 0 PPC0 PPC1 Consumer goods per period ▲ Figure 1.5 A change in production technology Similarly, if there is a reduction in the resources available – for example, if a key natural resource is exhausted or becomes unavailable – then the PPC will shift inwards. EXERCISE 1.5 Bijal has been cast away on a desert island, and has to survive by spending her time either fishing or climbing trees to get coconuts. The PPC in Figure 1.6 shows the maximum combinations of fish and coconuts that she can gather during a day. Which of the points A to E represents each of the following? a A situation where Bijal spends all her time fishing b An unreachable position c A day when Bijal goes for a balanced diet – a mixture of coconuts and fish d A day when Bijal does not fancy fish, and spends all day collecting coconuts e A day when Bijal spends some of the time trying to attract the attention of a passing ship Coconuts per day AS LEVEL PART 1 BASIC ECONOMIC IDEAS AND RESOURCE ALLOCATION Test yourself 1.9 Capital goods per period 1 A E B D PPC C 0 Fish per day ▲ Figure 1.6 Fish and coconuts SUMMARY: PRODUCTION POSSIBILITY CURVES » The production possibility curve shows the maximum combinations of goods or services that can be produced in a period by a given set of resources. » At any point on the PPC, society is making full use of all resources. » At any point inside the PPC, there is unemployment of some resources. KEY TERMS private (or economic) goods: goods that are scarce free goods: goods such as the earth’s atmosphere that are not normally regarded as being scarce » Points beyond the PPC are unattainable. » In a simple society producing two goods (consumer goods and capital goods), the choice is between consumption today and investment for the future. » As society increases its stock of capital goods, the productive capacity of the economy increases, and the production possibility curve moves outwards: this may be termed ‘potential economic growth’. 1.6 Classification of goods and services Free goods and private goods Goods which are scarce are known as private goods (sometimes known as economic goods). Most goods fall into this category. However, there are also some goods that may be regarded as free goods. An example might be the earth’s atmosphere, which would not normally be regarded as being scarce. The three features that characterise a private good are: » other people can be excluded from consuming it 20 308275_C01_CAM_IASAL ECO_007_023.indd 20 16/02/21 5:21 PM » once consumed by one person, it cannot be consumed by another » a person need not choose to consume it. 1 You buy a can of cola, you drink it, and it’s gone. You may choose to share it with a friend, but you do not have to: by drinking it you can prevent anyone else from doing so. Furthermore, once it is gone, it’s gone: nobody else can subsequently consume that cola. KEY TERMS Public goods public good: a good that is non-exclusive, non-rivalrous and nonrejectable – consumers cannot be excluded from consuming the good, consumption by one person does not affect the amount of the good available for others to consume, and once it is provided to all, no individual can reject it Examples of public goods that are often cited include street lighting, a lighthouse and a nuclear deterrent. For example, once street lighting has been provided in a particular street, anyone who walks along that street at night benefits from the lighting – no one can be excluded from consuming it. So street lighting is non-exclusive. In addition, the fact that one person has walked along the street does not mean that there is less street lighting left for later walkers. So street lighting is also non-rivalrous. Furthermore, one person walking along the street cannot avoid being lit. free-rider problem: when an individual cannot be excluded from consuming a good, and thus has no incentive to pay for its provision merit good: a good that brings unanticipated benefits to consumers, such that society believes it will be underconsumed in a free market STUDY TIP Do not confuse the idea of ‘public goods’ with publicly provided goods. For example, in common usage, we may refer to ‘public education’ and ‘public healthcare’. However, these are not public goods: they are merit goods because the government believes that they will be undervalued (and underconsumed) by individuals. 1 Introducing economics The first feature can be described as excludability, whereas the second feature might be described by saying that consumption of a private good is rivalrous: the act of consumption uses up the good. The third feature means that the good is rejectable: if an individual does not wish to consume the good, they do not have to do so. Not all goods and services have the characteristics of a private good. There are goods that, once provided, are available to all. In other words, people cannot be excluded from consuming such goods. There are other goods that do not diminish through consumption, so they are non-rivalrous in consumption. Goods that have the characteristics of nonexcludability, non-rivalry and non-rejectability are known as public goods. Once the good has been provided, there is no incentive for anyone to pay for it – so the market will fail, as no firm will have an incentive to supply the good in the first place. This is often referred to as the free-rider problem, as individual consumers can freeride and avoid having to pay for the good if it is provided. Roads are sometimes seen as examples of public goods, but it could be argued that rivalry is involved when roads become congested. In many cases roads are non-excludable, except where it is feasible to impose tolls. However, the rivalry aspect suggests that roads cannot be considered to be pure public goods, as they do not have all the characteristics of public goods. Instead they may be described as semi-public goods. Merit goods There are some goods that the government believes will be undervalued by consumers, so that too little will be consumed in a free market. In other words, individuals do not fully perceive the benefits that they will gain from consuming such goods. These are known as merit goods. One situation in which the merit good phenomenon arises is where the government is in a better position than individuals to take a long-term view of what is good for society. In particular, governments may need to take decisions on behalf of future generations as well as the present. Resources need to be used wisely in the present in order to protect the interests of tomorrow’s citizens. Notice that this may require decision-makers to make normative judgements about the appropriate weighting to be given to the present as opposed to the future. Underpinning the idea of a merit good is that the government has better information about the good than consumers, so needs to take decisions on their behalf. For example, if parents do not have full information about the benefits of education for their children, they may make poor decisions about their schooling. The authorities may then see that they should intervene and take decisions on behalf of the population, for example by imposing a minimum school-leaving age. Otherwise, education may be under-consumed. 21 308275_C01_CAM_IASAL ECO_007_023.indd 21 20/03/21 10:48 AM AS LEVEL PART 1 BASIC ECONOMIC IDEAS AND RESOURCE ALLOCATION 1 Demerit goods KEY TERM demerit good: a good that brings less benefit to consumers than they expect, such that too much will be consumed by individuals in a free market LEARNING LINKS Public, merit and demerit goods (and how to deal with them) are discussed further in Chapter 5. The idea of information failure is explored more fully in Chapters 5 and 21. Test yourself 1.10 Give an example each of public goods, merit goods and demerit goods. There is also a category of goods that governments think will be overconsumed in a free market. These are known as demerit goods – or sometimes as ‘merit bads’. Obvious examples are hard drugs and tobacco. Here the argument is that individual consumers overvalue the benefits from consuming such a good. Again, the root cause of demerit goods is an information failure. SUMMARY: CLASSIFICATION OF GOODS AND SERVICES » Most goods are economic goods because they are scarce, but there are also some free goods. » Public goods are non-exclusive, non-rivalrous and non-rejectable. » A merit good is one that brings unanticipated benefits to consumers, such that society believes it will be underconsumed in a free market. » A demerit good is one that brings less benefit to consumers than they expect, such that too much will be consumed by individuals in a free market. END OF CHAPTER QUESTIONS Multiple choice 1 The basic economic problem causes individuals, firms and governments to: A use up resources more intensively B make choices C act irrationally D increase their wants 2 What distinguishes human capital from physical capital? A Human capital yields a more variable reward than physical capital. B Human capital brings more economic value to the firm. C The use of human capital in the production process does not involve a transfer of title on the resource. D Human capital plays a more important role in mixed than in planned economies. Data response 1 Read the following extract and then answer the questions that follow. Resource allocation and the factors of production In a mixed economy such as that of the USA, it is the interaction of demand from consumers and supply from firms that predominantly allocates resources through the price mechanism. A centrally planned economy is one in which the state controls the allocation of resources and the distribution of goods and services. Countries such as North Korea employ this approach to their resource allocation. Those who support a planned economic system argue its superiority derives from the idea that ‘planning makes life fairer for everybody’. Moreover, they argue the pure market mechanism will face difficulties with the production and consumption of merit, demerit and public goods. Within any firm in any economic system, specialisation is evident when each worker performs specific tasks within an overall production process. Specialisation is likely to require additional training of the workforce. 22 308275_C01_CAM_IASAL ECO_007_023.indd 22 16/02/21 5:21 PM %5 1 4 3 2 1 0 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 Source: CEIC Data ▲ Figure 1.7 US labour productivity growth, 2010–19 a Labour productivity is a measure of output per worker. With reference to Figure 1.7, compare the trend in labour productivity growth in the USA between the periods 2011–13 and 2017–19. b Explain, with the use of an example from the extract, what is meant by a ‘value judgement’. c Consider the extent to which a firm is likely to experience advantages when introducing the division of labour and specialisation. d Define a ‘free good’ and explain how the nature of merit and demerit goods will affect the extent of their consumption in a free market. e North Korea and the USA adopt different economic systems to solve their basic economic problem. Identify two advantages of each system and justify which of the two systems you would recommend. 1 Introducing economics –1 Essay style 2 aAn economy categorises its output into public goods and all other goods andservices. With the help of a production possibility diagram, explain how potential economic growth can be illustrated for this economy and consider how an improvement in technology that favours one of the categories will affect the production possibility diagram. bDiscuss whether a pure public good is more likely to be provided in a market economy or a centrally planned economy. CASE STUDY Plantains and tobacco Jacob is a subsistence farmer who lives in Nangare, a village in the west of Uganda. He lives in a mud hut and owns two sheep, two chickens and one mattress for his household of ten people. He farms a small piece of land, on which he grows plantains (a staple food crop in Uganda, related to the banana) and some tobacco. One of the key decisions that Jacob faces is how to allocate his land between plantains and tobacco. If he chooses to plant more tobacco in his field, he faces a cost, as growing more tobacco means growing fewer plantains. A number of factors are likely to influence this decision. For example, the prices of plantains and tobacco may be important, and it may be that the costs involved in growing the two crops are different. Or it may be that some parts of the land are more suitable for growing one of the crops. There may also be other crops that could be grown on the land. All of these factors could affect Jacob’s decisions. Follow-up questions a With reference to Jacob’s choice between growing plantains and tobacco, explain the concept of opportunity cost. b Draw a production possibility curve to illustrate Jacob’s choice of producing plantains and tobacco. c Identify a point on the diagram that you drew for part (b) to illustrate a situation in which: i Jacob uses his land to produce only plantains. ii Jacob uses his land to produce a combination of plantains and tobacco. iii Jacob does not use all of the land available, but produces a combination of the two crops. Go online at hoddereducation.com/cambridgeextras for another case study for Chapter 1. 23 308275_C01_CAM_IASAL ECO_007_023.indd 23 18/03/21 2:39 PM AS LEVEL PART 2 The price system and the microeconomy AS LEVEL PART 2 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 2 Demand and supply curves What this chapter covers ★ demand for a good or service (individual and market) ★ supply of a good or service ★ the determinants of demand and the demand curve ★ the law of demand ★ the determinants of supply and the supply curve ★ movements along and shifts of the demand or supply curve The demand and supply model is perhaps the most famous of all pieces of economic analysis; it is also one of the most useful. It has many applications that help explain the way markets work in the real world. It is thus central to understanding economics. This chapter introduces the key features of the model, looking in turn at the behaviour of buyers (which tells us about demand) and sellers (which tells us about supply). 2.1 Demand KEY TERM effective demand: the quantity of a good or service that consumers are willing and able to buy given its price, the price of other goods, and consumers’ incomes and preferences Our starting point for looking at the demand and supply model is to be clear about what is meant by ‘demand’. As the word itself suggests, demand is partly about ‘wants’ – how much of a good or service consumers want to consume. However, the previous chapter argued that there is always scarcity, so consumers cannot simply demand everything that they might want. This suggests that when we come to talk about demand, it is important to be aware that demand for a good or service is constrained because of scarcity. So, effective demand is the quantity of a good or service that consumers are willing and able to buy given its price, the price of other goods, and consumers’ incomes and preferences. We will explore each of these elements in turn. Individual demand Consider an individual consumer. Think of yourself, and a product that you consume regularly. What factors influence your demand for that product? Put another way, what factors influence how much of the product you choose to buy? Test yourself 2.1 Which of the four categories would apply if you demand a good because you have been influenced by advertising that persuades you that everyone must have it? When thinking about the factors that influence your demand for your chosen product, common sense will probably mean that you focus on a range of different points. You may think about why you enjoy consuming the product. You may focus on how much it will cost to buy the product, and whether you can afford it. You may decide that you have consumed a product so much that you are ready for a change; or perhaps you will decide to try something advertised on television, or being bought by a friend. Whatever the influences you come up with, they can probably be organised into four categories that ultimately determine your demand for a good: » The price of the good is an important influence on your demand for it, and will affect the quantity of it that you choose to buy. » Your income will determine how much of the good you can afford to purchase. » The price of other goods may be significant. » Almost any other factor that you may have thought of can be listed as part of your preferences. 24 308275_C02_CAM_IASAL ECO_024_039.indd 24 16/02/21 5:25 PM Notice that however much you like a particular product, your effective demand is constrained by the prices of goods and the income that you have to devote to it. This reflects the notion of scarcity that was introduced in Chapter 1, and also applies across the whole market for a good. 2 This common-sense reasoning provides the basis for the economic analysis of demand. You will find that a lot of economic analysis begins in this way, by finding a way to construct a model that is rooted in how we expect people or firms to behave. A similar line of argument may apply if we think in terms of the demand for a particular product – say, smartphones. The market for smartphones can be seen as bringing together all the potential buyers (and sellers) of the product, and market demand can be analysed in terms of the factors that influence all potential buyers of that good or service. In other words, market demand can be seen as the total quantity of a good or service that all potential buyers would choose to buy at any given price. The same four categories of factors that influence an individual’s decision to buy will also influence the total market demand for a product. In addition, the number of potential buyers in the market will influence the size of total demand at any price. 2 Demand and supply curves Market demand SUMMARY: DEMAND » The effective demand for a good or service is the quantity that consumers are willing and able to buy given its price, the price of other goods, and consumers’ incomes and preferences. KEY TERM firm: an organisation (business) that brings together factors of production in order to produce output LEARNING LINKS The notion of factors of production was introduced in Chapter 1. The assumption that firms aim to maximise profits may not always be true in reality, but it provides the basis for exploring decisions taken by firms. In Chapter 20 we discuss alternative objectives that firms may have. » The individual demand for a good or service is the quantity that an individual consumer is willing and able to buy. » Market demand is the total demand for a good or service as provided by all sellers. 2.2 Supply In discussing demand, the focus of attention is on consumers, and on their willingness to pay for goods and services. In thinking about supply, attention switches to firms, as it is firms that take decisions about how much output to supply to the market. It is important at the outset to be clear about what is meant by a ‘firm’. A firm exists to organise production: it brings together various factors of production, and organises the production process in order to produce output. The organisation of a firm can take various forms. A firm could be a sole proprietor: probably a small business such as a newsagent where the owner of the firm also runs the firm. A firm could be a partnership – for example, a dental practice in which profits (and debts) are shared between the partners in the business. Larger firms may be organised as private or public joint-stock companies, owned by shareholders. The difference between private and public joint-stock companies is that the shares of a public joint-stock company are traded on the stock exchange, whereas this is not the case with the private company. In order to analyse how firms decide how much of a product to supply, it is necessary to make an assumption about what it is that firms are trying to achieve. Assume that they aim to maximise their profits, where ‘profits’ are defined as the difference between a firm’s total revenue and its total costs. As in the case of demand, individual supply considers the quantity of a good or service that is supplied by an individual firm, whereas market supply is concerned with the total supply of a good or service across all firms in the market. 25 308275_C02_CAM_IASAL ECO_024_039.indd 25 16/02/21 5:25 PM SUMMARY: SUPPLY 2 » The individual supply of a good or service is the quantity that an individual firm (business) is prepared and able to sell at any given price. » The market supply of a good or service is the quantity supplied by all firms 2.3 Determinants of demand There are several factors that determine the demand for a good or service, whether at the individual or the market level. Demand and the price of a good Perhaps the most obvious influence on the demand for a good is its price. Assume for the moment that all other influences that affect demand are held constant, so that the focus is only on the extent to which the price of a good influences the demand for it. This is a common assumption in economics, as mentioned in Chapter 1, when it was expressed by the Latin phrase ceteris paribus, meaning ‘other things being equal’. Given the complexity of the real world, it is often helpful to focus on one thing at a time. LEARNING LINK The term ‘ceteris paribus’ was explained in section 1.2 of Chapter 1. KEY TERMS law of demand: a law that states that there is an inverse relationship between quantity demanded and the price of a good or service, ceteris paribus demand curve: a graph showing how much of a good will be demanded by consumers at any given price So how is the demand for smartphones influenced by their price? Other things being equal (ceteris paribus), you would expect the demand for smartphones to be higher when the price is low and lower when the price is high. In other words, you would expect an inverse relationship between the price and the quantity demanded. This is such a strong phenomenon that it is referred to as the law of demand. It is one of a small number of ‘laws’ in economics – in other words, it is always expected to hold true. If you were to compile a list that showed how many smartphones would be bought at any possible price and plot these on a diagram, this would be called the demand curve. Figure 2.1 shows what this might look like. As it is an inverse relationship, the demand curve slopes downwards from left to right. Notice that this need not be a straight line: its shape depends on how consumers react at different prices. Price of smartphones ($) AS LEVEL PART 2 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY operating in the market. 60 50 40 30 20 Demand 10 0 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 Quantity of smartphones (thousands per period) ▲ Figure 2.1 A demand curve for smartphones 26 308275_C02_CAM_IASAL ECO_024_039.indd 26 16/02/21 5:26 PM QUANTITATIVE SKILLS 2.1 Reading a graph You may also wonder why this is called a demand ‘curve’ when it is a straight line. In fact, it need not be a straight line, but a straight line is convenient. Think of it as a straight curve. EXERCISE 2.1 Table 2.1 shows how the demand for trinkets varies with their price. a Draw the demand curve. b How many trinkets would be sold at a price of $65? c At what price would 50 trinkets be demanded? 2 2 Demand and supply curves An important skill is to be able to read off numerical values from a graph such as Figure 2.1. If you wanted to see what the quantity demanded would be at a particular price, you would select the price on the vertical axis, and then read off the value on the horizontal axis at that price. For example, in this figure, if price were to be set at $40, the quantity demanded would be 20,000 per period. However, if the price were only $20, the demand would be higher, at 60,000. If you are studying maths as one of your A Level subjects, you may wonder why we draw the demand curve with price on the vertical axis and quantity on the horizontal axis, when we are saying that quantity depends on price and not the other way round. The simple answer is that Alfred Marshall drew it this way when he became the first person to draw a demand curve in his economics textbook in 1890, and it became the norm. ▼ Table 2.1 The demand for trinkets Price ($) Quantity 100 0 90 3 80 7 70 15 60 25 50 40 40 60 30 85 20 120 EXTENSION MATERIAL Income and substitution effects An analysis of why the demand curve should be downward sloping would reveal that there are two important forces at work. At a higher price, a consumer buying a smartphone has less income left Test yourself 2.2 Which of the following would trigger the law of demand? A change in: a preferences b the price of other goods c the price of the good d income over. This is referred to as the income effect of a price increase. In addition, if the price of smartphones goes up, consumers may find other goods more attractive and choose to buy something else instead of smartphones. This is referred to as the substitution effect of a price increase. As the price of a good changes, a movement along the demand curve can be observed as consumers adjust their buying pattern in response to the price change. Notice that the demand curve has been drawn under the ceteris paribus assumption. In other words, it was assumed that all other influences on demand were held constant in order to focus on the relationship between demand and price. There are two important implications of this procedure. First, the price drawn on the vertical axis of a diagram such as Figure 2.1 is the relative price – it is the price of smartphones under the assumption that all other prices are constant. 27 308275_C02_CAM_IASAL ECO_024_039.indd 27 16/02/21 5:26 PM AS LEVEL PART 2 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 2 STUDY TIP Remember that a movement along the demand curve is a response to a change in the price of the good, whereas a change in any of the other factors that affect demand causes a shift of the curve. Second, if any of the other influences on demand change, you would expect to see a shift of the whole demand curve. It is very important to distinguish between factors that induce a movement along a curve, and factors that induce a shift of a curve. This applies not only in the case of the demand curve – there are many other instances where this is important. We return to this issue at the end of the chapter. EXTENSION MATERIAL Snob effects For some goods a ‘snob effect’ may lead to the demand curve sloping upwards. The argument is that some people may value certain goods more highly simply because their price is high, especially if they know that other people will observe them consuming these goods; an example might be Rolex watches. In other words, people gain value from having other people notice that they are rich enough to afford to consume a particular good. This idea that people like to show off by consuming expensive articles was first pointed out by Thorstein Veblen at the end of the nineteenth century. He referred to this as a conspicuous consumption effect. However, although there may be some individual consumers who react to price in this way, there is no evidence to suggest that there are whole markets that display an upward-sloping demand curve for this reason. In other words, most consumers would react normally to the price of such goods. Demand and consumer incomes KEY TERM normal good: a good where the quantity demanded increases in response to an increase in consumer incomes The second influence on demand is consumer incomes. For a normal good, an increase in consumer incomes will, ceteris paribus, lead to an increase in the quantity demanded at any given price. Foreign holidays are an example of a normal good because, as people’s incomes rise, they will tend to demand more foreign holidays at any given price. ▲ Foreign holidays are an example of a normal good Figure 2.2 illustrates this. D0 here represents the initial demand curve for foreign holidays. An increase in consumers’ incomes causes demand to be higher at any given price, and the demand curve shifts to the right – to D1. 28 308275_C02_CAM_IASAL ECO_024_039.indd 28 16/02/21 5:26 PM Price 2 0 D1 Quantity of foreign holidays per period ▲ Figure 2.2 A shift in the demand curve following an increase in consumer incomes (a normal good) KEY TERM This time an increase in consumers’ incomes in Figure 2.3 causes the demand curve to shift to the left, from its initial position at D0, to D1 where less is demanded at any given price. Price inferior good: a good where the quantity demanded decreases in response to an increase in consumer incomes However, demand does not always respond in this way. For example, think about bus journeys. As incomes rise in a society, more people can afford to have a car, or to use taxis. This means that, as incomes rise, the demand for bus journeys may tend to fall. Such goods are known as inferior goods. 2 Demand and supply curves D0 D1 0 D0 Quantity of bus journeys per period ▲ Figure 2.3 A shift in the demand curve following an increase in consumer incomes (an inferior good) EXERCISE 2.2 Test yourself 2.3 What is meant by a ‘normal’ good? Identify each of the following products as being either a normal good or an inferior good: a Digital camera d Bicycle b Magazine e New car c Potatoes f Second-hand car 29 308275_C02_CAM_IASAL ECO_024_039.indd 29 16/02/21 5:26 PM Giffen goods Remember that a consumer’s response to a change in the price of a good is made up of a substitution effect and a real income effect (see the extension point on page 27). The substitution effect always acts in the opposite direction to the price change: in other words, an increase in the price of a good always induces a switch away from the good towards other goods. However, it can now be seen that the real income effect may operate in either direction, depending on whether it is a normal good or an inferior good that is being considered. Suppose there is a good that is very inferior. A fall in the price of a good induces a substitution effect towards the good, but the real income effect works in the opposite direction. The fall in price is equivalent to a rise in real income, so consumers will consume less of the good. If this effect is really strong, it could overwhelm the substitution effect, and the fall in price could induce a fall in the quantity demanded: in other words, for such a good the demand curve could be upward sloping. Such goods are known as Giffen goods, after Sir Robert Giffen, who pointed out that this could happen. However, in spite of stories about the reaction of demand to a rise in the price of potatoes during the great Irish potato famine, no examples of Giffen goods have been identified. The notion remains only a theoretical possibility. Demand and the price of other goods substitutes: two goods are said to be substitutes if consumers regard them as alternatives, so that the demand for one good is likely to rise if the price of the other good rises complements: two goods are said to be complements if people tend to consume them jointly, so that an increase in the price of one good causes the demand for the other good to fall The demand for a good may respond to changes in the price of other related goods, of which there are two main types. On the one hand, two goods may be substitutes for each other. For example, consider two different (but similar) breakfast cereals. If there is an increase in the price of corn flakes, consumers may switch their consumption to muesli, as the two are likely to be substitutes for each other. Not all consumers will switch, of course – some may be deeply committed to corn flakes – but some of them are certainly likely to change to another cereal. On the other hand, there may also be goods that are complements – for example, products that are consumed jointly, such as breakfast cereals and milk, or cars and petrol. Here a fall in the price of one good may lead to an extension in its demand accompanied by an increase in demand for its complement. Whether goods are substitutes or complements determines how the demand for one good responds to a change in the price of another. Figure 2.4 shows the demand curves (per period) for two goods that are substitutes – tea and coffee. a) The market for tea b) The market for coffee Price of coffee KEY TERMS Price of tea AS LEVEL PART 2 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 2 EXTENSION MATERIAL P1 P0 Dc0 Dtea 0 Q1 Q0 Quantity of tea 0 Dc1 Quantity of coffee ▲ Figure 2.4 A shift in the demand curve following an increase in the price of a substitute good If there is an increase in the price of tea from P0 to P1 in panel (a), more consumers will switch to coffee and the demand curve in panel (b) will shift to the right – say, from Dc0 to Dc1. For complements the situation is the reverse: in Figure 2.5 an increase in the price of tea from P0 to P1 in panel (a) causes the demand curve for milk to shift leftwards, from Dm0 to Dm1. 30 308275_C02_CAM_IASAL ECO_024_039.indd 30 16/02/21 5:26 PM b) The market for milk 2 Price of milk Price of tea a) The market for tea P1 P0 Dm1 Dm0 Dtea Q1 Q0 Quantity of tea 0 Quantity of milk ▲ Figure 2.5 A shift in the demand curve following an increase in the price of a complementary good Demand, consumer preferences and other influences The discussion has shown how the demand for a good is influenced by the price of the good, the price of other goods, and by consumer incomes. It was stated earlier that almost everything else that determines demand for a good can be represented as ‘consumer preferences’. In particular, this refers to whether you like or dislike a good. There may be many things that influence whether you like or dislike a product. In part it simply depends on your own personal inclinations – some people like dark chocolate, others prefer milk chocolate. However, firms may try to influence your preferences through advertising, and sometimes they succeed. Or you might be one of those people who get so irritated by television advertising that you compile a blacklist of products that you will never buy! Even this is an influence on your demand. 2 Demand and supply curves 0 In some cases your preferences may be swayed by other people’s demand – again, this may be positive or negative. Fashions may influence demand, but some people like to go against (or lead) the trend. You may also see a movement of the demand curve if there is a sudden surge in the popularity of a good – or, indeed, a sudden collapse in demand. Test yourself 2.4 Are people likely to respond more or less strongly to a change in price as time passes? The above discussion has covered most of the factors that influence the demand for a good. However, in some cases it is necessary to take a time element into account. Not all of the goods bought are consumed instantly. In some cases, consumption is spread over long periods of time. Indeed, there may be instances where goods are not bought for consumption at all, but are seen by the buyer as an investment, perhaps for resale at a later date. In these circumstances, expectations about future price changes may be relevant. For example, people may buy antiques or works of art in the expectation that prices will rise in the future. There may also be goods whose prices are expected to fall in the future. This has been common with many hi-tech products; initially a newly launched product may sell at a high price, but as production levels rise, costs may fall, and prices also. People may therefore delay purchase in the expectation of future price reductions. EXERCISE 2.3 Draw some demand curves for the following situations, and think about how you would expect the demand curve to change (if at all). a The demand for chocolate following a campaign highlighting the dangers of obesity b The demand for oranges following an increase in the price of apples c The demand for oranges following a decrease in the price of oranges d The demand for Blu-ray discs following a decrease in the price of Blu-ray players e The demand for private transport following an increase in consumer incomes f The demand for public transport following an increase in consumer incomes 31 308275_C02_CAM_IASAL ECO_024_039.indd 31 16/02/21 5:26 PM 2 SUMMARY: DETERMINANTS OF DEMAND » An important influence on the demand for a good » The demand curve is downward sloping, as the relationship between demand and price is an inverse one. » The market demand for a good depends on the price of the good, the price of other goods, consumers’ incomes and preferences and the number of potential consumers. 2.4 Determinants of supply KEY TERMS competitive market: a market in which individual firms cannot influence the price of the good or service they are selling, because of competition from other firms supply curve: a graph showing the quantity supplied at any given price The demand curve shows a relationship between quantity demanded and the price of a good or service. A similar relationship between the quantity supplied by firms and the price of a good can be identified in relation to the behaviour of firms in a competitive market – that is, a market in which individual firms cannot influence the price of the good or service that they are selling, because of competition from other firms. In such a market it may well be supposed that firms will be prepared to supply more goods at a high price than at a lower one (ceteris paribus), as this will increase their profits. The supply curve illustrates how much the firms in a market will supply at any given price, as shown in Figure 2.6. As firms are expected to supply more goods at a high price than at a lower price, the supply curve will be upward sloping, reflecting this positive relationship between quantity and price. Price AS LEVEL PART 2 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY or service is its price. » The demand curve shows the relationship between demand for a product and its price, ceteris paribus. Supply STUDY TIP Always be careful to distinguish between ‘price’ and ‘cost’. These are sometimes used interchangeably in everyday language, but in economics they mean different things. From a consumer’s point of view ‘price’ is what has to be paid for a good or service; ‘cost’ is what the firm must pay out in producing a good or service. Test yourself 2.5 Explain why firms in a competitive market will be prepared to supply more output at a higher price, ceteris paribus. 0 Quantity per period ▲ Figure 2.6 A supply curve QUANTITATIVE SKILLS 2.2 Lines on a diagram Be clear about why the upward-sloping nature of the supply curve reflects the fact that firms are willing to supply more output at a higher price, whereas the downward-sloping nature of the demand curve reflects the way that consumers are willing to purchase more of a good when the price is relatively low. This is bound up with the way in which we interpret the supply (or demand) curve. In Figure 2.6, think about how firms behave when the price is relatively low – that is, when you pick a price low down on the vertical axis. The quantity that firms are willing to supply is read off from the supply curve – and is relatively low. However, if you read off the quantity from a higher price, the quantity is also higher. You need to become accustomed to interpreting lines and curves on a diagram in this way. The shape of the line (or curve) shows the extent to which firms respond at different prices. 32 308275_C02_CAM_IASAL ECO_024_039.indd 32 16/02/21 5:26 PM EXERCISE 2.4 ▼ Table 2.2 The supply of trinkets Price ($) Quantity 100 98 90 95 80 91 70 86 60 80 50 70 40 60 30 50 20 35 10 18 2 2 Demand and supply curves Table 2.2 shows how the supply of trinkets varies with their price. a Draw the supply curve. b How many trinkets will be supplied if the price is $35? c If 65 trinkets are supplied, what will be the price? Notice that the focus of the supply curve is on the relationship between quantity supplied and the price of a good in a given period, ceteris paribus – that is, holding other things constant. As with the demand curve, there are other factors affecting the quantity supplied. These other influences on supply will determine the position of the supply curve: if any of them changes, the supply curve can be expected to shift. We can identify six important influences on the quantity that firms will be prepared to supply to the market at any given price: » » » » » » production costs the technology of production taxes and subsidies the price of related goods firms’ expectations about future prices the number of firms in the market Costs and technology If firms are aiming to maximise profits, an important influence on their supply decision will be the costs of production that they face. Chapter 1 explained that in order to produce output, firms need to use inputs of the factors of production – labour, capital, land and enterprise. If the cost of those inputs increases, firms will in general be expected to supply less output at any given price. There is a decrease in supply. The effect of this is shown in Figure 2.7, where an increase in production costs induces firms to supply less output at each price. The curve shifts from its initial position at S0 to a new position at S1. For example, suppose the original price was $10 per unit; before the increase in costs, firms would have been prepared to supply 100 units of the product to the market. An increase in costs of $6 per unit that shifted the supply curve from S0 to S1 would mean that, at the same price, firms would now supply only 50 units of the good. Notice that the vertical distance between S0 and S1 is the amount of the change in cost per unit. 33 308275_C02_CAM_IASAL ECO_024_039.indd 33 16/02/21 5:26 PM Price ($) 2 S1 S0 10 0 50 100 Quantity per period ▲ Figure 2.7 The supply curve shifts to the left if production costs increase QUANTITATIVE SKILLS 2.3 Interpreting distance on a graph LEARNING LINK Chapter 1 introduced the factors of production and their importance to firms; the way in which a firm’s costs influence its decision making is discussed in Chapter 17. In Figure 2.7, we show the supply curve as shifting to the left with an increase in costs of $6 per unit. How do we know by how much the curve will shift? Notice that with quantity at 50 units, cost has increased from $4 to $10 per unit, and it is this vertical distance that determines how far the supply curve moves. We will see a similar effect in Figure 2.9 in relation to taxes and subsidies. In contrast, if a new technology of production is introduced, which means that firms can produce more cost effectively, this could have the opposite effect, shifting the supply curve to the right. This is shown in Figure 2.8, where improved technology reduces costs faced by firms and induces them to supply more output at any given price, so the supply curve shifts from its initial position at S0 to a new position at S1. Therefore, if firms in the initial situation were supplying 50 units with the price at $10 per unit, then the introduction of new technology that brings a fall in costs of $6 per unit would induce firms to increase supply to 100 units (if the price remained at $10). Price ($) AS LEVEL PART 2 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 4 S0 S1 10 4 0 50 100 Quantity per period ▲ Figure 2.8 The supply curve shifts to the right if new technology lowers production costs 34 308275_C02_CAM_IASAL ECO_024_039.indd 34 16/02/21 5:26 PM Taxes and subsidies The impact and incidence of taxes and subsidies are explored in Chapter 5, see pages 75–77. b) A subsidy S S with tax Price LEARNING LINK Price a) A sales tax Subsidy Tax 0 S Quantity 0 S with subsidy 2 2 Demand and supply curves Suppose the government imposes a sales tax such as VAT on a good or service. The price paid by consumers will be higher than the revenue received by firms, as the tax has to be paid to the government. This means that firms will (ceteris paribus) be prepared to supply less output at any given market price. Again, the supply curve shifts to the left. This is shown in panel (a) of Figure 2.9, which assumes a fixed per unit tax. The supply curve shifts, as firms supply less at any given market price. On the other hand, if the government pays firms a subsidy to produce a particular good, this will reduce their costs, and induce them to supply more output at any given price. The supply curve will then shift to the right, as shown in panel (b). Quantity ▲ Figure 2.9 The effects of taxes and subsidies on supply Prices of other goods It was shown earlier that from the consumers’ perspective, two goods may be substitutes for each other, such that if the price of one good increases, consumers may be induced to switch their consumption to substitute goods. Similarly, there may be substitution on the supply side. A firm may face a situation in which there are alternative uses to which its factors of production may be put: in other words, it may be able to choose between producing a range of different products. A rise in the price of a good raises its profitability, and therefore may encourage a firm to switch production from other goods. This may happen even if there are high switching costs, provided the increase in price is sufficiently large. For example, a change in relative prices of sweet potatoes and onions might encourage a farmer to stop planting sweet potatoes and grow onions instead. In other circumstances, a firm may produce a range of goods jointly. Perhaps one good is a by-product of the production process of another. An increase in the price of one of the goods may mean that the firm will produce more of both goods. This notion of joint supply is similar to the situation on the demand side where consumers regard two goods as complements. Expected prices Because production takes time, firms often take decisions about how much to supply on the basis of expected future prices. Indeed, if their product is one that can be stored, there may be times when a firm will decide to allow stocks of a product to build up in anticipation of a higher price in the future, perhaps by holding back some of its production from current sales. In some economic activities, expectations about future prices are crucial in taking supply decisions because of the length of time needed to increase output. For example, a firm producing palm oil, rubber or mangoes needs to be aware that newly planted trees will take several years to mature before they are able to yield their product. 35 308275_C02_CAM_IASAL ECO_024_039.indd 35 16/02/21 5:26 PM AS LEVEL PART 2 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 2 ▲ Newly planted trees may take several years to mature The number of firms in the market As the market supply curve is the sum of the supply curves of individual firms, if more firms join the market, the market supply curve will shift to the right. Similarly, if some firms go out of business, the market supply curve will shift to the left. SUMMARY: DETERMINANTS OF SUPPLY » The selling price of a good or service is an important influence on the quantity that firms are prepared to supply. » The market supply curve shows the quantity that firms in a market are prepared and able to supply at any given price. » The market supply of a good or service depends on production costs, the technology of production, taxes and subsidies, the price of related goods and firms’ expectations about future prices. STUDY TIP In order to emphasise the difference between a shift of the demand curve and a movement along it, the convention is to use an extension (or contraction) of demand (supply) for a movement along the demand (supply) curve, and to use an increase (or decrease) to denote a shift of the curve. 2.5 Movements along and shifts of the demand or supply curve It is important to be able to distinguish between the shift of a curve (demand or supply) and a movement along it. First think about the demand curve. Remember that the demand curve has been drawn under the ceteris paribus assumption. In other words, it was assumed that all other influences on demand were held constant in order to focus on the relationship between demand and price. There are two important implications of this procedure. As the price of a good changes, a movement along the demand curve can be observed as consumers adjust their buying pattern in response to the price change. However, if any of the other influences on demand changes, you would expect to see a shift of the whole demand curve. It is very important to distinguish between those factors that induce a movement along a curve (known as an extension (or contraction) of demand), and factors that induce a shift of a curve (an increase or decrease in demand). 36 308275_C02_CAM_IASAL ECO_024_039.indd 36 16/02/21 5:26 PM The two panels of Figure 2.10 show this difference. In panel (a) of the figure, the demand curve for Xbox games has shifted to the right because of a change in one of the factors that influences demand. In panel (b), the price of Xbox games falls from P0 to P1, inducing an extension (movement along the demand curve) as demand expands from Q0 to Q1. b) A movement along the demand curve Price of Xboxes P0 P1 Test yourself 2.6 D0 0 D1 Quantity of Xbox games D 0 Q0 Q1 Quantity of Xbox games ▲ Figure 2.10 A shift in the demand curve and a movement along it In the same way, a change in the price of a good or service induces a movement along the supply curve (known as an extension (or contraction) of supply), whereas an increase (or decrease) in the other determinants of supply leads to a shift in the curve itself. Test yourself 2.7 If a producer finds that the market price of its product has increased, would this induce a contraction of supply, an extension of supply or a shift in the supply curve? 2 Demand and supply curves Price of Xboxes a) A shift in the demand curve Explain the difference between an extension of demand and an increase in demand. 2 EXERCISE 2.5 Draw supply curves for each of the following situations to show whether there is a shift of the supply curve or a movement along it. a The supply of accountancy services following the introduction of more efficient computer software b The supply of a good following an increase in taxes on sales c The supply of ice cream following a rise in its selling price during a hot summer d The supply of tennis balls after several firms in the market go bankrupt EXERCISE 2.6 For each of the following, decide whether the demand curve or the supply curve will move, and in which direction. a Consumers are convinced by arguments about the benefits of organic vegetables. b A new process is developed that reduces the amount of inputs that firms need in order to produce bicycles. c There is a severe frost in Brazil that affects the coffee crop. d The government increases the rate of value added tax. e Real incomes rise. f The price of tea falls: what happens in the market for coffee? g The price of sugar falls: what happens in the market for coffee? 37 308275_C02_CAM_IASAL ECO_024_039.indd 37 16/02/21 5:26 PM AS LEVEL PART 2 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 2 SUMMARY: MOVEMENT ALONG AND SHIFTS OF A CURVE » There is an important distinction to be drawn between a movement along a curve and a shift of the curve. » For a demand curve, a change in the price induces a movement along the demand curve, but a change in one of the determinants of demand (other than its price) causes a shift of the curve. » An increase in price leads to a movement up along the demand curve, known as a contraction of demand. » A decrease in price leads to a movement down along the demand curve, known as an extension of demand. » For a supply curve, a change in the price induces a movement along the supply curve, but a change in one of the determinants of supply (other than its price) causes a shift of the curve. » An increase in price leads to a movement up along the supply curve, known as an extension of supply. » A decrease in price leads to a movement down along the supply curve, known as a contraction of supply. END OF CHAPTER QUESTIONS Multiple choice 1 The cost of a major factor of production in the steel industry increases. A steel producer manages to resist the rise in costs by retrenching workers. In response to the higher costs, many firms exit the industry. What is the effect on the steel producer of the reduction in competition? A a movement up along the steel producer’s supply curve B a shift in the steel producer’s supply curve to the right C an increase in the steel producer’s profits D an increase in the steel producer’s productivity 2 Which of the following changes will not increase market demand at every given price? A an effective advertising campaign promoting the benefits of the product B an increase in the quality of the product C a decrease in substitutes available D a fall in the price of the product Data response 1 Read the following extract and then answer the questions that follow. Cambodia’s energy problems and solutions Cambodia is experiencing increases in economic growth and an expanding population. In Phnom Penh, the capital of Cambodia, this can cause significant problems when the supply of electricity does not meet the demand. This results in frequent load-shedding power cuts that occur across different parts 5 of the city at different times. The impact of the power load shedding on the economy can be significant. Despite many shirt manufacturing firms in Phnom Penh experiencing increased effective demand, many are badly affected when their machines stand idle during the power cuts. Some have even gone out of business. In 10 November 2019, the president of Cambodia warned there would be loadshedding power cuts until April 2020. As part of a solution the authorities have considered increasing the price of electricity. Shirt manufacturers point out that this will lead to an increase 38 308275_C02_CAM_IASAL ECO_024_039.indd 38 16/02/21 5:26 PM in their costs and the price of the shirts they produce. At the same time the 15 government has subsidised the installation of solar panels as an alternative energy source. To help pay for the subsidy, the government is considering an increase in sales tax. 2 In Cambodia’s agricultural sector, there is a far smaller impact from the power cuts. However, in this sector, ongoing poor weather conditions are 20 significantly affecting supply. a Identify two factors that could have caused the current increase in the demand for shirts in Cambodia. b Explain what is meant by ‘effective demand’ in the extract (line 8). c Identify and explain the evidence in the extract that suggests there could be a decrease in the quantity of shirts demanded and a decrease in the supply of shirts in the future. d Explain how the number of firms that manufacture shirts in Phnom Penh going out of business would affect the market supply curve for shirts in Cambodia. e Explain, with the aid of a diagram and with reference to the extract, the likely change in the supply of agricultural products. f Assess, with the aid of a diagram, the likely effect of an increase in sales tax on the supply of shirts in Cambodia. 2 Demand and supply curves Source: adapted from ‘Cambodia Struggles to Keep the Lights On’, Asia Times, 2 December 2019 Essay style 2 a I n 2020, the Dutch government announced plans to double its financial assistance for firms producing renewable energy. The financial help included a higher price paid for energy produced through renewable sources and a production subsidy. With the help of a diagram, explain the likely effects on the supply of renewable energy as a result of the measures taken by the Dutch government in 2020 and consider whether the assumption of ceteris paribus is likely to hold in this situation. bDiscuss whether there will be an increase in the demand for a good following an increase in income and an increase in the price of a related good. 39 308275_C02_CAM_IASAL ECO_024_039.indd 39 20/03/21 10:49 AM AS LEVEL PART 2 The price system and the microeconomy AS LEVEL PART 2 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 3 Elasticity What this chapter covers ★ price elasticity of demand (PED), income elasticity (YED) and cross-price elasticity (XED) ★ formulae and calculation of elasticity measures ★ the PED and total revenue of a product ★ factors affecting the PED KEY TERMS elasticity: a measure of the sensitivity of one variable to changes in another variable price elasticity of demand (PED): a measure of the sensitivity of quantity demanded to a change in the price of a good or service. It is measured as: % change in quantity demanded % change in price elastic: a term used when the price elasticity of demand is numerically greater than 1 but less than infinity ★ ★ ★ ★ elastic, inelastic and unitary elastic demand factors affecting the YED and XED the price elasticity of supply (PES) the usefulness and significance of elasticity measures The previous chapter introduced the notions of demand and supply. We now turn our attention to the way in which demand and supply respond to changes in the factors that influence them, and examine how we can measure the degree to which demand and supply are sensitive to each of the main factors. Both the demand for and the supply of a good or service can be expected to depend on its price as well as other factors. It is often important to know just how sensitive demand and/or supply will be to a change in either price or one of the other determinants – for example, in predicting how consumers, firms and the government may be affected by a change in the market environment. The sensitivity of demand or supply to a change in one of its determining factors can be measured by its elasticity. 3.1 The price elasticity of demand The most common elasticity measure is the price elasticity of demand (PED). This measures the sensitivity of the quantity demanded of a good or service to a change in its price. The elasticity is defined as the percentage change in quantity demanded divided by the percentage change in the price. We define the percentage change in price as 100 × ΔP/P (where Δ means ‘change in’ and P stands for ‘price’). Similarly, the percentage change in quantity demanded is 100 × ΔQ/Q. When the demand is highly price sensitive, the percentage change in quantity demanded following a price change will be large relative to the percentage change in price. In this case, the PED will take on a value that is smaller than −1. For example, suppose that a 2% change in the price of a good leads to a 5% reduction in quantity demanded; the elasticity is then −5 divided by 2 = −2.5. When the price elasticity is smaller than −1, demand is referred to as being price elastic. QUANTITATIVE SKILLS 3.1 Describing elasticity Because the PED is always negative, economists sometimes omit the minus sign. Strictly speaking, demand is elastic where the PED is smaller than −1 and inelastic if the value is between 0 and −1. Another way of expressing this is that demand is elastic when the PED is negative with an absolute value larger than 1, but this is quite clumsy. You may sometimes find people saying that demand is elastic when the PED is larger than 1. What they mean is that the PED is smaller than −1, that it is negative but with a numerical value greater than 1. 40 308275_C03_CAM_IASAL ECO_040_053.indd 40 16/02/21 5:29 PM KEY TERMS inelastic: a term used when the price elasticity of demand is between 0 and −1 When demand is not very sensitive to price, the percentage change in quantity demanded will be smaller than the original percentage change in price, and the elasticity will then be between 0 and −1. For example, if a 2% change in price leads to a 1% reduction in quantity demanded, then the value of the elasticity will be −1 divided by 2 = −0.5. In this case, demand is referred to as being price inelastic. QUANTITATIVE SKILLS 3.2 3 3 Elasticity unitary elastic: a term used when the price elasticity of demand is equal to −1 There are two important things to notice about this. First, because the demand curve is downward sloping, the elasticity will always be negative. This is because the changes in price and quantity are always in the opposite direction. Second, you should try to calculate the elasticity only for a relatively small change in price, as it becomes unreliable for very large changes. Calculating an elasticity Price of pencils (cents) Figure 3.1 shows a demand curve for pencils. When the price of a pencil is 40c, the quantity demanded will be 20. If the price falls to 35c, the quantity demanded will rise to 30. The percentage change in quantity is 100 × 10/20 = 50 and the percentage change in price is 100 × −5/40 = −12.5. Thus, the elasticity can be calculated as (50/−12.5) = −4. At this price, demand is highly price elastic. 60 50 Elasticity is % change in Q /% change in P i.e. 50/–12.5 = –4 40 35 30 Elasticity is 2.5/–10 = –0.25 20 109 0 0 Demand 20 30 40 82 60 80 100 120 Quantity of pencils per period ▲ Figure 3.1 A demand curve for pencils At a lower price, the result is quite different. Suppose that the price is initially 10c, at which price the quantity demanded is 80. If the price falls to 9c, demand increases to 82. The percentage change in quantity is now 100 × 2/80 = 2.5, and the percentage change in price is 100 × −1/10 = −10, so the elasticity is calculated as 2.5/−10 = −0.25, and demand is now price inelastic. The phenomenon described in Quantitative skills 3.2 is true for any straight-line demand curve: in other words, demand is price elastic at higher prices and inelastic at lower prices. At the halfway point the elasticity is exactly −1, which is referred to as unitary elasticity. Test yourself 3.1 Why is the PED always negative? Why should the elasticity vary along a linear demand curve? The key is to be aware that elasticity is defined in terms of the percentage changes in price and quantity. When price is relatively high, a 1c change in price is a small percentage change, and the percentage change in quantity is relatively large – because when price is relatively high, the initial quantity is relatively low. The reverse is the case when price is relatively low. Figure 3.2 shows how the elasticity of demand varies along a straightline demand curve. 41 308275_C03_CAM_IASAL ECO_040_053.indd 41 16/02/21 5:29 PM Test yourself 3.2 Suppose that a good has a PED of −0.3. Would you describe this as being relatively elastic or relatively inelastic? Price When the demand curve is a straight line, it always has this property that the elasticity gets smaller as we move down along it. Demand curves need not always be straight lines, of course; they may be curved. This depends on how buyers respond at different prices. Within this range of the demand curve, demand is price elastic At the mid-point of the demand curve, we have unit elasticity Within this range of the demand curve, demand is price inelastic 0 Quantity per period ▲ Figure 3.2 The price elasticity of demand varies along a straight line The price elasticity of demand and total revenue One reason why firms may have an interest in the price elasticity of demand is that if they are considering changing their prices, they will be eager to know the extent to which demand will be affected. For example, they may want to know how a change in price will affect their total revenue. As it happens there is a consistent relationship between the price elasticity of demand and total revenue. Total revenue is given by price multiplied by quantity. In Figure 3.3, if price is at P0, quantity demanded is at Q0 and total revenue is given by the area of the rectangle 0P0AQ0. If price falls to P1 the quantity demanded rises to Q1, and you can see that total revenue has increased, as it is now given by the area 0P1BQ1. This is larger than at price P1, because in moving from P0 to P1 the area P1P0AC is lost, but the area Q0CBQ1 is gained, and the latter is the larger. As you move down the demand curve, total revenue at first increases like this, but then decreases – try sketching this for yourself to check that it is so. Price AS LEVEL PART 2 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 3 STUDY TIP A P0 P1 B C Demand 0 Q0 Q1 Quantity per period ▲ Figure 3.3 Demand and total revenue STUDY TIP Notice that from a firm’s point of view price times quantity is revenue (the amount that firms receive from selling the good), but from the buyers’ point of view, this is expenditure (i.e. spending by buyers). In this context, total revenue and total expenditure are the same. 42 308275_C03_CAM_IASAL ECO_040_053.indd 42 16/02/21 5:29 PM QUANTITATIVE SKILLS 3.3 Elasticity and total revenue Total revenue before and after the price change can be calculated. Total revenue is equal to price multiplied by quantity, so at the original price revenue was 40 × 20 = 800. At the new lower price, total revenue was 35 × 30 = 1,050. We can therefore see that when the price elasticity of demand is elastic, a fall in price leads to a rise in revenue. When the price of a pencil fell from 10 to 9, and quantity demanded rose from 80 to 82, demand was A mathematical note: because the elasticity varies along most demand curves, we would ideally like to measure the elasticity at a particular point on the curve. When calculating using percentage changes we are measuring the elasticity along a segment of the curve (an arc), so we may sometimes get misleading results. We should therefore try to calculate for as small a change as can be measured. Those taking A Level Maths may realise that calculus would enable us to measure elasticity at a point if we knew the formula for the demand curve. 3 3 Elasticity Quantitative skills 3.2 showed how to calculate the price elasticity of demand at different points along a demand curve for pencils. When the price of a pencil fell from 40 to 35, the quantity demanded rose from 20 to 30, and elasticity was calculated to be −4. inelastic (−0.25). At the original price, revenue was 10 × 80 = 800, and at the lower price it was 9 × 82 = 738. This time, total revenue has fallen with a fall in price and inelastic demand. Price For the case of a straight-line demand curve, the relationship between elasticity and total revenue is illustrated in Figure 3.4. Elastic Unit elastic Inelastic Demand Quantity Price 0 Total revenue 0 Quantity ▲ Figure 3.4 Elasticity and total revenue Remember that demand is price elastic when price is relatively high. This is the range of the demand curve in which total revenue rises as price falls. This makes sense, as in this range the quantity demanded is sensitive to a change in price and increases by more (in percentage terms) than the price falls. This implies that, as you move to the right in this segment, total revenue rises. The increase in quantity sold more than compensates for the fall in price. However, when the mid-point is reached and 43 308275_C03_CAM_IASAL ECO_040_053.indd 43 16/02/21 5:29 PM 3 This relationship is relevant in the discussion of firms’ behaviour in Chapter 20. ▼ Table 3.1 Total revenue, elasticity and a price change Price elasticity of demand For a price increase, total revenue… For a price decrease, total revenue… Elastic falls rises Unit elastic does not change does not change Inelastic rises falls If a firm is aware of the price elasticity demand for its product, it can anticipate consumer response to its price change, which may be a powerful strategic tool. Test yourself 3.3 What would happen to a firm’s total revenue if it were to increase the price of its product when demand is elastic? An important point must be made here. If the price elasticity of demand varies along a straight-line demand curve, such a curve cannot be referred to as either elastic or inelastic. To do so is to confuse the elasticity with the slope of the demand curve. It is not only the steepness of the demand curve that determines the elasticity, but also the point on the curve at which the elasticity is measured. Two extreme cases of the price elasticity of demand should also be mentioned. Demand may sometimes be totally insensitive to price, so that the same quantity will be demanded whatever price is set for it. In such a situation, demand is said to be perfectly inelastic. The demand curve in this case is vertical – as in Di in Figure 3.5. In this situation, the numerical value of the price elasticity is zero, as quantity demanded does not change in response to a change in the price of the good. Price AS LEVEL PART 2 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY LEARNING LINK demand becomes unit elastic, total revenue stops rising – it is at its maximum at this point. The remaining part of the curve is inelastic: that is, the increase in quantity demanded is no longer sufficient to compensate for the decrease in price, and total revenue falls. Table 3.1 summarises the situation. Di De Pe 0 Perfectly inelastic demand Perfectly elastic demand Qi Quantity per period ▲ Figure 3.5 Perfectly elastic and inelastic demand The other extreme is shown on the same figure, where De is a horizontal demand curve and demand is perfectly elastic. The numerical value of the elasticity here is infinity. Consumers demand an unlimited quantity of the good at price Pe. No firm has any incentive to lower price below this level, but if price were to rise above Pe, demand would fall to zero. An example A study carried out in Pakistan found that the price elasticity of demand for household electricity was −0.63. This means that demand for electricity was inelastic. If the price of electricity were to increase by 10%, there would be a fall of just 6.3% in the quantity of electricity demanded. 44 308275_C03_CAM_IASAL ECO_040_053.indd 44 16/02/21 5:29 PM Factors that influence the price elasticity of demand 3 3 Elasticity A number of important influences on the price elasticity of demand can now be identified. The most important is the availability of substitutes for the good or service under consideration. For example, think about the demand for cauliflowers. Cauliflowers and broccoli are often seen as being very similar, so if the price of cauliflowers is high one week, people might quite readily switch to broccoli. The demand for cauliflowers can be said to be price sensitive (elastic), as consumers can readily substitute an alternative product. On the other hand, if the prices of all vegetables rise, demand will not change very much, as there are no substitutes for vegetables in the diet. In other words, goods that have close substitutes available will tend to exhibit elastic demand, whereas the demand for goods for which there are no substitutes will tend to be more inelastic. Associated with this is the question of whether an individual regards a good or service as a necessity or as a luxury item. If a good is a necessity, then demand for it will tend to be inelastic, whereas if a good is regarded as a luxury, consumers will tend to be more price-sensitive. This is closely related to the question of substitutes, as by labelling a good as a necessity, one is essentially saying that there are no substitutes for it. A further influence on the price elasticity of demand is the relative share of the good or service in overall expenditure. You may not notice small changes in the price of an inexpensive item that is a small part of overall expenditure, such as salt. This tends to mean that demand for that good is relatively inelastic. On the other hand, an item that figures large in the household budget will be seen very differently, and consumers will tend to be much more sensitive to price when a significant proportion of their income is involved. Finally, the time period under consideration may be important. Consumers may respond more strongly to a price change in the long run than to one in the short run. An increase in the price of petrol may have limited effects in the short run; however, in the long run, consumers may buy smaller cars or switch to diesel. Thus, the elasticity of demand tends to be more elastic in the long run than in the short run. Habit or commitment to a certain pattern of consumption may dictate the short-run pattern of consumption, but people do eventually adjust to price changes. SUMMARY: THE PRICE ELASTICITY OF DEMAND » The price elasticity of demand measures the sensitivity of the quantity of a STUDY TIP Be ready to identify the four key influences on the PED: » the availability of close substitutes for the good » whether the good is perceived as a necessity » the proportion of income or expenditure devoted to the good » the time period over which elasticity is considered » » » » » » good demanded to a change in its price. As there is an inverse relationship between quantity demanded and price, the price elasticity of demand is always negative. Where consumers are sensitive to a change in price, the percentage change in quantity demanded will exceed the percentage change in price. The elasticity of demand then takes on a value that is smaller than −1, and demand is said to be elastic. Where consumers are not very sensitive to a change in price, the percentage change in quantity demanded will be smaller than the percentage change in price. Elasticity of demand then takes on a value that is between zero and −1, and demand is said to be inelastic. When demand is elastic, a fall (rise) in price leads to a rise (fall) in total revenue. When demand is inelastic, a fall (rise) in price leads to a fall (rise) in total revenue. The size of the price elasticity of demand is influenced by the availability of substitutes for a good, whether the good is seen as a luxury or a necessity, the relative share of expenditure on the good in the consumer’s budget and the time that consumers have to adjust. 45 308275_C03_CAM_IASAL ECO_040_053.indd 45 16/02/21 5:29 PM AS LEVEL PART 2 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 3 EXERCISE 3.1 Examine Table 3.2, which shows the demand for Pedro’s premium olive oil at different prices. a Draw the demand curve. b Calculate the price elasticity of demand when the price increases from $8 to $10. c Calculate the price elasticity of demand when the price increases from $6 to $8. d Calculate the price elasticity of demand when the price increases from $4 to $6. KEY TERM income elasticity of demand (YED): a measure of the sensitivity of quantity demanded to a change in consumer incomes LEARNING LINK Normal and inferior goods are discussed in Chapter 2 as part of the explanation of demand. Test yourself 3.4 What would be the value of the YED if a 5% increase in consumer income leads to a 10% fall in quantity demanded? KEY TERM necessity good: one for which the income elasticity of demand is income-inelastic, so demand varies by relatively little as income changes ▼ Table 3.2 Demand for Pedro’s olive oil Price ($) Quantity demanded (bottles per week) 10 20 8 40 6 60 4 80 2 100 3.2 Income elasticity of demand Elasticity is a measure of the sensitivity of a variable to changes in another variable. In the same way as the price elasticity of demand is determined, an elasticity measure can be calculated for any other influence on demand or supply. The income elasticity of demand (YED) is therefore defined as: YED = % change in quantity demanded % change in consumer income The YED measures the extent to which the demand for a good or service will change in response to a change in consumer incomes. The size and direction of the change in demand will depend on how consumers perceive the good or service. Factors affecting the YED Unlike the price elasticity of demand, the income elasticity of demand may be either positive or negative. Remember the distinction between normal and inferior goods? For normal goods the quantity demanded will increase as consumer income rises, whereas for inferior goods the quantity demanded will tend to fall as income rises. So, for normal goods the YED will be positive, whereas for inferior goods it will be negative. Suppose you discover that the YED for an economics magazine is 0.7. How do you interpret this number? If consumer incomes were to increase by 10%, the demand for the magazine would increase by 10 × 0.7 = 7%. This example of a normal good may be helpful information for the magazine publishers, if they know that consumer incomes are rising over time. On the other hand, if the YED for coach travel is −0.3, this means that a 10% increase in consumer incomes will lead to a 3% fall in the demand for coach travel – perhaps because more people are travelling by car. In this instance, coach travel would be regarded as an inferior good. Goods for which there are no substitutes (such as food, water or essential medicines) will be income-inelastic. People will buy such goods even if their income changes. Such goods are necessities. In some cases the YED may be very strongly positive. For example, suppose that the YED for digital cameras is +2. This implies that the quantity demanded of such cameras will increase by 20% for every 10% increase in incomes. Table 3.3 summarises the ranges of the YED. 46 308275_C03_CAM_IASAL ECO_040_053.indd 46 16/02/21 5:29 PM ▼ Table 3.3 Values of the YED YED value Description Below −1 Elastic inferior good Between −1 and 0 Inelastic inferior good 0 No relationship between income and quantity demanded Between 0 and 1 Inelastic normal good Above 1 Elastic normal good Calculate the income elasticity of demand in each of the following circumstances. In each case, assume that consumer income rises by 5%. In each case, classify the good using Table 3.3. a b c d e Quantity demanded changes from 150 to 165. Quantity demanded changes from 80 to 78. Quantity demanded changes from 100 to 102. Quantity demanded changes from 400 to 320. Quantity demanded stays at 600. 3 Elasticity EXERCISE 3.2 3 SUMMARY: INCOME ELASTICITY OF DEMAND » The income elasticity of demand (YED) measures the sensitivity of demand to a change in consumer incomes. » For a normal good, the YED is positive, as an increase (decrease) in income induces an increase (decrease) in demand. KEY TERM cross elasticity of demand (XED): a measure of the sensitivity of quantity demanded of a good or service to a change in the price of some other good or service LEARNING LINK Substitutes and complements are explained in section 2.3 of Chapter 2. » For an inferior good, the YED is negative, as an increase (decrease) in income induces a decrease (increase) in demand. 3.3 Cross elasticity of demand (XED) Another useful measure is the cross elasticity of demand (XED). This is helpful in revealing the interrelationships between goods. Again, this measure may be either positive or negative, depending on the relationship between the goods. It is defined as: % change in quantity demanded of good X XED = % change in price of good Y If the XED is seen to be positive, it means that an increase in the price of good Y leads to an increase in the quantity demanded of good X. For example, an increase in the price of apples may lead to an increase in the demand for pears. Here apples and pears are regarded as substitutes for each other; if one becomes relatively more expensive, consumers will switch to the other. A high value for the XED indicates that two goods are very close substitutes. This information may be useful in helping a firm to identify its close competitors. On the other hand, if an increase in the price of one good leads to a fall in the quantity demanded of another good, this suggests that they are likely to be complements. The XED in this case will be negative. An example of such a relationship is that between coffee and sugar, which tend to be consumed together. Examples Suppose you found that the XED for sugar with respect to a change in the price of coffee was −0.087. This would imply that a 10% increase in the price of coffee would lead to a 0.87% fall in the demand for sugar, suggesting that coffee and 47 308275_C03_CAM_IASAL ECO_040_053.indd 47 16/02/21 5:29 PM 3 Test yourself 3.5 If the XED for a good is negative, would this suggest that the goods are substitutes or complements? sugar are complements. If the XED for pineapples with respect to a change in the price of mangoes was +0.532, this would suggest that a 10% increase in the price of pineapples would lead to a 5.32% increase in the demand for mangoes, suggesting that pineapples and mangoes are substitutes. If the XED were seen to be zero, this would indicate that the goods concerned were unrelated – neither substitutes nor complements. Table 3.4 summarises the XED values. AS LEVEL PART 2 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY ▼ Table 3.4 Values of the XED XED value Description Below −1 Elastic complement Between −1 and 0 Inelastic complement 0 No relationship between the two goods Between 0 and 1 Inelastic substitute Above 1 Elastic substitute EXERCISE 3.3 Calculate the cross elasticity of demand in each of the following circumstances. In each case, assume that the price of another good rises by 15%. In each case, classify the good using Table 3.4. a Quantity demanded changes from 200 to 260. b c d e Quantity demanded changes from 400 to 310. Quantity demanded changes from 500 to 560. Quantity demanded changes from 50 to 47. Quantity demanded stays at 300. SUMMARY: CROSS ELASTICITY OF DEMAND » The cross elasticity of demand (XED) measures the sensitivity of the quantity demanded of one good or service to a change in the price of some other good or service. » If the XED is positive, this indicates that the two goods are substitutes. » If the XED is negative, this indicates that the goods are seen by consumers as complements. » If the XED is zero, then the goods are unrelated. 3.4 Price elasticity of supply KEY TERM price elasticity of supply (PES): a measure of the sensitivity of quantity supplied of a good or service to a change in the price of that good or service As elasticity is a measure of sensitivity, its use need not be confined to influences on demand, but can also be turned to evaluating the sensitivity of quantity supplied to a change in its determinants – in particular, its price. It was argued in Chapter 2 that the supply curve is likely to be upward sloping, so the price elasticity of supply can be expected to be positive. In other words, an increase in the market price will induce firms to supply more output to the market. The price elasticity of supply (PES) is defined as: PES = Test yourself 3.6 Why is the PES a positive number? % change in the quantity supplied % change in price So, if the price elasticity of supply is 0.8, an increase in price of 10% will encourage firms to supply 8% more. As with the price elasticity of demand, if the elasticity is greater than 1, supply is referred to as being elastic, whereas if the value is between 0 and 1, supply is considered inelastic. Unitary elasticity occurs when the price elasticity of supply is exactly 1, so that a 10% increase in price induces a 10% increase in quantity supplied. 48 308275_C03_CAM_IASAL ECO_040_053.indd 48 16/02/21 5:29 PM Factors affecting the PES Price The value of the elasticity will depend on how willing and able firms are to increase their supply. For example, if firms are operating close to the capacity of their existing plant and machinery, they may be unable to respond to an increase in price, at least in the short run. So here again, supply can be expected to be more elastic in the long run than in the short run. Figure 3.6 illustrates this. Ss 3 Sl 3 Elasticity Test yourself 3.7 Will a firm’s supply curve be more or less elastic in the long run as compared with the short run? 0 Quantity per period ▲ Figure 3.6 Short- and long-run elasticity of supply LEARNING LINK The distinction between the short run and the long run will be more fully discussed in Chapter 17, when we explore how producers face costs that may be fixed in the short run. KEY TERMS perfectly elastic supply: a situation in which firms will supply any quantity of a good at the going price – elasticity of supply is infinite perfectly inelastic supply: a situation in which firms can supply only a fixed quantity, so cannot increase or decrease the amount available – elasticity of supply is zero In the short run, firms may be able to respond to an increase in price only in a limited way, and so supply may be relatively inelastic, as shown by Ss in the figure. However, firms can become more flexible in the long run by installing new machinery or building new factories, so supply can then become more elastic, moving to Sl . There are two limiting cases of supply elasticity. For some reason, supply may be fixed such that no matter by how much price increases, firms will not be able to supply any more. For example, it could be that a certain amount of fish is available in a market, and however high the price goes, no more can be obtained. Equally, if the fishermen know that the fish they do not sell today cannot be stored for another day, they have an incentive to sell, however low the price goes. In these cases, supply is perfectly inelastic and the supply curve would be vertical. At the other extreme is perfectly elastic supply, where firms would be prepared to supply any amount of the good at the going price so the supply curve would be horizontal. Using the PES Knowing the value of the PES provides information about how readily firms are able to respond to changes in market conditions. If the PES is strongly positive (supply is highly elastic), then this indicates that firms are able to respond quickly and flexibly to a change in market conditions, whereas when supply is inelastic, firms in the market will not be able to react in the short run. This could be important for the government’s decision making. If the government wants to encourage the supply of a good, it will be important to know whether firms will be able to increase supply speedily and easily. A high PES implies that firms will not be able to react. There is no point in calling on firms to supply more if they do not have the capacity to do so. Important in this is whether firms have access to machinery, labour and raw materials needed to expand production. 49 308275_C03_CAM_IASAL ECO_040_053.indd 49 16/02/21 5:29 PM AS LEVEL PART 2 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 3 EXERCISE 3.4 Calculate the price elasticity of supply in each of the following circumstances. In each case, assume that the price of the good rises by 20%. a Quantity supplied changes from 500 to 800. b Quantity supplied changes from 200 to 220. c Quantity supplied stays at 750. SUMMARY: PRICE ELASTICITY OF SUPPLY » The price elasticity of supply (PES) measures the sensitivity of the quantity supplied to a change in the price of a good or service. » The size of the price elasticity of supply depends on how flexible firms can be in varying their output. » The price elasticity of supply can be expected to be greater in the long run than in the short run, as firms have more flexibility to adjust their production decisions in the long run. 3.5 T he usefulness and significance of elasticities for decision making Knowledge of the PED, YED and XED can be useful to firms and to the government as part of their decision making. These elasticities can help in assessing the likely impact of proposed decisions. The PED For a firm, the PED will be informative about how buyers of the good are likely to respond to a price change. This is important for a firm that is trying to set its price to maximise profits. If a firm knows that demand is elastic, an increase in price would lead to a fall in revenues, whereas if demand is inelastic, revenues would increase, as buyers would respond less strongly to a price increase. The significance of the PED turns partly on the difficulty of obtaining an estimate of it. This is beyond the means of even a medium-sized firm. However, firms are likely to have a sense of how consumers will react to a change in the price of their product, which may be important in setting or changing price. An understanding of the factors that influence the PED will help firms to come to a view about the likely elasticity of demand that they face in respect of their product. From the government perspective, imposing an indirect tax will raise the price and lead to a fall in demand, so knowing the PED helps to forecast the tax revenues expected. This is explored in Chapter 5. Introducing a subsidy would reduce the selling price of a good, and knowing the PED allows the government to assess the impact of such a move. The YED The YED will help a firm to forecast changing demand if real incomes are increasing, or if the economy is heading into a recession. Knowing whether a good is normal or inferior is significant in this situation. If a firm is trying to anticipate the future state of demand for its product, then knowing that it is producing a normal good (with a positive YED) will be good news if the economy is expanding, so that consumer incomes are expected to rise. 50 308275_C03_CAM_IASAL ECO_040_053.indd 50 16/02/21 5:29 PM LEARNING LINK The XED helps in anticipating changes in demand if the prices of other products are changing. A firm needs to know who its competitors are when devising its own strategy, so it may be important to be aware of whether another firm’s products are close substitutes, or whether they are complements. If the XED is strongly positive with respect to a good produced by a rival firm, the firm will be aware that it needs to take care when thinking about raising price, as demand would be affected and damage its position in the market. From the government perspective, imposing an indirect tax will raise the price and lead to a fall in demand, so knowing the PED helps to forecast the tax revenues expected. This is explored in Chapter 5. Introducing a subsidy would reduce the selling price of a good, and knowing the PED allows the government to assess the impact of such a move. 3 3 Elasticity The effects of an indirect tax are introduced in Chapter 5 and discussed in more detail in Chapter 21. The way in which firms in a market may react to each other’s actions is discussed in Chapters 18 and 19. The XED It may not always be straightforward to obtain estimates of the various elasticities. However, if economic agents know about the factors that influence the elasticities, and if they understand their significance, they may be able to take better decisions. EXERCISE 3.5 Imagine the following scenario. You are considering a pricing strategy for a bus company. The economy is heading into recession, and the company is running at a loss. Your local rail service provider has announced an increase in rail fares. How (if at all) do you use the following information concerning the elasticity of bus travel with respect to various variables to inform your decision on price? Would you raise or lower price? » price elasticity of demand −1.58 » income elasticity of demand −2.43 » cross elasticity of demand with respect to rail fares +2.21 » your price elasticity of supply +1.15 SUMMARY: THE USEFULNESS AND SIGNIFICANCE OF ELASTICITIES » The elasticity measures can be useful to firms by providing information about how demand is likely to change in the face of changing market conditions. » The government can also use measures of elasticity when seeking to devise policies. » Finding reliable quantitative estimates of elasticity measures is not straightforward. END OF CHAPTER QUESTIONS Multiple choice 1 Which of the options is valid along a normal, downward-sloping demand curve? A The PED and hence total revenue (TR) are constant along the whole demand curve. B The PED falls when moving down along the demand curve, while TR first rises, then falls. C The PED and hence TR first rise and then fall when moving down along the demand curve. D The PED and hence TR first fall and then rise when moving down along the demand curve. 2 Other things being equal, which of the following firms will experience an increase in total revenue in times of recession? A a firm with a PED of −0.8 B a firm with a PES of 1.8 C a firm with a XED of +0.8 D a firm with an YED of −1.8 51 308275_C03_CAM_IASAL ECO_040_053.indd 51 16/02/21 5:29 PM Data response 3 1 Study Tables 3.5 and 3.6 and then answer the questions that follow. ▼ Table 3.5 Estimated price and income elasticity data for selected food items in Vietnam, 2020 AS LEVEL PART 2 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY Food item Price elasticity of demand Price elasticity of supply Income elasticity of demand Rice −0.89 0.52 0.96 Goat −0.79 0.63 1.01 Poultry −1.09 0.58 1.01 Fish −0.94 0.64 1.03 Vegetables −0.97 0.31 0.99 Fruit −0.93 0.42 1.00 Source: adapted from Linh Hoang Vu, ‘Estimation and Analysis of Food Demand Patterns in Vietnam’, 2020 ▼ Table 3.6 Average salary/monthly consumer income in India, 2016–24 Year Average salary/monthly consumer income in India in Indian rupees (IRS) 2016 29,600 2017 30,700 2018 31,100 2019 31,600 2020 32,200 2024* 41,700 *estimated figure Source: http://www.salaryexplorer.com a With reference to Table 3.5: i Use a formula to calculate the value of the price elasticity of supply of rice and interpret the meaning of the value. ii Explain how goat and poultry can have the same income elasticity of demand but different price elasticity of demand. b With reference to Table 3.6, if the demand for petrol in India increased by 0.76% between 2019 and 2020, calculate the income elasticity of demand for petrol in India in 2020. c Explain, with reference to Table 3.5, why ‘time’ is likely to be an important factor in determining the price elasticity of supply of vegetables. d A Vietnamese poultry farmer is trying to increase her revenue as a result of altering the price she charges. Assess the usefulness of the information in Table 3.5. Essay style 2 a T he ‘Tiago’ is a small city car made by Tata Motors in India since 2016. It is considered a functional vehicle and one of the least expensive in Tata’s range. In 2020, Tata shifted its focus to the launch of the ‘Harrier’ – a five-seater petrol sports utility vehicle (SUV) that sits at the luxury end of Tata’s fleet. With the help of a formula, explain the meaning of income elasticity of demand and consider the likely success of the 2020 launch of Tata’s Harrier SUV at a time of rising incomes in India. b Discuss whether income elasticity of demand or price elasticity of demand of Tata’s Tiago car is likely to be greater. 52 308275_C03_CAM_IASAL ECO_040_053.indd 52 18/03/21 4:25 PM CASE STUDY 3 Fish 3 Elasticity Imagine a remote island in the South Seas. Some of the islanders own canoes which they use to go fishing, selling their catch on the beach when they return each day. Some islanders only go fishing occasionally, as they find it more worthwhile to spend their time on other activities. The island has no electricity, so there is no way of storing the fish that are caught – if they are not consumed on the day of the catch, they must be thrown away. ▲ Fishing in the Solomon Islands The market for fish on the island is limited by the size of the population. Fortunately for the fishermen, the islanders enjoy fish, and regard it as an important part of their diet, although they also grow vegetables and raise goats and chickens. Fruit and coconuts are also abundant. Follow-up questions a What would you expect to be the nature of the price elasticity of supply in the short run (that is, on any given day)? b Suppose that, on one particular day, fishing conditions are so good that all fishermen return with record catches. How would this affect the price of fish? c How might the situation in (b) affect the supply of fish on the following day? d How would you expect the supply of fish to be affected by the invention of a new style of canoe that makes it easier to catch fish? e How would the market be affected if this new-style canoe also enabled fish to be traded with a neighbouring island? Go online at hoddereducation.com/cambridgeextras for more case studies for Chapter 3. 53 308275_C03_CAM_IASAL ECO_040_053.indd 53 18/03/21 2:42 PM AS LEVEL PART 2 The price system and the microeconomy What this chapter covers ★ equilibrium and disequilibrium in a market ★ shifts in demand and supply ★ relationships between markets ★ the role of prices in allocating resources ★ consumer and producer surplus The previous chapters introduced the notions of demand and supply, and it is now time to bring the demand and supply curves together in order to meet the key concept of market equilibrium. The model can then be further developed to see how it provides insights into how markets operate. You will encounter demand and supply in a variety of contexts, and begin to glimpse some of the ways in which the model can help to explain how the economic world works. 4.1 Market equilibrium The previous chapters have described the components of the demand and supply model. It only remains to bring them together, for this is how the power of the model can be appreciated. Figure 4.1 shows the demand for and supply of rice. Suppose that the price were to be set at a relatively high price (above P*). At such a price, firms wish to supply lots of rice to the market. However, consumers are not very keen on rice at such a high price, so demand is not strong. Firms now have a problem: they find that their stocks of rice are building up. What has happened is that the price has been set at a level that exceeds the value that most consumers place on rice, so they will not buy it. There is excess supply. Given this surplus of supply over demand, firms need to reduce price in order to clear their stocks. Price AS LEVEL PART 2 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 4 Market equilibrium and the price system Excess supply when price is high Supply P* Excess demand when price is low Demand 0 Q* Quantity of rice per period ▲ Figure 4.1 Bringing demand and supply together Suppose they now set their price relatively low (below P*). Now it is the consumers who have a problem, because they would like to buy more rice at the low price than firms are willing and able to supply. There is excess demand. Some consumers may offer to pay more than the going price in order to obtain their rice supplies, and firms realise that because of the shortage, they can raise the price. 54 308275_C04_CAM_IASAL ECO_054_072.indd 54 16/02/21 5:34 PM EXERCISE 4.1 Identify the equilibrium market price if demand and supply are as in Figure 4.2. Pa Supply Pb Pc Test yourself 4.1 How would you expect price to adjust when there is excess demand for a good in a competitive market? 4 Pd Pe Demand 0 Quantity per period ▲ Figure 4.2 What is the equilibrium price? 4 Market equilibrium and the price system If a market is away from equilibrium (i.e. if it is in disequilibrium), it is important to understand how the price adjusts to return the market to equilibrium. When there is a surplus, price will tend to fall towards equilibrium. If there is a shortage, price will tend to rise. How will it all end? When the price settles at P* in Figure 4.1, there is a balance in the market between the quantity that consumers wish to demand and the quantity that firms wish to supply, namely Q*. This is the market equilibrium. In a free market, the price can be expected to converge on this equilibrium price, through movements along both demand and supply curves. When the price reaches equilibrium, there is no further reason for it to change, unless something disturbs that equilibrium. Price STUDY TIP KEY TERMS market equilibrium: a situation that occurs in a market when the price is such that the quantity that consumers wish to buy is exactly balanced by the quantity that firms wish to supply equilibrium price: the unique price at which the quantity demanded by consumers in a market is just balanced by the quantity that firms wish to supply QUANTITATIVE SKILLS 4.1 Identifying and interpreting an intersection on a diagram You will meet many diagrams in economics where there are upward- and downward-sloping lines that intersect at some point. Such intersection points are almost always significant. In the case of demand and supply, the downwardsloping line represents demand, and the upward-sloping curve shows supply. Only at the point where the two lines meet are the decisions of consumers and firms mutually consistent. In other words, consumers are choosing to demand exactly the quantity that firms are willing and able to supply. The important question to explore is the mechanism that will lead to this equilibrium point. This in turn depends on the incentives facing economic agents if the starting point is away from the intersection point. STUDY TIP In this section, we have discussed the market for a product. You will also meet other types of market – for example, there are markets for factors of production and for foreign exchange. SUMMARY: MARKET EQUILIBRIUM » Bringing demand and supply together, you can identify the market equilibrium. » The equilibrium price is the unique point at which the quantity demanded by consumers is just balanced by the quantity that firms wish to supply. » In a free market, natural forces can be expected to encourage prices to adjust to the equilibrium level. 55 308275_C04_CAM_IASAL ECO_054_072.indd 55 16/02/21 5:34 PM In the previous section, we explored the way in which a market moves towards equilibrium between demand and supply through price adjustments and movements along the demand and supply curves. This is static analysis, in the sense that a ceteris paribus assumption is imposed by holding constant the factors that influence demand and supply, in order to focus on the way in which the market reaches equilibrium. In the next stage, we explore the effect on market equilibrium if one of these background factors is changed. In other words, beginning with a market in equilibrium, one of the factors affecting either demand or supply is altered, and the new market equilibrium is then studied. A market for dried noodles Begin with a simple market for dried noodles, a basic staple foodstuff that is widely obtainable. Figure 4.3 shows the market in equilibrium. Price per kilo AS LEVEL PART 2 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 4 4.2 The effects of shifts in demand and supply curves S0 P0 D0 0 Q0 Quantity of noodles per week ▲ Figure 4.3 A market for noodles D0 represents the demand curve in this initial situation, and S0 is the supply curve. The market is in equilibrium with the price at P0, and the quantity being traded is Q0. It is equilibrium in the sense that noodles producers are supplying just the amount of noodles that consumers wish to buy at that price. This is the ‘before’ position. Some experiments will now be carried out with this market by disturbing the equilibrium. A change in consumer preferences Suppose that a study is published highlighting the health benefits of eating noodles, backed up with an advertising campaign. The effect of this is likely to be an increase in the demand for noodles at any given price. In other words, this change in consumer preferences will shift the demand curve to the right, as shown in Figure 4.4. 56 308275_C04_CAM_IASAL ECO_054_072.indd 56 16/02/21 5:34 PM Price per kilo S0 4 P1 P0 0 Q0 Q1 Quantity of noodles per week ▲ Figure 4.4 A change in consumer preferences for noodles The market now adjusts to a new equilibrium, with a new price P1, and a new quantity traded at Q1. In this case, both price and quantity have increased as a result of the change in preferences. A change in the price of a substitute Price per kilo A second possibility is that there is a fall in the price of fresh noodles. This is likely to be a close substitute for dried noodles, so the probable result is that some former consumers of dried noodles will switch to the fresh variety. This time the demand curve for dried noodles moves in the opposite direction, as can be seen in Figure 4.5. 4 Market equilibrium and the price system D1 D0 S0 P0 P2 D2 0 D0 Q2 Q0 Quantity of noodles per week ▲ Figure 4.5 A change in the price of a substitute for dried noodles Here the starting point is the original position, with market equilibrium at price P0 and a quantity traded of Q0. After the shift in the demand curve from D0 to D2, the market settles again with a price of P2 and a quantity traded of Q2. Both price and quantity traded are now lower than in the original position. An improvement in noodles technology Next, suppose that a new noodle-making machine is produced, enabling dried noodle makers to produce at a lower cost than before. This advance reduces firms’ costs, and consequently they are prepared to supply more dried noodles at any given price. The starting point is the same initial position, but now it is the supply curve that moves – to the right. This is shown in Figure 4.6. 57 308275_C04_CAM_IASAL ECO_054_072.indd 57 16/02/21 5:34 PM Price per kilo 4 S0 S3 P0 D0 0 Q0 Q3 Quantity of noodles per week ▲ Figure 4.6 New noodles-making technology Again, we can see how the market equilibrium changes. The new market equilibrium is at price P3, which is lower than the original equilibrium, but the quantity traded is higher at Q3. An increase in labour costs Finally, suppose that noodles producers face an increase in their labour costs. Perhaps the Noodle Workers’ Union has negotiated higher wages, or the noodles producers have become subject to stricter health and safety legislation, which raises their production costs. Figure 4.7 starts as usual with equilibrium at price P0 and quantity Q0. Price per kilo AS LEVEL PART 2 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY P3 S4 S0 P4 P0 D0 0 Q4 Q0 Quantity of noodles per week ▲ Figure 4.7 An increase in labour costs The increase in production costs means that noodles producers are prepared to supply fewer dried noodles at any given price, so the supply curve shifts to the left – to S4. This takes the market to a new equilibrium at a higher price than before (P4), but with a lower quantity traded (Q4). Shifts in both demand and supply In the real world, it is quite possible for there to be shifts in both demand and supply curves at the same time. The outcome for the market equilibrium will then depend on the relative strength and direction of the shifts. Figure 4.8 shows one example. In this case, the market begins in equilibrium with demand D0 and supply S0 in balance at price P0 and quantity traded Q0. Suppose that there is an increase in supply to S1 combined with a decrease in demand to D1. The new equilibrium is at price P1 and 58 308275_C04_CAM_IASAL ECO_054_072.indd 58 16/02/21 5:34 PM What factors could affect the position of the supply curve? Test yourself 4.3 Test yourself 4.4 In the summer of 2018 the UK experienced a heatwave and the media highlighted a shortage of carbon dioxide (CO2), which is used in manufacturing fizzy drinks and in storing food products. What effect would you expect this to have on the market for fizzy drinks? S1 S0 P0 P1 D1 0 Q0 Q1 4 D0 Quantity ▲ Figure 4.8 Shifts in both demand and supply curves 4 Market equilibrium and the price system In a competitive market, suppose that the equilibrium price and the equilibrium quantity traded are both seen to increase. What shifts in the demand and supply curves could have taken place? quantity traded Q1. So, in this case, there has been a fall in the price and a rise in the quantity traded. Notice that the extent of the increase in supply was large compared with the magnitude of the decrease in demand. If the supply curve had shifted by less and the demand curve by more, the result would have been different – indeed, the quantity traded might have stayed the same or fallen in this alternative situation. (You could sketch some diagrams to try for yourself what would happen with different combinations of demand and supply shifts.) Price Test yourself 4.2 STUDY TIP Economists use diagrams a lot to analyse how equilibrium is affected by external changes – in this case, a change in market conditions that induces a shift in the demand curve. Remember that practice makes perfect, so watch in the news for examples of events that are likely to affect a market, and draw demand and supply curves to analyse what is expected to happen next. SUMMARY: THE EFFECTS OF SHIFTS IN DEMAND AND SUPPLY CURVES » A change in the market environment can cause a shift in demand or supply. » The market then moves to a new equilibrium position as price adjusts to the change. 4.3 Relationships between different markets KEY TERM alternative demand: a situation in which demand for a good is affected by a change in the price of an alternative (substitute) good There are situations in which markets are interrelated, such that changes that affect one market have knock-on effects elsewhere. Alternative demand We have already seen one example of interrelated markets in the previous section. Figure 4.5 showed the effect of a change in the price of fresh noodles on the demand for dried noodles. This effect arose because the two goods were seen as substitutes for each other, as fresh noodles are viewed as being an alternative to dried noodles. This is known as alternative demand. 59 308275_C04_CAM_IASAL ECO_054_072.indd 59 16/02/21 5:34 PM 4 Test yourself 4.5 Joint demand Give examples of products that illustrate situations of alternative and joint demand. Where two goods are seen as complements in their use, there will also be an interrelationship between the markets, known as joint demand, because the goods are consumed together. For example, many people like to take some sugar with their coffee, so sugar and coffee are consumed together. If there is a surge in the popularity of coffee, this will also bring an increase in the demand for sugar. KEY Test TERMS yourself 4.5 joint demand: aof Give examples situation which goods products in that illustrate are consumed together situations of alternative – in other words, where and joint demand. they are complements derived demand: where the demand for a good or a factor of production derives not from the good or factor itself, but from the good or service that it provides There are situations in which the demand for a good or service is indirect. This is best seen through some examples. The labour market Within the economy, firms demand labour and employees supply labour – so can we use demand and supply to analyse the market for a factor of production? From the firms’ point of view, the demand for labour is a derived demand. In other words, firms want labour not for its own sake, but for the output that it produces. When the price of labour is low, firms will tend to demand more of it than when the price of labour is high. The wage rate can be regarded as this price of labour. On the employee side, it is argued that more people tend to offer themselves for work when the wage is relatively high. On this basis, the demand for labour curve is expected to be downward sloping and the supply of labour curve upward sloping, as in Figure 4.9. Wage rate AS LEVEL PART 2 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY Derived demand Labour supply W* Labour demand 0 L* Quantity of labour per period ▲ Figure 4.9 A labour market LEARNING LINKS The working of labour markets is discussed in more detail in Chapter 23. The significance of the exchange rate is examined in Chapters 13 and 29. As usual, the equilibrium in a free market will be at the intersection of demand and supply, so firms will hire L* labour at a wage rate of W*. The foreign exchange market If you were to take a holiday in the USA, you would need to buy dollars. Equally, when American tourists travel to visit Malaysia or Mauritius, they need to buy ringgits or rupees. If there is buying going on, then there must be a market. So here is another sort of market to be considered. The exchange rate is the price at which two currencies exchange, and it can be analysed using demand and supply. Consider the market for ringgits, and focus on the exchange rate between ringgits and dollars, as shown in Figure 4.10. 60 308275_C04_CAM_IASAL ECO_054_072.indd 60 16/02/21 5:34 PM 4 e* Demand 0 Quantity of ringgits per period ▲ Figure 4.10 The market for ringgits Think first about what gives rise to a demand for ringgits. It is not just Americans visiting Malaysia who need dollars to spend on holiday: anyone holding dollars who wants to buy Malaysian goods needs ringgits in order to pay for them. So the demand for ringgits comes from people outside Malaysia who want to buy Malaysian goods or services – or, indeed, assets. When the exchange rate for ringgits in terms of dollars is high, potential buyers of American goods get relatively few ringgits per dollar, so the demand will be relatively low, whereas if the dollar per ringgit rate is relatively low, they get more for their money. Hence the demand curve is expected to be downward sloping. 4 Market equilibrium and the price system Exchange rate (price of ringgits in dollars) Supply Foreign exchange is a derived demand, in the sense that people want ringgits not for their own sake, but for the goods or services that they can buy. One way of viewing the exchange rate is as a means by which to learn about the international competitiveness of exports from the USA. When the exchange rate (dollars per ringgit) is high, Malaysian goods are less competitive in the USA, ceteris paribus. Notice the ceteris paribus assumption here. This is important because the exchange rate is not the only determinant of the competitiveness of Malaysian goods: this also depends on the relative price levels in Malaysia and the USA. How about the supply of ringgits? Ringgits are supplied by Malaysians wanting dollars to buy goods or services from the USA. From this point of view, when the dollar/ ringgit rate is high, Malaysian residents get more dollars for their ringgits and therefore will tend to supply more ringgits. If the exchange market is in equilibrium, the exchange rate will be at e*, where the demand for ringgits is matched by the supply. Joint supply KEY TERM joint supply: where a firm produces more than one product together There are circumstances in which a firm may produce a range of goods jointly. Perhaps one good is a by-product of the production process of another. For example, a sheep farmer can produce both wool and meat from the sheep. An increase in the price of one of the goods may mean that the firm will produce more of both goods. This notion of joint supply is similar to the situation on the demand side where consumers regard two goods as complements. 61 308275_C04_CAM_IASAL ECO_054_072.indd 61 16/02/21 5:34 PM AS LEVEL PART 2 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 4 ▲ Sheep provide wool and meat EXERCISE 4.2 For each of the following market situations, sketch a demand and supply diagram, and see what happens to the equilibrium price and quantity. Explain your answers. a An increase in consumer incomes affects the market for bus travel. b New regulations on environmental pollution force a firm making paint to reduce its emission of toxic fumes. c A firm of accountants brings in new, faster computers to improve efficiency. d An outbreak of bird flu causes consumers of chicken to buy pizza instead. (What is the effect on both markets?) EXERCISE 4.3 Discuss how changes in the demand and supply of oil-based fuels could affect a related market. SUMMARY: RELATIONSHIPS BETWEEN DIFFERENT MARKETS » There are situations in which markets are interrelated, so that a change in one market affects others. » One way this happens is where two goods are substitutes for each other, which gives rise to alternative demand. » When two goods are complements, there is a situation of joint demand. » Derived demand is where something is demanded not for its own sake, but for the goods or services that it provides. » Joint supply occurs when a firm produces more than one good together. 62 308275_C04_CAM_IASAL ECO_054_072.indd 62 16/02/21 5:34 PM 4.4 The functions of prices in allocating resources The coordination problem Prices and preferences Price How can consumers signal their preferences to producers? Demand and supply analysis provides the clue. Figure 4.11 shows the demand and supply for smartphones. Over time there has been a rightward shift in the demand curve – in the figure, from D0 to D1. This simply means that consumers are placing a higher value on these goods; they are prepared to demand more at any given price. The result is that the market will move to a new equilibrium, with price rising from P0 to P1 and quantity traded from Q0 to Q1: there is an extension of supply. Supply 4 4 Market equilibrium and the price system As Chapter 1 indicated, all societies face the fundamental economic problem of scarcity. Because there are unlimited wants but finite resources, it is necessary to take decisions on which goods and services should be produced, how they should be produced and for whom they should be produced. For an economy the size of the USA or India, there is an immense coordination problem. Another way of looking at this is to ask how consumers can express their preferences between alternative goods so that producers can produce the best mix of goods and services. P1 P0 D0 0 D1 Q1 Q0 Quantity of smartphones per period ▲ Figure 4.11 The market for smartphones The shift in the demand curve is an expression of consumers’ preferences; it embodies the fact that they value smartphones more highly now than before. The price that consumers are willing to pay represents their valuation of smartphones. ▲ Smartphones are highly valued Notice also that price is effectively acting as a rationing device as part of coping with scarcity. Given limited resources, it is inevitable that not everyone who might want to consume a good or service will be able to do so. The price of the good limits access to those consumers who are willing and able to pay the price set by the market. Prices as signals and incentives From the producers’ perspective, the question is how they receive signals from consumers about their changing preferences. Price is the key. Figure 4.11 showed how an increase in demand for smartphones leads to an increase in the equilibrium price, which encourages producers to supply more smartphones – there is an extension of supply. This is really saying that producers find it profitable to expand their output of smartphones at that higher price. The price level is working as a signal to producers about consumer preferences. 63 308275_C04_CAM_IASAL ECO_054_072.indd 63 16/02/21 5:34 PM Notice that the price signal works equally well when there is a decrease in the demand for a good or service. In Figure 4.12 there has been a large fall in the demand for a good – for example, because a campaign has encouraged a switch away from junk food. The demand curve shifts to the left from D0 to D1. Producers of junk food begin to find that they cannot sell as much at the original price as before, so they have to reduce their price to avoid an increase in unsold stocks. They have less incentive to supply junk food, and will supply less. There is a contraction of supply and a movement along the supply curve to a lower equilibrium price at P1, and a lower quantity traded at Q1. LEARNING LINK Supply Price AS LEVEL PART 2 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 4 P0 P1 This may also affect the demand for factors of production (e.g. labour), as explained in Chapter 1. D1 D0 Q1 Q0 Quantity ▲ Figure 4.12 A decrease in demand This shows how existing producers in a market receive signals from consumers in the form of changes in the equilibrium price, and respond to these signals by adjusting their output levels. In this way, prices act to guide resource allocation in the economy. Test yourself 4.6 What would happen to the equilibrium price if there was a good harvest, creating excess supply? STUDY TIP Prices fulfil a range of functions in a market economy, including: » transmitting consumer preferences through signals to producers » providing incentives to producers » addressing shortages through rationing » guiding the allocation of resources SUMMARY: THE FUNCTIONS OF PRICES IN ALLOCATING RESOURCES » All societies face the fundamental problem of scarcity. » Prices can provide signals and incentives to guide the allocation of resources and can act as a rationing device. » Consumers can signal their preferences through the price mechanism. » Firms have incentives to respond to price signals. 4.5 Consumer and producer surplus Consumer surplus Think a little more carefully about what the demand curve represents. Figure 4.13 again shows the demand curve for smartphones. Suppose that the price is set at P* and quantity demanded is thus Q*. P* can be seen as the value that the last customer places on a smartphone. In other words, if the price were even slightly above P*, there would be one consumer who would choose not to buy: this individual will be referred to as the marginal consumer. 64 308275_C04_CAM_IASAL ECO_054_072.indd 64 16/02/21 5:34 PM Price 4 Consumer A’s valuation Consumer B’s valuation P* 0 AB Q* Quantity of smartphones per period ▲ Figure 4.13 Price as marginal benefit KEY TERM marginal social benefit (MSB): the additional benefit that society gains from consuming an extra unit of a good KEY TERM In most markets, all consumers face the same prices for goods and services. This leads to an important concept in economic analysis. P* may represent the value of smartphones to the marginal consumer, but what about all the other consumers who are also buying smartphones at P*? They would all be willing to pay a higher price for a smartphone. Indeed, consumer A in Figure 4.13 would pay a very high price indeed, and values a smartphone much more highly than P*. When consumer A pays P* for a smartphone, he gets a great deal, as he values the good so much more highly – as represented by the vertical green line on Figure 4.13. Consumer B also gains a surplus above her willingness to pay (the purple line). If all these surplus values are added up, they sum to the total surplus that society gains from consuming smartphones. This is known as the consumer surplus, represented by the shaded triangle in Figure 4.14. It can be interpreted as the welfare that society gains from consuming the good, over and above the price that has to be paid for it. Price consumer surplus: the value that consumers gain from consuming a good or service over and above the price paid for all but the last unit that is bought To that marginal consumer, P* represents the marginal benefit derived from consuming this good – it is the price that just reflects the consumer’s benefit from a smartphone, as it is the price that just induces her to buy. Thinking of the society as a whole (which is made up of all the consumers within it), P* can be regarded as the marginal social benefit (MSB) derived from consuming this good. The same argument could be made about any point along the demand curve, so the demand curve can be interpreted as the marginal benefit to be derived from consuming smartphones. 4 Market equilibrium and the price system Demand (MSB) A Test yourself 4.7 Explain why consumer surplus can be interpreted as representing the welfare that society gains from consuming a good. P* O B Demand (MSB) Q* Quantity of smartphones per period ▲ Figure 4.14 Consumer surplus 65 308275_C04_CAM_IASAL ECO_054_072.indd 65 16/02/21 5:34 PM 4 EXERCISE 4.4 Table 4.1 shows the price at which each of six consumers would be prepared to buy a good. AS LEVEL PART 2 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY ▼ Table 4.1 The price at which consumers A–F would buy a good Consumer A $20 Consumer B $18 Consumer C $16 Consumer D $14 Consumer E $12 Consumer F $10 Suppose the market price is at $14. a Which of the consumers would choose to buy the good? b What would be consumer A’s consumer surplus at this price? c What would be the total consumer surplus enjoyed by the consumers purchasing the good? d What would be the total consumer surplus if the price were to increase to $16? QUANTITATIVE SKILLS 4.2 Interpreting areas on a diagram In using diagrams like Figure 4.14, it is often important to be able to interpret areas on the graph as well as lines and positions. In this case, the area of interest is the total amount of consumer surplus. Notice that letters are used to identify points on the diagram (in this case, the points are labelled P*, Q*, A, B and O); a combination of these letters then identifies the area enclosed by the points. The area under the demand curve up to the quantity sold (Q*) represents the total value of the good that is sold. In total, consumers spend an amount on this which is the price multiplied by the quantity sold, namely P* multiplied by Q*. In Figure 4.14 total expenditure on the good is the area of the rectangle OP*BQ*. The consumer surplus is then the shaded triangle P*AB. LEARNING LINK The notion of the marginal principle was introduced in Chapter 1. Economists rely heavily on the idea that firms, consumers and other economic agents can make good decisions by thinking in terms of the margin, weighing up the effect of small changes. Consumer surplus and price There is a relationship between the size of consumer surplus and the price charged for a good. If the price of a good increases, this will reduce the overall size of consumer surplus, and affect the welfare that society receives from consuming the good. You can see this in Figure 4.15. 66 308275_C04_CAM_IASAL ECO_054_072.indd 66 16/02/21 5:34 PM Price 4 A C B Demand O G H Quantity ▲ Figure 4.15 Consumer surplus and price When the price of the good is relatively low at OE, quantity demanded is OH, consumers spend the area OEFH, and receive consumer surplus of AEF. However, if the price were to increase to OB, quantity demanded would fall to OG, spending would be the area OBCG, and consumer surplus would be lower than before, at ABC. KEY TERM Suppose there is an increase in the price of cinema tickets. What Figure 4.15 indicates is that there will be some people who will not go to the cinema as frequently as before, and that those who do go at the higher price will receive less in the way of consumer surplus than if the price had remained at its original lower level. Welfare has fallen. A key question is the extent to which the quantity demanded will fall, which depends on the elasticity of demand. When demand is elastic, the impact will be greater, because consumers will react more strongly than if demand is highly inelastic. Producer surplus Parallel to the notion of consumer surplus is the concept of producer surplus. Think about the nature of the supply curve: it reveals how much output firms are prepared to supply at any given price in a competitive market. Figure 4.16 depicts a supply curve. Assume the price is at P*, and that all units are sold at that price. P* represents the value to firms of the marginal unit sold. In other words, if the price had been set slightly below P*, the last unit would not have been supplied, as firms would not have found this profitable. Price producer surplus: the difference between the price received by firms for a good or service and the price at which they would have been prepared to supply that good or service 4 Market equilibrium and the price system F E Supply P* A 0 Q* Quantity supplied per period ▲ Figure 4.16 A supply curve 67 308275_C04_CAM_IASAL ECO_054_072.indd 67 16/02/21 5:34 PM marginal cost: the cost of producing an additional unit of output Notice that the threshold at which a firm will decide it is not profitable to supply is the point at which the price received by the firm reaches the cost to the firm of producing the last unit of the good. Thus, in a competitive market the supply curve reflects marginal cost. The supply curve shows that, in the range of prices between point A and P*, firms would have been willing to supply positive amounts of this good or service. So at P*, they would gain a surplus value on all units of the good supplied below Q*. The total area is shown in Figure 4.17: it is the area above the supply curve and below P*, shown as the shaded triangle. Price AS LEVEL PART 2 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 4 KEY TERM Supply P* A Test yourself 4.8 Explain why producer surplus may be considered as a motivation for firms. 0 Q* Quantity supplied per period ▲ Figure 4.17 Producer surplus One way of defining this producer surplus is as the surplus earned by firms over and above the minimum that would have kept them in the market. It is the reason for which firms exist. Notice that the extent to which suppliers can respond to a change in demand in the short run will depend on the elasticity of supply. If supply is inelastic, so that firms are unable to be flexible in varying their output level, then the short-run impact of a change in demand may be limited. Entry and exit of firms The discussion so far has focused on the reactions of existing firms in a market to changes in consumer preferences. However, this is only part of the picture. Think back to Figure 4.11, where there was an increase in demand for smartphones following a change in consumer preferences. The equilibrium price rose, and existing firms expanded the quantity supplied in response. Those firms are now earning a higher producer surplus than before. Other firms not currently in the market will be attracted by these surpluses, perceiving this to be a profitable market in which to operate. If there are no barriers to entry, more firms will join the market. This in turn will tend to shift the supply curve to the right, as there will then be more firms prepared to supply. As a result, the equilibrium market price will tend to drift down again, until the market reaches a position in which there is no further incentive for new firms to enter the market. This will occur when the rate of return for firms in the smartphone market is no better than in other markets. 68 308275_C04_CAM_IASAL ECO_054_072.indd 68 16/02/21 5:34 PM micro Price Figure 4.18 illustrates this situation. The original increase in demand leads, as before, to a new equilibrium with a higher price P1. As new firms join the market in quest of producer surplus, the supply curve shifts to the right to S2, pushing the price back down to P0, but with the quantity traded now up at Q2. 4 S0 S2 P0 D1 D0 0 Q0 Q1 Q2 Quantity of smartphones per period ▲ Figure 4.18 The market for smartphones revisited Price If the original movement in demand is in the opposite direction, as it was for junk food in Figure 4.12, a similar long-run adjustment takes place. As the market price falls, some firms in the market may decide that they no longer wish to remain in production, and will exit from the market altogether. This will shift the supply curve to the left in Figure 4.19 (to S2) until only firms that continue to find it profitable will remain in the market. In the final position, price is back to P0, and quantity traded has fallen to Q2. S2 4 Market equilibrium and the price system P1 S0 P0 P1 D1 0 Q2 D0 Q0 Q1 Quantity of junk food per period ▲ Figure 4.19 The market for junk food STUDY TIP These concepts of consumer and producer surplus will be important in later discussions of efficiency and inefficiency in resource allocation. 69 308275_C04_CAM_IASAL ECO_054_072.indd 69 16/02/21 5:34 PM AS LEVEL PART 2 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY Figure 4.20 shows the effect on consumer and producer surplus before and after a decrease in supply, caused by an increase in production costs. aIdentify the areas representing consumer surplus before and after the change. bIdentify the areas representing producer surplus before and after the change. c Comment on the relative size of the surpluses before and after the change. Price 4 EXERCISE 4.5 S1 S0 A P1 P0 B C E D F Q1 Q0 Quantity per period ▲ Figure 4.20 Consumer and producer surplus with a decrease in supply SUMMARY: CONSUMER AND PRODUCER SURPLUS » The demand curve shows the valuation that consumers place on a good, reflecting the satisfaction they gain from consuming it. » Consumer surplus represents the benefit that consumers gain from consuming a product, over and above the price they pay for that product. » Producer surplus represents the benefit gained by firms over and above the price at which they would have been prepared to supply a product. » Producers have an incentive to respond to changes in prices. In the short run this occurs through output adjustments of existing firms (movements along the supply curve), but in the long run firms will enter the market (or exit from it) until there are no further incentives for entry or exit. END OF CHAPTER QUESTIONS Multiple choice 1 The demand for ice cream increases. Other things being equal, what could explain a situation in which the price of ice cream stays unchanged? A a simultaneous increase in the demand for milk B a simultaneous decrease in the price of sugar C a simultaneous increase in the tax on ice cream D a simultaneous decrease in the price of frozen fruit 2 Fish is considered a staple food in some countries. In order to convert consumer surplus into producer surplus, sellers of fish should: A increase the quantity of fish caught B provide discounts for large quantities of fish bought C diversify the types of fish sold D increase the price of fish 70 308275_C04_CAM_IASAL ECO_054_072.indd 70 16/02/21 5:34 PM Data response 4 1 Read the following extract and then answer the questions that follow. Car production in the European Union 5 The supply of EVs is increasing more quickly than demand, so their price is falling. At the same time, 10 the price of lithium is increasing ▲ The price of electric cars is falling due to the increasing demand for its use in EV battery manufacture. By contrast, the demand for petrol and diesel fuel is set to fall up to 2040, reflecting the trend illustrated in Figure 4.21. 15 From 2020, new European Union rules will heavily penalise car makers if average carbon dioxide emissions from the cars they produce rise above 95g per kilometre. Number of vehicles demanded (million) Car makers’ excess emissions bill would have been £28.6 billion, based on 2018 sales figures. This illustrates the extent of the change required to their 20 production processes and the cost of compliance to suppliers. 4 Market equilibrium and the price system It is estimated that the number of electric vehicle (EV) models available to European consumers will increase from around 175 at the end of 2020 to more than 330 by the end of 2025. 100 Petrol/diesel vehicles Electric vehicles 80 48.8m 60 40 42.2m 20 0 2015 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 *2020–40 estimated Source: adapted from Bloomberg New Energy Finance ▲ Figure 4.21 Demand for electric vehicles and petrol/diesel vehicles, 2015–40 a With reference to Figure 4.21, give one reason for the trend in demand for electric vehicles after 2020. b With the use of an example from the extract, define the term ‘joint demand’. c With the use of an example from the extract, define the term ‘derived demand’. d The information provided states ‘From 2020, new European Union rules will heavily penalise car makers if average carbon dioxide emissions from the cars they produce rise above 95g per kilometre’ (lines 15–17). Explain how compliance with new European Union emissions rules will affect the firms’ equilibrium price and quantity. 71 308275_C04_CAM_IASAL ECO_054_072.indd 71 16/02/21 5:34 PM 4 e Explain, with reference to the extract, what is likely to happen to consumer surplus in the market for electric vehicles. f Assess, with reference to the extract, the likely impact of the increase in the supply of electric vehicles on the market for petrol and diesel vehicles. AS LEVEL PART 2 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY Essay style 2 a W ith the help of a diagram explain the impact on the housing market in Ghana of a time-limited government scheme involving financial support to benefit house buyers and consider whether this benefit is likely to continue in the long run. b The consumption of chocolate will grow at an annual rate of 4.7% between 2019 and 2025, driven by increasing demand in East Asia.Cocoa is a key ingredient of chocolate. In early 2020 Ghana, the world’s second largest producer of cocoa, estimated a shortfall in production of 75,000 tonnes compared with the previous year. This was caused in part by hot dry winds, which also damaged the crop in neighbouring Ivory Coast, the world’s largest cocoa producer. Discuss the likely effects of this information on the market for cocoa and whether this situation is likely to persist in the long run. CASE STUDY A healthy diet? Hardly a week seems to go by without scientists or nutritionists coming up with some new finding about the healthiness of our diets. Some blueberry muffins contain more than the recommended daily intake of sugar for adults. A study alleges that real butter is healthier than margarine. Smoked salmon from farmed fish may contain more fat than a pizza. Dark chocolate is good for you, but milk chocolate is damaging. In March 2018, a judge in Los Angeles ruled that coffee sold in California must carry a cancer warning because the chemical acrylamide (created as part of the roasting process) is regarded as carcinogenic. A growing obsession has focused on the health and environmental benefits of organic foods. The overuse of chemical fertilisers and pesticides is seen as damaging for the environment, and potentially damaging to our health. This has resulted in a premium price for certified organic foods, notably vegetables. However, converting to organic production and gaining authentication is a longwinded and costly process. Follow-up questions Suppose people become convinced of the benefits of consuming organic foods. a Sketch a demand and supply diagram to analyse how this would affect the market for non-organic foodstuffs in the short run. b Now use a demand and supply diagram to show how the market for certified organic foods would be affected in the short run. c With the help of more diagrams, explain how these interdependent markets will adjust in the longer term, remembering that achieving certified organic status is slow and costly. Go online at hoddereducation.com/cambridgeextras for another case study for Chapter 4. 72 308275_C04_CAM_IASAL ECO_054_072.indd 72 18/03/21 2:44 PM AS LEVEL PART 3 Government microeconomic intervention 5 The government in the microeconomy ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ reasons for government intervention in markets public goods and the free-rider problem merit and demerit goods specific indirect taxes subsidies direct government provision of goods and services ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ maximum and minimum prices buffer stock schemes wealth and income inequality the Gini coefficient reasons for inequality of income and wealth policies to redistribute income and wealth If markets are to be effective in guiding the allocation of resources in society, a precondition is that market prices are able to reflect the full costs and benefits associated with market transactions. However, there are situations in which the government may see that there is a need to intervene to influence markets. This chapter looks at ways in which governments intervene, either to improve the workings of markets or to affect the way in which resources are allocated – for example, by influencing the distribution of income in society. 5 The government in the microeconomy What this chapter covers 5.1 Reasons for government interventions in markets LEARNING LINK The meaning and significance of property rights is discussed in Chapter 21. Some roles are critical for a government to perform if a mixed economy is to function effectively. One important role is the provision by the government of an environment in which markets can operate effectively. There must be stability in the political system if firms and consumers are to take decisions with confidence about the future. And there must be a secure system of property rights, without which markets could not be expected to work. In addition, there are situations in which a free market will not produce good outcomes for society. This does not necessarily mean that governments need to substitute markets with direct action. However, it does mean that they need to be more active in markets that cannot operate effectively, while at the same time performing an enabling role to encourage markets to work well whenever this is feasible. Public goods STUDY TIP Remember that the key characteristics of a public good are that it is: » non-exclusive » non-rival » non-rejectable Chapter 1 explained the characteristics of a public good. The key feature of the market for a public good is that, once the good has been provided, there is no incentive for anyone to pay for it – so the market will fail, as no firm can make a profit, so will not have an incentive to supply the good in the first place. This market failure arises because of the free-rider problem, as individual consumers can free-ride and avoid having to pay for the good once it has been provided. Given the importance of goods such as street lighting, the government needs to find some way of addressing the issue of how such goods can be provided. LEARNING LINK The meaning of market failure is explained in Chapter 15. 73 308275_C05_CAM_IASAL ECO_073_087.indd 73 16/02/21 5:37 PM EXTENSION MATERIAL The problem of public goods Think about the supply and demand curves for a public good such as street lighting. To simplify matters, suppose there are just two potential demanders of the good, a and b. Consider Figure 5.1. If it is assumed that the supply is provided in a competitive market, S represents the supply curve, reflecting the marginal cost of providing street lighting. The curves da and db represent the demand curves of the two potential demanders. For a given quantity Q1, a would be prepared to pay Pa and b would pay P b. Price AS LEVEL PART 3 GOVERNMENT MICROECONOMIC INTERVENTION 5 Test yourself 5.1 Explain why a lighthouse might be regarded as having the characteristics of a public good. S (=MSC) PT Pa MSB Pb da db Q1 Q* Quantity ▲ Figure 5.1 Demand and supply of a public good Test yourself 5.2 Explain the free-rider problem in the context of the provision of national defence. LEARNING LINK The problem of how to provide public goods and services is not necessarily addressed through direct provision by the government. This is discussed in the next section of this chapter. Test yourself 5.3 Give an example of a merit good and a demerit good. If these prices are taken to be the value that each individual places on this amount of the good, then Pa + P b = P T represents the social benefit derived from consuming Q1 units of street lighting. Similarly, for any given quantity of street lighting, the marginal social benefit derived from consumption can be calculated as the vertical sum of the two demand curves. This is shown by the curve MSB. So the optimal provision of street lighting is given by Q*, at which point the marginal social benefit is equated with the marginal cost of supplying the good. However, if person a were to agree to pay Pa for the good, person b could then consume Q1 of the good free of charge, but would not be prepared to pay in order for the supply to be expanded beyond this point – as person b’s willingness to pay is below the marginal cost of provision beyond this point. So, when there are many potential consumers, the likely outcome is that none of this good will be produced: why should any individual agree to pay if he or she can free-ride on others? Merit and demerit goods Chapter 1 also explained that there may be goods or services known as merit and demerit goods where consumers face information failure because they do not clearly perceive their potential advantages or disadvantages. What this means is that consumers will demand less of a good or service that is a merit good, because they undervalue it, but will demand more of a demerit good because they fail to appreciate the potential disadvantages of the good. The government may see a need to address these problems in order to achieve a good allocation of resources in society. From society’s point of view, too few resources will be devoted to producing merit goods, and too many to the production of demerit goods. This misallocation of resources leaves society worse off than it could be. The next section of the chapter will discuss ways in which this problem can be tackled. Prices There may be markets in which the free-market equilibrium price may be seen to be inappropriate. For example, it might be that house rentals are seen to be too high, 74 308275_C05_CAM_IASAL ECO_073_087.indd 74 16/02/21 5:37 PM thus pricing poorer households out of the housing market, and causing homelessness. Alternatively, it might be that food prices are seen to be too low, creating inadequate incomes for farmers. In these circumstance, it may be tempting for the government to intervene in order to control prices directly. This will be discussed in the next section. 5 SUMMARY: REASONS FOR GOVERNMENT INTERVENTIONS IN MARKETS » There are several reasons why governments may » It may be seen to be important to address the problems of over-consumption of demerit goods and the under-consumption of merit goods. » In some situations, the government may wish to control prices in a market. 5.2 Methods and effects of government intervention in markets In this chapter so far, we have seen a number of reasons for governments to want to intervene in particular markets. We now turn our attention to the methods at the government’s disposal to address these issues, and their effectiveness. The impact and incidence of specific indirect taxes KEY TERMS indirect tax: a tax levied on expenditure on goods or services (as opposed to a direct tax, which is a tax charged directly to an individual based on a component of income) The effects of a sales tax can be seen in a demand and supply diagram. An indirect tax is levied on expenditure, and paid by the seller, so it affects the supply curve for a product. Figure 5.2 illustrates the case of a fixed rate or specific tax – a tax that is set at a constant amount per pack of cigarettes. Without the tax, the market equilibrium is at the intersection of demand and supply with a price of P0 and a quantity traded of Q0. The effect of the tax is to reduce the quantity that firms are prepared to supply at any given price – or, to put it another way, for any given quantity of cigarettes, firms need to receive the amount of the tax over and above the price at which they would have been prepared to supply that quantity. The effect is thus to move the supply curve upwards by the amount of the tax, as shown in the figure. We get a new equilibrium with a higher price at P1 and a lower quantity traded at Q1. Price specific tax: a tax of a fixed amount imposed on purchases of a commodity One of the issues that has been raised is that of demerit goods or services. These are goods where the government sees that a free market will result in overconsumption of a good or service. An example is tobacco. The medical evidence shows that smoking tobacco is harmful to health, and imposes costs on society. However, the addictive nature of tobacco means that individuals continue to smoke even in the face of the evidence. One way of trying to tackle this problem is to impose a tax on sales on tobacco. 5 The government in the microeconomy wish to intervene in individual markets. » The free market may not enable the adequate provision of public goods because of the free rider problem. Supply plus tax Supply Tax P1 Buyer pays P0 P1 – tax Seller pays Test yourself 5.4 If the government removes a tax on a good, will quantity demanded of the good decrease or increase? Demand 0 Q1 Q0 Packets of cigarettes per period ▲ Figure 5.2 The effects of an indirect tax on cigarettes 75 308275_C05_CAM_IASAL ECO_073_087.indd 75 16/02/21 5:37 PM AS LEVEL PART 3 GOVERNMENT MICROECONOMIC INTERVENTION 5 KEY TERMS incidence of a tax: the way in which the burden of paying a sales tax is divided between buyers and sellers subsidy: a grant given by the government to producers to encourage production of a good or service An important question is: who bears the burden of the tax? If you look at Figure 5.2, you will see that the price difference between the with-tax and without-tax situations (i.e. P1 − P0) is less than the amount of the tax, which is the vertical distance between the with-tax and without-tax supply curves. Although the seller may be responsible for the mechanics of paying the tax, part of the tax is effectively passed on to the buyer in the form of the higher price. In Figure 5.2, the incidence of the tax falls partly on the seller, but most of the tax is borne by the buyers, who pay (P1 − P0) per unit. The sellers pay the rest. The price elasticity of demand determines the incidence of the tax. If demand were perfectly inelastic, then the sellers would be able to pass the whole burden of the tax on to the buyers through an increase in price equal to the value of the tax, knowing that this would not affect demand. However, if demand were perfectly elastic, then the sellers would not be able to raise the price at all, so they would have to bear the entire burden of the tax. EXERCISE 5.1 Sketch demand and supply diagrams to confirm that the statements in the previous paragraph are correct – that is, that if demand is perfectly inelastic, then the tax falls entirely on the buyers, whereas if demand is perfectly elastic, it is the sellers who have to bear the burden of the tax. LEARNING LINK Indirect taxes are explored in more depth in Chapter 21. The impact and incidence of subsidies In some situations, the government may wish to encourage production of a particular good or service, perhaps because it views a good as having strategic significance to the country, or because it is seen as a merit good. One way it can do this is by giving subsidies. Subsidies are used to encourage producers to increase their output of particular goods. Subsidies have been especially common in agriculture, which is often seen as being of strategic significance. A museum may be regarded by government as being a merit good, so a subsidy may be used to encourage more people to visit a museum. Price We can regard a subsidy as a sort of negative indirect tax that shifts the supply curve down – as shown in Figure 5.3. Without the subsidy, market equilibrium is at a price P0 and the quantity traded is Q0. With the subsidy in place, the equilibrium price falls to P1 and quantity traded increases to Q1. Supply Supply with subsidy P0 P1 Subsidy Demand 0 Q0 Q1 Quantity per period ▲ Figure 5.3 The effect of a subsidy 76 308275_C05_CAM_IASAL ECO_073_087.indd 76 16/02/21 5:37 PM Test yourself 5.5 If demand for a good was relatively more elastic, would a subsidy have a lesser or greater effect on quantity traded? Again, notice that because the price falls by less than the amount of the subsidy, the incidence of the subsidy means that the benefits of the subsidy are shared between the buyers and sellers – depending on the elasticity of demand. If the aim of the subsidy is to increase production, it is only partially successful; the degree of success also depends on the elasticities of demand and of supply. If demand is inelastic, then the impact will be limited, as the fall in price will not induce many additional people to consume the good or service. If producers are not able to expand production (i.e. if supply is inelastic), then again the impact will be limited. The notion of public goods was introduced in Chapter 1. It was noted that a free market for public goods (or services) will not operate effectively because of the free-rider problem. An important question is whether the government needs to intervene in such circumstances by producing the good or service directly. Test yourself 5.6 Is it necessarily the case that a public good can only be provided directly by the government? For some public goods, the failure of the free market to ensure provision may be regarded as a serious problem – for example, in such cases as street lighting or law and order. Some government intervention may thus be needed to make sure that a sufficient quantity of the good or service is provided. Notice that this does not necessarily mean that the government has to provide the good itself, although it may choose to do so. It may be that the government will raise funds through taxation in order to ensure that street lighting is provided, but could still make use of private firms to supply the good through some sort of subcontracting arrangement. In some countries, it may be that the government delegates the responsibility for provision of public goods to local authorities, which in turn may subcontract to private firms. 5 The government in the microeconomy Direct provision of goods and services by government 5 Such intervention entails costs. There are costs of administering, and costs of monitoring the policy to ensure that it is working as intended. This includes the need to look out for the unintended effects that some policies can have on resource allocation in a society. It is therefore important to check that the marginal costs of implementing and monitoring policies do not exceed their marginal benefits. LEARNING LINK There may be situations in which the state may decide to take an industry or firm into public ownership. In some countries, utilities such as the provision of water, gas or electricity are run as nationalised industries, owned by the state. The issues surrounding nationalisation (and privatisation) are discussed in Chapter 21. Minimum and maximum prices Most governments see it as their responsibility to ensure that markets allocate resources efficiently. One way in which governments may intervene is through direct control of prices in some markets, because the market price of a good or service is seen as being either too low for some reason, or too high. KEY TERM minimum wage: legislation under which firms are not allowed to pay a wage below some threshold level set by the government A minimum wage One way in which governments have often intervened in markets by setting a minimum price is by the introduction of a minimum wage. To illustrate how this works, Figure 5.4 represents the labour market for office cleaners. Employers demand labour according to the wage rate – the lower the wage, the higher the demand for the labour of office cleaners. On the supply side, more workers will offer themselves for work when the wage rate is relatively high. If the market is unregulated, it will reach equilibrium with a wage rate W* and quantity of labour L*. 77 308275_C05_CAM_IASAL ECO_073_087.indd 77 16/02/21 5:37 PM Wage rate 5 Supply Wmin AS LEVEL PART 3 GOVERNMENT MICROECONOMIC INTERVENTION W* Demand 0 Ld L* Ls Quantity of labour ▲ Figure 5.4 A minimum wage Suppose that the government comes to the view that W* is not sufficiently high to provide a reasonable wage for cleaners. One response is to impose a minimum wage, below which employers are not permitted to offer employment – say, Wmin on the figure. This will have two effects on the market situation. First, employers will demand less labour at this higher wage, so employment will fall to Ld. Second, more workers will be prepared to offer themselves for employment at the higher wage, so labour supply will rise to Ls. However, the net effect of this is that there is disequilibrium in the market, with an excess supply of labour at this wage and hence unemployment, with more workers offering themselves for work than there are jobs available in the market. Test yourself 5.7 What would be the effect of setting a minimum price that was below the equilibrium level? Notice that this analysis rests on some assumptions that have not been made explicit. In particular, it rests on the assumption that the labour market is competitive. Where there are labour markets in which the employers have some market power, and are able to offer lower wages to workers than would be obtained in a free-market equilibrium situation, it is possible that the imposition of a minimum wage will increase employment. A maximum price: rent controls Rent Another market in which governments have been tempted to intervene is the housing market. Figure 5.5 represents the market for rented accommodation. The free-market equilibrium would be where demand and supply intersect, with the equilibrium rent being R* and the quantity of accommodation traded being Q*. Supply R* Rmax Demand 0 Qs Q* Qd Quantity of rented accommodation ▲ Figure 5.5 Rent controls 78 308275_C05_CAM_IASAL ECO_073_087.indd 78 16/02/21 5:37 PM If the government regards the level of rent as excessive, to the point where households on low incomes may be unable to afford rented accommodation, then, given that housing is one of life’s necessities, it may regard this as unacceptable. It can be seen that the well-meaning rent control policy, intended to protect low-income households from being exploited by landlords, merely has the effect of reducing the amount of accommodation available. This is not what was supposed to happen. Problems may arise whenever price controls are implemented, because holding a market away from equilibrium means that some buyers or sellers are affected. In some markets, this could mean that some buyers are rationed in their purchases and may turn to an unofficial market. Suppliers of perishable goods who cannot sell their goods will lose out. In addition, the administrative costs of operating the controls may be high. Buffer stock schemes 5 5 The government in the microeconomy The temptation for the government is to move this market away from its equilibrium by imposing a maximum level of rent that landlords are allowed to charge their tenants. Suppose that this level of rent is denoted by Rmax in Figure 5.5. The market is now in equilibrium. There is excess demand for rented accommodation resulting from two effects. First, landlords will no longer find it profitable to supply as much rental accommodation, and so will reduce supply to Qs. Second, at this lower rent there will be more people looking for accommodation, so that demand for rented accommodation will move to Qd. The upshot of the rent controls, therefore, is that there is less accommodation available, and more homeless people. In some commodity markets, prices can exhibit volatility over time. This could arise, for example, when the supply of a good varies from period to period because of the varying state of the harvest. In such a market, the supply curve will shift to the right when the harvest is good, but shift to the left in a period when the weather is poor or where crops are affected by some disease or blight. It may also be that the demand curve tends to shift around through time, with demand for some goods reflecting fluctuations in the performance of economies. In other words, demand may shift to the left when recession bites, but to the right in times of boom and prosperity. Price Suppose that Figure 5.6 represents a market in which demand is relatively stable between periods, but in which supply varies between Spoor when the harvest is poor and Sgood when the harvest is good. The price varies between Pp and Pg. This creates a high level of uncertainty for producers, who find it difficult to form accurate expectations about the future prospects for the commodity. This means that they are less likely to invest in ways of improving productivity because of uncertain future returns. If a way could be found of stabilising the price of the good, then this could encourage producers. Sgood Spoor Pp P* A B C Pg D KEY TERM buffer stock: a scheme intended to stabilise the price of a commodity by buying excess supply in periods when supply is high, and selling when supply is low 308275_C05_CAM_IASAL ECO_073_087.indd 79 Qp Q* Qg Quantity ▲ Figure 5.6 A buffer stock A buffer stock is a way of attempting to do this. A scheme is set up whereby excess supply is bought up by the buffer stock in good years to prevent the price from falling too low. In periods when the harvest is poor, stocks of the commodity are released on to the market in order to maintain the price at the agreed level. In terms of Figure 5.6, suppose that it is agreed to maintain the price at P*. When there is a good year, with the supply curve located at Sgood, there is excess supply at the agreed price of the 79 18/03/21 10:17 AM amount BC, so this amount is bought up by the buffer stock and stored. If the supply is at Spoor because of a poor harvest, there is excess demand, so the buffer stock releases the quantity AB on to the market, maintaining the price. AS LEVEL PART 3 GOVERNMENT MICROECONOMIC INTERVENTION 5 Although this does have the effect of stabilising the price at P*, there is a downside. If the members of the buffer stock scheme agree to maintain the price at too high a level, relative to the actual average equilibrium price over time, then it will run into difficulties. Notice in Figure 5.6 that to maintain price at P*, the buffer stock buys up more in the ‘good’ year than it has to sell in the poor harvest year. If this pattern is repeated, then the size of stocks to be stored will rise over time. This is costly and will eventually become unsustainable. EXERCISE 5.2 Discuss why prices in some markets may be unstable from year to year and evaluate ways in which more stability might be achieved. How effective would you expect such measures to be? What would be the benefits to economic agents of having greater stability in prices? Provision of information In the case of merit and demerit goods, it was suggested that the underlying problem was a failure of information. In other words, consumers make bad decisions about these types of goods and services because they do not have sufficient information about the costs or benefits of consuming the goods, or they do not take them enough into account. Test yourself 5.8 Explain why the demand for tobacco should be so inelastic. LEARNING LINK Information failure is discussed further in Chapter 21. For example, take the example of smoking tobacco. This is classed as a demerit good because consumers do not fully take on board the detrimental effects of smoking in the long run, and become habituated to the use of tobacco. This means that the demand for tobacco is relatively price inelastic, so taxes proved ineffective in discouraging smoking. In such a situation, a public information campaign to broadcast the ill effects of smoking might have an impact on behaviour, although people addicted to tobacco might not be affected by campaigns. Vaccination is an example of a merit good. During the Covid-19 pandemic, it was vital that as many people as possible should be vaccinated to control the spread of the virus. False stories about the dangers of vaccination circulated on social media, and there was growing resistance to vaccination, especially in some sections of the public. In response, many governments launched public information campaigns to make sure that people understood the importance and safety of vaccines and their importance in protecting healthcare systems and society as a whole. The extent to which people are affected by such campaigns may vary between societies and may depend partly on the degree of trust that people have in their governments. SUMMARY: METHODS AND EFFECTS OF GOVERNMENT INTERVENTION IN MARKETS » A range of methods are available to a government » » » » that wishes to influence a particular market. Specific indirect taxes can be used to affect the consumption of demerit goods and services. The price elasticity of demand affects whether it is producers or consumers who bear the burden of the tax. Subsidies can be used to encourage the consumption of merit goods. In some markets, the government may consider direct provision of goods or services such as public goods, or it may ensure provision by other means. » In some markets, government may intervene to set minimum or maximum prices – for example, through introducing a minimum wage or rent controls. » Where the government wishes to stabilise the price of a good over time, it may establish a buffer stock scheme. » Governments may launch an information campaign in order to combat an information failure. 80 308275_C05_CAM_IASAL ECO_073_087.indd 80 18/03/21 2:45 PM 5.3 Addressing income and wealth inequality Income and wealth Test yourself 5.9 Give an example of wealth held by a household. income: the flow of wages, salaries and earnings from other sources in a period wealth: the stock of accumulated assets income distribution: the way in which national income is distributed among the population of a country wealth distribution: the way in which the nation’s wealth is distributed among the population of a country LEARNING LINK International comparisons of income and the standard of living are discussed in Chapter 30. The distribution of income and wealth and inequality The income distribution describes how income is distributed amongst the population. You will be aware that not everyone receives the same income, so there is some inequality in the income distribution. The same applies to the wealth distribution; indeed, wealth tends to be more unequally distributed than income. There are differences between countries in the extent of such inequality in income and wealth. Measuring income and wealth inequality Inequality is present in all societies, and always will be. However, the degree of inequality varies from one country to another; and before exploring the causes of inequality, and the policies that might be used to influence how income and wealth are distributed within society, it is necessary to be able to characterise and measure inequality. This is important in order to be able to judge relative standards of living in different countries or different periods. 5 5 The government in the microeconomy KEY TERMS It is important to be aware of the distinction between income and wealth. Income is the flow of wages and earnings from other sources in a period, whereas wealth is the stock of accumulated assets. An example of such assets would be where an individual owns property. If an individual saves part of his or her income, this accumulates as wealth. However, wealth may also come from other sources – in particular, from legacies. Ownership of wealth can also generate a flow of income in the form of interest and dividend payments. One way of presenting data on this topic is to rank households in order of their incomes, and then calculate the share of total household income that goes to the poorest 10%, the poorest 20% and so on. QUANTITATIVE SKILLS 5.1 Deciles, quintiles and quartiles When the groups are divided into tenths in this way, they are referred to as deciles; thus, the poorest 10% is the first decile, the next 10% is the second decile and so on. Similarly, the poorest 20% is the first quintile, and the poorest 25% is the first quartile. This is useful in trying to explore the pattern of the distribution of income because it quantifies the difference between income going to low-income and high-income households. According to the World Bank, the top decile (richest 10%) of households in Brazil receives 41.9 times higher income than the lowest decile (poorest 10%). In Belarus, on the other hand, the ratio is only 5.1. These are extreme examples of the degree of inequality in the distribution of income within countries. Table 5.1 presents some data for three countries. Notice that the unit of measurement is normally the household rather than the individual, on the presumption that members of a household tend to share their resources – a millionaire’s life-partner may not earn any income, but he or she is not usually poor. 81 308275_C05_CAM_IASAL ECO_073_087.indd 81 16/02/21 5:37 PM AS LEVEL PART 3 GOVERNMENT MICROECONOMIC INTERVENTION 5 ▲ Inequality in Brazil Test yourself 5.10 Calculate the decile ratio for each of the countries in Table 5.1. Do these give the same ranking as for the quintile ratios in the table? ▼ Table 5.1 Distribution of income in Pakistan, the USA and China, by quintiles (%) First decile First quintile Pakistan USA China 3.9 1.7 2.6 8.9 5.0 6.4 Second quintile 12.2 10.2 10.6 Third quintile 15.6 15.3 15.3 Fourth quintile 20.5 22.6 22.3 Top quintile 42.8 46.9 45.4 Top decile 28.9 30.6 29.4 4.8 9.4 7.1 Ratio top quintile: first quintile Note: the data are the most recent available at the time of writing. Source: World Development Indicators EXERCISE 5.3 Use the data provided in Table 5.2 to calculate the ratios of top decile income to bottom decile income, and of top quintile income to bottom quintile income. Then compare the inequalities shown for Belarus and South Africa with each other and with the countries already discussed. ▼ Table 5.2 Income distribution in Belarus and South Africa Percentage share of income or consumption South Africa Belarus Lowest decile 0.9 4.2 Lowest quintile 2.4 9.9 Second quintile 4.8 14.2 Third quintile 8.2 17.9 Fourth quintile 16.5 22.5 Highest quintile 68.2 35.5 Highest decile 50.5 21.3 Note: the data are the most recent available at the time of writing. Source: World Development Indicators 82 308275_C05_CAM_IASAL ECO_073_087.indd 82 16/02/21 5:37 PM In data published by the World Bank and United Nations (and sometimes the UK’s ONS), the Gini coefficient is known as the Gini index. The Gini coefficient is a way of expressing the degree of inequality in a country in quantitative terms, making it possible to compare inequality across countries. 5 In published data, the Gini coefficient is usually expressed as a percentage (i.e. multiplied by 100). The closer the Gini coefficient is to 100, the more unequal is the income distribution. Table 5.3 shows some values for the Gini coefficient for a selection of countries. ▼ Table 5.3 The Gini coefficient Country Gini coefficient (%) USA 41.5 Pakistan 33.5 China 38.6 Brazil 53.3 Belarus 25.4 South Africa 63.0 Source: World Development Indicators The Gini coefficient can be used to see how the overall income distribution has changed over time. This is shown in Figure 5.7 for selected countries. 5 The government in the microeconomy If every individual in a country received the same income, the Gini coefficient would be 0, but of course this never happens. In the 2019 Human Development Report (published by the United Nations Development Programme), the lowest value recorded was for Ukraine at 25.0%; the highest was South Africa at 63%, so when you come to interpret a Gini value, remember that countries fall within this sort of range. The Gini coefficient Gini coefficient STUDY TIP 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 1990 Brazil China Belarus 1995 USA Pakistan 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 Source: based on data from World Development Indicators ▲ Figure 5.7 The Gini coefficient, selected countries Notice that these data are not collected for each country in each year, and that inequality does not vary greatly over time for any country. The figure confirms earlier findings that inequality in Brazil has been relatively high, whereas it has been lower in Belarus, and this pattern was true throughout the period for which we have data. Indeed we can see that inequality improved slowly but slightly in Brazil during most of the period. In China, inequality showed a slight upward trend, but all these changes were relatively small in scale. Economic reasons for inequality of income and wealth There are reasons based in microeconomic analysis for expecting there to be differences in income and wealth between individuals and groups in society. Labour market explanations There are various ways in which the labour market may be expected to give rise to inequalities in earnings. This arises from demand and supply conditions in labour markets, which respond to changes in the pattern of consumer demand for goods and services, and changes in international comparative advantage between countries. Furthermore, differences between different occupations and economic sectors reinforce income inequalities. 83 308275_C05_CAM_IASAL ECO_073_087.indd 83 16/02/21 5:37 PM 5 LEARNING LINK AS LEVEL PART 3 GOVERNMENT MICROECONOMIC INTERVENTION The way in which labour markets operate is discussed in Chapter 23. A by-product of changes in the structure of the economy may be rising inequality between certain groups in society. For example, if there is a change in the structure of employment away from unskilled jobs towards occupations that require a higher level of skills and qualifications, then this could lead to an increase in inequality, with those workers who lack the skills to adapt to changing labour market conditions being disadvantaged by the changes taking place. In other words, if the premium that employers are prepared to pay in order to hire skilled or well-qualified workers rises as a result of changing technology in the workplace, then people without those skills are likely to suffer. A decline in the power of trade unions may contribute to the situation, as low-paid workers may find that their unions are less likely to be able to offer employment protection. It has been argued that this is a good thing if it increases the flexibility of the labour market. However, again a balance is needed between worker protection and having free and flexible markets. Inequality in wealth Perhaps the most obvious way in which inequality in wealth arises and changes through time is through the pattern of the ownership of assets. This in turn may reflect the way in which assets are passed through the generations, which depends on the inheritance laws of a country. When wealth accumulates in a family over time and is then passed down to succeeding generations, this generates a source of inequality that does not arise from the current state of the economy or the operations of markets. Notice, however, that although wealth and income are not the same thing, inequality in wealth can also lead to inequality in income, as wealth (the ownership of assets) leads to an income flow, from rents and profits. Demographic change A feature of many countries in recent years has been a change in the age structure of the population. Improved medical drugs and treatments have meant that people are living longer, and this has combined with low fertility rates in many economically developed countries to bring about an increase in the proportion of the population who are in the older age groups. This has put pressure on the provision of pensions, and increased the vulnerability of this group in society. State pensions in some countries have been funded primarily by the contributions of those in work, but if the number of people of working age falls as a proportion of the whole population, then this funding stream comes under pressure. These differences in income and wealth mean that there will always be some inequality in any society, in the sense that some individuals and groups will have greater command over resources than others. In other words, resources will not be equally distributed across society. Policies to redistribute income and wealth Governments have a range of measures that can be introduced to affect the distribution of income and wealth. A minimum wage The idea of a minimum wage was introduced earlier in the chapter. This can be seen as one way of influencing the distribution of income, by ensuring that low-paid workers are not exploited by employers paying low wages. It is not clear to what extent this will have a significant impact on the overall income distribution. With a minimum wage in effect, workers (those who manage to remain in employment) are better off, and now receive a better wage. However, those who are now unemployed are worse off. It is not then clear whether the effect of the minimum wage is to make society as a whole better off – some people will be better off, but others will be worse off. 84 308275_C05_CAM_IASAL ECO_073_087.indd 84 16/02/21 5:37 PM KEY TERM LEARNING LINKS The impact of transfer payments and other policies to influence inequality and poverty are discussed in Chapter 22. The effects of imposing taxes are discussed in Chapter 21. KEY TERMS direct tax: a tax levied directly on income progressive tax: a tax in which the marginal rate rises with income marginal tax rate: tax on additional income, defined as the change in tax payments divided by the change in taxable income regressive tax: a tax bearing more heavily on the relatively poorer members of society 5 Transfer payments Governments in many countries make transfer payments to poor households. These may be in the form of cash benefits, such as income support, child benefit, incapacity benefit and working families tax credit. These benefits are designed to protect families in certain circumstances whose income would otherwise be very low. Second, there are benefits in kind, such as health and education. These benefits accrue to individual households depending on the number of members of the household and their age and gender. Taxation There are two main forms of taxation – direct taxes levied on various forms of income, and indirect taxes that are levied on expenditure. Direct taxes (taxes on incomes) tend to be progressive: in other words, higher income groups pay tax at a higher rate. Direct taxes include income tax, corporation tax (paid by firms on profits) and capital gains tax (paid by individuals who sell assets at a profit). There may also be taxes levied by local authorities on property, such as the UK’s council tax. Some countries impose inheritance taxes, which are designed to affect the distribution of wealth. 5 The government in the microeconomy transfer payment: occurs where the government provides benefits (in cash or in kind) to poor households; hence there is a transfer from taxpayers to the recipients of the benefits It is not clear how many workers would benefit from the imposition of a minimum wage, even if they remain in employment. Partly this may depend on the level at which the minimum wage is set – there may be workers who are unaffected by the policy because they earn marginally more than the minimum, or because they are paid on piecework rather than by time. In countries where there is significant informal working, the policy may not reach those in most need. With a tax such as income tax, its progressive nature is reflected in the way that the percentage rates payable increase as an individual moves into higher income ranges. In other words, the marginal tax rate increases as income increases. The progressive nature of the tax ensures that it does indeed contribute to reducing inequality in the income distribution. The effect of indirect taxes can sometimes be regressive: in other words, indirect taxes may fall more heavily on lower-income households. Indirect taxes are taxes that are paid on items of expenditure, rather than on income. State provision of essential goods and services In the case of public or merit goods, the state may choose to intervene directly to ensure that essential goods and services are made accessible to the population. This was discussed earlier in the chapter, where it was pointed out that the authorities may subcontract this provision to the private sector. In the case of goods and services like health and education, the government may indeed intervene directly, but practice does vary between countries. In times of war or civil conflict, it may be that markets break down, so that the state (or other organisations) have to supply essential goods and services to the population. SUMMARY: ADDRESSING INCOME AND WEALTH INEQUALITY » There is an important distinction between income (a flow) and wealth (a stock). » Income and wealth distribution in a country can be measured by the Gini coefficient. » Inequality of income and wealth arises because of a variety of factors. » The government can use various policies to influence the distribution of income and wealth. » A minimum wage can help people or households at the low end of the income distribution. » Transfer payments can enable resources to be transferred from the rich to the poor. » Taxes can also be used to influence the distribution of income and wealth. » In some countries, the state makes provision of essential goods and services to the poor, or takes steps to ensure that provision takes place. 85 308275_C05_CAM_IASAL ECO_073_087.indd 85 16/02/21 5:37 PM END OF CHAPTER QUESTIONS AS LEVEL PART 3 GOVERNMENT MICROECONOMIC INTERVENTION 5 Multiple choice 1 Which set of policies is classified correctly? Price control Direct provision Transfer payment A Rent controls Free provision of face masks Minimum wage B Free admission to Nationalisation of railway museums for children and links pensioners Price ceiling on bread C Minimum wage Emergency treatment in a hospital Child benefits D Subsidised schooling Price floor on bread Pensions 2 Other things being equal, what is a common disadvantage of the state provision of essential goods and services available to all individuals? A Those who have sufficient income to afford paid provision would also benefit. B State provision would result in reduced quality of the essential good or service. C The government cannot accurately judge the level of demand for essential goods and services. D State provision could lead to worse resource allocation than the competitive market outcome. Data response 1 Read the following extract and then answer the questions that follow. The rising price of maize meal in Zimbabwe Maize meal is a basic food consumed across much of southern Africa. In Zimbabwe throughout most of 2019 the price of maize meal increased beyond the budget of many consumers (see Figure 5.8). In November 2019, to keep its most consumed food affordable the government of Zimbabwe introduced a subsidy on the production of maize meal. The subsidy was regarded as the most effective way to protect vulnerable citizens from rising food prices. This intervention was chosen over the imposition of a maximum price or the introduction of a buffer stock scheme. 80 60 40 20 19 cDe 9 Ju n19 Se p19 ar -1 M c18 De Ju n18 Se p18 ar -1 8 De M 17 0 c- Price of maize (Zimbabwe dollars per 10kg) During 2019, the price of bread in Zimbabwe increased by as much as 60% overnight in some cases. Local bakers said they were forced to increase their prices due to rising production costs. Electricity prices increased significantly, as did the price of fuel and the cost of importing wheat. While businesses, farmers and the government searched for solutions, many Zimbabweans said they would no longer be able to buy dinner if they bought bread. Source: ZIMSTAT ▲ Figure 5.8 Retail price of maize meal in Zimbabwe, December 2017–December 2019 86 308275_C05_CAM_IASAL ECO_073_087.indd 86 16/02/21 5:37 PM Essay style ompare the direct provision of goods and services with provision of 2 a C information as a means to encourage consumption in a particular market and consider the likely effectiveness of each. b Discuss whether the introduction of a minimum wage or progressive taxation is more likely to lead to a successful redistribution of income towards the relatively poor. CASE STUDY A bitter-sweet tax? In the UK Budget Statement in 2016, the then chancellor of the exchequer announced a new tax intended to tackle the growing problem of childhood obesity. This soon became popularly known as the ‘sugar tax’, although the levy targets the producers and importers of sugary soft drinks, not all products that contain sugar. The ‘Soft Drinks Industry Levy’ came into effect on 6 April 2018. The consultation document on the gov.uk website stated that: ‘This is not a tax on consumers. The government is not increasing the price of products; companies don’t have to pass the charge on to their customers. If companies take the right steps to make their drinks healthier they will pay less tax, or even nothing at all.’ The levy is charged at different rates according to the total sugar content, with companies having to pay 18p per litre of drink if the product contains more than 5 grams of sugar per 100 millilitres and 24p per litre if it contains more than 8 grams per millilitre. Pure fruit juices and drinks with a high milk content are exempt. When the levy was originally announced, it was thought that revenue from the levy would be in the region of £520 million, which was intended to be used to encourage children to participate in sport. However, on the day the levy came into effect, this estimate was reduced to £240 million. 5 5 The government in the microeconomy a With reference to Figure 5.8, compare the change in the retail price of maize meal between June–December 2018 and June–December 2019. b Explain, with reference to the extract, how a buffer stock scheme could be an alternative way to protect vulnerable citizens from rising food prices. c Discuss the impact of one indirect tax that the government of Zimbabwe could alter in order to reduce the price of bread in Zimbabwe. d Analyse, with the aid of a diagram, the impact of the introduction of the maize meal production subsidy in Zimbabwe on the market for maize meal. e The government of Zimbabwe chose to protect its vulnerable consumers from rising food prices by introducing a production subsidy. Discuss the extent to which imposing a maximum price for maize meal below the market price could protect vulnerable consumers in Zimbabwe. Some firms had taken action before the introduction of the levy, by cutting the sugar content of drinks – in some cases attracting complaints from their consumers. Several other countries have introduced similar levies. For example, in Mexico it was found that a 10% tax led to a 6% reduction in sales of sugarsweetened drinks in 2014 (the figure for lower-income households was a reduction of 9%). The Danish experience of a so-called ‘fat tax’ was less successful, and it was repealed after just a year of operation. Similar taxes have been introduced in Brunei, Sri Lanka and the UAE, amongst others. Follow-up questions a Would you expect the manufacturers of sugary drinks to absorb all of the levy, or would they pass some of the cost on to consumers? Explain your answer. b Discuss the sort of market failure that the government was trying to tackle through the levy. c The estimated revenue from the levy was seen as being much lower at the time of its launch than had been originally envisaged. Discuss whether this is an indication that the levy was not working. Go online at hoddereducation.com/cambridgeextras for another case study for Chapter 5. 87 308275_C05_CAM_IASAL ECO_073_087.indd 87 18/03/21 2:46 PM AS LEVEL PART 4 The macroeconomy AS LEVEL PART 4 THE MACROECONOMY 6 National income What this chapter covers ★ what is meant by national income ★ the concepts of gross domestic product (GDP), gross national income (GNI) and net national income (NNI) ★ the difference between market prices and basic prices ★ the adjustment needed between gross and net values ★ the circular flow of income in a closed economy and an open economy, recognising the flow of income between households, firms, government and the international economy ★ injections into and leakages from the circular flow ★ equilibrium and disequilibrium in the context of the circular flow This part of the book switches attention to macroeconomics. Macroeconomics has much in common with microeconomics, but focuses on the whole economy, rather than on individual markets and how they operate. Although the way of thinking about issues is similar, and although similar tools are used, now it is interactions between economic variables at the level of the whole economy that are studied. The starting point is to consider what is meant by national income, which is a key measure of economic activity in an economy. 6.1 National income statistics The standard of living that can be achieved by the residents of a country will be strongly influenced by the quantity of resources available – although, of course, the way in which those resources are divided among the country’s residents will also be important. What is national income? In terms of measurement, it would be helpful to be able to count up the total quantity of resources in an economy, and to explore how they are divided between the country’s residents. Such a total is known as national income. KEY TERM gross domestic product (GDP): the total amount of goods and services produced in an economy during a given period This is easier said than done. A typical economy produces a wide range of different goods and services during a given time period. This might include rice, onions, cars, electronic goods, curry, banking services and so on. The quantities of these are all likely to be counted in different units of measurement, so adding them together is problematic. What can be done is to measure the value of these various commodities in money terms – and this is the approach that governments use. The total amount of goods and services produced in an economy during a time period is known as the gross domestic product (GDP). This is one of the most important economic indicators used in judging the performance of an economy. The United Nations System of National Accounts (SNA) is the internationally recognised framework used for compiling estimates of GDP. Measurement of national income When it comes to undertaking the measurement of GDP, three alternative approaches can be taken. 88 308275_C06_CAM_IASAL ECO_088_096.indd 88 16/02/21 5:40 PM Test yourself 6.1 What is measured by GDP? The pattern of expenditure in the economy is discussed in Chapter 7. In principle, these three measures should produce the same result. Each of these measures provides information about different aspects of a society’s total resources. 6 6 National income LEARNING LINK » Expenditure: add up all expenditure undertaken in the economy during a period, including the various items purchased by households, the expenditure by firms on capital equipment, spending by government and net export spending. Notice that although foreigners may purchase domestic goods, domestic residents also spend money on imported goods – which is why it is net export spending that is included when calculating total expenditure. » Income: measure the total amount of income received by people in the country in the form of wages, salaries, profits, rent, etc. » Output: add up the total amount of output produced by firms in the economy. This needs to be calculated in terms of the value added by each firm to avoid double counting. The expenditure estimate describes how those resources are being used, so that it can be seen what proportion of society’s resources is being used for consumption and what for investment, etc. LEARNING LINK These factors of production and their rewards were introduced in Chapter 1. The income estimate reports on the way in which households earn their income. In other words, it tells something about the balance between rewards to labour (e.g. wages and salaries), capital (interest), land (rents), enterprise (profits) and so on. The output estimate focuses on the structure of the economy. One way in which countries differ is in the balance between primary production such as agriculture, secondary activity such as manufacturing, and tertiary activity such as services. Service activity has increased in importance in many economies in recent years. Real and nominal measurements The measurement of economic variables poses many dilemmas for statisticians. Not least is the fundamental problem of what to use as units of measurement. Suppose we want to measure GDP in successive years. We cannot use volume measures. It may be possible to count how many computers, passenger cars, tins of paint and cauliflowers the economy produces – but how can these different items be combined to produce a total? KEY TERMS nominal value: the value of an economic variable based on current prices, taking no account of changing prices through time real value: the value of an economic variable, taking account of changing prices through time An obvious solution is to use the money values. Given prices for all the items, it is possible to calculate the money values of all these goods and thus produce a measurement of the total output produced in an economy during a year in terms of their monetary value. However, this is just the beginning of the problem because in order to monitor changes in total output between two years, it is important to be aware that not only do the volumes of goods produced change, but so too do their prices. In effect, this means that if dollars or local currencies are used as the unit of measurement, that unit of measurement will change in value from one year to the next as prices change. This is a problem that is not faced by most of the physical sciences. After all, the length of a metre does not alter from one year to the next, so if the length of something is being measured, the unit is fixed. Economists, however, have to make allowance for changing prices when measuring in money terms. Measurements made using prices that are current at the time a transaction takes place are known as measurements of nominal values. When prices are rising, these nominal measurements will always overstate the extent to which an economic variable is growing through time. Clearly, to analyse performance economists will be more interested in real values – that is, the quantities produced after having removed the effects of price changes. One way in which these real measures can be obtained is by taking the volumes produced in each year and valuing these quantities at the prices 89 308275_C06_CAM_IASAL ECO_088_096.indd 89 16/02/21 5:40 PM that prevailed in some base year. This then enables allowance to be made for the changes in prices that take place, permitting a focus on the real values. These can be thought of as being measured at constant prices. 6 AS LEVEL PART 4 THE MACROECONOMY LEARNING LINK The way in which we measure the extent to which prices are changing through time is by calculating a price index. This takes an average of prices across the economy, and compares the value in any particular year to that in a chosen base year. This will be explained more carefully in Chapter 10. KEY TERMS nominal GDP: GDP at current prices, taking no account of changing prices through time real GDP: GDP at constant prices, taking account of changing prices through time Test yourself 6.2 The same principle applies to other economic variables that change through time. For example, we need to distinguish between real GDP and nominal GDP. Figure 6.1 traces both real and nominal GDP in Pakistan since 1990, measured in US$ billions. It is quite difficult to interpret the time path of real GDP, as the trend component of the series is so strong. In other words, real GDP has been increasing steadily throughout the period. There are one or two periods in which there was a movement away from the trend, but these are relatively rare and not easy to analyse. This reflects the nature of economic variables such as GDP, where the fluctuations around trend are small relative to the trend, but can seem substantial when the economy is experiencing them. GDP (US$bn) Would GDP it current prices be known as real GDP or as nominal GDP? For example, suppose that last year you bought a tub of ice cream for $2, but that inflation has been 10%, so that this year you had to pay $2.20 for the same tub. Your real consumption of the item has not changed, but your spending has increased. If you were to use the value of your spending to measure changes in consumption through time, it would be misleading, as you know that your real consumption has not changed at all (so it is still $2), although its nominal value has increased to $2.20. 400 Real GDP Nominal GDP 300 200 Test yourself 6.3 Why would it be misleading to consider changes in GDP through time without adjusting for changing prices? 100 0 1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 2010 2014 2018 Source: based on data from World Development Indicators ▲ Figure 6.1 Real and nominal GDP in Pakistan since 1990 Comparing the path of real GDP with that of the nominal version, you can see how failing to take changing prices into account could give a misleading impression of how GDP has grown over time. The time-path shown by the nominal GDP series is much steeper than for real GDP, so creates an impression of stronger increase through the period. LEARNING LINK The rate at which GDP changes through time is important for the economy, as it gives an indication about economic growth. This is discussed further in Chapter 8. The debate about whether GDP can be a good indicator of living standards is discussed in Chapter 30. 90 308275_C06_CAM_IASAL ECO_088_096.indd 90 16/02/21 5:40 PM QUANTITATIVE SKILLS 6.1 Converting nominal measurements to real 6 The relationship between nominal and real values is captured by using a price index. The ratio of the current (nominal) value of a variable to its constant price (real) value (multiplied by 100) is a price index. For example, nominal GDP real GDP is a price index. So, if we know GDP at current prices and we know the relevant price index, we can calculate the real value of GDP. 100 × If a country’s real GDP was $120 billion and the underlying price index was 105, what would be the value of nominal GDP? Test yourself 6.5 What is the difference between GNI and GDP? 6 National income Test yourself 6.4 For example, in 2018, GDP for Pakistan in current prices was estimated to be $315 billion, and the underlying price index was 123.9 (based on 2010 = 100). The real value of GDP can thus be calculated as 100 × 315/123.9 = $254.2 billion. GDP can be interpreted as the amount of output produced in an economy during a period of time. It is tempting to think of this as being the resources that residents of the economy have at their disposal. However, it is also important to recognise that there are income flows that take place between countries. For example, there may be foreign workers in a country who remit part of their earnings back to their families – or there may be nationals of the country who work abroad and send income back to the domestic economy. Gross national income (GNI) is GDP plus net income from abroad. For some economies the difference is significant. For example, in 2018/19 net factor income from abroad amounted to about 6% of GNI in Pakistan, partly reflecting the number of Pakistani nationals who were working abroad. Market prices and basic prices KEY TERMS gross national income (GNI): GDP plus net income from abroad basic prices: the prices used for valuing gross value added, being exclusive of taxes but including subsidies market prices: the prices used for valuing GDP, including taxes net of subsidies When compiling a measure of national income by adding up the value of output produced in the various sectors that make up the economy, it is important to avoid double counting, so total output is measured as the sum of value added across the sectors. Value added here is naturally measured at what is known as basic prices. These prices exclude indirect taxes, as these are not part of the value added in production. However, they include subsidies. When using a measure based on expenditures, it is natural to value transactions using the prices actually being paid in the market. This is inclusive of indirect taxes on expenditure, net of subsidies. So, the expenditure measure of GDP is GDP at market prices. In other words, GDP at market prices is equal to gross value added plus taxes on products minus subsidies on products. EXERCISE 6.1 Table 6.1 shows values of some key items in the national accounts for a country in 2019. ▼ Table 6.1 Items in the national accounts ($m) Gross value added at basic prices 1,275 Taxes on products 91 Net income from abroad 86 Subsidies on products 9 Calculate GDP at market prices and GNI. 91 308275_C06_CAM_IASAL ECO_088_096.indd 91 16/02/21 5:40 PM 6 KEY TERMS depreciation (of capital equipment): the fall in the value of capital goods due to wear and tear AS LEVEL PART 4 THE MACROECONOMY net domestic product: GDP – depreciation net national income (NNI): GNI – depreciation Test yourself 6.6 What is the difference between GNI and NNI? Gross and net values As time goes by, physical capital is used up – in other words, machinery and other equipment is subject to wear and tear. This process is known as depreciation, which also affects the calculation of total output. Depreciation cannot be directly observed, so national statistical offices make an estimate of it. Net domestic product and net national income (NNI) are calculated by deducting depreciation from GDP and GNI respectively. SUMMARY: NATIONAL INCOME STATISTICS » There are three ways in which the total level of economic activity in an economy during a period of time can be measured: by total income, by total expenditure, and by total output produced. » In principle, the three ways of measuring GDP should give the same answers, but in practice data measurements are not so accurate. » Real GDP is a measure of the total economic activity carried out in an economy during a period by residents living on its territory, adjusted for price changes. » Real GNI also takes into account net income from abroad. 6.2 Introduction to the circular flow of income A closed economy Assume for the moment that there are just two types of economic agent in an economy: households and firms. In other words, ignore the government and assume there is no international trade. (These will be brought back into the picture soon.) We also assume that all factors of production are owned and supplied to firms by households. In this simple world, firms produce goods and spend on investment goods. Households supply labour and other factor inputs, in return for which they receive income, which they spend on consumer goods. Figure 6.2 shows how all this works. Households Factor incomes Factors of production Output of goods and services Expenditure Firms ▲ Figure 6.2 The circular flow of income 92 308275_C06_CAM_IASAL ECO_088_096.indd 92 23/03/21 10:26 AM KEY TERMS leakages: where money flows out of the circular flow in the form of savings, taxation and imports injections: where money flows into the circular flow in the form of investment, government spending and exports Test yourself 6.7 What is meant by a ‘closed economy’ in this context? » There is a flow of income from firms to households, including wages, salaries, rents, interest and profits. This flow is represented by the blue arrow in Figure 6.2. » The output of goods and services produced by firms flows from firms to households in the form of consumer goods. This is the orange arrow in Figure 6.2. » Balancing the flow of output is a flow of expenditure, as households (and firms) pay for the goods they obtain from firms. This is the green arrow in Figure 6.2. » Households also supply factor services to firms, in the form of labour, land, capital and enterprise. This is represented by the red arrow in Figure 6.2. This model is known as the circular flow model. As this is a closed system, these flows must balance. This means that there are three ways in which the total amount of economic activity in this economy can be measured: by factor incomes that firms pay out, by the total amount of goods and services that is produced, or by total expenditure. Whichever method is chosen, it should give the same result. 6 6 National income circular flow model: a model of the economy which shows the movement of goods and services between households and firms and their corresponding payments in money terms, together with the supply of factors of production The main flows in this model are as follows: An open economy A real-world economy is more complicated than this, so it is also necessary to take into account the economic activities of government and the fact that economies engage in international trade, so that some of the output produced is sold abroad and some of the expenditure goes on foreign goods and services. In other words, a real-world economy is not a closed system, as there are leakages from the system and injections into it. These arise because of the economic activities of government and through an economy’s international trade with the rest of the world. Injections into the circular flow There are three key injections into the circular flow: » government expenditure (G) » exports (X) » investment by firms (I) The government spends money on goods and services. For example, it may spend on the provision of public goods, and has to spend in order to carry out its other governmental obligations. STUDY TIP Notice that in economics ‘investment’ is used in this specific way. In everyday language the term is sometimes used to refer to investing in shares or putting money into a deposit account at the bank. Be careful not to confuse these different concepts. In economics ‘investment’ relates to a firm buying new capital, such as machinery or factory buildings. If you put money into a bank account, that is an act of saving, not investment. Foreign residents buy goods and services produced in the home economy. From the home economy’s point of view, these are exports of goods and services. Associated with exports is an inflow of expenditure from the rest of the world. Firms also undertake expenditure when they buy capital goods, such as machinery, factory buildings or transport equipment. This is termed ‘investment’, as it involves obtaining goods that will be used in future production. Leakages from the circular flow On the other side of the coin, there are leakages from the circular flow, comprising: » taxes raised by the government from households (T) » spending on imports from the rest of the world (M) » household savings (S) The government raises taxes in order to finance its spending. This includes direct taxes such as income tax and corporation tax, but also indirect taxes such as VAT and customs duties. Residents in the domestic economy buy goods and services from abroad, in the form of imports. This is a leakage from the system simply because it is expenditure that is not going on home-produced goods and services. 93 308275_C06_CAM_IASAL ECO_088_096.indd 93 16/02/21 5:40 PM Households save part of their income, so these savings are also a leakage from the circular flow. 6 Figure 6.3 adds all of these effects on to the circular flow diagram. The flow of expenditure is no longer just made up of household consumption expenditure on consumer goods, but is augmented by investment expenditure by firms (I), export expenditure from overseas (X) and government expenditure (G). These can be regarded as injections into the circular flow. AS LEVEL PART 4 THE MACROECONOMY S Households T Factor incomes Factors of production M Output of goods and services Expenditure Firms G I X ▲ Figure 6.3 Injections and leakages in the circular flow of income Notice that there are connections between the injections and leakages – for example, household savings may enter financial markets, and firms borrow from financial markets in order to finance their investment expenditure. Test yourself 6.8 Suppose that there were to be a fall in investment expenditure by firms. How would this affect the circular flow? International trade also affects the circular flow. Part of the expenditure on goods and services in the economy comes from abroad in the form of exports. In addition, part of the expenditure undertaken by households is on imported goods and services. The saving activity of households also affects the circular flow, as there is a part of household income that is saved instead of being spent on goods and services. It is also important to realise that firms contribute to expenditure when they buy investment goods to add to their productive capacity. EXERCISE 6.2 For each of the following, state whether it is an injection or a leakage, and whether it increases or decreases the circular flow (ceteris paribus). a The government cancels a road improvement scheme. b People become more thrifty because the future seems more uncertain. c Domestically produced goods become more popular with foreigners. d The government reduces the rate of income tax. e People choose to take more holidays abroad. f Firms reduce their spending on plant and machinery. Equilibrium in the overall economy The overall economy will be in equilibrium when planned injections are equal to planned leakages. In other words, when plans of economic agents are fulfilled, there is no incentive to change behaviour. Suppose that planned injections are higher than planned leakages, perhaps because the government decides to spend more on the road network. This will cause an increase in national income, but as household income rises, individuals will be likely to save more, and will need to pay more of their income in tax, or spend part of their 94 308275_C06_CAM_IASAL ECO_088_096.indd 94 23/03/21 10:28 AM LEARNING LINK This phenomenon is known as the ‘multiplier’ process, and will be examined in Chapter 24. additional income on imported goods. Leakages will rise, and eventually the economy will return to equilibrium, where planned injections equal planned leakages. Notice that investment in the form of expenditure by firms on machinery, buildings and other productive resources plays an important role within the macroeconomy. By undertaking investment expenditure, firms add to the productive capacity of the economy, and thus enable economic growth to take place. A change in the balance between investment and consumption activity therefore affects the long-run path of the economy. SUMMARY: INTRODUCTION TO THE CIRCULAR FLOW » The circular flow of income describes the relationship between income, expenditure and output. » The circular flow diagram needs to accommodate injections and leakages. » The government affects the circular flow through expenditure (an injection) and taxation (a leakage). » International trade is important because of exports (an injection) and imports (a leakage). 6 National income An increase in expenditure on investment by firms may have other effects as well. In order to meet the additional demand for machinery, other firms need to expand production. This means that they need to hire extra workers – and pay them, of course. The additional workers will then spend part of their income on consumer goods, thus unleashing a second round of expenditure. 6 » The circular flow is also affected by household savings (a leakage) and by firms’ investment expenditure (an injection). » Investment is also important because it affects the productive capacity of the economy in the long run, and is thus important for economic growth. » Equilibrium is achieved when total injections equal total leakages. END OF CHAPTER QUESTIONS Multiple choice 1 A government official stated that the total money value resulting from all economic activities in a country over a year increased. What term underpins their statement? A real economic growth C income per head B circular flow of income D national income 2 What is a likely reason why, in a given year, a country’s GDP would be higher than its GNI? A The country has received net inflows of foreign investment in the past. B The country has encouraged local companies to invest abroad. C The country’s net income from abroad has increased. D The value of capital accumulation exceeds depreciation. Data response 1 Read the following extract and then answer the questions that follow. HS2: A circular argument In the UK in early 2020, the prime minister gave the go-ahead to continue with the planned new 400 km per hour railway line known as HS2. The first phase of the project will be the line between London and Birmingham, England’s second city. This is projected to be operational by 5 2031. Later phases are planned to extend the route further north to the cities of Manchester and Leeds, for which the estimated completion date is 2040; later still there are plans to extend the line into Scotland. Government expenditure on the HS2 project is estimated to be US$135bn, which equates to US$380m per mile. 95 308275_C06_CAM_IASAL ECO_088_096.indd 95 16/02/21 5:40 PM AS LEVEL PART 4 THE MACROECONOMY 6 10 The approval of the plans is a big deal because the HS2 project is controversial. With the UK tax burden already near a 50-year high, the money for HS2 must come from somewhere, so taxation is thought likely to increase further. Those who support the project say it will reduce transport times, create jobs and help the country’s economy. The government’s aim, spelled out in 15 its 2013 strategic case, was to ‘build a stronger, more balanced economy capable of delivering lasting growth and widely shared prosperity’. Transport links are critical for economic success, particularly high-quality infrastructure that would join up cities around the country. Locally, the leaders of the cities along the HS2 route believe beneficial 20 investment by firms will accompany the new line. HSBC, TalkTalk and Deutsche Bank are among the companies that have already relocated some operations out of the London area. It is hoped that HS2 will encourage more to follow. Meanwhile, according to the HS2 company, the construction of the line itself will employ about 30,000 people at its peak. In addition, research shows how 25 HS2 can help to better connect the region’s exporters by cutting journey times from Newcastle in the far northeast of England to London’s Heathrow airport in the southeast by 1 hour and 20 minutes. In these ways, HS2 will boost not only the GDP of the UK but potentially the GNI of many other countries as well. 2020 US$135bn 2015 2011 US$71bn US$41bn Data from the BBC ▲ Figure 6.4 How the projected cost of HS2 has changed (current prices) a Explain, with reference to the data in Figure 6.4, the importance of using real rather than nominal values if a meaningful comparison of the volume of resources used in the HS2 project is to be made. b ‘HS2 will boost not only the GDP of the UK but potentially the GNI of many other countries as well’ (lines 27–28). Distinguish between GDP and GNI and explain why HS2 might potentially boost the GNI of other countries. c Explain the difference between injections and leakages in the circular flow of income model and identify one example of each in the extract. d ‘Locally, the leaders of the cities along the HS2 route believe beneficial investment by firms will accompany the new line’ (lines 19–20). Explain some of the potential benefits of the investment by firms that the city leaders anticipate. e The following has been asserted. ‘The government decision to inject a large sum of money in the HS2 project will lead to a temporary disequilibrium in the overall UK economy. However, there will follow a return to a general equilibrium.’ Discuss the validity of this statement. 96 308275_C06_CAM_IASAL ECO_088_096.indd 96 16/02/21 5:40 PM AS LEVEL PART 4 The macroeconomy 7 Aggregate demand and aggregate supply analysis ★ the definition of aggregate demand (AD) ★ the components of AD, their meanings and determinants ★ the shape of the AD curve and what influences its position ★ aggregate supply (AS) and its determinants ★ the shape of the AS curve in the short run (SRAS) and the long run (LRAS) and what causes them to shift ★ the distinction between a movement along and a shift in AD and AS ★ equilibrium in the AD/AS model and the determination of the level of real output, the price level and employment ★ the effects of shifts in the AD curve and the AS curve on the level of real output, the price level and employment This chapter introduces a model that brings together concepts of aggregate demand and aggregate supply – in other words, the total level of demand and supply in an economy. The starting point is to consider the components of aggregate demand. The way in which the levels of these components are determined in practice is important for the operation of the economy when considered at the aggregate level. It is also important to examine aggregate supply and the factors that influence it. Macroeconomic equilibrium is seen to occur when aggregate demand equals aggregate supply. There are some important differences between this model and the model of demand and supply seen in microeconomics. 7 Aggregate demand and aggregate supply analysis What this chapter covers 7.1 Aggregate demand KEY TERM aggregate demand: the total amount of effective demand in the economy Macroeconomics deals with relationships between economic variables at the aggregate level – that is, in the economy viewed as a whole. In building a theory to explain those relationships, the starting point is to consider aggregate demand. This represents the total amount of effective demand in the economy as a whole. From the discussion of the circular flow, this includes households, firms, the government and overseas residents who buy home-produced goods and services. The main components of aggregate demand are: » » » » consumption (which we will denote by C) investment by firms (I) government expenditure (G) net exports – that is, exports minus imports (X – M) We can write this as: AD = C + I + G + (X – M) The components of aggregate demand Consumption The largest component of aggregate demand is household spending on goods and services produced in the domestic economy, often known as consumption (C). The main factor that will influence the size of consumption expenditure is likely to be the level of real income that households have at their disposal. When real incomes 97 308275_C07_CAM_IASAL ECO_097_113.indd 97 16/02/21 5:44 PM are relatively high, households will tend to spend more than when real incomes are low. Consumption may also be influenced by interest rates, wealth and expectations about the future. Notice that people may not choose to spend all of their income on domestically produced goods: some expenditure may be on imported goods, and they may choose to save part of their income against future needs. 7 Investment AS LEVEL PART 4 THE MACROECONOMY A second key part of aggregate demand is spending by firms – in particular, spending on investment goods (I). For example, firms may choose to invest in new machinery or transport equipment. This is important not only because it contributes to aggregate demand in the current period, but because investment in new machinery enables higher production of goods in the future. The amount of investment that firms will wish to undertake depends on a number of factors. For example, it may be influenced by whether firms are optimistic or pessimistic about future demand for their products. If their expectations are high, they are more likely to invest in order to meet future demand. However, investment expenditure needs to be financed, so the level of investment may also depend on the availability of finance. If firms have made good profits, then this may provide a fund for investment. However, if firms need to borrow, then the cost of borrowing will also be important, and so the rate of interest will be important. Government expenditure The government plays an important role in the macroeconomy. It spends on goods and services, both to allow it to carry on its normal operations and to provide improved facilities that will allow the economy to develop in the future or to protect vulnerable members of society. In other words, government expenditure (G) may be partly consumption and partly investment. Government expenditure may be considered to be autonomous: in other words, it is determined by government decisions rather than by other economic items. International trade KEY TERM trade balance: the balance between expenditure on exports and on imports (net exports) LEARNING LINK The determinants of the components of aggregate demand are explained in Chapter 24. Most economies are open to international trade, and transactions between the domestic economy and the rest of the world will affect aggregate demand. Domestic residents and firms may spend on imports (M), bringing in goods and services that are produced elsewhere in the world. At the same time, foreign consumers and firms may purchase goods and services in the domestic economy in the form of exports (X). The contribution of these transactions to domestic aggregate demand will depend on the balance between exports and imports, known as the trade balance, or net exports. Trade in goods and services (exports and imports) is determined by the competitiveness of domestic goods and services compared with the rest of the world, which in turn is determined by relative inflation rates and the exchange rate. Imports are also affected by domestic income, and exports are affected by incomes in the rest of the world. Figure 7.1 shows the shares of the components of aggregate expenditure in selected countries in 2018. In all countries except China, consumption is by far the largest component, which is the typical pattern. China is unusual in devoting such a high proportion of expenditure to investment. Also of interest is the relatively high proportion of GDP in Malaysia that is trade (exports and imports). This reflects the fact that Malaysia’s economy is very oriented towards international trade. 98 308275_C07_CAM_IASAL ECO_097_113.indd 98 16/02/21 5:44 PM % of GDP 170 C I G X M 7 120 70 20 –30 –80 India Malaysia USA Note: C includes spending by non-profit institutions serving households; I includes changes in inventory holdings; the statistical discrepancy is not shown. Source: based on data from World Development Indicators ▲ Figure 7.1 GDP expenditure shares, 2018 Test yourself 7.1 In thinking about the components of aggregate demand, which economic agent or agents undertake investment expenditure? 7 Aggregate demand and aggregate supply analysis China ▲ A container terminal in Johor in Malaysia EXERCISE 7.1 Suppose there is an economy in which the following values apply. ▼ Table 7.1 Values for an economy Values $m Consumption 75 Profits 60 Investment 30 Government expenditure 25 Exports 50 Private saving 50 Imports 55 a Calculate the level of aggregate demand. b Calculate the trade balance. 99 308275_C07_CAM_IASAL ECO_097_113.indd 99 16/02/21 5:44 PM » Aggregate demand is the total amount of effective demand in the economy. » The components of aggregate demand are consumption, investment, government expenditure and net exports. » Consumption is the largest of these components and is determined by income and other influences, such as interest rates, wealth and expectations about the future. » Investment leads to increases in the capital stock and is influenced by interest rates, past profits and expectations about future demand. » Government expenditure may be regarded as largely autonomous. » Trade in goods and services (exports and imports) is determined by the competitiveness of domestic goods and services compared with the rest of the world, which in turn is determined by relative inflation rates and the exchange rate. Imports are also affected by domestic income, and exports are affected by incomes in the rest of the world. 7.2 The aggregate demand curve KEY TERM aggregate demand curve (AD): a curve showing the relationship between the level of aggregate demand in an economy and the overall price level; it shows planned expenditure at any given overall price level A key relationship to help in explaining the macroeconomy is the aggregate demand curve (AD), which shows the relationship between aggregate demand and the overall price level. This curve shows the total amount of goods and services demanded in an economy at any given overall level of prices. It is important to realise that this is a very different sort of demand curve from the microeconomic demand curves that were introduced in Chapter 2, where the focus was on an individual product and its relationship with its own price. Here the relationship is between the total demand for goods and services and the overall price level. Aggregate demand is made up of all the components discussed above, and the price is an average of all prices of goods and services in the economy. Figure 7.2 shows an aggregate demand curve. Price level AS LEVEL PART 4 THE MACROECONOMY 7 SUMMARY: AGGREGATE DEMAND AD STUDY TIP It is important to remember this difference between the aggregate demand curve and the microeconomic demand curve for a product. In the macroeconomic context, always label the vertical axis as ‘Price level’ and the horizontal axis as ‘Real output’ or ‘Real GDP’ as a reminder. Do not just use ‘P’ and ‘Q’. 0 Real output ▲ Figure 7.2 An aggregate demand curve The shape of the AD curve An important question is why the AD curve slopes downwards. To answer this, it is necessary to determine the likely influence of the price level on the various components of aggregate demand that have been discussed in this chapter, as prices have not been mentioned explicitly. First, the discussion needs to be cast in terms of the price level. When the overall level of prices is relatively low, the purchasing power of income is relatively high. In other words, low overall prices can be thought of as indicating relatively high real income. Furthermore, when prices are low, this raises the real value of households’ wealth. For example, suppose a household holds a financial asset such as a bond with a fixed money value of $100. The relative (real) value of that asset is higher when the overall price level is relatively low. This suggests that, ceteris paribus, a low overall price level means relatively high consumption. 100 308275_C07_CAM_IASAL ECO_097_113.indd 100 16/02/21 5:44 PM LEARNING LINK A third argument concerns exports and imports. It can be argued that, ceteris paribus, when prices at home are relatively low compared with the rest of the world, this will increase the competitiveness of domestically produced goods, leading to an increase in foreign demand for exports, and a fall in the demand for imports into the economy as people switch to buying home goods and services. All of these arguments support the idea that the aggregate demand curve should be downward sloping. In other words, when the overall price level is relatively low, aggregate demand will be relatively high, and when prices are relatively high, aggregate demand will be relatively low. The position of the AD curve What will cause the AD curve to shift its position? Any change in the components of aggregate demand will affect the position of AD. For example, an increase in firms’ expenditure on investment goods will cause the AD curve to shift to the right. A fall in government expenditure would cause the AD to shift to the left. Test yourself 7.2 What factors would induce a shift of the aggregate demand curve and what would induce a movement along it? SUMMARY: THE AGGREGATE DEMAND CURVE » The aggregate demand curve (AD) shows the relationship between the level of aggregate demand in an economy and the overall price level. » The AD curve is downward sloping with respect to the overall price level. » Changes in the components of aggregate demand affect the position of the AD curve. 7 7 Aggregate demand and aggregate supply analysis The way in which shifts in AD affect the economy will be discussed after we have explored the other key relationship – the aggregate supply curve. A second argument relates to interest rates. When prices are relatively low, interest rates also tend to be relatively low, which would encourage both investment and consumption expenditure, as interest rates can be seen as representing the cost of borrowing to households and firms. 7.3 Aggregate supply The previous section discussed the notion of aggregate demand and introduced the aggregate demand curve. In order to analyse the overall macroeconomic equilibrium, it is necessary to derive a second relationship: that between aggregate supply and the price level. It is important to remember that the level of aggregate supply covers the output of all sorts of goods and services that are produced within an economy during a period of time. However, it is not simply a question of adding up all the individual supply curves from individual markets. Within an individual market, an increase in price may induce higher supply of a good because firms will switch from other markets in search of higher profits. What you now need to be looking for is a relationship between the overall price level and the total amount supplied, which is a completely different thing. The total quantity of output supplied in an economy over a period of time depends on the quantities of factors of production employed: that is, the total amounts of labour, capital and other factors used. The ability of firms to vary output in the short run will be influenced by the degree of flexibility that the firms have in varying inputs. This suggests that it is important to distinguish between short-run and long-run aggregate supply. Short-run aggregate supply In the short run, firms may have relatively little flexibility to vary their inputs. Money wages are likely to be fixed, and firms will not be able to expand the amount of capital needed in the production process. Furthermore, raw materials may be in short supply, and firms may find that hiring additional workers brings less additional output than is obtained from existing workers because of the lack of additional machinery. However, at a higher price level firms will want to produce more in order to increase 101 308275_C07_CAM_IASAL ECO_097_113.indd 101 16/02/21 5:44 PM AS LEVEL PART 4 THE MACROECONOMY short-run aggregate supply curve (SRAS): a curve showing how much output firms would be prepared to supply in the short run at any given overall price level their profits. This suggests that in the short run, aggregate supply may be upward sloping, as shown in Figure 7.3, where SRAS represents short-run aggregate supply. Price level 7 KEY TERM SRAS 0 Real GDP ▲ Figure 7.3 The short-run supply curve (SRAS) Test yourself 7.3 What would induce a movement up along the SRAS? Underlying the aggregate supply curve are the decisions taken by firms about production levels at any given price. Firms are assumed to choose how much output to produce in order to maximise profits. In the short run, firms must take as given: » the state of technology and the effectiveness with which factors are used » the total supply of factors of production The state of technology and the total supply of factors of production change only gradually through time, which is why the short-run aggregate supply curve is important: it shows how firms act in the short run. On the other hand, input prices can change more rapidly – for example, wage rates can change, as can the prices of some inputs such as oil or other raw materials. These changes in input prices affect the costs faced by firms, and can affect the position of the SRAS. The cost of inputs There are several factors that could influence costs in the short run. For example, suppose there is a change in the cost of raw materials. If a key raw material becomes more limited in supply, perhaps because reserves are exhausted, then the prices of inputs will tend to rise, thus raising firms’ costs of production. They may then choose to supply less output at any given product price – and the aggregate supply curve would shift to the left. The price of oil has been subject to significant variations over time. Oil is a key input for many firms, and an increase in the price of oil affects the cost of energy and transport. It also affects the economy in many other ways – for example, oil is a key input in the production of many fertilisers used in the agricultural sector. The price of oil may therefore have a significant impact on the position of aggregate supply in the short run by affecting the costs faced by firms. Another key input for firms is labour, so an increase in labour costs will also affect the position of the short-run aggregate supply curve. The exchange rate ▲ Oil is a key input for many firms Where firms rely on imported inputs of raw materials, energy or component parts used in production, then a change in the exchange rate could affect aggregate supply, by affecting the domestic price of imported inputs, and in turn affecting the costs faced by firms. This could be favourable, of course, depending on the direction in which the exchange rate changes. It could be that the exchange rate rises (appreciates), thus reducing the domestic price of imports. Firms may then be prepared to supply more output at any given price. 102 308275_C07_CAM_IASAL ECO_097_113.indd 102 23/03/21 10:31 AM LEARNING LINK Government intervention There are some forms of government intervention that can affect firms’ costs in the short run. An increase in regulation that forced firms to spend more on health and safety measures would raise costs. An increase in the rate of corporation tax would have similar effects. Shifts in the short-run aggregate supply curve Test yourself 7.4 How would a fall in labour costs affect the SRAS? 7 If any of the factors assumed to influence aggregate supply in the short run change, then the aggregate supply curve will shift. The costs faced by firms are the main cause of shifts in SRAS. For example, given that aggregate supply arises from the use of inputs of factors of production, one important influence is the price of factor inputs. Other factors that influence the costs faced by firms will also be important, as mentioned above. Price level Figure 7.4 shows how the short-run aggregate supply curve would respond if the government introduced measures that require firms to spend more on health and safety. The increase in costs means that firms will be prepared to supply less output at any given price, so the SRAS curve shifts to the left, from SRAS0 to SRAS1. SRAS1 7 Aggregate demand and aggregate supply analysis The significance of the exchange rate and the way in which it is determined is explained in Chapters 13, 28 and 29. The exchange rate can change in the short run for a variety of different reasons, so firms may face some quite sudden changes in their costs. One way that firms can guard against this is through the nature of the contracts drawn up with their foreign suppliers, if future prices can be specified in a way that hedges against possible exchange rate fluctuations. SRAS0 0 Real GDP ▲ Figure 7.4 A shift in the SRAS curve EXERCISE 7.2 For each of the following, state whether the short-run aggregate supply curve would shift to the left or to the right. a The discovery of a new source of a raw material, reducing its price b An increase in the exchange rate c An increase in wage rates d A fall in the price of oil Short-run aggregate supply: an alternative view There are different views about the shape of the SRAS. Some economists have argued that the SRAS will have a gentler slope when there is some ‘slack’ in the economy – in other words, if the economy is operating at a relatively low level of real GDP, an increase in aggregate supply will have a relatively weak effect on the overall price level. However, as resources become more scarce, the pressure on the price level increases as real GDP increases, and the SRAS becomes steeper. Figure 7.5 shows an example of such a curve. 103 308275_C07_CAM_IASAL ECO_097_113.indd 103 16/02/21 5:44 PM Price level 0 Real GDP ▲ Figure 7.5 An alternative view of the SRAS Long-run aggregate supply KEY TERMS full-employment level of output: the level of output at which the economy is operating at full potential capacity long-run aggregate supply curve (LRAS): a curve showing the level of real output when the economy is at full capacity Test yourself 7.5 Why would firms not want to pay overtime to their staff in the long run? LEARNING LINK Notice that although this level of employment is regarded as being ‘full’ employment, this does not mean that that there is no unemployment in the economy. This is explained in Chapter 9. At a given point in time, the state of technology and the availability of factors of production determine the total capacity of the economy to produce. In the short run, firms may be able to produce above this level, but only by increasing the intensity of use of factors of production – for example, by paying their workers overtime. However, firms will not want to do this on a long-term basis, so producing beyond the natural full capacity of the economy will not be sustainable. There may also be periods in which total output falls below the potential capacity to produce – for example, if there is a recession in which unemployment increases. So, in the long run, there is a potential capacity level of output, often referred to as the full-employment level of output. If the economy always adjusts to this level, then the long-run aggregate supply curve (LRAS) will be vertical at this fullemployment level. This is shown in Figure 7.6, where YFE represents the potential full capacity output of the economy. In other words, this level of output corresponds to a level of employment that is regarded as being ‘full’ employment. Price level AS LEVEL PART 4 THE MACROECONOMY 7 SRAS 0 LRAS YFE Real GDP ▲ Figure 7.6 The long-run aggregate supply curve Shifts in the LRAS The position of the long-run supply curve depends on: » the quantity of factor inputs available » the effectiveness with which factor inputs are used The quantity of factor inputs As far as labour input is concerned, an increase in the size of the workforce will affect the position of aggregate supply. In practice, the size of the labour force tends to change relatively slowly unless substantial international migration is taking place: 104 308275_C07_CAM_IASAL ECO_097_113.indd 104 16/02/21 5:44 PM for example, the expansion of membership of the EU in May 2004 led to significant migration into the UK. An increase in the quantity of capital will also have this effect, by increasing the capacity of the economy to produce. However, such an increase requires firms to have undertaken investment activity. In other words, the balance of spending between consumption and investment may affect the position of the aggregate supply curve in future periods. Price level The effectiveness with which factor inputs are used The effectiveness with which inputs are utilised is another important influence on the position of LRAS. Advances in technology are one route through which inputs can be more effectively utilised. New machinery can improve the efficiency with which other inputs are used, and the development of new materials can also have an impact. Such developments can reduce firms’ costs and increase the amount of aggregate output that can be produced, leading to a shift in the long-run aggregate supply curve. This is shown in Figure 7.7, where aggregate supply was originally at LRAS0. Technological change that improves efficiency in the use of capital and other inputs means that firms are prepared to supply more output at any given overall price level, so the aggregate supply curve shifts to LRAS1, with real GDP increasing from YFE0 to YFE1. 0 LRAS0 YFE0 LRAS1 7 Aggregate demand and aggregate supply analysis Demographic changes and migration can also affect the size of the workforce in the long run. The UK and many other advanced economies have been characterised by an ageing population in recent years. As more people live longer into retirement, the working population falls as a proportion of the total, and the LRAS may shift to the left. In many developing countries in sub-Saharan Africa, the HIV/AIDS epidemic was especially devastating to people of working age, so reduced the size and effectiveness of the labour force. In-migration can also affect the size of the workforce. 7 YFE1 Real GDP ▲ Figure 7.7 A shift in LRAS Labour as a factor of production can also become more effective and productive, and can be seen as a form of human capital. Improvements to education and the provision of skills training can improve the productivity of labour, again leading to a rightward shift of long-run aggregate supply. Training and education may be especially important for an economy that is undergoing structural change, so that workers need to be prepared to move between occupations. Government encouragement or provision of such training can improve the flexibility of the labour market and affect aggregate supply. EXERCISE 7.3 For each of the following, identify whether the change described will affect short-run or longrun aggregate supply, and whether the result is a leftward or rightward shift. a A fall in the exchange rate that affects the price of imported inputs b c d e An increase in the rate of immigration An increase in the price of oil A reduction in corporation tax The introduction of new super-computers 105 308275_C07_CAM_IASAL ECO_097_113.indd 105 16/02/21 5:44 PM Long-run aggregate supply: an alternative view The assumption that LRAS is vertical depends on the assumption that prices and wages adjust rapidly to take the economy to equilibrium. This assumption reflects a classical or neoclassical view of the economy. A group of economists (sometimes known as ‘Keynesians’) held that the macroeconomy was not sufficiently flexible to enable continuous full employment, and that the adjustment to full-employment equilibrium would not be as smooth as had been suggested. They argued that the economy could settle at an equilibrium position below full employment, at least in the medium term. In particular, inflexibilities in labour markets would prevent or slow the adjustment. For example, if firms had pessimistic expectations about aggregate demand, and thus reduced their supply of output, this would lead to lower incomes because of the workers being laid off. This would then mean that aggregate demand was indeed deficient, so firms’ pessimism was self-fulfilling. AS LEVEL PART 4 THE MACROECONOMY 7 Price level These sorts of argument led to a belief that there would be a range of output over which aggregate supply would be upward sloping. Figure 7.8 illustrates such an aggregate supply curve, in which YFE represents full employment. When the economy is operating below this level of output, aggregate supply is somewhat sensitive to the price level, becoming steeper as full employment is approached. LRAS YFE Real GDP ▲ Figure 7.8 Aggregate supply in the long run (the ‘Keynesian’ view) Table 7.2 summarises the different views of long-run aggregate supply. ▼ Table 7.2 Summary of classical and Keynesian views Classical view Keynesian view LRAS is vertical at the full-employment level LRAS is upward-sloping for a range of output below full employment The economy converges rapidly to full employment The economy could settle at a level of output below full employment Policy intervention is not needed because the economy adjusts rapidly Policy intervention may be needed to move towards full employment Aggregate supply is not sensitive to the price level Aggregate supply is sensitive to the price level when the economy is below full employment SUMMARY: AGGREGATE SUPPLY » In the short run, firms aiming to maximise profits will be prepared to supply more output at higher prices. » There is an upward-sloping relationship between real output and the price level. » Changes in factor prices may lead to a shift in the position of the short-run aggregate supply curve. » The level of output produced when the economy is operating at full capacity (given technology and the availability of factors of production) is known as the full-employment level of output. » In the long run, aggregate supply is vertical at this full-employment level of real output, although some economists have argued that it could slope upwards over some range of output. 106 308275_C07_CAM_IASAL ECO_097_113.indd 106 16/02/21 5:44 PM 7.4 Macroeconomic equilibrium As with demand and supply in microeconomics, it is important to understand how equilibrium is achieved at the macroeconomic level, both in the short run and in the long run. 7 Macroeconomic equilibrium in the short run Price level SRAS P AD 0 Y Real GDP ▲ Figure 7.9 Short-run macroeconomic equilibrium This is an equilibrium, in the sense that if nothing changes then firms and households will have no reason to alter their behaviour in the next period. At the price P, aggregate supply is matched by aggregate demand. 7 Aggregate demand and aggregate supply analysis Bringing aggregate demand and short-run aggregate supply together, the overall equilibrium position for the macroeconomy can be identified. In Figure 7.9, with aggregate supply given by SRAS and aggregate demand by AD, equilibrium is reached at the real GDP level Y, with the price level at P. Can it be guaranteed that the equilibrium will occur at the full-employment level of real GDP? For example, suppose that in Figure 7.10 the output level YFE corresponds to the full-employment level of output – that is, the level of output that represents productive capacity when all factors of production are fully employed. If aggregate demand is at AD*, the macroeconomic equilibrium is at this full-employment output YFE. However, if the aggregate demand curve is located at AD1 the equilibrium will occur at Y1, which is below the full-employment level, so there is surplus capacity in the economy. Price level It may be possible to produce more than YFE in the short run, but only on a temporary basis, perhaps by the use of overtime. In other words, in the short run it is possible that the SRAS could move to a position with equilibrium to the right of YFE, but this would be unsustainable in the long run, so the SRAS would move back to the left. SRAS P* P1 AD* AD1 0 Y1 YFE Real GDP ▲ Figure 7.10 Will macroeconomic equilibrium be at full employment in the short run? 107 308275_C07_CAM_IASAL ECO_097_113.indd 107 16/02/21 5:44 PM In the long run, the equilibrium level of real GDP cannot be higher than YFE, and may only be below YFE temporarily when the LRAS is vertical. Figure 7.11 shows the long-run equilibrium position with a ‘classical’, vertical, LRAS curve. In this long-run equilibrium position, the overall price level in the economy is P*. Price level AS LEVEL PART 4 THE MACROECONOMY 7 Macroeconomic equilibrium in the long run LRAS P* AD 0 YFE Real GDP ▲ Figure 7.11 Long-run macroeconomic equilibrium Two important questions need to be explored. One is how the economy adjusts to equilibrium if there is a change in the market environment. The second question is how long it takes to reach a new equilibrium. We will explore these questions by considering how the equilibrium changes in response to a change in aggregate demand or aggregate supply. The effect of an increase in aggregate demand The position of the aggregate demand curve depends on the components of aggregate demand: consumption, investment, government spending and net exports. Factors that affect these components will affect the position of aggregate demand. Price level Consider Figure 7.12, which shows the short-run position. Suppose that the economy begins in equilibrium with aggregate demand at AD0. The equilibrium level of real GDP is Y0, and the price level is at P0. An increase in government expenditure will affect the position of the aggregate demand curve, shifting it to AD1. The economy will move to a new equilibrium position, with a higher output level Y1 and a higher price level P1. SRAS P1 P0 AD1 AD0 0 Y 0 Y1 Real GDP ▲ Figure 7.12 A shift in aggregate demand in the short run The shift in the AD curve from AD0 to AD1 results in a new equilibrium with higher real GDP at Y1 and a higher overall price level at P1. Notice that the change brings about a relatively large increase in the price level with a relatively modest increase in real GDP. This reflects the shape of the SRAS. 108 308275_C07_CAM_IASAL ECO_097_113.indd 108 16/02/21 5:44 PM Price level Figure 7.13 illustrates the effect of an increase in aggregate demand with a short-run aggregate supply curve shaped as a sweeping upward curve. The key difference is that with this shape of SRAS, the effect of the shift in AD is seen more in its impact on real GDP than on the price level. In other words, the resulting increase in price in the new equilibrium is relatively small compared to the increase in real GDP. 7 SRAS AD1 0 AD0 Y0 Y1 Real GDP ▲ Figure 7.13 An increase in aggregate demand in the short run with a curved SRAS In the long run, the economy will move to its long-run equilibrium at the full capacity level of real output. But how does this adjustment work? Price level Figure 7.14 demonstrates, using a linear SRAS. The economy begins with real output at its full-employment level YFE and the price level at P0. If there is an increase in aggregate demand from AD0 to AD1 firms respond by increasing output, and there is a movement along the short-run aggregate supply curve SRAS0. Real output has increased to Y1 and the price level has risen to P1. As the economy begins to adjust, firms find that their costs rise because of rising raw material prices and wage costs. This means that there is a shift of the short-run aggregate supply curve from SRAS0 to SRAS1. Real output has returned to the full-employment level, but the economy is left with a higher equilibrium price level at P2. LRAS 7 Aggregate demand and aggregate supply analysis P1 P0 SRAS1 SRAS0 P2 P1 P0 AD1 AD0 Test yourself 7.6 Explain why the effect of an increase in aggregate demand cannot be sustained if the economy begins at the full-employment level of real GDP. 0 YFE Y1 Real GDP ▲ Figure 7.14 Adjustment following an increase in aggregate demand This adjustment process would work in reverse if there is an initial fall in aggregate demand. There would be an initial movement along the SRAS, with equilibrium real output and price level falling. In the longer run, the economy would move back towards the long-run equilibrium as firms’ costs adjust downwards with less upward pressure on prices. An important question in this situation is how long it takes for the economy to return to long-run equilibrium. Economists who subscribe to the classical view of the world would 109 308275_C07_CAM_IASAL ECO_097_113.indd 109 16/02/21 5:44 PM argue that adjustment will be rapid. However, those in the Keynesian camp would tend to argue that the adjustment could be slow, or that the economy could settle below full employment in the medium or even long run. Figure 7.15 illustrates how this could occur. If the AD curve comes to intersect the LRAS at a level of real GDP below full employment, then the adjustment back to full employment may not take place, or it may take a long time for the adjustment to work through the economy. This is an equilibrium position for the economy, given that aggregate demand is equal to long-run aggregate supply. AS LEVEL PART 4 THE MACROECONOMY Price level 7 LRASK PFE PK AD 0 YK YFE Real GDP ▲ Figure 7.15 Long-run macroeconomic equilibrium below full employment The effect of a short-run supply shock The AD/AS model can also be used to analyse the effects of an external shock that affects aggregate supply. For example, suppose there is an increase in oil prices arising from a disruption to supplies in the Middle East. This raises firms’ costs, and leads to a reduction in aggregate supply. Again, we can examine the likely effects on equilibrium. Figure 7.16 analyses the short-run situation. The economy begins in equilibrium with output at Y0 and the overall level of prices at P0. The increase in oil prices causes a movement of the aggregate supply curve from SRAS0 to SRAS1, with aggregate demand unchanged at AD. After the economy returns to equilibrium, the new output level has fallen to Y1 and the overall price level has increased to P1. STUDY TIP In trying to analyse the effects of a shock, the first step is to think about whether the shock affects AD or AS, and the second is to analyse whether the shock is positive or negative: that is, which way the relevant curve will shift. The move towards a new equilibrium can then be investigated. Price level At the time of the first oil price crisis back in 1973–74, the UK government of the day tried to maintain the previous level of real output by stimulating aggregate demand. This had the effect of pushing up the price level, but did not have any noticeable effect on real output. In the long run, the impact of a supply shock will depend on whether the shock was a temporary or a permanent change. If oil prices revert to their original level, then the economy would self-adjust back to the full-employment level of real GDP. However, if the change is permanent, the LRAS would also shift to the left. SRAS1 SRAS0 P1 P0 AD 0 Y 1 Y0 Real GDP ▲ Figure 7.16 A supply shock 110 308275_C07_CAM_IASAL ECO_097_113.indd 110 16/02/21 5:44 PM Shifts of and movements along AD and AS As in many other circumstances, it is important to be aware of the distinction between shifts of the AD and AS curves, and movements along them. Typically, if a shock affects the position of one of the curves, it will lead to a movement along the other. For example, if the AS curve shifts as a result of a supply shock, the response is a movement along the AD curve, and vice versa. EXERCISE 7.4 For each of the following, decide whether the change affects aggregate demand or long-run aggregate supply, and draw a diagram to illustrate the effects on equilibrium real output and overall price level. a A technological advance that improves the efficiency of capital b A financial crisis in Asia that reduces the demand for UK exports c An improvement in firms’ expectations about future demand, such that investment expenditure increases d An increase in firms’ transport costs For each of these changes, indicate whether the result is a shift of or a movement along the AD and LRAS curves. SUMMARY: MACROECONOMIC EQUILIBRIUM » Macroeconomic equilibrium is achieved in the » » » » short run at the intersection of the AD and SRAS curves. It is possible to produce more than the theoretical capacity output, but only in the short run. In the long run the economy converges on the fullemployment level of output where AD equals LRAS. An increase in AD results in a higher price level and higher real GDP. With a classical SRAS the main impact is on price rather than real GDP. » If the SRAS has a shallower slope when output is below full employment, then an increase in AD affects real GDP more strongly than the price level. » There has been some debate about how long it takes for an economy to return to long-run equilibrium. » A shock to aggregate demand leads to a movement along the aggregate supply curve, whereas a shock to aggregate supply leads to a movement along the aggregate demand curve. 7 Aggregate demand and aggregate supply analysis The onset of the coronavirus (Covid-19) pandemic in 2020 caused substantial shifts in both aggregate demand and aggregate supply curves in countries around the world. This is discussed in the case study on page 113. 7 END OF CHAPTER QUESTIONS Multiple choice 1 When constructing a market supply curve, economists sum horizontally the supply curves of all firms in the market. Why is it not possible to construct the aggregate supply curve of an economy by simply summing horizontally all firms’ supply curves from all individual markets? A The aggregate supply curve measures the relationship between the general price level and total output. B The short-run aggregate supply curve is constrained by the availability of resources in the economy. C As prices rise, each level of output brings higher profits. D At higher output produced, firms will experience rising costs of production. 2 Why is the AS curve not perfectly elastic throughout the whole range of output? A As firms increase output, they bid up the prices of factors of production. B Firms become less willing to increase supply at higher levels of output. C Aggregate demand increases faster over higher levels of output. D Firms are more likely to increase investment as their scale of operation increases. 111 308275_C07_CAM_IASAL ECO_097_113.indd 111 16/02/21 5:44 PM Data response AS LEVEL PART 4 THE MACROECONOMY 7 1 Read the following extract and then answer the questions that follow. Aggregate demand and supply in France 5 In the years prior to 2020, the French economy had showed consistent economic growth fuelled by higher consumption, a surge in investment by firms and increased global trade. The inflation rate in France had also been consistently below the average of its trade partners. Table 7.3 summarises some key economic data from this period. ▼ Table 7.3 France’s exchange rate (euro) against the US$ and trade balance in goods and services, January 2018–January 2020 Date Exchange rate: €1 to US$ France trade balance in goods and services (exports minus imports) (€bn) Jan 2018 1.200 −6,344 April 2018 1.230 −5,212 July 2018 1.165 −4,472 Oct 2018 1.153 −4,342 Jan 2019 1.147 −4,321 April 2019 1.122 −5,383 July 2019 1.129 −5,060 Oct 2019 1.010 −4,710 Jan 2020 1.160 −5,894 Source: tradingeconomics.com However, in the first quarter of 2020, household consumption fell by 5.6%, a record amount, government spending dropped by 2.0%, investment by firms plunged by 10.5% and net exports of goods and services fell by 0.4%. On an annual basis, economic activity dropped by 5.0% in quarter 1, in contrast to the 10 growth of 0.9% in quarter 1 of 2019. The French economy is forecast to shrink throughout 2020, ravaged by Covid-19. Increases in unemployment and social distancing measures will dampen household consumption, while heightened uncertainties over the length of the pandemic are likely further to reduce investment by firms. 15 Like other countries, in 2020 the French government put in place a fiscal rescue package. Even before the difficulties the French government had pledged in its 2019 budget to increase spending on tertiary education and had introduced the income tax reforms summarised in Table 7.4. ▼ Table 7.4 French income tax rates, 2019 and 2020 Income tax rates 2019 Income Income tax rates 2020 Tax rate Income Tax rate Up to €10,064 Nil Up to €10,064 Nil €10,065 to €27,794 14% €10,065 to €25,659 11% €27,795 to €74,517 30% €25,660 to €73,369 30% €74,518 to €157,806 41% €73,370 to €157,806 41% Over €157,806 45% Over €157,806 45% Source: Blevinsfranks.com 112 308275_C07_CAM_IASAL ECO_097_113.indd 112 16/02/21 5:44 PM Essay style xplain what is meant by inward migration and consider whether a high rate 2 a E of inward migration will always lead to an increase in an economy’s long run aggregate supply. b When government expenditure increases, in the short run the price level is more strongly affected than real GDP.’ Assess the validity of this statement. CASE STUDY The Covid-19 pandemic The Covid-19 pandemic that swept across the world in 2020 affected people in almost every country. Healthcare systems came under enormous and unanticipated pressure; many people were unable to work; in many countries there were strong restrictions on movement, with many people confined to their homes. International travel was restricted, with many airlines facing financial difficulties. In terms of macroeconomics, countries faced major disruption that will have repercussions for many years beyond the end of the pandemic. The AD/AS model explained in Chapter 7 cannot capture all of these effects, but it may help to begin to understand how economies have been affected. The pandemic brought sudden changes to both the demand and supply sides of the macroeconomy. Aggregate demand was quickly affected as illness spread and many individuals were unable to work, reducing consumption. Firms were discouraged from undertaking new investment. There was also severe disruption to the supply chain. Firms faced loss of workers, or had to find ways of enabling workers to work from home. As the pandemic progressed, further restrictions were introduced, with firms producing products that were considered to be non-essential being forced to cease production. This effectively meant that there was a forced reduction in the potential full capacity of the economy. 7 7 Aggregate demand and aggregate supply analysis a ‘The inflation rate in France had also been consistently below the average of its trade partners’ (lines 3–4). Use this information to explain one possible reason why the aggregate demand curve slopes downwards from left to right. b Explain, using the trade balance data in Table 7.3, what would have happened to the position of the aggregate demand curve of France between January 2018 and January 2019, ceteris paribus. c Discuss, using the exchange rate data in Table 7.3, the impact on the position of the short-run aggregate supply curve of France between April 2018 and April 2019. d Explain, with reference to the extract, which action taken by the French government is likely to affect its long-run aggregate supply. e Explain, with reference to Table 7.4, whether the changes in income tax would cause a movement along or a shift of the French aggregate demand curve. ▲ Travel was restricted during the Covid-19 pandemic Some governments launched massive spending programmes to offset the impact of the pandemic. These were targeted partly at building capacity in healthcare systems and searching for treatments and vaccines. However, they were also intended to try to protect small and medium-sized enterprises, by providing support for employees who had been prevented from working. Follow-up questions a Use an AD/AS diagram to identify the impact of the pandemic in the short run. b Discuss problems that need to be faced as an economy emerges from the pandemic. 113 308275_C07_CAM_IASAL ECO_097_113.indd 113 18/03/21 2:51 PM AS LEVEL PART 4 The macroeconomy AS LEVEL PART 4 THE MACROECONOMY 8 Economic growth What this chapter covers ★ the meaning of economic growth and how it can be measured ★ the distinction between growth in nominal GDP and real GDP ★ the causes of economic growth ★ the consequences of economic growth One of society’s prime responsibilities is to provide a reasonable standard of living for its citizens and to promote their wellbeing. Hence one of the major objectives for economic policy in the long run is to enable improvements in wellbeing, and in order to do this it is first necessary to expand the resources available within society. A key element in this process is to achieve economic growth, which is the subject of this chapter. 8.1 What is economic growth? KEY TERMS potential economic growth: an increase in the productive capacity of the economy actual economic growth: an increase in measured real GDP over a period of time LEARNING LINK The concept of GDP as a measurement of the total amount of economic activity taking place in a period of time is introduced in Chapter 6. Economic growth is one of the most carefully monitored indicators of the performance of an economy. It is important in looking at an economy’s performance because it is through economic growth that a country expands the resources available to its citizens. But what do we mean by ‘economic growth’? From a theoretical point of view, potential economic growth can be thought of as an expansion of the productive capacity of an economy. It is an expansion of the potential output of the economy. Actual economic growth is where aggregate output increases in the short run in response to an increase in aggregate demand or an improvement in utilisation of the factors of production – for example, when unemployment falls. This is measured in terms of the rate of change of real gross domestic product (GDP) over a period of time (normally a year). STUDY TIP Notice the important distinction between the level of real GDP and the rate of economic growth. The actual rate of growth is calculated as the percentage change in the level of real GDP. Notice that in comparing economic growth across countries it is important to adjust for the size of countries in terms of population, by calculating GDP per head (GDP per capita). Chapter 1 discussed economic growth in terms of the production possibility curve (PPC). In Figure 1.4 on page 19, economic growth was characterised as an outward movement of the production possibility frontier from PPC0 to PPC1. In other words, economic growth enables a society to produce more goods and services in any given period as a result of an expansion in its resources. This is long-run economic growth. Shortrun economic growth takes place when an economy moves towards the production possibility curve from a point within it. Remember that if the economy is operating inside its PPC, it is failing to use all of its factors of production effectively, so a move towards the PPC is possible when employment rises and output increases as a result. 114 308275_C08_CAM_IASAL ECO_114_124.indd 114 17/02/21 10:42 AM EXERCISE 8.1 Capital goods per period 8 D C B A PPC0 PPC1 Consumer goods per period ▲ Figure 8.1 Economic growth? Price level A second way of thinking about economic growth is to use the AD/AS model. In Figure 8.2, an increase in the skills of the workforce will enable firms to produce more output at any given price, so that the aggregate supply curve will shift outwards from LRASFE0 to LRASFE1. This entails an increase in full-employment output (capacity output) from YFE0 to YFE1. This again can be characterised as economic growth. LRASFE0 8 Economic growth In Figure 8.1, which of the following represent(s) potential economic growth? a A shift from A to B b A shift from B to C c A shift from C to A d A shift from C to D e None of the above LRASFE1 P0 P1 AD 0 YFE0 YFE1 Real GDP ▲ Figure 8.2 An increase in long-run aggregate supply Test yourself 8.1 STUDY TIP If there is an increase in the full-employment level of real GDP, would this be classified as actual or potential economic growth? Notice that you can show long-run economic growth using either a PPC diagram or an AD/AS diagram, depending on the context in which you need to demonstrate long-run economic growth. A shift in the PPC shows that the potential production opportunities have expanded, but does not show exactly what would happen. The AD/AS approach shows the effect on real GDP and the price level. EXERCISE 8.2 Which of the following represent(s) potential economic growth, and which may just involve a move to the PPC (i.e. actual economic growth)? a An increase in the rate of change of potential output b A fall in the unemployment rate c Improved work practices that increase labour productivity d An increase in the proportion of the population joining the workforce e An increase in the utilisation of capital f A rightward shift in the LRAS curve 115 308275_C08_CAM_IASAL ECO_114_124.indd 115 17/02/21 10:42 AM » Economic growth is an important indicator of the » Potential economic growth can be shown as performance of an economy. » Potential economic growth is an expansion of the productive capacity of an economy. » If aggregate output increases in the short run in response to an increase in aggregate demand or a recovery from recession, this is actual economic growth. an outward shift of an economy’s production possibility curve. » In the AD/AS model, potential economic growth is shown as a rightward shift of the long-run aggregate supply curve. 8.2 Measuring economic growth Real GDP is a way of measuring the total output of an economy over a period of time, and its rate of change is used as a measure of economic growth. However, if economists try to measure potential economic growth using the rate of change of real GDP as an indicator, they are not necessarily measuring what they want to. GDP growth measures the actual rate of change of output rather than the growth in the potential output capacity of the economy. In Figure 8.3, a movement from A to B represents a move to the frontier. This is an increase in actual output resulting from using up surplus capacity in the economy, but it is not potential economic growth in our theoretical sense, as moving from A to B does not entail an increase in productive capacity. On the other hand, a movement of the frontier itself, enabling the move from B to C, does represent potential economic growth. However, when economists observe a change in GDP they cannot easily distinguish between the two sorts of effect, especially if the economy is not always operating at full capacity. It is therefore better to think of economic growth in terms of the underlying trend rate of growth of real GDP. STUDY TIP Be careful to avoid confusing the level of GDP with economic growth, which is the rate of change of GDP. For example, a reduction in the rate of economic growth from 3% to 2% does not mean that GDP itself is falling – it just means that the rate of growth is slowing. Test yourself 8.2 Would GDP at constant prices be known as real GDP or as nominal GDP? Capital goods per period AS LEVEL PART 4 THE MACROECONOMY 8 SUMMARY: WHAT IS ECONOMIC GROWTH? C B A PPC0 0 PPC1 Consumer goods per period ▲ Figure 8.3 Economic growth? Actual economic growth can be calculated as the annual percentage rate of change of real GDP, normally on an annual basis. The rate of change of GNI, which also includes net income from abroad, is an alternative measure. This may be seen as a more helpful LEARNING LINK Notice that when calculating economic growth it is important to use data for real GDP. The distinction between real and nominal values of a variable was explained in Chapter 6. You may recall that the reason for this is that real GDP has been adjusted to remove the effect of changing prices over time. 116 308275_C08_CAM_IASAL ECO_114_124.indd 116 23/03/21 1:58 PM indicator for countries where citizens of a country work abroad and send income back to their families. This is significant for countries such as Pakistan and the Philippines. QUANTITATIVE SKILLS 8.1 8 Calculating a percentage change Test yourself 8.3 Test yourself 8.4 GDP in New Zealand grew by 3.1% between 2016 and 2017 and by 2.8% between 2017 and 2018. What happened to the level of GDP in 2018? As an example, consider the growth rate of real GDP in Malaysia between 2017 and 2018. GDP in 2017 was 1.23 trillion ringgits. This increased to 1.36 trillion ringgits in 2018. To calculate the percentage change in real GDP, we need to calculate the change in real GDP (1.36 – 1.23 = 0.13), then express that as a percentage of the original value. In other words, the percentage change is: 1.36 – 1.23 = 10.6% 100 × 1.23 Notice that the change in the variable is always expressed as a percentage of the initial value, not the final value. 8 Economic growth Explain why it is difficult to identify potential economic growth. In macroeconomics it is often important to be able to calculate the percentage change in a variable. For example, it may be that there is interest in calculating the rate of economic growth or in knowing how rapidly prices are changing. EXERCISE 8.3 Table 8.1 provides data on real GDP in the USA for the period 2005–18. Calculate the growth rate of GDP for each year from 2005/06 to 2017/18. Calculate your answers to 2 decimal places. In which year was growth at its highest and in which year was it at its lowest? ▼ Table 8.1 Real GDP in the USA, 2005–18 ($ trillion) 2005 14.333 2006 14.742 2007 15.018 2008 14.998 2009 14.617 2010 14.992 2011 15.225 2012 15.567 2013 15.854 2014 16.243 2015 16.710 2016 16.972 2017 17.349 2018 17.856 SUMMARY: MEASURING ECONOMIC GROWTH » Actual economic growth is measured as the percentage rate of change of real GDP or real GNI over time. » Potential economic growth is more difficult to measure, as economies are not always operating at full capacity. » It is important to use data for real GDP as this takes into account the effect of changing prices. Looking at the rate of change of nominal GDP or GNI would be misleading. 117 308275_C08_CAM_IASAL ECO_114_124.indd 117 17/02/21 10:42 AM 8 8.3 Causes of economic growth KEY TERMS AS LEVEL PART 4 THE MACROECONOMY productivity: a measure of the efficiency of a factor of production labour productivity: a measure of output per worker, or output per hour worked capital productivity: a measure of output per unit of capital total factor productivity: the average productivity of all factors, measured as the total output divided by the total amount of inputs used investment: expenditure undertaken by firms on capital goods depreciation (of capital equipment): the fall in the value of capital goods due to wear and tear gross investment: net investment plus depreciation net investment: investment net of the replacement of existing capital (depreciation) STUDY TIP Always be careful not to confuse these two different meanings of ‘investment’. Test yourself 8.5 Name the two key ways in which productive capacity can increase. Test yourself 8.6 What is the difference between gross and net investment? At a basic level, production arises from the use of factors of production – capital, labour, enterprise and so on. Capacity output is reached when all factors of production are fully and efficiently utilised. From this perspective, an increase in capacity output can come either from an increase in the quantity of the factors of production, or from an improvement in their efficiency or productivity. Productivity is a measure of the efficiency of a factor of production. For example, labour productivity measures output per worker, or output per hour worked. The latter is the more helpful measure, as clearly total output is affected by the number of hours worked, which varies somewhat across countries. Capital productivity measures output per unit of capital. Total factor productivity refers to the average productivity of all factors, measured as the total output divided by the total amount of inputs used. An increase in productivity raises long-run aggregate supply and the potential capacity output of an economy, and contributes to economic growth. Capital Capital is a critical factor in the production process. An increase in capital input is therefore one source of economic growth. In order for capital to accumulate and increase the capacity of the economy to produce, investment needs to take place. Notice that in economics ‘investment’ is used in this specific way. In everyday language, the term is sometimes used to refer to investing in shares or putting money into a deposit account at the bank. Do not confuse these different concepts. In economics, ‘investment’ relates to a firm buying new capital, such as machinery or factory buildings. If you put money into a bank account, that is an act of saving, not investment. In the national income accounts, the closest measurement that economists have to investment is ‘gross fixed capital formation’. This covers net additions to the capital stock, but it also includes depreciation. Some of the machinery and other capital purchased by firms is to replace old, worn-out capital: that is, to offset depreciation. It does not therefore represent an addition to capital stock. As depreciation cannot be observed easily, the convention in the accounts is to measure gross investment (i.e. including depreciation) and then make an adjustment for depreciation to arrive at net investment. Society has to decide between using resources for current consumption and using resources for investment. Investment entails sacrificing present consumption in order to have more resources available in the future. Different countries give investment very different priorities. Something of this can be seen in Figure 8.4, which shows gross fixed capital formation in a selection of countries around the world in 2018. The diversity is substantial, ranging from just 12.5% in Zimbabwe to 42.3% in China. Given this high rate of investment, it is perhaps not surprising to discover that China is among the fastest-growing economies in the world in the early twenty-first century – but it must also be remembered that there is a cost to this, as it means sacrificing present consumption in China. 118 308275_C08_CAM_IASAL ECO_114_124.indd 118 17/02/21 10:42 AM Nepal Pakistan Kenya Bangladesh Zimbabwe India Sri Lanka South Africa China Brazil Malaysia Korea New Zealand UAE UK Japan USA 8 10 20 30 40 50 % of GDP 8 Economic growth 0 Note: countries are in ascending order of GDP per capita. Source: based on data from World Development Indicators ▲ Figure 8.4 Gross fixed capital formation, 2018 QUANTITATIVE SKILLS 8.2 Calculating a percentage share As with this discussion of the share of investment in GDP, it is often useful to calculate how important a component of a total is within the whole by calculating the percentage share. For example, in China in 2018, gross fixed capital formation was $5,755.4 billion, and GDP was $13,608.2 billion. The percentage share is calculated as 100 × 5,755.4/13,608.2 = 42.3%. LEARNING LINK Ways in which we can compare living standards across countries (including the use of GDP or GNI per capita) are discussed in Chapter 30. QUANTITATIVE SKILLS 8.3 Interpreting bar graphs when the data have been ranked Notice that the data in Figure 8.4 have been ordered in ascending order of GDP per capita (i.e. with the lowest income countries at the top). GDP per capita is simply GDP divided by the size of population, so it is an estimate of the average GDP per person. This can be used to compare average incomes between countries. The rather jagged pattern shown in the figure is informative. If there had been a clear and smooth pattern, we might have concluded that there is a close correlation between average incomes and the proportion of GDP devoted to investment. However, this is clearly not the case for this selection of countries. The contribution of capital to growth is reinforced by technological progress, as the productivity of new capital is greater than that of old capital that is being phased out. For example, the speed and power of computers has increased enormously over recent years, which has had a great impact on productivity. Effectively, this means that technology is increasing the contribution that investment can make towards enlarging capacity output in an economy. 119 308275_C08_CAM_IASAL ECO_114_124.indd 119 17/02/21 10:42 AM AS LEVEL PART 4 THE MACROECONOMY 8 ▲ Improvements in the speed and power of computers have helped to increase productivity Innovation can also contribute, through the invention of new forms of capital and new ways of using existing capital, both of which can aid economic growth. Labour Capital has sometimes been seen as the main driver of growth, but labour too has a key contribution to make. There is little point in installing a lot of hi-tech equipment unless there is the skilled labour to operate it. KEY TERM human capital: the stock of skills and expertise that contribute to a worker’s productivity; it can be increased through education and training LEARNING LINK Merit goods are discussed in Chapters 1 and 5. There is relatively little scope for increasing the size of the labour force in a country, except through international migration. (Encouraging population growth is a rather long-term policy!) Nonetheless, the size of the workforce does contribute to the size of capacity output. A number of sub-Saharan African countries experienced this effect in reverse during the HIV/AIDS epidemic. The spread of this epidemic had a devastating impact in a number of countries in the region; at the peak of the epidemic the percentage of adults affected in some countries rose to over 30% – nearly 40% in Botswana. It is estimated that by 2018 the disease had caused the deaths of some 32 million people worldwide. This had a serious impact on capacity output in the affected countries because the disease affects people of working age disproportionately, diminishing the size of the workforce and the productivity of workers. The quality of labour input is more amenable to policy action. Education and training can improve the productivity of workers, and can be regarded as a form of investment in human capital. If individuals do not perceive the full social benefits associated with education, training and certain kinds of healthcare, they may choose to invest less in these forms of human capital than is desirable from the perspective of society as a whole. This can be seen as a justification for viewing education and healthcare as merit goods. For many developing countries, the provision of healthcare and improved nutrition can be seen as additional forms of investment in human capital, since such investment can lead to future improvements in productivity. SUMMARY: CAUSES OF ECONOMIC GROWTH » Economic growth can stem from an increase in the inputs of factors of production, or from an improvement in their productivity: that is, the efficiency with which factors of production are utilised. » Investment contributes to growth by increasing the capital stock of an economy, although some investment is to compensate for depreciation. » The contribution of capital is reinforced by the effects of technological progress. » Labour is another critical factor of production that can contribute to economic growth: for instance, education and training can improve labour productivity. This is a form of human capital formation. 120 308275_C08_CAM_IASAL ECO_114_124.indd 120 17/02/21 8:49 PM 8.4 Consequences of economic growth For many people, economic growth is viewed as the most important indicator of an economy’s performance. Expanding the availability of resources in an economy enables the standard of living of a country’s citizens to increase. For low-income countries this may facilitate the easing of poverty, and may allow investment in human capital that will improve standards of living further in the future. In the industrial economies, populations have come to expect steady improvements in incomes and resources. 8 Economic growth Many economies enjoyed a period of steady economic growth during the 2000s, but the onset of financial crisis in the late 2000s brought a significant slowdown in the growth of GDP. The concerns raised by this period highlight the negative consequences when economic growth does not occur, and the importance of this key variable. If the negative impact of the financial crisis was bad, the onset of the Covid-19 pandemic in 2020 brought economic growth to a complete standstill in countries all round the world. It will take time to assess the long-run effects of this pandemic. 8 % per annum Figure 8.5 shows the annual growth rates of real GDP since 2005 for a selection of countries. This shows that not all countries were equally affected by the financial crisis of the late 2000s. The UK, USA and Malaysia all experienced negative growth in 2008/09, but the other countries shown escaped the effects. The figure also shows the strong performance of China and India throughout this period. 15 10 5 China India Malaysia Pakistan UK 2018 2017 2016 2015 2014 2013 2012 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 –5 2005 0 USA Source: calculated using data from World Development Indicators ▲ Figure 8.5 Annual percentage growth rate of real GDP in selected countries since 2005 The benefits and costs of economic growth Even in periods of steady economic growth, there may be costs as well as benefits arising from economic growth. Economic growth in the long run entails an expansion of productive capacity, which in turn expands the resources available within the country. This means that standards of living can improve, together with healthcare provision and educational opportunities. This is the fundamental benefit of economic growth, allowing the country’s population to enjoy better living conditions and hopefully improving people’s morale. Growth can also mean higher employment – or improved employment opportunities and working conditions. People may also benefit from an improved environment and from advancing technology. From the government’s perspective, tax revenues may increase, allowing higher expenditure that further adds to the improvements in living standards. Economic growth also brings costs, perhaps most obviously in terms of pollution and degradation of the environment. In designing long-term policy for economic growth, governments need to be aware of the need to maintain a good balance 121 308275_C08_CAM_IASAL ECO_114_124.indd 121 17/02/21 10:42 AM AS LEVEL PART 4 THE MACROECONOMY 8 LEARNING LINK The impact of economic growth on the environment, and questions of whether economic growth can be sustainable in the long run, are explained in Chapter 25, which also explores inclusive growth and the effect growth may have on inequality. between enabling resources to increase and safeguarding the environment. Pollution reduces the quality of life, so pursuing economic growth without regard to this may be damaging. This means that it is important to consider the long-term effects of economic growth – it may even be important to consider the effects not only for today’s generation of citizens, but also for future generations. Although economic growth may expand the resources available, there is no guarantee that these will be evenly distributed among the population. If growth leads to higher concentration of income and wealth in a relatively small proportion of people, then inequality may increase. This may lead to increasing tension and even to civil conflict. EXTENSION MATERIAL Growth versus basic needs In some less developed countries the perspective may be different, and there has been a long-running debate about whether a society in its early stages of development should devote its resources to achieving the growth objective or to catering for basic needs. By making economic growth the prime target of policy, it may be necessary in the short run to allow inequality of incomes to continue, in order to provide the incentives for entrepreneurs to pursue growth. With such a ‘growth-first’ approach, it is argued that eventually, as growth takes place, the benefits will trickle down: in other words, growth is necessary in order to tackle poverty and provide for basic needs. However, others have argued that the first priority should be to deal with basic needs, so that people gain in human capital and become better able to contribute to the growth process. It is also important to realise that economic growth does not necessarily translate into improvements in living standards: for example, where the benefits from growth are concentrated in certain groups within a society, rather than being spread widely. SUMMARY: CONSEQUENCES OF ECONOMIC GROWTH » Economic growth is seen as one of the most important indicators of an economy’s performance. » Economic growth expands the availability of resources within a country, and enables an increase in the standard of living for the country’s citizens. » Periods of slowdown and recession highlight the importance that is attached to economic growth. » Economic growth can bring benefits to workers, firms and governments. » Economic growth may also impose costs on society by harming the environment or by increasing inequality in the distribution of income. END OF CHAPTER QUESTIONS Multiple choice 1 Potential growth can be illustrated on both a PPC diagram and an AS/AD diagram. Which of the following changes would represent potential growth on each diagram? A a rightward shift of the PPC and a rightward shift of the AD B a rightward shift of the PPC and an outward shift of the LRAS C a movement along the PPC and a rightward shift of the SRAS D a movement towards the PPC from a point within and an outward shift of the LRAS 122 308275_C08_CAM_IASAL ECO_114_124.indd 122 2 Which consequence of economic growth could have undesirable side-effects if the economy is approaching full employment? A higher average incomes B more efficient use of national resources C higher utilisation of the economy’s productive capacity D better quality of life 17/02/21 10:42 AM Data response 8 1 Read the following extract and then answer the questions that follow. Nepal: economic growth Earlier, the World Bank had projected Nepal’s economy to grow at 7.1%, primarily driven by private investment and consumption. The Asian Development Bank, on the other hand, had forecast Nepal’s economy to grow at 6.3%, stating that the country’s economy can only expand further if gross 10 fixed capital formation improves substantially. There are, however, two sides to any increase in economic growth that Nepal might enjoy. These include issues around benefits and costs at a national and individual level for the Nepalese people. 8 Economic growth 5 In early 2020 (before the Covid-19 pandemic), the Nepalese government revised the economic growth target for 2019/20 down by 1.49 percentage points to a 7.01% increase in GDP. The revised economic growth projection was primarily backed by anticipation of low agricultural growth in 2019/20 and government expenditure failing to gather pace. Table 8.2 shows GDP in Nepal between 2012 and 2018, and Figure 8.6 gives its 15 gross fixed capital formation between the same dates. ▼ Table 8.2 Nepal GDP (constant prices), 2012–18 Year GDP at constant prices (Nepalese rupees) 2012 699,727 2013 740,010 2014 770,055 2015 771,081 2016 837,241 2017 887,455 2018 950,033 350,000 300,000 250,000 200,000 150,000 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 100,000 Sources: tradingeconomics.com; Central Bureau of Statistics, Nepal ▲ Figure 8.6 Nepal real gross fixed capital formation, 2012–18 123 308275_C08_CAM_IASAL ECO_114_124.indd 123 17/02/21 10:42 AM a ‘…the Nepalese government revised the economic growth target for 2019/20 down by 1.49 percentage points to a 7.01% increase in GDP’ (lines 1–3). Distinguish between ‘actual’ and ‘potential’ economic growth and, using the information provided, suggest which is being referred to in lines 1–2. b Calculate the annual rate of change of GDP (constant prices) in Nepal between 2017 and 2018. c Table 8.2 presents GDP at ‘constant prices’. Explain the importance of using ‘real’ GDP data if the figures are to allow a meaningful discussion of economic growth in terms of the improved wellbeing of the people of Nepal. d i Explain the relationship you would expect between gross fixed capital formation and the level of real GDP. ii Consider the extent to which this relationship is evident in the data in Table 8.2 and Figure 8.6. e Discuss the view that the benefits of economic growth in Nepal will outweigh the costs. AS LEVEL PART 4 THE MACROECONOMY 8 CASE STUDY China’s economic growth Since China adopted market reforms in the late 1970s, its economy has enjoyed a period of rapid economic growth that is unprecedented by historical standards. One of the characteristics of this period of rapid growth has been the gradual move towards allowing market forces to operate after a long period of central planning. This would be expected to have benefits for the economy in terms of the efficiency of resource allocation. Although China’s success in achieving such rapid economic progress has been much admired, it has also been much criticised, for a number of reasons. One source of criticism centres on the environmental damage that results from a rapid rate of economic growth. A key ingredient of the growth process – especially in terms of industrialisation – is an expansion in energy supplies. Factories cannot operate without reliable electricity and other energy sources. Proposals to double China’s production of hydroelectric power caused concerns about the effects of new dams on river levels in downstream countries in Southeast Asia and in India. Air pollution has become a severe problem, with heavy smog levels in Beijing and other cities. The problem is not confined within China’s boundaries, and neighbours Japan and South Korea have suffered from pollution spreading from China into their territories. Booming car ownership raises further concerns: one estimate is that the number of cars in China had reached an estimated 240 million by 2018 (from just 4 million in 2000). This number continues to rise rapidly, and China is the largest car producer in the world. The effect of this on the demand for oil has already been reflected in higher world prices – China is already the world’s second biggest oil importer ▲ Hydroelectric power production in China (behind the USA). China is also the world’s biggest producer of coal, which accounts for some 80% of China’s energy use. All of this means that China has now overtaken the USA as the largest emitter of carbon dioxide. It seems unlikely that environmental damage on this sort of scale is sustainable from a global perspective. During the Covid-19 pandemic, large reductions in air pollution in China were reported as traffic fell and industries scaled back their production. Follow-up questions a Explain why a move towards a market-based system would be expected to ‘have benefits for the economy in terms of the efficiency of resource allocation’. b How can the problems caused when pollution crosses international borders be tackled? c Discuss whether China should seek to restrain the growing car ownership that is a by-product of rapid economic growth, which has led to rising real incomes. 124 308275_C08_CAM_IASAL ECO_114_124.indd 124 17/02/21 8:51 PM AS LEVEL PART 4 The macroeconomy 9 Unemployment ★ the meaning of unemployment ★ how unemployment is measured, and some of the difficulties in so doing ★ the causes and types of unemployment ★ the consequences of unemployment 9 Unemployment What this chapter covers Full employment is a key macroeconomic objective. The existence of high unemployment suggests that the economy is not operating at full capacity, but some kinds of unemployment will always be present in a dynamic economy. This chapter explores the nature of employment and unemployment, and examines some of the problems in measuring unemployment as well as setting out the causes and consequences of this important indicator. 9.1 The meaning and measurement of unemployment From society’s point of view, surplus capacity in the economy represents waste. In the macroeconomic policy arena, attention in this context focuses on unemployment, although there may also be situations in which capital is underutilised. There are two ways in which we can view underutilisation of resources in an economy. The production possibility curve (PPC) shows the maximum combinations of goods that can be produced in an economy. If an economy is producing within the PPC, it is not fully employing all of its resources (labour, capital or other factor inputs). LEARNING LINK Chapter 26 discusses this situation at more length and defines what is meant by full employment. KEY TERM working population: all people between the ages of 16 and 64 In the AD/AS model, a leftward shift in aggregate demand leads to a movement along the short-run aggregate supply curve, so that real GDP falls below what we have referred to as the full-employment level. This means that there will be some unemployment in the short run, which will last until the economy returns to its equilibrium. Under Keynesian assumptions, the adjustment process could be slow, and the impact on real GDP relatively large. It is also important to be aware that there will always be some unemployment in labour markets, even when the economy is at ‘full employment’. The way in which people earn a living is an important aspect of any economy. One measure on which governments are judged is whether people who want to work can find jobs – and find jobs that are appropriate to their talents and training. In order to evaluate this, it is necessary to explore the composition of the population, and the way in which unemployment is measured. The first step is to define the working population. In any society, there are individuals who are either too young or too old to work. The working population is defined as the number of people of working age – normally taken to be those aged between 16 and 64. Notice that the minimum and maximum ages at which people may work vary between countries. Indeed, in a number of high-income countries, the retirement age is being increased. 125 308275_C09_CAM_IASAL ECO_125_133.indd 125 17/02/21 10:58 AM AS LEVEL PART 4 THE MACROECONOMY 9 KEY TERMS workforce: people who are economically active – either in employment or unemployed employed (in employment): people who are either working for firms or other organisations, or selfemployed economically inactive: those people of working age who are not looking for work, for a variety of reasons discouraged workers: people who have been unable to find employment and who are no longer looking for work unemployed: people who are economically active but not in employment Among those people of working age, there may be some who choose not to participate in work. The participation rate measures the percentage of the working population who choose to join the labour force or workforce, by becoming economically active. The participation rate varies significantly between countries, and between males and females. Female participation rates tend to be lower than for males, partly because of childcare responsibilities, but also because of cultural differences between societies. Those people who are in the workforce fall into three economic categories: the employed, the unemployed and the economically inactive. Those in employment in this context include both those who are employed by firms or other organisations (such as government) and also the self-employed. The economically inactive include students, and those who have retired, are sick or are looking after family members. Also included are discouraged workers – people who have failed to find work and have given up looking. In other words, the economically inactive category includes all those people in the age range who are not considered to be active in the workforce. The unemployed are those who are in the workforce, but who are without jobs. Figure 9.1 shows how the people in the 16–64 age group in the UK were distributed between the three key economic categories in 2019. Economically inactive, including students, retired, sick, carers, discouraged workers, 8.566 m, 21% Unemployed,1.284 m, 3% Employed, 31.486 m, 76% Source: based on data from ONS (UK) Test yourself 9.1 ▲ Figure 9.1 The structure of the UK population aged 16–64 years, 2019 Would the unemployed be classified as being economically active or inactive? In this context, the unemployment rate is defined as the percentage of the labour force that is unemployed. In order to be able to measure the unemployment rate, it is necessary to count the number of people who are in the labour force and the number of people who are unemployed. The International Labour Organization (ILO) has recommended a definition of unemployment to be used for measurement across countries. The ILO measure captures three key characteristics. A person is defined as unemployed if they are: » without work » available for work » seeking work Historically in the UK, unemployment was measured by the so-called claimant count of unemployment, which simply counted the number of people registered as unemployed and claiming unemployment benefit (the Jobseeker’s Allowance (JSA)). One of the problems with the claimant count is that although people claiming the JSA must declare that they are available for work, it nonetheless includes some people who are claiming benefit, but are not actually available or prepared to work. It also 126 308275_C09_CAM_IASAL ECO_125_133.indd 126 17/02/21 10:58 AM KEY TERM ILO unemployment rate: measure of the percentage of the workforce who are without jobs, but are available for work, willing to work and looking for work excludes some people who would like to work, and who are looking for work, but who are not eligible for unemployment benefit, such as women returning to the labour force after childbirth. It defines as being unemployed those people who are: ‘without a job, want a job, have actively sought work in the last four weeks and are available to start work in the next two weeks; or out of work, have found a job and are waiting to start it in the next two weeks’ (Labour Market Statistics). Notice that in order to measure the percentage unemployment rate, data on the number of people employed is also required, as the unemployment rate is defined as the percentage of the workforce who are unemployed. 9 Unemployment Because of these problems, the claimant count does not meet the ILO definition, so it has been replaced for official purposes by the ILO unemployment rate, a measure based on the Labour Force Survey. This identifies the number of people available for work, and seeking work, but without a job. This definition corresponds to that used by the ILO, and is closer to what economists would like unemployment to measure. 9 QUANTITATIVE SKILLS 9.1 Calculating the percentage rate of unemployment When calculating the percentage rate of unemployment, the key question concerns the portion of the active workforce who are unemployed at any point in time. This is calculated by expressing the number of unemployed as a percentage of the active workforce (i.e. employed plus unemployed). In the UK in the last quarter of 2019 it was estimated that there were 31.637 million people in employment and 1.257 people unemployed. The percentage rate was thus: 100 × 1.257 ÷ (31.637 + 1.257) = 3.82%. STUDY TIP The relevant formulae used in this context are as follows: Working population = economically active + economically inactive (aged between 16 and 64) Workforce = economically active = employed + unemployed Employed = those working for firms + self-employed Participation rate = 100 × economically active/working population Unemployment rate = 100 × unemployed/workforce EXERCISE 9.1 In Greece in 2019, there were 6,935,000 people aged between 15 and 64. Of these, 3,945,000 were employed and 2,205,000 were economically inactive. Calculate the number of people in this age bracket who were unemployed and the percentage unemployment rate. Figure 9.2 shows the percentage unemployment rate for selected countries since 2005. Notice that unemployment in the high-income countries (the UK, USA and New Zealand) increased appreciably during the financial crisis of the late 2000s, but the other countries were relatively unaffected. 127 308275_C09_CAM_IASAL ECO_125_133.indd 127 17/02/21 10:58 AM % of workforce 9 12 China India New Zealand Pakistan Sri Lanka UK USA 10 8 4 2 2019 2018 2017 2016 2015 2014 2013 2012 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 0 2005 AS LEVEL PART 4 THE MACROECONOMY 6 Source: based on data from World Development Indicators ▲ Figure 9.2 Unemployment rate, selected countries Comparing unemployment across countries can be problematic, even when a standard definition is adopted. Recall that two key things need to be counted in order to measure the unemployment rate – the number of people in the workforce and the number of people who are unemployed. It may not always be straightforward to count either of these things. In particular, if there is no provision for unemployment benefit in a country, then there is no possibility of counting those who register as unemployed – because they have no incentive to do so. It is then necessary to rely on a survey in order to be able to count the number of unemployed – and the number of people in the workforce. Such surveys are expensive, and more difficult to undertake in a country that covers a large geographic area, and in which there may be remote rural areas to be covered. Furthermore, there are some countries in which there remains substantial subsistence agriculture and a large informal sector. The informal economy covers largely unregulated economic activity, which is widespread in many less developed countries. In this context, the number of people classified as economically inactive would be potentially much higher and the reliability of data may be expected to vary between countries. A further cause of difficulty in interpreting unemployment as an indicator of underutilisation of labour is that the data may conceal the extent to which labour is underused, even when some individual workers are employed. In some cases, there may be workers who would like to work for longer hours, but can only find parttime jobs. In other cases, there may be workers who cannot find employment in the occupation for which their skills have prepared them. For example, a university graduate may find him or herself driving a taxi or sweeping the streets. The notion of a full-employment level of real GDP was introduced in Chapter 7 in the context of the AD/AS model. The full-employment level of real GDP corresponds to a situation in which the economy is operating at its full capacity level, utilising its resources (including workers) effectively. However, does this mean that everyone should have a job or be self-employed? Setting aside those who are economically inactive, there will always be some unemployment in a society, if only because there will be some people between jobs, or engaging in job searching. Furthermore, if the economy were to be operating very close to full capacity, this would be likely to put upward pressure on wages and thus prices. 128 308275_C09_CAM_IASAL ECO_125_133.indd 128 17/02/21 10:58 AM LEARNING LINK 9 So full employment does not mean that unemployment will be zero. But it is difficult to specify a particular percentage that would constitute full employment. This may vary in different periods, and in different countries, partly reflecting the degree of flexibility in the labour market. SUMMARY: THE MEANING AND MEASUREMENT OF UNEMPLOYMENT 9 Unemployment The possibility of there being trade-offs or conflicts between macroeconomic variables and policy objectives is discussed in Chapter 28. In other words, there may be a conflict between achieving full employment and maintaining the stability of prices. » Underutilisation of resources in an economy can be seen when production Test yourself 9.2 » Why will unemployment not be zero if there is full employment? » » » » » » takes place within the PPC or when real GDP is below the full-employment level in the AD/AS model. The working population in a country is the number of people between the ages of 16 and 64. At any time, only a proportion of these are economically active, and these make up the workforce. The ILO defines unemployment as those people who are without work, are available for work and are seeking work. The unemployment rate is measured by the percentage of the workforce who meet these conditions. A number of difficulties may arise in comparing unemployment rates across countries. Measurement depends on surveys, and countries may differ in the extent to which individuals are classified as being economically inactive. There may also be disguised unemployment where people are employed for fewer hours than they would like, or are employed in occupations for which they are overqualified. 9.2 Causes of unemployment Frictional unemployment KEY TERM frictional unemployment: unemployment associated with job search: that is, people who are between jobs There will always be some unemployment in a dynamic economy. At any point in time, there will be workers transferring between jobs. This may occur simply because an individual wishes to improve their job prospects, and needs to spend time searching for a new job. Accordingly, there will be some unemployment while this transfer takes place, and this is known as frictional unemployment. Searching may take some time if information about the availability of jobs is not good. Structural unemployment In a typical period of time there will be some sectors of an economy that are expanding and others that are in decline. This happens when the pattern of production changes in order to keep up with changing patterns of consumer demand and relative opportunity cost. In this case, it is important that workers are able to transfer from those activities that are in decline to those that are booming. For example, coal mining may be on the decline in an economy, but international banking may be booming. It is clearly unreasonable to expect coal miners to turn themselves into international bankers overnight. In this sort of situation there may be some longerterm unemployment while workers retrain for new occupations and new sectors of activity. Indeed, there may be workers who find themselves redundant at a relatively late stage in their career and for whom the retraining is not worthwhile, or who cannot find firms that will be prepared to train them for a relatively short payback 129 308275_C09_CAM_IASAL ECO_125_133.indd 129 17/02/21 10:58 AM AS LEVEL PART 4 THE MACROECONOMY 9 KEY TERMS structural unemployment: unemployment arising because of changes in the pattern of economic activity within an economy technological unemployment: unemployment that arises when workers do not have the skills needed to work with newly developed technology cyclical unemployment: unemployment that arises during the downturn of the economic cycle, such as a recession seasonal unemployment: unemployment that arises in seasons of the year when demand is relatively low time. Such unemployment is known as structural unemployment. It arises because of the mismatch between the skills of workers leaving contracting sectors and the skills required by expanding sectors in the economy. Technological unemployment Technological unemployment is a type of structural unemployment that arises from the introduction of technology, when existing workers do not have the skills to operate the new technology. Cyclical unemployment Economies can be subject to fluctuations in real GDP around an underlying trend. In the AD/AS model, this would be reflected in movements along the short-run aggregate supply curve, with the economy sometimes rising above the full-employment level of real GDP, and at other times falling below it. If real GDP does fall below the fullemployment level, then unemployment is likely to be present during the period when the economy is adjusting back to its long-run equilibrium. This is known as cyclical unemployment. Under Keynesian assumptions, this adjustment period may not be rapid. Seasonal unemployment There may also be times of the year when the demand for labour varies because of seasonal effects: for example, the tourist sector experiences quiet periods during the winter. This may give rise to seasonal unemployment. LEARNING LINK More discussion of the types and causes of unemployment can be found in Chapters 23 and 26. Test yourself 9.3 Migration and unemployment In Figure 9.2 you can see how unemployment in the UK, USA and New Zealand was affected in the recession that followed the financial crisis of 2008/09. What sort of unemployment was this? In some countries, a contentious issue in recent years has been the question of migration, and the effect of an inflow of migrants on a domestic labour market. From the point of view of economic analysis, this issue turns on the characteristics of immigrant workers, especially in relation to skills. If immigrant workers have skills that are complementary to those of native workers, then an inflow of migrants can have beneficial effects on the domestic economy, by raising national income, resulting in an increase in the demand for workers. The situation is different where migrants are substitutes for domestic workers, such that the result may be a decrease in the equilibrium wage, and an increase in unemployment among native workers. EXERCISE 9.2 Classify each of the following types of unemployment as arising from frictional, structural or other causes. a Unemployment arising from a decline of the manufacturing sector and the expansion of financial services b A worker leaving one job to search for a better one c Unemployment that occurs when real GDP falls below the full-employment level as part of the regular fluctuations that occur in the level of economic activity d Unemployment of workers in the tourist sector during the winter months e Unemployment arising because workers do not have the appropriate skills to service new and unfamiliar machinery 130 308275_C09_CAM_IASAL ECO_125_133.indd 130 17/02/21 10:58 AM SUMMARY: CAUSES OF UNEMPLOYMENT » Unemployment can arise for a number of reasons, in some cases when the 9 economy is at full employment. » Structural unemployment arises because of changes in the pattern of 9.3 Consequences of unemployment 9 Unemployment economic activity within an economy. » Technological unemployment arises when workers do not have the skills needed to work with newly developed technology. » Cyclical unemployment arises during the downturn of the economic cycle, such as a recession. » Seasonal unemployment arises in seasons of the year when demand is relatively low. Perhaps the most obvious consequence of unemployment is the costs it imposes on prospective workers, in terms of forgone earnings and the need to rely on social security support (if it is available). At the same time, the inability to find work and to contribute to the family budget may impose a cost in terms of personal worth and dignity. From society’s perspective, if the economy is operating below full capacity, then it is operating within the PPC, and therefore is not making the best possible use of society’s resources. In other words, if those unemployed workers were in employment, society would be producing more aggregate output; the economy would be operating more efficiently overall. Test yourself 9.4 Why might structural unemployment be more persistent than some other types of unemployment? When unemployment is high, the government will raise less tax revenue in the form of income tax, but will face higher expenditure in the form of social security payments. Firms will be unable to sell as much output as previously, so will make lower profits. In addition, when unemployment is rising and aggregate demand is falling, there will be negative knock-on effects, so other workers will suffer, either by becoming unemployed, or by having to work fewer hours. Long-term unemployment has potentially important social effects. Workers who are unemployed for a long period will become dispirited and deskilled, and thus find it increasingly difficult to get back into the workforce. A by-product of this may be an increase in crime and vandalism or social unrest, imposing costs on other members of society. Frictional unemployment, on the other hand, may have beneficial effects. When workers are able to find better jobs, this leads to an improvement in the overall efficiency of production, and could potentially improve allocative efficiency. SUMMARY: CONSEQUENCES OF UNEMPLOYMENT » Unemployment imposes costs on those workers who are unable to find work. » From society’s perspective, unemployment may be seen as a loss of potential output if the economy is operating below its full capacity. » Governments will raise less tax revenue when there is unemployment, and may face higher expenditure in the form of social security payments. » Long-term unemployment imposes higher costs, as workers may become deskilled, and may find it difficult to get back into work. » Frictional unemployment may have beneficial effects by allowing workers to transfer between jobs. 131 308275_C09_CAM_IASAL ECO_125_133.indd 131 17/02/21 10:58 AM END OF CHAPTER QUESTIONS AS LEVEL PART 4 THE MACROECONOMY 9 Multiple choice 1 An economy is going through a process of industrialisation. Which type of unemployment is present? A frictional B structural C cyclical D regional 2 Which consequences of unemployment can be considered as benefits to the employers and to the unemployed individuals? Benefit to employers Benefit to unemployed individuals A Larger pool of job applicants Abundant job opportunities B Lower recruitment costs The opportunity to find a better-paid job C Lower training costs Lower stress levels D Acquisition of new skills More free time Data response 1 Read the following extract and then answer the questions that follow. Unemployment in selected countries 5 In the three decades to 2020, Bangladesh experienced a steady transformation. The economy moved from traditional primary-based activities to modern secondary and tertiary sector-related production. In 1991, agriculture contributed approximately 70% of GDP, which had slumped to around 40% of GDP by 2019. The shares of secondary and tertiary sectors of total employment increased to 20% and 40% respectively from 13% and 17% during the period 1991–2019. In April 2020, Spain had an unemployment rate of 14.8% calculated by the International Labour Organization method. The youth unemployment rate in 10 Spain (15- to 24-year-olds) was far higher at 33.2% and looking forward it was expected to increase further to 34.7% by April 2021. This rate is relatively high by international standards – the forecast for the average G20* youth unemployment rate in 2021 was 13.94%. Long-term unemployment refers to people who have been unemployed for 15 12 months or more. Italy, South Africa and Greece suffer some of the worst long-term unemployment rates with 59%, 62% and 70% respectively of those unemployed having been out of work for more than 1 year. *A group of finance ministers and central bank governors from 19 of the world’s largest economies along with the European Union. ▼ Table 9.1 Labour force status in Norway (April 2020) Employed persons Absolute numbers Unemployed persons Absolute numbers Males 1,445,000 Males 57,000 Females 1,283,000 Females 46,000 132 308275_C09_CAM_IASAL ECO_125_133.indd 132 17/02/21 10:58 AM CASE STUDY The cost of unemployment By setting full employment as a key objective of macroeconomic policy, there is an underlying presumption that unemployment is a bad thing. But what are the costs associated with unemployment? From society’s point of view there are some obvious costs. If people are unemployed, they are not contributing to society’s output, so there is an opportunity cost in relation to the work that unemployed individuals could have been providing. High unemployment may create low morale, and therefore affect firms’ expectations of future demand for their products. If this is so, they may decide to invest less in expanding capacity, which would then affect the rate of economic growth. There may also be a social impact arising from a high rate of unemployment, as some commentators have pointed to the effect of unemployment on crime or social disorder. On the other hand, if unemployment is low, this could put pressure on prices, potentially resulting in inflation. It should also be remembered that it is important that the economy responds to changes in the economic environment. At any point in time, there are likely to be some activities that are in decline, and others that are expanding. This is the nature of a dynamic economy. The labour market thus needs to be sufficiently flexible to allow workers to transfer from declining to expanding sectors – even if this requires retraining and a period of unemployment. 9 9 Unemployment a Explain how the information contained in the extract (lines 1–7) could lead to structural unemployment. b Calculate, using the information in Table 9.1, the female unemployment rates in Norway in April 2020. c Explain one difficulty in calculating the International Labour Organization figure for unemployment. d Explain why longer-term unemployment in Italy, South Africa and Greece imposes higher costs on individuals than short-term unemployment. e Discuss, with reference to the information provided, the consequences of youth unemployment in Spain for the Spanish economy. There is also the issue of the costs that are incurred by the individuals who are unemployed. They may face not only loss of income and descent into relative poverty, but also a loss of dignity and the ability to contribute to society. In considering this, it is important to distinguish between different types of unemployment. Individuals may choose to be unemployed for various reasons. It could be that they simply want to find a better job than the one they have, or to join an expanding sector where they can be better paid. Of course, there may also be those who view the available social security benefits as being adequate for their needs, enabling them to enjoy more leisure. Unemployment may be of more concern when it involves people who would like to work but cannot find suitable employment. Even this may not be of major concern if the period for which they are unemployed is relatively short. Of most concern are those in this category who are unemployed for extended periods of time. Follow-up questions a Evaluate the consequences of unemployment from the point of view of society as a whole. b Discuss the extent to which society should be concerned about the situation facing individuals who are unemployed. 133 308275_C09_CAM_IASAL ECO_125_133.indd 133 17/02/21 10:58 AM AS LEVEL PART 4 The macroeconomy AS LEVEL PART 4 THE MACROECONOMY 10 Price stability What this chapter covers ★ reasons why price stability is important for an economy ★ inflation, deflation and disinflation ★ the interpretation of index numbers and how they are constructed KEY TERMS inflation: a sustained rise in the general price level, measured by the rate of change of the average price level in an economy over a period of time index number: a way of comparing the value of a variable with a base observation such as a location or past period (e.g. the consumer price index measures the average level of prices relative to a past year, known as a base period) ★ changes in the price level as estimated using a consumer price index ★ possible difficulties in measuring price changes ★ the causes of inflation through cost-push and demand-pull pressures ★ the consequences of inflation Inflation is one of the key indicators of macroeconomic performance, and its control has been a primary objective of governments. This chapter explores what is meant by inflation, how it is calculated and why price stability is so important. 10.1 Price stability and the measurement of inflation Economic growth is often seen as the most fundamental objective of economic policy. However, successive governments in many parts of the world have made stability of prices a fundamental objective of macroeconomic policy. Inflation occurs when there is a sustained increase in the average price level in an economy. When looking to monitor whether the government of a country is achieving stability of prices, the question is therefore whether inflation is being kept under control. Deflation occurs when there is a fall in the general price level. The main reason why inflation is seen as a key indicator of the performance of an economy is the fear that if inflation is high and volatile, firms will be deterred from undertaking investment, which would hinder economic growth. This is because firms base their investment plans on their expectations of the future. If inflation is high and volatile, it becomes more difficult to form reliable expectations about the future, or to be sure of the likely return on investment expenditure. To put this another way, it is believed that a stable macroeconomic environment is crucial if there is to be economic growth. 10.2 Measuring the price level and inflation If the control of inflation is to be a policy objective, some way of monitoring it is needed. The first step is therefore to measure the average level of prices in the economy. Inflation can then be calculated as the percentage rate of increase of prices over time. STUDY TIP If you are writing an essay, be careful not to claim that inflation is a policy objective of the government – it is low and stable inflation that is the objective! Index numbers In setting out to measure the general level of prices in an economy, there is no obvious way of producing a meaningful ‘average’ price. The solution is to use index numbers, a form of ratio that compares the value of a variable with some base point. For example, suppose the price of a kilo of oranges last year was $0.80, and this year it is $0.84. How can the price between the two periods be compared? One way of doing it is to calculate the percentage change: 100 × (84 – 80) ÷ 80 = 5% 134 308275_C10_CAM_IASAL ECO_134_145.indd 134 2/17/21 1:27 PM LEARNING LINK The calculation of a percentage change is discussed in Quantitative skills 8.1 on page 117. (Note that this is the formula for calculating any growth rate in percentage terms. The change in the variable is always expressed as a percentage of the initial value, not the final value.) QUANTITATIVE SKILLS 10.1 Creating an index number If a bundle of goods costs 4% higher in year 2 than in year 1, what would be the value of an index for year 2 based on year 1 = 100? 10 Price stability A way of showing how prices have changed is to calculate an index number. In the above example, the current value of the index could be calculated as the current value divided by the base value, multiplied by 100. In other words, this would be 100 × 84 ÷ 80 = 105. The resulting number gives the current value relative to the base value. This turns out to be a useful way of expressing a range of economic variables where you want to show the value relative to a base period. Index numbers can also be used to compare between regions or to compare variables measured in different units – anything where you want to compare with some base level. Test yourself 10.1 10 This technique is used to show the average level of prices at different points in time. If the aim is to see how changing prices are affecting consumers, the first step is to select a representative bundle of goods and services that the average consumer purchases in a period. Of course, some goods and services will be more important in a household’s budget than others, so when calculating the average, some products must have a higher weight than others. For example, in January 2020 in the UK, ‘Food’ counted for 71 per 1,000 of household spending, compared with 9 per 1,000 for footwear. These weights reflect the relative importance of different goods and services when calculating the average cost of the bundle of goods and services, which is intended to capture the pattern of spending by a representative household in the UK. The cost of that bundle can be calculated in a base year, and then in subsequent years. The cost in the base year is set to equal 100, and in subsequent years the index is measured relative to that base date, thereby reflecting the change in prices since then. For example, if in the second year the average increase in prices were 2.5%, then the index in year 2 would take on the value 102.5 (based on year 1 = 100). Such a general index of prices would give the level of prices faced by the average household relative to the base year. Notice that there is a crucial distinction between such measurements of the general price level and the notion of inflation, which is a key economic indicator frequently discussed in the media. A price index such as those described above measures the average level of prices at a particular moment in time. Inflation, on the other hand, is the rate of increase of the price index – it measures the rate at which prices are increasing through time. These two different things should not be confused with each other, although clearly they are related. In any economy, prices of different goods and services change at different rates through time. This is partly in response to changes in demand and supply – if a good becomes popular, excess demand will tend to push up the price of the good as the market moves to a new equilibrium, while some other goods may face the opposite effect so that prices rise less steeply. A price index designed to represent the general level of prices in an economy is based on taking a weighted average of individual prices, as described above. With prices changing at different rates, the choice of which goods and services to include in the index – and with what weights – is an important step. For example, it is likely that different groups in a society choose to consume different combinations of goods and services, so may experience inflation at different rates. Furthermore, the content of the representative bundle is likely to change over time, so the weights must be regularly updated. 135 308275_C10_CAM_IASAL ECO_134_145.indd 135 2/17/21 1:27 PM The consumer price index 10 A consumer price index is therefore designed to capture the changes in the general level of prices of goods and services that households buy (or use) for consumption purposes. The International Monetary Fund (IMF) publishes a manual for National Statistical Offices explaining good practice in the compilation of an index, and collates data from member countries. AS LEVEL PART 4 THE MACROECONOMY KEY TERM consumer price index (CPI): a measure of the general level of prices; in the UK, this was adopted as the government’s inflation target in December 2003 LEARNING LINK Another use of a price index is to adjust a data series from nominal into real terms. This is explained in Chapter 6, where it was noted that real GDP is calculated as nominal GDP divided by an appropriate price index. STUDY TIP As noted in the previous section, it is important to remember that the CPI provides a measurement of the level of prices in the economy. This is not inflation: inflation is the rate of change of prices, and the percentage change in the CPI provides an estimate of the inflation rate. In the UK the consumer price index (CPI), which has been used by the government in setting its inflation target since the beginning of 2004, is compiled in line with the IMF recommendation. This index is based on the prices of a bundle of goods and services measured at different points in time. A total of 180,000 individual price quotes on more than 700 different products are collected by the Office for National Statistics (ONS) each month, by visits to shops, and using the telephone and internet. Data on spending from Household Final Monetary Consumption Expenditure is used to compile the weights for the items included in the index. These weights are updated each year, as changes in the consumption patterns of households need to be accommodated if the index is to remain representative. EXERCISE 10.1 Table 10.1 provides data on consumer prices for Malaysia, Pakistan and Sri Lanka. ▼ Table 10.1 Consumer prices Consumer price index (2011=100) Malaysia Pakistan Sri Lanka 2006 90.9 59.7 64.1 2007 92.8 64.2 74.2 2008 97.8 77.3 91.0 2009 98.4 87.8 94.1 2010 100.0 100.0 100.0 2011 103.2 111.9 106.7 2012 104.9 122.8 114.8 2013 107.1 132.2 122.7 2014 110.5 141.7 126.6 2015 112.8 145.3 131.4 2016 115.1 150.8 136.6 2017 119.6 156.9 147.1 2018 120.7 164.9 150.2 Source: MyOECD a Calculate the annual inflation rates for each of the countries from 2007 to 2018. b Plot these three inflation series on a graph against time. c By what percentage did prices increase in each country over the whole period – that is, between 2006 and 2018? d Which economy do you judge to have experienced most stability in the inflation rate? Alternative measurements of inflation The traditional measure of inflation in the UK for many years was the retail price index (RPI), which was first calculated (under another name) in the early twentieth century to evaluate the extent to which workers were affected by price changes during the First World War. This was later replaced by RPIX, which is the RPI excluding mortgage interest payments. 136 308275_C10_CAM_IASAL ECO_134_145.indd 136 2/17/21 1:27 PM The CPI replaced RPIX partly because it is believed to be a more appropriate indicator for evaluating policy effectiveness. In addition, it has the advantage of being calculated using the methodology recommended by the IMF, so that it is more useful than the RPIX for making international comparisons of inflation. The indexes share a common failing, arising from the fixed weights used in calculating the overall index. Suppose the price of a particular item rises more rapidly than other prices during the year. One response by consumers is to substitute an alternative, cheaper, product. As the indices are based on fixed weights, they do not pick up this substitution effect, and therefore tend to overstate the price level in terms of the cost of living. Some attempt is made to overcome this problem by changing the weights on an annual basis in order to limit the impact of major changes. This includes incorporating new items when appropriate in order to reflect changes in consumer spending patterns. 10 Price stability The CPI and RPI are based on a similar approach, although there are some significant differences in the detail of the calculation. Both measures set out to calculate the overall price level at different points in time. Each is based on calculating the overall cost of a representative basket of goods and services at different points in time relative to a base period. Both are produced from the same raw data, but use different formulae to produce the index. The result of these calculations is an index that shows how the general level of prices has changed relative to the base year. The rate of inflation is then calculated as the percentage rate of change of the price index, whether it be the CPI or the RPI. 10 The CPI and RPI differ for a number of reasons, partly because of differences in the content of the basket of goods and services that are included, and partly in terms of the population of people who are covered by the index. For example, in calculating the weights, the RPI excludes pensioner households and the highest-income households, whereas the CPI does not. There are also some other differences in the ways that the calculations are carried out. Figure 10.1 shows data for the rates of change of the CPI and RPI since January 2008. These rates have been calculated on a monthly basis, computing the percentage rate of change of each index relative to the value 12 months previously. Calculating the inflation rate in this way smooths out the effect of seasonal variations. Test yourself 10.2 % change over 12 months Give reasons why pensioner households might display a different pattern of consumption than other households. A noticeable characteristic of Figure 10.1 is that for much of the period the CPI has shown a lower rate of change than the RPI. In part this reflects the way in which the prices are combined, but it also reflects the fact that different items and households are covered. The large drop in the RPI in 2009 reflects the substantial fall in interest rates at this time, which affected mortgage interest rates, which are not included in the CPI. In early 2020 you can see the early effects of the Covid-19 pandemic. 6.0 CPI 5.0 RPI Target rate 4.0 3.0 2.0 1.0 0.0 2020 Jan 2019 Jul 2019 Jan 2018 Jul 2018 Jan 2017 Jul 2017 Jan 2016 Jul 2016 Jan 2015 Jul 2015 Jan 2014 Jul 2014 Jan 2013 Jul 2013 Jan 2012 Jul 2012 Jan 2011 Jul 2011 Jan 2010 Jul 2010 Jan 2009 Jul 2009 Jan 2008 Jul –2.0 2008 Jan –1.0 Source: based on data from ONS (UK) ▲ Figure 10.1 Alternative inflation measures in the UK since 2008 137 308275_C10_CAM_IASAL ECO_134_145.indd 137 2/17/21 1:27 PM 10 Deflation and disinflation KEY TERMS deflation: a fall in the average level of prices AS LEVEL PART 4 THE MACROECONOMY disinflation: a fall in the rate of inflation Test yourself 10.3 If the rate of change of prices decelerates but remains positive, would this be described as deflation or disinflation? STUDY TIP Be careful not to confuse falling prices (deflation) with falling inflation (disinflation). Falling inflation just means that prices are rising less quickly than before. The recession that began to affect many advanced economies in the late 2000s raised the possibility that the overall level of prices in an economy might fall. This situation of negative inflation is known as deflation. This can occur when there is a substantial fall in aggregate demand, leading to recession. Figure 10.1 showed that the UK experienced falling prices according to the RPI for a period. This is not to be confused with disinflation, which refers to a period in which inflation falls relative to the previous period: in other words, a period in which inflation decelerates. Japan experienced periods of deflation between 1999 and 2005, and again in 2009–12. Figure 10.1 shows UK inflation falling at the beginning of the Covid-19 pandemic in early 2020, but up to August 2020 this was disinflation rather than deflation, as prices were not actually falling; the rate of price increases was just decelerating. Deflation is perceived to be bad for the economy on the grounds that economic agents will see this as a sign that the economy is in terminal decline. If people expect prices to continue to fall, they may postpone purchases in the expectation of being able to buy at a lower price in the future. Deflation may also affect the confidence of firms when forming expectations about the future, so they may reduce their expenditure on investment. This would then mean a fall in aggregate demand in the economy, and a movement down along the short-run aggregate supply curve. Firms that receive lower prices for their goods may reduce the size of their workforce, so unemployment may rise. If expectations remain low, this could delay the adjustment back to full employment. EXERCISE 10.2 Table 10.2 shows annual inflation in the UK between 2007 and 2011, as measured by changes in the RPI. Identify years in which there was inflation, deflation and disinflation. ▼ Table 10.2 RPI inflation in the UK, 2007–11 RPI inflation 2007 4.3 2008 4.0 2009 –0.5 2010 4.6 2011 5.2 Hyperinflation KEY TERM hyperinflation: a situation in which inflation reaches extreme or excessive rates When inflation gets completely out of control, a situation of hyperinflation may arise. When inflation is running at an extreme or excessive rate, the associated costs can also be extreme. Hyperinflation has been rare in high-income countries in recent years, although many Latin American economies were prone to hyperinflation for a period in the 1980s, and some of the transition economies also went through periods of very high inflation as they began to introduce market reforms; one example of this was Ukraine, where inflation reached 10,000% per year in the early 1990s. Another example is the African country of Zimbabwe, where The Economist in April 2013 claimed that inflation had reached 230,000,000% in 2008. Inflation around the world Economies have experienced inflation to varying degrees in the past. Figure 10.2 shows how inflation has affected the world in the period since 1972, and how advanced and developing economies were affected in different ways. 138 308275_C10_CAM_IASAL ECO_134_145.indd 138 2/17/21 1:27 PM % change in prices (p.a.) 120 Advanced economies Emerging and developing economies World 10 100 80 60 40 20 2018 2016 2014 2012 2010 2008 2006 2004 2002 2000 1998 1996 1994 1992 1990 1988 1986 1982 1984 1980 1978 1976 1972 1974 Source: based on data from IMF ▲ Figure 10.2 World inflation since 1972 (% change in consumer prices) 10 Price stability 0 For the world as a whole, inflation had been steady (below 10% per year) through most of the 1960s until the mid-1970s, when there was an acceleration following the first oil-price crisis in 1973–74. Average inflation then remained relatively high until the period of relative stability in the late 1990s and early 2000s. The figure also shows that in the advanced economies, inflation decelerated relatively quickly from about 1980 onwards, with those countries showing inflation rates that were consistently lower than the world average. % change in prices (p.a.) In part, this was a regional phenomenon, with Latin America being especially prone to very high inflation during this period, even hyperinflation in some countries. This can be seen in Figure 10.3, which contrasts inflation in Latin America (‘Western hemisphere’) with that in developing Asian economies and the world as a whole. Notice the scale of the vertical axis – in order to show average inflation across the Western hemisphere, the other series on the graph get compressed to the axis. Average inflation in the Western hemisphere peaked at 515% in 1990, but this conceals the wide variation in inflation between countries. In 1990, Argentina was experiencing inflation of 2,314% (down from 3,079% in 1989), Brazil was suffering 2,947% and Peru 7,482%. Bolivia had experienced inflation at 11,750% in 1985. 600 Emerging and developing Asia Western hemisphere World 500 400 300 200 100 2012 2010 2008 2006 2004 2002 2000 1998 1996 1994 1992 1990 1988 1986 1984 1982 1980 1978 1976 1974 1972 0 Source: based on data from IMF ▲ Figure 10.3 Inflation in Latin America and developing Asia In contrast, Figure 10.4 shows inflation in developing countries in Asia and in subSaharan Africa over the same period. Again, notice that the vertical scale of the graph has changed radically. The figure reveals that these countries in Asia experienced inflation below the world average for much of the period, although the spike at the time of the 1973–74 oil-price hike is more marked. Notice that countries in subSaharan Africa suffered from higher inflation from the 1990s onwards. 139 308275_C10_CAM_IASAL ECO_134_145.indd 139 2/17/21 1:27 PM % change in prices (p.a.) 10 45 Developing Asia 40 World sub-Saharan Africa 35 30 25 20 15 5 2012 2010 2008 2006 2004 2002 2000 1998 1996 1994 1992 1990 1988 1986 1984 1982 1980 1978 1976 1974 0 1972 AS LEVEL PART 4 THE MACROECONOMY 10 Source: based on data from IMF ▲ Figure 10.4 Inflation in developing Asia and sub-Saharan Africa SUMMARY: MEASURING THE PRICE LEVEL AND INFLATION » Inflation is the rate of change of the general level measure of the price level, and inflation is monitored through the rate of change of CPI. » Deflation is a situation in which prices fall, so there is a negative change in the price level. » Disinflation is where inflation decelerates. » When inflation reaches such high levels that it is out of control, there is hyperinflation. of prices in an economy. » Index numbers are helpful in comparing the value of a variable with a base date or unit, and are used to arrive at a measure of the average level of prices in an economy. » In December 2003 the UK government adopted the consumer price index (CPI) as its preferred 10.3 Causes of inflation Inflation occurs when there is a rise in the general price level. However, it is important to distinguish between a one-off increase in the price level and a sustained rise over a long period of time. Cost-push inflation Price level Suppose there is a one-off permanent rise in the price of oil. Such an increase means that firms face higher production costs, because oil is a key input. Therefore, this is one reason why prices may begin to increase. In the AD/AS model, this permanent change would be seen as a decrease in long-run aggregate supply. In Figure 10.5, aggregate supply moves from LRASFE0 to LRASFE1 and the price level rises from P0 to P1. Notice that real GDP falls from YFE0 to YFE1. LRASFE0 LRASFE1 P1 P0 AD 0 YFE1 YFE0 Real GDP t Figure 10.5 A decrease in long-run aggregate supply 140 308275_C10_CAM_IASAL ECO_134_145.indd 140 2/17/21 1:27 PM KEY TERMS cost-push inflation: inflation initiated by an increase in the costs faced by firms, arising on the supply side of the economy money stock: the quantity of money in the economy Test yourself 10.4 Demand-pull inflation An alternative explanation for a rise in the general price level could come from the demand side, where an increase in aggregate demand leads to a rise in prices, especially if the economy is close to its full capacity. An increase in the price level arising from the demand side of the macroeconomy is referred to as demand-pull inflation. An increase in aggregate demand can arise from an increase in any of the components of aggregate demand, or from a cut in taxes. In terms of the AD/AS model, an increase in expenditure by consumers, firms or government would cause a rightward shift in the AD curve, as would an increase in exports or a decrease in taxes. This is shown in Figure 10.6, with a shift from AD0 to AD1 and an increase in the price level from P0, first to P1 and finally to P2. In this case, real GDP returns to YFE. However, the AD/AS diagram again shows that there would be a one-off increase in the price level, which is not the same as saying there would be persistent inflation. Price level Name two examples (other than the price of oil) of how firms’ costs may rise and trigger cost-push inflation. 10 LRAS 10 Price stability demand-pull inflation: inflation initiated by an increase in aggregate demand In this way, inflation may be initiated by an increase in the costs faced by firms. This is referred to as cost-push inflation, as the increase in the overall level of prices is cost-driven. However, the AD/AS diagram only shows that there would be a one-off increase in the price level, which is not the same as saying there would be persistent inflation. Indeed, if the increase in the price of oil is only temporary, the economy would be expected to adjust back to equilibrium. SRAS1 SRAS0 P2 P1 P0 AD1 AD0 0 YFE Y1 Real GDP STUDY TIP Notice that if an increase in aggregate demand is accompanied by a corresponding increase in long-run aggregate supply, there would not be demand-pull inflation. Test yourself 10.5 Would cost-push inflation be initiated by demand- or supply-side factors? ▲ Figure 10.6 Adjustment following an increase in aggregate demand Why should there be persistent inflation? Why should there be persistent increases in prices over time? The AD/AS model shows that there may be one-off movements in either aggregate demand or aggregate supply that may lead to one-off changes in the overall price level, but unless the movements continue in subsequent periods there is no reason to suppose that inflation will continue. One explanation is provided by changes in the supply of money circulating in an economy. Persistent inflation can take place only when the money stock grows more rapidly than real output. This can be shown in terms of aggregate demand and aggregate supply. If the money supply increases, firms and households in the economy find they have excess cash balances: that is, for a given price level they have more purchasing power than they expected to have. Their impulse will thus be to increase their spending, which will cause the aggregate demand (AD) curve to move to the right. They will probably also save some of the excess, which will tend to result in lower interest rates – which will then reinforce the increase in aggregate demand. However, 141 308275_C10_CAM_IASAL ECO_134_145.indd 141 2/17/21 1:27 PM 10 LEARNING LINK AS LEVEL PART 4 THE MACROECONOMY The role of money and its relationship with inflation is discussed more fully in Chapter 27. as the AD curve moves to the right, the equilibrium price level will rise, returning the economy to the full-employment equilibrium. If the money supply continues to increase, the process repeats itself, with prices then rising persistently. One danger of this is that people will get so accustomed to the process that they speed up their spending decisions, which simply accelerates the whole process. To summarise, the analysis suggests that although a price rise can be triggered on either the supply side or the demand side of the macroeconomy, persistent inflation can arise only through persistent excessive growth in the money stock. SUMMARY: CAUSES OF INFLATION » Cost-push inflation is initiated by an increase in the costs faced by firms, arising on the supply side of the economy. » Demand-pull inflation is initiated by an increase in aggregate demand. » Inflation will only persist if there is an increase in the money supply. 10.4 Consequences of inflation It is worth noting that when governments have set targets for inflation, they do not choose to set the target at 0%. For example, the UK has set a target of 2% per annum, as is the case in the USA. New Zealand aims to keep average inflation between 1 and 3% per annum in the medium term. India has a target of 4% per annum. This suggests that inflation is not always bad. The main argument here is that a stable and modest rate of inflation allows prices to work effectively as signals. In particular, it is important that prices can signal to producers where sectors are expanding or declining, and this is more easily achieved when prices are rising at different rates, rather than allowing some prices to fall. However, there are also a number of costs that can arise if an economy experiences inflation. Uncertainty and investment If the rate of change of prices cannot be confidently predicted by firms, the increase in uncertainty may be damaging, and firms may become reluctant to undertake the investment that would expand the economy’s productive capacity. Resource allocation Chapter 4 emphasised that prices are very important in allocating resources in a market economy. Inflation may consequently inhibit the ability of prices to act as reliable signals in this process, leading to a wastage of resources and lost business opportunities. Effects on income distribution Test yourself 10.6 If workers are awarded a 3% increase in wages when inflation is running at 5%, what would be the effect on their real wages? As inflation accelerates, there could be an increase in inequality in the distribution of income, because some groups in society are less able to protect themselves against rising prices. In particular, pensioners and others on fixed incomes find the value of their incomes (and savings) are diluted by rising prices. Effect on wages Another consequence of high inflation is that workers negotiate for higher wages to compensate for the increase in prices. This further increases the costs faced by firms, which may reinforce the inflationary process. 142 308275_C10_CAM_IASAL ECO_134_145.indd 142 2/17/21 1:27 PM Menu and shoe-leather costs Test yourself 10.7 This reluctance to use money for transactions may inhibit the effectiveness of markets. For example, there was a period in the early 1980s when inflation in Argentina was so high that some city parking fines had to be paid in litres of petrol rather than in cash. Markets will not work effectively when people do not use money and the economy begins to slip back towards a barter economy. The situation may be worsened if taxes or pensions are not properly indexed so that they do not keep up with inflation. 10 10 Price stability What is meant by the menu costs of inflation? When inflation is very high and volatile, firms have to keep amending their price lists, which raises the costs of undertaking transactions. These costs are often known as the menu costs of inflation; however, these should not be expected to be significant unless inflation really is very high. A second cost of very high inflation is that it discourages people from holding money because, at the very high nominal interest rates that occur when inflation is high, the opportunity cost of holding money becomes great. People therefore try to keep their money in interest-bearing accounts for as long as possible, even if it means making frequent trips to the bank – for which reason these are known as the shoe-leather costs of inflation. Inflation as a policy objective STUDY TIP The key costs of inflation are: » uncertainty reduces incentives for investment » prices fail to be reliable signals for resource allocation » redistribution of income away from those on fixed incomes » menu costs » shoe-leather costs » reluctance to use money for transactions Although the menu costs and shoe-leather costs become important only at quite high rates of inflation, the potential negative consequences of inflation have caused the governments of many countries to focus on maintaining stability of prices as a key part of macroeconomic policy. The reasoning here is twofold. One argument is that measured inflation will overstate actual inflation, partly because it is so difficult to take account of quality changes in products such as smartphones, where it is impossible to distinguish accurately between a price change and a quality change. Second, wages and prices tend to be sticky in a downward direction: in other words, firms may be reluctant to lower prices and wages. A modest rate of inflation (e.g. 2%) thus allows relative prices to change more readily, with prices rising by more in some sectors than in others. This may help price signals to be more effective in guiding resource allocation. EXERCISE 10.3 Suppose that next year inflation in the economy in which you live suddenly takes off, reaching 15% per annum – in other words, prices rise by 15% – but so do incomes. Discuss how this would affect your daily life.Why would it be damaging for the economy in the future? SUMMARY: CONSEQUENCES OF INFLATION » High and volatile inflation causes uncertainty, which may discourage investment by firms. » Inflation may disguise price signals and cause a misallocation of resources. » Inflation can cause a worsening of income inequality. » Workers may negotiate for higher wages when inflation is high, which could fuel further inflation. » High inflation inflicts menu and shoe-leather costs on society. » Inflation may cause an increase in transaction costs if people become reluctant to use money for transactions. 143 308275_C10_CAM_IASAL ECO_134_145.indd 143 2/17/21 1:27 PM END OF CHAPTER QUESTIONS AS LEVEL PART 4 THE MACROECONOMY 10 Multiple choice 1 The consumer price index in a country changes from 110 to 115. For the same period the nominal interest rate on an individual’s savings account changes by +5%. What can be concluded with certainty? A The individual is on fixed income. B The individual is now 5% better off. C The real value of the individual’s savings stayed unchanged. D The real value of the individual’s savings increased. 2 A desirable consequence of domestic inflation could be: A more competitive exports B reduced burden of real debt C reduced real interest on savings D reduced international value of the country’s currency Data response 1 Read the following extract and then answer the questions that follow. Inflation and deflation The consumer price index (CPI) is a measure designed to record the general price level of household goods and services. The CPI is produced as a weighted average index for which the International Monetary Fund provides construction guidelines. 5 The potential negative consequences of price instability cause the governments of many countries to focus on maintaining a target rate of inflation. This is monitored through their CPI and forms a key part of their macroeconomic strategy. In early 2020, this was brought into sharp focus when a sinking global economy 10 was suffering through disinflation that briefly pushed some economies into dangerous deflation territory for the first time in decades. In 2008 and again in 2011, increased oil prices caused temporary spikes in UK inflation to over 5%. However, in 2020, with many national economies all but shutting down in an effort to contain Covid-19, prices of everything from oil and 15 copper to hotel rooms and takeaway food were tumbling. While falling prices may seem like good news for consumers, widespread deflation is likely to be harmful for the macroeconomy. The concern was that even after the Covid-19 crisis eased, the scars from the shutdown, elevated unemployment, shattered consumer and company 20 confidence, and staggered returns to work may have prolonged the disinflation. However, some economists thought that it was inflation, not deflation, that would be the problem. As the lockdown lifted and recovery ensued, following a period of massive fiscal and monetary expansion, there were concerns there 25 would be a surge in inflation, quite likely more than 5% and even in the order of 10% in 2021. One commentator said, ‘If we get inflation that would be good. That would be a good sign that we have adequate demand.’ 144 308275_C10_CAM_IASAL ECO_134_145.indd 144 2/17/21 1:27 PM CASE STUDY Inflation and the economy Since the mid-1970s inflation has been regarded by the governments of many countries around the world as economic public enemy number one. How did it gain this reputation? The view that inflation is dangerous for the economy was initially fuelled by the experience of many countries after the sudden and unexpected rise in oil prices in 1973–74 and 1979–80. In addition, some countries, especially in South America, went through periods of hyperinflation, partly caused by excessive spending. What harm does inflation do? Many arguments have been advanced to show that inflation causes damage. Many pensioners rely on incomes that are fixed in money terms, so they lose out when prices rise rapidly – at a time when other groups in society gain. This means that inequality worsens. At high levels of inflation, transaction costs rise: firms need to keep changing their prices, and people try to avoid using cash, and keep as much as possible of their money in interest-bearing accounts that they access less frequently. Rapid changes in relative prices make it difficult for firms to interpret prices. This makes it hard to make plans for future contracts, so firms tend to form pessimistic expectations about the future course of the economy. Inflation in the twenty-first century In the early years of this century, prices were relatively stable in many countries and people began to become accustomed to low inflation rates. Some countries successfully introduced inflation targeting to maintain stability. Everything then went horribly wrong. A sudden rise in commodity prices led to an acceleration of inflation, but this trend was interrupted by a financial crisis, with many banks in the USA, UK and elsewhere needing to be bailed out. As the global economy began to recover from this, tariff wars broke out between the USA and China, the UK decided to exit from the EU, and uncertainty spread through the global community. As if this were not enough, the Covid-19 pandemic hit. Inflation no longer seemed to be the major concern. 10 10 Price stability a ‘The CPI is produced as a weighted average index’ (lines 2–3). Explain one difficulty arising from the use of weights when attempting to provide a meaningful measure of inflation in an economy. b Distinguish between ‘inflation’ (line 7) and ‘disinflation’ (line 10). c Use the information provided and an AD/AS diagram to show how a temporary spike in inflation can be caused. d Explain why ‘widespread deflation is likely to be harmful for the macroeconomy’ (lines 16–17). e Discuss whether the disinflation predicted in the extract is likely to persist over the longer term. Follow-up questions a Identify examples of demand-pull and cost-push inflationary pressures in the passage. b What are the potential benefits that come from having low and stable inflation? c What are the main costs of inflation? d Which of the costs do you regard as the most important? e How has inflation changed since the onset of the pandemic in the country in which you live? 145 308275_C10_CAM_IASAL ECO_134_145.indd 145 2/17/21 1:27 PM AS LEVEL PART 5 Government macroeconomic intervention AS LEVEL PART 5 GOVERNMENT MACROECONOMIC INTERVENTION 11 Macroeconomic policy What this chapter covers ★ the main objectives of macroeconomic policy ★ what is meant by the government budget and the meaning and significance of the national debt ★ the working of fiscal policy ★ monetary policy and how the tools of monetary policy can affect the path of the economy ★ the meaning and significance of supply-side policy The previous chapters have identified some of the key indicators used to judge a country’s macroeconomic performance. In looking to improve the performance of the macroeconomy, a government can call on a range of policy options. These are the subjects of this chapter. 11.1 Government macroeconomic policy objectives and instruments LEARNING LINK Although these are arguably the most important objectives that a government can pursue at the macroeconomic level, they are not the only ones. Avoiding an imbalance on the balance of payments and ensuring that the exchange rate is at an appropriate level are also important objectives, and are discussed in Chapters 13 and 29. Policies to promote sustainable economic growth are discussed in Chapter 25; economic development is the topic of Chapter 30. Chapter 8 explored the topic of economic growth. Chapter 9 looked at unemployment. Chapter 10 examined price stability. Together, these are the main objectives of government macroeconomic policy that we will discuss in this chapter: » price stability » low unemployment » economic growth Price stability Low inflation has been seen as a key part of macroeconomic policy design for many countries since the mid-1970s. There have nonetheless been periods when inflation has risen appreciably – notably in some Latin American economies in the 1980s and more recently in some transition and African countries. When inflation is high and unpredictable, firms do not have confidence to undertake productive investment, which is a key component of economic growth. Low unemployment Chapter 9 has argued that high unemployment is wasteful for a society as it means that the economy is operating below its full potential capacity. It also imposes costs on those individuals who are unemployed. Economic growth If the ultimate aim of a society is to improve the wellbeing of its citizens, then in economic terms this means that the resources available within the economy need to expand through time in order to widen people’s choices. Economic growth may be regarded as the most fundamental of all macroeconomic policy objectives, with other policy objectives being subsidiary to it. For example, one of the key reasons for maintaining stability of prices is to encourage firms to undertake investment – because this enables economic growth. Maintaining full employment ensures the best possible use of a society’s resources, enabling it to reach the production possibility curve – and failure to do this may have consequences for economic growth. 146 308275_C11_CAM_IASAL ECO_146_163.indd 146 17/02/21 3:38 PM Test yourself 11.1 Explain why economic growth may be regarded as the most fundamental of all macroeconomic policy objectives. Macroeconomic policy instruments 11 11 Macroeconomic policy The government has three main types of policy instrument with which to attempt to meet its macroeconomic objectives: 1 Fiscal policy: the term ‘fiscal policy’ covers a range of policy measures that affect government expenditures and revenues through the decisions made by the government on its expenditure, taxation and borrowing. Fiscal policy is used to influence the level and structure of aggregate demand in an economy. As this chapter unfolds, you will see that the effectiveness of fiscal policy depends crucially on the whole policy environment in which it is utilised, and on the interrelationship between the three types of policy. 2 Monetary policy: this entails the use of monetary variables such as money supply, interest rates and credit regulations to influence aggregate demand. The effectiveness of monetary policy will depend on the policy environment in which it is used. In particular, the exchange rate has an important impact on how effective monetary policy can be. The importance of exchange rates and how they are determined is discussed in Chapters 13, 28 and 29. The financial crisis of the late 2000s highlighted the need for adequate regulation of financial markets to influence the flow of credit in the economy. 3 Supply-side policies: such policies comprise a range of measures intended to have a direct impact on aggregate supply – specifically, on the potential capacity output of the economy. These measures are often microeconomic in character and are designed to increase output and hence economic growth. 11.2 Fiscal policy KEY TERMS fiscal policy: decisions made by the government on its expenditure, taxation and borrowing government budget: the balance between government receipts and outlays government budget deficit: a situation in which government expenditure exceeds government revenue government budget surplus: a situation in which government expenditure is less than government revenue government balanced budget: a situation in which government expenditure equals government revenue Fiscal policy covers a range of policy measures involving government expenditures and revenues. As the government has discretion over the amount of expenditure that it undertakes and the amount of revenue that it chooses to raise from taxation, these can be manipulated in order to influence its policy objectives. An important question concerns the extent to which a government can use fiscal policy to influence the level of aggregate demand in the economy. The government budget Fiscal policy can be used to affect the level of aggregate demand in the economy. The overall balance between government receipts and outlays comprises the government budget. Receipts come mainly from taxation; outlays cover the range of expenditures undertaken by government. The overall government budget position An important issue in considering fiscal policy is the balance between government expenditure and government revenue, as it is this balance that affects the position of the aggregate demand curve. When total government expenditure exceeds revenues, there is a government budget deficit, whereas if revenues exceed expenditure, there is a government budget surplus. In the event that revenues were to equal expenditure, there would be a balanced budget. This is rarely achieved in any single year, but for sustainability, having a balanced budget may be seen as a long-term objective for the government. An increase in the government budget deficit (or a decrease in the government budget surplus) increases aggregate demand. A budget deficit may arise either from an increase in expenditure or from a decrease in taxation, although the two have some differential effects. The overall size of the budget deficit may limit the government’s actions in terms of fiscal policy. In addition, the overall pattern of revenue and expenditure has a 147 308275_C11_CAM_IASAL ECO_146_163.indd 147 17/02/21 3:38 PM strong effect on the overall balance of activity in the economy. A neutral government budget can be attained either with high expenditure and high revenues, or with relatively low expenditure and low revenues. Such decisions affect the overall size of the public sector relative to the private sector. Over the years and in different countries, different governments have taken different decisions on this issue. 11 AS LEVEL PART 5 GOVERNMENT MACROECONOMIC INTERVENTION The national debt and government borrowing KEY TERM national debt: the total amount of government debt, based on accumulated previous deficits and surpluses Test yourself 11.2 If a government spends more than it receives from taxation, will there be a budget deficit or budget surplus? If the government spends more than it raises in revenue, the resulting deficit has to be financed in some way. The government budget deficit is known as the public sector net cash requirement (PSNCR). Part of the PSNCR is covered by borrowing, and the government closely monitors its net borrowing. Over time, such borrowing leads to net debt, which is the accumulation of past borrowing, known as the national debt. A major argument in favour of controlling the level of public sector net debt arises from the long-run effects of policy on spending and borrowing. It has been argued that sustainable economic growth has to take into account the needs of future generations. It can be argued that future generations should not have to meet the cost of the consumption of the present population. In the UK, public sector debt was stable for some time at less than 40% of GDP, and it was not seen as being of major concern. However, the financial crisis of the late 2000s led to a refocusing of macroeconomic policy. In the UK, the government provided a bailout for failing banks, as this was seen to be needed to safeguard the financial system. Public sector net debt rose to more than 140% of GDP by the end of 2009. This began to fall as the government gradually reduced its stake in bailed-out banks. However, when the Covid-19 pandemic started in early 2020, the net debt was already above 90% of GDP, and the measures taken to try to conserve the economy in the face of the virus increased debt by even more. Debt continued to rise well into 2021. Figure 11.1 shows the national debt as a percentage of GDP for a range of countries. (These data predate the Covid-19 pandemic.) This highlights the varied nature of experience in different countries around the world. Japan has the highest national debt of any country in the world, at almost 240% of GDP. In the UAE national debt is less than 20% of GDP. A problem of having a high level of national debt is the interest payments that need to be made, and the difficulty that may be faced in repaying the debt in the longer term may restrict the ability of the government to carry out its expenditure plans. The low level of interest rates in the 2010s eased the position in the short run. Nepal Pakistan Bangladesh Zimbabwe India Sri Lanka China Malaysia New Zealand UAE UK Japan USA 0 50 100 150 200 250 % of GDP Source: based on data from World Population Review ▲ Figure 11.1 National debt (% of GDP) 148 308275_C11_CAM_IASAL ECO_146_163.indd 148 17/02/21 3:38 PM LEARNING LINK Reasons for taxation Governments impose taxes for a variety of purposes. In particular, there is a need to raise revenue to finance government expenditures, but taxes are also used to address some forms of market failure and to influence the macroeconomy. 11 Revenue is needed to: » provide services to people, such as healthcare and education » finance infrastructure projects that will increase future productive capacity, such as roads and communication networks Taxes can address market failures, such as: » the provision of public goods, which would not otherwise be provided by the market » the need to deal with externalities, such as pollution At the macroeconomic level, taxes can be used to: » influence the level of aggregate demand » influence the distribution of income and wealth 11 Macroeconomic policy The use of indirect taxes to address issues of market failure is discussed in Chapter 5 with some further coverage in Chapter 21. Externalities are explained in Chapter 16. Taxation Tax collection Tax collection presents a challenge to many less developed countries. In many cases, the institutions needed to collect taxes are absent, or are ineffective. To some extent this is reflected in the data shown in Figure 11.2, which shows tax revenue in a range of countries as a percentage of GDP. Notice how the UK and New Zealand in this group are able to raise a significantly higher proportion of GDP in the form of tax revenue. Of course, there may also be countries (such as UAE, where tax revenue is only 0.06% of GDP) that could raise a higher level of taxes, but which choose not to do so. However, there are also countries that are not able to collect taxes efficiently and effectively. KEY TERMS direct tax: a tax levied directly on income progressive tax: a tax in which the marginal tax rate rises with income, i.e. a tax bearing most heavily on the relatively well-off members of society Nepal Kenya Bangladesh Zimbabwe India Sri Lanka South Africa China Brazil Malaysia Korea New Zealand UAE UK Japan USA 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 % of GDP Source: based on data from World Development Indicators ▲ Figure 11.2 Tax revenue (% of GDP) Direct taxes Direct taxes are taxes levied on income of various kinds, such as personal income tax. Such taxes are designed to be progressive and so can be effective in redistributing income. The progressive nature of income tax is reflected in the way the tax rate 149 308275_C11_CAM_IASAL ECO_146_163.indd 149 17/02/21 3:38 PM marginal tax rate: the rate of tax on additional income, defined as the change in tax payments divided by the change in taxable income average tax rate: the ratio of tax payments to the level of income increases as an individual moves into a higher income range. In other words, the marginal tax rate increases as income increases. The average tax rate also increases as income rises. The progressive nature of the tax ensures that it does indeed help to reduce inequality in income distribution. STUDY TIP In contrast, indirect taxes – taxes on expenditure, such as VAT and excise duties – tend to be regressive. As poorer households tend to spend a higher proportion of their income on items that are subject to excise duties, a greater share of their income is taken up by indirect taxes. Even VAT can be regressive if higher-income households save a greater proportion of their incomes. This is explained in Chapter 5 and in a later section of this chapter. Figure 11.3 shows average direct tax rates for UK households by quintile group in 2015/16. Notice that the figure shows average rather than marginal tax rates. When average rates are rising, marginal tax rates are higher than the average. Exercise 11.1 illustrates this. % of gross income 25 20 Income tax Employees’ NIC Council tax and rates 15 10 All households Top quintile 4th quintile 3rd quintile 0 2nd quintile 5 Bottom quintile AS LEVEL PART 5 GOVERNMENT MACROECONOMIC INTERVENTION 11 KEY TERMS Note: NIC = National Insurance contributions Source: ONS (UK) ▲ Figure 11.3 Average direct taxes by quintile households, 2015/16 Test yourself 11.3 Looking at Figure 11.3, would you say that employees’ National Insurance contribution* payments are progressive or regressive? *National Insurance is a tax on earnings and self-employment profits. Figure 11.3 shows how income tax is progressive in the UK, as the average tax rate increases from 3.8% in the bottom quintile to 16.5% in the top quintile. However, it also shows that council tax (a tax on property) is certainly not progressive, as it takes a higher percentage from the bottom quintile than from the top. EXERCISE 11.1 Table 11.1 shows the amount of tax paid by an individual as income increases. Calculate the average and marginal tax rates at each of the income levels. (Remember the definition of the marginal tax rate provided above.) ▼ Table 11.1 Amount of tax at various income levels Income ($) 1,000 Tax paid ($) 100 2,000 300 3,000 600 4,000 1,000 150 308275_C11_CAM_IASAL ECO_146_163.indd 150 17/02/21 3:38 PM Test yourself 11.4 Explain why producers are more able to pass on an increase in indirect taxes to consumers when demand is relatively price inelastic. Indirect taxes Indirect taxes are taxes paid on items of expenditure, rather than on income. Examples of indirect taxes are value added tax (VAT), which is charged on most goods and services sold in the UK, tobacco taxes, excise duties on alcohol and oil duties. These taxes are levied per unit sold. When demand is price inelastic, producers are able to pass much of an increase in the tax rate on to consumers, whereas if demand is price elastic they have to absorb most of the increase as part of their costs. KEY TERMS regressive tax: a tax in which the marginal tax rate falls with income, i.e. a tax bearing most heavily on the relatively less-well-off members of society proportional tax: a tax that is proportional to income, being neither regressive nor progressive government current expenditure: spending by the government on goods and services transfer payments: occur when the government provides benefits (in cash or in kind) to poor households government capital expenditure: spending by government on investment projects for the future benefit of the economy STUDY TIP Notice that what is important for aggregate demand is not only government expenditure, but also the level of taxation. In other words, it is the size of the government deficit or surplus that influences aggregate demand. Why should some of these taxes be regressive? Take the tobacco tax. In the first place, the number of smokers is higher among lower-income groups than among the relatively rich – research has shown that only about 10% of people in professional groups now smoke compared with nearly 40% of those in unskilled manual groups. Second, expenditure on tobacco tends to take a lower proportion of income of the rich compared with that of the poor, even for those in the former group who do smoke. Thus, the tobacco tax falls more heavily on lower-income groups than on the better-off. It is estimated that for UK households in the bottom quintile of the income distribution in 2015/16, indirect taxes accounted for 27.0% of their disposable income, compared with 14.4% for households in the top quintile. The largest share of indirect tax was VAT, which accounted for 11.4% of disposable income of households in the bottom quintile, compared with 7.1% for the top quintile. 11 Macroeconomic policy The effect of indirect taxes can sometimes be regressive: in other words, indirect taxes may fall more heavily on lower-income households. 11 Notice that a tax that is simply proportional to income would be neither regressive nor progressive, but would be charged at the same percentage rate to all taxpayers. STUDY TIP Make sure you are clear about the distinction between the different effects of taxes: » a progressive tax (such as income tax) bears most heavily on relatively highincome households » a regressive tax (such as an expenditure tax) tends to fall more heavily on relatively low-income households » a proportional tax falls equally on households at all income levels Government expenditure Government undertakes spending on a wide range of goods and services. Government current expenditure is spending on goods and services for immediate use. This includes transfer payments such as social security payments, but also covers expenditure on the wages of civil servants and on health and education, which takes a significant portion of the budget in many countries. Government capital expenditure is spending that is investment for the future benefit of the economy. This covers expenditure on infrastructure projects such as improving transport and communications. Such projects are intended to facilitate economic growth. Expansionary and contractionary fiscal policy Government expenditure is a component of aggregate demand, so changes in expenditure can affect aggregate demand. There may be situations in which the government wants to influence the level of aggregate demand in the economy, so fiscal policy can be a part of macroeconomic policy. 151 308275_C11_CAM_IASAL ECO_146_163.indd 151 17/02/21 3:38 PM contractionary fiscal policy: where the government reduces its expenditure or raises taxes in times when real GDP is above its fullemployment level expansionary fiscal policy: where the government increases its spending or reduces taxes when real GDP is below its fullemployment level LEARNING LINK The AD/AS model was introduced in Chapter 7. For example, there may be periods in which real GDP rises above the full-employment level so that there is a danger that the economy will overheat, and inflation begin to rise. If the government is not certain that the economy will adjust rapidly to its long-run equilibrium position, it may wish to dampen aggregate demand by reducing government expenditure or raising taxes. This would be a contractionary fiscal policy. Conversely, if the economy is operating below its full capacity, an increase in aggregate demand fuelled by government spending (or by reducing taxes) could speed the process of adjustment back to equilibrium. This could be particularly important if the short-run aggregate supply curve is a sweeping curve. This would be an expansionary fiscal policy. Fiscal policy and the AD/AS model The effects of contractionary and expansionary fiscal policy changes can be seen using the AD/AS model. First consider an expansionary policy, which is shown in Figure 11.4. Suppose that for some reason there has been a fall in aggregate demand, so that the economy begins in short-run equilibrium with real GDP at Y0 and price level at P0. Price level AS LEVEL PART 5 GOVERNMENT MACROECONOMIC INTERVENTION 11 KEY TERMS SRASK Test yourself 11.5 How would spending on building a new power station be classified? P1 P0 AD1 AD0 0 Y0 Y1 YFE Real GDP ▲ Figure 11.4 An expansionary fiscal policy The figure has been drawn with short-run aggregate supply as a sweeping curve, so real GDP has fallen a relatively long way below full employment. The government may perceive that the adjustment back to full employment will be long-lived, so may wish to speed up the return to equilibrium. An expansionary fiscal policy may enable this. The government could increase its expenditure, raising aggregate demand so that there is a shift to AD1, taking the economy back towards long-run equilibrium more quickly. Figure 11.5 shows an economy that starts in long-run equilibrium with real GDP at YFE and overall price level at P0. Suppose that there is an increase in aggregate demand because of an increase in exports. The aggregate demand curve shifts from AD0 to AD1. In the short run there is a movement along the short-run aggregate supply curve, with real GDP rising to Y1 and the price rising to P1. The new equilibrium in the long run would be with real GDP back at YFE, but with a higher price P2. In other words, SRAS would adjust until it intersects AD at the point at which AD1 cuts LRAS. The government could use fiscal policy to moderate the increase in price, by reducing government expenditure so that the aggregate demand curve shifted to AD3, with the price level only rising to P3. This contractionary fiscal policy has the effect of moderating the increase in price that would otherwise have occurred. Real GDP returns to its full-employment level. 152 308275_C11_CAM_IASAL ECO_146_163.indd 152 17/02/21 3:38 PM Price level LRAS SRAS1 SRAS3 SRAS0 11 P2 P1 P3 P0 AD1 AD0 0 YFE Y1 Real GDP ▲ Figure 11.5 Adjustment to an increase in aggregate demand Test yourself 11.6 The use of fiscal policy to influence aggregate demand might be seen differently if the long-run aggregate supply curve has a Keynesian shape, being upward-sloping for some range below full employment. Figure 11.6 shows this situation. Suppose that the initial equilibrium is with aggregate demand AD0, with price PK and real GDP at YK. Because this is a long-run equilibrium, there is no immediate reason why this position should not remain, although it may be that eventually the economy will find its way back to full employment. Price level Give an example of a fiscal measure that would increase aggregate demand. A danger of both of these policy moves is that the government might misjudge the size of stimulus that was needed, so the economy could overshoot. 11 Macroeconomic policy AD3 LRASK PFE P1 PK AD1 AD0 0 YK Y1 YFE Real GDP ▲ Figure 11.6 An expansionary fiscal policy with a Keynesian LRAS An expansionary fiscal policy could shift the aggregate demand curve to AD1, so that the economy moves back towards full employment, with real GDP rising to Y1 and the price level increasing to P1. The relative size of movements in real GDP and the overall price level will depend on the slope of the LRAS in this range. If the natural adjustment is very slow, this intervention might be helpful, but there is still a danger that the timing of the adjustment will be misjudged, so that the economy overshoots its equilibrium. EXERCISE 11.2 Use a diagram to analyse the effect of an expansionary fiscal policy when the economy begins with real GDP at its full-employment level. 153 308275_C11_CAM_IASAL ECO_146_163.indd 153 17/02/21 3:38 PM 11 SUMMARY: FISCAL POLICY » Fiscal policy covers decisions made by the » AS LEVEL PART 5 GOVERNMENT MACROECONOMIC INTERVENTION » » » » » » government on its expenditure, taxation and borrowing. The government budget shows the balance between government receipts and outlays. When government expenditure exceeds revenues, there is a government budget deficit. When government expenditure is less than revenues, there is a government budget surplus. A balanced budget, where revenues equal expenditures, may be seen as a desirable long-term objective. The national debt is the accumulation of past borrowing. Changes in the government budget can affect the overall level of aggregate demand. Indirect taxes may often be regressive, and can be used for addressing market failure and for » » » » » affecting the distribution of income, but may also affect aggregate demand. Direct taxes tend to be progressive, and may influence the distribution of income. Governments undertake expenditure on goods and services for immediate use (current expenditure), but also spend on investment projects to benefit the economy in the long run (capital expenditure). An increase in the government budget deficit is expansionary, as it leads to an increase in aggregate demand. A decrease in the government budget deficit is contractionary, as it leads to a fall in aggregate demand. The AD/AS model can be used to show the effects of a change in aggregate demand on the economy in the short and long run. 11.3 Monetary policy KEY TERM monetary policy: decisions made by the government regarding monetary variables such as money supply and interest rates LEARNING LINK The significance of the exchange rate is discussed in Chapters 13, 28 and 29. LEARNING LINK The roles of money supply and interest rates are discussed more fully in Chapter 27, where there is also an explanation of quantitative easing. Monetary policy entails the use of monetary variables to influence aggregate demand in the economy, with the intention of meeting the government’s macroeconomic objectives. The key tools are the money supply, the interest rate and credit regulations, although the exchange rate also has an important impact, and may in some circumstances be manipulated in support of the other tools of monetary policy. In many less developed countries, monetary policy may also aim to encourage the development of the financial sector and to promote confidence in it. Monetary policy has become the prime instrument of government macroeconomic policy in many developed countries. Monetary policy involves the manipulation of monetary variables in order to influence aggregate demand in the economy, with the intention of meeting the government’s inflation target. The tools of monetary policy Until the financial crisis of the late 2000s, the interest rate was viewed as the main instrument of monetary policy in the UK and elsewhere. However, as interest rates fell to record low levels during and after the crisis, it became necessary to make more use of changes in money supply to influence the economy, through a process that became known as ‘quantitative easing’. The financial crisis also highlighted the key importance of financial regulation to ensure an appropriate flow of credit in the economy. Although reference has been made to ‘the interest rate’, this is a simplification. In the real-world economy, there are many different interest rates. For example, if you borrow from a bank, you will pay a higher interest rate than would be paid to you on your savings. Indeed, it is this difference between the rates for savers and borrowers that enables the banks to make a profit. Similarly, interest rates on financial assets differ depending on the nature of the asset. In part, these differences reflect different degrees of risk associated with the assets. A risky asset pays a higher interest rate than a relatively safe asset. 154 308275_C11_CAM_IASAL ECO_146_163.indd 154 17/02/21 3:38 PM How does monetary policy work? In evaluating the tools of monetary policy, it is important to understand the route by which a change in a monetary variable can have an effect on the real economy. In other words, how can a change in money supply, or the interest rate, affect the level of equilibrium output in the economy? 11 The monetary transmission mechanism transmission mechanism of monetary policy: the channel by which monetary policy affects aggregate demand LEARNING LINK A contractionary monetary policy Suppose that the monetary authorities need to dampen aggregate demand to reduce inflationary pressure. At a higher interest rate, firms undertake less investment expenditure because fewer projects are worthwhile. In addition, a higher interest rate may encourage higher saving, which also means that households undertake less consumption expenditure. This may then reinforce the impact on investment because if firms perceive consumption to be falling, this will affect their expectations about future demand, and further dampen their desire to undertake investment. These factors lower the level of aggregate demand, shifting the AD curve to the left. This can be seen by looking at Figure 11.7. Suppose that there has been an increase in aggregate demand to AD0 that has taken the economy to Y0, which is beyond its full-employment level of real GDP. The authorities realise that there is a danger that the economy will move to a new long-run equilibrium with the overall price level rising to P*. To prevent price from rising beyond its current level (at P0) they can raise the interest rate so that aggregate demand shifts to the left at AD1. The economy settles back in equilibrium with the price at P0 and real GDP back to full employment at YFE. Price level The transmission mechanism of monetary policy is explained in more detail in Chapter 28. In drawing this analysis together, an important issue concerns the relationship between the rate of interest and the level of aggregate demand. This is critical for the conduct of monetary policy. Indeed, the interest rate has been seen as the prime instrument of monetary policy in recent years – and monetary policy is seen as the prime instrument of macroeconomic policy. By setting the interest rate, monetary policy is intended to affect aggregate demand through the so-called monetary transmission mechanism. 11 Macroeconomic policy KEY TERM LRAS SRAS1 SRAS0 P* P0 AD0 AD1 0 YFE Y0 Real GDP ▲ Figure 11.7 A contractionary monetary policy Test yourself 11.7 Explain why investment may be sensitive to the rate of interest. Notice that this may not be the end of the story. If one of the effects of the higher interest rate is to discourage investment that might otherwise have occurred, this will also have long-term consequences. Investment allows the productive capacity of the economy to increase, leading to a rightward drift in the AS curve. With lower 155 308275_C11_CAM_IASAL ECO_146_163.indd 155 17/02/21 3:38 PM investment, this process will slow down, leaving the economy with lower productive capacity than it otherwise could have had. 11 The AD/AS graph is drawn in terms of the overall price level. However, in a dynamic context, such a policy stance may be needed in order to maintain control of inflation. An expansionary monetary policy? AS LEVEL PART 5 GOVERNMENT MACROECONOMIC INTERVENTION A reduction in interest rates would, of course, have the reverse effect. If the economy were to be in a position where real GDP was below its full-employment level, the monetary authorities could consider an expansionary monetary policy. Reducing interest rates would shift aggregate demand to the right. If the economy faced a curved SRAS curve, the result would be to stimulate real GDP with only a modest increase in the price level. The effect would be similar to the impact of an expansionary fiscal policy, as shown in Figure 11.4 on page 152 and Figure 11.6 on page 153. In creating a stable macroeconomic environment, the ultimate aim of monetary policy is not simply to keep inflation low, but to improve the confidence of decision-makers, and thereby encourage firms to invest in order to generate an increase in production capacity. This will stimulate economic growth and create an opportunity to improve living standards. Monetary policy in practice The monetary transmission mechanism explains the way in which a change in the interest rate affects aggregate demand in the economy. In summary, suppose there is a reduction in the interest rate. From firms’ point of view, this lowers the cost of borrowing, and would be expected to encourage higher investment spending. Furthermore, consumers may also respond to a fall in the interest rate by increasing their expenditure, both because this lowers the cost of borrowing – so there may be an increase in the demand for consumer durable goods – and because households may perceive that saving now pays a lower return, so may decide to spend more. An expansionary monetary policy intended to stimulate aggregate demand would be damaging if the economy were close to (or at) full employment, as the main impact would be on the overall price level rather than real output. This suggests that monetary policy should only be used to stimulate aggregate demand with careful consideration of where the economy is in relation to full employment. However, monetary policy can still play an important role in managing the economy. This arises through its influence on the price level and hence the rate of change of prices – that is, inflation. Inflation targeting KEY TERM inflation targeting: an approach to monetary policy in which the central bank is given independence to set interest rates in order to meet an inflation target An increasing number of countries (both developed and less developed) have introduced inflation targeting. This approach to monetary policy gives independence to the central bank to set interest rates at such a level as to meet an inflation target set by the government. The idea of this was to boost the credibility of government policy, by establishing a firm commitment to controlling inflation, as the control of money supply would now be out of the government’s control. It cannot expand money supply to boost aggregate demand in order to create a temporary boom that might bolster its popularity in the lead-up to an election. Monetary policy in the UK has been the responsibility of the Bank of England since 1997. The Bank’s responsibility is to meet the government’s target for inflation. The Bank’s Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) meets each month to decide whether or not the interest rate needs to be altered. The objective of this exercise is to ensure that 156 308275_C11_CAM_IASAL ECO_146_163.indd 156 17/02/21 3:38 PM Test yourself 11.8 Would a rise in interest rates lead to a leftward or rightward shift of the AD curve? KEY TERM Operationally, the MPC sets the interest rate which it pays on commercial bank reserves. This is known as the bank rate. The commercial banks tend to use this rate as their own base rate, from which they calculate the rates of interest that they charge to their borrowers. If the MPC changes the bank rate, the commercial banks soon adjust the rates they charge to borrowers. These will vary according to the riskiness of the loans – for example, credit cards are charged at a higher rate than mortgages – but all the rates are geared to the base rate set by the commercial banks, and hence indirectly to the bank rate set by the Bank of England. However, decisions to change the rate of interest are not taken solely in the light of expected inflation. In its deliberations about the interest rate, the MPC takes a wide variety of factors into account, including developments in: » » » » » » LEARNING LINK The way in which changes in interest rates are transmitted to affect aggregate demand is discussed in Chapter 28 together with a discussion of the effectiveness of monetary policy. financial markets the international economy money and credit demand and output the labour market costs and prices (e.g. changes in oil prices) 11 11 Macroeconomic policy bank rate the interest rate that is set by the Monetary Policy Committee of the Bank of England in order to influence inflation; it is the rate of interest charged by the Bank of England on short-term loans to other banks the government’s inflation target is met. If the rate of inflation threatens to accelerate beyond the target rate, the Bank of England can intervene by raising interest rates, thereby having a dampening effect on aggregate demand and reducing the inflationary pressure. In reaching its decisions, the MPC takes a long-term view, projecting inflation ahead over the next 2 years. ▲ Credit cards are charged at higher rates than mortgages A good example was in 2008, when the UK and other countries were struggling to cope with the financial crisis. At this time, inflation was accelerating, and had reached a rate that was more than 1 percentage point above the target. This being so, it might have been expected that the Bank of England would raise interest rates in order to stem aggregate demand and bring inflation back into line with the target. However, this would have been damaging in other ways, pushing the economy further into recession. With house prices falling, an increase in interest rates could have damaged this sector too. It was also thought that there were other pressures affecting the world economy that would in any case mean that the rate of inflation was likely to slow down of its own accord. In the event, inflation accelerated way beyond its target range, but the MPC refrained from raising the bank rate because of fears that the recession would become even deeper, or that the economy would recover more slowly. The financial crisis arose in part because of inadequate credit regulation. Banks had found ways of extending credit in ways that seemed to be secure, but which in the event carried high risk, leading to bank failures in the USA, the UK and elsewhere. The response during the post-crisis period was to put in place more stringent financial regulation to ensure there was no repeat of the crisis and that credit could be supplied to meet the needs of the economy in a more secure way. STUDY TIP Fiscal policy is used to influence real GDP through aggregate demand via the government budget, using expenditure and taxation as its tools. Monetary policy is used to maintain price stability by influencing aggregate demand, using interest rates and money supply (through quantitative easing) as its tools. 157 308275_C11_CAM_IASAL ECO_146_163.indd 157 17/02/21 3:42 PM 11 SUMMARY: MONETARY POLICY » Monetary policy entails the manipulation of » AS LEVEL PART 5 GOVERNMENT MACROECONOMIC INTERVENTION » » » monetary variables in order to influence aggregate demand in the economy. The prime instruments of monetary policy are the interest rate, money supply and credit regulation. There is not a single interest rate in the economy, but a variety of rates associated with the wide range of financial assets available. The monetary authorities can control either the money supply or interest rates, but not both independently. The transmission mechanism from the interest rate to aggregate demand works through » » » » investment and consumption, and indirectly via the exchange rate. A number of countries around the world have adopted inflation targeting, under which the central bank is given independence to meet the government’s inflation target. Monetary policy cannot focus solely on meeting the inflation target, but must also operate with an awareness of other developments in the macroeconomy. With the financial crisis of the late 2000s a new approach was needed. Quantitative easing was introduced to help manage an economy in recession. 11.4 Supply-side policies KEY TERM supply-side policies: a range of measures intended to have a direct impact on longrun aggregate supply LEARNING LINK These are also the two factors identified in Chapter 8 as being the underlying causes of economic growth. Test yourself 11.9 Explain what is meant by human capital. The fiscal and monetary policy instruments that we have discussed in this chapter so far have been aimed at affecting aggregate demand and at stabilising the macroeconomy in the relatively short run. Supply-side policies are measures intended to have a direct impact on long-run aggregate supply – specifically, on the potential capacity output of the economy. These measures are often microeconomic in character and are designed to increase output and hence economic growth. Supply-side policies are directed at affecting long-run aggregate supply, and are therefore important for the macroeconomic objective of economic growth. These policies are much less concerned with other macroeconomic objectives of the government. Supply-side policies focus on affecting the determinants of aggregate supply in order to shift the LRAS curve to the right. The factors that influence the position of long-run aggregate supply were discussed in Chapter 7. Recall that the position of the long-run supply curve depends on: » the quantity of factor inputs available » the effectiveness with which factor inputs are used. Supply-side policies include encouraging education and training, improving the flexibility with which markets operate and encouraging firms to invest in new technology. Notice that it is quite difficult to quantify the effects of these supplyside policies. In the case of education and training, the idea is that by increasing education and training, the human capital of the labour force is increased, thus resulting in improvements in productivity, which enable an increase in the overall productive capacity of the economy – in other words, this will lead to a rightward shift of the aggregate supply curve. However, some of the effects of increased spending become evident only after very long time lags. Education and training An important interventionist supply-side policy takes the form of encouraging workers (and potential workers) to undertake education and training to improve their productivity. This takes place partly through education in schools and colleges in preparation for work. It is important, therefore, that the curriculum is designed to provide key skills that will be useful in the workplace. However, this does not 158 308275_C11_CAM_IASAL ECO_146_163.indd 158 17/02/21 3:42 PM LEARNING LINK The meaning and significance of human capital was discussed in Chapter 8. Why might the government need to intervene to encourage firms to train their workers? LEARNING LINK The need to ensure adequate provision of public goods is discussed in Chapter 5. Test yourself 11.11 How would you decide whether an item of government spending is a demand-side fiscal policy or a supply-side policy? Adult education is also important. When the structure of the economy is changing, retraining must be made available to enable workers to move easily between sectors and occupations. This is crucial if structural unemployment is not to become a major problem. For any society, education and skills are necessary to enable workers to switch into new activities in response to structural changes in the economy. For example, workers displaced from manufacturing industry are likely to need retraining if they are to find jobs in the service sector. Workers released from agriculture in a less developed country will need training before they can become productive members of the industrial workforce. The market may not deliver the training that is necessary, as firms will not invest in training workers unless they can be sure that they will not be poached by competitors once they have completed their training. The government may thus need to provide incentives. Such intervention by government can improve the flexibility of the labour market, by enabling workers to move more readily between jobs – or even occupations. Education and training also have a direct impact on the productivity of workers, which can improve productive efficiency. 11 11 Macroeconomic policy Test yourself 11.10 mean that all education has to be geared directly to providing skills. For example, problem-solving and analytical skills can be developed through the study of a wide range of disciplines. Infrastructure An important area of government expenditure relates to the provision of infrastructure. Firms need efficient transport and communication networks, and other types of infrastructure that enable markets to operate effectively. The public goods aspects of infrastructure means that they will not be adequately provided by the free-market mechanism, so government intervention is needed. The objective of investing in infrastructure is to improve future productive efficiency, which again should have the effect of shifting long-run aggregate supply to the right. However, a word of caution is needed. Government undertakes expenditure for a wide variety of reasons. This means that it is important to set priorities in the allocation of funds. EXERCISE 11.3 Discuss the relative merits of government spending on improving the country’s road network as compared to increasing spending on the provision of healthcare. Subsidies One of the hindrances to structural change in the economy has been that declining sectors of activity have not always been located in the same regions as the expanding sectors, making it difficult for displaced workers to gain employment in the newly growing industries. In England, this led to a north–south divide, with industries in the north in decline, and the growth areas being in the south. This phenomenon is not unique to the UK economy, and across Europe there are substantial differences in unemployment rates. One way in which this can be tackled is through the use of subsidies. For example, firms that agree to set up their operations in disadvantaged regions could be offered incentives in the form of investment subsidies. The UK has operated such subsidies in the past, and the European Commission has also 159 308275_C11_CAM_IASAL ECO_146_163.indd 159 17/02/21 3:42 PM provided assistance to regions with high unemployment rates. Indeed, regions such as Wales in the UK benefited from such subsidies. 11 By giving subsidies in this way, the hope is to influence aggregate supply. However, it must be remembered that subsidies need to be financed somehow, and the danger is that by providing subsidies to encourage investment in some areas, there will be less investment elsewhere. AS LEVEL PART 5 GOVERNMENT MACROECONOMIC INTERVENTION Information gaps are a form of market failure. One area in which this may be a problem is in the labour market, where workers may not have adequate information about job opportunities – especially in other regions of the economy. By providing information about job vacancies, the authorities may be able to encourage mobility of workers, thus improving the way in which the labour market operates. Subsidies for key workers in regions where housing and transport costs are high may also be a useful interventionist strategy to encourage labour mobility. Research and development One of the most important influences on economic growth is technological change. As technology improves over time, production becomes potentially more efficient. One way of achieving technological progress is through research and development (R&D). In spite of its universities and research institutes, the UK has not devoted as much funding to R&D as some other advanced countries. You can see something of this in Figure 11.8, which shows the percentage of GDP devoted to R&D in a range of countries. Korea Sweden Japan Germany USA Belgium France China Norway EU UK Italy Poland Greece 0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 3.0 3.5 4.0 4.5 5.0 % of GDP Source: based on data from OECD ▲ Figure 11.8 R&D expenditure, 2018 (% of GDP) This may be an area in which the UK could do more if it could find a way of encouraging more R&D. This could be achieved through direct government funding, or by tax relief on R&D expenditure. However, again it may be important to bear in mind the opportunity cost of supporting R&D relative to other areas of government spending. LEARNING LINK Labour markets and their operation are discussed in Chapter 23. Improved labour market flexibility An important supply-side approach is to find ways of improving the flexibility of the labour market. Where labour markets are flexible, the structure of economic activity can more readily be adjusted to changing patterns of global demand. If declining lowproductivity sectors can give way to more dynamic activities where productivity is higher, then productive efficiency improves, and this will lead to a rightward shift in the long-run aggregate supply curve. One possibility is to limit the power of the trade unions, whose actions can sometimes lead to inflexibility, either through resistance to new working practices that could improve productivity or by pushing up wages so that the level of employment is reduced. 160 308275_C11_CAM_IASAL ECO_146_163.indd 160 17/02/21 3:42 PM It has also been argued that abolishing the minimum wage would improve flexibility. However, this must be balanced against the need to protect low-paid workers. Maintaining the flexibility of markets is one way in which the macroeconomic stability promoted by disciplined fiscal and monetary policy can improve aggregate supply. Macroeconomic stability enables price signals to work more effectively, as producers are better able to observe changes in relative prices. This can promote allocative efficiency. 11 Reforms of the tax and benefit system There are dangers in having a taxation system that is too progressive. Most people accept that income tax should be progressive, as a way of redistributing income within society and preventing inequality from becoming extreme. However, there may come a point at which marginal tax rates are so high that a large proportion of additional income is taxed away, reducing incentives for individuals to supply additional effort or labour. This could also have an effect on aggregate supply. Again, however, it is important to balance these incentive effects against the distortion caused by having too much inequality in society. 11 Macroeconomic policy Incentive effects are important in economic analysis. In this context, questions have been raised about the extent to which the tax system provides appropriate incentives to supply work effort. An important influence on labour supply, particularly for low-income workers, is the level of unemployment benefit. If unemployment benefit is provided at too high a level, it may inhibit labour force participation, in that some workers may opt to live on unemployment benefit rather than take up low-skilled (and low-paid) employment. In such a situation, a reduction in unemployment benefit may induce an increase in labour supply, which again will move the aggregate supply curve to the right. Such a policy needs to be balanced against the need to provide protection for those who are unable to find employment. It is also important that unemployment benefit is not reduced to such a level that workers are unwilling to leave their jobs to search for better ones, as this may inhibit the flexibility of the labour market. Supply-side policies and the AD/AS model If you look back at Figure 8.2 on page 115, you can see how an increase in long-run aggregate supply can be viewed in the AD/AS model. An increase in the productivity of factor inputs leads to a higher potential capacity level of real GDP. In the figure, the LRAS curve shifts to the right from YFE0 to YFE1. There is a movement down along the aggregate demand curve as the economy moves to a new equilibrium, with a lower overall price level and higher real GDP. Associated with this higher level of real GDP, there is higher employment. SUMMARY: SUPPLY-SIDE POLICIES » Supply-side policies are measures intended to have a direct impact on long-run aggregate supply. » The position of the LRAS curve depends on the quantity of factor inputs available and the effectiveness with which inputs are used. » Education and training can enable workers to become more productive. » Improving the social infrastructure (such as efficient transport and communication networks) can improve firms’ efficiency. » Subsidies can be used to influence aggregate supply by reducing regional variations in unemployment and capital availability. » Research and development helps firms to become more efficient through the development of new technologies. » Improving the flexibility of labour markets can influence long-run aggregate supply. » The structure of taxes and benefits needs to be carefully defined to offer protection to low-income households without damaging their incentives to accept jobs. 161 308275_C11_CAM_IASAL ECO_146_163.indd 161 17/02/21 3:42 PM END OF CHAPTER QUESTIONS AS LEVEL PART 5 GOVERNMENT MACROECONOMIC INTERVENTION 11 Multiple choice 1 The marginal rate of taxation under a progressive tax system: A is higher for the first tax bracket than for the last one B increases as income increases C is considered less equitable than a flat tax rate D only applies to income earned within the highest tax bracket applicable 2 Which supply-side policy is correctly matched with the objective it aims to achieve? Supply-side policy Objective A Privatisation Lower the general price level B Deregulation Attain economies of scale C Vocational training Protect declining industries D Reduce the power of trade unions Increase labour market flexibility Data response 1 Read the following extract and then answer the questions that follow. Macroeconomic policy in New Zealand 5 The fiscal strategy of the government of New Zealand is to ensure a progressive taxation system that is fair, balanced, and promotes the long-term sustainability and productivity of the economy. Through this strategy in 2019, the government of New Zealand delivered a budget surplus of NZ$7.5bn, up NZ$2bn on the previous year and very different from the NZ$1.2bn deficit recorded in 2014. ‘This allows the government to spend more on infrastructure and make record investments in health and education,’ the finance minister said. He claimed this was already under way following a NZ$10bn infrastructure spend in the 2018 budget. The national debt was also better than expected at 19.2% 10 of GDP, below the government’s self-imposed target. In New Zealand, monetary policy is comprised of the actions taken by the Reserve Bank of New Zealand (RBNZ) to influence the Official Cash Rate (OCR), which is the interest rate for overnight transactions between banks. Through that mechanism, the RBNZ changes monetary policy to meet its goals of price stability 15 while avoiding undue volatility in the economy and the exchange rate. This process is illustrated in Figure 11.9. 1 OCR 2 Interest rates Exchange rate 3 Economic activity Inflation expectations 4 CPI inflation Trading partner inflation Source: RBNZ ▲ Figure 11.9 Monetary policy process in New Zealand 162 308275_C11_CAM_IASAL ECO_146_163.indd 162 17/02/21 3:42 PM In 2019, the RBNZ cut the OCR to a record low of 1% to give the economy a boost. It has also said that it would like increased spending by the government to raise aggregate demand. 11 20 In practice the linkages in Figure 11.9 take varying lengths of time to influence The World Bank’s ‘Doing Business’ project looks at domestic firms and measures the local regulations applied to them. By analysing data to compare business regulation across economies, the relative ‘ease of doing business’ can be 30 calculated. Supplier-friendly regulations implemented over a number of years in New Zealand have led to increasing productivity and increasing productive capacity. The outcome was that in 2018 and again in 2019, New Zealand was placed first out of 190 economies in the World Bank’s ‘ease of doing business’ rankings. 11 Macroeconomic policy behaviour. Interest rate changes typically take 1 to 2 years to achieve their full impact on economic activity and inflation. So, the RBNZ has to look ahead in formulating monetary policy, often based on forecasts and judgement. Moreover, recent historically low interest rates have meant the RBNZ and 25 many other central banks have turned to ‘alternative’ monetary policies to expand their economies. a Explain what is meant by ‘progressive taxation’ (line 1). b Explain the likely effect of the change in the fiscal balance between 2014 and 2019 on the national debt of New Zealand. c ‘…recent historically low interest rates have meant the RBNZ and many other central banks have turned to “alternative” monetary policies to expand their economies’ (lines 24–26). Explain the need for and the operation of one ‘alternative’ monetary policy. d Explain, using the information provided, one supply-side reason why New Zealand has experienced ‘increasing productivity and increasing productive capacity’ (lines 31–32). e Explain, with reference to Figure 11.9, how an increase in interest rates can lead to a decrease in the consumer price index (CPI). Essay style 2 a C ompare the causes of an increase in a government’s budget surplus with the cause of an increase in the country’s national debt and consider whether an increase in the budget surplus will always lead to a reduction in the national debt. b Evaluate the extent to which fiscal policy focused on reduced taxation will move an economy toward its full-employment output level. CASE STUDY Macroeconomic policy instruments Governments in a modern economy have three main types of policy instrument for affecting the macroeconomy – monetary policy, fiscal policy and supply-side policy. Monetary policy is dedicated to ensuring the stability of the economy by influencing aggregate demand. Fiscal policy is used to influence aggregate demand and to maintain balance in the economy between public and private sectors and between present and future generations of citizens. Supply-side policies are dedicated to affecting the productive capacity of the economy, operating primarily through microeconomic incentives. Follow-up question Explain these distinctions between the types of policy instrument. Discuss the roles of each type of policy in meeting the government’s macroeconomic objectives. Go online at hoddereducation.com/cambridgeextras for another case study for Chapter 11. 163 308275_C11_CAM_IASAL ECO_146_163.indd 163 18/03/21 2:52 PM AS LEVEL PART 6 International economic issues AS LEVEL PART 6 INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC ISSUES 12 International trade and protectionism What this chapter covers ★ the distinction between absolute and comparative advantage ★ the economic arguments in favour of specialisation and free trade ★ the significance of the terms of trade ★ the limitations of the theories of absolute and comparative advantage ★ the meaning of protectionism in international trade ★ the tools of protectionism ★ evaluation of protectionism as a trade strategy International trade between countries is a well-established feature of the global economy. Economics can help to explain why international trade can be beneficial to the countries that engage in it. However, individual countries sometimes try to intervene to restrict trade in order to protect their domestic markets. These arguments are explained and evaluated in this chapter. 12.1 The reasons for international trade Trade between countries has become part of the global landscape, and enables consumers in a country to have an expanded range of choice of products. Consumers in the UK may like to buy mangoes, but these can only be obtained from abroad, as they cannot be grown in the UK. On the other hand, the UK may have expertise in professional services or infrastructure design and planning that a country such as Pakistan might be less fitted to produce. The central importance of international trade for growth and development has been recognised since the days of Adam Smith and David Ricardo. For example, during the Industrial Revolution a key factor was that Britain could bring in raw materials from its colonies for use in manufacturing activity. Today, consumers in the UK are able to buy and consume many goods that simply could not be produced within the domestic economy. In the twenty-first century most, if not all, countries engage in international trade to some extent. From the point of view of economic analysis, Ricardo showed that countries could gain from trade through a process of specialisation. Absolute and comparative advantage The notion of specialisation was briefly introduced in Chapter 1, where it was pointed out that the division of labour could enable efficiency gains. This analysis can now be extended to demonstrate the potential gains to be made from specialisation and trade. Consider a simple example. Ali and Ayesha supplement their incomes by making pots and bracelets to sell at a local market. Depending on how they divide their time, they can make differing combinations of these goods; some of the possibilities are shown in Table 12.1. Notice that Ayesha is much better at both activities than Ali. If they each devote all their time to producing pots, Ali produces only 12 to Ayesha’s 18. If they each produce only bracelets, Ali produces 12 and Ayesha 36. 164 308275_C12_CAM_IASAL ECO_164_181.indd 164 17/02/21 4:08 PM ▼ Table 12.1 Ali and Ayesha’s production Ali comparative advantage: the ability to produce a good relatively more efficiently (i.e. at lower opportunity cost) law of comparative advantage: a theory arguing that there may be gains from trade arising when countries (or individuals) specialise in the production of goods or services in which they have a comparative advantage Test yourself 12.1 Is the presence of absolute advantage sufficient to ensure that there are potential gains from specialisation and trade? Bracelets Pots Bracelets 12 0 18 0 9 3 12 12 6 6 6 24 3 9 3 30 0 12 0 36 This illustrates absolute advantage. Ayesha is simply better than Ali at both activities. Another way of looking at this is that, in order to produce a given quantity of a good, Ayesha needs less labour time than Ali. There is another significant feature of this table. Although Ayesha is better at producing both goods, the difference is much more marked in the case of bracelet production than for pot production. So Ayesha is relatively more proficient in bracelet production: in other words, she has a comparative advantage in making bracelets. This is reflected in differences in opportunity cost. If Ayesha switches from producing pots to producing bracelets, she gives up 6 pots for every 12 additional bracelets that she makes. The opportunity cost of an additional bracelet is thus 6/12 = 0.5 pots. For Ali, there is a oneto-one trade-off between the two, so his opportunity cost of a bracelet is 1 pot. 12 More interesting is what happens if the same calculation is made for Ali and pot making. Although Ayesha is absolutely better at making pots, if Ali increases his production of pots, his opportunity cost in terms of bracelets is still 1. But for Ayesha the opportunity cost of making pots in terms of bracelets is 12/6 = 2, so Ali has the lower opportunity cost. Although Ayesha has an absolute advantage in pot making, Ali has a comparative advantage. It is this difference in comparative advantage that gives rise to the gains from specialisation. The law of comparative advantage states that overall output can be increased if all individuals specialise in producing the goods in which they have a comparative advantage. Gains from international trade This same principle can be applied in the context of international trade. Suppose there are two countries – call them Overthere and Elsewhere. Each country can produce combinations of agricultural goods and manufactures. However, Overthere has a comparative advantage in producing manufactured goods, and Elsewhere has a comparative advantage in agricultural goods. Their respective PPCs are shown in Figure 12.1. Manufactures absolute advantage: the ability to produce a good more efficiently (e.g. with less labour) Pots 12 International trade and protectionism KEY TERMS Ayesha 70 60 50 Trading possibilities curve 40 30 PPC for Elsewhere 20 10 PPC for Overthere 0 0 20 40 60 80 Agricultural goods ▲ Figure 12.1 Trading possibilities for Overthere and Elsewhere 165 308275_C12_CAM_IASAL ECO_164_181.indd 165 17/02/21 4:08 PM The pattern of comparative advantage held by the two countries is reflected in the different slopes of the countries’ PPCs. In the absence of trade, each country is constrained to consume along its PPC. For example, if Elsewhere wants to consume 20 units of manufactures, it can consume a maximum of 20 units of agricultural goods. 12 AS LEVEL PART 6 INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC ISSUES KEY TERM trading possibilities curve: shows the consumption possibilities under conditions of free trade However, suppose that each country were to specialise in producing the product in which it has a comparative advantage. Overthere could produce 60 units of manufactures and Elsewhere could produce 60 units of agricultural goods. If each country were to specialise completely in this way, and if trade were to take place on a one-to-one basis (i.e. if one unit of manufactures is exchanged for one unit of agricultural goods), then it can be seen that this expands the consumption possibilities for both countries. The trading possibilities curve in Figure 12.1 shows the potential consumption points for each country in this situation. QUANTITATIVE SKILLS 12.1 Calculating opportunity cost ratios The key to comparative advantage is the difference in the opportunity costs faced by each country in the production of these goods. This can be calculated using Figure 12.1. First, notice that if Overthere chooses to increase output of agricultural goods by 10 units, it must sacrifice 20 units of manufactures, so the opportunity cost ratio is 2:1, meaning that for every unit of extra agricultural goods it must sacrifice 2 units of manufactures. However, for Elsewhere 10 units of manufactures are sacrificed if 10 more units of agricultural goods are to be produced, so the opportunity cost ratio is 1:1. Similarly, the opportunity cost ratios for manufactured goods are 0.5 for Overthere and 1 for Elsewhere. For example, if Elsewhere still wishes to consume 20 units of manufactures, with specialisation it could produce 60 units of agricultural goods, and exchange 20 units of them for 20 units of manufactures. It would then have its 20 units of manufactures, but have more agricultural goods than without trade. In this particular exchange, Overthere would now have 40 units of manufactures and 20 units of agricultural goods, and would also be better off than without trade. Test yourself 12.2 Country A’s opportunity cost ratio for good X relative to good Y is 3:1, compared with a ratio of 2:1 for country B. Which country should specialise in producing good X? It can be seen that in this situation trade may be mutually beneficial. Notice that this particular result of trading has assumed that the countries exchange the goods on a one-to-one basis. Although this makes both better off, it is not the only possibility. It is possible that exchange will take place at different prices for the goods, although it will only be mutually beneficial if the rate of exchange lies between the opportunity cost ratios of the two countries. The prices at which exchange takes place will determine which of the countries gains more from the trade that occurs. In the above example, specialisation and trade are seen to lead to higher overall production of goods. Although the examples have related to goods, you should be equally aware that services too may be a source of specialisation and trade. Who gains from international trade? KEY TERM trade liberalisation: a process of moving towards freer trade by removing restrictions on trade Specialisation can result in an overall increase in total production. However, one of the fundamental questions of economics introduced in Chapter 1 is ‘for whom?’ So far nothing has been said about which of the countries will gain from trade. It is possible that exchange can take place between countries in such a way that both countries are better off. But whether this will actually happen in practice depends on the prices at which exchange takes place. There have been many advocates of free trade, or at least of reducing restrictions on trade (a process known as trade liberalisation), but equally there have been many people who have resisted freeing up trade between countries. The World Bank has 166 308275_C12_CAM_IASAL ECO_164_181.indd 166 17/02/21 4:08 PM Figure 12.2 shows production possibility curves for two countries, each of which produces both coats and scooters. The countries are called ‘Here’ and ‘There’. 450 400 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 Here’s PPC There’s PPC 0 0 200 400 600 800 1,000 Coats ▲ Figure 12.2 Coats and scooters LEARNING LINK The role of the World Bank (and the International Monetary Fund) is discussed in Chapter 31. 12 a Suppose that Here produces 200 scooters and There produces 100: how many coats are produced in each country? b Now suppose that 300 scooters and 200 coats are produced by Here, and that There produces only coats. What has happened to the total production of coats and scooters? 12 International trade and protectionism Don’t forget the three fundamental questions of economics that were introduced in Chapter 1: what, how and for whom. They underpin economic analysis. EXERCISE 12.1 Scooters LEARNING LINK been among those who have been in favour of liberalising trade, and have recommended this strategy to less developed countries as a way of achieving economic growth and development. However, specialisation may bring dangers and risks, as well as benefits. One obvious way in which this may be relevant is that, by specialising, a country allows some sectors to run down. For example, suppose a country came to rely on imported food, and allowed its agricultural sector to waste away. If the country then became involved in a war, or for some other reason was unable to import its food, there would clearly be serious consequences if it could no longer grow its own foodstuffs. For this reason, many countries have in place measures designed to protect their agricultural sectors – or other sectors that are seen to be strategic in nature. This argument was key in the establishment of the Common Agricultural Policy in Europe. Overreliance on some commodities may also be risky. For example, the development of artificial substitutes for rubber had an enormous impact on the demand for natural rubber; this was reflected in falls in its price and caused difficulties for countries such as Malaysia that had specialised in producing rubber. ▲ Rubber tapping in Malaysia – a fall in prices caused problems for countries that specialise in producing rubber KEY TERM terms of trade: the ratio of export prices to import prices Exports, imports and the terms of trade When a country engages in international trade, it sells goods and services to buyers abroad and buys goods and services from overseas. In other words, the country exports goods and services in order to purchase imports of goods and services. The question of who gains from such trading depends not only on the volume of goods and services exported and imported, but also on the prices of these goods and services. A key factor that determines which of the countries will gain from trade – and whether trade will take place at all – is the relative prices at which trade takes place, known as the terms of trade. In practice, the relative prices are set in world markets, although it is possible that for some commodities there are countries large enough to influence prices. The terms of trade are defined as the ratio of export prices to import prices. 167 308275_C12_CAM_IASAL ECO_164_181.indd 167 17/02/21 4:27 PM QUANTITATIVE SKILLS 12.2 12 Calculating and interpreting the terms of trade AS LEVEL PART 6 INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC ISSUES Export and import prices are expressed as index numbers, based on a particular year. Suppose we want to know how the terms of trade for a country have changed in October 2019 relative to 2000. This can be done using the data in Table 12.2, which shows price indexes for exports and imports based on 2011 = 100. ▼ Table 12.2 The terms of trade STUDY TIP When interpreting the terms of trade index, be aware that an increase in the index means that the terms of trade have become more favourable, and if they fall, the terms of trade have worsened. STUDY TIP Price index of exports Price index of imports 2000 72.1 74.4 October 2019 94.8 95.7 First calculate the price index number for October 2019 based on 2000 = 100. The rebased price index for exports is 100 × 94.8/72.1 = 131.5. For the price of imports, the index is 128.6 (check this calculation to make sure you understand how to do it). These calculations show that prices of both exported and imported goods have risen over the period. The terms of trade represent the relative price change over the period, so for October 2019 we calculate the ratio of the price of exports to the price of imports. This is normally expressed as a percentage (i.e. as an index number), so the calculation is 100 × 131.5/128.6 = 102.3. The terms of trade increased by 2.3% between 2000 and October 2019. This indicates that the same volume of exports will purchase a greater volume of imports than in 2000. Notice that when the prices of both exports and imports are changing, it is their relative movement that determines what happens to the terms of trade. For example, if both export and import prices rise, but export prices rise proportionately more, the terms of trade will improve. A fall in the terms of trade indicates that the same volume of exports will purchase a smaller volume of imports than before. A downward movement in the terms of trade is thus unfavourable for an economy. Figure 12.3 shows the terms of trade for selected countries since 2000. You can see from this that different countries can experience changes in the terms of trade in very different ways in the same period of time. This depends strongly on the pattern of a country’s exports and imports. For the countries shown, Zambia’s exports are dominated by copper, so copper prices have a strong influence on the terms of trade. You can see that for Pakistan and Nepal, the terms of trade fell through much of the period. Sri Lanka showed relatively little variation. Index Be careful to avoid confusing the terms of trade (relative export and import prices) with the balance of trade (the difference between the volume of exports and imports). Date 250 New Zealand Zambia Pakistan Sri Lanka Nepal 200 150 100 50 2018 2017 2016 2015 2014 2013 2012 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 0 Source: based on data from World Development Indicators ▲ Figure 12.3 The terms of trade in selected countries, 2000–18 (2000 = 100) 168 308275_C12_CAM_IASAL ECO_164_181.indd 168 17/02/21 4:27 PM Test yourself 12.3 If the export prices for a country increase by 15% over a given period, but import prices rise by 20%, have the terms of trade improved or deteriorated? income terms of trade: the value of a country’s exports divided by the price of its imports: measures the purchasing power of a country’s exports in terms of the price of its imports LEARNING LINK The identity and characteristics of less developed countries (LDCs) are explored in Chapter 30. The terms of trade described above are known as the net barter terms of trade. As noted, the net barter terms of trade relate only to the relative prices of exports and imports, so do not take into account changes in the volume of exports and imports. The income terms of trade take the volume of trade into account, being defined as the value of a country’s exports divided by the price of imports. In other words, this measures the purchasing power of a country’s exports in terms of the price of its imports: a rise in the value of exports can more than offset an increase in the price of imports. It is possible for all countries to experience an increase in the income terms of trade simultaneously. Suppose that both export and import prices are rising through time, but import prices are rising more rapidly than export prices. This means that the ratio of export to import prices will fall – which in turn means that a country must export a greater volume of its goods in order to acquire the same volume of imports. In other words, a fall in the terms of trade makes a country worse off. Concerns have been raised about the effect of changes in the terms of trade for less developed countries (LDCs). One problem faced by LDCs that export primary products is that they are each too small as individual exporters to be able to influence the world price of their products. In other words, the problem for LDCs is that they have little market power in world markets, so they cannot influence the terms of trade that they face in their international transactions. They must accept the prices that are set in world commodity markets. 12 12 International trade and protectionism KEY TERM The terms of trade are calculated purely with respect to prices, and take no account of changing volumes of trade. In other words, a deterioration in the terms of trade does not necessarily mean that an economy is worse off, so long as the volume of trade is increasing sufficiently rapidly. The terms of trade change over time as the prices of exports and imports change. Economic analysis suggests that there are reasons to expect the terms of trade to be volatile in the short run, and to follow trends in the longer run. Neither of these may prove favourable for many LDCs. EXERCISE 12.2 In 2018, the terms of trade index for United Arab Emirates was 165.6 (based on 2000 = 100). For Bangladesh it was 62.2, and for the USA it was 99.8. Explain what is implied by these statistics. Limitations of the theory of absolute and comparative advantage The theory of absolute and comparative advantage seems to provide clear messages to countries that there are potential gains to be made from specialising in products in which a country has a comparative advantage, and engaging in international trade. But can a country be sure that these potential gains can be realised in practice? And how does a country identify the goods or services in which it should specialise? Two Swedish economists, Eli Heckscher and Bertil Ohlin, argued that a country’s comparative advantage would depend crucially on its relative endowments of factors of production. They argued that the optimal techniques for producing different commodities varied. Some commodities are most efficiently produced using labourintensive techniques, whereas others could be more efficiently produced using relatively capital-intensive methods. This suggests that if a country has abundant labour but scarce capital, then its natural comparative advantage would lie in the production of goods that require little capital but lots of labour. In contrast, a country with access to capital but facing a labour shortage would tend to have a comparative advantage in capital-intensive goods or services. 169 308275_C12_CAM_IASAL ECO_164_181.indd 169 17/02/21 4:27 PM Under these arguments, it would seem to make sense for LDCs to specialise in labouror land-intensive activities such as agriculture or other primary production. More economically developed countries could specialise in more capital-intensive activities such as manufacturing activity or financial services. By and large, this describes the way in which the pattern of world trade developed. However, some limitations of this approach have become apparent over time. In particular, the strategy that LDCs should specialise in primary production has come under criticism because of problems that arose in the short run and in the long run. 12 AS LEVEL PART 6 INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC ISSUES Short-run volatility Price In the case of agricultural goods, demand tends to be relatively stable over time, but supply can be volatile, varying with weather and climatic conditions from season to season. Figure 12.4 shows a typical market in two periods. In period 1 the global harvest of this commodity is poor, with supply given by S1: equilibrium is achieved with price at P1 and quantity traded at Q1. In period 2 the global harvest is high at S2, so that prices plummet to P2 and quantity traded rises to Q2. S1 S2 P1 P2 Demand 0 Q1 Q2 Quantity ▲ Figure 12.4 Volatility in supply Notice that in this case the movement of prices is relatively strong compared with the variation in quantity. This reflects the price elasticity of demand, which is expected to be relatively inelastic for many primary products. From the consumers’ point of view, the demand for foodstuffs and other agricultural goods will tend to be inelastic, as demand will not be expected to respond strongly to changes in prices. For many minerals and raw materials, however, the picture is different. For such commodities, supply tends to be stable over time, but demand fluctuates with the economic cycle in economically developed countries, which are the importers of raw materials. Figure 12.5 illustrates this. At the trough of the economic cycle, demand is low, at D1, and so the equilibrium price will also be low, at P1. At the peak of the cycle, demand is more buoyant, at D2, and price is relatively high, at P2. STUDY TIP Notice that export earnings in the face of volatility in prices depend on the elasticity of demand for exports as well as their price. From an individual country’s point of view, the result is the same: the country faces volatility in the prices of its exports. From this perspective it does not matter whether the instability arises from the supply side of the market or from the demand side. The problem is that prices can rise and fall quite independently of conditions within the domestic economy. Instability of prices also means instability of export revenues, so if the country is relying on export earnings to fund its development path, to import capital equipment or to meet its debt repayments, such volatility in earnings can constitute a severe problem: for example, if export earnings fall such that a country is unable to meet its commitments to repaying debt. 170 308275_C12_CAM_IASAL ECO_164_181.indd 170 17/02/21 4:27 PM Price Supply 12 P2 D1 0 D2 Q2 Q1 Quantity ▲ Figure 12.5 Volatility in demand Long-run deterioration The nature of the demand for primary products may be expected to influence the long-run path of relative prices. In particular, the income elasticity of demand is an important consideration. As real incomes rise in the high-income countries, the demand for agricultural goods can be expected to rise relatively slowly. Ernst Engel pointed out that at relatively high income levels, the proportion of expenditure devoted to foodstuffs tends to fall and the demand for luxury goods rises. This suggests that the demand for agricultural goods shifts relatively slowly through time. 12 International trade and protectionism P1 In the case of raw materials, there have been advances in the development of artificial substitutes for many commodities used in manufacturing. Furthermore, technology has changed over time, improving the efficiency with which inputs can be converted into outputs. This has weakened the demand for raw materials produced by LDCs. Price Furthermore, if some LDCs are successful in boosting output of these goods, there will be an increase in supply over time. Figure 12.6 shows the result of such an increase. Suppose that the market begins with demand at D0 and supply at S0. Market equilibrium results in a price of P0 and quantity of Q0. As time goes by, demand moves to the right a little to D1, and supply shifts to S1. The result is a fall in the price of the commodity to P1. S0 S1 P0 P1 D0 0 Q0 Q1 D1 Quantity ▲ Figure 12.6 Long-term movements of demand and supply 171 308275_C12_CAM_IASAL ECO_164_181.indd 171 17/02/21 4:28 PM It is clear that, not only may LDCs experience short-run volatility in prices, but the terms of trade may also deteriorate in the long run. AS LEVEL PART 6 INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC ISSUES 12 In the light of these twin problems, it is perhaps no surprise that many LDCs see themselves as trapped by their pattern of comparative advantage, rather than being in a position to exploit it. They are therefore reluctant to continue in such a state of dependency on (non-fuel) primary products, but the process of diversification into a wide range of products has been difficult to achieve. Test yourself 12.4 Explain why a long-run deterioration in the terms of trade for primary products is a problem for many less developed countries. A potential change in this pattern was seen in 2007 and 2008, with food prices rising rapidly. This included the prices of some staple commodities such as maize and rice. The net effect of this on LDCs was not clear. Countries in a position to export these commodities would benefit from the rise in prices – that is, an increase in their terms of trade. However, there are many LDCs that need to import these staple commodities and for them the terms of trade deteriorated. These trends were interrupted by the onset of recession in many high-income countries in 2008. The balance of market power LEARNING LINK The relationships between countries at different levels of development are explored in Chapter 31. Further problems faced by LDCs looking to increase their involvement in international trade are that they lack experience of trading in global markets, and are likely to find themselves having to compete with producers in high-income economies that are able to exert significant market power. This may mean that the gains from trade are more likely to go to the high-income economies, rather than to the LDCs. Taking these arguments together, it would seem that countries may not always be well advised to follow their natural pattern of comparative advantage too closely. This in turn suggests that there may be potential for countries to seek to alter the pattern of their comparative advantage by diversifying their economies and developing new specialisms in the face of changing patterns of global consumer demand. This is not an easy path for an economy to travel, and it may be tempting to turn instead to a more inward-looking protectionist strategy. The Covid-19 pandemic affected countries all around the world, and interrupted the flow of international trade, with consequences that have yet to be fully understood. SUMMARY: THE REASONS FOR INTERNATIONAL TRADE » The theory of absolute and comparative advantage » » » » suggests that a country can potentially gain from specialising in production and engaging in international trade. Absolute advantage reflects the ability to produce a good more efficiently than another individual, firm or country. Comparative advantage is the ability to produce a good relatively more efficiently (that is, at a lower opportunity cost). The trading possibilities curve shows the consumption possibilities under conditions of free trade. The potential gains from trade depend on the terms of trade, which influence how the gains from trade are distributed between the trading partners. » The terms of trade can be defined in terms of the ratio of export prices to import prices. » The nature of comparative advantage varies between countries according to the relative availability of factors of production. » This could be taken to suggest that a less developed country (LDC) should specialise in primary production, given the relative abundance of labour and land compared to capital. » However, prices of primary goods tend to be volatile in the short run, and may experience a fall relative to manufactured products over the long term. » In addition, LDCs may be at a disadvantage in entering global markets because of the greater experience and market power of high-income countries. 172 308275_C12_CAM_IASAL ECO_164_181.indd 172 17/02/21 4:28 PM 12.2 Protectionism KEY TERMS protectionism: measures taken by a country to restrict international trade tariff: a tax imposed on imported goods In spite of these potential gains from trade, countries have often seemed reluctant to open their economies fully to international trade, and have tended to intervene in various ways to protect their domestic producers: a process known as protectionism. Forms of protectionism When recession began to threaten in 2008, there was strong lobbying in several countries, including the USA, in favour of introducing protectionist measures. Indeed, in the lead-up to the G20 Summit in April 2009, the World Bank reported that the 17 members of that group had taken a total of 47 trade-restricting steps in the previous months. However, the drive towards globalisation has created a more integrated global economy, in which many firms rely on a global supply chain. With the production process fragmented between different parts of the world, the dangers of protectionism become more severe, and the possibilities of rapid contagion from a crisis become acute. 12 12 International trade and protectionism Comparative advantage is just one of many reasons for countries to engage in international trade. Trade enables consumers in a country to have access to products that could not be produced at home, and enables producers to have access to new markets and resources. In some cases it allows producers to take advantage of economies of scale that would not be possible if they had to rely only on selling to the domestic market. From the country’s perspective, export-led growth may be possible, and there are countries such as China and other countries in Southeast Asia that have benefited from this. It is also possible that exposure to competition from foreign firms provides a good incentive for domestic firms to become more efficient, raising the quality of their goods or the efficiency with which they are produced. Consumers may then gain from wider variety of available products, improved quality and lower prices. Tariffs A policy instrument commonly used in the past to give protection to domestic producers is the imposition of a tariff. Tariff rates have been considerably reduced in the period since the Second World War, but nonetheless are still in place. Figure 12.7 shows how a tariff is expected to operate. D represents the domestic demand for a commodity, and Sdom shows how much domestic producers are prepared to supply at any given price. The price at which the good can be imported from world markets is given by Pw. If dealing with a global market, it is reasonable to assume that the supply at the world price is perfectly elastic. So, in the absence of a tariff, domestic demand is given by D0, of which S0 is supplied within the domestic economy and the remainder (D0 − S0) is imported. If the government wishes to protect this industry within the domestic economy, it needs to find a way of restricting imports and encouraging home producers to expand their capacity. By imposing a tariff, the domestic price rises to Pw + T, where T is the amount of the tariff. This has two key effects. One is to reduce the demand for the good from D0 to D1; the second is to encourage domestic producers to expand their output of this good from S0 to S1. As a consequence, imports fall substantially to (D1 − S1). On the face of it, the policy has achieved its objective. Furthermore, the government has been able to raise some tax revenue (given by the green rectangle). 173 308275_C12_CAM_IASAL ECO_164_181.indd 173 17/02/21 4:28 PM Price 12 Sdom AS LEVEL PART 6 INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC ISSUES Pw + T Pw D 0 S0 S1 D1 D0 Quantity ▲ Figure 12.7 The effects of a tariff Test yourself 12.5 Identify the ways in which consumer surplus is reduced following the imposition of a tariff. LEARNING LINK Notice that the notions of consumer and producer surplus turn up again here. These were explained in Chapter 4. Test yourself 12.6 However, not all the effects of the tariff are favourable for the economy. Consumers are certainly worse off, as they have to pay a higher price for the good; they therefore consume less, and there is a loss of consumer surplus. Some of what was formerly consumer surplus has been redistributed to others in society. The government has gained the tariff revenue, as mentioned. In addition, producers gain some additional producer surplus, shown by the dark-blue area. There is also a welfare loss to society, represented by the red and pale-blue triangles. In other words, overall society is worse off as a result of the imposition of the tariff. Effectively, the government is subsidising inefficient local producers, and forcing domestic consumers to pay a price that is above that of similar goods imported from abroad. Some would defend this policy on the grounds that it allows the country to protect an industry, thus saving jobs that would otherwise be lost. However, this involves sacrificing the benefits of specialisation. In the longer term it may delay structural change. For an economy to develop new specialisations there needs to be a transitional process in which old industries contract and new ones emerge. Although this process may be painful, it is necessary in the long run if the economy is to remain competitive. Furthermore, the protection that firms enjoy that allows them to reap extra producer surplus from the tariff may foster complacency and an inward-looking attitude. This complacency is likely to lead to inefficiency, and an inability to compete in the global market. Even worse is the situation that develops where nations respond to tariffs raised by competitors by putting up tariffs of their own. This has the effect of further reducing the trade between countries, and everyone ends up worse off, as the gains from trade and specialisation are sacrificed. How would the effectiveness of a tariff be affected if domestic supply were highly inelastic? President Trump’s decision to extend the tariffs on steel to Canada, the EU and Mexico in 2018 brought an immediate response from those countries, threatening a trade war that would leave all involved worse off as a result. When tariffs against China were raised further, China responded with tariffs of its own. Although the World Trade Organization (WTO) is committed to reducing tariffs over time, retaliation in the form of ‘countervailing duties’ is permitted. KEY TERM Quotas quota: an agreement by a country to limit its exports to another country to a given quantity An alternative policy that a country may adopt is to limit the imports of a commodity to a given volume. For example, a country may come to an agreement with another country that only a certain quantity of imports will be accepted by the importing country. Such arrangements are sometimes known as quotas or voluntary export restraints (VERs). 174 308275_C12_CAM_IASAL ECO_164_181.indd 174 17/02/21 4:28 PM Price Figure 12.8 illustrates the effects of a quota. D represents the domestic demand for this commodity, and Sdom is the quantity that domestic producers are prepared to supply at any given price. Suppose that, without any agreement, producers from country A would be prepared to supply any amount of the product at a price PA. If the product is sold at this price, D0 represents domestic demand, of which S0 is supplied by domestic producers and the remainder (D0 − S0) is imported from country A. Sdom Quota P1 PA D S0 S1 D1 D0 Quantity ▲ Figure 12.8 The effects of a quota STUDY TIP Notice that the diagram for a quota is very like the diagram for a tariff. Make sure you do not confuse the two, as they differ in terms of who gains and who loses from the measure. 12 International trade and protectionism Stotal 0 12 By imposing a quota, total supply is now given by Stotal, which is domestic supply plus the quota of imports allowed into the economy from country A. The market equilibrium price rises to P1 and demand falls to D1, of which S1 is supplied by domestic producers and the remainder is the agreed quota of imports. Figure 12.8 shows who gains and who loses by this policy. Domestic producers gain by being able to sell at the higher price, so (as in the case of the tariff) they receive additional surplus given by the dark-blue area. Furthermore, the producers exporting from country A also gain, receiving the green rectangle (which, in the case of the tariff, was tax revenue received by the government). As in the case of the tariff, the two triangles (red and pale blue) represent the loss of welfare suffered by the importing country. Such an arrangement effectively subsidises the foreign producers by allowing them to charge a higher price than they would have been prepared to accept. Furthermore, although domestic producers are encouraged to produce more, the protection offered to them is likely to lead to inefficiency and weak attitudes towards competition. Embargoes Countries have sometimes used embargoes to prohibit imports of particular goods or imports from particular countries. Imports of certain goods may be embargoed because the products themselves are seen as being undesirable. For example, Australia prohibits the imports of chemical weapons and plant materials. The embargoing of imports from a country may be introduced as part of a political policy of sanctions against a country. In other cases, there may be an embargo on exporting to a country. For example, in 2006 the UN Security Council imposed sanctions on North Korea following North Korea’s first nuclear test. One downside of such a policy is that it may encourage smuggling activity. An export subsidy Another way in which a country may attempt to restrict trade is by subsidising domestic producers to enable them to compete more effectively with imports. Figure 12.9 illustrates a possible scenario. 175 308275_C12_CAM_IASAL ECO_164_181.indd 175 17/02/21 4:28 PM Price 12 Sdom A Pw + Sub Pw B C D AS LEVEL PART 6 INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC ISSUES S0 S1 D0 Quantity ▲ Figure 12.9 The effects of an export subsidy This shows domestic demand and supply for a product that can be imported at the world price Pw. Without intervention, demand is D0, of which S0 is supplied by domestic producers, with the remainder being imported. Assume that the country is too small a producer to affect the world price. If the government decides to pay a subsidy of an amount Sub to domestic producers, this affects the supply curve such that it is horizontal up to S1 in Figure 12.9. This encourages domestic firms to increase production up to S1, but unlike the case of the tariff, domestic consumers are still able to buy the good at the world price, so there is not the same impact on consumer surplus. Imports are D0 – S1, so this measure has reduced the country’s dependence on imported goods. Producers gain from this, receiving the additional producer surplus given by the dark-blue shaded area. However, this needs to be covered by the government, as does the area ABC in the figure, which represents the production inefficiency that was a welfare loss in the case of the tariff. The total cost to the government of providing the subsidy is thus the sum of the dark- and light-blue areas. The downside of this approach is that these funds need to be raised from elsewhere in the economy, thus distorting the allocation of resources in other markets. Although consumers are better off in respect of this product with the subsidy than with a tariff, as taxpayers they may pay the price in other ways. Furthermore, it is not clear that subsidising domestic production in this way provides any better incentives for efficiency than the tariff approach. If governments wish to encourage firms to become more efficient in order to compete, a better approach might be to subsidise education and training or research and development to improve production techniques, and thus tackle the problem more directly. Of course, this would depend on what was causing the inefficiency in the first place. At the WTO ministerial summit in Nairobi in 2015, it was agreed that developed economy members would eliminate all export subsidies immediately, and that developing country members would eliminate them by the end of 2018. Non-tariff barriers KEY TERM non-tariff barrier: an obstacle to free trade other than a tariff (e.g. quality standards imposed on imported products) There are other ways in which trade can be hampered, one example being the use of what are known as non-tariff barriers. These often comprise rules and regulations that control the standard of products that can be sold in a country. This is a grey area, as some of the rules and regulations may seem entirely sensible and apply equally to domestic and foreign producers. For example, laws that prohibit the sale of refrigerators that contain CFCs are designed to protect the ozone layer, and may be seen to be wholly appropriate. In this case, the regulation is for purposes other than trade restriction. However, there may be other situations in which a regulation is more clearly designed to limit trade. For example, the USA specifies a larger minimum size for vine-ripened 176 308275_C12_CAM_IASAL ECO_164_181.indd 176 17/02/21 4:28 PM tomatoes than for green tomatoes, thereby raising costs for the former. This has to do with trade because vine-ripened tomatoes are mainly imported from Mexico, but green tomatoes are mainly grown in Florida. Thus, the regulation gives Florida producers an advantage. Test yourself 12.7 EXERCISE 12.3 Figure 12.7 showed the effects of a tariff. If a country decides to remove the tariff, identify the effects on: a consumers of the good b producers of the good c the government Advantages and disadvantages of protectionism The debate about whether countries should engage in protectionism or allow free trade has a long history, and still does not seem to have been resolved, given the USA’s decision to raise tariffs in 2018 – and the impulse of other countries to respond in kind. Some of the arguments that have been advanced by politicians in favour of protectionism have little grounding in economic analysis. 12 International trade and protectionism Explain how trade would be affected if a country insisted that all imports of a particular product had to be imported through a single understaffed office. Such rules and regulations may operate against producers in less developed countries, who may find it especially difficult to meet demanding standards of production or to cope with excessive administrative burdens (‘red tape’). This applies in particular where such countries are trying to develop new skills and specialisations to enable them to diversify their exports and engage more actively in international trade. 12 There may be political reasons for wanting to protect domestic industries. For example, there may be strategic arguments that a country should always maintain an agricultural sector so as not to be overdependent on imported foodstuffs, as this could be disastrous in the event of war. Such arguments were used in setting up the Common Agricultural Policy in Europe. President Trump’s arguments for imposing a levy on steel imports in 2018 similarly claimed that the USA’s steel industry was suffering from unfair competition, which was a threat to national security. KEY TERMS dumping: where domestic producers face competition from imported goods that are priced below marginal cost, perhaps as a result of export subsidies sunset industry: an industry in decline that needs protection for its displaced workers infant industry: an industry that needs protection from international competition in the short run so that it can learn to become competitive A country may find that it faces competition from foreign producers which have had the benefit of export subsidies from their government. This means that they have been shielded from facing the full costs of production, so have been given an unfair advantage in international trade. This might be seen as dumping, by which the foreign producers are able to undercut domestic producers, rather than facing the full cost of their production activities. The imposition of a tariff may then be justified in allowing domestic producers to compete on fairer terms. This may also guard against the possibility that competition will force domestic firms out of business, leaving the importing producers with a monopoly. Some have also argued that domestic industries should be protected because of the impact of high unemployment among workers displaced from declining sectors – so-called sunset industries. This is really an argument about the period of transition to more open trade, as it could also be noted that workers released from those declining sectors could, in time, be redeployed in sectors that are more efficient in comparative advantage terms. A common line of argument is about the need to protect so-called infant industries. This may be especially important in the context of less developed countries wanting to develop their manufacturing sectors. The argument is that protecting a domestic industry from international competition will allow the new firms to become familiar with the market so that in the longer term they will be able to compete. A problem with both infant and sunset industries is that once protection is put in place, it is difficult to remove. The infants may never grow up and declining sectors may never expire completely. 177 308275_C12_CAM_IASAL ECO_164_181.indd 177 17/02/21 4:28 PM The impact of protectionism Why might overprotection of an infant industry be ineffective in allowing the industry to compete in global markets? Consumers Protectionist policies have a number of effects on economic agents in a country. These effects differ according to which policy is in operation, but are most clearly illustrated with reference to the imposition of a tariff, which is the most common form of protectionist policy. In general, consumers are likely to be worse off as a result of protectionist measures. Consumer surplus is lower after a tariff is imposed, as consumers must pay a higher price for the good, and will consume less. AS LEVEL PART 6 INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC ISSUES 12 Test yourself 12.8 Producers Producers in the domestic economy will gain from protection, as they will receive higher producer surplus (at the expense of consumers). However, their incentives to produce efficiently will be low, so in the long run they may never become able to compete effectively in world markets. The infant industry benefits are rarely delivered. Governments When a government imposes a tariff, it gains by the revenue that it raises. This may be valuable for the government of a less developed country that faces problems with raising revenue through other forms of taxation because of the lack of an adequate administrative structure. The balance of payments will be affected, as imports will fall after the imposition of a tariff. Whether domestic production will actually rise to compensate will depend on the elasticity of supply. If home producers are unable to respond by increasing production, then the benefits from the tariff will be lower. Living standards For society as a whole, the imposition of a tariff imposes costs on society, so overall wellbeing is lower with a tariff in place. Equality Protectionist measures entail a redistribution of resources, from consumers to producers, so there may be an increase in inequality in the society. For example, as explained above, the imposition of a tariff means that the domestic price of a good will rise, which leads to a fall in consumer surplus, some of which becomes an increase in producer surplus. This represents a redistribution of income away from consumers. SUMMARY: PROTECTIONISM » Although comparative advantage suggests that countries can potentially gain from engaging in international trade, there is often a temptation to interfere with free trade. » Countries may wish to protect their domestic industries from international competition. » A common protectionist tool is a tariff – a tax placed on imports of a good. » A tariff has the effect of reducing imports of a good, but there is a welfare loss associated with it. » A quota has a similar effect to a tariff, but benefits foreign producers without providing revenue to the home government. » An export subsidy can be used to encourage home producers to export more, but this is costly from the perspective of the home government. » Non-tariff barriers are administrative rules and regulations that make it more difficult for foreign producers to meet local requirements. » Protectionist policies have a number of effects on economic agents in a country. 178 308275_C12_CAM_IASAL ECO_164_181.indd 178 17/02/21 4:28 PM END OF CHAPTER QUESTIONS 2 Infant industries are often criticised for becoming complacent and inefficient due to government protection, so they fail to grow and develop economies of scale. What can the government do to prevent this? A expose infant industries to more competition B only choose to protect manufacturing industries C combine tariffs on imports with import quotas D encourage the formation of monopolies through mergers and acquisitions Data response 1 Read the following extract and then answer the questions that follow. Comparative advantage, trade and protectionism 12 12 International trade and protectionism Multiple choice 1 In a world with two countries and two products only, if Country A has greater factor endowment, it would have the absolute advantage in both products. What explains why Country B can also participate in international trade? A Country A is more abundant in resources than Country B. B Country B negotiates more favourable conditions of international trade. C Country B’s domestic opportunity cost in one of the products is lower than Country A’s. D Country B’s PPC lies further to the left of Country A’s PPC. In countries such as Indonesia and the Philippines where labour is abundant, but capital relatively scarce, the law of comparative advantage would suggest the country should specialise in labour- or land-intensive activities such as agriculture or other primary production. Indeed, Indonesia and the Philippines 5 account for most of the world’s production of coconuts. More recently, the palm oil industry has expanded in these countries. Unlike coconut production, which is dominated by smallholders, about 60% of palm oil is grown on large plantations. The palm oil corporations get ample government support in the form of export subsidies, scientific research and even lobbying to 10 keep export markets open. Some coconut farmers say they need the same kind of support from the government if they are to continue exporting. ▲ A large palm oil plantation in Indonesia Palm oil is not a common edible oil in China because the oil palm grows only in the extreme southern part of the country. The production of the oil has been small, and its consumption was originally limited to local areas. However, 15 changes in consumer tastes have meant the demand for the foods that use palm oil in their processing has increased dramatically, such that in 2020 China 179 308275_C12_CAM_IASAL ECO_164_181.indd 179 17/02/21 4:35 PM removed palm oil from its import quota management list. This will increase Chinese imports of palm oil from Indonesia and the Philippines, expanding this key market at a time when environmental concerns elsewhere fuel opposition to 20 the product. 12 International trade is assumed to benefit both the exporter and the importer. However, the question of who gains from such trading depends largely on the prices of the goods. 25 Table 12.3 provides data on the average indexed prices of imports and exports AS LEVEL PART 6 INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC ISSUES to and from the Philippines. ▼ Table 12.3 Index of export and import prices for the Philippines, January 2018–January 2020 (2000 = 100) Index of export prices Index of import prices January 2018 109.15 116.94 January 2019 107.55 119.32 January 2020 105.82 119.91 Source: tradingeconomics.com a Explain, with the use of an example, why export subsidies (line 9) can be viewed as a form of protectionism. b With reference to Table 12.3, calculate the change in the terms of trade between January 2019 and January 2020, and explain one reason why this could be unfavourable for the Philippines. c Explain the operational impact of one non-tariff barrier to trade referred to in the extract (other than an export subsidy). d Explain, with reference to the extract, the advantage to China of engaging in greater palm oil trade with Indonesia and the Philippines. e Discuss the benefit in the short run to the Philippines of specialising in agricultural production as suggested by the law of comparative advantage. Essay style 2 a With the use of a numerical example explain what is meant by a country having a comparative advantage in the production of a good and consider whether trade will always be beneficial between two countries when a comparative advantage exists. b A ssess the impact on domestic economic welfare when a protectionist tariff is imposed on imports to a country. CASE STUDY International trade and the Covid-19 pandemic The Covid-19 pandemic had an unprecedented impact on economies throughout the world, not least in its impact on international trade. The impact on trade was most significant in the trade for medical supplies, especially in relation to products for prevention, testing and treatment. According to the World Trade Organization (WTO), medical products in normal times have comprised about 5% of total world trade. The USA, Germany and China account for 34% of world imports of medical goods; Germany, the USA and Switzerland supply 35% of medical products to the world. The top ten exporters supply almost three-quarters of world exports of these goods. As the pandemic took off in early 2020, it soon became apparent that some countries (such as Germany) were better prepared for dealing with a pandemic than others, and there was a widespread global shortage of protective equipment necessary for medical staff treating Covid-19 patients. Members of the WTO face rules about the imposition of quantitative restrictions on exports of particular goods, but temporary prohibitions are permitted ‘to prevent or relieve critical shortages of foodstuffs or other products essential to the exporting member’. Some countries faced with serious domestic 180 308275_C12_CAM_IASAL ECO_164_181.indd 180 18/03/21 2:54 PM shortages of protective equipment took advantage of this and restricted exports to secure supplies for their own citizens. By April 2020, some 80 countries were thought to have imposed such prohibitions, although this only includes the countries that had formally notified the WTO that they were in place. One response to this may be that countries will begin to develop local capacity to produce. In the long run, this may have the effect of reducing global trade interdependencies. It may also be that in order to allow these new activities to survive and grow, some countries will raise tariffs to protect these infant industries. Other countries may react by imposing export restrictions of their own. As the pandemic grew, there was a search for treatments and vaccines. This also produced temptation for countries to adopt protectionist attitudes. For example, a US company produced a treatment that was effective in shortening hospital stays for Covid-19 patients. The USA promptly Follow-up questions a If a country that is a significant global supplier of a good prohibits exports, how will the domestic price of the good be affected? b What would be the effect on world prices of the good? c How will export prohibition affect the incentives faced by domestic producers? d Who benefits and who loses from the prohibition of exports? e Discuss the relative merits of protectionism and openness in the context of the pandemic. 12 12 International trade and protectionism Such measures are likely to have economic effects. In particular, relative domestic and world prices may be affected, and protectionism may reduce the extent to which countries are prepared to work collaboratively. secured the entire supply for a 3-month period. In July 2020, the New York Times reported that there were 155 teams of researchers worldwide working on producing a vaccine. Further evidence of the lack of international collaboration were the rumours circulating of attempts to hack vaccine research progress. As vaccines became available, there were squabbles between countries over their distribution. The losers from this protectionism are likely to be many less developed countries that find themselves struggling to contain the virus. Go online at hoddereducation.com/cambridgeextras for another case study for Chapter 12. 181 308275_C12_CAM_IASAL ECO_164_181.indd 181 18/03/21 2:55 PM AS LEVEL PART 6 International economic issues AS LEVEL PART 6 INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC ISSUES 13 The balance of payments and exchange rates What this chapter covers ★ components of the balance of payments accounts, ★ ★ ★ ★ with a particular focus on the current account how to calculate the current account balance (CAB) causes and consequences of imbalances in the current account the definition of the exchange rate how the exchange rate is determined in a floating exchange regime ★ causes of changes in a floating exchange rate ★ the impact of exchange rate changes on macroeconomic equilibrium in the AD/AS model ★ the relationship between macroeconomic policy and the current account of the balance of payments Most economies in the world are open economies – they engage in international trade, exporting and importing goods and services, albeit to varying degrees. This chapter analyses these transactions, and explores ways in which the domestic economy can be influenced by the international environment. This requires discussion of the balance of payments and the foreign exchange (Forex) market. 13.1 The balance of payments KEY TERM balance of payments: a set of accounts showing the transactions conducted between residents of a country and the rest of the world STUDY TIP Don’t forget that it is the direction of currency flows that distinguishes between exports and imports. Exports cause an inflow of currency, whereas imports cause a currency outflow. Test yourself 13.1 Explain why the balance of payments must always balance overall. When a country engages in international trade, it is important to be able to keep track of the various transactions that take place between the residents of a country and the rest of the world. The balance of payments is the set of accounts that monitors these transactions. For an individual household it is important to monitor incomings and outgoings, as items purchased must be paid for in some way – either by using income or savings, or by borrowing. In a similar way, a country has to pay for goods, services or assets that are bought from, or sold to, other countries. The balance of payments accounts enable the analysis of such international transactions. As with the household, transactions can be categorised as either incoming or outgoing items. For example, if a car made in Malaysia is exported (i.e. purchased by a non-resident of Malaysia), this is an ‘incoming’ item, as the payment for the car is a credit item for Malaysia. On the other hand, the purchase of Thai pineapples (an import) is a debit item. Similarly, all other transactions entered into the balance of payments accounts can be identified as credit or debit items, depending on the direction of the payment. In other words, when money flows into the country as the result of a transaction, that is a credit; if money flows out, it is a debit. As all items have to be paid for in some way, the overall balance of payments when everything is added together must be zero. However, individual components can be positive or negative. It is important to be able to monitor these transactions because of the increasing interconnectedness of economies through the process of international trade – a process known as globalisation. This is the way in which economies have become more and more linked as a result of rapid changes in the technology of communications and transport, and with increasing deregulation of markets. The onset of the Covid-19 pandemic in 2020 caused enormous disruption to international trade, hopefully temporarily. The UK’s decision to reduce its dependence on the EU through Brexit goes against the trend 182 308275_C13_CAM_IASAL ECO_182_196.indd 182 17/02/21 4:40 PM KEY TERMS financial account of the balance of payments: account identifying transactions in financial assets between the residents of a country and the rest of the world capital account of the balance of payments: account identifying transactions in (physical) capital between the residents of a country and the rest of the world reserve assets: stocks of foreign assets (e.g. foreign currency or gold) owned by the central bank of a country to enable it to meet any mismatch between the demand and supply of a country’s currency LEARNING LINK The significance of the financial and capital accounts is discussed in Chapter 29, but for now we focus on the current account. LEARNING LINK 13 This process of globalisation, by which economies have become increasingly interconnected, is discussed in Chapter 32. In line with international standards (as set out by the International Monetary Fund (IMF)), the balance of payments accounts are divided into three categories: the current account, the capital account and the financial account. In addition, it is important to identify transactions in reserve assets. Taken together, these items should all sum to zero, as the overall balance of payments must always be in balance. However, because it is not possible to record everything accurately, a final item called ‘errors and omissions’ or the ‘balancing item’ ensures overall balance. The current account The current account identifies transactions in goods and services, together with income payments and international transfers. Income payments here include compensation of employees, which is where an employee and employer are located in different countries. Also important are payments of investment income. Transfers are mainly transactions between governments and workers’ remittances. Flows of bilateral aid and social security payments abroad are also included here. Commentators in the media often focus on the current account. Three main items appear on this account: 13 The balance of payments and exchange rates current account of the balance of payments: account identifying transactions in goods and services between the residents of a country and the rest of the world, together with income payments and international transfers towards globalisation, and the success of this decision will depend on whether the UK is able to develop new links with economies elsewhere in the world. » Trade in goods and services » Primary income » Secondary income (transfers) Trade in goods and services The balance of trade in goods and services is simply the balance between exports and imports of goods and services. Notice that not all of the trade carried on involves physical goods; the trade in services is also important. The trade in goods is known as visible trade, and the trade in services is known as invisible trade. In looking at the components of the current account of the balance of payments, it is the balance between positive and negative elements that is important. For example, the balance between exports of goods and services (i.e. exports minus imports) is a component of aggregate demand. QUANTITATIVE SKILLS 13.1 Calculate the balance of an item in the balance of payments accounts In 2018, exports of goods from China were estimated as $2,417.4 billion and imports were $2,022.3 billion. The balance of trade in goods was therefore total exports of goods minus imports of goods: that is, $2,417.4bn – $2,022.3bn = +$395.1bn. In other words, there was a net surplus in trade in goods. In a similar way, we can calculate balances for the trade in services, and in goods and services combined. The overall balance taking into account all of the items that are part of the current account (including primary and secondary income) is known as the current account balance (CAB), and is an important indicator of the performance of an economy. 183 308275_C13_CAM_IASAL ECO_182_196.indd 183 17/02/21 4:40 PM AS LEVEL PART 6 INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC ISSUES 13 LEARNING LINK Net exports comprise an important part of aggregate demand, as is discussed in Chapter 7. Trade policies and negotiations are discussed in Chapter 32. EXERCISE 13.1 In Pakistan in 2018, exports of goods were estimated at $24.8 billion and exports of services were $5.3 billion. Imports of goods were $57.4 billion and imports of services $10.4 billion. The balance in secondary income was +$24.1 billion. Calculate the overall balance for trade in goods and services. The process of trading with other countries creates important connections across national borders. After all, exports from one country become the imports of its trading partners. In principle, this suggests that overall the sum of all countries’ trade balances should be zero. In practice, this will not be the case – if only because of data inaccuracies and mis-recordings. However, it is important to realise that the demand for a country’s exports depends in part on economic conditions in its trading partners. Primary income Primary income is the second important item in the current account. This comprises compensation to employees and earnings accruing to domestic citizens on past investment abroad (less income earned by overseas residents who own assets in the domestic economy). The primary income balance for Pakistan in 2018 showed a relatively small deficit of $5.5 billion. Secondary income Test yourself 13.2 Would an inflow of foreign direct investment be included as part of the current account of the balance of payments? Secondary income is made up of current transfers. These include taxes and social contributions received from non-resident workers and businesses, bilateral aid flows and military grants. For Pakistan in 2018, this part of the current account showed a surplus of $24.1 billion, part of which was transfers in the form of aid from abroad. Secondary income also includes remittances, where an individual works abroad but remits part of their income back to a family in the home country. For Pakistan, such remittances made up about 60% of the secondary income balance in 2018. It is important to realise that the overall balance on the current account arises from combining the balances on all of these items. An overall current account deficit arises when the deficit items outweigh the surplus items in the accounts. It is also important to realise that a deficit on the current account must be balanced by a surplus on the financial and capital accounts if the overall balance of payments is to be in balance. In the short run, it may be possible to finance a trade deficit by selling domestic financial assets to foreigners, or by borrowing from overseas. However, this might not be regarded as being desirable in the longer term if it affects the overall ownership pattern of assets. For this reason, the current account cannot be viewed in isolation from the rest of the balance of payments. Causes and consequences of imbalances in the current account As already mentioned, the overall balance of payments (combining the credit and debit items from all three accounts) must always be zero because outgoings must be equal to incomings – in other words, everything must be paid for. However, this does not mean that each of the three accounts will always balance, and imbalances can arise for a number of reasons. In the UK economy, the current account has been in deficit every year since 1984. China has shown a surplus on the current account in every year since 1990 (except in 1993). There are several possible causes of an imbalance on the current account of the balance of payments. » Changes in the structure of economic activity affect the pattern of trade in goods and services. 184 308275_C13_CAM_IASAL ECO_182_196.indd 184 17/02/21 4:40 PM » The competitiveness of domestic production relative to other countries is important. If productivity at home is weak, or if domestic firms are producing poor-quality products, then the demand for exports will be relatively low. » If inflation in the home country is high relative to elsewhere, this will again discourage exports and encourage imports. With high inflation, rising labour costs can fuel this process. » Rapid economic growth can draw in imports and contribute to a current account deficit. % of GDP STUDY TIP The data here show the balances on the component items of the current account as a percentage of GDP. This helps to put the data into perspective, but also is a way of removing the effect of changing prices over time. 10 Trade in goods Trade in services Primary income Secondary income CAB 5 0 –5 –10 –15 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 13 The balance of payments and exchange rates Figure 13.1 shows the components of the current account in India since 2010 together with the overall balance. You can see that overall, it is the trade in goods that has the strongest impact on the overall current account balance, with the overall balance on the current account (CAB) tracking the trade in goods quite closely. The deficit in the trade in goods has been partially offset by surpluses in the trade in services and secondary income (transfers). For India, trade in services has been strong given its strength in professional services. 13 2018 Source: calculated using data from World Development Indicators ▲ Figure 13.1 The composition of the current account of the balance of payments in India since 2010 (balances, % of GDP) QUANTITATIVE SKILLS 13.2 Reading a composite graph Test yourself 13.3 Looking at Figure 13.1, which items contributed to the smaller current account deficit in 2016? You may not have met a composite graph like Figure 13.1 before. Effectively, there are two graphs here superimposed on each other. The bars on the graph show the component items of the current account and the way they change through time. Credit items are shown above the line. In this case, these are trade in services and secondary income. Debit items (trade in goods and primary income) are shown below the line. These are stacked for each year, and show you their relative size as well as whether they are positive or negative balances. The line that is superimposed on the bars is the overall current account balance. This, of course, is the sum of the individual components. The fact that it is negative throughout this period indicates that the combined debit items exceed the combined credit items. Notice that the data here have been expressed as a percentage of GDP. As the data are measured in current prices, steps have to be taken to remove the effect of changing prices through time. This pattern is not unique. For example, trade in goods has traditionally shown a deficit for the UK – it has shown a surplus in only 6 years since 1950. On the other hand, trade in services has recorded a surplus in every year since 1966. This imbalance partly reflects changes in the pattern of economic activity in the UK, with 185 308275_C13_CAM_IASAL ECO_182_196.indd 185 17/02/21 4:40 PM manufacturing in decline and services expanding. Exports of cars and consumer goods have typically shown a significant deficit, whereas services such as insurance and financial services have been in surplus. 13 AS LEVEL PART 6 INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC ISSUES This and the other causes outlined above are all concerned with the relative competitiveness of goods produced domestically compared with those produced abroad. If a country loses international competitiveness, then net exports are likely to fall, thus reducing aggregate demand and potentially resulting in an increase in unemployment. To some extent, these effects can be mitigated through exchange rate movements, as is discussed in the next section of this chapter. There is an important consequence that arises if persistent deficits are being sustained over long periods of time. A deficit on the current account must be balanced by a surplus on the financial and capital accounts if the overall balance of payments is to be zero. For an economy like the UK, it may be possible to finance the trade deficit in the short run by selling UK financial assets to foreigners or by borrowing from overseas. However, this might not be regarded as being desirable in the longer term if this affects the overall ownership pattern of British assets. For this reason, the current account cannot be viewed in isolation from the rest of the balance of payments. % of GDP Figure 13.2 shows that the situation for the current account of the balance of payments in China is very different. Trade in goods again dominates the pattern, but this item has shown a consistent and strong surplus throughout the period, partly offset by a deficit in the trade in services. Notice that in the late 2010s the surplus on trade in goods declined somewhat while the deficit on trade in services remained fairly constant. 6 Trade in goods Trade in services Primary income Secondary income CAB 5 4 3 2 1 0 –1 –2 –3 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 Source: calculated using data from World Development Indicators ▲ Figure 13.2 The composition of the current account of the balance of payments in China since 2010 (balances, % of GDP) SUMMARY: THE BALANCE OF PAYMENTS » The balance of payments is a set of accounts showing the transactions conducted between the residents of a country and the rest of the world. » The accounts are made of separate components: the current account, capital account and financial accounts, together with an ‘errors and omissions’ item. Changes in the holdings of reserve assets may also feature in some countries. » The current account of the balance of payments identifies transactions in goods and services together with flows of primary and secondary income. » The balances on each component of the current account contribute to the overall current account balance (CAB). » Any imbalance on the current account must be countered by an opposite balance on the financial and capital account to ensure that the overall balance of payments is zero. » Imbalances on the current account reflect changes in the structure of economic activity in a country and its relative competitiveness compared with its trading partners. 186 308275_C13_CAM_IASAL ECO_182_196.indd 186 17/02/21 4:40 PM 13.2 Exchange rates exchange rate: the price of one currency in terms of another Test yourself 13.4 LEARNING LINK The notion of a derived demand is explained in Chapter 4. Chapter 4 introduced the notion of the demand and supply of foreign currency in the diagram reproduced here as Figure 13.3. This uses ringgits as an example, with the vertical axis representing the price of Malaysian ringgits in terms of US dollars. The demand for ringgits arises from people holding US dollars wanting to purchase Malaysian goods, services or assets, whereas the supply comes from holders of ringgits wanting to purchase US goods, services or assets. The balance of payments accounts itemise these transactions, which entail the demand for and supply of ringgits. Notice that the demand for currency is a derived demand – thus ringgits are demanded when people holding dollars or other currencies want to buy Malaysian goods, services or assets. Similarly, ringgits are supplied when Malaysians want to buy foreign goods, services or assets. Supply 13 13 The balance of payments and exchange rates Suppose that the exchange rate between US dollars and euros is 0.8 (€ per $). If you have 60 euros, what would be the value in dollars? Closely associated with the balance of payments is the exchange rate – the price of one currency in terms of another. The exchange rate is important because it influences the prices that domestic consumers must pay for imported goods, services and assets, and also the price that foreigners pay for domestically produced goods, services and assets. A foreign exchange transaction is needed whenever trade takes place. If you buy goods from abroad, you need to purchase foreign exchange – say, dollars – and you have to supply some of your own currency in order to buy dollars. For example, if a French tourist in the UK buys UK goods or services, the transaction needs to be carried out in pounds, so there is a demand for pounds. Exchange rate (price of ringgits in dollars) KEY TERM e* Demand 0 Quantity of ringgits per period ▲ Figure 13.3 The market for ringgits The demand curve in Figure 13.3 is downward sloping because when the $/RM rate is low, Malaysian goods, services and assets are relatively cheap in terms of dollars, so demand is relatively high. On the other hand, when the $/RM rate is relatively high, Americans receive fewer ringgits for their dollars, so the demand for ringgits will be relatively low. Test yourself 13.5 How would the market for sterling be affected if Europeans find British goods less attractive after Brexit? The supply curve of ringgits is upward sloping. When the $/RM rate is relatively high, the supply of ringgits will be relatively strong, as Malaysian residents will get plenty of dollars for their ringgits and thus will demand American goods, services and assets, supplying ringgits in order to buy the foreign exchange needed for the transactions. When the $/RM rate is low, US goods, services and assets will be relatively expensive for Malaysian residents, so fewer ringgits will be supplied. The market is in equilibrium at e*, where the demand for ringgits is just matched by the supply of ringgits. This position has a direct connection with the balance of payments. If the demand for ringgits exactly matches the supply of ringgits, this implies that there is a balance between the demand from Malaysians for US goods, services and assets and the demand by US residents for Malaysian goods, services and assets. In other words, the balance of payments is in overall balance. 187 308275_C13_CAM_IASAL ECO_182_196.indd 187 17/02/21 4:40 PM In analysing the balance of payments, the relative competitiveness of domestically produced goods and services is an important issue. The exchange rate plays a key role in this process. If a country persistently shows a deficit on the current account, does that imply that the goods that it produces are uncompetitive in international markets? Consider the situation from the perspective of the Malaysian economy. The demand for Malaysian exports in world markets depends on a number of factors. In some ways, it is similar to the demand for a good. In general, the demand for a good depends on its price, on the prices of other goods, and on consumer incomes and preferences. In a similar way, you can think of the demand for Malaysian exports as depending on the price of Malaysian goods, the price of other countries’ goods, incomes in the rest of the world and foreigners’ preferences for Malaysian goods over those produced elsewhere. However, in the case of international transactions the exchange rate is also relevant, as this determines the purchasing power of Malaysian incomes in the rest of the world. Similarly, the demand for imports into Malaysia depends on the relative prices of domestic and foreign goods, incomes in Malaysia, preferences for foreign and domestically produced goods and the exchange rate. These factors will all come together to determine the balance of demand for exports and imports. The exchange rate plays a key role in influencing the levels of both imports and exports, and thus affects the balance of payments, so the way it changes over time and the way in which it is determined is important. Figure 13.4 shows the $/Pakistan rupee exchange rate since 2000. This seems to suggest that the exchange rate remained fairly stable until about 2007, after which it declined steadily. This decline between 2007 and 2018 suggests that, other things being equal, there was a gradual decline in the international competitiveness of Pakistan’s goods. There is discussion of international competitiveness in Chapter 29, which also considers the effects of fixing a currency in terms of the dollar or some other currency. For now, we focus on how exchange rates are determined when allowed to adjust to the free-market equilibrium. KEY TERM floating exchange rate system: a system in which the exchange rate is permitted to find its own level in the market 0.02 0.018 0.016 0.014 0.012 0.01 0.008 0.006 0.004 0.002 0 20 0 20 0 0 20 1 02 20 0 20 3 04 20 0 20 5 06 20 0 20 7 0 20 8 09 20 1 20 0 1 20 1 12 20 1 20 3 1 20 4 1 20 5 16 20 1 20 7 18 LEARNING LINK Exchange rate (US$/rupee) AS LEVEL PART 6 INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC ISSUES 13 Source: calculated using data from World Development Indicators ▲ Figure 13.4 The US$/Pakistan rupee exchange rate However, some care is needed because other things do not remain equal. In particular, remember that the competitiveness of domestic goods in overseas markets depends not only on the exchange rate, but also on movements in the prices of goods over time, so this needs to be taken into account. In other words, if the prices of Pakistan’s goods have risen more rapidly than prices in the USA in this period, this will have partly offset the downward movement in the exchange rate. The determination of the exchange rate in a floating exchange rate regime The way in which a country’s exchange rate is determined has important implications for the balance of payments, and for macroeconomic policy. Viewing the foreign exchange market as a variant of the demand and supply model seems to suggest that the exchange rate will be determined by the interaction of demand and supply. If the market were to be left to find its way to equilibrium, this is exactly what would happen, and where this is permitted to happen, it is known as a floating exchange rate system. 188 308275_C13_CAM_IASAL ECO_182_196.indd 188 17/02/21 4:40 PM Under a floating exchange rate system, the value of the currency is allowed to find its own way to equilibrium. This means that the overall balance of payments is automatically assured, and the monetary authorities do not need to intervene to make sure it happens. In practice, however, governments have tended to be wary of leaving the exchange rate entirely to market forces, and there have been occasional periods in which intervention has been used to affect the market rate. KEY TERMS appreciation: a rise in the exchange rate in a floating exchange rate system Causes of changes in the exchange rate If the foreign exchange market is left free to find its own way to equilibrium, there are several reasons for the exchange rate to change. The key factors that determine the exchange rate in a floating rate system are: » » » » » relative inflation rates the trade balance net investment in the domestic economy speculation relative interest rates and monetary policy 13 The balance of payments and exchange rates depreciation (of a currency): a fall in the exchange rate in a floating exchange rate system If the foreign exchange market is left free to find its own way to equilibrium, it becomes important to consider what factors will influence the level of the exchange rate. Notice that under a floating exchange rate system, a fall in the value of a currency is known as a depreciation, whereas an increase is known as an appreciation. For example, between 2001 and 2003, the exchange rate between the Pakistan rupee and the US dollar rose from 0.0161 to 0.0173 (rupees per dollar), which was an appreciation. Between 2007 and 2009, it fell from 0.0165 to 0.0122 (a depreciation). 13 STUDY TIP When answering a question or writing an essay, remember to explain that these factors influence the exchange rate through the effect they have on either the demand for or the supply of the currency. Relative inflation rates Exchange rate equilibrium also implies a zero overall balance of payments. If the exchange rate always adjusts to the level that ensures this, it might be argued that the long-run state of the economy is one in which the competitiveness of domestic firms remains constant over time. In other words, you would expect the exchange rate to adjust through time to offset any differences in inflation rates between countries. EXTENSION MATERIAL The purchasing power parity theory The purchasing power parity theory of exchange rates argues that this is exactly what should be expected in the long run if there are differences in inflation rates between countries. The nominal exchange rate should adjust in such a way as to offset changes in relative prices between countries. The trade balance The exchange rate in a free market is determined by the demand for and supply of the currency. This means that changes in the balance between exports and imports can affect the exchange rate. An increase in the demand for exports implies an increase in the demand for domestic currency, so would lead to an appreciation of the currency (ceteris paribus). 189 308275_C13_CAM_IASAL ECO_182_196.indd 189 17/02/21 4:40 PM 13 LEARNING LINK AS LEVEL PART 6 INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC ISSUES The interaction between the current and financial accounts is discussed in Chapter 29. Net foreign investment in the economy An increase in foreign direct investment would have similar effects. If the economy becomes an attractive prospect for foreign investors, this could also lead to an appreciation of the exchange rate (or at least some upward pressure). Speculation In the short run the exchange rate may diverge from its long-run equilibrium. An important influence on the exchange rate in the short run is speculation. So far, the discussion of the exchange rate has focused on the current account of the balance of payments. The financial account is also important, as large-scale movements of financial capital can affect the exchange rate. These effects are discussed in Chapter 29. Changes in the domestic real interest rate can have a significant effect on these flows. Interest rates and monetary policy Test yourself 13.6 Give an example of how the exchange rate for the currency of the country in which you live has been affected by a news item. Financial flows between countries may be induced by the relative level of interest rates. If interest rates in a country are high relative to elsewhere, this may attract an inflow of financial capital, thus putting upward pressure on the exchange rate and leading to an appreciation. The significance of this is that changes in the stance of monetary policy will have an effect on the exchange rate under a floating exchange rate system. These become an important part of the operation of monetary policy. Indeed, the decision of the monetary authorities in setting interest rates may be partly influenced by movements in the exchange rate. EXERCISE 13.2 A British firm wants to purchase a machine tool which is obtainable in the UK for a price of £125,000, or from a US supplier for $300,000. Suppose that the exchange rate is fixed at £1 = $3. a What is the sterling price of the machine tool if the firm chooses to buy in the USA? b From which supplier would the firm be likely to purchase? c Suppose that, between ordering the machine tool and its delivery, the pound depreciates, so that when the time comes for the firm to pay up the exchange rate is £1 = $2. What is the sterling price of the machine tool bought from the USA? d Comment on how the competitiveness of British goods has been affected. e Discuss the effects that the depreciation is likely to have on the economy as a whole. Exchange rate changes and the AD/AS model Price level Given the factors that can lead to a change in the exchange rate, how would such changes be seen in the AD/AS model? Suppose that for some reason there is an increase in demand for a country’s exports. This can be shown in Figure 13.5. LRAS SRAS0 P1 P0 AD1 AD0 0 YFE Y1 Real GDP ▲ Figure 13.5 An increase in exports with a floating exchange rate 190 308275_C13_CAM_IASAL ECO_182_196.indd 190 17/02/21 4:40 PM The economy begins at full employment with real GDP at YFE and the overall price level at P0. The increase in demand for exports is reflected in a rightward shift of aggregate demand from AD0 to AD1, with the price level increasing to P1. Associated with the increase in the demand for exports is an increase in demand for domestic currency, so the demand curve shifts to the right, leading to an appreciation of the exchange rate. A change in the opposite direction would have similar effects, but in reverse. For example, suppose that after Brexit, the UK experiences a fall in the demand for exports, causing the AD curve to shift to the left. There would be a fall in the demand for pounds, so the exchange rate would depreciate. Remember that with a depreciation, imports would become more expensive, and exports would become cheaper. (The reverse would happen with an appreciation.) Aggregate demand would tend to increase because of these changes. However, with a curved short-run aggregate supply curve, the new short-run equilibrium would be at a relatively lower real GDP, with only a relatively minor impact of the price level. The adjustment back to full employment could be relatively slow, especially if the lower real GDP led firms to form low expectations about future demand, and reduce their investment expenditure as a result. SUMMARY: EXCHANGE RATES » The exchange rate is the price of one currency in terms of another. » It is important because it influences the prices of international transactions in goods and services. » Under a floating exchange rate regime, the exchange rate is determined by the interaction of demand and supply. 13 The balance of payments and exchange rates The appreciation of the exchange rate means that imports become cheaper and exports become more expensive. In response, there will be an increase in demand for imports (with a fall in the demand for domestically produced goods that compete with imports) and a fall in the demand for exports. In other words, the rise in the exchange rate will at least partially offset the original increase in aggregate demand, so AD will tend to move back to the left, perhaps even returning to its original position. 13 » The fall in the value of a currency is known as a depreciation; a rise is known as an appreciation. » The exchange rate of a currency can change in response to changes in relative inflation rates, the trade balance, net investment in the domestic economy, speculation or changes in relative interest rates. » The AD/AS model can be used to examine the effects of a change in the exchange rate. 13.3 Macroeconomic policy and the current account of the balance of payments LEARNING LINK The business (trade) cycle is explained in Chapter 25. When writing an essay, it is worth drawing attention to the distinction between a cyclical deficit and a structural one. Under floating exchange rates, problems arise not with the overall balance of payments, but with an imbalance between components of the balance of payments. However, this does not mean that an imbalance on the current account can be ignored, and the state of the current account is carefully monitored by the government and economic commentators. Stability on the current account is one of the objectives of macroeconomic policy. A deficit on the current account of the balance of payments may be a temporary situation, perhaps associated with the business cycle. When the economy enters into an expansionary boom period, there will tend to be a move towards deficit on the current account, as imports tend to rise. Such a cyclical deficit will be of less concern than if the deficit arises from long-term structural factors. If the current account is in deficit, domestic residents are purchasing more in imports of goods and services than the economy is exporting. In other words, earnings from exports are not sufficient to pay for imports. This is a bit like a household spending beyond its income, which can be sustained only by selling assets or by borrowing. 191 308275_C13_CAM_IASAL ECO_182_196.indd 191 17/02/21 4:40 PM AS LEVEL PART 6 INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC ISSUES 13 Test yourself 13.7 What will be the effect on the current account of the balance of payments in the long run if the economy experiences a persistent inflow of foreign direct investment? LEARNING LINK The influence of the exchange rate in the context of monetary policy is discussed in Chapter 29. The concern for the economy is that a large and sustained deficit on the current account implies that the financial account must be in a large and sustained surplus. This in turn means that the country is effectively exporting assets. And this means that overseas residents are buying up domestic assets, which in turn may mean a leakage of investment income in the future. Alternatively, overall balance could be achieved through the sale of foreign exchange reserves. This soaks up the excess supply of domestic currency that arises because residents are supplying more currency in order to buy imports than overseas residents are demanding in order to buy exports from the home economy. However the current account deficit is financed, a large deficit cannot be sustained indefinitely. Equally, running a persistent surplus on the current account can create difficulties. China showed a persistent surplus on current account during its period of rapid economic growth, when exports were expanding rapidly. Domestically, this was only possible because the economy was able to expand so quickly in order to supply exports, but this was probably at the expense of domestic consumption. It also meant political pressure from the USA, which perceived that China’s undervalued currency was creating an unfair competitive advantage. A critical issue for a deficit country is whether home assets will remain attractive to foreign buyers. Running a sustained deficit on current account requires running a surplus on financial account. If foreign buyers of domestic assets become reluctant to buy, interest rates in the home economy might have to rise in order to make assets more attractive. A by-product of this would be a curb in spending by domestic firms and consumers. Given that part of this reduction in spending would have an impact on imports, this would begin to reduce the current account deficit. The quantity of exports of goods and services from an economy depends partly on income levels in the rest of the world and partly on the competitiveness of domestically produced goods and services, which in turn depends partly on the exchange rate and partly on relative price levels at home and abroad. Similarly, the level of imports depends partly on domestic income and partly on the international competitiveness of domestic and foreign goods and services. This suggests that a fundamental cause of a deficit on the current account is a lack of competitiveness of domestic goods and services, arising from an overvalued exchange rate or from high relative prices of home-produced goods and services. There may thus be a need to improve the efficiency of production in order to compete more effectively with foreign producers. Alternatively, domestic incomes may be rising more rapidly than those in the rest of the world. How is the current account of the balance of payments affected by macroeconomic policy? The current account of the balance of payments is monitored by the authorities because an imbalance is indicative of underlying problems and because of its longterm effects. However, the situation is complicated because macroeconomic policy changes also affect the current account. Fiscal policy Suppose that the government increases expenditure in order to stimulate aggregate demand. As we saw earlier in the chapter, an increase in aggregate demand puts upward pressure on the overall price level. This reduces the competitiveness of the country’s goods. Exports become more expensive to foreigners, and imports become 192 308275_C13_CAM_IASAL ECO_182_196.indd 192 17/02/21 4:40 PM less expensive to domestic residents. There will be a deterioration in the current account of the balance of payments as exports fall and imports rise, and aggregate demand will fall because of the reduction in net exports. In other words, the original increase in government expenditure as part of fiscal policy will be partly offset by the impact on net exports. 13 Monetary policy The way in which the exchange rate affects the transmission mechanism of monetary policy is explained in Chapter 28. Supply-side policy Successful supply-side policies result in a rightward shift in the long-run aggregate supply curve. This reflects improvements in productivity and efficiency in domestic production. In other words, this improves the competitiveness of domestic products both at home and abroad. This would be expected to result in an increase in net exports, thus improving the balance on the current account of the balance of payments. 13 The balance of payments and exchange rates LEARNING LINK Suppose now that the monetary authorities raise interest rates in order to combat an increase in inflation. The widening of the differential between domestic and foreign interest rates would attract an inflow of financial capital, which will result in an appreciation of the currency. The appreciation of the currency reduces the competitiveness of domestic goods in both home and overseas markets, so net exports (and aggregate demand) fall. The current account deficit increases. Indeed, in this case the exchange rate is part of the transmission mechanism by which monetary policy affects aggregate demand. The increase in the interest rate is also likely to affect investment and consumption directly. If firms become reluctant to invest, this then affects long-run economic growth. Protectionist policies LEARNING LINK The effects of a tariff are explained in Chapter 12. The use of protectionist policies is designed to improve the current account of the balance of payments by reducing dependence on imported goods and encouraging increased domestic production. But how will this work out? For example, suppose that tariffs are imposed across a range of products. This is indeed likely to reduce imports, but there are other effects that will also come into play. The immediate impact of the imposition of tariffs is that the prices of the goods that are subject to the tariff will increase. This affects both consumers and producers. From the consumers’ point of view, they face an increase in the price of imports, so will switch demand from imports to domestically produced goods. There will be an improvement in the balance on the current account of the balance of payments and (ceteris paribus) an increase in net exports and aggregate demand. However, there will also be a fall in demand for the goods subject to the tariff. From the point of view of domestic producers, they receive a higher price for their goods and are encouraged to expand output. What happens next depends partly on whether they are able (and willing) to respond to the increase in demand, especially if they also face higher prices for imports of material inputs. Even if they do expand production, they will be producing less efficiently than foreign producers. This is because they are only prepared to expand their production because of the higher prices that they receive with the tariffs in place. This reduction in relative productivity could mean a decrease in long-run aggregate supply. In other words, the use of protectionist policies may improve the current account of the balance of payments in the short run, but the sacrifice of the gains from trade may leave the country worse off in the long run. 193 308275_C13_CAM_IASAL ECO_182_196.indd 193 17/02/21 4:40 PM 13 SUMMARY: MACROECONOMIC POLICY AND THE CURRENT ACCOUNT OF THE BALANCE OF PAYMENTS AS LEVEL PART 6 INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC ISSUES » Stability of the current account of the balance of payments is seen as one of the objectives of macroeconomic policy. » A large and sustained deficit on the current account must be offset by a large and sustained surplus on the financial account, which affects the long-term ownership of assets in the economy. » Neither a persistent deficit nor a persistent surplus is sustainable in the long run. » A fundamental cause of a deficit on the current account is a lack of competitiveness of domestic goods both at home and abroad. » Macroeconomic policy changes, whether in fiscal, monetary or supply-side policies, have effects on the current account of the balance of payments. END OF CHAPTER QUESTIONS Multiple choice 1 Other things being equal, which of the following sets of events is most likely to cause an overall appreciation of a country’s exchange rate? A An increase in the quality of the country’s exports and higher domestic interest rates. B Domestic inflation greater than that of trading partners and an increase in the substitutes available to the country’s exports. C Higher interest rates abroad and greater demand for foreign holidays by the country’s residents. D An increase in foreign investment opportunities and more favourable local business climate. 2 Why is stability of the current account of the balance of payments an important policy objective for the government? A Cyclical current account deficits can signal a loss in comparative advantage. B A current account disequilibrium reduces national income. C Growing current account imbalances unmatched by other components of the balance of payments can put undesired pressure on the exchange rate. D A financial account disequilibrium is corrected more easily than a current account disequilibrium. Data response 1 Read the following extract and then answer the questions that follow. The balance of payments and exchange rates A floating exchange rate is determined by market forces. In relation to the Covid-19 pandemic in early 2020, the key changes to these market forces operating on currencies were demand shocks caused by quarantines and travel restrictions, and supply shocks caused when global supply chains were interrupted and destabilised. Amidst this, the Australian dollar, having fallen 9% in value against the US dollar (US$) in early 2020, had the largest gain among major currencies, appreciating 4.9% versus the US$ in May 2020. This trend was forecast to continue. The emerging market currencies of Mexico, Brazil and Russia were among the hardest hit in 2020. The Russian rouble fell around 20% against the Chinese yuan between January and March 2020. In 2019, China was the destination for US$56.8 billion of Russian exports, making it Russia’s largest trade partner, purchasing 13.4% of Russian exports. Moreover, China’s recovery from the Covid-19 downturn was quicker than other nations, and more sustained. 194 308275_C13_CAM_IASAL ECO_182_196.indd 194 17/02/21 4:40 PM The balance of payments is a set of accounts showing the transactions conducted between residents of one country and the rest of the world. They include, among other items, the trade in goods and services. These data are summarised in Table 13.1 for the USA for April 2020. 13 ▼ Table 13.1 USA: value of goods and services imported and exported, April 2020 (US$bn) Imports Trade in goods 95.5 167.4 Trade in services 55.8 33.3 In early 2020, final quarter forecasts for 2021 of the current account balance as a percentage of GDP placed the UK, at −3.5%, as one of the largest deficit countries among the 37-member Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. Other members with similarly large deficit figures were Colombia at −3.7% and Canada at −3.4%. All three nations operate a floating exchange rate. The inflation rate of 0.6% in Canada was also problematic at that time, being significantly below the Canadian government’s 2% target rate. Figure 13.6 shows the current account position of Norway up to early 2020. Norway is a country where work–life balance is highly valued, and family is a huge priority. Norway has the third lowest average working week in the world, 38 hours, and for the 3 years 2017–20 achieved the highest productivity rate in the world. 100,000 83,893 13 The balance of payments and exchange rates Exports 80,000 69,758 66,411 66,078 58,799 60,000 47,127 39,820 27,654 40,000 27,022 26,913 25,059 20,000 12,440 Jul 2017 Jan 2018 Jul 2018 Jan 2019 Jul 2019 Jan 2020 0 Source: tradingeconomics.com ▲ Figure 13.6 Current account balance of Norway (NOK million), July 2017–April 2020 a i b c d e Explain the relationship you would expect between the productivity rate and the current account position of a country. ii Consider whether this relationship is evident in the extract. Calculate the balance of trade in goods for the USA in April 2020. Explain, using AD/AS analysis, how the change in the value of the Australian currency in May 2020 would cause a change in the equilibrium price level in the short run. Describe, using the information provided, the likely impact on the trade balance of Russia of the change in its exchange rate and the strengthening Chinese economy. Assess the impact on the current account of the balance of payments of Canada of a fiscal policy measure that the government may take in light of the country’s inflation rate. 195 308275_C13_CAM_IASAL ECO_182_196.indd 195 17/02/21 4:40 PM Essay style 2 aWith the help of a diagram, explain how an increase in the rate of interest will affect a floating exchange rate in the short run and consider how expectations of the future exchange rate could impact on the outcome. bDiscuss whether a deficit on the current account of the balance of payments will always cause problems for the domestic economy. CASE STUDY The UK balance of trade Figure 13.7 shows the UK’s balance of trade in goods since 1990, measured in current prices. The picture is startling, showing a steady increase in the deficit since 1997, following a period of relative stability. There are several possible causes underpinning this picture. One relates to the production of North Sea £bn at current prices AS LEVEL PART 6 INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC ISSUES 13 0 –20 –40 –60 oil and gas, which peaked in the late 1990s and has declined steadily since then. Secondly, the structure of economic activity has been changing, such that the trade balance in services has increased steadily, which partly offsets the decline in the goods trade balance. Overall, the negative trade balance has contributed to the overall deficit on the current account of the balance of payments, which has meant that the overall balance of payments has only been maintained by surpluses on the financial account. –80 Follow-up questions a What is the significance of the fact that the trade –120 balance as shown in Figure 13.7 is measured in –140 current prices? –160 b Why is the changing structure of the economy 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 relevant in trying to understand why the trade deficit has declined so rapidly? Source: based on data from ONS (UK) c To what extent does the increasing deficit in the ▲ Figure 13.7 The UK balance of trade in goods since 1990 trade balance raise concerns for the authorities? –100 196 308275_C13_CAM_IASAL ECO_182_196.indd 196 20/03/21 10:50 AM A LEVEL PART 7 The price system and the microeconomy 14 Marginal utility and consumer choice ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ marginal and total utility the law of diminishing marginal utility marginal utility and demand the equi-marginal principle limitations of marginal utility theory KEY TERMS utility: the satisfaction received from consuming a good or service marginal utility: the additional utility gained from consuming an additional unit of a good or service ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ the assumption of rational behaviour the budget line and indifference curves consumer equilibrium income and substitution effects limitations of the indifference curve model Chapter 2 explained the nature of demand as part of the basis for the demand and supply model. This chapter extends that analysis by introducing the notion of marginal utility and using this to add to your understanding of the demand curve. The consumer’s budget line is introduced, and there is discussion of how a consumer’s reaction to a change in the price of a good or service can be broken down into two separate effects – the income effect and the substitution effect. 14 Marginal utility and consumer choice What this chapter covers 14.1 Utility Suppose you could measure the satisfaction that you derive from consuming a good? For example, consider the case of chocolate bars. Consuming a chocolate bar gives you a certain amount of satisfaction – which economists often refer to as utility in this context. Imagine that it is possible to put a numerical value on this utility, and for the sake of argument that the utility you get from consuming a chocolate bar is 30 ‘utils’, this being the unit in which utility is measured. Marginal and total utility Having consumed the chocolate bar, you are now offered a second, which you also consume, this time receiving 26 utils of utility. You probably get less utility from the second bar simply because you have already had some chocolate – and the more chocolate bars you eat, the less utility you are likely to get from the additional bar. Notice here that the valuation of the utility refers to the additional satisfaction that is gained from the second bar. This is therefore known as the marginal utility from consuming an additional chocolate bar. Indeed, there will come a time when you have eaten so much chocolate that you cannot face eating any more, as you know you would be ill. Table 14.1 shows the marginal utility that Majida gains from consuming chocolate bars. ▼ Table 14.1 Utility from chocolate Number of bars Marginal utility (utils) 1 30 2 26 3 21 4 15 5 8 6 0 197 308275_C14_CAM_IASAL ECO_197_207.indd 197 17/02/21 4:47 PM law of diminishing marginal utility: the more units of a good that are consumed, the lower the utility from consuming those additional (marginal) units total utility: the total satisfaction received from consuming all chosen units of a good or service In this example, the sixth chocolate bar gives no satisfaction to Majida, who has already had enough chocolate for the day. This idea that the more of a good you consume, the less additional pleasure you get from the extra unit of it is known as the law of diminishing marginal utility. It is a ‘law’ because it has been found to be universally true. If you keep consuming more of something, you get less additional satisfaction from extra units. Figure 14.1 plots the marginal utility values on a graph. The law of diminishing marginal utility ensures that the MU curve is downward sloping. Marginal utility (in utils) A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 14 KEY TERMS 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 MU 0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Number of chocolate bars ▲ Figure 14.1 A marginal utility curve If it were really possible to measure satisfaction in this way, it would also be possible to calculate the total utility that Majida receives from consuming chocolate bars. For instance, if she consumes two bars, she gets 30 + 26 = 56 utils. If she has a third bar, her total utility would be 77 utils. Test yourself 14.1 What would be Majida’s total utility if she were to consume four bars of chocolate? Equally, if we know the total utility that Majida obtains from consuming different quantities of a good, we can calculate the marginal utility. For example if Majida gets total utility of 60 utils from consuming two ice creams but 65 utils from consuming three, her marginal (additional) utility from consuming the third ice cream is the total utility from consuming three ice creams minus the total utility from consuming two ice creams, i.e. 65 – 60 = 5 utils. Notice that maximum total utility is achieved when marginal utility is zero, because if marginal utility is zero, this adds nothing to total utility. STUDY TIP The relationship between ‘total’ and ‘marginal’ appears in many areas of economic analysis, and it is good to be clear about it. The ‘marginal’ value is calculated as the change in the ‘total’. EXERCISE 14.1 Table 14.2 shows the total utility that Nazim obtains from consuming a good. ▼ Table 14.2 Nazim’s total utility from good X Units of X Total utility (utils) 1 10 2 19 3 27 4 34 5 40 6 45 7 49 a Calculate the marginal utility at each level. b Draw the MU curve on a diagram. 198 308275_C14_CAM_IASAL ECO_197_207.indd 198 17/02/21 4:47 PM Marginal utility and demand Price, MU MU* D (MU ) 0 14 14 Marginal utility and consumer choice If marginal utility were measured in terms of money, then the MU curve would become a person’s demand curve. Consider Figure 14.2. The quantity of the good Q* provides this individual with marginal utility of MU*. If the price of the good were higher than MU*, then the individual would not buy Q* of the good, as the price exceeds his valuation. On the other hand, if price were to be set lower than MU*, then the individual would be prepared to buy more than Q*, as the marginal utility would be higher than the asking price. Another way of putting this is to say that the consumer will purchase the good up to the point where the price is equal to the marginal utility gained from consuming the good. Of course, a similar argument applies at each point along the MU curve, so this is indeed the individual’s demand curve when utility is measured in money terms. Q* Quantity ▲ Figure 14.2 An individual’s demand curve Test yourself 14.2 How quickly would the marginal utility curve drop away if the product concerned were haircuts? LEARNING LINK We will see another way of looking at this principle later in the chapter. The previous discussion of the demand curve emphasised that the curve shows the relationship between the quantity demanded of a good and its price, ceteris paribus. In other words, it focused on the relationship between demand and price, holding other influences on demand constant. This argument also applies in this case. Changes in the price of other goods, in consumer incomes or in preferences would all affect the position of the demand (MU) curve. This highlights the fact that decisions about the consumption of one good are interconnected with decisions being made about other goods. If a consumer chooses to consume more of one good, that means there is less income available to be spent on other goods. Furthermore, a decision to consume more of one good will affect the consumption of complementary and substitute goods. So rather than focusing on a consumer’s decisions about the demand for a single good, it is also necessary to consider the demand for a bundle of goods and services, and how a consumer can arrive at a joint decision. The equi-marginal principle To keep things simple, consider an individual choosing a combination of two goods, X and Y. The individual gains utility from each good, and sets out to maximise the utility received from consumption of both. The quantity chosen of one good affects the demand for the other, given a limited budget to spend on the items. Therefore, it is not a simple question of setting marginal utility equal to price, as the decision on one good affects the position of the MU curve for the other good because of the linkage through the budget constraint. 199 308275_C14_CAM_IASAL ECO_197_207.indd 199 17/02/21 4:48 PM A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 14 KEY TERM equi-marginal principle: a consumer maximises utility by consuming at the point where the marginal utilities per dollar from each of the two goods are equal It turns out that the best a consumer can do is to consume the two goods at the point where the ratio of the marginal utilities per dollar from each of the two goods is equal. In other words, this is where: MUX MUY = PX PY This is known as the equi-marginal principle. It describes the conditions under which a consumer will maximise his or her utility. In principle, this can be extended to the case where consumers are choosing between many goods and services. Let’s look at an example. Suppose that Abdul is choosing a combination of apples (priced 20c each) and cans of cola (priced at 40c). Table 14.3 shows the marginal utility that he receives from each of the goods and the ratio of his marginal utility to price. ▼ Table 14.3 Abdul’s MU and MU/P for apples and cola Number consumed Marginal utility from apples Marginal utility from apples divided by price Marginal utility from cola Marginal utility from cola divided by price 1 160 8 440 11 2 140 7 280 7 3 80 4 200 5 4 60 3 60 1.5 5 40 2 40 1 The point at which the marginal utility from apples is equal to that from cola occurs when Abdul chooses to consume two apples and two cans of cola. Of course, the quantities consumed need not always be the same. In this case, this happens by coincidence. Limitations of marginal utility theory The marginal utility approach provides insights into consumer behaviour, but it has its limitations. First, utility is not something that can be measured; there is no objective way of valuing utility because this will vary from individual to individual. In other words, because each consumer is different and has different preferences, it is impossible to compare utility between individuals. One person may gain different utility from $1 than another, and there is no way of comparing their utility values. This does not mean that the analysis is unhelpful – but it must be recognised that there are limitations when it comes to putting the theory into practice. For example, it may be difficult to think of aggregating across individual consumers in order to build a market demand curve for a good. However, it will be shown that there are some important insights to be gained from pushing this analysis a bit further. It is also difficult to imagine how the marginal utility approach would work when the analysis needs to be extended to multiple goods and services, so that the many interactions between the demand for one good and the demand for another need to be taken into account. One way of making some sense of this would be to consider the consumer’s choice as being between the utility gained from one good and the utility gained from all other goods considered together. KEY TERM behavioural economics: a branch of economics that builds on the psychology of human behaviour in decision making Do consumers always act rationally? Marginal utility theory rests on the crucial assumption that consumers act rationally in taking decisions about their spending and consumption by setting out to maximise their utility. Recent advances in behavioural economics suggest that this is not always the case. This branch of economic analysis recognises that the psychology of human decision making is more complex than the simple desire to maximise utility. People do not always focus on 200 308275_C14_CAM_IASAL ECO_197_207.indd 200 17/02/21 4:48 PM Test yourself 14.3 Other than the example of charitable donations, identify another way in which consumers may take decisions that may not maximise their utility. purely economic influences, but may act on impulse, or in response to their feelings. This can lead them to take decisions about their spending that cannot be explained only by utility maximisation. For example, they may make charitable donations or may purchase more of some goods than would be dictated by rational economic behaviour. SUMMARY: UTILITY » Marginal utility represents the additional » The equi-marginal principle shows that an satisfaction that a consumer receives from consuming an additional unit of a good. » Marginal utility diminishes as more of a good is consumed. » Diminishing marginal utility helps to explain why demand curves are downward sloping. individual’s utility is maximised where the ratio of the marginal utilities per dollar is equal for the two goods. » Although it offers some insights into consumer choice, marginal utility analysis has some limitations. » There is some evidence that consumers do not always act rationally. 14 Marginal utility and consumer choice Increasingly, behavioural economists are using experimental situations to discover more about how people react in situations of risk and how their spending behaviour is influenced by impulse and in response to stimuli. This analysis is potentially valuable to firms: if they can understand what induces people to behave in certain ways, they may be able to influence their spending. Governments are also using findings from behavioural economics when designing and publicising policies where they want to influence behaviour. 14 14.2 Indifference curves and budget lines Suppose that a consumer is choosing between two goods. How can we analyse the decision process under the assumption that the aim is to maximise utility from the two goods? The budget line KEY TERMS Bottles of cola budget line: shows the boundary of an individual’s consumption set, given the amount available to spend and the prices of the goods Suppose that Abdul has $1.20 to spend, and wants to split his purchases between apples (which are 20c each) and cola (which is 40c per bottle). He can choose to spend the whole amount on apples, or on cola – or can buy some of each. Given these prices, he could buy six apples or three bottles of cola. The possibilities are shown as the budget line in Figure 14.3. This connects the combinations of apples and cola that Abdul could purchase. For example, he could buy four apples and one bottle of cola, as marked on the figure. One way of interpreting the budget line is as the boundary showing the combinations of apples and cola that Abdul can afford – he could not choose to consume beyond the budget line. The slope of the budget line is given by the relative prices of the two goods. 4 3 2 1 BL 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 Apples ▲ Figure 14.3 Abdul’s budget line 201 308275_C14_CAM_IASAL ECO_197_207.indd 201 17/02/21 4:48 PM indifference curve: a curve showing the combinations of two goods that give equal total utility to a consumer marginal rate of substitution: the slope of an indifference curve, showing the amount of one good that a consumer must give up in exchange for another while keeping total utility constant Test yourself 14.4 How would the budget line differ if Abdul had $2 to spend, with the prices of these goods having remained the same? The indifference curve In order to analyse Abdul’s choice between apples and cola, some way is needed to show his preferences on the diagram. This can be done using indifference curves. An indifference curve shows the various combinations of apples and cola that give Abdul equal satisfaction – that is, equal utility. These are downward sloping because Abdul can trade off the satisfaction received from one of the goods against that from the other. In other words, if he consumes fewer apples, he needs to consume more cola in order to maintain equal utility. The slope of an indifference curve is known as the marginal rate of substitution between the goods, and is equal to the ratio of the marginal utilities that Abdul receives from the two goods. Figure 14.4 shows three such curves. Consider the curve IC2. This shows that Abdul would receive equal utility from consuming two bottles of cola and two apples as he would from three bottles of cola and one apple. Similarly, any point along this curve would be equally satisfactory to Abdul (if he could consume fractions of bottles or apples). The same argument applies to the other curves shown in the diagram, but because we assume that Abdul would prefer more to less, he would maximise utility by reaching the highest possible curve that he can reach. In other words, he would prefer to be on IC2 than on IC1, but IC3 would be better than both. Bottles of cola A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 14 KEY TERMS 4 3 2 IC3 IC2 IC1 1 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 Apples ▲ Figure 14.4 Abdul’s indifference curves Abdul’s choice KEY TERM Bottles of cola consumer equilibrium: the point at which a consumer maximises utility at the tangency between an indifference curve and the budget line Abdul cannot choose to be on just any of the curves, as he is constrained by his budget line. If the budget line is superimposed on the map of indifference curves, his choice can be identified. This can be seen in Figure 14.5. The highest indifference curve that Abdul can reach given his budget line (BL) is IC2. The budget line just touches the indifference curve at one point, where Abdul consumes two bottles of cola and two apples. At any other point along the budget line or below it, he would receive lower utility than this. The tangency point at A is his choice point, and represents consumer equilibrium. It is the point at which the ratio of the marginal utilities (the slope of the indifference curve) is equal to relative prices (the slope of the budget line). STUDY TIP Notice that this consumer equilibrium at the tangency point echoes the earlier discussion of the equimarginal principle. 4 3 A 2 IC3 IC2 IC1 BL 1 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 Apples ▲ Figure 14.5 Abdul’s choice 202 308275_C14_CAM_IASAL ECO_197_207.indd 202 17/02/21 4:48 PM A shift in Abdul’s budget Bottles of cola 6 5 4 B 3 A 2 Test yourself 14.5 1 Explain why Abdul is better off at point B than at point A. 0 IC3 IC2 BL IC1 BL1 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 Apples 14 14 Marginal utility and consumer choice Suppose that Abdul receives an increase in his income, so that his budget for spending on these goods increases: for example, suppose he found an extra 80c in his pocket so he now has $2 to spend on these goods. Given that the prices of the goods remain as before, his budget line moves out, but keeps the same slope as before. This is shown in Figure 14.6, where the budget line moves from BL0 to BL1. As a result, Abdul can now reach a higher indifference curve by moving from point A to point B. He now consumes three bottles of cola and four apples. In this example, Abdul increases his consumption of both goods as income rises, indicating that they are both normal goods. ▲ Figure 14.6 A change in Abdul’s budget Bottles of cola This need not be the case. The indifference curves could be such that the change in income causes Abdul to consume less of one of the goods. In other words, one of the goods could be an inferior good. Figure 14.7 illustrates this on the assumption that Abdul can consume fractions of bottles of cola and apples. In this example, Abdul responds to the change in income by consuming more apples, but less cola. 6 5 4 3 A 2 B IC2 BL0 1 0 0 2 4 6 IC1 BL1 8 IC3 10 12 Apples ▲ Figure 14.7 A change in Abdul’s budget when cola is an inferior good LEARNING LINK The concepts of normal and inferior goods were introduced in Chapter 2. A change in relative prices If there is a fall in the price of apples, Abdul’s budget line is again affected. Figure 14.8 shows what happens to his budget line if the price of apples halves. He can now consume either three bottles of cola (if he spends his entire budget on cola), or 12 apples. With this set of indifference curves, his choice changes from point A to point B, and he continues to consume two bottles of cola, but now chooses four apples. 203 308275_C14_CAM_IASAL ECO_197_207.indd 203 17/02/21 4:48 PM Bottles of cola 14 4 3 A 2 B IC3 IC2 0 BL0 0 2 4 IC1 6 BL1 8 10 12 Apples ▲ Figure 14.8 A fall in the price of apples KEY TERMS substitution effect of a price change: reflects the way that a change in the price of a good affects relative prices income effect of a price change: reflects the way that a change in the price of a good affects purchasing power (income) Notice that a fall in the price of apples has two separate effects on Abdul. On the one hand, there has been a change in the relative price of apples and cola, so Abdul will tend to substitute his consumption from the more expensive to the cheaper item (i.e. he will tend to switch from consuming cola to consuming apples). However, there is also a second effect, which is that the fall in the price of apples means that Abdul has higher real income, in the sense that his budget line has shifted out, and his choice set has expanded. It is possible to identify these two effects. Consider Figure 14.9. This time, suppose that there is an increase in the price of apples, shifting the budget line from BL0 to BL1. Abdul’s initial choice point is at A, and the increase in the price of apples means that he can no longer reach this point, and thus ends up at B. Given the new relative prices, the shadow budget line BL* shows the level of income that would have left Abdul at his original utility level – that is, this would have allowed him to reach IC2. The impact of the price change is partly a substitution effect along the indifference curve from A to C, and partly an income effect from C to B. Bottles of cola A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 1 IC2 IC1 C A LEARNING LINK These effects were introduced briefly in an extension box in Chapter 2 (see page 27). B BL1 BL* BL0 Apples ▲ Figure 14.9 Income and substitution effects of a price change Notice that in this example, both apples and cola are normal goods, and the substitution and income effects work in the same direction. In other words, when the price of apples increases, both income and substitution effects reduce the consumption of apples. 204 308275_C14_CAM_IASAL ECO_197_207.indd 204 17/02/21 4:48 PM C A B IC2 BL1 LEARNING LINK The notion of the Giffen good was introduced in an extension box in Chapter 2 (see page 30), where it was noted that such goods exist in theory, but rarely (if ever) in practice. STUDY TIP Remember that three key limitations of the indifference curve model are: » indifference curves cannot be identified » consumers’ expectations may not be realised » consumers may not act rationally BL0 Apples KEY TERM Giffen good: a good for which the income effect is so strong that it more than offsets the substitution effect, so that the demand curve becomes upward sloping BL* IC1 ▲ Figure 14.10 Income and substitution effects of a price change when apples are an inferior good 14 14 Marginal utility and consumer choice Bottles of cola Figure 14.10 shows that when apples are an inferior good, the substitution and income effects work in opposite directions. Abdul’s tendency to substitute cola for apples (from A to C) is partly offset by the income effect from C to B: as income falls, Abdul tends to consume more apples. Notice that in this case, the demand (MU) curve would still be downward sloping, because the income effect only partially offsets the substitution effect. The demand curve would only become upward sloping if the income effect were so strong that it more than offset the substitution effect. If this did happen, the good would be classed as a Giffen good. EXERCISE 14.2 Suppose that Jennifer is allocating her available budget between two goods. Using a diagram, explain the impact of an increase in the price of one of the goods, distinguishing between the income and substitution effects. Limitations of the indifference curve model The indifference curve model allows us to analyse consumer choice and to identify how individuals may respond to a price change in terms of income and substitution effects. However, there are some limitations of the model. For an individual consumer, the budget line can be identified, but it is not possible to plot out the indifference curves, so these are effectively just a theoretical construct that cannot be observed in practice. Even if it were possible to persuade consumers to reveal the satisfaction that they expect to receive from consuming a set of goods and services, those expectations may not be fulfilled in reality. For example, it could be that the experience of actually consuming a product may exceed those expectations – or provide less satisfaction than had been anticipated. Advertising or recommendations from friends and relatives may not paint an accurate picture of what it will be like to consume a product. It was noted earlier that consumers may not always act rationally to maximise their utility. If this is the case, then a model that rests on the assumption that consumers are rational would not help us to explain actual behaviour. 205 308275_C14_CAM_IASAL ECO_197_207.indd 205 17/02/21 4:48 PM » The budget line shows the combination of goods » The effects of a price change can be divided into an that an individual can consume given the amount available to spend and the prices of the goods. » An indifference curve maps the preferences of a consumer between two goods. » Utility from consuming two goods is maximised where an indifference curve is at a tangent to the budget line. income effect and a substitution effect. » The indifference curve model is a tool that aids our understanding of consumer choice, but it has its limitations in practice. END OF CHAPTER QUESTIONS Multiple choice 1 Figure 14.11 illustrates the effect of a rise in the price of a Giffen good B. Good A A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 14 SUMMARY: INDIFFERENCE CURVES AND BUDGET LINES b a c I1 B2 0 I2 B1’ B1 Qb2 Qb1 Qb3 Good B ▲ Figure 14.11 The effect of a rise in the price of a Giffen good Which option correctly describes the effects taking place on the diagram following the rise in price? Qb1 to Qb2 Qb2 to Qb3 Qb1 to Qb3 A Price effect Income effect Substitution effect B Income effect Substitution effect Price effect C Price effect Substitution effect Income effect D Substitution effect Income effect Price effect 2 What is a valid limitation of indifference analysis applying when an individual purchases a washing machine versus most other goods? A The individual can be misled by advertising, thus distorting their rational choice. B The individual might have derived more utility from purchasing other goods. C Indifference analysis considers consumer choice at a point in time, but consumer durables are only purchased infrequently but consumed over an extended period. D The individual cannot plot the indifference curves to determine the point of tangency to their highest attainable budget line. 206 308275_C14_CAM_IASAL ECO_197_207.indd 206 17/02/21 4:49 PM Data response 1 Read the following extract and then answer the questions that follow. 14 Mei’s iced latte and chocolate muffin utility Mei lives in Hong Kong close to the Causeway Bay railway station. She sometimes buys an iced latte coffee or a chocolate muffin from a coffee shop at the station. Mei has calculated the utility derived from her consumption of a chocolate muffin and an iced latte coffee, the results of which are summarised in Table 14.4. ▼ Table 14.4 Utility derived from the consumption of a chocolate muffin and iced latte Number of (large) iced latte coffee drinks Total utility Number of chocolate muffins Marginal utility 1 80 1 44 2 144 2 40 3 192 3 36 4 224 4 32 5 240 5 28 14 Marginal utility and consumer choice The price of a chocolate muffin is 20 HKD (Hong Kong dollars) while her favourite (large) iced latte coffee is priced at 40 HKD. a Explain how the law of diminishing marginal utility can justify Mei’s downwardsloping (left to right) demand curve for large iced latte drinks. b Use the equi-marginal principle to explain Mei’s utility-maximising consumption of chocolate muffins and iced latte drinks and comment on the validity of the outcome. c Suppose Mei had 160 HKD. Draw her budget line with respect to chocolate muffins and iced latte and the indifference curve on which she will consume. Mark on your diagram a point X, where Mei spends all her income but does not attain maximum utility, and a point Y, Mei’s utility-maximising level of consumption. d Distinguish between the income and substitution effects following an increase in the price of a chocolate muffin compared to those effects when the price of an inferior good increases. 207 308275_C14_CAM_IASAL ECO_197_207.indd 207 17/02/21 4:49 PM A LEVEL PART 7 The price system and the microeconomy A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 15 Efficiency and market failure What this chapter covers ★ productive efficiency and allocative efficiency ★ Pareto optimality ★ dynamic efficiency ★ the meaning and sources of market failure In the early stage of your study of economics, you became familiar with the demand and supply model and the way in which prices act as signals to guide resource allocation. It is now time to take this discussion further and adopt a wider view of how resources are allocated within a society. We will explore how economists view the important concept of efficiency, and whether markets can be relied on to guide this process, or whether there are times when markets will fail. 15.1 Productive efficiency and allocative efficiency Prices and resource allocation The notions of consumer surplus and producer surplus are important because they can be used to evaluate the total benefit that consumers and producers receive from consuming and producing a good. When consumers all pay the same price for a good in a market, then the area of consumer surplus can be interpreted as the total welfare that consumers receive from consuming that good. Similarly, the producer surplus is interpreted as the surplus earned by firms over and above the minimum return that would have kept them in the market. In a market system, prices are the signals that carry information between consumers and producers, and which ultimately guide the decisions that influence the way in which resources are allocated. LEARNING LINK The concepts of consumer and producer surplus were introduced in Chapter 4. Test yourself 15.1 Why is it difficult to judge whether society is better off at B than C in Figure 15.1? The underlying assumption that is made in this context is that consumers aim to maximise their surplus, and firms aim to maximise profits. In other words, both consumers and firms are assumed to be motivated by self-interest, and the key question is whether this will lead to a good outcome for society as a whole in the way that resources are allocated. Will resources be allocated in an efficient way? And what do we mean by efficiency? Efficiency In tackling the fundamental economic problem of scarcity, a society needs to find a way of using its limited resources as effectively as possible. In everyday language it might be natural to refer to this as a quest for efficiency. From an economist’s point of view there are two key aspects of efficiency, both of which are important in evaluating whether markets in an economy are working effectively to deliver efficiency. Chapter 1 introduced one of these aspects in relation to the production possibility curve (PPC). Figure 15.1 shows a country’s production possibility curve. One of the choices to be made in allocating resources in this country is between producing agricultural or manufactured goods. In Chapter 1 it was seen that at a production point such as A, the economy would not be using its resources fully, since by moving to a point on the PPC it would be possible to produce more of both types of good. For example, if production took place at point B, then more of both agricultural and manufactured goods could be produced, so that society would be better off than at A. 208 308275_C15_CAM_IASAL ECO_208_217.indd 208 17/02/21 4:59 PM Quantity of manufactured goods per period C B A PPC Quantity of agricultural goods per period ▲ Figure 15.1 Productive efficiency and the PPC ▲ Vilfredo Pareto KEY TERMS Pareto optimum: an allocation of resources is said to be a Pareto optimum if no reallocation of resources can make an individual better off without making some other individual worse off productive efficiency: attained when a firm operates at minimum average total cost, choosing an appropriate combination of inputs (cost efficiency) and producing the maximum output possible from these inputs (technical efficiency) average total cost: total cost of production divided by the quantity produced economies of scale: occur for a firm when an increase in the scale of production leads to production at lower long-run average cost A similar claim could be made for any point along the PPC: it is more efficient to be at a point on the frontier than at some point within it. However, if you compare point B with point C, you will notice that the economy produces more manufactured goods at C than at B – but only at the expense of producing fewer agricultural goods. 15 Efficiency and market failure 0 15 This draws attention to the trade-off between the production of the two sorts of goods. It is difficult to judge whether society is better off at B or at C without knowing more about the preferences of consumers. This discussion highlights the two aspects of efficiency. On the one hand, there is the question of whether society is operating on the PPC, and thus using its resources effectively. On the other hand, there is the question of whether society is producing the balance of goods that consumers wish to consume. These two aspects of efficiency are known as productive efficiency and allocative efficiency, and are discussed in more detail below. An efficient point for a society would be one in which no redistribution of resources could make any individual better off without making some other individual worse off. This is known as the Pareto criterion, after the nineteenth-century economist Vilfredo Pareto, who first introduced the concept. Notice, however, that any point along the PPC is a Pareto optimum: with a different distribution of income among individuals in a society, a different overall equilibrium will be reached. Aspects of efficiency can be explored further by considering an individual market. First, however, it is necessary to identify the conditions under which productive and allocative efficiency can be attained. Productive efficiency The production process entails combining a range of inputs of factors of production in order to produce output. Firms may find that there are benefits from large-scale production, so that efficiency may improve as firms expand production. One way of measuring productive efficiency is in terms of the average total cost of production. This is simply the total cost of production divided by the quantity of output produced. Productive efficiency can then be defined in terms of the minimum average cost at which output can be produced, noting that average cost is likely to vary at different scales of output. Economies of scale occur when an increase in the scale of production leads to production at lower long-run average cost. 209 308275_C15_CAM_IASAL ECO_208_217.indd 209 17/02/21 5:01 PM The nature of the costs faced by firms is examined in Chapter 17, where there is also an explanation of economies of scale. There are two aspects to productive efficiency. One entails making the best possible use of the inputs of factors of production: in other words, it is about producing as much output as possible from a given set of inputs. This is sometimes known as technical efficiency. However, there is also the question of whether the best set of inputs has been chosen. For example, there may be techniques of production that use mainly capital and not much labour, and alternative techniques that are more labour intensive. The firm’s choice between these techniques will depend crucially on the relative prices of capital and labour. This is sometimes known as cost efficiency. To attain productive efficiency, both technical efficiency and cost efficiency need to be achieved. In other words, productive efficiency is attained when a firm chooses the appropriate combination of inputs (cost efficiency) and produces the maximum output possible from those inputs (technical efficiency). It is worth noting that the choice of technique of production may depend crucially on the level of output that the firm wishes to produce. The balance of factors of production may well change according to the scale of activity. If the firm is producing very small amounts of output, it may well choose a different combination of capital and labour than if it were planning mass production on a large scale. Thus, the firm’s decision process is a three-stage procedure. First, the firm needs to decide how much output it wants to produce. Second, it has to choose an appropriate combination of factors of production, given that intended scale of production. Third, it needs to produce as much output as possible, given those inputs. Once the intended scale of output has been decided, the firm has to minimise its costs of production. These decisions are part of the response to the question of how output should be produced. Remember also the concept of marginal cost, which refers to the cost faced by a firm in changing the output level by a small amount. This becomes an important part of the discussion. Allocative efficiency KEY TERM allocative efficiency: achieved when society is producing an appropriate bundle of goods relative to consumer preferences – this occurs when price equals marginal cost Allocative efficiency is about whether an economy allocates its resources in such a way as to produce a balance of goods and services that matches consumer preferences. In a complex modern economy, it is clearly difficult to identify such an ideal result. How can an appropriate balance of goods and services be identified? Take the market for an individual product, such as the market for smartphones that was considered in Chapter 4. It was then argued that in the long run, the market could be expected to arrive at an equilibrium price and quantity at which there was no incentive for firms either to enter the market or to exit from it. Figure 15.2 will remind you of the market situation. Price A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 15 LEARNING LINK S0 S2 P1 P0 D0 0 Q0 D1 Q1 Q2 Quantity of smartphones per period ▲ Figure 15.2 The market for smartphones revisited 210 308275_C15_CAM_IASAL ECO_208_217.indd 210 17/02/21 5:01 PM The sequence of events in the diagram shows that, from an initial equilibrium with price at P0 and quantity traded at Q0, there was an increase in demand, with the demand curve shifting to D1. In response, existing firms expanded their supply, moving up the supply curve. However, the lure of the producer surplus (abnormal profits) that was being made by these firms then attracted more firms into the market, such that the supply curve shifted to S2, a process that brought the price back down to the original level of P0. However, it was also argued that from the consumers’ point of view any point along the demand curve could be regarded as the marginal benefit received from consuming a good or service. Where is all this leading? Putting together the arguments, it would seem that market forces can carry a market to a position in which, from the firms’ point of view, the price is equal to marginal cost, and from the consumers’ point of view, the price is equal to marginal benefit. 15 Efficiency and market failure Now think about that price from the point of view of a firm. P0 is at a level where there is no further incentive to attract new firms, but no firm wishes to leave the market. In other words, no surplus is being made on that marginal unit, and the marginal firm is just breaking even on it. The price in this context would seem to be just covering the marginal cost of production. 15 This is an important result. Suppose that the marginal benefit from consuming a good were higher than the marginal cost to society of producing it. It could then be argued that society would be better off producing more of the good because, by increasing production, more could be added to benefits than to costs. Equally, if the marginal cost were above the marginal benefit from consuming a good, society would be producing too much of the good and would benefit from producing less. The best possible position is thus where marginal benefit is equal to marginal cost – in other words, where price is set equal to marginal cost. One way of viewing this system is through the notion of opportunity cost, introduced in Chapter 1. For example, in choosing to produce onions, a farmer faces an opportunity cost. If resources are indeed used to produce onions, those resources are not being EXERCISE 15.1 Quantity of investment goods per period Consider Figure 15.3, which shows a production possibility curve (PPC) for an economy that produces consumer goods and investment goods. A Identify each of the following (hint: in some cases more than one answer is possible): a a point of productive inefficiency b a point that is Pareto-superior to B c a point of productive efficiency d a point of allocative efficiency e an unreachable point (hint: think about what would need to happen for society to reach such a point) C B D PPC 0 Quantity of consumer goods per period ▲ Figure 15.3 A production possibility curve 211 308275_C15_CAM_IASAL ECO_208_217.indd 211 17/02/21 5:01 PM A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 15 Test yourself 15.2 What are the two key aspects of efficiency? used to grow sweet potatoes. There may come a point at which the cost of producing onions becomes too high if the profitability of sweet potatoes is so much higher than that for onions, because of changes in the pattern of consumer demand. When the firm finds that it is not covering its opportunity costs, it will transfer production from the market for onions to the market for sweet potatoes. Notice that this discussion is built on the assumption that firms are free to enter a market, or to exit from it. If all markets in an economy operated in this way, resources would be used so effectively that no reallocation of resources could generate an overall improvement. Allocative efficiency would be attained. The key question is whether the market mechanism will work sufficiently well to ensure that this happens – or whether it will fail. In other words, are there conditions that could arise in a market, in which price would not be set at marginal cost? We will return to this issue shortly. Dynamic efficiency KEY TERM dynamic efficiency: a view of efficiency that takes into account the effects of innovation and technological progress on productive and allocative efficiency in the long run The discussion of efficiency so far has been conducted in terms of how to make the best use of existing resources, producing an appropriate mix of goods and services and using factor inputs as efficiently as possible given existing knowledge and technology. This is good as far as it goes, but it does represent a relatively static view of efficiency. Dynamic efficiency goes one step further, recognising that the state of knowledge and technology changes over time. For example, investment in research and development today means that production can be carried out more efficiently at some future date. Furthermore, the development of new products may also mean that a different mix of goods and services may serve consumers better in the long term. The notion of dynamic efficiency stemmed from the work of Joseph Schumpeter, who argued that a preoccupation with static efficiency (efficiency in the short run) may sacrifice opportunities for greater efficiency in the long run. In other words, there may be a trade-off between achieving efficiency today and improving efficiency tomorrow. SUMMARY: PRODUCTIVE EFFICIENCY AND ALLOCATIVE EFFICIENCY » A society needs to find a way of using its limited resources as efficiently as possible. » Productive efficiency occurs when firms have chosen appropriate combinations of factors of production and produce the maximum output possible from those inputs. » Allocative efficiency occurs when firms produce an appropriate bundle of goods and services, given consumer preferences. » An allocation of resources is said to be a Pareto optimum if no reallocation of resources can make KEY TERM market failure: a situation in which the free-market equilibrium does not lead to a socially optimal allocation of resources, such that too much or too little of a good is being produced and/or consumed an individual better off without making some other individual worse off. » An individual market exhibits aspects of allocative efficiency when the marginal benefit received by society from consuming a good or service matches the marginal cost of producing it – that is, when price is equal to marginal cost. » Dynamic efficiency recognises that there may be a trade-off between efficiency in the short run and in the long run. 15.2 Market failure What is market failure? A key question in microeconomics is whether markets will work in such a way as to produce a good outcome for society as a whole. Market failure occurs when this is not the case. When we look at how markets do work, it turns out that there are significant situations in which markets do not produce the best for society. An ideal outcome for society would be where, for each good or service, the marginal benefit that society receives from consuming the good matches the marginal cost of 212 308275_C15_CAM_IASAL ECO_208_217.indd 212 17/02/21 5:01 PM KEY TERMS marginal social cost (MSC): the cost to society of producing an extra unit of a good asymmetric information: a situation in which some participants in a market have better information about market conditions than others Test yourself 15.3 In the case of a merit good, will too much or too little of the good be consumed? LEARNING LINK Externalities are discussed in more detail in the next chapter, which shows how they lead to allocative inefficiency. 15 Reasons for market failure Externalities If the costs that firms and consumers face and the prices to which they respond do not reflect the actual costs and benefits associated with the production and consumption of goods, then the market equilibrium will not represent the best outcome for society, even if demand seems to equal supply. Suppose your elder sister is on a gap year before going to uni. She owns a car and is still living at home. You persuade her to give you a lift to college, although this takes her out of her way. What would she charge you for this? The journey will obviously cost her fuel, but is that the only cost? What about the wear and tear on her car? Her time? The loss of value of her car because of the increase in mileage? If she only charges you for the fuel, you will think that the journey is cheaper than it actually is and might ask her to drive you every day. An externality exists where the economic agents do not pay all of the costs, or are unaware of all the benefits. These extra costs or benefits are often to society, rather than specifically to the agents. 15 Efficiency and market failure marginal social benefit (MSB): the additional benefit that society gains from consuming an extra unit of a good producing it. If the actual amount is larger or smaller than this then the society could be better off. Notice that when we talk about marginal benefit and marginal cost here, it is the marginal benefit and cost to society that is relevant. We will refer to these as marginal social benefit and marginal social cost. Information failures If markets are to be effective in guiding resource allocation, it is important that economic decision-makers receive full and accurate information about market conditions. Consumers need information about the prices at which they can buy and the quality of the products for sale. Producers need to be able to observe how consumers react to prices. Information is thus of crucial significance if markets are to work. However, there are some markets in which not all traders have access to good information, or in which some traders have more or better access to it than others. This is known as a situation of asymmetric information, and can be a source of market failure. EXERCISE 15.2 Mary, who has retired, is sitting quietly at home when there is a knock on the door. At the door is a stranger who tells her that he has noticed that her roof is in desperate need of repair, and if she does not get something done about it very soon, there will be problems in the next rainstorm. Fortunately, he can help – for a price. Discuss whether there is a market failure in this situation, and what Mary (or others) could do about it. Healthcare One example of asymmetric information is in healthcare. Suppose you go to your dentist for a check-up. He tells you that you have a filling that needs to be replaced, although you have had no pain or problems with it. In this situation the seller in a market has much better information about the product than the buyer. You as the buyer have no idea whether or not the recommended treatment is needed, and without going to another dentist for a second opinion you have no way of finding out. You might think this is an unsatisfactory situation, as it seems to give a lot of power to the seller relative to the consumer. The situation is even worse where the dentist does not even publish the prices for treatment until after it has been carried out! 213 308275_C15_CAM_IASAL ECO_208_217.indd 213 17/02/21 5:01 PM The same argument applies in the case of other areas of healthcare, where doctors have better information than their patients about the sort of treatment that is needed. 15 A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY Test yourself 15.4 Eighteen-year-olds whose parents or relatives have attended university are much more likely to take up a university place than those from families where nobody has ever attended. To what extent could this be a result of an information failure? Education The market for education is similar. Teachers or government inspectors may know more about the subjects and topics that students need to study than the students do themselves. This is partly because teachers are able to take a longer view and can see education provision in a broader perspective. Students taking economics at university may have to take a course in mathematics and statistics in their first year, and some will always complain that they have come to study economics, not maths. It is only later that they come to realise that competence in maths is crucial these days for the economics that they will study later in their course. How could this problem be tackled? The answer would seem to be obvious – if the problem arises from an information failure, then the answer should be to improve the information flow, in this case to students. This might be achieved by providing a convincing explanation of why the curriculum has been designed in a particular way. It may also be necessary to provide incentives for students to study particular unpopular subjects, perhaps by making success a requirement for progression to the next stage of the course. By understanding the economic cause of a problem, it is possible to devise a strategy that should go some way towards removing the market failure. Second-hand cars One of the most famous examples of asymmetric information relates to the secondhand (or ‘pre-owned’, by the latest terminology) car market. This is because the first paper that drew attention to the problem of asymmetric information, by Nobel laureate George Akerlof, focused on this market. ▲ Second-hand cars Akerlof argued that there are two types of car. Some cars are good runners and are totally reliable, whereas some are continually breaking down and needing parts and servicing; the latter are known as ‘lemons’ in the USA (allegedly from fruit machines, where lemons offer the lowest prize). The problem in the second-hand car market arises because the owners of cars (potential sellers) have better information about their cars than the potential buyers. In other words, when a car owner decides to sell a car, he or she knows whether it is a lemon or a good-quality car – but a buyer cannot tell. In this sort of market, car dealers can adopt one of two possible strategies. One is to offer a high price and buy up all the cars in the market, knowing that the lemons will be sold on at a loss. The problem is that, if the lemons make up a large proportion 214 308275_C15_CAM_IASAL ECO_208_217.indd 214 17/02/21 5:03 PM STUDY TIP You may recall that the key characteristics of public goods are that they are non-exclusive, non-rivalrous and nonrejectable. The concepts of merit and demerit goods and public goods were introduced in Chapter 1 and discussed further in Chapter 5. STUDY TIP Don’t forget that having price equal to marginal cost is the key indicator of allocative efficiency. You will see in Chapters 18 and 19 that there are some market structures in which price is likely to be set above marginal cost. Test yourself 15.5 Name three possible causes of market failure. 15 Again, the solution may be to tackle the problem at its root, by finding a way to provide information. In the case of second-hand cars, some dealers may offer warranties as a way of improving the flow of information about the quality of cars for sale. Merit and demerit goods Information failure is at the heart of the examples of merit and demerit goods. In this case, the nature of the information failure is that the government sees that consumers of a good misperceive the benefits and/or costs of consuming a good or service. This may then cause merit goods to be underconsumed and demerit goods to be overconsumed. This in turn means that there will be a divergence between marginal social benefits and marginal social costs. Public goods Another form of market failure involves the provision of public goods, where the problem arises from the characteristics of the goods. The root of the market failure here is the free-rider problem, which removes the incentive for firms to supply public goods. 15 Efficiency and market failure LEARNING LINK of the cars in the market, this could generate overall losses for the dealers. The alternative is to offer a low price, and just buy up all the lemons to sell for scrap. In this situation, the market for good-quality used cars is effectively destroyed – an extreme form of market failure! Firm dominance in a market Another form of market failure may occur when a firm or firms hold such a strong position in a market that they can take advantage of the situation at the expense of others – either their consumers or their suppliers. For example, a firm may be able to charge a higher price for its product because of the lack of effective competition in the market. This will be discussed further in Chapters 18 and 19. EXERCISE 15.3 Identify the form of market failure associated with each of the following: a the use of tobacco b the provision of a police officer c vaccination against measles d a situation in which a firm cannot easily monitor how hard an employee is working e a firm with such a dominant position in a market that it is able to raise the price of its product SUMMARY: MARKET FAILURE » Free markets do not always lead to the best possible allocation of resources: there may be market failure, causing the market equilibrium to diverge from the socially optimum position. » When there are costs or benefits that are external to the price mechanism, the economy will not reach allocative efficiency. » Markets can operate effectively only when participants in the market have full information about market conditions. » Goods that the government believes will be underconsumed (overconsumed) in a free market are known as merit goods (demerit goods). » Public goods have characteristics that prevent markets from supplying the appropriate quantity. » Markets may fail when firms are able to utilise market power to disadvantage consumers. 215 308275_C15_CAM_IASAL ECO_208_217.indd 215 17/02/21 5:03 PM END OF CHAPTER QUESTIONS Multiple choice 1 A student has written the following three statements about economic efficiency: i Productive efficiency is attained at lowest long-run average cost (LRAC). ii Allocative efficiency is achieved where P = MU. iii Allocative efficiency is achieved where MSB = MSC. Which of the statements are true? A i and ii B i and iii C ii and iii D only i 2 The diagram represents the relationship between R&D costs and LRAC. Which economic concept is being illustrated? R&D costs A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 15 0 LRAC A productive efficiency C dynamic efficiency B allocative efficiency D economic efficiency Data response 1 Read the following extract and then answer the questions that follow. The problems of Kenyan flower production Kenya is one of the largest exporters of cut flowers in the world. Indeed, in 2020 Kenya’s main export was horticultural products, closely followed by tea. Europeans often turn to surprisingly cheap supermarket blooms at celebration times, but many may not realise that up to 38% of those bouquets were grown in Kenya. Cheap labour helps Kenyan flower farmers to minimise costs with over 2 million workers employed locally in the labour-intensive industry. However, with increasing competition, notably from the technology-rich Netherlands, Kenyan flower producers must be very aware of getting the right cost combination of labour and capital inputs. Despite clear success in this multi-billion-dollar industry, Kenya will not necessarily achieve Pareto optimality in its resource allocation. Moreover, its success will almost certainly have come at a price. An initial lack of regulation over the use of chemical fertilisers has resulted in the significant pollution of freshwater sources such as Kenya’s Lake Naivasha. More recently, interventions have been put in place reflecting dynamic efficiency. However, fish farmers face smaller catches as experts warn it could take 40 years for lakes such as Naivasha to recover. Those bathing in contaminated water can also suffer health problems; eye infections have been reported. Therein lies a further set of problems. Those suffering with such conditions will be unsure if they require relatively expensive local healthcare. If they decide they do, they may be similarly unsure whether any medication they receive is necessary or ultimately the best value for money. 216 308275_C15_CAM_IASAL ECO_208_217.indd 216 17/02/21 8:53 PM a Explain why a point on a production possibility curve diagram using Kenya’s two main exports could be productively but not allocatively efficient. b Assume that a Kenyan flower farm is producing its desired output level from a given set of inputs at the minimum average cost from those inputs. With reference to the extract, explain why this flower farm may not be productively efficient. 15 c Define the term ‘dynamic efficiency’. e Discuss, using the extract, the extent to which market failure in the healthcare sector could be caused by asymmetric information. 15 Efficiency and market failure d Explain what is meant by Pareto optimality in resource allocation and state where on a production possibility curve diagram Pareto optimality is achieved. 217 308275_C15_CAM_IASAL ECO_208_217.indd 217 17/02/21 5:04 PM A LEVEL PART 7 The price system and the microeconomy A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 16 Private costs and benefits, externalities and social costs and benefits KEY TERMS What this chapter covers private cost: a cost incurred by an individual (firm or consumer) as part of its production or other economic activities ★ private and social benefits and costs ★ externalities: negative and positive externalities in production and external cost: a cost associated with an individual’s (a firm or household’s) production or other economic activities, which is borne by a third party and is not reflected in market prices social costs: the sum of private and external costs private benefit: the benefit received by an individual (a firm or consumer) as part of its economic activity external benefit: the benefit received by society (a firm or household) that accrues to a third party (firm or household) not engaged in that economic activity, but which is not reflected in market prices social benefits: the sum of private benefits and external benefits Test yourself 16.1 What is the difference between marginal private cost and marginal social cost? ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ consumption deadweight loss associated with externalities examples of markets with externalities asymmetric information and moral hazard costs and benefits in decision making social cost–benefit analysis If markets are to be effective in guiding the allocation of resources in society, a precondition is that market prices are able to reflect the full costs and benefits associated with market transactions. However, there are many situations in which this is not so, and there are costs or benefits that are external to the workings of the market mechanism. This chapter examines the circumstances in which this may happen, and provides a justification for government intervention to improve the workings of the market. 16.1 Private and social benefits and costs In the next chapter, we will be considering the costs faced by producers in the production process. Such costs are private costs, in the sense that firms must meet these costs, which they do by factoring them into the prices that they charge for their products. However, in the case of some products there are costs associated with production that are not borne directly by the producers, but by third parties. These are known as external costs. From the viewpoint of society as a whole, the costs of production should include both private and external costs. So, the social costs of production are equal to private costs plus external costs. Similarly, we should realise that the private benefits received by an individual (consumer or firm) from the production of a good or service may be augmented by external benefits that are received by third parties to a transaction. So, the social benefits are equal to private benefits that accrue to individuals plus the external benefits received by third parties. When considering whether a market is achieving allocative efficiency, it is important that these external costs and benefits are taken into account to avoid inflicting costs on society. EXERCISE 16.1 In the production of a product, the costs faced by firms amount to $75 and the consumers of the product receive benefits of $90. However, there are also costs that are not borne directly by the firms, which amount to $20. In addition, there are spin-off benefits of $15. Is the overall balance of social benefits and social costs positive or negative? 218 308275_C16_CAM_IASAL ECO_218_233.indd 218 17/02/21 5:20 PM SUMMARY: PRIVATE AND SOCIAL BENEFITS AND COSTS » A cost borne by an individual (firm or consumer) as consumer) as part of its economic activity is a private benefit. » The benefit received by society (a firm or household) that accrues to a third party (firm or household) not engaged in that economic activity, but which is not reflected in market prices, is an external benefit. » The social benefit associated with an economic activity is the sum of private and external benefits. 16.2 Externalities KEY TERMS externality: a cost or a benefit that is external to a market transaction, and is thus not reflected in market prices consumption externality: an externality that impacts on the consumption side of a market, which may be either positive or negative production externality: an externality that impacts on the production side of a market, which may be either positive or negative Externality is one of those ugly words invented by economists, which says exactly what it means. It simply describes a cost or a benefit that is external to the market mechanism. An externality will lead to a form of market failure because if the cost or benefit is not reflected in market prices, it cannot be taken into consideration by all parties to a transaction. In other words, there may be costs or benefits resulting from a transaction that are borne (or enjoyed) by some third party not directly involved in that transaction. This in turn implies that decisions will not be aligned with the best interests of society. For example, if there is an element of costs that is not borne by producers, it is likely that ‘too much’ of the good will be produced. Where there are benefits that are not included, it is likely that too little will be produced. Later in the chapter, it will be shown that this is exactly what does happen. Externalities can affect either demand or supply in a market: that is to say, they may arise either in consumption or in production. In approaching this topic, begin by tackling Exercise 16.2, which offers an example of each type of externality. 16 16 Private costs and benefits, externalities and social costs and benefits part of its production or other economic activities is a private cost. » A cost that is associated with an individual’s (a firm or household’s) production or other economic activities that is borne by a third party and is not reflected in market prices is an external cost. » The social cost of an economic activity is the sum of private and external costs. » The benefit received by an individual (a firm or EXERCISE 16.2 Each of the following situations describes a type of externality. Does it affect production or consumption? a A factory situated in the centre of a town, and close to a residential district, emits toxic fumes through a chimney during its production process. As a result, residents living nearby have to wash their clothes more frequently, and incur higher medical bills as a result of breathing in the fumes. b Residents living along a main road cover their houses with lavish lights and decorations during major festivals, helping passers-by to capture the festive spirit. c A factory that produces chemicals, which is located on the banks of a river, installs a new water purification plant that improves the quality of water discharged into the river. A fish farm located downstream finds that its productivity increases, and that it has to spend less on filtering the water. d Fatima enjoys playing her music at high volume late at night, in spite of the fact that she lives in a flat with inadequate sound insulation. The neighbours prefer peace and quiet, but cannot escape the noise of Fatima’s music. 219 308275_C16_CAM_IASAL ECO_218_233.indd 219 17/02/21 5:20 PM Toxic fumes Example a in Exercise 16.2 is a negative production externality. The factory emits toxic fumes that impose costs on the residents (third parties) living nearby, who incur high washing and medical bills. The households face costs as a result of the production activities of the firm, so the firm does not face the full costs of its activity. Thus, the private costs faced by the producer are lower than the social costs: that is, the costs faced by society as a whole. The producer will take decisions based only on its private costs, ignoring the external costs it imposes on society. From society’s point of view, social costs are the sum of private and external costs. Figure 16.1 illustrates this situation under the assumption that firms operate in a competitive market (i.e. there is not a monopoly). Here, D (MSB) represents the demand curve, which was characterised in Chapter 4 as representing the marginal social benefit derived from consuming a good. In other words, the demand curve represents consumers’ willingness to pay for the good, and thus reflects their marginal valuation of the product. Costs, benefits A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 16 S (MSC ) Y P* P1 MPC X Z D (MSB) Q* Q1 Quantity per period ▲ Figure 16.1 A negative production externality LEARNING LINK The way that decisions are taken ‘at the margin’ was explained in Chapter 1. Producers face marginal private costs given by the line MPC, but in fact impose higher costs than this on society. S represents the supply curve that includes these additional costs imposed on society, and therefore represents the true cost to society of producing the good. This may be regarded as being the marginal social cost (MSC) of the firms’ production. If the market is unregulated by the government, firms will choose how much to supply on the basis of the marginal (private) cost they face, shown by MPC in Figure 16.1. The market equilibrium will thus be at quantity traded Q1, where firms just break even on the marginal unit sold; price will be set at P1. This is not a good outcome for society, as it is clear that there is a divergence between the price in the market and the ‘true’ marginal cost – in other words, a divergence between marginal social benefit and marginal social cost. It is this divergence that is at the heart of the market failure. The last unit of this good sold imposes higher costs on society than the marginal benefit derived from consuming it. Too much is being produced at the free-market equilibrium. In fact, the socially optimum position is at Q*, where marginal social benefit is equal to marginal social cost. This will be reached if the price is set equal to (social) marginal cost at P*. Less of the good will be consumed, but also less pollution will be created, and society will be better off than at Q1. 220 308275_C16_CAM_IASAL ECO_218_233.indd 220 17/02/21 5:20 PM QUANTITATIVE SKILLS 16.1 KEY TERM The extent of the welfare loss that society suffers can be identified: it is shown by the shaded triangle (XYZ) in Figure 16.1. Each unit of output that is produced above Q* imposes a cost equal to the vertical distance between MSC and MPC. The shaded area represents the difference between marginal social cost and marginal benefit over the range of output between the optimum output and the free-market level of output. This is known as the deadweight welfare loss of the externality. STUDY TIP Test yourself 16.2 Does the presence of a negative production externality cause overproduction or underconsumption? Make sure that you are clear about these key ideas: » Demand represents consumers’ willingness and ability to purchase a good or service – this is consumers’ marginal private benefit (MPB). » Where society receives more or less benefit from the consumption of a good or service, this is the marginal social benefit (MSB). It includes the external benefits. » Supply represents firms’ willingness and ability to supply a good or service – this is firms’ marginal private cost (MPC). » Where society incurs more or less cost from the production of a good or service, this is the marginal social cost (MSC). It includes the external costs. Festive lights and decorations Example b in Exercise 16.2 is an example of a positive consumption externality. Residents of this street decorate their homes in order to share the festival spirit with passers-by. The benefit they gain from the decorations (the private benefit) spills over and adds to the enjoyment of others (providing external benefit). In other words, the social benefits from the residents’ decision to provide festive decorations go beyond the private enjoyment that they receive. The social benefit is equal to the sum of private and external benefits. Test yourself 16.3 Costs, benefits Does the presence of a positive consumption externality cause overproduction or underconsumption? Figure 16.2 illustrates this situation. MPB represents the marginal private benefits gained by residents from the festive decorations; but MSB represents the full marginal social benefit that the community gains, which is higher than the MPB. Residents will provide decorations up to the point Q2, where their marginal private benefit is just balanced by the marginal cost of the decorations. However, if the full social benefits received are taken into account, Q* would be the optimum point: the residents do not provide enough décor for the community to reach the optimum. The shaded triangle in Figure 16.2 shows the deadweight welfare loss: that is, the amount of social benefit forgone if the outcome is at Q2 instead of Q*. Again, there is a divergence between the free-market equilibrium and the socially preferred position. 16 16 Private costs and benefits, externalities and social costs and benefits deadweight welfare loss (of an externality): the loss in social welfare that arises when an externality moves a market away from its optimum position Identifying welfare loss in a diagram MC MSB MPB Figure 16.2 A positive consumption externality 0 Q2 Q* Quantity of festive decorations 221 308275_C16_CAM_IASAL ECO_218_233.indd 221 17/02/21 5:20 PM It is important to realise that both negative and positive externalities are situations of market failure. Positive externalities carry a market away from the social optimum just as negative externalities do. LEARNING LINK The distinction between positive and normative statements was introduced in Chapter 1. Example b may be seen as a reminder of the distinction between positive and normative analysis. Economists would agree that Figure 16.2 shows the effects of a beneficial consumption externality. However, probably not everyone would agree that the lavish festive decorations are providing such benefits. This is where a normative judgement comes into play. It could equally be argued that the lavish decorations are unsightly and inappropriate, or that they constitute a distraction for drivers and are therefore likely to cause accidents. After all, not everyone appreciates over-the-top decorations. Water purification Example c in Exercise 16.2 is a production externality that has positive effects. The action taken by the chemical firm to purify its waste water has beneficial effects on the fish farm, which finds that its costs have been reduced without it having taken any action whatsoever. Indeed, it finds that it has to spend less on filtering the water. Figure 16.3 shows the position facing the chemicals firm. It faces relatively high marginal private costs given by MPC. However, its actions have reduced the costs faced by the fish farm, so the ‘social’ cost of the firm’s production activities is lower than its private cost. Thus, in this case marginal social cost, shown by MSC in the figure, is lower than marginal private cost. The firm will produce up to the point where MPC equals marginal social benefit: that is, at Q3. Costs, benefits A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 16 STUDY TIP MPC MSC D (MSB) 0 Q3 Q* Quantity of chemicals per period ▲ Figure 16.3 A positive production externality In this market position, notice that the marginal benefit that society receives from consuming the product is higher than the marginal social cost of producing it, so too little of the product is being consumed for society’s good. Society would be better off at Q*, where marginal social benefit is equal to marginal social cost. Again, the shaded triangle in Figure 16.3 represents the extent of the inefficiency: it is given by the excess of marginal social benefit over marginal social cost, over the range of output between the market outcome and society’s optimum position. This is the deadweight welfare loss in this situation. Loud music Example d in Exercise 16.2 is a negative consumption externality. Fatima gains benefit from listening to her music at high volume, but the neighbours also hear her music and suffer as a result. Their private benefit is reduced by having to hear the music when all they want is peace and quiet. 222 308275_C16_CAM_IASAL ECO_218_233.indd 222 17/02/21 5:21 PM Costs, benefits Figure 16.4 illustrates this. The situation can be interpreted in terms of the benefits that accrue as a result of Fatima’s consumption of loud music. She gains benefit as shown by the line MPB, which represents marginal private benefit. However, the social benefit is lower than this if the annoyance suffered by the neighbours is taken into account, so MSB in Figure 16.4 represents the marginal social benefits from Fatima’s loud music. MSC MSB Q* Q4 Quantity of music ▲ Figure 16.4 A negative consumption externality Fatima will listen to music up to the point where her marginal private benefit is just equal to the marginal cost of playing it, at Q4. However, the optimal position that takes the neighbours into consideration is where marginal social benefit is equal to marginal cost – at Q*. Thus, Fatima plays too much music for the good of society. Externalities occur in a wide variety of market situations, and constitute an important source of market failure. This means that externalities may hinder the achievement of good resource allocation from society’s perspective. The final section of this chapter explores some ways in which attempts have been made to measure the social costs imposed by externalities. First, however, a number of other externalities that appear in various parts of the economy will be examined. Test yourself 16.4 STUDY TIP Explain how to identify the area of welfare loss in a diagram showing the effect of a positive production externality. Externalities are a common topic, so be ready to respond if questioned. Be very careful when drawing the diagram, especially in identifying the area representing welfare loss. If you understand why this area represents welfare loss, you should be able to check whether you have identified it correctly. If you are uncertain about this, look back at Quantitative skills 16.1 on page 221. 16 Private costs and benefits, externalities and social costs and benefits MPB 0 16 Examples of markets with externalities Externalities and the environment Concern for the environment has been growing in recent years, with ‘green’ lobbyist groups demanding attention, sometimes through demonstrations and protests. There are so many different facets to this question that it is sometimes difficult to isolate the core issues. Externalities are central to much of the debate. Some of the issues are international in nature, such as the debate over global warming. At the heart of this concern is the way in which emissions of greenhouse gases are said to be warming up the planet. Sea levels are rising and major climate change seems imminent. One reason why this question is especially difficult to tackle is that actions taken by one country can have effects on other countries. Scientists argue that the problem is 223 308275_C16_CAM_IASAL ECO_218_233.indd 223 17/02/21 5:21 PM caused mainly by pollution created by transport and industry, especially in the richer countries of the world. However, poorer countries suffer the consequences as well, especially countries such as Bangladesh, where much of the land is low lying and prone to severe flooding. 16 In principle, this is very similar to example a in Exercise 16.2: it is an example of a negative production externality, in which the nations causing most of the damage face only part of the costs caused by their lifestyles and production processes. The inevitable result in an unregulated market is that too much pollution is produced. A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY When externalities cross international borders in this way, the problem can be tackled only through international cooperation. For example, as part of the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) the Paris Agreement was launched in 2016. This covers greenhouse gas emissions mitigation, adaptation and finance, and by 2020, 189 countries had become parties to the agreement. President Trump’s decision to withdraw from the agreement in 2020 threatened the effectiveness of the measures, but Joe Biden reversed this as one of his first acts as President. Global warming is not the only example of international externality effects. Scandinavian countries have suffered from acid rain caused by pollution in other European countries, including the UK. Forest fires left to burn in Indonesia have caused air pollution in neighbouring Singapore. ▲ Forest fire in Indonesia Another environmental issue concerns rivers. Some of the big rivers of the world, such as the Nile in Africa, pass through several countries on their way to the sea. For Egypt, through which the river runs at the end of its journey, the Nile is crucial for the livelihood of the economy. If countries further upstream were to increase their usage of the river, perhaps through new irrigation projects, this could have disastrous effects on Egypt. Again, the actions of one set of economic agents would have damaging effects on others, and these effects would not be reflected in market prices, in the sense that the upstream countries would not have to face the full cost of their actions. LEARNING LINK The importance of property rights is discussed in Chapter 21, together with measures that could be taken to tackle externalities. Part of the problem here can be traced back to the difficulty of enforcing property rights. If the countries imposing the costs could be forced to make appropriate payment for their actions, this would help to bring the costs back within the market mechanism. Such a process is known in economics as ‘internalising the externality’. Concern has also been expressed about the loss of biodiversity, a word that is shorthand for ‘biological diversity’. The issue here is that when a section of rainforest is cleared to plant soya, or for timber, it is possible that species of plants, insects or animals whose existence is not even known at present may be wiped out. Many modern medicines are based on chemicals that occur naturally in the wild. By eradicating species before they have been discovered, possible scientific advances will be forgone. Notice that when it comes to measuring the value of what is being destroyed, biodiversity offers particular challenges – namely, the problem of putting a value on something that might not even be there. 224 308275_C16_CAM_IASAL ECO_218_233.indd 224 17/02/21 5:29 PM Externalities and transport Costs, benefits Cities in many parts of the world, such as Singapore and London, have been attempting to tackle traffic congestion. When traffic on the roads reaches a certain volume, congestion imposes heavy costs on road users. This is another example of an externality. MSC MPC Q* Q1 Number of journeys per period ▲ Figure 16.5 Traffic congestion Figure 16.5 illustrates the situation. Suppose that D (MSB) represents the demand curve for car journeys along a particular stretch of road. When deciding whether or not to undertake a journey, drivers will balance the marginal benefit gained from making the journey against the marginal cost that they face. This is given by MPC – the marginal private cost of undertaking journeys. When the road is congested, a motorist who decides to undertake the journey adds to the congestion, and slows the traffic. The MPC curve incorporates the cost to the motorist of joining a congested road, and the chosen number of journeys will be at Q1. However, in adding to the congestion the motorist not only suffers the costs of congestion, but also imposes some marginal increase in costs on all other users of the road, as everyone suffers from the slower journeys resulting from the extra congestion. Thus, the marginal social costs (MSC) of undertaking journeys are higher than the cost faced by any individual motorist. MSC is therefore higher than MPC. Society would be better off with lower congestion: that is, with the number of journeys undertaken being limited to Q*, where marginal social benefit equals marginal social cost. 16 Private costs and benefits, externalities and social costs and benefits D (MSB) 0 16 Externalities and health Healthcare is a sector in which there is often public provision, or at least some state intervention in support of the health services. However, in many countries public provision of healthcare is augmented with private healthcare, and the use of private health insurance schemes is on the increase. Again, externalities can help to explain why there should be a need for government to intervene. Consider the case of vaccination against a disease such as measles. Suppose an individual is considering whether or not to be vaccinated. Being vaccinated reduces the probability of that individual contracting the disease, so there are palpable potential benefits. However, these benefits must be balanced against the costs. There may be a direct charge for the vaccine; some individuals may have a phobia of needles; or they may be concerned about possible side-effects. Individuals will opt to be vaccinated only if the marginal expected benefit to them is at least as large as the marginal cost. From society’s point of view, however, there are potential benefits that individuals will not take into account. After all, if they do contract measles, there is a chance of their passing it on to others. Indeed, if lots of people decide not to be vaccinated, 225 308275_C16_CAM_IASAL ECO_218_233.indd 225 17/02/21 5:29 PM there is the possibility of a widespread epidemic, which would be costly and damaging to many. Figure 16.6 illustrates this point. A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY Costs, benefits 16 MSC MSB MPB 0 Q1 Q* Quantity of vaccinations ▲ Figure 16.6 Vaccination Test yourself 16.5 Why might there be externality effects associated with smoking tobacco? The previous paragraph argues that the social benefits to society of having people vaccinated against measles exceed the private benefits that will be perceived by individuals, so that marginal social benefits exceed marginal private benefits. Private individuals will choose to balance marginal private benefit against marginal private cost at Q1, whereas society would prefer more people to be vaccinated at Q*. This parallels the discussion of a positive consumption externality. EXTENSION MATERIAL The Covid-19 pandemic and externalities During the Covid-19 pandemic, externalities became vitally important. With no vaccine available, and little knowledge about how to treat the virus, containing the spread of the disease relied on individuals being prepared to act in a socially desirable manner. Lockdowns and the use of face coverings were central to the strategy for preventing the spread of the virus. This was all about controlling the negative externalities that arose from people who were infected with the disease (perhaps without realising it) passing it on to others. Those countries that were slow to recognise the importance of this, or which refused to believe it, suffered huge pressure on healthcare services and massive loss of life. Individuals who broke the rules on social distancing imposed heavy costs on others. And there were some cases where social isolation was simply not possible. In this case, there was the added complication that the costs of dealing with the externalities had an enormous cost in economic terms, with many industries and activities being closed down altogether for the period of the lockdown. This then created difficult decisions for political leaders in trying to balance the economic costs of lockdown against the human costs of allowing the virus to take hold. Externalities and education As you are reading this textbook, it is reasonably safe to assume that you are following a course in economics. You have decided to demand education. This is yet another area in which externalities may be important. When you decided to take A levels (including economics), there were probably a number of factors that influenced your decision. Perhaps you intend to demand even more education in the future, by proceeding to study at university. Part of your decision process probably takes into account the fact that education improves your future earnings potential. Your expected lifetime earnings depend in part on the level of educational qualifications that you attain. Research has shown that, on average, 226 308275_C16_CAM_IASAL ECO_218_233.indd 226 17/02/21 5:29 PM graduates earn more during their lifetimes than non-graduates. This is partly because there is a productivity effect: by becoming educated, you cultivate a range of skills that in later life will make you more productive, and this helps to explain why you can expect higher lifetime earnings than someone who chooses not to demand education. Test yourself 16.6 In other words, when you decide to undertake education, you do so on the basis of the expected private benefits that you hope to gain from education. However, you do not take into account the additional benefits through cooperation that society will reap. So here is another example of a positive consumption externality. Externalities and tourism As international transport has become easier and cheaper, more people are wanting to travel to new and different destinations. For less developed countries, this offers an opportunity to earn much-needed foreign exchange. There has been some criticism of this. The building of luxury hotels in the midst of the poverty that characterises many less developed countries is said to have damaging effects on the local population by emphasising differences in living standards. However, constructing the infrastructure that tourists need may have beneficial effects on the domestic economy. Improved roads and communication systems can benefit local businesses. This effect can be interpreted as an externality, in the sense that the local firms will face lower costs as a result of the facilities provided for the tourist sector. EXERCISE 16.3 Discuss examples of some externalities that you meet in everyday situations, and classify them as affecting either production or consumption. 16 Private costs and benefits, externalities and social costs and benefits School drop-out rates tend to be high in some less developed countries. What sort of externality effect might be at work here? What does society get out of this? Evidence suggests that, not only does education improve productivity, but a group of educated workers cooperating with each other becomes even more productive. This is an externality effect, as it depends on interaction between educated workers – but each individual perceives only the individual benefit, and not the benefits of cooperation. 16 Asymmetric information and moral hazard One of the reasons advanced for possible market failure in the previous chapter was the presence of asymmetric information. When some parties to a transaction have better information than others, they may be able to benefit at the others’ expense. This is another situation in which there may be costs entailed in an economic transaction which take place outside of market prices and which affect a third party. A good example of this is in the market for insurance. The insurance market KEY TERMS adverse selection: a situation in which a person at risk is more likely to take out insurance moral hazard: a situation in which a person who has taken out insurance is prone to taking more risk People take out insurance to cover themselves against the risk of uncertain future events. Asymmetric information can cause problems with this market in two different ways. Suppose an individual approaches an insurance company wanting health insurance. The individual knows more about his or her current health and health history than the insurance company. After all, the individual knows whether they are prone to illness or if they are accident-prone. This could mean that the people most likely to take out health insurance are the ones most likely to fall ill or be involved in accidents. This is known as adverse selection. A second form of information failure in terms of insurance is known as moral hazard. An individual who has taken out insurance may be more likely to take risks, knowing that he or she is covered by insurance. For example, if someone has taken out insurance against the loss of their mobile phone, they may be less careful about leaving it around. 227 308275_C16_CAM_IASAL ECO_218_233.indd 227 17/02/21 5:29 PM Test yourself 16.7 A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 16 A bank makes risky loans believing that it will be bailed out if it gets into trouble. Is this an example of adverse selection or moral hazard? EXERCISE 16.4 Table 16.1 shows the situation in a market where pollution is generated by the production process. a At what level of output would marginal social benefit be equal to marginal private cost? (Note: this would be the quantity of output that would be produced by firms in an unregulated competitive market.) b By how much would marginal social cost exceed marginal private cost at this level of output? c At what level of output would marginal social benefit be equal to marginal social cost? d What amount of tax would induce firms to supply this quantity of output? ▼ Table 16.1 A market with pollution Quantity produced (thousands per week) Marginal social benefit Marginal private cost Marginal social cost 10 80 5 10 20 75 10 20 30 70 20 35 40 60 32 60 50 48 48 90 60 30 75 125 70 8 110 175 SUMMARY: EXTERNALITIES » Markets can operate effectively only if all relevant » » » » costs and benefits are taken into account in decision making. Some costs and benefits are external to the market mechanism, and are thus neglected, causing a distortion in resource allocation. Such external costs and benefits are known as ‘externalities’. Externalities may occur in either production or consumption, thereby affecting either demand or supply. Externalities may be either positive or negative, but either way resources will not be optimally allocated if they are present. » Externalities arise in many aspects of economic life. » Environmental issues are especially prone to externality effects, as market prices do not always incorporate environmental issues, especially where property rights are not assigned. » Congestion on the roads can be seen as a form of externality. » Externalities also arise in the areas of healthcare provision and education, where individuals do not always perceive the full social benefits that arise. » Asymmetric information can also result in problems of adverse selection and moral hazard. 16.3 Costs and benefits in decision making The importance of externalities in regard to environmental and other issues means that it is especially important to be aware of externalities when taking decisions that are likely to affect the environment. This is especially important for large-scale projects that can have far-reaching effects on the economy, such as the construction of a new dam or a major road-building project. If good decisions are to be taken, it is crucial to be able to measure the external costs and benefits that are associated with those decisions, and not focus only on the private costs and benefits. 228 308275_C16_CAM_IASAL ECO_218_233.indd 228 17/02/21 5:29 PM This suggests that in taking such decisions, it is important to be able to weigh up the costs and benefits of a scheme. If it turns out that the benefits exceed the costs, it might be thought appropriate to go ahead. However, in valuing the costs and the benefits, it is clearly important to include some estimate for the externalities involved in order that the decision can be based on all relevant factors. In other words, it is important to take a ‘long and wide view’ and not to focus too narrowly on purely financial costs and benefits. Social cost–benefit analysis KEY TERM social cost–benefit analysis: a process of evaluating the worth of a project by comparing its costs and benefits, including both direct and social costs and benefits – including externality effects Social cost–benefit analysis is a procedure for bringing together the information needed to make appropriate decisions on such large-scale schemes. This entails a sequence of key steps. 1 Identify relevant costs and benefits The first step is to identify all relevant costs and benefits. This needs to cover all of the direct costs of the project. These can probably be identified relatively easily, and include the production costs, labour costs and so on. The indirect costs also need to be identified, and this is where externality effects need to be considered. For example, in constructing a dam across a river, there are the visible direct costs that are inevitably entailed in such a large engineering project. But there are also the indirect costs, i.e. the opportunity costs. How many people and businesses will be uprooted by the project, and how much land that could have been used for agriculture will be flooded as a result of the new dam? Similarly, in a roadbuilding scheme, it is important to think in terms not only of the costs of construction, but also of the opportunity cost – how else could the land being used for the road have been used? How will the increase in traffic affect the quality of life enjoyed by local residents? For example, they may suffer from noise from the traffic using the road, or from the traffic fumes. Similarly, direct and indirect benefits need to be identified. The dam may bring benefits in terms of hydroelectric power, or irrigation for crops. A new road may increase the efficiency of transportation, and reduce costs for firms. 16 Private costs and benefits, externalities and social costs and benefits A further complication is that with many such schemes the costs and benefits will be spread out over a long period of time, and it is important to come to a reasonable balance between the interests of present and future generations. 16 2 Valuation If the costs and benefits are to be compared, they all need to be given a monetary valuation. It is likely that some of them will be items that have a market price attached to them. For these, valuation is not a problem. However, for externalities, or for other indirect costs and benefits without a market valuation, it is necessary to establish a shadow price – an estimate of the monetary value of each item. Notice that this can be quite difficult, as some of the external costs may be elusive, especially if the impact is on the quality of life, rather than on measurable production loss. 3 Discounting the future It is also important to recognise that costs and benefits that will flow from the project at some point in the future need to be expressed in terms of their value in the present. From today’s perspective, a benefit that is immediate is more valuable than one that will only become relevant in 20 years’ time. In order to incorporate this notion into the calculations, we need to discount the future at an appropriate rate, and estimate the future stream of costs and benefits associated with the project under consideration. Notice that a government taking decisions on behalf of future generations may choose take a longer perspective than consumers who prefer to enjoy benefits in the present. Equally, a government that is feeling vulnerable may prefer to provide benefits in the present to persuade the electorate, rather than taking decisions that will not bear fruit until the distant future. In other words, there may be a political backdrop to take into account. 229 308275_C16_CAM_IASAL ECO_218_233.indd 229 17/02/21 5:29 PM The decision-making process If it is possible to identify all the private and external costs of a project, to place a monetary valuation on each of them and to choose an appropriate discount rate, then there is a framework for taking decisions about a project. The bottom line is whether the total social benefits expected to arise from a project outweigh the social costs. This may sound straightforward, but it is important to remember all the assumptions on which such decisions would be based. In particular, the valuations made of the various elements of benefits and costs may be considered to be at least partially subjective, and different members of society may take different views of what is an appropriate discount rate. However, this does not mean that social cost–benefit analysis is unhelpful. For example, a government may be choosing between a range of different development projects. By using consistent assumptions in valuation and discount rates across the projects, it may be possible to produce a coherent ranking of alternative projects, and thus identify the project that would produce the highest benefit–cost ratio. EXERCISE 16.5 You discover that your local authority has chosen to locate a new landfill site for waste disposal close to your home. What costs and benefits for society would result? Would these differ from your private costs and benefits? Would you object? EXERCISE 16.6 Each of the Figures 16.7–16.10 shows a particular type of externality. Costs, benefits For each figure, identify the sort of externality, and state whether the result is too much or too little output being traded in a free market. Costs, benefits A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 16 MSC MPC MSC MPB MSB MSB Quantity Quantity ▲ Figure 16.8 Externality B MSC Costs, benefits Costs, benefits ▲ Figure 16.7 Externality A MSC MPC MSB MSB MPB Quantity ▲ Figure 16.9 Externality C Quantity ▲ Figure 16.10 Externality D 230 308275_C16_CAM_IASAL ECO_218_233.indd 230 17/02/21 5:30 PM SUMMARY: COSTS AND BENEFITS IN DECISION MAKING » A number of approaches have been proposed to » Each component must then be valued. » An appropriate discount rate needs to be applied to those benefits and costs that will arise in the future. » The project with the highest ratio of benefits to costs is likely to be the one that is most beneficial for society. END OF CHAPTER QUESTIONS Multiple choice 1 During the Covid-19 pandemic, mathematical models of exponential growth were used to predict the number of new infections that an infected individual would cause. Which economic concept can be used to explain the cost this individual inflicts on others? A private cost B social cost C external cost D marginal cost 2 Which of the following is not an example of moral hazard? A The managers of a public limited company choose a project that will not maximise shareholder value because they do not bear the risk of losing investment in the company if the project is unsuccessful. B The owner of a car insured against theft leaves the engine running while they are getting a coffee. C An employee leaves their company mobile phone unattended. D A borrower takes out a loan at a higher interest rate because they do not have full information about the bank’s products. Data response 16 Private costs and benefits, externalities and social costs and benefits measure externalities. Measurement may enable a social cost–benefit analysis to be made of projects involving a substantial externality element. » The first step is to identify all direct and indirect (private and external) benefits and costs of a project. 16 Billion metric tonnes 1 Study Figure 16.11, read the following extract and then answer the questions that follow. 2019 3.0 History Projections 2.5 Petroleum 2.0 Natural gas 1.5 1.0 Coal 0.5 0 1990 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050 Source: Energy Policy Update ▲ Figure 16.11 US energy-related carbon dioxide emissions by fuel, 1990–2050 231 308275_C16_CAM_IASAL ECO_218_233.indd 231 17/02/21 5:30 PM New bike share scheme launched in Norwich A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 16 Norwich is the largest city in the east of England. In 2020, Transport for Norwich announced a new bike-sharing scheme aimed at reducing road traffic and carbon dioxide emissions through the government’s Transforming Cities Fund. The idea is to convert commuters away from using their own cars and even from using buses, and to encourage them instead to share the readily available environmentally more friendly cycles. This would both reduce emissions and increase the health and wellbeing of local people. However, this will spell double trouble for struggling local bus firms, which spend a large amount each year training their new bus drivers. Each year many of the existing bus drivers leave to work as coach drivers for local coach firms. The costs of the coach company are reduced as they receive the benefit of the previously trained and qualified drivers at no cost. As the cycle share scheme expands, driving schools are likely to see a reduction in demand for their services. The owner of one local driving school has been told to take the positives from this outcome because there will be a reduction in the deadweight welfare loss that results from driving their vehicles. The owner opined that it is existing heavily insured drivers who need additional lessons due to the excessive risks they take while driving, regardless of the damage they may cause. Source: Norfolk County Council a Compare the trends in energy-related carbon dioxide emissions illustrated in Figure 16.11 between 1990 and 2050. b State what is meant by private cost and identify one example from the extract. c Explain why the externality received by local coach firms in Norwich will lead to a social benefit greater than the corresponding private benefit. d Explain the positive externality in consumption created by the people of Norwich who take part in the cycle share scheme. e Assess, with the use of a diagram, the impact on the deadweight welfare loss created by the reduced demand from student drivers attending driving schools in Norwich. f State what is meant by moral hazard and provide one possible example from the extract. Essay style 2 Xiaoshan international airport serves Hangzhou, a major city in the Yangtze River Delta region of China. A proposed expansion to the airport is part of a wider push to strengthen Hangzhou’s infrastructure as the city prepares to host the 2022 Asian Games. Assess the contribution of social cost–benefit analysis in decision making with respect to undertaking a proposed airport expansion such as that of Xiaoshan. 232 308275_C16_CAM_IASAL ECO_218_233.indd 232 17/02/21 8:56 PM CASE STUDY Healthcare: public or market? The pandemic brought a new perspective. Suddenly the healthcare system was under enormous pressure, and there was a rush to try to protect the health service. The pandemic highlighted a particular problem with care homes, which were mainly provided by the private sector, and were strongly affected by the virus. Meanwhile, in the USA, the president was keen to dismantle the care funding system that had been put in place by his predecessor, which had provided affordable health insurance for poorer members of society. So, how should healthcare be funded? What does economic analysis have to say about the matter? The justification for public provision of healthcare rests on the existence of market failure. There are a number of reasons why there might be some form of market failure in the provision of healthcare, whether we consider the provision of preventative or curative measures. In the case of preventative healthcare, there may be other factors at work. Take the case of vaccination against disease. If vaccinations are provided by a private competitive market, an individual faces costs of the treatment, both financial and perhaps in the unpleasantness and possible risks of being vaccinated. The benefits of having been vaccinated may be perceived to be relatively low, if the individual sees a low probability of being infected. However, the benefits of vaccination from the point of view of society may be greater, because a widespread vaccination programme not only reduces the risk of infection for each individual, but also reduces the likelihood of an epidemic. Here again, the Covid-19 pandemic highlighted the controversy over vaccination programmes. 16 Private costs and benefits, externalities and social costs and benefits The UK’s National Health Service (NHS) was founded in 1948. Seventy years on, it faced crisis, with much talk in the media about failures in providing care and long waiting lists. This revitalised the debate about whether healthcare should be stateprovided, or whether market forces should be given a greater role. In the UK, market forces have played ▲ Protective medical equipment an increasing part in allocating resources within the public health sector through the operation of internal markets, but the debate over public versus private provision continues. Until the Covid-19 pandemic, the proportion of health expenditure undertaken by the public sector changed little. 16 Follow-up questions a Explain what is meant by market failure. b Draw a diagram to help to explain the possible market failure outlined in relation to a vaccination programme. 233 308275_C16_CAM_IASAL ECO_218_233.indd 233 17/02/21 5:37 PM A LEVEL PART 7 The price system and the microeconomy A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 17 Types of cost, revenue and profit, short-run and long-run production What this chapter covers ★ types of firm ★ production in the short run and the short-run production function ★ the law of diminishing returns ★ the relationship between total, average and marginal product ★ how short-run costs vary with output ★ fixed, variable and sunk costs ★ production and costs in the long run ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ economies and diseconomies of scale the minimum efficient scale X-inefficiency a firm’s revenue total, average and marginal revenue normal, supernormal and subnormal profit the shutdown price in the short run and long run profit maximisation Firms play a central role in the operation of markets. This chapter introduces the theory of the firm by examining some of the key concepts that are needed for this important part of economic analysis. The discussion will explore the relationship between costs and production in the short run and the long run, and explain how firms may act to maximise profit. 17.1 Types of firm KEY TERM firm (business): an organisation that produces output (a good or service) The economic agents concerned with providing the supply of goods and services are firms (businesses). Firms exist in order to organise production by bringing together factors of production in order to supply output to market. Internally, firms may be organised in various ways, from small businesses such as a corner shop to mega-sized multinational corporations (such as Google). A key decision that all firms face concerns the scale of their operations. This decision turns partly on the nature of the market that they are serving, but it also depends on the technology of the sector in which they operate and the structure of costs that they face. Some firms may need to grow in order to compete with other large-scale competitors in global markets. There may be many reasons why firms wish to expand their operations. In some sectors, there are examples of both large and small firms. For example, in the leisure sector, your local gymnasium may be a relatively small enterprise, but there are also some big players in the sports market, such as Chelsea FC and Sky. In the transport sector, there may be small local taxi firms, but there are also large firms such as global airlines. EXERCISE 17.1 Identify firms that operate in the town or city where you live. Classify them into three categories: 1 Small local firms that only operate in your area 2 National firms that sell throughout the country 3 International and multinational corporations that sell goods and services in global markets 234 308275_C17_CAM_IASAL ECO_234_255.indd 234 17/02/21 6:16 PM SUMMARY: TYPES OF FIRM » A firm is an organisation that exists to bring together factors of production in order to produce goods or services. » Firms range in the complexity of their organisation from sole traders to large companies. » Firms vary in size, from local concerns to large multinational corporations operating in global markets. In thinking about production in the short run, we consider a single firm and assume that it produces a single product. Of course, in reality this does not apply to all firms. There are many large conglomerate firms that produce a range of different products. However, this complicates the analysis unnecessarily, so the focus here is on a firm that produces a single product. In order to undertake production, the firm uses inputs of factors of production. These include human resources (labour, enterprise and management), natural resources (land, raw materials, energy) and produced resources (physical capital). The factors of production were explained in Chapter 1. The factors of production are organised by the firm in order to produce output. For example, in the leisure sector, your local gym uses capital in the form of exercise equipment, and labour in the form of the training staff and receptionist. In transport, a taxi firm uses capital in the form of the cars, and labour – the drivers and phone operators. KEY TERMS Notice that these factors have some differing characteristics that affect the analysis of firms’ behaviour. In the short run, the firm faces limited flexibility. Varying the quantity of labour input that the firm uses may be relatively straightforward – it can increase the use of overtime, or hire more workers, fairly quickly. However, varying the amount of capital the firm has at its disposal may take longer. For example, it takes time to commission a new piece of machinery, or to build a new sports centre or power station. Hence labour is regarded as a flexible factor and capital as a fixed factor. The short run is defined by this characteristic as the period in which the input of at least one factor of production is fixed. short run: the period in which at least one factor of production is in fixed supply production function: a relationship that embodies information about technically efficient ways of combining labour and other factors of production to produce output law of diminishing returns: a law stating that if a firm increases its inputs of one factor of production while holding inputs of other factors fixed, eventually the firm will get diminishing marginal returns from the variable factor 17 Types of cost, revenue and profit, short-run and long-run production 17.2 Production in the short run LEARNING LINK 17 The short-run production function As the firm changes its volume of production, it needs to vary the inputs of its factors of production. So, the total amount of output produced in a given period depends on the labour, capital and other inputs used in the production process. Of course, there are many different ways of combining these inputs, some combinations being more efficient than others. The production function summarises the technically most efficient combinations for any given output level. It specifies how the level of output produced by a firm depends on the quantities of the factors of production that are utilised. The nature of technology in an industry will determine the way in which output varies with the quantity of inputs. However, one thing is certain. If the firm increases the amount of inputs of the variable factor (labour) while holding constant the inputs of the other factors, it will gradually derive less additional output per unit of labour for each further increase. This is known as the law of diminishing returns (or the law of variable proportions), and is one of the few ‘laws’ in economics. It is a short-run concept, as it relies on the assumption that capital and other factor inputs are fixed. It can readily be seen why this should be the case. Suppose a firm has ten computer operators working in a travel agency, using ten computers. The 11th worker may add some extra output, as the workers may be able to ‘hot-desk’ and take their coffee breaks at different times. The 12th worker may also add some extra output, perhaps 235 308275_C17_CAM_IASAL ECO_234_255.indd 235 17/02/21 6:16 PM by keeping the printers stocked with paper. However, if the firm keeps adding staff without increasing the number of computers, each extra worker will be adding less additional output to the office. Indeed, the 20th worker may add nothing at all, being unable to get access to a computer. 17 Why is the law of diminishing returns regarded as a short-run concept? Figure 17.1 illustrates the short-run relationship between labour input and total physical product (TPPL), with capital held constant. The shape of the TPPL curve reflects the law of diminishing returns: as labour input increases, the amount of additional output produced gets smaller. An increase in the amount of capital available will raise the amount of output produced for any given labour input, so the TPPL will shift upwards, as shown in Figure 17.2. TPPL Output The production function carries information about the physical relationship between the inputs of the factors of production and the physical quantity of output. Output A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY Test yourself 17.1 TPPL1 TPPL0 0 Labour input ▲ Figure 17.1 A short-run production function 0 Labour input ▲ Figure 17.2 The effect of an increase in capital input QUANTITATIVE SKILLS 17.1 Total, average and marginal There is a very important relationship between the total, average and marginal values of a variable. This can be illustrated by looking at how production of a good varies in the short run. In other words, how does production change as a firm increases labour input with other factor inputs remaining constant? Table 17.1 provides a simple arithmetic example. Reading down column (2), you can see how output (total physical product) increases as the firm takes on more workers. So, the first worker produces 10 units of output; with two workers, 26 units are produced – and so on down the column. Column (3) shows the average output per worker. This is calculated as the value in column (2) divided by the number of workers, shown in column (1). The marginal product is shown in column (4). This shows the change in output as more workers are added. So, the marginal change in output as the firm moves from one worker to two is calculated as the output produced by two workers minus the output produced by one worker, divided by the number of workers added (in this case this is 1, as the table shows increments of 1; this will not always be the case). The figure for the marginal product is shown between the entries in the other columns because it is the change between successive entries. ▼ Table 17.1 Total, average and marginal product (short run) (1) Number of workers (2) Total product 0 0 (3) Average product (4) Marginal product 10 1 10 10 16 2 26 13 16 3 42 14 12 4 54 13.5 4 5 58 11.6 −4 6 54 9 236 308275_C17_CAM_IASAL ECO_234_255.indd 236 17/02/21 6:17 PM at a point where the marginal product is positive, then total output increases. If the marginal product is higher than the average product, then the average product must also rise. If the marginal product is lower than the average, the average will fall. You can see this by comparing columns (3) and (4) in the table. 17 20 15 Average physical product 10 5 Marginal physical product 0 –5 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Number of workers ▲ Figure 17.3 Average and marginal product SUMMARY: PRODUCTION IN THE SHORT RUN » A firm may face inflexibility in the short run, with some factors being fixed in quantity and only some being variable. » The short run is defined in this context as the period over which a firm is free to vary some factors, but not others. » The production function shows how output can be efficiently produced through the input of factors of production. » The law of diminishing returns states that, if a firm increases the input of a variable factor while holding input of the fixed factors constant, eventually the firm will get diminishing marginal returns from the variable factor. » It is important to distinguish between total, average and marginal product. 17 Types of cost, revenue and profit, short-run and long-run production Average and marginal product Figure 17.3 plots the values for average and marginal (physical) product. Notice that the marginal product curve passes through the maximum point of the average product curve. This is a mathematical property of the relationship between average and marginal values. If a firm increases its production 17.3 The short-run cost function Given the short-run production function and the prices of factor inputs, it is possible to identify the way in which costs will vary with output in the short run. This is important in analysing the way in which firms will take decisions in the short run. KEY TERMS total cost: the sum of all costs that are incurred in producing a given level of output (including opportunity cost) average total cost: total cost divided by the quantity produced; sometimes known as unit cost marginal cost: the cost of producing an additional unit of output As with the earlier discussion of total, average and marginal product, economists distinguish between total, marginal and average costs. Total cost is the sum of all costs that are incurred in order to produce a given level of output. Total cost will always increase as the firm increases its level of production, as this will require more inputs of factors of production, materials and so on. Average total cost is simply the cost per unit of output – it is total cost divided by the level of output produced. Equally important as these measures is the concept of marginal cost. Economists rely heavily on the idea that firms, consumers and other economic actors can make good decisions by thinking in terms of the margin. As was pointed out in Chapter 1, this is known as the marginal principle. For example, a firm may examine whether a small change in its behaviour makes matters better or worse. In this context, marginal cost is important. It is defined as the change in total cost associated with a small change in output. In other words, it is the additional cost incurred by the firm if it increases output by one unit. 237 308275_C17_CAM_IASAL ECO_234_255.indd 237 17/02/21 6:17 PM fixed costs: costs that do not vary with the level of output in the short run variable costs: costs that do vary with the level of output STUDY TIP Notice that by definition fixed costs do not vary with output, so all marginal costs are variable costs. total costs = total fixed costs (TFC) + total variable costs (TVC) Total costs will increase as the firm increases the volume of production because more of the variable input is needed to increase output. The way in which the costs will vary depends on the nature of the production function, and on whether the prices of labour or other factor inputs alter as output increases. A common assumption made by economists is that in the short run, at very low levels of output, total costs will rise more slowly than output, but that as diminishing returns set in, total costs will accelerate, as shown in Figure 17.4. Costs sunk costs: costs incurred by a firm that cannot be recovered if the firm ceases trading Because the firm cannot vary some of its inputs in the short run, some costs may be regarded as fixed, and some as variable. In this short run, some fixed costs are sunk costs: that is, they are costs that the firm cannot avoid paying even if it chooses to produce no output at all. Short-run total costs (STC) are the sum of fixed and variable costs: STC TVC Test yourself 17.2 For an ice cream factory, would business rates be a fixed or a variable cost? How about overtime pay? Or interest on a loan taken out on variable terms? TFC 0 Output ▲ Figure 17.4 Total costs in the short run Short-run average and marginal curves are plotted in Figure 17.5, which shows how they relate to each other. First, notice that short-run average total costs (SATC) are shown as a U-shaped curve. This is the form often assumed in economic analysis. SATC is the sum of average fixed and variable costs (SAFC and SAVC, respectively). Average fixed costs slope downwards throughout – this is because fixed costs do not vary with the level of output, so as output increases, SAFC must always get smaller, as the fixed costs are spread over more and more units of output. However, SAVC is also a U-shape, and it is this that gives the U-shape to SATC. Costs ($) A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 17 KEY TERMS SMC SATC SAVC Test yourself 17.3 A firm produces 50 units of a good. What is the firm’s average (total) cost if it faces fixed costs of $4,000 and total variable costs of $2,500? SAFC 0 Output per period ▲ Figure 17.5 The firm’s short-run average and marginal cost curves 238 308275_C17_CAM_IASAL ECO_234_255.indd 238 17/02/21 6:17 PM QUANTITATIVE SKILLS 17.2 The relationship between output and costs ▼ Table 17.2 The short-run relationship between output and costs ($) (1) Output (000 units per week) (2) Fixed costs (STFC) (3) Total variable costs (STVC) (4) Total costs (2) + (3) (STC) (5) Average total cost (4)/(1) (SATC) 1 225 85 310 310 2 225 150 375 187.5 3 225 210 435 145 4 225 300 525 131.25 5 225 475 700 140 6 225 870 1,095 Average total cost (SATC, column (5)) is calculated as total cost divided by output. To calculate marginal cost, you need to work out the additional cost of producing an extra unit of output at each output level. This is calculated as the change in costs divided by the change in output (Δ column (4) divided by Δ column (1), where Δ means ‘change in’). Finally, average variable costs (SAVC, column (3)/ column (1)) and average fixed costs (SAFC, column (2)/column (1)) can be calculated. 182.5 (6) Marginal cost ∆(4)/∆(1) (SMC) 65 60 90 175 395 (7) Average variable cost (3)/(1) (SAVC) (8) Average fixed cost (2)/(1) (SAFC) 85 225 75 112.5 70 75 75 56.25 95 45 145 37.5 Notice that SATC initially falls as output increases, but after 4,000 units of output it begins to increase. SATC is composed of average variable and average fixed costs (SAVC and SAFC). SAFC falls continuously as output increases, because the fixed costs are being spread out across more units of output. This helps to explain why SATC initially falls. However, as diminishing marginal returns set in, average variable costs begin to increase, and this helps to explain the way that SATC varies with output. 17 17 Types of cost, revenue and profit, short-run and long-run production Table 17.2 provides an arithmetic example to illustrate the relationship between these different aspects of costs. The firm represented here faces fixed costs of $225 per week. The table shows the costs of production for up to 6,000 units of the firm’s product per week. Column (3) shows total variable costs of production: you can see that these rise quite steeply as the volume of production increases. Adding fixed and variable costs gives the total costs at each output level. This is shown in column 4, which is the sum of columns (2) and (3). QUANTITATIVE SKILLS 17.3 Graphing short-run costs Quantitative skills 17.2 showed the arithmetic relationship between the components of short-run costs. The short-run average and marginal curves based on these data are plotted in Figure 17.6. First, notice that short-run average total costs (SATC) takes on the typical U-shape. SATC is the sum of average fixed and variable costs (SAFC and SAVC, respectively). Average fixed costs slope downwards throughout – this is because fixed costs do not vary with the level of output, so as output increases, SAFC must always get smaller, as the fixed costs are spread over more and more units of output. However, SAVC also shows a U-shape, and it is this that gives the U-shape to SATC. A very important aspect of Figure 17.6 is that the short-run marginal cost curve (SMC) cuts both SAVC and SATC at their minimum points. This is always the case. If you think about this for a moment, you will realise that it makes good sense. If you are adding on something that is greater than the average, the average must always increase. For a firm, when the marginal cost of producing an additional unit of a good is higher than the average cost of doing so, the 239 308275_C17_CAM_IASAL ECO_234_255.indd 239 17/02/21 6:17 PM A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY An example can show how general this rule is. Suppose that a team newly promoted to the country’s top league brings in a new striker, whose wage far exceeds that of existing players. What happens to the average wage? Of course it must increase, as the marginal wage of the new player is higher than the previous average wage. This is quite simply an arithmetic property of the average and the marginal, and always holds true. Costs (£) 17 average cost must rise. If the marginal cost is the same as the average cost, then average cost will not change. 450 400 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 0 SMC SATC SAVC SAFC 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Output (thousands) ▲ Figure 17.6 Short-run cost curves Test yourself 17.4 STUDY TIP When drawing average and marginal cost curves, what is the key relationship between them? Remember that when you draw the average and marginal cost curves for a firm, the marginal cost curve will always cut average cost at the minimum point of average cost. Another way of viewing marginal cost is as the slope or gradient of the total cost curve. Remember that the short-run cost curves show the relationship between the volume of production and costs under the assumption that the quantity of capital and other inputs are fixed, so that in order to change output the firm has to vary the amount of labour. The position of the cost curves thus depends on the quantity of capital. In other words, there is a short-run average total cost curve for each given level of other inputs. EXERCISE 17.2 In producing a good, a firm incurs fixed costs of 300. If it produces 40 units of the good, it finds that variable costs (STVC) amount to 140. a Calculate STC, SATC, SAVC and SAFC. If the firm increases output to 50 units, it now faces variable costs (STVC) of 200. LEARNING LINK The distinction between the short run, the long run and the very long run was discussed in Chapter 1. b Calculate STC, SATC, SAVC, SAFC and SMC. When production is 60, short-run total costs (STC) are 660. c Calculate short-run variable costs (STVC). SUMMARY: THE SHORT-RUN COST FUNCTION » Short-run costs can be separated into fixed, sunk and variable costs. » There is a clear and fixed relationship between total, average and marginal costs. » For a U-shaped average cost curve, marginal cost always cuts the minimum point of average cost. 17.4 Production and costs in the long run KEY TERM long run: the period over which the firm is able to vary the inputs of all its factors of production The short-run production and cost functions show the relationship between the volume of production and costs under the assumption that the quantities of capital and other inputs are fixed, so that in order to change output the firm can only vary the amount of labour. This assumption does not apply in the long run, so we define the long run as the period over which the firm can vary all its inputs of factors of production. 240 308275_C17_CAM_IASAL ECO_234_255.indd 240 17/02/21 6:17 PM increasing returns to scale: when a percentage increase in inputs results in a larger percentage increase in output constant returns to scale: when a percentage increase in inputs results in the same percentage increase in output STUDY TIP Remember that there are no fixed costs in the long run. Test yourself 17.5 A firm finds that when it increases its use of inputs by 10%, its output increases by 2%. What type of returns to scale is the firm experiencing? STUDY TIP It is important not to confuse the notion of returns to scale with the idea introduced earlier of diminishing marginal returns to a factor. The two concepts arise in different circumstances. The law of diminishing returns to a factor applies in the short run, when a firm increases its inputs of one factor of production while facing fixed amounts of other factors. It is thus solely a short-run phenomenon. However, a firm facing decreasing returns to scale is confronting a long-run phenomenon. Costs in the long run In the long run, a firm is able to vary capital and labour (and other factor inputs). It is thus likely to choose the level of capital that is appropriate for the level of output that it expects to produce. Figure 17.7 shows a selection of short-run average total cost curves corresponding to different expected output levels, and thus different levels of capital. With the set of SATC curves in Figure 17.7, the long-run average cost curve also takes on a U-shape. SATC1 C2 SATC2 SATC3 SATC4 LAC C1 C3 q1 q2 17 17 Types of cost, revenue and profit, short-run and long-run production decreasing returns to scale: when a percentage increase in inputs results in a smaller percentage increase in output What will happen if a firm increases inputs of its factors of production? In some cases, it could be that the resulting percentage increase in output is greater than the percentage increase in inputs. This is known as a position of increasing returns to scale, and suggests that the firm gains efficiency in production as it expands (although this will also depend on the prices of its factor inputs). On the other hand, it could be that as the firm expands its factor inputs, it finds that the resulting increase in output is less in percentage terms than the increase in inputs. This is known as decreasing returns to scale. Constant returns to scale describes a situation where an increase in inputs results in the same percentage increase in output. Costs KEY TERMS q3 Output ▲ Figure 17.7 Short-run cost curves with different levels of capital input STUDY TIP Notice in Figure 17.7 the LAC just touches each of the SATCs, but not at the minimum point of each SATC, except at the minimum point of the LAC at q3. For the firm in Figure 17.7, the choice of capital is important. Suppose the firm wants to produce the quantity of output q1. It would choose to install the amount of capital corresponding to the short-run total cost curve SATC1, and could then produce q1 at an average cost of C1 in the short run. However, if the firm finds that demand is more buoyant than expected, and so wants to increase output to q2, in the short run it has no option but to increase labour input and expand output along SATC1, taking cost per unit to C2. In the longer term, the firm will be able to adjust its capital stock and move on to SATC2, reducing average cost to C3. Thus, as soon as the firm moves away from the output level for which capital stock is designed, it incurs higher average cost in the short run than is possible in the long run. In this way a long-run average cost curve can be derived to illustrate how the firm chooses to vary its capital stock for any given level of output. The dashed line in Figure 17.7 shows what such a curve would look like for the firm. The long-run average 241 308275_C17_CAM_IASAL ECO_234_255.indd 241 17/02/21 6:17 PM cost curve (LAC) just touches each of the short-run average cost curves, and is known as the ‘envelope’ of the SATC curves. 17 Economies of scale A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY KEY TERM economies of scale: occur for a firm when an increase in the scale of production leads to production at lower long-run average cost Test yourself 17.6 Will firms always benefit from economies of scale if they increase production? LEARNING LINK The idea of the division of labour was introduced in Chapter 1. One of the reasons why some firms find it beneficial to be large is the existence of economies of scale. These occur when a firm finds that it is more efficient in cost terms to produce on a larger scale. It is not difficult to imagine industries in which economies of scale are likely to arise. For example, recall the notion of the division of labour. When a firm expands, it reaches a certain scale of production at which it becomes worthwhile to take advantage of division of labour. Workers begin to specialise in certain stages of the production process, and their productivity increases. Because this is only possible for relatively large-scale production, this is an example of economies of scale. It is the size of the firm (in terms of its output level) that enables it to produce more efficiently – that is, at lower average cost. Although the division of labour is one source of economies of scale, it is by no means the only source, and there are several explanations of cost benefits from producing on a large scale. Some of these are industry-specific, and thus some sectors of the economy exhibit more significant economies of scale than others – it is in these activities that the larger firms tend to be found. There are no hairdressing salons that come into the top ten largest firms, but there are plenty of oil companies. Technology One source of economies of scale is in the technology of production. There are many activities in which the technology is such that large-scale production is more efficient. One source of technical economies of scale arises from the physical properties of the universe. There is a physical relationship between the surface area of an object and the volume of material that it can enclose. In other words, a large ship can transport proportionally more than a small ship, and large storage tanks hold more liquid relative to the surface area of the tank than small tanks. Hence there may be benefits in operating on a large scale. Furthermore, some capital equipment is designed for large-scale production, and would only be viable for a firm operating at a high volume of production. Agricultural machinery designed for large plantations cannot be used in small fields; a production line for car production would not be viable for small levels of output. In other words, there may be indivisibilities in the production process. There are many economic activities in which there are high overhead expenditures. Such components of a firm’s costs do not vary directly with the scale of production. For example, having built a factory, the cost of that factory is the same regardless of the amount of output that is produced in it. Expenditure on research and development could be seen as such an overhead, which may be viable only when a firm reaches a certain size. ▲ Constructing the Channel Tunnel Notice that there are some economic activities in which these overhead costs are highly significant. For example, think about the Channel Tunnel that links England with France. The construction (overhead) costs were enormous 242 308275_C17_CAM_IASAL ECO_234_255.indd 242 17/02/21 6:17 PM compared to the costs of running trains through the tunnel. Thus the overhead cost element is substantial – and the economies of scale will also be significant for such an industry. 17 Marketing Firms need to reach their intended customers. This means that they need to devote resources to advertising in order to attract buyers. But this is not all – they also need to find out what characteristics those potential buyers are looking for in the product. This requires firms to devote part of their resources to a marketing budget. Management A further source of economies of scale pertains to the management of firms. One of the key factors of production is managerial input. A certain number of managers are required to oversee the production process. As the firm expands, there is a range of volumes of output over which the management team does not need to grow as rapidly as the overall volume of the firm, as a large firm can be managed more efficiently. Notice that there are likely to be limits to this process. At some point, the organisation begins to get so large and complex that management finds it more difficult to manage. At this point diseconomies of scale are likely to cut in – in other words, average costs may begin to rise with an increase in output at some volume of production. All firms need to conduct certain functions such as accounting or human resource management. As a firm expands, it may be able to employ specialist staff to handle these functions, and may not need to expand those sections of the company proportionately with the growth of the business. Again, this may lead to economies of scale. A firm operating on a small scale may need to buy in the expertise that it needs – for example, to audit its accounts or advise on employment law. However, if its market is limited in size, or confined to a local area, this may be unavoidable, and the firm may not be looking to expand. 17 Types of cost, revenue and profit, short-run and long-run production There may be scale economies involved here, as the average spend on marketing for a large firm is likely to be less per unit sold than for a small firm. In other words, the average cost per unit of marketing may be lower for a larger firm. A large firm such as Cadbury’s incurs high marketing expenditure, but because of its large volume of sales, its per unit spend is lower than some smaller-scale chocolatiers with lower sales volume. Although expenditure may increase as output increases, it will do so less than proportionately. Finance A large firm with a strong reputation may be able to raise finance for further expansion on more favourable terms than a small firm. In other words, a large firm may be able to persuade a bank to advance the firm loans at lower rates of interest than a small firm, where the risks may be seen to be greater. This, of course, reinforces the market position of the largest firms in a sector and makes it more difficult for relative newcomers to become established. Test yourself 17.7 List factors that may result in economies of scale for a firm when it expands its scale of production. Purchasing Once a firm has grown to the point where it is operating on a relatively large scale, it will also be purchasing its inputs in relatively large volumes. In particular, this relates to raw materials, energy and transport services. When buying in bulk in this way, firms may be able to negotiate good deals with their suppliers, and thus again reduce average cost as output increases. It may even be the case that some of the firm’s suppliers will find it beneficial to locate in proximity to the firm’s factory, which would reduce costs even more. 243 308275_C17_CAM_IASAL ECO_234_255.indd 243 17/02/21 6:17 PM Internal and external economies of scale A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 17 KEY TERMS internal economies of scale: economies of scale that arise from the expansion of a firm external economies of scale: economies of scale that arise from the expansion of the industry in which a firm is operating The factors listed so far that may lead to economies of scale arise from the internal expansion of a firm. These are therefore known as internal economies of scale. For example, as a firm grows it may find that the firm can be managed more efficiently. However, if the firm is in an industry that is itself expanding, there may also be external economies of scale. Firms may benefit from the fact that they operate in an industry that is expanding. Concentration One example of an external economy of scale is where a firm is located close to other firms in the same industry or related activities. Such geographical concentration can mean that transport and communication links will be developed, so all firms will benefit. For example, if several mining companies set up in a region, the government could decide that it is important to provide a railway link, which would then reduce transport costs for all of the companies. Technology and skills Some of the most successful firms of recent years have been in activities that require high levels of technology and skills. Web design is one example of an economic activity that has expanded rapidly. As the sector expands, a pool of skilled labour is built up that all the firms can draw on. The very success of the sector encourages people to acquire the skills needed to enter it, colleges may begin to find it viable to provide courses, and so on. Each individual firm benefits in this way from the overall expansion of the sector. The greater availability of skilled workers reduces the amount that individual firms need to spend on training. Web design is by no means the only example of this. Formula 1 development teams, pharmaceutical companies and others similarly enjoy external economies of scale. EXTENSION MATERIAL Economies of scope There are various ways in which firms expand their scale of operations. Some do so within a relatively focused market, but others are multi-product firms that produce a range of different products, sometimes in quite different markets. For example, look at Nestlé. You may immediately think of instant coffee, and indeed Nestlé produces 200 different brands of instant coffee worldwide. However, Nestlé also produces baby milk powder, mineral water, ice cream and pet food, and has diversified into hotels and restaurants. Such conglomerate companies can benefit from economies of scope, whereby there may be benefits of size across a range of different products. These economies may arise because there are activities that can be shared across the product range. For example, a company may not need a finance or accounting section for each different product, or human resource or marketing departments. There is thus scope for economies to be made as the firm expands. EXERCISE 17.3 Which of the following reflects a movement along a long-run average cost curve, and which would cause a shift of a long-run average cost curve? a A firm becomes established in a market, learning the best ways of utilising its factors of production. b A firm observes that average cost falls as it expands its scale of production. c The larger a firm becomes, the more difficult it becomes to manage, causing average cost to rise. d A firm operating in the financial sector installs new, faster computers, enabling its average cost to fall for any given level of service that it provides. 244 308275_C17_CAM_IASAL ECO_234_255.indd 244 17/02/21 6:17 PM Diseconomies of scale KEY TERM diseconomies of scale: occur for a firm when an increase in the scale of production leads to higher long-run average costs The problems caused when the owners of a firm are separated from the managers who take everyday decisions are discussed in Chapter 20. 17 Internal diseconomies of scale Communication One issue that arises as a firm expands is that it becomes more difficult to communicate across the organisation. This is especially the case if the firm has to operate across a range of different locations. This makes the organisation more difficult to manage, if the central managers cannot readily communicate their needs and intentions to the workforce. Coordination Similarly, coordinating activity across a large firm becomes more costly and less efficient. For example, suppose that a manufacturing firm has separate factories producing components of a good, which then need to be assembled somewhere else. Coordinating in order to establish an efficient supply chain becomes more and more difficult as the firm expands. Indeed, it is possible that some multinational corporations have divided their production activities across a number of countries in order to take advantage of local conditions or resources in different locations. This adds to the problems of coordinating the production process. Motivation When a firm becomes large, it comes to rely on managers to oversee everyday production activities and take day-to-day decisions. The firm’s owners may find it difficult to motivate these managers to run the firm in the way that they want. External diseconomies of scale Pollution If several firms choose to locate in a region, the result may be an increase in pollution in the area. Firms may then face higher pollution taxes or higher costs to reduce pollution levels. 17 Types of cost, revenue and profit, short-run and long-run production LEARNING LINK Notice that there are likely to be limits to the extent of economies of scale. At some point, diseconomies of scale are likely to cut in – in other words, average costs may begin to rise with an increase in output at some volume of production. There may be a variety of reasons why such diseconomies may arise. Infrastructure If a number of firms choose to locate in an area, this can cause congestion on transport and communication links, which can raise costs. For example, if there is growing pressure on road and rail links that the government does not tackle, firms either face higher costs or find that they need to invest in upgrading the transport network. Over-extraction of minerals In the case of mining companies that operate in a region, there may be pressure arising from over-extraction of minerals. With many firms operating, it is likely that the costs of mining will rise because the most accessible reserves are exhausted, and the difficulty of reaching the remaining stocks increases. Input prices The growth of firms in an area may put pressure on wages. Firms may find that in order to recruit the workers that they need, they need to pay higher wages or offer non-pecuniary benefits or assistance with housing costs. EXERCISE 17.4 Discuss for what sort of firm each of the causes of economies and diseconomies of scale may be important. 245 308275_C17_CAM_IASAL ECO_234_255.indd 245 17/02/21 6:17 PM The minimum efficient scale KEY TERM A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY minimum efficient scale: the level of output at which longrun average cost stops falling as output increases When considering long-run costs it is important to note that the point at which longrun average cost stops falling is known as the minimum efficient scale. This is the smallest level of output that a firm can produce at the minimum level of long-run average cost. The long-run average cost curve (LAC) is often drawn as a U-shape because of the assumptions that were made about the technology of production. The underlying assumption here is that the firm faces economies of scale at relatively low levels of output, so that LAC slopes downwards. However, at some point diseconomies set in, and LAC then begins to slope upwards. Possible shapes of the LAC curve Costs Costs Will the LAC curve always take this shape? It turns out to be a convenient representation, but in practice the LAC curve can take on a variety of shapes. Figure 17.8 shows some of these. LAC1 is the typical U-shape, which has been discussed. LAC2 shows an example of a situation in which there are economies of scale up to a point, after which longrun average cost levels out and there is a long flat range over which the firm faces constant returns to scale, with costs increasing at the same rate as output. LAC3 is a bit similar, except that the constant returns to scale (flat) segment eventually runs out and diseconomies of scale set in. In LAC4 the economies of scale continue over the whole range of output shown. This could occur in a market where the fixed costs are substantial, dominating the influence of variable costs. LAC1 LAC2 Costs Output Output Costs 17 LAC3 LAC4 LEARNING LINK The extent of economies of scale influences the number of firms that can operate effectively in a market, and thus affects the intensity of competition. This will be discussed in Chapters 18–20. Output Output ▲ Figure 17.8 Possible shapes of the LAC curve It turns out that the size of the minimum efficient scale relative to market demand has an important influence on the way in which a market will develop, and this has implications for the market power held by firms. This will be explored in the following chapters. The significance of economies and diseconomies of scale The extent of economies of scale in an industry and the level of output at which diseconomies set in is significant because it affects the operation of markets. In particular, the existence of economies of scale affects the ability of a firm to compete with other firms – and ultimately the extent of economies (or diseconomies) of scale has a major impact on the structure of the market and the number of firms that will be viable. 246 308275_C17_CAM_IASAL ECO_234_255.indd 246 17/02/21 6:17 PM As we will see later, when diseconomies of scale set in at a low level of output relative to the size of market demand, there is likely to be scope for firms to enter the market quite readily (ceteris paribus). However, if there are substantial economies of scale, it becomes more likely that the market will be dominated by a relatively small number of firms. 17 EXERCISE 17.5 ▼ Table 17.3 Output and long-run costs Output (000 units per week) Total cost ($000) 0 0 1 32 2 48 3 82 4 140 5 228 6 352 a Calculate long-run average cost and long-run marginal cost for each level of output. b Plot long-run average cost (LAC) and long-run marginal cost (LMC) curves on a graph (hint: don’t forget to plot LMC at points that are halfway between the corresponding output levels). c Identify the output level at which long-run average cost is at a minimum. d Identify the output level at which LAC = LMC. e Within what range of output does this firm enjoy economies of scale? f Within what range of output does the firm experience diseconomies of scale? X-inefficiency KEY TERM Costs X-inefficiency: situation arising when a firm is not operating at minimum cost, perhaps because of organisational slack Will a firm always operate as efficiently as it can? Consider a monopolist operating behind secure barriers to entry, so it knows that it does not face effective competition from other firms. One possibility is that the firm becomes complacent, and fails to keep looking to be as efficient as possible. This can result in what is called X-inefficiency. For example, in Figure 17.9 LAC* represents the long-run average cost curve showing the most efficient cost positions for the firm at any output level. With X-inefficiency, a firm could end up producing on a long-run average cost curve such as LAC1 that is above the most efficient that could be achieved. For example, at output q1, the firm would produce at an average cost of AC1, although it could have produced at AC* if it were not for the X-inefficiency. Thus, in the presence of X-inefficiency the firm will be operating above its lowest-possible long-run average cost curve. It is also possible that some X-inefficiency will exist for some firms in the short run, with a similar impact on costs. LAC1 LAC* AC1 LEARNING LINK Productive efficiency is explained in Chapter 15. 17 Types of cost, revenue and profit, short-run and long-run production A firm faces long-run total cost conditions as shown in Table 17.3. AC* q1 Output ▲ Figure 17.9 X-inefficiency 247 308275_C17_CAM_IASAL ECO_234_255.indd 247 17/02/21 6:18 PM A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 17 SUMMARY: PRODUCTION AND COSTS IN THE LONG RUN » The long run is defined as the period over which the firm is able to vary the input of all of its factors of production. » Increasing returns to scale occur when an increase in a firm’s inputs results in a higher percentage increase in output. » The firm may also experience decreasing or constant returns to scale. » Economies of scale occur for a firm when an increase in the scale of production leads to production at lower long-run average cost. » There are several reasons why such economies of » » » » scale may arise, either from reasons internal to the firm or from external effects. However, the firm may experience diseconomies of scale when long-run average cost rises as output expands. The minimum efficient scale is the level of output at which long-run average cost stops falling. The long-run average cost curve can take a variety of shapes. X-inefficiency occurs when a firm is not operating at as low a cost as is possible. 17.5 A firm’s revenue KEY TERMS total revenue: the revenue received by a firm from its sales of a good or service; it is the quantity sold, multiplied by the price average revenue: the average revenue received by the firm per unit of output; it is total revenue divided by the quantity sold marginal revenue: the additional revenue received by the firm if it sells an additional unit of output In Chapter 3, you saw how the total revenue received by a firm varies along the demand curve, according to the price elasticity of demand. In the same way that there is a relationship between total, average and marginal cost, there is also a relationship between total revenue, average revenue and marginal revenue. Chapter 3 introduced the relationship between the demand curve and the revenues received by a firm from selling different levels of output. The relationship between total revenue and the price elasticity of demand was also explained. Ignoring indirect taxes, the price of a good is the average revenue received by the firm, and the total revenue is the price multiplied by the quantity sold. LEARNING LINK You may find it useful to remind yourself of the discussion in Chapter 3, which explored the relationship between average and total revenue and the price elasticity of demand. Moving down along the demand curve, the average revenue per unit (i.e. the price) of a good falls but the quantity demanded increases. What happens to total revenue depends on the balance between the fall in price and the increase in quantity. You saw earlier in this chapter that there is a fixed mathematical relationship between total, average and marginal costs. The same applies to total, average and marginal revenue. Marginal revenue is the additional revenue received by the firm when it sells an additional unit of output. When average revenue (price) falls, marginal revenue also falls, as the revenue received on the last unit is now lower. However, because all customers also experience a fall in the price, marginal revenue must fall more rapidly than average revenue. Indeed mathematically, when the demand curve is a straight line marginal revenue always falls at twice the rate of the fall in average revenue (price). 248 308275_C17_CAM_IASAL ECO_234_255.indd 248 17/02/21 6:18 PM What is the relationship between average revenue and price? How would total revenue be affected if there is an increase in price when demand is elastic? The formulae for these are: total revenue = price × quantity sold 17 average revenue = total revenue/quantity sold marginal revenue = change in revenue/change in quantity sold Price Test yourself 17.8 A Elastic Inelastic MR B C Demand (AR) D Price Quantity Total revenue 0 qr Quantity ▲ Figure 17.10 Elasticity and total revenue 17 Types of cost, revenue and profit, short-run and long-run production Unit elastic Figure 17.10 reminds you of the relationship between total revenue and the price elasticity of demand (PED). The marginal revenue (MR) curve has also been added to the figure, and has a fixed relationship with the average revenue (AR) curve. MR shares the intercept point on the vertical axis (at point A on Figure 17.10), and has exactly twice the slope of AR. STUDY TIP Whenever you have to draw this figure, remember that MR and AR have this relationship, meeting at A, and with the distance BC being the same as the distance CD. MR is zero (meets the horizontal axis) at the maximum point of the total revenue curve. Remember also that the AR curve is the demand curve, as AR is the same as price when all units of a good are sold at the same price. 249 308275_C17_CAM_IASAL ECO_234_255.indd 249 17/02/21 6:18 PM The relationship between sales and revenue A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY Table 17.4 provides an arithmetic example to illustrate the relationship between these different aspects of revenue. ▼ Table 17.4 The relationship between sales and revenue (1) Quantity sold 0 (2) Average revenue (price, $) 12 (3) Total revenue (TR, $) 0 20 10 200 40 8 320 60 6 360 (4) Marginal revenue (MR, $) 10 6 2 4 320 2 0 12 10 6 200 2 –2 0 Columns (1) and (2) describe the demand curve for this product, showing the quantities sold at each price. Column (3) calculates total revenue (TR) as column (1) multiplied by column (2). Marginal revenue is shown in column (4). This is calculated by taking the change Demand (AR) MR 0 −10 120 14 4 −6 100 Figure 17.11 plots these values (but not all of the negative values of MR have been plotted). This shows the relationship between AR and MR. The two lines (curves) share the same intercept with the y-axis, and the MR curve is exactly twice as steep as the AR line (curve). This relationship always holds. 8 −2 80 in revenue between the points on the demand curve, expressed per unit. For example, if price goes from $10 to $8, the quantity sold increases from 20 to 40, and total revenue goes from $200 to $320, so revenue increases by $320 − $200 = $120, which is $6 per unit sold. In the table, the values for marginal revenue are shown halfway between the values in the other columns, as we are looking at the change between the successive points. Price 17 QUANTITATIVE SKILLS 17.4 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 Quantity ▲ Figure 17.11 Average and marginal revenue Notice that the MR line cuts the x-axis at the quantity 60, which is the point at which TR is at a maximum. This is also a mathematical feature of the relationship. SUMMARY: A FIRM’S REVENUE » Total revenue (TR) is the revenue received by a firm from selling the goods and services that it produces: it is the quantity sold multiplied by the price. » Average revenue (AR) is the revenue per unit of output: TR/Q. » Marginal revenue (MR) is the revenue received from selling an additional unit of output. » There is a fixed (mathematical) relationship between AR and MR. » There is a relationship between total revenue and the price elasticity of demand. 17.6 Profit and loss Economists define profit as the difference between the total revenue received by a firm and the total costs that it incurs in production: profits = total revenue − total cost Total revenue here is seen in terms of the quantity of the product that is sold multiplied by the price. Total cost includes the fixed and variable costs that have 250 308275_C17_CAM_IASAL ECO_234_255.indd 250 17/02/21 6:18 PM KEY TERMS normal profit: the return needed for a firm to stay in a market in the long run subnormal profits: profits less than normal profits accounting profits: the profits made by a business based on explicit costs incurred but excluding opportunity cost shutdown price (short run): the price below which a firm will choose to exit the market in the short run because it is not able to cover its fixed costs shutdown price (long run): the price below which a firm will choose to exit the market in the long run because it is not able to cover its long-run average total costs Consider the case of a sole trader – a small local business such as a gym or a taxi firm. It seems reasonable to assume that such a firm will set out to maximise its profits. However, from the entrepreneur’s perspective there is an opportunity cost of being in business, which may be seen in terms of the earnings that the proprietor could make in an alternative occupation. This required rate of return is regarded as a fixed cost, and is included in the total cost of production. The same procedure applies to cost curves for other sorts of firm. In other words, when economists refer to costs, they include the rate of return that a firm needs to make if it is to stay in a particular market in the long run. This is known as normal profit. Profits made by a firm above that level are known as supernormal profits. If a firm makes profits that are lower than normal profit, this is known as subnormal profit. As ‘opportunity cost’ cannot be identified as an explicit item in the accounts, accounting profit differs from the economist’s view of profit because of this component of costs. In other words, accounting profits are defined in terms of the explicit (observable) costs of doing business. Notice that when total revenue is smaller than total cost, the firm makes a loss. If the total revenue equals total cost, the economist sees the firm as making normal profit, as it is covering the opportunity cost of production. The shutdown price In the short run, a firm may choose to remain in a market even if it is not covering its opportunity costs, provided its revenues are covering its variable costs. Since the firm has already incurred fixed costs, if it can cover its variable costs in the short run, it will be better off remaining in business and paying off part of the fixed costs than exiting the market and losing all of its fixed costs. Thus, the level of average variable costs represents the shutdown price (short run), below which the firm will exit from the market in the short run. In situations where firms in a market are making supernormal profits, it is likely that other firms will be attracted to enter the market. The absence or existence of supernormal profits will thus be important in influencing the way in which a market may evolve over time. 17 17 Types of cost, revenue and profit, short-run and long-run production supernormal, abnormal or economic profits: profits above normal profits already been discussed. However, one important item of costs should be highlighted before going any further. In the long run, there are no fixed costs, so the long-run shutdown price is where the price does not cover average total cost for a firm, so that it is not able to make normal profits. Test yourself 17.9 Explain why it would be rational for a firm to leave a market in the short run if price were to be below its variable costs. EXERCISE 17.6 Table 17.5 shows how a firm’s output sold and average cost vary with price. ▼ Table 17.5 A firm’s price, output and average (total) cost a b c d Price ($) Quantity of output sold Average cost ($) 35 200 24 30 300 18 25 400 18 20 500 20 15 600 25 Calculate the amount of profit made at each price. At what level(s) of output does the firm make supernormal profit? At what level(s) of output does the firm make normal profit? At what level(s) of output does the firm make subnormal profit? 251 308275_C17_CAM_IASAL ECO_234_255.indd 251 17/02/21 6:18 PM Profit maximisation Traditional economic analysis has tended to start from the premise that firms set out with the objective of maximising profits. How does a firm choose its output level if it wishes to maximise profits? An application of the marginal principle shows how. Suppose a firm realises that its marginal revenue is higher than its marginal cost of production. What does this mean for profits? If it were to sell an additional unit of its output, it would gain more in revenue than it would incur additional cost, so its profits would increase. Similarly, if it found that its marginal revenue was less than marginal cost, it would be making a loss on the marginal unit of output, and profits would increase if the firm sold less. This leads to the conclusion that profits will be maximised at the level of output at which marginal revenue (MR) is equal to marginal cost (MC). Indeed, this MR = MC rule is a general rule that tells a firm how to maximise profits in any market situation. STUDY TIP The MR = MC rule for profit maximisation is an important one, as it applies in any market situation where a firm sets out to maximise profits, so make sure you understand and remember it. Test yourself 17.10 If a firm were to find that it was producing at an output level at which marginal cost exceeded marginal revenue, would it be likely to increase or decrease output if it wants to maximise profits? EXERCISE 17.7 Figure 17.12 shows a firm operating in a market in which it has no influence over price, so it gains the same marginal revenue from the sale of each unit of output. Marginal revenue and average revenue are thus the same. P1, P2 and P 3 represent three possible prices that could prevail in the market. a For each price level, identify the output level that the firm would choose in order to maximise profits. b For each of these output levels, compare the level of average revenue with that of average cost, and consider what this means for the firm’s profits. Revenue, cost A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 17 SMC SATC AVC P1 MR1 MR2 P2 P3 MR3 A BC D E Output ▲ Figure 17.12 Profit maximisation in the short run SUMMARY: PROFIT AND LOSS » Normal profit is where total revenue equals total cost, where total cost includes the rate of return needed to keep the firm in the market. » Profits above normal profit are known as supernormal profits; profits below normal profits are known as subnormal profits. » Profits are maximised at the level of output at which marginal revenue equals marginal cost. 252 308275_C17_CAM_IASAL ECO_234_255.indd 252 17/02/21 6:18 PM END OF CHAPTER QUESTIONS Multiple choice 1 The table gives information on the number of workers in a firm and the total product they produce. No. of workers 17 Total product (units) 0 1 5 2 10 3 40 4 55 5 65 6 70 7 70 8 68 TPP The manager of the firm changes their objective from producing maximum output to maximising productivity. What is the change in the number of workers? A They should employ 3 workers rather than 7. B They should employ 4 workers rather than 6. C They should employ 5 workers rather than 6. D They should employ 6 workers rather than 8. 2 The diagram shows the production function of a firm, where TPP is total physical product. TPP 17 Types of cost, revenue and profit, short-run and long-run production 0 b 0 Number of workers What is observed at point b and beyond? A increasing productivity B diminishing marginal returns C increasing marginal physical product D increasing returns to scale 253 308275_C17_CAM_IASAL ECO_234_255.indd 253 17/02/21 6:18 PM Data response A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 17 1 a Table 17.6 shows the output and short-run costs of a manufacturing firm. ▼ Table 17.6 Output and short-run costs (US$) Output Fixed cost Variable cost 1 400 200 2 400 320 3 400 400 4 400 480 5 400 600 6 400 880 Define marginal cost and calculate the marginal cost of the 4th unit produced. b Define average total cost and calculate the average total cost when 5 units of output are produced. c Explain the relationship between average fixed cost and the quantity of output. d Table 17.7 shows how the long-run total costs of a firm making dining tables change as the scale of its output increases. The firm is currently operating at its minimum efficient scale (MES). ▼ Table 17.7 Output and total cost of production Output Total cost of production (US$) 200 800 300 900 400 1,000 500 1,050 600 1,320 The total cost of production then decreases by 10% at all levels of output. Calculate the decrease in total costs if the firm continues to operate at its MES after the decrease in total cost. e In 2010, nickel-cadmium batteries powered many of our phones and computers. By 2020, more efficient lithium-ion batteries had taken over and were powering our cars and houses too. Over that 10-year period Panasonic Sanyo grew to be one of the world’s leading lithium-ion battery manufacturers. Explain one internal economy of scale and one external economy of scale that Panasonic Sanyo might enjoy as it increases its output of lithium-ion batteries. Assess the likelihood of these economies of scale occurring. f Table 17.8 shows how the total product of a firm changes when the number of workers employed increases while holding all other factor inputs constant. 254 308275_C17_CAM_IASAL ECO_234_255.indd 254 17/02/21 6:18 PM ▼ Table 17.8 Number of workers and total product Total product (units produced) 0 0 1 8 2 20 3 32 4 42 5 47 6 42 17 Use the data in the table to illustrate the law of diminishing returns. Essay style 2 Table 17.9 shows how a profit-maximising firm’s output sold and average total cost vary with price. ▼ Table 17.9 Price, output sold and average total cost Price (US$) Quantity of output sold Average total cost (US$) 9 1 2.00 8 2 1.50 7 3 1.67 6 4 2.00 5 5 2.40 4 6 2.80 Explain why this firm will make supernormal profit in the short run and assess the reliability of such conclusions. 17 Types of cost, revenue and profit, short-run and long-run production No. of workers CASE STUDY The costs of a hypothetical firm In producing 100 units of output, a firm incurs average fixed costs per unit (AFC) of $15 and total variable costs (TVC) of $1,700. a Calculate total fixed cost (TFC), total cost (TC) and average (total) cost (ATC). The firm sees that the marginal cost per unit (MC) of producing 100 more units of output is $14. b Calculate total cost (TC), total variable cost (TVC), average fixed cost (AFC) and average total cost (ATC). The firm knows that the total cost of producing 300 units is $5,700. c Calculate the marginal cost (MC) of producing the last 100 units. Also calculate average fixed cost (AFC) and average (total) cost (ATC). d Is the firm experiencing economies of scale at this level of output? Explain your answer and comment on the pattern shown by the way that AFC varies with output. e What additional information would you need in order to identify the profitmaximising level of output? 255 308275_C17_CAM_IASAL ECO_234_255.indd 255 17/02/21 6:18 PM A LEVEL PART 7 The price system and the microeconomy A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 18 Different market structures: perfect competition and monopoly What this chapter covers ★ the characteristics of different market structures ★ the model of perfect competition ★ profit maximisation for a firm in the short run under perfect competition ★ industry equilibrium under perfect competition in the short run and the long run ★ efficiency under perfect competition ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ the model of monopoly barriers to entry profit maximisation under monopoly natural monopoly efficiency under monopoly monopoly and perfect competition compared The previous chapter discussed the way in which firms may be expected to operate. Further analysis shows that the behaviour of firms is strongly influenced by the market environment in which they find themselves. It is now time to look at market structure more closely in order to evaluate the way that markets work, and the significance of this for resource allocation. The fact that firms try to maximise profits is not in itself bad for society. However, the structure of a market has a strong influence on how well the market performs. ‘Structure’ here is seen in relation to a number of dimensions, but in particular to the number of firms operating in a market and the way in which they interact. This chapter considers two extreme forms of market structure: perfect competition and monopoly. 18.1 Different market structures Firms cannot take decisions without some awareness of the market in which they are operating. In some markets, a firm finds itself to be such a small player that it cannot influence the price at which it sells. In others, a firm may find itself to be the only firm, which clearly gives it much more discretion in devising a price and output strategy. There may also be many intermediate situations where the firm has some control over price, but needs to be aware of rival firms in the market. KEY TERM market structure: the market environment within which firms operate Economists have devised a range of models that allow such different market structures to be analysed. Before looking carefully at the most important types of market structure, the key characteristics of alternative market structures will be introduced. The main models are summarised in Table 18.1. In many ways, we can regard these as a spectrum of markets with different characteristics. Each form of market structure will be discussed more carefully in this chapter and the next. ▼ Table 18.1 Types of market structure Perfect competition Monopolistic competition Oligopoly Monopoly Number of firms Many Many Few One Freedom of entry Not restricted Not restricted Some barriers High barriers to entry Firm’s influence over price None Some Some Price maker, subject to the demand curve Nature of product Homogeneous Differentiated Varied No close substitutes Examples Fast-food outlets, travel agents Cars, mobile phones PC operating systems, local water supply Cauliflowers, onions 256 308275_C18_CAM_IASAL ECO_256_275.indd 256 23/03/21 10:35 AM LEARNING LINK LEARNING LINK We will return to analyse the monopoly model and barriers to entry later in this chapter, after we have discussed perfect competition. 18 At one extreme of the spectrum of market structures is perfect competition. This is a market in which each individual firm is a price taker. This means that there is no individual firm that is large enough to be able to influence the price, which is set by the market as a whole. This situation would arise where there are many firms operating in a market, producing a product that is much the same whichever firm produces it. You might think of a market for a particular sort of vegetable, for example. One cauliflower is very much like another, and it would not be possible for a particular cauliflower-grower to set a premium price for its product. Such markets are also typified by freedom of entry and exit. In other words, it is relatively easy for new firms to enter the market, or for existing firms to leave it to produce something else. The market price in such a market will be driven down to that at which the typical firm in the market just makes enough profit to stay in business. If firms make more than this, other firms will be attracted in, and thus any supernormal profits will be competed away. If some firms in the market do not make sufficient profit to want to remain in the market, they will exit, allowing price to drift up until again the typical firm just makes enough to stay in business. Monopoly At the other extreme of the spectrum of market structures is monopoly. This is a market where there is only one firm in operation. Such a firm has some influence over price, and can choose a combination of price and output in order to maximise its profits. The monopolist is not entirely free to set any price that it wants, as it must remain aware of the demand curve for its product. Nonetheless, it has the freedom to choose a point along its demand curve. Monopolistic competition Between the two extreme forms of market structure are many intermediate situations in which firms may have some influence over their selling price, but still have to take account of the fact that there are other firms in the market. One such market is known as monopolistic competition. This is a market in which there are many firms operating, each producing similar but not identical products, so that there is some scope for influencing price, perhaps because of brand loyalty. However, firms in such a market are likely to be relatively small. Such firms may find it profitable to make sure that their own product is differentiated from other goods, and may advertise in order to convince potential customers that this is the case. For example, small-scale local restaurants may offer different styles of cooking. 18 Different market structures: perfect competition and monopoly The model of perfect competition is fully analysed later in this chapter. The concepts of normal and supernormal profits are explained in Chapter 17, and are crucial in understanding and evaluating the alternative models of market structure. Perfect competition ▲ A small local restaurant 257 308275_C18_CAM_IASAL ECO_256_275.indd 257 18/03/21 10:30 AM A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 18 Test yourself 18.1 What form of market structure could be regarded as being at the opposite extreme of the market structure spectrum to monopoly? LEARNING LINK The market structures of monopolistic competition and oligopoly are examined in Chapter 19. KEY TERM barrier to entry: a characteristic of a market that prevents new firms from readily joining the market Test yourself 18.2 Give an example of a barrier to entry that might make it difficult for new firms to enter a market. Oligopoly Another intermediate form of market structure is oligopoly, which literally means ‘few sellers’. This is a market in which there are just a few firms that supply the market. Each firm will take decisions in close awareness of how other firms in the market may react to its actions. In some cases, the firms may try to collude – to work together in order to behave as if they were a monopolist – thus making higher profits. In other cases, they may be intense rivals, which will tend to result in supernormal profits being competed away. The question of whether firms in an oligopoly collude or compete has a substantial impact on how the overall market performs in terms of resource allocation, and whether consumers will be disadvantaged as a result of the actions of the firms in the market. Barriers to entry and exit It has been argued that if firms in a market are able to make supernormal profits, this will act as an inducement for new firms to try to gain entry into that market in order to share in those profits. A barrier to entry is a characteristic of a market that prevents new firms from joining the market. The existence of such barriers is thus of great importance in influencing the market structure that will evolve. For example, if a firm holds a patent on a particular good, this means that no other firm is permitted by law to produce the product, and the patent-holding firm thus has a monopoly. The firm may then be able to set a price such as to make supernormal profits without fear of rival firms competing away those profits. On the other hand, if there are no barriers to entry in a market, then if the existing firms set price to make supernormal profits, new firms will join the market, and the increase in market supply will push price down until no supernormal profits are being made. Firms may also face barriers to exit – a situation in which leaving a market may cause the firm to incur high costs. For example, there may be significant sunk costs that cannot be recovered if a firm leaves its market. Such costs may arise because a firm has invested in specific capital goods that cannot be used for alternative reasons, or it may have contracts with suppliers that cannot be broken. SUMMARY: DIFFERENT MARKET STRUCTURES LEARNING LINK Barriers to entry are explained in more detail later in this chapter in the context of monopoly, where the existence of barriers to entry is a key assumption. » The decisions taken by firms must be taken in the context of the market » » » » » environment in which they operate. Under conditions of perfect competition, each firm must accept the market price as given, but can choose how much output to produce in order to maximise profits. In a monopoly market, where there is only one producer, the firm can choose output and price (subject to the demand curve). Monopolistic competition combines some features of perfect competition and some characteristics of monopoly. Firms have some influence over price, and will produce a differentiated product in order to maintain this influence. Oligopoly exists where a market is occupied by just a few firms. In some cases, these few firms may work together to maximise their joint profits; in other cases, they may seek to outmanoeuvre each other. An important characteristic of a market is the existence (or absence) of barriers to entry and exit. 258 308275_C18_CAM_IASAL ECO_256_275.indd 258 17/02/21 6:40 PM EXERCISE 18.1 Market situations: a A fairly large number of fast-food outlets in a city centre, offering various different styles of cooking (Indian, Chinese, fish and chips, burgers, etc.) at broadly similar prices b An island’s only airport c A large number of farmers selling onions at the same price d A small number of large firms that between them supply most of the market for commercial vans 18.2 The model of perfect competition KEY TERM perfect competition: a form of market structure that produces allocative and productive efficiency in long-run equilibrium At one end of the spectrum of market structures is perfect competition. This model has a special place in economic analysis because if all its assumptions were fulfilled, and if all markets operated according to its precepts, the best allocation of resources would be ensured for society as a whole. Although it may be argued that this ideal is not often achieved, perfect competition nonetheless provides a yardstick by which all other forms of market structure can be evaluated. The assumptions of the model The model of perfect competition rests on some important assumptions: 1 Firms aim to maximise profits. 2 There are many participants (both buyers and sellers), none of whom is large enough to influence price. 3 The product is homogeneous. 4 There are no barriers to entry or exit from the market. 5 There is perfect knowledge of market conditions. LEARNING LINK The conditions necessary for a firm to maximise profits are explained in Chapter 17. LEARNING LINK The concept of the minimum efficient scale and its relevance were discussed in Chapter 17. 18 18 Different market structures: perfect competition and monopoly For each of the market situations listed below, select the form of market structure that is most likely to apply. In each case, comment on the way in which the firm’s actions may be influenced by the market structure. Forms of market structure: A perfect competition B monopoly C monopolistic competition D oligopoly Profit maximisation The first assumption is that firms act to maximise their profits. You might think that firms acting in their own self-interest are unlikely to do consumers any favours. However, it turns out that this does not interfere with the operation of the market. Indeed, it is the pursuit of self-interest by firms and consumers that ensures that the market works effectively. Many participants This is an important assumption of the model: that there are so many buyers and so many sellers that no individual trader is able to influence the market price. The market price is thus determined by the operation of the market. On the sellers’ side of the market, this assumption is reinforced where there are limited economies of scale in the industry. If the minimum efficient scale (that is, the level of output at which a firm’s long-run average costs reach their minimum) is small relative to market demand, then no firm is likely to become so large that it will gain influence in the market. A homogeneous product This assumption means that buyers of the good see all products in the market as being identical, and will not favour one firm’s product over another. If there were brand loyalty, such that one firm was more popular than others, then that firm would be able to charge a premium on its price. By ruling out this possibility the previous assumption is reinforced, and no individual seller is able to influence the selling price of the product. 259 308275_C18_CAM_IASAL ECO_256_275.indd 259 17/02/21 6:40 PM No barriers to entry or exit 18 By this assumption, firms are able to join the market if they perceive it to be a profitable step, and they can exit from the market without hindrance. This assumption is important when it comes to considering the long-run equilibrium towards which the market will tend. Why is the assumption of perfect knowledge important in perfect competition? Perfect knowledge It is assumed that all participants in the market have perfect information about trading conditions in the market. In particular, buyers always know the prices that firms are charging, and thus can buy the good at the cheapest possible price. Firms that try to charge a price above the market price will get no takers. At the same time, traders are aware of the product quality. Perfect competition in the short run The firm under perfect competition KEY TERM price taker: a firm that must accept whatever price is set in the market as a whole With the above assumptions, it is possible to analyse how a firm will operate in the market. An important implication of these assumptions is that no individual trader can influence the price of the product. In particular, this means that the firm is a price taker, and has to accept whatever price is set in the market as a whole. As a price taker, the firm faces a perfectly elastic demand curve for its product, as is shown in Figure 18.1. In this figure P1 is the price set in the market, and the firm cannot sell at any other price. If it tries to set a price above P1 it will sell nothing, as buyers are fully aware of the market price and will not buy at a higher price, especially as they know that there is no quality difference between the products produced by different firms in the market. What this also implies is that the firm can sell as much output as it likes at that going price – which means there is no incentive for any firm to set a price below P1. Thus, all firms charge the same price, P1. Price A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY Test yourself 18.3 P1 Demand (AR = MR) 0 Output per period ▲ Figure 18.1 The firm’s demand curve EXTENSION MATERIAL Competition and the internet The assumption of perfect knowledge of market conditions can seem unrealistic in some situations, but it is necessary for the model of perfect competition to work. This is because if some traders have better information than others, they may be able to exploit the situation, and firms may not all face the same price. Chapter 16 explored some of the implications of asymmetric information for a market. The internet has had an enormous impact on the information available to buyers – and to sellers in relation to their competitors. The proliferation of price comparison sites makes it easy to look for good deals when buying goods and services. In this context, the assumption of perfect knowledge begins to appear rather less unrealistic. So, we might argue that the arrival of the internet has made it more likely that firms in some markets will indeed be price takers, less able to charge high prices because consumers are better informed. 260 308275_C18_CAM_IASAL ECO_256_275.indd 260 17/02/21 6:40 PM The firm’s short-run supply decision If the firm can sell as much as it likes at the market price, how does it decide how much to produce? Price, costs SMC SATC SAVC P1 KEY TERM short-run supply curve: for a firm operating under perfect competition, the curve given by its short-run marginal cost curve above the price at which MC = SAVC; for the industry, the horizontal sum of the supply curves of the individual firms Test yourself 18.4 What shape will the demand curve take if a firm is a price taker? Demand (AR = MR) 0 q1 Output per period ▲ Figure 18.2 The firm’s short-run supply decision If the market price were to change, the firm would react by changing output, but always choosing to supply output at the level at which MR = SMC. This suggests that the short-run marginal cost curve represents the firm’s short-run supply curve: in other words, it shows the quantity of output that the firm would supply at any given price. 18 Different market structures: perfect competition and monopoly The previous chapter explained that to maximise profits a firm needs to set output at such a level that marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost. Figure 18.2 illustrates this rule by adding the short-run cost curves to the demand curve. (Remember that SMC cuts SAVC and SATC at their minimum points.) As the demand curve is horizontal, the firm faces constant average and marginal revenue and will choose output at q1, where MR = SMC. 18 However, there is one important proviso to this statement. If the price falls below short-run average variable cost, the firm’s best decision will be to exit from the market, as it will be better off just incurring its fixed costs. This is the shutdown price in the short run. So the firm’s short-run supply curve is the SMC curve above the point where it cuts SAVC (at its minimum point). EXERCISE 18.2 Table 18.2 shows the costs (SATC and SMC) facing a firm under perfect competition at different levels of output. ▼ Table 18.2 A firm’s costs Output Short-run average cost (SATC) Short-run marginal cost (SMC) 100 60 25 200 40 20 300 30 18 400 25 25 500 30 40 600 40 60 Notice that under perfect competition, the firm is a price taker, which means that it faces a horizontal demand curve such that price = AR = MR. Assume that the firm maximises profit. a If the firm faces a price of 40, how much output will the firm supply, and what will be the level of supernormal profit or loss per unit? b If the firm faces a price of 25, how much output will the firm supply, and what will be the level of supernormal profit or loss per unit? c If the firm faces a price of 20, how much output will the firm supply, and what will be the level of supernormal profit or loss per unit? 261 308275_C18_CAM_IASAL ECO_256_275.indd 261 17/02/21 6:40 PM Industry equilibrium in the short run 18 Supply = SMC P1 Demand 0 Q1 Quantity per period ▲ Figure 18.3 A perfectly competitive industry in short-run equilibrium Test yourself 18.5 Which curve represents the individual firm’s short-run supply curve under perfect competition? On the supply side, it has been shown that the individual firm’s supply curve is its marginal cost curve above SAVC. If you add up the supply curves of each firm operating in the market, the result is the industry supply curve, shown in Figure 18.3 as Supply = ∑SMC (where ‘∑’ means ‘sum of’). The price will then adjust to P1 at the intersection of demand and supply. The firms in the industry between them will supply Q1 output, and the market will be in equilibrium. As this seems to be a well-balanced situation, with price adjusting to equate market demand and supply, the only question is why it is described as just a short-run equilibrium. The clue to this is to be found back with the individual firm. Figure 18.4 illustrates the position facing an individual firm in the market. As before, the firm maximises profits by accepting the price P1 as set in the market and producing up to the point where MR = SMC, which is at q1. However, now the firm’s average revenue (which is equal to price) is greater than its average cost (which is given by AC1 at this level of output). The firm is thus making supernormal profits at this price. (Remember that ‘normal profits’ are included in average cost.) The total amount of supernormal profits being made is shown as the shaded area on the graph. Notice that average revenue minus average costs equals profit per unit, so multiplying this by the quantity sold determines total profit. Price, costs A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY Price One crucial question that we have not yet examined is how the market price comes to be determined. To answer this, it is necessary to consider the industry as a whole. In this case there is a conventional downward-sloping demand curve. This is formed according to preferences of consumers in the market and is shown in Figure 18.3. SMC SATC P1 Demand (AR = MR) AC1 0 q1 Output per period ▲ Figure 18.4 The firm in short-run supply equilibrium 262 308275_C18_CAM_IASAL ECO_256_275.indd 262 17/02/21 6:41 PM This is where the assumption about freedom of entry becomes important. If firms in this market are making profits above opportunity cost, the market is generating more profits than other markets in the economy. This will prove attractive to other firms, which will try to enter the market – and the assumption is that there are no barriers to prevent them from doing so. If the price were to fall even further, some firms would choose to exit from the market, and the process would go into reverse. Therefore price can be expected to stabilise such that the typical firm in the industry is just making normal profits. Price, costs Figure 18.5 shows a different situation. This firm also tries to maximise profits by setting MC = MR, but finds that its average cost exceeds the price. It makes losses shown by the shaded area, and in the long run will choose to leave the market. As this and other firms exit from the market, the market supply curve shifts to the left, and the equilibrium price will drift upwards until firms are again making normal profits. SMC SATC AC1 P1 Demand (AR = MR) q1 Output per period 18 Different market structures: perfect competition and monopoly This process of entry will continue for as long as firms are making supernormal profits. However, as more firms join the market, the position of the industry supply curve, which is the sum of the supply curves of an ever-larger number of individual firms, will be affected. As the industry supply curve shifts to the right, the market price will fall. At some point the price will have fallen to such an extent that firms are no longer making supernormal profits, and the market will then stabilise. 18 ▲ Figure 18.5 The firm in short-run equilibrium again Perfect competition in the long run Long-run equilibrium under perfect competition Figure 18.6 shows the situation for a typical firm and for the industry as a whole once long-run equilibrium has been reached and firms no longer have any incentive to enter or exit the market. The market is in equilibrium, with demand equal to supply at the going price. The typical firm sets marginal revenue equal to marginal cost to maximise profits, and just makes normal profits. Test yourself 18.6 What is the long-run shutdown price for a firm under perfect competition? LMC LAC S = SMC AR = MR P* 0 Price, costs Industry Price, costs Typical firm 0 q* Output Demand Q* Output ▲ Figure 18.6 Long-run equilibrium under perfect competition 263 308275_C18_CAM_IASAL ECO_256_275.indd 263 17/02/21 6:41 PM The long-run supply curve Suppose there is an increase in the demand for a product. Perhaps, for some reason, everyone becomes convinced that the product is really health promoting, so demand increases at any given price. This disturbs the market equilibrium, and the question then is whether (and how) equilibrium can be restored. Figure 18.7 reproduces the long-run equilibrium that was shown in Figure 18.6. In the initial position market price is at P*, the typical firm is in long-run equilibrium, producing q*, and the industry is producing Q*. Demand was initially at D0, but with the increased popularity of the product it has shifted to D1. In the short run this pushes the market price up to P1 for the industry because, as market price increases, existing firms have the incentive to supply more output: that is, they move along their short-run supply curves. So in the short run a typical firm starts to produce q1 output. The combined supply of the firms then increases to Q1. Typical firm Industry LMC S = SMC0 Price, costs Price, costs A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 18 S = SMC1 LAC P1 AR = MR P* P1 P* KEY TERM industry longrun supply curve (LRS): under perfect competition, the curve that, for the typical firm in the industry, is horizontal at the minimum point of the long-run average cost curve Test yourself 18.7 What level of profit is made by a firm operating under perfect competition in long-run equilibrium? LRS D0 0 q* 0 q1 Output D1 Q* Q1 Q** Output ▲ Figure 18.7 Adjusting to an increase in demand under perfect competition However, at the higher price the firms start making supernormal profits (shown by the shaded area in Figure 18.7), so in time more firms will be attracted into the market, pushing the short-run industry supply curve to the right. This process will continue until there is no further incentive for new firms to enter the market – which occurs when the price has returned to P*, but with increased industry output at Q**. In other words, the adjustment in the short run is borne by existing firms, but the long-run equilibrium is reached through the entry of new firms. This suggests that the industry long-run supply curve (LRS) is horizontal at price P*, which is the minimum point of the long-run average cost curve for the typical firm in the industry. Strictly speaking, the LRS is perfectly flat only if all firms face equal cost conditions, and if factor prices remain constant as the industry expands. For example, if there is a labour shortage, then industrial expansion may drive up labour costs, causing firms to face higher costs at any output level. In these sorts of circumstances, the LRS is slightly upward sloping. EXTENSION MATERIAL Different cost conditions If firms are not identical, but face different cost conditions, then the LRS may slope upwards. This could happen because some firms face a more favourable environment than others. Perhaps their location confers some advantage because they are closer to the market, or to some raw material. This would then allow some firms to survive for longer if the market price falls. In this case, as price falls, the least efficient firms would exit from the market until the marginal firm just makes normal profits. Notice that this also suggests that the most efficient firms in the market are able to make some supernormal profits even in long-run equilibrium, and it is only the marginal firm that just breaks even. 264 308275_C18_CAM_IASAL ECO_256_275.indd 264 17/02/21 6:41 PM QUANTITATIVE SKILLS 18.1 Points and areas on a diagram Price, costs SMC SATC SAVC A E I L O B C F J G D H K M N P Q Output per period ▲ Figure 18.8 A firm operating under short-run perfect competition A first question is to consider at what price the firm would just make ‘normal’ profits. This point would be where the price (average revenue) is just equal to average total costs, which would be at a price OA in the figure. Now consider the conditions under which a firm would choose to exit the market. In the short run, if the firm is getting a sufficiently high price to cover its variable cost then it will stay in business, as it is at least covering a part of its fixed costs. However, if the price falls below average variable cost, this no longer applies. So the firm would exit if the price were to fall below OI (which is the minimum point of the SAVC curve). In other words, when the price is between OI and OE the firm makes a loss in the short run but continues in the market. Notice that as the price varies, the firm effectively moves along its SMC curve, so we can interpret the SMC curve (above OI) as showing the short-run supply curve of the firm. Notice also that if the price is above OA, the firm makes supernormal profits. EXERCISE 18.3 18 18 Different market structures: perfect competition and monopoly Figure 18.8 shows the short-run cost curves for a firm that is operating in a perfectly competitive market. We can use a diagram like this to analyse some key aspects of the firm’s situation. Think carefully about what follows, and make sure you understand the points and areas mentioned. If the price were indeed at OA, then we could find areas of the figure to represent fixed and variable costs. With the price at OA the firm would produce OQ output (where MC = MR), so, average variable costs would be given by OE, and total variable costs would be the area OEHQ. We can then infer that total fixed costs are the area EADH. Starting from a diagram like Figure 18.6, track the response of a perfectly competitive market to a decrease in market demand for a good – in other words, explain how the market adjusts to a leftward shift of the industry demand curve. Efficiency under perfect competition STUDY TIP These diagrams can be quite confusing until you get used to them, and you would be well advised to practise both interpreting and drawing them, so you can be confident in using them when you need to do so. Having reviewed the characteristics of long-run equilibrium in a perfectly competitive market, you may wonder what is so good about such a market in terms of productive and allocative efficiency. Productive efficiency For an individual market, productive efficiency is reached when a firm operates at the minimum point of its long-run average cost curve. Under perfect competition, this is indeed a feature of the long-run equilibrium position. So, productive efficiency is achieved in the long run – but not in the short run, when a firm is not necessarily operating at minimum average cost. Allocative efficiency For an individual market, allocative efficiency is achieved when price is set equal to marginal cost. In perfect competition, the process by which supernormal profits are competed away through the entry of new firms into the market ensures that price is equal to marginal cost when the market is in long-run equilibrium. So allocative 265 308275_C18_CAM_IASAL ECO_256_275.indd 265 17/02/21 6:41 PM LEARNING LINK A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 18 The idea of allocative efficiency was introduced in Chapter 15, along with the notion that it will be achieved when price is equal to marginal cost. efficiency is achieved. Indeed, price is equal to marginal cost even in the short run, so allocative efficiency is a feature of perfect competition in both the short run and the long run. Evaluation of perfect competition A criticism sometimes levelled at the model of perfect competition is that it is merely a theoretical ideal, based on a sequence of assumptions that rarely holds in the real world. Perhaps you have some sympathy with that view. It could be argued that the model does hold for some agricultural markets. One study in the USA estimated that the price elasticity of demand for an individual farmer producing sweetcorn was –31,353, which is pretty close to being perfectly elastic. However, to argue that the model is useless because it is unrealistic is to miss a very important point. By allowing a glimpse of what the ideal market would look like, at least in terms of resource allocation, the model provides a benchmark against which alternative market structures can be compared. Furthermore, economic analysis can be used to investigate the effects of relaxing the assumptions of the model, which can be another valuable exercise. For example, it is possible to examine how the market is affected if firms can differentiate their products, or if traders in the market are acting with incomplete information. The impact of the internet on how markets work is also significant in this respect, as information is becoming much more accessible than ever before. So, although there may be relatively few markets that display all the characteristics of perfect competition, that does not destroy the usefulness of the model in economic theory. It will continue to be a reference point when examining alternative models of market structure. SUMMARY: THE MODEL OF PERFECT COMPETITION » The model of perfect competition describes an » The industry’s short-run supply curve is the » » » » » extreme form of market structure. It rests on a sequence of assumptions. Its key characteristics include the assumption that no individual trader can influence the market price of the good or service being traded, and that there is freedom of entry and exit. In such circumstances each firm faces a perfectly elastic demand curve for its product, and can sell as much as it likes at the going market price: it is a price taker. A profit-maximising firm chooses to produce the level of output at which marginal revenue (MR) equals marginal cost (MC). The firm’s short-run marginal cost curve, above its short-run average variable cost curve, represents its short-run supply curve. KEY TERM monopoly: a form of market structure in which there is only one seller of a good or service » » » horizontal summation of the supply curves of all firms in the market. Firms may make supernormal profits in the short run, but because there is freedom of entry these profits will be competed away in the long run by new firms joining the market. The long-run industry supply curve is horizontal, with price adjusting to the minimum level of the typical firm’s long-run average cost curve. Allocative efficiency is achieved under perfect competition because price is equal to marginal cost. Under perfect competition in long-run equilibrium, both productive efficiency and allocative efficiency are achieved. 18.3 The model of monopoly At the opposite end of the spectrum of market structures is monopoly, which strictly speaking is a market with a single seller of a good. However, there is a bit more to it than that, and economic analysis of monopoly rests on some important assumptions. In the real world, the Competition and Markets Authority, the official body in the UK with responsibility for monitoring monopoly markets, is empowered to investigate mergers which could restrict competition. Similar bodies operate in other countries 266 308275_C18_CAM_IASAL ECO_256_275.indd 266 17/02/21 6:41 PM around the world: for example, the Competition Commission of Pakistan, the Federal Trade Commission in the USA or the Malaysian Competition Commission. In a situation where a single firm dominates a market, it may be able to act as if it were the only firm – a dominant monopoly. Some discussion of the theory of how monopoly markets operate is necessary in order to understand why such monitoring is required. 18 The assumptions of the model Test yourself 18.8 What is the significance of the assumption that there are no substitutes for the product of a monopolist for the market position of the firm? LEARNING LINK Chapter 19 will explore how the market would be affected if there were potential substitutes for the good produced by a monopolist. These assumptions all have their counterparts in the assumptions of perfect competition, and this is why the model can be described as being at the opposite end of the market structure spectrum. If there is a single seller of a good, and if there are no substitutes for the good, the monopoly firm is thereby insulated from competition. Furthermore, any barriers to entry into the market will ensure that the firm can sustain its market position into the future. The assumption that there are no potential substitutes for the good reinforces the situation. Barriers to entry The existence of barriers to the entry of firms into a market is especially important in a monopoly market because these barriers enable the firm to maintain its position. Without barriers to entry, the market would soon cease to be a monopoly. Some key factors that create barriers to entry are: » » » » » » » economies of scale high fixed costs cost advantages government regulation switching costs strategic action network effects 18 Different market structures: perfect competition and monopoly The assumptions of the monopoly model are as follows: 1 The firm aims to maximise profits. 2 There is a single seller of a good. 3 There are no substitutes for the good, either actual or potential. 4 There are barriers to entry into the market. Some of these barriers arise from government regulation (legal barriers). Others may arise because of the set-up of the market or from cost considerations, and there may also be physical barriers. It is important to note that some of these barriers are natural, reflecting the nature of the product or the market conditions. However, there may be situations in which the existing firm or firms take strategic action in order to maintain their position in the market. Economies of scale Economies of scale can act as a barrier to the entry of new firms into an industry. If a monopoly firm faces significant economies of scale – for example, if the minimum efficient scale is close to the extent of market demand, then it will always be able to produce at lower cost than any potential entrant, so this will make it difficult for new firms to join the market. High fixed costs One situation in which a firm may face substantial economies of scale is where fixed costs are high relative to marginal costs. For example, if a potential entrant knows that it needs to invest heavily in set-up costs before being able to produce, this may deter entry. 267 308275_C18_CAM_IASAL ECO_256_275.indd 267 17/02/21 6:41 PM There may be circumstances where the existing monopoly firm is able to consolidate its position by taking strategic action to affect its fixed costs to deter entry from new firms. For example, heavy investment in research and development can make it difficult for potential entrants to become established in a market, because they need to undertake high expenditure before being able to compete with the existing firm. 18 A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY Cost advantages A monopoly firm may hold some absolute cost advantage over potential entrants. For example, the firm may have control over a key input needed for the production process. This could be control over a raw material or a supply chain. Or it might be that the firm has a locational advantage, being sited close to suppliers of a key input – or, indeed, to the market for the good. Government regulation In some cases, a firm may have some form of legal protection against competition. A common example of this is the patent system, whereby a firm may be protected from competition for a period following the introduction of a new innovative product. The aim of such government action is to encourage research and development and innovation in product development. Switching costs In some cases, the barrier to entry may arise because a firm’s customers face high costs in switching to a new substitute product. Such costs may occur because a consumer has signed a contract for a fixed term, or simply because of brand loyalty. A person who is familiar with using Microsoft products, for example, may be reluctant to invest time in learning to use new systems and software. LEARNING LINK Strategic action is discussed in Chapter 19. Strategic action An incumbent firm may undertake actions that create barriers to the entry of new firms. This action could be in taking out patents that the firm does not intend to use, thus preventing new firms from setting up in a market, or it might be that the firm adopts a pricing policy that deters entry. Network effects Some goods or services have significant network effects. This is where people use a product because they know that there are many others who also use it. Adobe Acrobat’s .pdf format is so widely used that it would be difficult for a new firm to come along with a different format for files. How the monopoly model works KEY TERM price maker: a firm that is able to choose the selling price for its good or service, as it faces a downward-sloping demand curve The first point to note is that a monopoly firm faces the market demand curve directly. Thus, unlike in perfect competition, the demand curve slopes downwards. For the monopolist, the demand curve may be regarded as showing average revenue (notice that for a firm charging the same price for all units sold, price is the same as average revenue). Unlike a firm under perfect competition, therefore, the monopolist has some influence over price, and can make decisions regarding price as well as output. This is not to say that the monopolist has complete freedom to set the price, as the firm is still constrained by market demand. However, the firm is a price maker and can choose a location along the demand curve. As with the firm under perfect competition, a monopolist aiming to maximise profits will choose to produce at the level of output at which marginal revenue (MR) equals marginal cost (MC). This is at Qm in Figure 18.9. Having selected output, the monopolist will then set the price at the highest level at which all output will be sold – in Figure 18.9 this is Pm. 268 308275_C18_CAM_IASAL ECO_256_275.indd 268 17/02/21 6:41 PM This choice allows the monopolist to make supernormal profits, which can be identified as the shaded area in the figure. As before, this area is average revenue minus average cost, which gives supernormal profit per unit, multiplied by the quantity. Price, costs MC AC Pm AR (= D) MR 0 Qm Output ▲ Figure 18.9 Profit maximisation and monopoly It is important to notice that the monopolist cannot be guaranteed always to make such substantial profits as are shown in Figure 18.9. The size of the profits depends on the relative position of the market demand curve and the cost curves. If the cost curves in the diagram were higher, the monopoly profits would be much smaller, as the distance between average revenue and average costs would be less. It is even possible that the cost curves will be so high as to force the firm to incur losses, in which case it would be expected to shut down. Test yourself 18.9 Will a profit-maximising monopoly firm always make supernormal profits? Briefly explain your answer. 18 Different market structures: perfect competition and monopoly It is at this point that barriers to entry become important. Other firms may see that the monopoly firm is making healthy supernormal profits, but the existence of barriers to entry will prevent those profits from being competed away, as would happen in a perfectly competitive market. With secure barriers to entry, the monopolist can continue to make supernormal profits in the long run. 18 EXERCISE 18.4 Table 18.3 shows the demand situation faced by a monopolist. ▼ Table 18.3 Demand situation for a monopolist Demand (000s per week) Price ($) 0 80 1 70 2 60 3 50 4 40 5 30 6 20 7 10 a Calculate total revenue and marginal revenue for each level of demand. b Plot the demand curve (AR) and marginal revenue on a graph. c Plot total revenue on a separate graph. d Identify the level of demand at which total revenue is at a maximum. e At what level of demand is marginal revenue equal to zero? f At what level of demand is the price elasticity of demand unitary? g If the monopolist maximises profits, will the chosen level of output be higher or lower than the revenue-maximising level? h What does this imply for the price elasticity of demand when the monopolist maximises profits? 269 308275_C18_CAM_IASAL ECO_256_275.indd 269 17/02/21 6:41 PM If a monopoly experiences (or can induce) an increase in the demand for its product, it will benefit. In Figure 18.10, suppose that initially the monopoly faces the demand curve D0. It maximises profits by setting MR = MC, producing Q0 output and charging a price P0. If the demand curve shifts to the right, notice that the MR curve will also shift, as this has a fixed relationship with the demand curve. After the increase in demand, the monopoly chooses to produce Q1 output, where MR = MC, and now sets a higher price at P1, making higher profits. Price, costs A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 18 A monopoly and an increase in demand MC AC P1 P0 MR0 Q0 Q1 MR1 D0 D1 Output ▲ Figure 18.10 A monopoly and an increase in demand How do monopolies arise? Monopolies may arise in a market for a number of reasons. In a few instances, a monopoly is created by the authorities. For example, for 150 years the UK Post Office held a licence giving it a monopoly on delivering letters. From the beginning of 2006, the service was fully liberalised. The Post Office monopoly covered a wide range of services, but its coverage was gradually eroded over the years, and it was finally privatised in 2013. Nonetheless, it remains an example of one way in which a monopoly can be created. Another example of a monopoly is Tenaga Nasional Berhad in Malaysia, which holds a monopoly as an electric utility in Peninsular Malaysia. ▲ Tenaga Nasional Berhad, Malaysia The patent system offers a rather different form of protection for a firm. The patent system was designed to provide an incentive for firms to innovate through the development of new techniques and products. By prohibiting other firms from copying the product for a period of time, a firm is given a temporary monopoly. There are markets in which firms have risen to become monopolies by their actions in the market. Such a market structure is sometimes known as a competitive monopoly. Firms may get into a monopoly position through effective marketing, or by 270 308275_C18_CAM_IASAL ECO_256_275.indd 270 18/03/21 10:31 AM establishing a new product as a widely accepted standard. For example, by the mid2010s, Google had come to control some 90% of the search engine market in Europe. Monopolies may also be created through mergers and acquisitions, if one firm is able to buy out its competitors or combine with them to exploit economies of scale. 18 A natural monopoly natural monopoly: a monopoly that arises in an industry in which there are such substantial economies of scale that only one firm is viable Figure 18.11 illustrates this point. The firm in this market enjoys economies of scale right up to the limit of market demand. The largest firm operating in the market can always produce at a lower cost than any potential entrant, so will always be able to price such firms out of the market. Here the economies of scale act as an effective barrier to the entry of new firms and the market is a natural monopoly. A profit-maximising monopoly would set MR = MC, produce at quantity Qm and charge a price Pm. Price, costs KEY TERM Pm AR (= D) 18 Different market structures: perfect competition and monopoly In some cases the technology of the industry may create a monopoly situation. In a market characterised by substantial economies of scale, there may not be room for more than one firm in the market. This could happen where there are substantial fixed costs of production but low marginal costs. For example, in establishing an underground railway in a city, a firm faces very high fixed costs in building the network of track and stations and buying the rolling stock. However, once it is in operation, the marginal cost of carrying an additional passenger is very low. LAC LMC MR 0 Qm Output Test yourself 18.10 Explain why the rail network (that is, the track) might be regarded as a natural monopoly. ▲ Figure 18.11 A natural monopoly Such a market poses particular problems regarding allocative efficiency. Notice in the figure that marginal cost is below average cost over the entire range of output. If the firm were to charge a price equal to marginal cost, it would inevitably make a loss, so such a pricing rule would not be viable. EXERCISE 18.5 A rail company is awarded a franchise to operate trains on a route joining two neighbouring cities. Discuss the extent to which the company would be able to operate as a profit-maximising monopoly. Monopoly and efficiency The characteristics of the monopoly market can be evaluated in relation to productive and allocative efficiency (see Figure 18.9). 271 308275_C18_CAM_IASAL ECO_256_275.indd 271 17/02/21 6:42 PM Productive efficiency A firm is said to be productively efficient if it produces at the minimum point of long-run average cost. It is clear from the figure that this is extremely unlikely for a monopoly. A monopoly firm will produce at the minimum point of long-run average cost only if it so happens that the marginal revenue curve passes through this exact point – and this would happen only by coincidence. More likely is that it will produce in a position of excess capacity at an output below the minimum point of long-run average cost. The intensity of competition in this market structure makes it unlikely that firms will be able to operate with X-inefficiency. Allocative efficiency For an individual firm, allocative efficiency is achieved when price is set equal to marginal cost. It is clear from Figure 18.9 that this will not be the case for a profitmaximising monopoly firm. The firm chooses output where MR equals MC; however, given that MR is below AR (i.e. price), price will always be set above marginal cost. Monopoly and perfect competition How does monopoly compare with perfect competition in terms of efficiency? The two models have different implications for resource allocation. By its behaviour, a monopoly distorts resource allocation, and by comparing a monopoly market with a perfectly competitive market, we can identify the extent of the distortion. To do this, the situation can be simplified by setting aside the possibility of economies of scale. This is perhaps an artificial assumption to make, but it could be relaxed. Suppose that there is an industry with no economies of scale, which can be operated either as a perfectly competitive market with many small firms, or as a monopoly firm running a large number of small plants. Figure 18.12 shows the market demand curve (D = AR) and the long-run supply curve under perfect competition (LRS). If the market is operating under perfect competition, the long-run equilibrium will produce a price of Ppc and the firms in the industry will together supply Qpc output. Consumer surplus (the surplus that consumers gain from consuming this product) is given by the area APpcE. This is a measure of the welfare that society receives from consuming the good, as was explained in Chapter 4. Price, costs A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 18 A B Pm Ppc The deadweight loss caused by monopoly E C MR 0 LRS (= LMCm) Qm D = AR Qpc Output ▲ Figure 18.12 Comparing perfect competition and monopoly Now suppose that the industry is taken over by a profit-maximising monopolist. The firm can close down some of the plants to vary its output over the long run, and the LRS can be regarded as the monopolist’s long-run marginal cost curve. As the monopoly firm faces the market demand curve directly, it will also face the MR curve shown, so will maximise profits at quantity Qm and charge a price Pm. 272 308275_C18_CAM_IASAL ECO_256_275.indd 272 17/02/21 6:42 PM Thus, the effect of this change in market structure is that the profit-maximising monopolist produces less output than a perfectly competitive industry and charges a higher price. LEARNING LINK X-inefficiency is explained in Chapter 17. This deadweight loss is a measure of the welfare loss imposed on society in a monopoly situation. However, there are two key aspects of efficiency, as was shown in Chapter 15. The loss in allocative efficiency shown in Figure 18.12 may be partly offset by improved productive efficiency: for example, because a monopoly is able to take advantage of economies of scale that would be sacrificed if it were to be split into many small firms, none of which would be able to reach the minimum average cost level of output. It is also worth noting that when a monopoly faces no competition from other firms, it is possible that it will become complacent, and allow some X-inefficiency to occur. In other words, a monopolist may not always operate on its lowest average cost curve. SUMMARY: THE MODEL OF MONOPOLY » A monopoly market is one in which there is a single seller of a good. » The model of monopoly used in economic analysis also assumes that there are no substitutes for the goods or services produced by the monopolist, and that there are barriers to the entry of new firms. » The monopoly firm faces the market demand curve, and is able to choose a point along that demand curve in order to maximise profits. » Such a firm may be able to make supernormal profits, and sustain them in the long run because of barriers to entry and the lack of substitutes. » A monopoly may arise because of patent protection or from the nature of economies of scale in the industry (a ‘natural monopoly’). » A profit-maximising monopolist does not achieve allocative efficiency, and is unlikely to achieve productive efficiency in the sense of producing at the minimum point of the long-run average cost curve. » Comparing monopoly with perfect competition, a monopoly will produce less output and charge a higher price, thus imposing a deadweight loss on society. 18 Different market structures: perfect competition and monopoly It is also apparent that consumer surplus is now very different, as in the new situation it is limited to the area APmB. Looking more carefully at Figure 18.12, you can see that the loss of consumer surplus has occurred for two reasons. First, the monopoly firm is now making profits shown by the blue shaded area PmBCPpc. This is a redistribution of welfare from consumers to the firm, but as the monopolist is also a member of society, this does not affect overall welfare. However, there is also a loss, which represents a loss to society resulting from the monopolisation of the industry. This is measured by the area of the red triangle BCE. This is known as the deadweight loss that society incurs as a result of the restriction of competition. Notice that a small number of firms in collusion with each other may have similar effects to a monopoly. 18 END OF CHAPTER QUESTIONS Multiple choice 1 The marginal costs of a perfectly competitive firm and a monopolist both exceed the respective firms’ average revenue. Both firms aim to maximise profits. What should each of the firms do to maximise profits? Perfectly competitive firm Monopoly A Increase output Increase output B Decrease output Increase output C Increase output Decrease output D Decrease output Decrease output 273 308275_C18_CAM_IASAL ECO_256_275.indd 273 17/02/21 6:42 PM A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 18 2 Firms in perfect competition are often claimed to lead to a more efficient outcome, lower prices and higher output than monopolies. On the other hand, arguments in favour of monopolies suggest a single seller can yield more efficiency. What is a necessary condition to ensure the monopolist would operate at a lower price and higher output? A Consumers must place more value per unit on the product sold by the monopolist. B The marginal cost curves of the perfectly competitive firm and the monopolist must be different. C The monopolist must be protected by sufficiently high barriers to entry. D The perfectly competitive firm must operate at excess capacity. Data response 1 Read the following extract and then answer the questions that follow. Inefficiency in the Australian water market In 2020, Australian Water was estimated to have an annual revenue of AUS$22.71 billion. Commercial water firms such as Australian Water occur in markets characterised by extremely high set-up costs and extensive sunk costs. This can often lead to a natural monopoly emerging because only one firm is viable. This in turn can impact on the efficiency of the market. In Australia the efficiency of the centralised water industry has been declining rapidly. On a microeconomic level, the operating costs for water companies in many parts of Australia have soared and the economic efficiency of water supply has plunged by up to 2,300% while consumers appear to be paying for it through higher prices. a Define the terms ‘sunk cost’ and ‘fixed cost’ and explain with the use of an example one fixed cost that Australian Water might incur that is not a sunk cost. b Other than sunk costs identify one barrier to entry in the extract and explain the importance of barriers to entry for Australian Water in maintaining long-run supernormal profit. c i Explain what is meant by X-inefficiency and why Australian Water is unlikely to achieve X-efficiency. ii State the condition under which a firm will achieve allocative efficiency and explain why Australian Water is unlikely to achieve allocative efficiency. d Discuss, with the aid of a diagram, whether a profit-maximising monopolist such as Australian Water will always make supernormal profit. Essay style 2 ‘The market structure of perfect competition will deliver both allocative and productive efficiency in the long run.’ Analyse the validity of this statement and assess the view that the model and its outcomes are meaningless because it does not reflect reality. 274 308275_C18_CAM_IASAL ECO_256_275.indd 274 17/02/21 6:42 PM CASE STUDY Of cabbages and rings Edward de Vere owns a diamond mine – the only such mine in the country. His company cuts the stones and uses them to produce diamond rings. In selling the rings, Edward takes into account the strength of demand, choosing a price that will clear the market. He finds that by restricting the number of rings that he produces, he is able to charge a higher price. By doing so he is able to increase the Follow-up questions a Which of the two producers appears to operate under conditions of perfect competition, and which is a monopoly? b Explain your answer to part (a), referring to the assumptions that underlie the two theories of market structure. c Under what conditions would Ted Greens decide to give up growing cabbages? d Can you think of steps that Ted Greens might take in order to improve his profits on cabbages? e Draw a diagram to explain how Edward de Vere would react to an increase in the demand for diamond rings. f Suppose that a foreign firm starts to import diamond rings into the country in competition with Edward de Vere. How would you expect him to react? Go online at hoddereducation.com/cambridgeextras for another case study for Chapter 18. 18 18 Different market structures: perfect competition and monopoly Ted Greens has a farm on which he grows a variety of crops, including cabbages that grow well on his south field, which seems especially suited to the crop. When Ted takes his cabbage crop to market, hoping to make as much profit as possible, he finds that the price he can charge for cabbages depends on market conditions – after all, one cabbage is very much like any other. He thus has to accept the price that he can get, which is the same as that charged by his many rival producers. If he tries to set a higher price, he sells nothing as all traders in the market have good awareness of market conditions. But as he can sell as much as he likes at the going price, there is no need to drop price below that prevailing in the market. Price tends to fluctuate from one harvest season to the next, and in some years when cabbages are plentiful, Ted finds that he barely covers his costs. profits that he makes. As he controls the only source of diamonds, Edward does not have to worry about other producers entering the market, and there are no substitutes for diamonds that people are prepared to accept. 275 308275_C18_CAM_IASAL ECO_256_275.indd 275 18/03/21 3:00 PM A LEVEL PART 7 The price system and the microeconomy A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 19 Different market structures: monopolistic competition and oligopoly What this chapter covers ★ the model of monopolistic competition ★ product differentiation ★ the importance of freedom of entry in monopolistic competition ★ short- and long-run equilibrium under monopolistic competition ★ efficiency in monopolistic competition ★ characteristics of oligopoly ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ non-price competition game theory and the Prisoners’ Dilemma a two-player pay-off matrix contestable markets efficiency in a contestable market market concentration calculating a concentration ratio market dominance The previous chapter introduced the models of perfect competition and monopoly, and described them as being at the extreme ends of a spectrum of forms of market structure. In between those two extremes are other forms of market structure, which have some but not all of the characteristics of either perfect competition or monopoly. It is in this sense that there is a spectrum of structures. Attention in this chapter is focused on some of these intermediate forms of market structure, including a discussion of the sorts of pricing strategy that firms may adopt, and ways in which firms may try to prevent new firms from joining a market, in terms of both pricing and non-price strategies. The theory of contestable markets is outlined, and the chapter concludes by explaining how to measure concentration in a market. 19.1 Monopolistic competition KEY TERMS monopolistic competition: a market that shares some characteristics of monopoly and some of perfect competition product differentiation: a strategy adopted by firms that marks their product as being different from their competitors’ If you consider the characteristics of the markets that you frequent on a regular basis, you will find that few of them display all of the characteristics associated with perfect competition. However, there may be some that show a few of these features. In particular, you will find some markets in which there appears to be intense competition but in which the products for sale are not identical. For example, think about restaurants. In many cities, you will find a wide range of restaurants, cafés and coffee bars that compete with each other for business, but do so by offering slightly different products: this is called product differentiation. The theory of monopolistic competition was devised by Edward Chamberlin, writing in the USA in the 1930s, and his name is often attached to the model, although Joan Robinson published her book on imperfect competition in the UK at the same time. The motivation for the analysis was to explain how markets worked when they were operating neither as monopolies nor under perfect competition. The model describes a market in which there are many firms producing similar, but not identical products: for example, package holidays, hairdressers and fast-food outlets. In the case of fast-food outlets, the high streets of many cities are characterised by large numbers of different types of takeaway – burgers, curries, noodles, fried chicken and so on. 276 308275_C19_CAM_IASAL ECO_276_291.indd 276 17/02/21 5:50 PM Characteristics of monopolistic competition The model of monopolistic competition shares some characteristics with perfect competition and some with monopoly. Its features are: » » » » » a downward-sloping demand curve product differentiation no (or low) barriers to entry many firms no dominant firm As with a monopoly, a firm in monopolistic competition has some control over price. In other words, it can choose the price at which it sells, rather than having to accept the market price as it would in perfect competition. A fall in price would increase the quantity demanded, so the demand curve slopes downwards. In this respect it resembles monopoly rather than perfect competition. When a firm engages in advertising or product development in order to differentiate its product, it is known as non-price competition. This is also important in the context of oligopoly, and is discussed in more detail later in this chapter. Test yourself 19.1 Why is product differentiation an important characteristic of the model of monopolistic competition? Product differentiation Monopolistic competition differs from monopoly because the firm faces competition from other firms. This means that the firm needs to find ways to distinguish itself from the other firms. It does this by making its product slightly different. This allows the firms to build up brand loyalty among their regular customers, which gives them some influence over price. It is likely that firms will engage in advertising or in product design in order to maintain such brand loyalty, and heavy advertising is a common characteristic of a market operating under monopolistic competition. This strategy is known as product differentiation. Notice that by spending on advertising or on improving product quality and design, the firm is adding to its costs, so that the average cost curve will shift upwards. However, competition between firms may discourage X-inefficiency. Because other firms are producing similar goods, there are substitutes for each firm’s product, which means that demand is relatively price elastic (although this does not mean that it is never inelastic). However, it is certainly not perfectly price elastic, as was the case with perfect competition. These features – that the product is not homogeneous and demand is not perfectly price elastic – represent significant differences from the model of perfect competition. 19 Different market structures: monopolistic competition and oligopoly A downward-sloping demand curve LEARNING LINK 19 Freedom of entry In the model, there are no (or low) barriers to entry into the market. Firms are able to join the market if they observe that existing firms are making supernormal profits. New entrants will be looking for some way to differentiate their product slightly from the others – perhaps the next fast-food restaurant will be Nepalese or Peruvian. This characteristic distinguishes the market from the monopoly model, as does the existence of fairly close substitutes. Many firms STUDY TIP One way of gauging whether a firm or some firms have some dominance in the market is to look at whether it is concentrated. This is explained later in the chapter. A further assumption of the model is that there are many firms operating in the market. For this reason, a price change by one of the firms will have negligible effects on the demand for its rivals’ products. This characteristic means that the market is also different from an oligopoly market, where there are a few firms that interact strategically with each other. STUDY TIP Remember these characteristics, and why they are important in making the model of monopolistic competition distinct from both perfect competition and monopoly. 277 308275_C19_CAM_IASAL ECO_276_291.indd 277 17/02/21 5:50 PM 19 LEARNING LINK A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY Oligopoly models are discussed later in this chapter. No dominant firm Although there are many firms in the market, no individual firm is dominant. If one firm had significantly more power than others, so was able to dictate how the market operated, perhaps by setting price, then the market would work differently. Overview Taking these characteristics together, it can be seen that a market of monopolistic competition has some of the characteristics of perfect competition and some features of monopoly; hence its name. Short-run equilibrium in monopolistic competition Price Figure 19.1 represents short-run equilibrium under monopolistic competition. Ds is the demand curve and MRs is the corresponding marginal revenue curve. AC and MC are the average and marginal cost curves for a representative firm in the industry. If the firm is aiming to maximise profits, it will choose the level of output such that MRs = MC. This occurs at output qs, and the firm will then choose the price that clears the market at ps. MC AC ps MRs 0 Ds(= AR) qs Output ▲ Figure 19.1 Short-run equilibrium under monopolistic competition This closely resembles the standard monopoly diagram that was introduced in Chapter 18. As with monopoly, a firm under monopolistic competition faces a downward-sloping demand curve, as already noted. The difference is that now it is assumed that there is some freedom of entry into the market under monopolistic competition, so that Figure 19.1 represents equilibrium only in the short run. This is because the firm shown in the figure is making supernormal profits, shown by the shaded area (which is AR − AC multiplied by output). Test yourself 19.2 If a firm operating under monopolistic competition is making supernormal profits, what would you expect to happen to its demand curve? The importance of no (or low) barriers to entry This is where the assumption of freedom of entry into (and exit from) the market becomes important. In Figure 19.1 the supernormal profits being made by the representative firm will attract new firms into the market. The new firms will produce differentiated products, and this will affect the demand curve for the representative firm’s product. In particular, the new firms will attract some customers away from this firm, so that its demand curve will tend to shift to the left. Its shape may also change as there are now more substitutes for the original product. Long-run equilibrium in monopolistic competition This process of entry of firms will continue as long as firms in the market continue to make supernormal profits that attract new firms into the activity (or make losses, causing some firms to leave). It may be accelerated if firms are persuaded to spend money on advertising in an attempt to defend their market shares. The advertising may help to keep the demand curve downward sloping, but it will also affect the position of the average cost curve, by pushing up average cost at all levels of output. 278 308275_C19_CAM_IASAL ECO_276_291.indd 278 17/02/21 5:50 PM MC AC pl MRl 0 Dl ql Output ▲ Figure 19.2 Long-run equilibrium under monopolistic competition Efficiency under monopolistic competition One way of evaluating the market outcome under this model is to examine the consequences for productive and allocative efficiency. It is clear from Figure 19.2 that neither of these conditions will be met. For productive efficiency to be achieved, the firm would need to be operating at minimum average cost, but Figure 19.2 shows that the firm will not be at this point. Allocative efficiency requires price to be set equal to marginal cost, but a firm maximising profit under monopolistic competition will set a price higher than this, as is also shown in Figure 19.2. Evaluation of monopolistic competition Test yourself 19.3 Why are firms under monopolistic competition more keen to sell a higher output than firms under perfect competition? LEARNING LINK X-inefficiency is explained in Chapter 17. 19 19 Different market structures: monopolistic competition and oligopoly The conditions under which a firm will exit from a market depend crucially on whether the price falls below the shutdown price in the short or long run. The notion of the shutdown price is explained in Chapter 17. Figure 19.2 shows the final position for the market. The typical firm is now operating in such a way that it maximises profits (by setting output such that MR = MC); at the same time, the average cost curve (AC) at this level of output is at a tangent to the demand curve. This means that AC = AR, and the firm is just making normal profit (i.e. is just covering opportunity cost). There is thus no further incentive for more firms to join the market. In Figure 19.2 this occurs when output is at ql and price is set at pl. Price LEARNING LINK If the typical firm in the market is not fully exploiting the possible economies of scale that exist, it could be argued that product differentiation is a disadvantage that damages society’s total welfare, in the sense that product differentiation allows firms to keep their demand curves downward sloping. In other words, too many different products are being produced. However, this argument could be countered by pointing out that consumers may enjoy having more freedom of choice, which could be seen as an advantage of this type of market structure. The very fact that they are prepared to pay a premium price for their chosen brand indicates that they have some preference for it. Another crucial difference between monopolistic competition and perfect competition is that under monopolistic competition firms would like to sell more of their product at the going price, whereas under perfect competition they can sell as much as they like at the going price. This is because price under monopolistic competition is set above marginal cost. The use of advertising to attract more customers and to maintain consumer perception of product differences may be considered a disadvantage of this market. It could be argued that excessive use of advertising to maintain product differentiation is wasteful, as it leads to higher average cost curves than needed. Given the higher costs, firms may need to charge higher prices. On the other hand, the need to compete in this way may result in less X-inefficiency than under a complacent monopolist. In addition, it might be argued that with plenty of advertising, customers are better informed about the products available. 279 308275_C19_CAM_IASAL ECO_276_291.indd 279 17/02/21 5:50 PM a Identify the profit-maximising level of output. b At what price would the firm sell its product? c What supernormal profits (if any) would be made by the firm? d Is this a short-run or a long-run equilibrium? Explain your answer. e Describe the subsequent adjustment that might take place in the market (if any). f At what level of output would productive efficiency be achieved? (Assume that AC represents long-run average cost for this part of the question.) Figure 19.3 shows a firm under monopolistic competition. Price 19 EXERCISE 19.1 MC A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY AC B A C F J E H G K M L Demand MR 0 N R S Output ▲ Figure 19.3 A firm under monopolistic competition SUMMARY: MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION » The theory of monopolistic competition has its » » » » origins in the 1930s, when economists such as Edward Chamberlin and Joan Robinson were writing about markets that did not conform to the models of perfect competition and monopoly. The model describes a market where there are many firms producing similar, but not identical, products. By differentiating their product from those of other firms, it is possible for firms to maintain some influence over price. To do this, firms engage in advertising to build brand loyalty. There are no barriers to entry into (or exit from) the market, and concentration is low. » Firms may be able to make supernormal profits in » » » » the short run. In response, new entrants join the market, shifting the demand curves of existing firms and affecting their shape. The process continues until supernormal profits have been competed away, and the typical firm has its average cost curve at a tangent to its demand curve. Neither productive nor allocative efficiency is achieved in long-run equilibrium. Consumers may benefit from the increased range of choice on offer in the market. 19.2 Oligopoly KEY TERM oligopoly: a market with a few sellers, in which each firm must take account of the behaviour and likely behaviour of rival firms in the industry A number of markets seem to be dominated by relatively few firms – think of commercial banking, cinemas or the newspaper industry. A market with just a few sellers is known as an oligopoly market. An important characteristic of such markets is that when making economic decisions each firm must take account of its rivals’ behaviour and reactions. The firms are therefore interdependent. An important characteristic of oligopoly is that each firm has to act strategically, both in reacting to rival firms’ decisions and in trying to anticipate their future actions and reactions. This interdependence of firms is a strong influence on their behaviour in the market, as we shall see. Unlike monopolistic competition, an oligopoly market is likely to be protected by barriers to entry, although the strength of those barriers may vary from industry to industry. 280 308275_C19_CAM_IASAL ECO_276_291.indd 280 17/02/21 5:50 PM The key characteristics of an oligopoly are therefore: » a few firms dominate the market » there is strategic interdependence between the firms » there are barriers to entry 19 There are many different ways in which a firm may take such strategic decisions, and this means that there are many ways in which an oligopoly market can be modelled, depending on how the firms behave in relation to each other. This chapter reviews just a few examples. KEY TERMS non-price competition: a strategy whereby firms compete by advertising to encourage brand loyalty or by quality or design, rather than on price game theory: a method of modelling the strategic interaction of firms within an oligopoly market Prisoners’ Dilemma: an example of game theory with a range of applications in oligopoly theory Test yourself 19.4 Give two examples of ways in which firms may indulge in nonprice competition. LEARNING LINK One interesting application of this theory is in the analysis of cartels (a form of collusion between firms): this is explained in Chapter 20. Within an oligopoly market, firms may adopt rivalrous behaviour or they may choose to cooperate with each other. The two attitudes have implications for how markets operate. Cooperation will tend to take the market towards the monopoly end of the spectrum, whereas non-cooperation will take it towards the competitive end. In either scenario, it is likely that the market outcome will be somewhere between the two extremes. Non-price competition One feature of oligopoly is that firms may engage in non-price competition. Nonprice competition is exactly what it says: firms do not use price to compete with rival firms, but find other ways, such as product differentiation (as used by firms in monopolistic competition). For example, they may use advertising to set their own products out from the crowd, and encourage customers to be loyal to a brand. Alternatively, they may compete on the quality or design of their goods or services. Launching a loyalty card system can also encourage customers to stick with a particular brand. The use of clever packaging, or the offering of discounts to return customers, can also be effective. Non-price competition may be favoured by firms in an oligopoly market, because there are relatively few firms in the market, so the way in which products are differentiated can be more targeted to counter the actions of rival firms. Furthermore, there may be situations in oligopoly in which firms may be reluctant to compete on price, or to become involved in a price war. 19 Different market structures: monopolistic competition and oligopoly Oligopolies may come about for many reasons, but perhaps the most convincing concerns economies of scale. An oligopoly is likely to develop in a market where there are some economies of scale – economies that are not substantial enough to require a natural monopoly, but which are large enough to make it difficult for too many firms to operate at minimum efficient scale. Game theory and the Prisoners’ Dilemma An important development in the economic theory of the firm has been in the application of game theory. This began as a branch of mathematics, but it became apparent that it had wide applications in explaining the behaviour of firms in an oligopoly. Game theory itself has a long history, with some writers tracing it back to correspondence between Pascal and Fermat in the mid-seventeenth century. Early applications in economics were by Antoine Augustin Cournot in 1838, Francis Edgeworth in 1881 and J. Bertrand in 1883, but the key publication was the book by John von Neumann and Oskar Morgenstern, Theory of Games and Economic Behaviour, in 1944. Other famous names in game theory include John Nash (played by Russell Crowe in the film A Beautiful Mind), John Harsanyi and Reinhard Selten, who shared the 1994 Nobel prize for their work in this area. Almost certainly, the most famous game is the Prisoners’ Dilemma, introduced in a lecture by Albert Tucker (who taught John Nash at Princeton) in 1950. This simple example of game theory turns out to have a multitude of helpful applications in economics. 281 308275_C19_CAM_IASAL ECO_276_291.indd 281 17/02/21 5:50 PM Two prisoners, Al Fresco and Des Jardins, are being interrogated about a major crime, and the police know that at least one of the prisoners is guilty. The two are kept in separate cells and cannot communicate with each other. The police have enough evidence to convict them of a minor offence, but not enough to convict them of the major one. A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 19 Each prisoner is offered a deal. If he turns state’s evidence and provides evidence to convict the other prisoner, he will get off – unless the other prisoner also confesses. If both refuse to deal, they will just be charged with the minor offence. Table 19.1 summarises the sentences that each will receive in the various circumstances. ▼ Table 19.1 The prisoners’ dilemma: possible outcomes (years in jail) Des Confess Al Refuse Confess 10 10 0 15 Refuse 15 0 5 5 QUANTITATIVE SKILLS 19.1 Reading and using a matrix of numerical data depends on what Des chooses to do. If Des also confesses, then Al gets a sentence of 10 years, but if Des refuses to deal, then Al gets away scot-free. In each case, Al’s sentence (in years) is shown in red and Des’s in blue. How do we read the matrix? Think about this from Al’s perspective. If Al confesses, we look at the red entries in the first row of the table. This shows that the sentence that Al will receive Suppose Al instead refuses to confess. We then read across the second row, and see that Al gets a heavy sentence if he refuses to confess but Des confesses (i.e. testifies against Al), but if they both refuse to confess they both get off relatively lightly. If both Al and Des refuse to deal, they will be convicted of the minor offence, and each will go down for 5 years. However, if Al confesses and Des refuses to deal, Al will get off completely free, and Des will take the full rap of 15 years. If Des confesses and Al refuses, the reverse happens. However, if both confess, they will each get 10 years. KEY TERMS dominant strategy: a situation in game theory where a player’s best strategy is independent of those chosen by others duopoly: a market with two firms Test yourself 19.5 Why does Des face a dominant strategy to confess? Think about this situation from Al’s point of view, remembering that the prisoners cannot communicate, so Al does not know what Des will choose to do and vice versa. You can see from Table 19.1 that, whatever Des chooses to do, Al will be better off confessing. John Nash referred to such a situation as a dominant strategy. The dilemma is, of course, symmetric, so for Des too the dominant strategy is to confess. The inevitable result is that, if both prisoners are selfish, they will both confess – and both will then get 10 years in jail. If they had both refused to deal, they would both have been better off; but this is too risky a strategy for either of them to adopt. A refusal to deal might have led to 15 years in jail. What has this to do with economics? Think about the market for DIY products. Suppose there are two firms (Diamond Tools and Better Spades) operating in a duopoly market (i.e. a market with only two firms). Each firm has a choice of producing ‘high’ output or ‘low’ output. The profit made by one firm depends on two things: its own output and the output of the other firm. Table 19.2 shows the range of possible outcomes for a particular time period. Consider Diamond Tools: if it chooses ‘low’ when Better Spades also chooses ‘low’, it will make $2 million profit (and so will Better Spades); but if Diamond Tools chooses ‘low’ when Better Spades chooses ‘high’, Diamond Tools will make zero profits and Better Spades will make $3 million. 282 308275_C19_CAM_IASAL ECO_276_291.indd 282 17/02/21 5:50 PM ▼ Table 19.2 Diamond Tools and Better Spades: possible outcomes (profits in $m) 19 Better Spades High Diamond Tools Low High 1 1 3 0 Low 0 3 2 2 KEY TERM Nash equilibrium: a situation occurring within a game when each player’s chosen strategy maximises payoffs given the other players’ choices, so no other player has an incentive to alter behaviour If Better Spades produces ‘low’, you will maximise profits by producing ‘high’, whereas if Better Spades produces ‘high’, you will still maximise profits by producing high! So Diamond Tools has a dominant strategy to produce high – it is the profit-maximising action whatever Better Spades does, even though it means that joint profits will be lower. Given that the table is symmetric, Better Spades faces the same decision process, and also has a dominant strategy to choose high, so they always end up in the northwest corner of the table, even though southeast would be better for each of them. Furthermore, after they have made their choices and seen what the other has chosen, each firm feels justified by its actions, and thinks that it took the right decision, given the rival’s move. This is known as a Nash equilibrium, which has the characteristic that neither firm needs to amend its behaviour in any future period. This model can be used to investigate a wide range of decisions that firms need to take strategically. EXERCISE 19.2 Suppose there are two cinemas in a market, X and Y; you are taking decisions for firm X. You cannot communicate with the other firm; both firms are considering only the next period. Each firm is choosing whether to set price ‘high’ or ‘low’. Your expectation is that the payoffs (in terms of profits) to the two firms are as shown in Table 19.3 (firm X in red, firm Y in blue). a If firm Y sets price high, what strategy maximises profits for firm X? b If firm Y sets price low, what strategy maximises profits for firm X? c So what strategy will firm X adopt? d What is the market outcome? LEARNING LINK In Chapter 18 it was shown that a monopoly firm would impose a deadweight loss on society by restricting output and raising price. Firms that collude under oligopoly can have a similar impact. ▼ Table 19.3 Cinemas X and Y: possible outcomes Firm Y chooses: High price Firm X chooses: Low price High price Low price 10 10 1 15 15 1 4 4 19 Different market structures: monopolistic competition and oligopoly The situation that maximises joint profits is for both firms to produce low; but suppose you were taking decisions for Diamond Tools – what would you choose? e What outcome would maximise the firms’ joint profit? f How might this outcome be achieved? g Would the outcome be different if the game were played over repeated periods? Advantages and disadvantages of an oligopoly market When evaluating an oligopoly market in terms of the possible advantages and disadvantages, a key question is whether firms in the market collude with each other, or whether they look for ways of competing with each other. The very fact that legislation has been introduced to protect consumers from market abuse by cartels and other forms of collusion between firms in an oligopoly market suggests that there is a downside to a collusive oligopoly: at least potentially. This argument is based on the way in which colluding firms may act to maximise their joint profits. On the other hand, if firms in an oligopoly do compete intensively with each other, then consumers may benefit from seeing the price being set at a competitive level. They may also gain through having wider consumer choice. Notice that where firms in an oligopoly are acting competitively, there may be little X-inefficiency present, but where there is collusion, this may be different. 283 308275_C19_CAM_IASAL ECO_276_291.indd 283 17/02/21 5:50 PM A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY Figure 19.4 shows a market in which there are only two firms operating. a The two firms competing in the market produce at constant marginal cost 0D, which means that average cost is also constant and equal to marginal cost. Competing intensively, the price is driven down to a level at which no surplus above marginal cost is made. Identify the price charged, the quantity traded and consumer surplus. b Suppose the two firms decide to collude to raise price to a level 0B. Identify the quantity traded and the consumer surplus. c You should have found that consumer surplus is much smaller in the second situation than in the first. What has happened to the areas that were formerly part of consumer surplus? Price 19 EXERCISE 19.3 A C B D E F MC = AC Demand 0 G H Output ▲ Figure 19.4 Anti-competitive behaviour EXTENSION MATERIAL Monopsony The discussion of market structure so far has focused on the number of sellers in a market, and the interrelationships between them. However, it is also important to consider the number of traders who are potential buyers in a market. An extreme situation would be where there is a single buyer of a good or service. Such a market structure is known as a monopsony. A single buyer may be able to exert substantial influence over the suppliers of the good when drawing up contracts on the price and quality of goods. Suppose that a firm is producing computer chips in competition with other similar firms, but enters into a contract to sell all of its output to a particular computer manufacturer. This may have advantages for the firm, which is assured of a secure market for its output. However, in return for this it may have to agree a competitive price and production schedule with the buyer, which is effectively acting as a monopsonist. The monopsonist gains by keeping its costs down and by being assured of regular supply of components. The consumer gains indirectly because of the monopsonist’s low cost base. Another example might occur in some labour markets. There may be towns in which there is a single large employer that employs a significant proportion of the local labour force. Again, such an employer might be seen to have market power within that local labour market. This is discussed in Chapter 23. EXERCISE 19.4 For each of the following markets, identify the model that would most closely describe it (e.g. perfect competition, monopoly, monopolistic competition or oligopoly). a A large number of firms selling branded varieties of toothpaste b A sole supplier of postal services c A large number of farmers producing cauliflowers, sold at a common price d A situation in which a few large banks supply most of the market for retail banking services e A sole supplier of rail transport 284 308275_C19_CAM_IASAL ECO_276_291.indd 284 17/02/21 5:50 PM SUMMARY: OLIGOPOLY » An oligopoly is a market with a few sellers, each of which takes strategic decisions based on likely rival actions and reactions. » As there are many ways in which firms may interact, there is no single way of modelling an oligopoly market. » Game theory (such as the Prisoners’ Dilemma) can be used to analyse strategic interaction between firms. It has been argued that in some markets, in order to prevent the entry of new firms, the existing firm would have to charge such a low price that it would be unable to reap any supernormal profits at all. hit-and-run entry: where a firm enters a market to take shortrun supernormal profits, knowing it can exit without incurring costs LEARNING LINK Sunk costs were first defined in Chapter 17, and now become critical as an essential ingredient of contestability. Test yourself 19.6 Why is the absence of exit costs important for a market to be contestable? A contestable market is one in which new firms: » » » » » face no barriers to entry or exit incur no sunk costs in entering the market have no competitive disadvantage compared with the incumbent firm or firms have access to the same technology as the incumbent(s) are able to enter and exit rapidly Under these conditions, the incumbent firm cannot set a price that is higher than average cost because, as soon as it does, it will open up the possibility of hit-and-run entry by new firms, which can enter the market and compete away the supernormal profits. Consider Figure 19.5, which shows a monopoly firm in a market. The argument is that, if the monopolist charges the profit-maximising price at P1, then in a contestable market the firm will be vulnerable to hit-and-run entry — a firm could come into the market, take some of the supernormal profits, then exit again. The only way the monopolist can avoid this happening is to set price equal to average cost (for example, at P2 in Figure 19.5), so that there are no supernormal profits to act as an incentive for entry. However, if the monopolist adopted this tactic, it would still be possible for new firms to enter the market and make at least normal profit, given that by assumption there are no barriers to entry and new firms face the same technology as the incumbent firm. Of course, as soon as new firms enter the market, it ceases to be a monopoly. The best chance a monopoly would have to prevent entry would be to make sure that the long-run average cost curve is as low as possible (no X-inefficiency), and that it does not set a price above the minimum point of the AC curve – for example, at P3 in Figure 19.5. Even this may not deter firms from entering the market to make normal profit, as there is unmet demand if the firm only sells Q3 of the good. Price contestable market: a market in which the existing firm makes only normal profit, as it cannot set a price higher than average cost without attracting entry, owing to the absence of barriers to entry and sunk costs This theory was developed by William Baumol and is known as the theory of contestable markets. It was in recognition of this theory that the monopoly model in Chapter 18 included the assumption that there must be no substitutes for the good, either actual or potential. 19 Different market structures: monopolistic competition and oligopoly 19.3 Contestable markets KEY TERMS 19 MC P1 AC P2 P3 MR AR (= D) Q1 Q3 Q2 Output Figure 19.5 Contestability 285 308275_C19_CAM_IASAL ECO_276_291.indd 285 17/02/21 5:50 PM On the face of it, the conditions for contestability sound pretty stringent. However, suppose a firm has a monopoly on a domestic air route between two destinations. An airline with surplus capacity (i.e. a spare aircraft sitting in a hangar) could enter this route and exit again without incurring sunk costs in response to profits being made by the incumbent firm. This is an example of how contestability may limit the ability of the incumbent firm to use its market power. 19 A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY Notice in this example that although the firm only makes normal profits when setting price equal to average cost, neither productive nor allocative efficiency is achieved. The firm does not produce at minimum average cost (needed for productive efficiency), nor is price set at marginal cost (needed for allocative efficiency). A moot point is whether the threat of entry will in fact persuade firms that they cannot set a price above average cost. Perhaps the firms can risk making some profit above normal profits and then respond to entry very aggressively if and when it happens. After all, it is difficult to think of an example in which there are absolutely no sunk costs. Almost any business is going to have to advertise in order to find customers, and such advertising expenditure cannot be recovered. The impact of the internet on contestability The growth of the internet has had a significant impact on the contestability of markets and hence on competitiveness. By making information more freely available, the internet has given consumers improved knowledge of market conditions and enabled them to make more informed choices. Furthermore, the growth of online sales has made it much easier for new firms to enter markets. One good example of this is the travel industry. In 2016 UK residents made more than 70 million trips abroad, so this is a significant sector. In the past, many overseas trips, especially holidays, were arranged by the high street travel agents. Although there were many retail outlets, the largest chains of travel agents were responsible for a significant market share. The internet has revolutionised this sector, with online firms competing effectively with the established firms, and individual consumers able to make their own travel arrangements much more effectively. This is an example of where increased contestability of a market has resulted in an increase in competitiveness. EXERCISE 19.5 Discuss the extent to which the following markets may be considered to be contestable – or to have become more so in recent years. a Opticians b c d e Travel agents Financial services The postal service Aircraft manufacture SUMMARY: CONTESTABLE MARKETS » In contestable markets, the incumbent firm or firms may be able to make only normal profit. » Contestability requires that there are no barriers to entry or exit and no sunk costs – and that the incumbent firm(s) have no cost advantage over hitand-run entrants. 19.4 Market concentration As firms grow, markets may become more concentrated, especially if the growth takes place through mergers and acquisitions. With fewer firms in a market, the market may move closer to being an oligopoly, so an important question is whether such markets behave more like a competitive market or more like a monopoly. 286 308275_C19_CAM_IASAL ECO_276_291.indd 286 17/02/21 5:50 PM It is helpful to have some way of gauging how close a particular market is to being a monopoly. One way of doing this is to examine the degree of concentration in the market. KEY TERM n-firm concentration ratio: a measure of the market share of the largest n firms in an industry Concentration is normally measured by reference to the concentration ratio, which measures the market share of the largest firms in an industry. For example, the threefirm concentration ratio measures the market share of the largest three firms in the market; the five-firm concentration ratio calculates the share of the top five firms, and so on. Concentration can also be viewed in terms of employment, reflected in the proportion of workers in any industry who are employed in the largest firms. Calculating a concentration ratio Consider the following example. Table 19.4 gives average circulation figures for firms that publish national newspapers in the UK (with a circulation of more than 100,000 per day). In the final column these are converted into market shares. Where one firm produces more than one newspaper, their circulations have been combined (e.g. News UK publishes both The Sun and The Times). ▼ Table 19.4 Concentration in the UK newspaper industry, January 2018 Firm Newspapers Average circulation Market share (%) dmg media Daily Mail, Metro 2,818,514 34.6 News UK The Sun, The Times 1,986,152 24.4 London Evening Standard London Evening Standard 888,017 10.9 Northern & Shell Daily Star, Daily Express 756,719 9.3 Trinity Mirror Daily Mirror, Daily Record 717,279 8.8 Telegraph Group Daily Telegraph 385,346 4.7 Johnston Press I 257,223 3.2 Pearson Financial Times 189,579 2.3 Guardian Media Group The Guardian Total 152,714 1.9 8,151,543 100.0 19 Different market structures: monopolistic competition and oligopoly QUANTITATIVE SKILLS 19.2 19 Source: based on data from Audit Bureau of Circulations The market shares are calculated by expressing the average circulation for a firm as a percentage of the total. For example, the market share of the Financial Times is 100 × 189,579/8,151,543 = 2.3%. The three-firm concentration ratio is calculated as the sum of the market shares of the biggest three firms: that is, 34.6 + 24.4 + 10.9 = 69.9%. Test yourself 19.7 How would you calculate the four-firm concentration ratio for an industry in terms of sales? Concentration ratios may be calculated on the basis of either shares in output or shares in employment. In the above example, the calculation was on the basis of output (daily circulation). The two measures may give different results because the largest firms in an industry may be more capital-intensive in their production methods, which means that their share of employment in an industry will be smaller than their share of output. For the purposes of examining market structure, however, it is more helpful to base the analysis of market share on output. This might seem an intuitively simple measure, but it is too simple to enable an evaluation of a market. For a start, it is important to define the market appropriately: for instance, in the above example are the Financial Times and The Sun really part of the same market? They cater for a very different readership. 287 308275_C19_CAM_IASAL ECO_276_291.indd 287 17/02/21 5:50 PM There may be other difficulties too. Table 19.5 gives some hypothetical market shares for two markets. The 5-firm concentration ratio is calculated as the sum of the market shares of the largest five firms. For markets A and B, the result is the same. In both cases the market is perceived to be highly concentrated, at 75%. However, the nature of likely interactions between the firms in these two markets is very different because the large relative size of firm 1 in market A is likely to give it substantially more market power than any of the largest five firms in market B. Nonetheless, the concentration ratio is useful for giving a first impression of how the market is likely to function. 19 A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY ▼ Table 19.5 Market shares (% of output) Largest firms in rank order Market A Market B Firm 1 68 15 Firm 2 3 15 Firm 3 2 15 Firm 4 1 15 Firm 5 1 15 Scale and market concentration Average cost An important issue that arises as firms become larger concerns the number of firms that a market can support. Suppose that economies of scale are available almost to the limit of market demand, as in Figure 19.6. If more than one firm were to try to supply this market, each producing at minimum average cost, there would be substantial excess supply, and the situation would not be viable. LAC Demand 0 Qmes Output ▲ Figure 19.6 How many firms can a market support? LEARNING LINK The situation of a natural monopoly was explained in Chapter 18. Test yourself 19.8 Explain why competition in a market is more likely if the minimum efficient scale is small relative to market demand. In this situation, the largest firm in the market will come to dominate, as it will be able to produce at lower average costs than any potential competitor. This will be reinforced if there are significant learning-by-doing effects, which will further entrench the largest firm as the market leader. Such a market is likely to become a natural monopoly. Such substantial economies of scale are not available in all sectors. It will depend on the nature of technology and all the other factors that can give rise to economies of scale. In some activities there may be little scope at all for economies of scale. For example, there are no great fixed costs in setting up a restaurant or a hairdressing salon – at least, compared with those involved in setting up a steel plant or an underground railway. The level of output at which minimum average cost is reached for such activities may thus be relatively small compared with market demand, so there may be room for many firms in the market. This helps to explain the proliferation of bars, takeaway restaurants and hairdressing salons. There may also be an intermediate position, where the economies of scale are not sufficient to bring about a monopoly situation, but only relatively few firms can operate efficiently. 288 308275_C19_CAM_IASAL ECO_276_291.indd 288 23/03/21 10:37 AM How does this affect the way in which a market works? Is there any reason to believe that a monopoly or oligopoly will work against society’s best interests? If market share is concentrated among a small number of firms, does this inevitably mean that consumers will suffer? If there is an incentive for a single firm to act in this way, there is a similar incentive for firms in an oligopoly to do the same, as they can increase their joint profits – with the same effects on consumers. However, the oligopoly case is more complicated, as there is always the possibility that individual firms will try to increase their own share of the market at the expense of others in the oligopoly. SUMMARY: MARKET CONCENTRATION » It is important to be able to evaluate the degree of » The size of the minimum efficient scale relative to concentration in a market. » While not a perfect measure, the concentration ratio is one way of doing this, by calculating the market share of the largest firms. market demand influences the number of firms that the market can support. END OF CHAPTER QUESTIONS Multiple choice 1 The following market structures are presented in ranked order: i monopoly ii oligopoly iii monopolistic competition iv perfect competition 19 Different market structures: monopolistic competition and oligopoly The answer to these questions depends on the behaviour of firms within the market. There may be an incentive for a monopoly firm to use its market power to increase its profits. It can do this by restricting the amount of output that it releases on to the market, and by raising the price to consumers. In Chapter 18 it was shown that a monopoly has the incentive to act in this way, since by lowering output and raising price it can increase its overall profits. From the consumer’s point of view, the result is a loss of consumer surplus. 19 The market structures are ranked from (i) to (iv) in order of: A increasing barriers to entry B increasing contestability C increasing product differentiation D increasing abnormal profits 2 The table gives the 3-firm concentration ratio in four industries. Which industry is most fragmented? 3-firm concentration ratio A 68.7% B 54.3% C 45.2% D 32.4% 289 308275_C19_CAM_IASAL ECO_276_291.indd 289 17/02/21 5:50 PM Data response A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 19 1 Read the following extract and then answer the questions that follow. Markets and market concentration in Bangladesh and the UK In Bangladesh, ‘kitchen markets’ are where most customers purchase their daily vegetables. It is relatively easy to become a small-scale kitchen market vegetable trader. These entrepreneurs know their market well and set their own prices to gain the custom of well-informed buyers. Vendors sell similar but not identical produce; this is because the quality varies between the many sellers spread between the various kitchen markets in each city. Mobile Financial Services (MFS), popularly known as ‘Mobile Banking Bangladesh’, is a service provided by a bank allowing customers to conduct financial transactions remotely. Table 19.6 shows this market to be highly concentrated. ▼ Table 19.6 Total market share of Bangladesh MFS providers MFS provider Market share (%) BRAC 55.11 DBBL 38.26 FSIBL 0.60 OBL 0.65 Other 0.67 SEBL 0.52 TBL 3.16 UCB 1.03 The prices charged by the MFS providers in Bangladesh are remarkably similar. In fact, there is no charge for opening a mobile account with any of the main providers, which also offer the facility of paying cash in for free. Many of the providers are also trying to attract new customers by being the first to link their mobile accounts to other banking services such as paying utility bills and receiving salary payments. The banking sector in the UK is also highly concentrated. In the past, the European Commission (which upholds EU legislation) has fined eight UK banks a total of €1.7 billion ($1.9 billion) for forming illegal cartels to fix interest rates. The cartels operated in markets used to manage the risk of interest rate movements. Two of the eight were excused their financial penalties for revealing the cartels’ existence. The Commission said it was shocking that competing banks had operated such collusion. Sources: FinTech a Explain, with reference to the extract, the view that the vegetable sellers in the kitchen markets of Bangladesh are operating under conditions of monopolistic competition. b Discuss, with the use of a diagram, the conditions under which a profitmaximising vegetable seller in the kitchen markets of Bangladesh might continue trading if they were making less than normal profit. c Calculate the 3-firm concentration ratio in the MFS market in Bangladesh. d Explain the importance of the non-price competition between firms in the oligopolistic MFS market in Bangladesh. e Suggest why the eight UK banks referred to in the extract may have engaged in the collusive activity identified. Essay style 290 308275_C19_CAM_IASAL ECO_276_291.indd 290 2 Discuss the likely impact on profits when new firms, attracted by supernormal profits, enter a monopolistically competitive market. 17/02/21 5:50 PM Competition in oligopolistic markets 19 v x w y MC = AC z D MR O a b Quantity ▲ Figure 19.7 Maximising joint profits? If the firms were producing different products (as is usually the case) then the analysis would be more complex, but again we could take the monopoly price or prices to be the upper limit on possible choices. An alternative option for each of our two firms would be to set a price below the monopoly level. If one firm were to choose the monopoly price and the other a lower price, then the latter would gain a larger market share and, provided the price was not too low, a larger profit. But if both chose the low price, each would earn less profit than if they had both chosen the monopoly price. The situation facing the firms is illustrated in Table 19.7. ▼ Table 19.7 Profits of two firms Firm B chooses: ▲ The oil industry is an example of an oligopoly Modelling oligopoly The defining characteristic of oligopoly is that the actions of one firm have an appreciable effect on its rival(s), and thus when modelling such a market it is natural to begin by assuming that each firm recognises this interdependence and takes it into account when formulating its strategy. To keep things simple, let’s suppose there are just two firms in the market and each of them is thinking about what price to charge for its product. Again, just for simplicity, we will focus on two possibilities. What is the highest price that they might conceivably choose? To answer this, consider the maximum aggregate profit that the two firms could theoretically generate. Figure 19.7 depicts the two firms as producing identical products with identical horizontal marginal cost (average cost) curves. The market demand curve is D, and MR shows the (joint) marginal revenue accruing to the firms if they set the same price. This is the same marginal revenue curve that would have existed had the market been a monopoly. Firm A High price chooses: Low price High price Low price 2 2 0 3 3 0 1 1 19 Different market structures: monopolistic competition and oligopoly An oligopolistic market is one in which firms engage in strategic competition. Strategic competition exists when the actions of one firm have an appreciable effect on its rival or rivals. Common textbook examples of oligopoly include the oil industry, motor manufacturing, soft drinks and airlines operating between particular city pairs. But oligopolists are not necessarily large firms. Close to the university campus in Southampton, in the UK, there is a road containing several small restaurants and takeaways. They are engaged in strategic competition locally because if one firm were to change its prices, this would have an appreciable effect on the sales and thus profits of the others. So you can see that many firms will find themselves competing in oligopolistic markets and thus it is important that, as economists, we try to understand how such markets operate. Price CASE STUDY The two firms, A and B, must choose either a high price or a low price and the decisions are assumed to be made simultaneously, in the sense that each firm makes its decision without knowledge of the other firm’s choice. The figures represent the profits of the two firms, with the red numbers denoting the profit of firm A and the blue numbers the profit of firm B. Thus, for example, if both opt for high (the monopoly price) then each will earn a profit of 2 (half the monopoly profit), but if, say, A chooses high and B chooses low, A will make a profit of 0 and B will make 3. Follow-up questions a What is the maximum joint profit that the firms could theoretically generate? Explain how this could be achieved. b What prices will the two firms choose? c The passage describes the situation close to the campus at the University of Southampton in the UK, in which there are several restaurants operating in close proximity. Discuss whether they would be able to maximise their joint profits through collaboration. 291 308275_C19_CAM_IASAL ECO_276_291.indd 291 17/02/21 5:50 PM A LEVEL PART 7 The price system and the microeconomy A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 20 The growth and objectives of firms What this chapter covers ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ the growth and survival of firms organic growth of firms and diversification mergers and takeovers horizontal, vertical and backward integration conglomerate mergers cartels the principal–agent problem objectives of firms behavioural theories and satisficing ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ revenue maximisation sales volume maximisation utility maximisation first-, second- and third-degree price discrimination limit pricing predatory pricing price leadership the kinked demand curve model Firms range in size, from small local enterprises to giant global firms. Firms undergo growth in different ways, through internal and external expansion. So far, we have assumed that firms act rationally, and set out to maximise their profits. This is one possible motivation for firms, and one that is readily analysed, but it is not the only possible objective. This chapter explores profit maximisation as well as alternative theories that have been put forward to explain how firms take decisions. In particular, it begins to explore how firms take decisions about the level of output to produce and the price at which it is to be sold. 20.1 The growth and survival of firms A key decision that all firms face concerns the scale of their operations. This decision turns partly on the nature of the market that they are serving, but it also depends on the technology of the sector in which they operate and the structure of costs that they face. Some firms may need to grow in order to compete with other large-scale competitors in global markets. There may be many reasons why firms wish to expand their operations. LEARNING LINK The way that costs vary with the scale of production is important; Chapter 19 explains how the minimum efficient scale relative to market demand influences the size of firms. The nature of the activity being undertaken by the firm and its scale of operation will help to determine its most efficient form of organisation. For firms to operate successfully, they must minimise the transaction costs of undertaking business. Some firms may not wish to grow into large organisations – nor may it be profitable for them to do so. A feature of the economic environment in recent years has been the increasing size of firms. Some, such as Microsoft, Wal-Mart and Google, have become giants. Why is this happening? Of course, not all firms become giants, and many small firms operate profitably and effectively. In part, this may reflect the nature of the markets in which small firms thrive. The service sector in particular provides opportunities for small firms to operate effectively, perhaps because of the absence of economies of scale, or because there are niche products where small firms have a competitive advantage over larger enterprises. After all, small firms may be more flexible and responsive to customer 292 308275_C20_CAM_IASAL ECO_292_309.indd 292 17/02/21 5:46 PM needs, and able to provide a high-quality personal service. Small firms tend to emerge in times of high unemployment, when jobs are scarce and self-employment becomes an attractive option for some individuals, as it can offer high job satisfaction. 20 There are drawbacks with being small as a firm. Obtaining finance for investment may be more difficult, and a small firm may find it more difficult to survive when times are hard. In some markets, competing with larger firms may pose problems. Organic growth Some firms grow simply by being successful. For example, a successful marketing campaign may increase a firm’s market share, and provide it with a flow of profits that can be reinvested to expand the firm even more. Some firms may choose to borrow in order to finance their growth, perhaps by issuing shares (equity). KEY TERM organic growth: when a firm grows internally by reinvesting profits or borrowing from banks Such organic growth may encounter limits. A firm may find that its product market is saturated, so that it can grow further only at the expense of other firms in the market. If its competitors are able to maintain their own market shares, the firm may need to diversify its production activities by finding new markets for its existing product, or perhaps offering new products. 20 The growth and objectives of firms Firms may wish to increase their size in order to gain market power within the industry in which they are operating. A firm that can gain market share, and perhaps become dominant in the market, may be able to exercise some control over the price of its product, and thereby influence the market. However, firms may wish to grow for other reasons, which will be explained later in the chapter. There are many examples of growth through diversification. Tesco, a leading UK supermarket, has launched itself into new markets by opening branches overseas, and has also introduced a range of new products, including financial services, to its existing customers. Microsoft has famously used this strategy, by selling first its internet browser and later its media player as part of its Windows operating system, in an attempt to persuade existing customers to buy its new products. This aggressive approach attracted the attention of the regulatory authorities in the USA and Europe. Test yourself 20.1 If a firm expands its market share by using funds from past profits, is this classified as ‘organic growth’? ▲ Tesco supermarket in China Test yourself 20.2 Explain what is meant by ‘diversification’ in this context. Diversification may be a dangerous strategy: moving into a market in which the firm is inexperienced and where existing rival firms already know the business may pose quite a challenge. In such circumstances, much may depend on the quality of the management team. However, diversification may reduce risk if the products do not follow the same cycle of activity through time. 293 308275_C20_CAM_IASAL ECO_292_309.indd 293 17/02/21 5:46 PM Mergers and takeovers A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 20 Instead of growing organically – that is, based on the firm’s own resources – many firms choose to grow by merging with, or taking over, other firms. The distinction here is that a takeover (or acquisition) may be hostile, whereas a merger may be the coming together of equals, with each firm committed to forming a single entity. Growth in this way has a number of advantages: for example, it may overcome the management problem and allow some rationalisation to take place. On the other hand, firms tend to develop their own culture, or way of doing things, and some mergers have failed because of an incompatibility of corporate cultures. Horizontal mergers LEARNING LINK Market concentration is discussed in Chapter 19. KEY TERMS horizontal merger: a merger between two firms at the same stage of production in the same industry Mergers (or takeovers) can be of three different types. A horizontal merger is a merger between firms operating in the same industry and at the same stage of the production process: for example, the merger of two car assembly firms. The car industry has been characterised by such mergers, including the takeover of Rover by BMW and the merger of Daimler-Benz with Chrysler in the 1990s. The merger of Hewlett-Packard with Compaq is another example of a horizontal merger. A more recent example was the takeover of Instagram by Facebook in the early 2010s. This sort of merger leads to horizontal integration, which can affect the degree of market concentration because after the merger takes place there are fewer independent firms operating in the market. This may increase the market power held by the new firm. Vertical mergers horizontal integration: the result of a horizontal merger A car assembly plant merging with a tyre producer, on the other hand, is an example of a vertical merger. A real-life example of this was the merger in 2000 of AOL with Time Warner. vertical merger: a merger between two firms in the same industry, but at different stages of the production process Vertical mergers may be either upstream or downstream. If a car company merges with a component supplier, that is known as backward integration, as it involves merging with a firm that is involved in an earlier part of the production process. Forward integration entails merging in the other direction, as for example if the car assembly plant decided to merge with a large distributor. backward integration: a process under which a firm merges with a firm that is involved in an earlier part of the production chain forward integration: a process under which a firm merges with a firm that is involved in a later part of the production chain conglomerate merger: a merger between two firms operating in different markets Test yourself 20.3 Give another example of forward integration. 294 308275_C20_CAM_IASAL ECO_292_309.indd 294 Vertical integration may allow rationalisation of the process of production. Car producers often work on a just-in-time basis, ordering components for the production line only as they are required. This creates a potential vulnerability because if the supply of components fails then production has to stop. If a firm’s component supplier is part of the firm rather than an independent operator, this may improve the reliability of, and confidence in, the justin-time process, and in consequence may make life more difficult for rival firms. However, vertical mergers have different implications for concentration and market power. Conglomerate mergers The third type of merger, conglomerate merger, involves the merging of two firms that are operating in quite different markets or industries. For example, companies like Unilever, Tata and Nestlé operate in a wide range of different markets, partly as a result of takeovers. The UK supermarket Sainsbury’s acquired Argos in 2016, thus expanding its non-food business. In 2018, Nestlé announced a global coffee alliance, whereby it would pay Starbucks $7.1 billion to sell its coffee, thus extending its supply chain downwards. One argument in favour of conglomerates is that they reduce the risks faced by firms. Many markets follow fluctuations that are in line with the business cycle but are not always fully synchronised. By operating in a number of markets that are on different cycles, the firm can even out its activity overall. However, it is not necessarily an efficient way of doing business, as the different activities undertaken may require different skills and specialisms. In recent years, conglomerate mergers seem to have become less popular. 17/02/21 5:46 PM Test yourself 20.4 Give another example of a conglomerate firm. Not all mergers turn out to be successful, and there may be circumstances in which merged firms choose to ‘demerge’ and split. A common factor that can lead to this happening is where firms from different countries merge, only to find that their corporate cultures are incompatible. This can even happen with firms from the same country, where management styles in the individual companies do not fit well together. In other situations, it may be that synergies achieved between the production activities of the firms are not as strong as expected. Demergers can turn out to be costly and bitterly disputed. Categorise each of the following as a horizontal, vertical or conglomerate merger: a the merger of a firm operating an instant coffee factory with a coffee plantation b the merger of a soft drinks manufacturer with a bakery c the merger of a soft drinks manufacturer with a crisp manufacturer STUDY TIP d the merger of a soft drinks manufacturer with a chain of fast-food outlets e the merger of an internet service provider with a film studio f a merger between two firms producing tyres for cars Evaluation of mergers and takeovers Make sure that you are familiar with the three types of merger (horizontal, vertical and conglomerate) and be ready with examples of each to illustrate your answers. Mergers and takeovers seem at first glance to be an attractive option for a firm wishing to expand. Organic growth may offer a more controlled environment for growth, as it builds on the known existing strengths of the growing firm. However, it may be a slower process, as the rate of growth may be constrained by the availability of finance, whereas a merger offers an instant expansion of market share and of the expertise available within the merged firm. It also seems to offer the potential for cost savings through rationalisation of key functions within the internal organisation of a firm. Test yourself 20.5 A vertical merger, whether forward or backward, offers greater control over the supply chain. If the firm after the merger now has its own suppliers of components, or its own distribution chain, it is clearly less subject to interruptions in supply, and has more control over the margins at each stage of the production process. Why is it an advantage for a firm to have greater control over its supply chain after a vertical merger? 20 The growth and objectives of firms EXERCISE 20.1 20 In the case of a horizontal merger, the advantages may be seen as providing instant access to increased economies of scale, and an increase in market share, perhaps leading to increased market power. In practice, this may also be a disadvantage, because such gains in market share may attract the attention of the regulator, as will be discussed in Chapter 21. A conglomerate merger may also offer advantages because a diversified portfolio of production activities may leave the firm less vulnerable to recession, if different activities are affected to different degrees by fluctuations in the general level of economic activity. There may also be possibilities for cost savings, if the merged firms can find synergies in core business functions such as financial accounting or marketing. It is thus likely to consolidate these functions, shedding staff and perhaps relocating some functions. On the other hand, there may be managerial diseconomies if the management team do not understand all aspects of the new diversified business. SUMMARY: THE GROWTH AND SURVIVAL OF FIRMS » Firms range, in the size and complexity of their » If limited by the size of their markets, firms may organisation, from sole proprietors to public limited companies. » Firms may undergo organic growth, building on their own resources and past profits. diversify into new markets or products. » Firms may also undergo external growth through horizontal, vertical or conglomerate mergers and takeovers. 295 308275_C20_CAM_IASAL ECO_292_309.indd 295 17/02/21 5:46 PM 20.2 Cartels 20 Look back at the prisoners’ dilemma game in Table 19.2 on page 283. It is clear that the requirement that the firms are unable to communicate with each other is a serious impediment from the firms’ point of view. If both firms could agree to produce ‘low’, they would maximise their joint profits, but they will not risk this strategy if they cannot communicate. A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY KEY TERM cartel: an agreement between firms on price and output with the intention of maximising their joint profits If they could join together in a cartel, the two firms could come to an agreement to adopt the low–low strategy. However, if they were to agree to this, each firm would have a strong incentive to cheat because, if each now knew that the other firm was going to produce low, they would also know that they could produce high and dominate the market – at least, given the payoffs in the table. This is a common feature of cartels. Collusion can bring high joint profits, but there is always the temptation for each of the member firms to cheat and try to sneak some additional market share at the expense of the other firms in the cartel. EXTENSION MATERIAL The operation of a cartel You can see how a cartel might operate in Figure 20.1, which shows the situation facing a two-firm cartel (a duopoly). Panels (a) and (b) show the cost conditions for each of the firms, and panel (c) shows the whole market. (a) Firm 1 (b) Firm 2 £ MC1 £ (c) Cartel MC2 £ MC P* SAC2 Dm MR* SAC1 MRm Q2 Q2* Q1 Output (Q1 + Q2) Output Output ▲ Figure 20.1 Market allocation in a two-firm cartel If the firms aim to maximise their joint profits, then they set MR = MC at the level of the market (shown in panel (c)). This occurs at the joint level of output Q1 + Q2, with the price set at P*. Notice that the joint marginal cost curve is the sum of the two firms’ marginal cost curves. The critical decision is how to divide the market up between the two firms. In the figure, the two firms have different cost conditions, with firm 1 operating at lower short-run average cost than firm 2. If the firms agree to set price at P*, and each produces up to the point where marginal cost equals the level of (market) marginal revenue at MR*, then the market should work well. Firm 1 produces Q1 and firm 2 produces Q2. Joint profits are maximised, and there is a clear rule enabling the division of the market between the firms. However, notice that firm 2 is very much the junior partner in this alliance, as it gets a much smaller market share. The temptation to cheat is obvious. If firm 2 accepts price P*, it sees that its profits will be maximised at Q2*, so there is a temptation to try to steal an extra bit of market share. Of course, the temptation is also there for firm 1, but as soon as either one of the firms begins to increase output, the market price will have to fall to maintain equilibrium, and the cartel will be broken: the market will move away from the joint profit-maximising position. 296 308275_C20_CAM_IASAL ECO_292_309.indd 296 17/02/21 5:46 PM Test yourself 20.6 Why should cartels be illegal? There is another downside to the formation of a cartel. In the vast majority of countries around the world they are illegal. For example, in the UK the operation of a cartel is illegal under the UK Competition Act, under which the Competition and Markets Authority (CMA) is empowered to fine firms up to 10% of their turnover for each year the cartel is found to have been in operation. Some conditions may favour the formation of cartels – or at least, some form of collusion between firms. The most important of these is the ability of each of the firms involved to monitor the actions of the other firms, and so ensure that they are keeping to the agreement. Test yourself 20.7 What factors might hinder collusion between firms? In this context, it helps if there are a relatively small number of firms; otherwise it will be difficult to monitor the market. It also helps if they are producing similar goods; otherwise one firm could try to steal an advantage by varying the quality of the product. When the economy is booming it may be more difficult to monitor market shares, because all firms are likely to be expanding. If firms have excess capacity, this may increase the temptation to cheat by increasing output and stealing market share; on the other hand, it also makes it possible for the other firms to retaliate quickly. The degree of secrecy about market shares and market conditions is also important. 20 The growth and objectives of firms This means that overt collusion is rare. The most famous example is not between firms but between nations, in the form of the Organisation of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC), which over a long period of time has operated a cartel to control the price of oil. 20 SUMMARY: CARTELS » A cartel is an agreement between firms on price and output with the intention of maximising their joint profits. » Collusion between the firms can increase profits, but there is a tendency for individual firms to cheat on the agreement. » Cartels are illegal in most countries. 20.3 The principal–agent problem KEY TERM principal–agent problem: a problem arising from conflict between the objectives of the principals and those of the agents who take decisions on their behalf LEARNING LINK The various objectives that firms (or their managers) pursue are discussed later in this chapter. One issue for many larger firms – especially public limited companies – is that the owners may not be directly involved in running the business. This gives rise to the principal–agent problem. In a public limited company, the shareholders delegate the day-to-day decisions concerning the operation of the firm to managers who act on their behalf. In this case the shareholders are the principals, and the managers are the agents who run things for them. The degree of accountability of managers to the owners may be weak when the shareholders are a disparate group of individuals. If the agents are fully in sympathy with the objectives of the owners, there is no problem and the managers will take exactly the decisions that the owners would like. Problems arise when there is conflict between the aims of the owners and those of the managers. Shareholders (the owners) are likely to want the firm to maximise its profits, but the managers may have other motivations. One simple explanation of why this problem arises is that the managers like a quiet life, and therefore do not push to make as much profit as possible, but do just enough to keep the shareholders off their backs. LEARNING LINK The situation where managers aim to produce satisfactory profits rather than maximum profits is discussed later in the chapter. 297 308275_C20_CAM_IASAL ECO_292_309.indd 297 17/02/21 5:46 PM A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 20 Test yourself 20.8 Why might there be conflict between a firm’s owners and its managers? LEARNING LINK X-inefficiency is explained in Chapter 17; asymmetric information is discussed in Chapter 15. Another possibility is that managers become negligent because they are not fully accountable. One manifestation of this may be organisational slack: costs will not be minimised, as the firm is not operating as efficiently as it could. In other words, there could be some degree of X-inefficiency. The principal–agent problem arises primarily because there is asymmetric information. This arises because the agents have better information about the effects of their decisions than the owners (the principals), who are not involved in the day-to-day running of the business. In order to overcome this, the owners need to overcome the information problem by improving their monitoring of the managers’ actions, or to provide the managers with an incentive to take decisions that align with the owners’ objectives. For example, if bonuses related to profit are offered, the managers will be more likely to try to maximise profits. EXERCISE 20.2 The principal–agent distinction is applicable in many different contexts. In each of the following cases, identify which is the principal and which is the agent. a The owners of a firm and the managers hired to run it b A department store and its employees c A department store and its customers d An electricity supplier and consumers of electricity e A dentist and his or her patients SUMMARY: THE PRINCIPAL–AGENT PROBLEM » For many larger firms, where day-to-day control is delegated to managers, a principal–agent problem may arise if there is conflict between the objectives of owners (principals) and those of the managers (agents). » Where this occurs, the managers may be able to pursue their own interests, rather than those of the owners of the firm. LEARNING LINK Profit maximisation as a motivation for firms is discussed in Chapter 17. 20.4 Differing objectives and policies of firms Most of the discussion so far has rested on the assumption that firms set out to maximise profits. When we consider a relatively small, owner-managed firm, this may be a reasonable assumption – but it is clear that many firms do not fall into this category. Firms may not always appear to be only concerned with profit. There may be explanations for this. Survival Not all firms have ambitions to grow into large (or even medium-sized) companies. Indeed, where there are limited economies of scale, it may not be feasible to grow significantly. A small family business may be content for the family to remain in control of their enterprise rather than striving to maximise profits. It may be that they aim to serve their local community, perhaps in a small village where there are close personal links with customers. Some firms may actually gain advantage from being small, having low overheads and being flexible in the face of changing demand. Or there may be firms that are reluctant to take on debt in order to expand. Without ambition to grow, a firm may be content with survival rather than maximum profits. 298 308275_C20_CAM_IASAL ECO_292_309.indd 298 17/02/21 5:46 PM Behavioural theories and profit satisficing KEY TERMS corporate social responsibility (CSR): actions that a firm takes in order to demonstrate its commitment to behaving in the public interest Although firms may set out to take rational decisions, they may not have all the relevant information about market conditions that is needed, or might not have the capacity to analyse the information that they have. It might be that the information is costly to acquire, or costly to analyse fully. In such a situation, firms do the best they can to take good decisions, but without full information they may not achieve a fully rational outcome. Firms may wish to develop a favourable reputation by demonstrating a commitment to acting in ways that benefit society at large, or that improve the welfare of their employees and the community in which they are located. This notion of corporate social responsibility (CSR) has become widespread, with firms devoting resources to promoting community programmes of various kinds and encouraging their employees to engage in volunteering activities. EXERCISE 20.3 Google ‘corporate social responsibility’ with the name of some large firms with which you are 20 20 The growth and objectives of firms satisficing behaviour: managers of firms aim to produce satisfactory results for the firm, e.g. in terms of profits, rather than trying to maximise them Businesses may not set out to maximise anything, either consciously because they have other motivations, or as a result of the principal–agent issue. For example, it might be that managers simply prefer a quiet life, and therefore do not push for the absolute profit-maximising position, but do just enough to keep the shareholders off their backs. Herbert Simon referred to this as satisficing behaviour, where managers aim to produce satisfactory profits rather than maximum profits. familiar, and check out the range of activities in which firms engage under this banner. Has this now become a prerequisite for firms’ survival? If it is perceived that failure to engage with CSR has a major impact on firms’ sales, then it becomes crucial for a firm to be able to demonstrate its commitment in order to compete with its rivals. Devoting resources to CSR then becomes part of a firm’s strategy to safeguard its market position. Test yourself 20.9 Explain what is meant by ‘satisficing’ behaviour. Test yourself 20.10 The industrial economist William Baumol argued that managers may set out with the objective of maximising sales revenue. One reason is that in some firms managerial salaries are related to sales revenue rather than profits. The effects of this can be seen in Figure 20.2, which shows how total revenue (TR) varies as output increases. (The TR curve always takes this shape when the firm faces a downward-sloping straight-line demand curve.) You can see that total revenue is maximised at the peak of the TR curve (which is also the point at which MR = 0), at qr. A revenue-maximising firm will produce more output than a profit-maximising one, and will need to charge a lower price in order to sell the extra output. This should be apparent from the fact that profits are maximised where MR = MC, which must be at a positive level of MR – and thus to the left of qr in Figure 20.2. Revenue, cost Give an example of an action taken by a firm to demonstrate a commitment to behaving responsibly. Revenue maximisation TC TR q qr Output ▲ Figure 20.2 Sales revenue maximisation 299 308275_C20_CAM_IASAL ECO_292_309.indd 299 17/02/21 5:46 PM Baumol pointed out that the shareholders might not be too pleased about this. The way the firm behaves then depends on the degree of accountability that the agents (managers) have to the principals (shareholders). For example, the shareholders may have sufficient power over their agents to be able to insist on some minimum level of profits. The result may then be a compromise solution. 20 In some cases, managers may focus more on the volume of sales than on the resulting revenues. For example, a newspaper publisher may be more concerned about circulation figures than revenue. This could lead to output being set even higher, as shown in Figure 20.3. The firm would now push for higher sales up to the point where it just breaks even at qs. This is the point at which total revenue only just covers total cost. Remember that total cost includes normal profit – the opportunity cost of the resources tied up in the firm. The firm would have to close down if it did not cover this opportunity cost. Revenue, cost A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY Sales volume maximisation TC STUDY TIP Remember that the ‘break-even’ point is where the firm makes just normal profits, which is where AC = AR (i.e. where TC = TR). Test yourself 20.11 What is the difference between sales volume and sales revenue? TR q qr qs Output ▲ Figure 20.3 Sales volume maximisation Again, the extent to which the managers will be able to pursue this objective without endangering their positions with the shareholders depends on how accountable the managers are to the shareholders. Remember that the managers are likely to have much better information about the market conditions and the internal functioning of the firm than the shareholders, who view the firm only remotely. This may be to the managers’ advantage. Utility maximisation Oliver Williamson argued that managers would set out to maximise their utility. Just as consumers gain satisfaction from consuming goods, it is argued that managers gain satisfaction in various ways. For example, they may enjoy the status of having a large team of people working for them, or they may like to have discretion over the way in which profits made by the firm are used, perhaps allowing them to have a large and well-appointed office or a prestigious company car. Again, such activity would take the firm away from its profit-maximising position, and may result in X-inefficiency. Long-run profit maximisation Firms may be prepared to take a long-term view of their situation. There may be times when the decision to maximise profits in the short run may damage their long-run prospects. For example, firms may undertake costly investment now in order to reap higher profits in the long term. Or firms may delay adjusting price to an increase in costs so that they maintain customer loyalty. In other words, short-run profit maximisation may not always be in the best long-run interests of the firm. 300 308275_C20_CAM_IASAL ECO_292_309.indd 300 17/02/21 5:46 PM 20.5 Price discrimination A profit-maximising monopoly firm will set a price that is above marginal cost, producing a level of output that is below the level required for allocative efficiency. However, there is a special case in which a monopolist could produce the level of output that is allocatively efficient. $ A Pm LMC = AC B P* Demand MR 0 Qm Q* 20 The growth and objectives of firms Consider Figure 20.4. Suppose this market is operated by a monopolist that faces the constant marginal cost curve LMC. (This is to simplify the analysis.) In Chapter 18, we saw that under perfect competition the market outcome would be a price P* and quantity Q*. What would induce the monopolist to produce at Q*? 20 Output ▲ Figure 20.4 First-degree price discrimination STUDY TIP There may be circumstances in which different firms charge different prices to their customers for products that may seem identical or similar. This is not price discrimination. The difference here is that a single firm is able to charge different prices to individual customers. This is price discrimination. One of the assumptions made throughout the analysis so far is that all consumers in a market get to pay the same price for the product. This leads to the notion of consumer surplus, which was introduced in Chapter 4. In Figure 20.4, if the market were operating under perfect competition and all consumers were paying the same price, consumer surplus would be given by the area AP*B. If the market were operated by a monopolist, also charging the same price to all buyers, then profits would be maximised where MC = MR: that is, at quantity Qm and price Pm. But suppose this assumption is now relaxed; suppose that the monopolist is able to charge a different price to each individual consumer. The monopolist is then able to charge each consumer a price that is equal to his or her willingness to pay for the good. In other words, the demand curve effectively becomes the marginal revenue curve, as it represents the amount that the monopolist will receive for each unit of the good. It will then maximise profits at point B in Figure 20.4, where MR (i.e. AR) is equal to LMC. The difference between this situation and that under perfect competition is that the area AP*B is no longer consumer surplus, but producer surplus: that is, the monopolist’s profits. The monopolist has hijacked the whole of the original consumer surplus as its profits. First-degree price discrimination KEY TERM first-degree price discrimination: situation arising in a market whereby a monopoly firm is able to charge each consumer a different price From society’s point of view, total welfare is the same as it is under perfect competition (but more than under monopoly without discrimination). However, now there has been a redistribution, from consumers to the monopoly – and presumably to the shareholders of the firm. This situation is known as perfect price discrimination or first-degree price discrimination. First-degree price discrimination is fairly rare in the real world, although it might be said to exist in the world of art or fashion, where customers may commission a painting, sculpture or item of designer jewellery and the price is a matter of negotiation between the buyer and supplier. 301 308275_C20_CAM_IASAL ECO_292_309.indd 301 17/02/21 5:46 PM A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 20 Second-degree price discrimination KEY TERMS second-degree price discrimination: situation in which a firm is able to charge consumers a different price for the same product, according to the quantity that they purchase Another way in which firms can engage in price discrimination is by giving consumers some choice in their buying pattern. For example, supermarkets may offer shoppers a choice between buying a single unit of a good at one price, or buying two units at a lower average price (a ‘2 for $x’ type of offer). In this situation, consumers are charged a different unit price for a product depending on the quantity that they purchase. This is known as second-degree price discrimination. third-degree price discrimination: situation in which a firm is able to charge groups of consumers a different price for the same product arbitrage: a process by which prices in two market segments will be equalised by a process of purchase and resale by market participants ▲ Shoppers may be charged a unit price dependent on how much they buy Third-degree price discrimination In some circumstances, firms are able to charge a different price to different groups of consumers. This is known as third-degree price discrimination. For example, students or older people may get discounted bus fares, the young and/or old may get cheaper access to sporting events or theatres, etc. In these instances, individual consumers are paying different prices for what is in fact the same product. Conditions for price discrimination There are three conditions under which a firm may be able to price discriminate: » The firm must have market power. » The firm must have information about consumers and their willingness to pay – and there must be identifiable differences between consumers (or groups of consumers). » The consumers must have limited ability to resell the product. Market power Clearly, price discrimination is not possible in a perfectly competitive market, where no seller has the power to charge other than the going market price. So price discrimination can take place only where firms have some ability to vary the price. Information about different groups of consumers From the firm’s point of view, it needs to be able to identify different groups of consumers with different willingness to pay. What makes price discrimination profitable for firms is that different consumers display different sensitivities to price: that is, they have different price elasticities of demand. Test yourself 20.12 Why would a firm not be able to use price discrimination if consumers could resell the product? Ability to resell If consumers could resell the product easily, then price discrimination would not be possible, as consumers would engage in arbitrage. In other words, the group of consumers who qualified for the low price could buy up the product and then turn a profit by reselling to consumers in the other segment(s) of the market. This would mean that the firm would no longer be able to sell at the high price, and would no longer try to discriminate in pricing. 302 308275_C20_CAM_IASAL ECO_292_309.indd 302 17/02/21 5:47 PM Consequences of price discrimination In the case of student discounts and concessions, the firm can identify particular groups of consumers; and such ‘products’ as bus journeys and dental treatment cannot be resold. But why should a firm undertake this practice? 20 The simple answer is that, by undertaking price discrimination, the firm is able to increase its profits by switching sales from a market with relatively low marginal revenue to a market where it is higher. (a) Market A £ (b) Market B (c) Combined market £ A £ MC PA P* PB MRB MR* P* Total demand MR ARB MRA MRA MRB ARA qA qA* qB* qB Output 20 The growth and objectives of firms This is shown in Figure 20.5, which separates two distinct groups of consumers with differing demand curves. Thus, panel (a) shows market A and panel (b) shows market B, with the combined demand curve being shown in panel (c), which also shows the firm’s marginal cost curve. Q* Output Output ▲ Figure 20.5 A price-discriminating monopolist STUDY TIP Be ready with the three conditions that are necessary if a firm is to be able to use price discrimination: » The firm must have some market power. » The firm must be able to identify different consumers (or groups of consumers) and differences in their elasticities of demand. » There must be limited ability for consumers to resell the product. Test yourself 20.13 What incentive would a firm have to practise price discrimination? If a firm has to charge the same price to all consumers, it sets marginal revenue in the combined market equal to marginal cost, and produces Q* output, to be sold at a price of P*. This maximises profits when all consumers pay the same price. The firm sells qA* in market A, and qB* in market B. However, if you look at panels (a) and (b), you will see that marginal revenue in market A is much lower (at MRA) than that in market B (at MRB). It is this difference in marginal revenue that opens up a profit-increasing opportunity for the firm. By taking sales away from market A and selling more in market B, the firm gains more extra revenue in B than it loses in A. This increases its profit. The optimal position for the firm is where marginal revenue is equalised in the two markets. In Figure 20.5 the firm sells qA in market A at the higher price of PA. In market B sales increase to qB with price falling to PB. Notice that in both situations the amounts sold in the two submarkets sum to Q*. The consumers in market B seem to do quite well by this practice, as they can now consume more of the good. Indeed, it is possible that with no discrimination the price would be so high that they would not be able to consume the good at all. In 2016, the UK’s Competition and Market Authority reported on an investigation of the UK energy market. One of its findings was that there was wide variation in the prices paid by domestic customers for energy, although electricity and gas are homogeneous products. Potentially, most customers could have made savings by switching suppliers, tariffs or payment methods. Indeed, average potential gains from switching were equivalent to more than 20% of customers’ bills. A number of remedies were recommended to address this situation. 303 308275_C20_CAM_IASAL ECO_292_309.indd 303 17/02/21 5:47 PM In which of the following products might price discrimination be possible? Explain your answers. a Hairdressing b Peak and off-peak rail travel c d e f Apples Air tickets Newspapers Plastic surgery SUMMARY: PRICE DISCRIMINATION » In some markets a monopolist may be able to » Under first-degree price discrimination, the firm is engage in price discrimination by selling its product at different prices to different consumers or groups of consumers. » This enables the firm to increase its profits by absorbing some or all of the consumer surplus. able to charge a different price to each customer and absorb all of the consumer surplus. » The firm can practise price discrimination only where it has market power, where consumers have differing elasticities of demand for the product, and where consumers have limited ability to resell the product. 20.6 Other pricing policies There are other pricing policies that a firm may adopt in markets where it has some influence over price, as in oligopoly or monopoly. Some of these are designed to help a firm to maintain its market position by making it more difficult for other firms to enter the market. Limit pricing KEY TERM limit price: the highest price that an existing firm can set without enabling new firms to enter the market and make a profit One such strategy is limit pricing. This assumes that the incumbent firm has some sort of cost advantage over potential entrants – for example, economies of scale. Figure 20.6 shows a firm facing a downward-sloping demand curve, and thus having some influence over the price of its product. If the firm is maximising profits, it is setting output at Q0 and price at P0. As average revenue is comfortably above average cost at this price, the firm is making healthy supernormal profits. Price A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 20 EXERCISE 20.4 MC AC P0 P2 MR Q1 AR (= D) Q0 Q0 + Q1 Output ▲ Figure 20.6 Limit pricing Suppose that the natural barriers to entry in this industry are weak. The supernormal profits will be attractive to potential entrants. Given the cost conditions, the incumbent firm is enjoying the benefit of economies of scale, although producing below the minimum efficient scale. If a new firm joins the market, producing on a relatively small scale, say at Q1, the impact on the market can be analysed as follows. The immediate effect is on price, as now the amount Q0 + Q1 is being produced, pushing price down to P2. The new firm (producing Q1) is just covering average cost, so is making normal profits and feeling justified in having joined the market. The original firm is still making supernormal 304 308275_C20_CAM_IASAL ECO_292_309.indd 304 17/02/21 5:47 PM profits, but at a lower level than before. The entry of the new firm has competed away part of the original firm’s supernormal profits. Test yourself 20.14 Explain why setting a price equal to average cost could be a rational strategy. So, by setting a price below the profit-maximising level, the original firm is able to maintain its market position in the longer run. This could be a reason for avoiding making too high a level of supernormal profits in the short run, in order to make profits in the longer term. Notice that such a strategy need not be carried out by a monopolist, but could also occur in an oligopoly, where existing firms may jointly seek to protect their market against potential entry. Predatory pricing KEY TERM predatory pricing: an anti-competitive strategy in which a firm sets price below average variable cost in an attempt to force a rival or rivals out of the market and achieve market dominance STUDY TIP Be careful to distinguish between limit pricing and predatory pricing. Limit pricing is used as a barrier to entry, making it more difficult for a new firm to join an industry. However, the limit price is set at a level that still allows the incumbent firm(s) to make profits. Predatory pricing is a more aggressive strategy by which a firm is prepared to set price below SAVC, taking losses as a result. The hope is to force competitors out of business, leaving the predatory firm with a dominant position in the market. There is an aggressive strategy that has sometimes been used by firms wishing to deter entry into their market, known as predatory pricing. This is illegal in many countries, including the UK and USA. It should be noted that, in order to declare an action illegal, it is necessary to define that action very carefully – otherwise it will not be possible to prove the case in the courts. In the case of predatory pricing, the legal definition is based on economic analysis. 20 20 The growth and objectives of firms One way in which the firm could have guarded against entry is by charging a lower price than P0 to begin with. For example, if it had set output at Q0 + Q1 and price at P2, then a new entrant joining the market would have pushed the price down to a level below P2, and without the benefit of economies of scale would have made losses and exited the market. In any case, if the existing firm has been in the market for some time, it will have gone through a process of learning by doing, and therefore will have a lower average cost curve than the potential entrant. This makes it more likely that limit pricing can be used. Remember that if a firm fails to cover average variable costs, its strategy should be to close down immediately, as it would be better off doing so. The courts have backed this theory, and state that a pricing strategy should be interpreted as being predatory if the price is set below average variable costs, as the only motive for remaining in business while making such losses must be to drive competitors out of business and achieve market dominance. This is known as the Areeda–Turner principle (after the case in which it was first argued in the USA). On the face of it, consumers have much to gain from such strategies through the resulting lower prices. However, a predator that is successful in driving out the opposition is likely to recoup its losses by putting prices back up to profit-maximising levels thereafter, so the benefit to consumers is short lived. In some cases, the very threat of predatory pricing may be sufficient to deter entry by new firms, if the threat is a credible one. In other words, the existing firms need to convince potential entrants that they, the existing firms, will find it in their best interests to fight a price war, otherwise the entrants will not believe the threat. The existing firms could do this by making it known that they have surplus capacity, so that they would be able to increase output very quickly in order to drive down the price. Whether entry will be deterred by such means may depend in part on the characteristics of the potential entrant. After all, a new firm may reckon that if the existing firm finds it worth sacrificing profits in the short run, the rewards of dominating the market must be worth fighting for. It may therefore decide to sacrifice short-term profit in order to enter the market – especially if it is diversifying from other markets and has resources at its disposal. The winner will then be the firm that can last the longest; but, clearly, this is potentially very damaging for all concerned. EXERCISE 20.5 Discuss the extent to which consumers benefit from a price war. 305 308275_C20_CAM_IASAL ECO_292_309.indd 305 17/02/21 5:47 PM KEY TERM A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY price leadership: a form of tacit collusion that allows firms in a market to synchronise their prices without formally communicating STUDY TIP Notice the importance of firms’ perceptions in this analysis. Firms take decisions based on their perceptions of their own position in the market, and on their expectations of how rival firms will react. This is a key feature of oligopoly markets – and of economists’ models that attempt to explain firms’ behaviour. LEARNING LINK The relationship between a firm’s revenues and the price elasticity of demand was first explained in Chapter 3: see especially Table 3.1 on page 44. Firms in an oligopoly face the dilemma that although they could benefit from collusion with other firms in the market, forming a cartel is illegal. One way in which tacit collusion may happen is through some form of price leadership. If one firm is a dominant producer in a market, then it may take the lead in setting the price, with the other firms following its example. It has been suggested that the OPEC cartel operated according to this model in some periods, with Saudi Arabia acting as the dominant country. An alternative is barometric price leadership, in which one firm tries out a price increase and then waits to see whether other firms follow. If they do, a new higher price has been reached without the need for overt discussions between the firms. On the other hand, if the other firms do not feel the time is right for the change, they will keep their prices steady and the first firm will drop back into line or else lose market share. The initiating firm need not be the same one in each round. It has been argued that the domestic air travel market in the USA has operated in this way on some internal routes. The practice is facilitated by the ease with which prices can be checked via computerised ticketing systems, so that each firm knows what the other firms are doing. The frequency of anti-cartel cases brought by regulators in recent years suggests that firms continue to be tempted by the gains from collusion. The operation of a cartel is now a criminal act in the UK, as it has been in the USA for some time. The kinked demand curve model One model of oligopoly revolves around how a firm perceives its demand curve. This is called the kinked demand curve model, and was developed by Paul Sweezy in the USA in the 1930s. In this model, a firm’s pricing policy is influenced by its perceptions of how rival firms will react to a change in price, given the relationship between a firm’s revenues and its price elasticity of demand. The model relates to an oligopoly in which firms try to anticipate the reactions of rivals to their actions. One problem that arises is that a firm cannot readily observe its demand curve with any degree of certainty, so it must form expectations about how consumers will react to a price change. Figure 20.7 shows how this works. Suppose the price is currently set at P*; the firm is selling Q* and is trying to decide whether to alter the price. The problem is that there is only one point on the demand curve that can be observed: that is, when the price is P*, the firm sells Q*. Price 20 Price leadership Dcop MC1 P* AC1 A Dig AC* Supernormal profits B 0 dd MR Q* Quantity Figure 20.7 The kinked demand curve However, the firm is aware that the degree of sensitivity to its price change will depend on whether or not the other firms in the market will follow its lead. In other words, if its rivals ignore the firm’s price change, there will be more sensitivity to this change than if they all follow suit. 306 308275_C20_CAM_IASAL ECO_292_309.indd 306 17/02/21 5:47 PM Figure 20.7 shows the two extreme possibilities for the demand curve which the firm perceives that it faces. If other firms ignore its action, Dig will be the relevant demand curve, which is relatively elastic. On the other hand, if the other firms copy the firm’s moves, Dcop will be the relevant demand curve. Test yourself 20.15 KEY TERM price rigidity: a situation that arises in the kinked demand curve model, where firms in a market avoid changing the price of their product because of the expected response of rival firms, which will lead to a fall in revenue On the other hand, a price reduction takes the firm into the relatively inelastic part of the demand curve, where it can expect to experience a fall in revenue. This is because such a move is likely to be seen by the rivals as threatening, and they are likely to copy in order to preserve their market positions. For a price decrease, then, Dcop is relevant. Putting these together, the firm perceives that it faces a kinked demand curve (dd). If the firm faces cost curves MC1 and AC1, the shaded area shows the supernormal profit being made at the profit-maximising level of output. Notice that the marginal revenue curve has a break in it at the kink. This means that even if the firm’s cost curves shift up or down, as long as the marginal cost curve cuts marginal revenue between points A and B, the firm will continue to maximise profit at Q* output. The model predicts that if the firm perceives its demand curve to be of this shape, it has a strong incentive to do nothing, even in the face of changes in costs. However, it all depends on the firm’s perceptions. If all firms perceive things in the same way, there will tend to be price rigidity. In other words, no single firm will want to change its price because of the consequences of so doing. Price will tend to remain constant. 20 The growth and objectives of firms In the kinked demand curve model, is the price prevailing in the market likely to be volatile? The question then is: under what conditions will the other firms copy the price change, and when will they not? The firm may imagine that if it raises its price, there is little likelihood that its rivals will copy. By raising its price, the firm faces relatively elastic demand for its product, so its total revenue will fall. This is a non-threatening move that gives market share to the other firms. So for a price increase, Dig is the relevant section. 20 If there is a general increase in costs that affects all producers, this may affect the firm’s perception of rival reaction, and thus encourage it to raise price. If other firms are reading the market in the same way, they are likely to follow suit. Notice that this model does not explain how the price reaches P* in the first place. If firms are so keen to avoid competing on price, they may turn to non-price competition as a way of maintaining or increasing their market share. The kinked demand curve model is just one way of trying to explain how firms may behave in an oligopoly, and goes some way towards explaining why firms may be keen to engage in non-price competition. However, it is not the only model to explore how firms act strategically, nor is it inevitable that firms in an oligopoly will always act competitively. They may instead perceive that it is in their best interest to work together in the market. SUMMARY: OTHER PRICING POLICIES » There are many pricing rules that a firm may » Firms cannot collude by setting up a cartel as choose to adopt, depending on the objectives it wishes to achieve. » Limit pricing occurs when a firm or firms choose to set price below the profit-maximising level in order to prevent entry. The limit price is the highest price that an existing firm can set without allowing entry. » Predatory pricing is an extreme strategy that forces all firms to endure losses. It is normally invoked in an attempt to eliminate a competitor, and is illegal in many countries. this is illegal in many countries. Firms may thus look for covert ways of colluding in a market: for example, through some form of price leadership. » The kinked demand curve model argues that firms’ perceptions of the demand curve for their products are based on their views about whether or not rival firms will react to their own pricesetting actions. » The model suggests that price is likely to remain stable over a wide range of market conditions. 307 308275_C20_CAM_IASAL ECO_292_309.indd 307 17/02/21 5:47 PM A LEVEL PART 7 THE PRICE SYSTEM AND THE MICROECONOMY 20 END OF CHAPTER QUESTIONS Multiple choice 1 The managers of a company are considering merging with another company in a period of boom because they are concerned the market is becoming less fragmented and competition is reduced. Which of the following reasons for integration are they pursuing? A to prevent being taken over by a larger rival B to achieve economies of scales C to maximise growth D to increase market share 2 The dominant firm price leadership model assumes all other firms in the industry: A believe the price leader can best decide on the prices in the industry B have the same cost structure as the price leader C form a cartel D are price takers Data response 1 Read the following extract and then answer the questions that follow. Company objectives and pricing: the PSA-FCA merger and pricing in coach travel The French motor manufacturer PSA Group and Fiat Chrysler Automobiles (FCA) have officially signed a deal for a full merger, creating the world’s fourth largest car manufacturer with combined revenues of US$180 billion. The two firms say the newly formed public limited company will create ‘leadership, resources and scale to be at the forefront of a new era of sustainable mobility’. PSA-FCA will focus on its core markets of Europe, North America and Latin America – but says it will ‘reshape the strategy in other regions’. Both firms have struggled to gain a foothold in the vital Chinese market in recent years and view the merger as their chance to correct this while maximising shareholder return as they move forward. The PSA-FCA group aims to retain its commitment to the economic development of the regions in which it operates. It selects suppliers that meet strict social and environmental standards and supports the least privileged members of society through its Corporate Foundation, which funds mobilitybased inclusion and access to education. The merger will allow for increased investment efficiency. The group is in the process of launching several electric vehicles including the Peugeot e-208 and an electric Fiat 500. For some an alternative to travel by car is travel by coach. In many countries, coach travel is a competitive market, and typically the price of a ticket will depend on age, when the journey is being made and how far in advance a booking is made. A typical set of discounted fare types might include the following: » Off-peak prices – lower rates than peak times. » Senior citizen and student fare – 1/3 reduction on standard fare prices. a Discuss the possible effects of a merger between PSA and FCA on consumers who are planning the purchase of an electric car. b Do you agree with the view that the principal–agent problem should not be a source of concern for PSA-FCA at this time? c Explain how the sense of corporate social responsibility demonstrated in the extract might influence the objectives of firms such as PSA-FCA. d Explain which form of price discrimination there is evidence of in the extract. 308 308275_C20_CAM_IASAL ECO_292_309.indd 308 17/02/21 5:47 PM Essay style 2 Almost the whole of today’s standard theory of the firm is derived from neoclassical models developed during the early part of the twentieth century that assume the objective of profit maximisation. To what extent do you agree that profit maximisation will always be the objective of a firm? 20 CASE STUDY 20 The growth and objectives of firms Coke versus Pepsi in India In the mid-2000s it was reported that Coca-Cola and PepsiCo were fighting to increase their sales in India. A pesticide scare in the previous year had caused sales to plummet, and the two firms were anxious to recover the situation. The tactics they adopted were to reduce the size of the bottles for sale in order to appeal to consumers with low incomes, to cut prices, to increase the availability of the products in rural areas, and to encourage more at-home consumption in urban areas. It was seen that there was plenty of scope for growth in the market, as India showed one of the lowest average levels of consumption of fizzy drinks in the world, and was substantially below the Asian average. This may partly reflect the way that children have been discouraged from drinking colas by their teachers at school. The prices being charged were rated as being the world’s lowest prices for cola as the two firms battled to increase their market shares. However, in consequence the firms faced reductions in their profit margins, and continued to face competition from local producers. The logistics of supplying such a geographically large and diverse region, given the need to ensure refrigeration, added significantly to costs. Attempts were made to counter this by reducing the weight of the bottles and by making use of cheap transport in the form of bullock carts and cycle rickshaws in the rural areas. Market analysts said that soft-drink companies should be able to improve profits, but executives remained bent on boosting volumes. The vicepresident of Coca-Cola marketing in India was quoted as saying that ‘any affordability strategy will put pressure on margins, but it is critical to build the market’. ▲ Pepsi or Coca-Cola? The pesticide issue proved to be a long-lasting controversy, and the Kerala government filed a criminal complaint against PepsiCo over its environmental impact, although this was rejected by the Supreme Court of India in 2010. Indeed, the US Department of State named PepsiCo as one of the 12 multinationals that displayed ‘the most impressive corporate social responsibility credentials in emerging markets’. Follow-up questions a Given the statements in the passage, do you think that Coca-Cola and PepsiCo were trying to maximise short-run profits? b Explain your answer to (a) and comment on what the firms were trying to achieve by their strategies. c Identify ways in which the firms were seeking to influence their costs. d How do you think PepsiCo’s record on corporate social responsibility will have affected its position in the market? e Discuss what you think the firms would want to achieve in the long run. Go online at hoddereducation.com/cambridgeextras for another case study for Chapter 20. 309 308275_C20_CAM_IASAL ECO_292_309.indd 309 18/03/21 3:01 PM A LEVEL PART 8 Government microeconomic intervention A LEVEL PART 8 GOVERNMENT MICROECONOMIC INTERVENTION 21 Government policies to achieve efficient resource allocation and correct market failure What this chapter covers ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ taxes and subsidies indirect taxes – and ad valorem tax a tax on pollution direct controls production quotas, prohibitions and licences nationalisation, privatisation, regulation and deregulation ★ ★ ★ ★ ★ direct provision by government pollution permits property rights and information provision behavioural insights and nudge theory government failure Markets do not always deliver the best outcome for society – for example, where marginal social benefit is not equal to marginal social cost, or where price is not set equal to marginal cost. This chapter discusses the effectiveness of policies available to government to achieve efficient resource allocation and to correct market failure. 21.1 Taxes and subsidies Taxation LEARNING LINK The effect of direct taxes on the distribution of income is discussed in Chapter 22; the role of taxes in the context of fiscal policy is discussed in Chapter 28. Governments need to raise funds to finance the expenditure that they undertake, and the imposition of taxes is a way of raising revenue. One way of doing this is through expenditure taxes such as value added tax (VAT), which is levied on a wide range of goods and services. Such taxes levied on goods are known as indirect taxes, in contrast to direct taxes (such as income tax), which are charged on the basis of income received by economic agents. In general, direct taxes are applied at the economy-wide level, rather than being intended to influence particular markets. An indirect tax Chapter 5 explained the effects of a specific indirect tax – a fixed rate tax that is set at a constant rate for each unit of a good that is purchased. The way in which the burden of such a tax is shared between buyers and sellers (the incidence of the tax) was also discussed. LEARNING LINK KEY TERM ad valorem tax: a tax on expenditure imposed as a percentage of the selling price You may find it helpful to revisit this discussion in Chapter 5, which you will find on pages 75–76. Not all indirect taxes work like this. An alternative way of imposing an indirect tax is by setting the tax at a percentage of the selling price. This is known as an ad valorem tax. 310 308275_C21_CAM_IASAL ECO_310_328.indd 310 17/02/21 8:58 PM An ad valorem tax Supply plus tax Supply P1 P0 Demand Q1 Q0 Packets of cigarettes per period ▲ Figure 21.1 The effects of an ad valorem tax on cigarettes Without the tax, the equilibrium for the market occurs at quantity Q0 and price P0. Imposing the tax causes the price to increase to P1. STUDY TIP Notice the difference between a specific tax, in which the supply curve shifts in parallel to the original curve, and an ad valorem tax, where the slope of the supply curve steepens with the imposition of the tax. There are several reasons why the government might want to discourage smoking. There is the demerit good argument, which suggests that individuals may take poor decisions about smoking cigarettes. However, there are also externality effects. Smoking imposes costs on others through passive smoking. Furthermore, smokers require more medical and hospital treatment as their health declines, taking up scarce resources in the health sector. An important question is whether this is an effective approach to discouraging smoking. The problem is that tobacco is addictive – once someone starts smoking, they will continue, so their demand for cigarettes will tend to be highly inelastic. The incidence of the tax will therefore fall primarily on the consumers. In addition, if demand is highly inelastic, the tax will not have much impact on behaviour, so it will not have the desired effect of reducing tobacco consumption. 21 21 Government policies to achieve efficient resource allocation and correct market failure Price The effect of an ad valorem tax is similar to the impact of a specific tax. It is analysed in the same way – through shifting the position of the supply curve, but now the supply curve steepens, as the monetary size of the tax is higher at higher prices. Figure 21.1 shows the situation if an ad valorem tax is imposed on the sale of cigarettes in an attempt to discourage the consumption of this demerit good. A tax on pollution A tax can also be used to tackle a negative production externality such as pollution. Figure 21.2 illustrates the situation. Suppose that firms in the market for chemicals use a production process that emits toxic fumes, thereby imposing costs on society that the firms themselves do not face. In other words, the marginal private costs faced by these firms are less than the marginal social costs that are inflicted on society. Firms in this market will choose to produce up to point Q1 and charge a price of P1 to consumers. At this point, marginal social benefit is below the marginal cost of producing the chemicals, so it can be claimed that ‘too much’ of the product is being produced – that society would be better off if production were at Q*, with a price charged at P*. 311 308275_C21_CAM_IASAL ECO_310_328.indd 311 17/02/21 5:25 PM Costs, benefits 21 MSC MPC P* Pollution tax D (MSB) 0 Q* Q1 Quantity of chemicals per period ▲ Figure 21.2 Pollution Note that this optimum position is not characterised by zero pollution. In other words, from society’s point of view it pays to abate pollution only up to the level where the marginal benefit of reducing pollution is matched by the marginal cost of doing so. Reducing pollution to zero would be too costly. KEY TERM polluter pays principle: an argument that a firm causing pollution should be charged the full external cost that they inflict on society How can society reach the optimum output of chemicals at Q*? The polluter pays principle argues that polluters should face the full external costs caused by their actions. One approach would be to impose a tax on firms in line with this principle. In Figure 21.2, if firms were required to pay a tax equivalent to the vertical distance between marginal private cost (MPC) and marginal social cost (MSC), they would choose to produce at Q*, paying a tax equal to the green line on the figure. An alternative way of looking at this question is via a diagram showing the marginal benefit and marginal cost of emissions reduction. In Figure 21.3, MB represents the marginal social benefits from reducing emissions of some pollutant and MC is the marginal costs of reducing emissions. The optimum amount of reduction is found where marginal benefit equals marginal cost, at e*. Up to this point, the marginal benefit to society of reducing emissions exceeds the marginal cost of the reduction, so it is in the interest of society to reduce pollution. However, beyond that point the marginal cost of reducing the amount of pollution exceeds the benefits that accrue, so society will be worse off. Setting a tax equal to t* in Figure 21.3 will induce firms to undertake the appropriate amount of emission reduction. Costs, benefits A LEVEL PART 8 GOVERNMENT MICROECONOMIC INTERVENTION P1 MC t* MB 0 e* Emission reduction ▲ Figure 21.3 Reducing the emission of toxic fumes 312 308275_C21_CAM_IASAL ECO_310_328.indd 312 17/02/21 5:25 PM This is not the only way of reaching the objective, however. Figure 21.3 suggests that there is another possibility – namely, to impose environmental standards, and to prohibit emissions beyond e*. This amounts to controlling quantity rather than price; and, if the government has full information about marginal costs and marginal benefits, the two policies will produce the equivalent result. The marginal social benefits of reducing pollution cannot be measured with great precision, for many reasons. It may be argued that there are significant gains to be made in terms of improved health and lower death rates if pollution can be reduced, but quantifying this is not straightforward. Even if it were possible to evaluate the saving in resources that would need to be devoted to future medical care resulting from the pollution, there are other considerations: quantification of the direct improvements to quality of life; whether or not to take international effects into account when formulating domestic policy; and the appropriate discount rate for evaluating benefits that will be received in the future. Moreover, the environmentalist and the industrialist may well arrive at different evaluations of the benefits of pollution control, reflecting their different viewpoints. Test yourself 21.1 What will be the effect if the government overestimates the size of the tax needed to discourage pollution? LEARNING LINK Subsidies were discussed in Chapter 5: in particular, look back at Figure 5.3 on page 76. 21 Government policies to achieve efficient resource allocation and correct market failure Either of the approaches outlined above will be effective – if the authorities have full information about the marginal costs and benefits. But how likely is this? There are many problems with this proviso. The measurement of both marginal benefits and marginal costs is fraught with difficulties. 21 ▲ How can we measure the benefits of controlling air pollution? The measurement of costs may also be problematic. For example, it is likely that there will be differences in efficiency between firms. Those using modern technology may face lower costs than those using relatively old capital equipment. Do the authorities try to set a tax that is specific to each firm to take such differences into account? If they do not, but instead set a flat-rate tax, then the incentives may be inappropriate. This would mean that a firm using modern technology would face the same tax as one using old capital. The firm using new capital would then tend to produce too little output relative to those using older, less efficient capital. A subsidy Subsidies are used to encourage producers to increase their output of particular goods. A government may wish to do this if it regards certain products as being necessary for strategic reasons, or because there is some form of market failure that results in a product being undersupplied. 313 308275_C21_CAM_IASAL ECO_310_328.indd 313 17/02/21 5:25 PM How does a subsidy address market failure? A museum may be seen by government as being a merit good, so a subsidy may be used to encourage more people to visit a museum or art gallery. Figure 21.4 shows how such a subsidy might be used to affect the quantity of museum services provided. Demand (MPB) again shows the demand for museum services from the public, and supply is given by S. Marginal social benefit (MSB) is what the authorities perceive to be the true value of museum services, but we assume there is no production externality, so supply is equal to marginal social cost. The free-market equilibrium position is at Q0, where MPB = S. However, the government believes that Q* is the socially optimum position, where MSC = S. There is a deadweight loss in this situation given by the area ABC. LEARNING LINK This is an example of a positive consumption externality, which is explained in Chapter 16 (see page 221). STUDY TIP Remember that if you are asked to discuss an indirect tax or a subsidy in the exam, the effect is to shift the supply curve to the left/ upwards (for a tax) or to the right/downwards (for a subsidy). Test yourself 21.2 If demand for a good is relatively inelastic, will a subsidy have a lesser or greater effect on quantity traded? If the government could intervene in such a way as to achieve the socially optimum output of Q*, then this deadweight loss could be avoided. By providing a subsidy, the supply curve is shifted to S with subsidy, and consumers will choose to demand the optimum quantity at the subsidised price P1. Price A LEVEL PART 8 GOVERNMENT MICROECONOMIC INTERVENTION 21 S S with subsidy A B D P0 C P1 E Subsidy per unit 0 MSB MPB Q0 Q* Quantity per period ▲ Figure 21.4 Subsidising museums Again, because the price falls by less than the amount of the subsidy, the benefits of the subsidy are shared between buyers and sellers, depending on the elasticity of demand. Consumers benefit from paying a lower price, whereas firms receive the subsidy. The downside of this is that the government has to meet the cost of the subsidy, which is represented by the area DBEP1. This means that it is not clear whether there will be a net welfare gain as a result of the subsidy. The deadweight loss has been avoided, but the government will need to raise the funds to pay the subsidy, which may involve raising taxes or reducing expenditure elsewhere in the economy. If the aim of the subsidy is to increase production, it is only partially successful – the degree of success also depends on the elasticity of demand. STUDY TIP Notice from this that a net welfare gain is not necessarily the exact opposite of a deadweight loss, as markets in the economy are interrelated, so that intervention in one market may have unintended effects on other markets. SUMMARY: TAXES AND SUBSIDIES »Taxes and subsidies may be used to correct some forms of market failure. » Indirect taxes may be used in the case of demerit goods. » Subsidies can help to encourage higher demand for merit goods. 314 308275_C21_CAM_IASAL ECO_310_328.indd 314 17/02/21 5:25 PM 21.2 Direct controls Although taxes and subsidies are one way in which a government may attempt to correct market failure, there may be other situations in which intervention takes the form of direct controls on prices, or the setting of production quotas or licences. Indeed, a government may sometimes decide to prohibit the production of some goods altogether. 21 Price controls Chapter 5 discussed the examples of policies for a minimum wage (see page 77) and for rent controls (see page 78); the effect of a minimum wage is further discussed in Chapter 23. Test yourself 21.3 How would the market for rice be affected if the government set the price at which it can be sold below the market equilibrium level? Controlling prices may be introduced if firms are seen to be exploiting their market power. Will such policies be effective in tackling market failure? If the authorities do choose to impose direct control of prices, the inevitable result is that the market concerned will be held in a disequilibrium position. In the case of a minimum wage, the result could be to increase the level of unemployment; in the case of rent controls, the result could be that the supply of rental accommodation will be reduced. Neither of these outcomes is what is intended. A buffer stock scheme can be used to ensure that agricultural producers receive a minimum price for their products (see page 79). In some less developed countries, governments have been tempted to control prices. Most governments are based in urban areas, and a government may wish to keep the urban population contented, especially if the government knows that its situation is insecure. One way in which this may be achieved is by controlling food prices in the urban areas, ensuring that people there can get food supplies. The problem with this approach is that if farmers do not receive a fair price for their produce, they will not have the incentive to supply it, or to improve their farming methods. This will then have long-term damaging effects on the agricultural sector. Pakistan is one country that has intervened to try to control prices of essential foodstuffs. Production quotas and licences Instead of controlling through price, another approach would be to control quantity. The discussion of pollution earlier in this chapter noted the possibility of controlling pollution by limiting emissions of toxic substances. This could be administratively costly, because it is difficult to be sure about the appropriate level of emissions to be permitted, not to mention the problem of monitoring whether firms are following the rules. Price Production quotas are one way of approaching quantity control. Figure 21.5 shows how a production quota might work. A Quota Supply B Pq P* 21 Government policies to achieve efficient resource allocation and correct market failure LEARNING LINK C E F Demand 0 Qq Q* Quantity ▲ Figure 21.5 A production quota 315 308275_C21_CAM_IASAL ECO_310_328.indd 315 17/02/21 5:25 PM A LEVEL PART 8 GOVERNMENT MICROECONOMIC INTERVENTION 21 LEARNING LINK The operation of import quotas was explained in Chapter 12. Be careful not to confuse the two things, which are not the same thing. Assume this is a competitive market, and that in equilibrium the market would settle with output Q* and price P*. If the government were to impose a quota of Qq, the equilibrium price would rise to Pq. This would have several effects. Consumer surplus would be reduced from ACP* to ABPq. Producer surplus would also change from 0P*C to 0PqBF. For producers, they gain the area PqBEP*, which was previously part of consumer surplus. However, they lose the area ECF. Notice also that the area BCF is a deadweight loss. Another way in which it is possible to affect production by firms is through a licensing arrangement. The authorities can choose to permit firms to operate in a particular market only if they hold a licence. The licence can then specify the conditions under which production can take place. For example, the government may impose quality or environmental conditions, or insist that prices do not rise by more than inflation, perhaps with some allowance being made for productivity improvements. In this way, the market can operate, but within a controlled framework. An example might be in water supply, where the authorities specify the standards to which firms operate to ensure that the supply of water can be secured and its quality assured. It may also be that the authorities wish to ensure that steps are taken to conserve the environment. Prohibition KEY TERM prohibition: an attempt to prevent the consumption of a good by declaring it illegal There may be some goods that a government wishes to prohibit entirely – in other words, a form of extreme demerit good. Direct action to prohibit the sale of a good may have some unintended effects. Consider the example of offensive items, such as certain types of knives. It can be argued that such items represent a danger to the public and have no legal uses. One response to this issue is to ban the sale of such goods – a policy known as prohibition. One result of such prohibition may be an increase in smuggling activity. It may also be likely that those individuals who would want to own such offensive items will instead obtain knives that are designed for legitimate purposes, such as chef’s knives. Prohibition may be effective in reducing the supply of these offensive items but will not necessarily have a major impact on the outcomes in terms of crime. SUMMARY: DIRECT CONTROLS » There are situations in which the government may decide to control prices. » The downside of this is that price controls force a market to operate in disequilibrium. » Imposing a production quota also results in a market being out of equilibrium and results in a deadweight welfare loss. » Licensing allows the authorities to influence production in a market – for example, by specifying quality standards or ensuring productivity improvements. » For an extreme demerit good, a government may prohibit production or sale of a good, but this may have unintended effects. 21.3 Nationalisation, privatisation, regulation and deregulation Natural monopolies pose particular problems with regard to allocative efficiency. Figure 21.6 involves an industry with substantial economies of scale relative to market demand – indeed, the minimum efficient scale is beyond the market demand curve. (In other words, long-run average cost is still falling beyond market demand.) 316 308275_C21_CAM_IASAL ECO_310_328.indd 316 18/03/21 10:35 AM 21 Pm AR (= D) LAC AC* P* LMC MR Qm Q* Output ▲ Figure 21.6 A natural monopoly This market is almost bound to end up as a monopoly because the largest firm is always able to dominate the market and undercut smaller competitors, as it has a natural cost advantage over possible rivals. If the monopoly chooses to maximise profits, it will set marginal revenue equal to marginal cost, choose output Qm and set price at Pm. Such industries tend to have large fixed costs relative to marginal costs. Railway systems, water or gas supply and electricity generation are all examples of natural monopolies. The key problem is that if such firms were forced to set a price equal to marginal cost, they would make a loss. If the firm in Figure 21.6 were required to set price equal to marginal cost (i.e. at P*) then it would not be viable: average cost would be AC*, with losses represented by the shaded area on the diagram. Nationalisation KEY TERM nationalisation: where a privately owned firm or industry is taken into public ownership Test yourself 21.4 Why would a government not regard it as appropriate for a nationalised industry to make supernormal profits? LEARNING LINK The principal– agent problem was explained in Chapter 20. One response to this situation is to nationalise the industry (i.e. take it into state ownership), since no private sector firm would be prepared to operate at a loss, and the government would not allow firms running such natural monopolies to act as profit-maximising monopolists making supernormal profits. In order to prevent the losses from becoming too substantial, many utilities such as gas and electricity supply adopted a pricing system known as a two-part tariff system, under which all consumers paid a monthly charge for being connected to the supply, and on top of that a variable amount based on usage. In terms of Figure 21.6, the connection charge would cover the difference between AC* and P*, spread across all consumers, and the variable charge would reflect marginal cost. However, this sort of system has been heavily criticised. In particular, it has been argued that the managers of the nationalised industries were insufficiently accountable. The situation could be regarded as an extreme form of the principal– agent problem, in which the consumers (the principals) had very little control over the actions of the managers (their agents), a situation leading to considerable X-inefficiency and waste. 21 Government policies to achieve efficient resource allocation and correct market failure The notion of a natural monopoly was first introduced in Chapter 18 as part of the discussion of monopoly markets. Price LEARNING LINK Nationalisation has been much less used in the twenty-first century in high-income countries, but there have been some high-profile examples. These have occurred when a government has chosen to intervene to bail out failing firms. The bailout of a number of banks in many countries during the financial crisis in the late 2000s is one prominent example. The existence of natural monopoly was a key reason for nationalisation in many countries. However, for some countries such as India state-ownership was seen as a way of directing resources in order to achieve economic growth. 317 308275_C21_CAM_IASAL ECO_310_328.indd 317 17/02/21 5:25 PM A LEVEL PART 8 GOVERNMENT MICROECONOMIC INTERVENTION 21 Privatisation KEY TERM privatisation: where an enterprise in public ownership is returned to private ownership Test yourself 21.5 Why would competition flourish more readily in telecommunications than in some other natural monopolies? Privatisation is the transfer of nationalised industries into private ownership, and has often been a response to the apparent inefficiency of many nationalised or state-owned enterprises. This was especially the case where the sector being privatised was a natural monopoly, where it was perceived that managers had faced low incentives to become efficient. One central argument for privatisation was that this would force managers to be accountable to their shareholders, which would encourage an increase in efficiency. In the UK during the 1980s, there was widespread privatisation, as there was in other Western European countries. This did not remove the original problem: that these industries were natural monopolies. Therefore, wherever possible, privatisation was also accompanied by measures to encourage competition, which was seen as an even better way to ensure efficiency improvements. This proved to be more feasible in some industries than in others because of the nature of economies of scale – there is little to be gained by requiring that there be several firms in a market where the economies of scale can be reaped only by one large firm. However, the changing technology in some of the industries did allow some competition to be encouraged, especially in telecommunications. The most recent example in the UK was that of Royal Mail, which was privatised in October 2013, becoming a quoted company on the London Stock Exchange. The company has a ‘Universal Service Obligation’, under which it must continue to provide 6-days a week, one price goes anywhere postal service. It delivers to 30 million addresses in the UK and is also subject to control on prices. These obligations are subject to regulation by Ofcom. Privatisation has not been confined to Western Europe, but it has taken a different form in transition economies, where there was a need to move away from central planning and allow market forces to play a greater role in allocating resources. In developing countries there has also been privatisation, again in a somewhat different form. The aims of privatisation tend to be similar across different economies. There are three key motivations: » to improve the performance of natural monopolies » to encourage economic growth » to raise revenue for the government The first two of these reflect a belief that firms in the private sector would have stronger incentives to look for higher efficiency, especially where there was competition in the market. Raising revenue by selling off state-owned enterprises was often a secondary motivation, but may have been an influence in some situations. The effectiveness of privatisation depends on the feasibility of competition and may also reflect whether the enterprise was sold to domestic or foreign firms. Where an enterprise is taken over by a foreign firm with experience of operating in the relevant market, this may be beneficial, especially in the context of a developing economy. Also significant is the extent to which the market can be monitored or regulated after privatisation. Regulation Test yourself 21.6 Explain why regulation is important after privatisation of a stateowned enterprise. In many markets, it was seen as crucial that the newly privatised enterprises should be regulated to ensure that the desired efficiency improvements would be made. The problems of using regulation differ between countries. In the UK and other Western European economies, the institutional structure allowed close monitoring. In transition and developing economies, there were challenges to be faced in ensuring monitoring and regulation. In Europe, regulation was seen as important in the case of natural monopoly, especially in sectors where it was not possible or feasible, to encourage competition. In the case of the UK, regulatory bodies focused on price, and the key control method was only to allow price increases each year at a rate that was a set amount below changes in the retail price index (RPI − X). The idea was that it would force companies to look for productivity gains to eliminate the inefficiency that had built 318 308275_C21_CAM_IASAL ECO_310_328.indd 318 17/02/21 9:00 PM up. The X refers to the amount of productivity gain that the regulator believed could be achieved, expressed in terms of the change in average costs. For example, if the regulator believed that it was possible to achieve productivity gains of 5% per year, and if the RPI was increasing at a rate of 10% per year, then the maximum price increase that would be allowed in a year would be 10% − 5% = 5%. An alternative method of regulation would be to place a limit on the rate of return the firm is permitted to make, thereby preventing it from making supernormal profits. This too may affect the incentive mechanism: the firm may not feel the need to be as efficient as possible, or may fritter away some of the profits in managerial perks to avoid declaring too high a rate of return. Price regulation came under criticism as it was perceived that there was too strong a focus on cost-saving rather than output delivery, and that companies were looking for static rather than dynamic efficiency. There was also increasing concern about environmental issues, and the quality of output that was being produced. Some less developed countries have faced issues in trying to monitor and regulate privatised industries because of a lack of rigorous institutions and underdeveloped stock markets. KEY TERM regulatory capture: a situation in which the regulator of an industry comes to represent the industry’s interests rather than regulating it In some cases, regulatory capture is a problem. This occurs when the regulator becomes so closely involved with the firm it is supposed to be regulating that it begins to champion its cause rather than imposing tough rules where they are needed. EXERCISE 21.1 How does the principal–agent argument help to explain why nationalised industries may become inefficient? How does privatisation (with regulation) attempt to remedy this situation? Deregulation Deregulation occurs where a government removes restrictions placed on producers in a market in order to encourage competition. This reflects the belief that competition in a market benefits consumers by encouraging innovation and efficiency improvements and by limiting the market power of firms. LEARNING LINK The concept of X-inefficiency is explained in Chapter 17. 21 Government policies to achieve efficient resource allocation and correct market failure There are problems inherent in this approach. For example, how does the regulator set X? This is problematic in a situation where the company has better information about costs than the regulator – another instance of the problems caused by the existence of asymmetric information. There is also the possibility that the firm will achieve its productivity gains by reducing the quality of the product, or by neglecting long-term investment for the future and allowing maintenance standards to lapse. 21 The main argument here is that if firms are over-regulated, they may become complacent, which may result in X-inefficiency. Over-regulation may stifle innovation and risk-taking that could otherwise lead to new developments that could benefit consumers. A danger of deregulation is that firms may take too much advantage of their newfound freedom from rules and restrictions. Widespread deregulation of financial markets in the early 2000s allowed banks in many countries to become too inventive in their search for new profit-making opportunities, laying the foundations for the financial crisis that affected the global economy in the late 2000s. Direct provision Another way in which the government could intervene to correct a market failure, or to improve resource allocation, is to undertake direct provision of a good. In the 319 308275_C21_CAM_IASAL ECO_310_328.indd 319 17/02/21 5:25 PM case of public goods, there has to be some sort of government involvement, as a free market will not ensure the provision of these goods. 21 Test yourself 21.7 A LEVEL PART 8 GOVERNMENT MICROECONOMIC INTERVENTION Why is government intervention needed to ensure the supply of a public good? Direct provision is closely akin to nationalisation, and many governments have been reluctant to follow this route. It has been recognised that the same arguments that apply to the impact of competition on private sector efficiency are also relevant for public sector activity, so there is no guarantee that direct government provision will produce a more efficient allocation of resources. Furthermore, governments may not have the administrative or practical experience to be able to engage directly in the production process. However, direct provision is not the only way of ensuring that a good is supplied, and there are several ways in which the public sector can ensure provision through some sort of engagement with the private sector that have been developed. KEY TERMS contracting out: a situation in which the public sector places activities in the hands of a private firm and pays for the provision competitive tendering: a process by which the public sector calls for private firms to bid for a contract for provision of a good or service public–private partnership (PPP): an arrangement by which a government service or private business venture is funded and operated through a partnership of government and the private sector The simplest form of this is contracting out. Under such an arrangement, the public sector issues a contract to a private firm for the supply of some good or service. One example is waste disposal, where a local authority may issue a contract for a firm to provide the necessary waste disposal service. Competition between firms can be encouraged by a competitive tendering process. In other words, the contract would be announced and firms invited to put in bids specifying the quality of service they are prepared to provide, and at what price. The local authority would then be in a position to look for efficiency in choosing the most competitive bid. More complex models of cooperation between public and private sectors have been developed, involving various kinds of public–private partnership (PPP). A PPP is ‘an arrangement by which a government service or private business venture is funded and operated through a partnership of government and the private sector’ (UK National Audit Office). Such arrangements have been set up in a number of countries. For example, India has been developing a number of PPPs to help to enhance the country’s infrastructure such as roads and port developments, which is seen as vital to allow economic growth and poverty alleviation. The Covid-19 pandemic that swept the world in 2020 brought unprecedented reactions from governments around the world. This involved far-reaching interventions in economies, closing ‘non-essential’ businesses, diverting production to ensure medical supplies and taking over wages and salaries of workers forced to remain in quarantine. SUMMARY (NATIONALISATION, PRIVATISATION, REGULATION AND DEREGULATION) » Natural monopolies pose particular problems » » » » for policy, as setting price equal to marginal cost would force such firms to make a loss. One response to this problem was nationalisation. However, this can lead to widespread X-inefficiency. Privatisation was expected to encourage competition and provide better incentives for managers. Regulation was put into place to ensure that the newly privatised firms did not abuse their market positions, for example by inflating prices or reducing quality. » In some cases, regulatory capture was a » » » » problem, whereby the regulators became too close to their industries. Deregulation of some markets was designed to encourage competition, which was expected to benefit consumers. The danger with deregulation is that firms may take too much advantage of their freedom. Direct provision of goods by the government is possible, but may not always be an effective solution. Establishing public-private partnerships is one way in which the government can ensure provision of public goods without direct involvement in production. 320 308275_C21_CAM_IASAL ECO_310_328.indd 320 17/02/21 5:25 PM 21.4 Pollution permits Test yourself 21.8 Why might it be difficult to quantify the size of the tax needed to reduce pollution to the desired level? pollution permit system: a system for controlling pollution based on a market for permits that allow firms to pollute up to a limit Another approach is to use a tradable pollution permit system, under which the government issues or sells permits to firms, allowing them to pollute up to a certain limit. These permits are then tradable, so that firms that are relatively ‘clean’ in their production methods and do not need to use their full allocation of permits can sell their polluting rights to other firms, whose production methods produce greater levels of pollution. Advantages One important advantage of such a scheme lies in the incentives for firms. Firms that pollute because of their relatively inefficient production methods will find they are at a disadvantage because they face higher costs. Rather than continuing to purchase permits, they will find that they have an incentive to produce less pollution – which, of course, is what the policy is intended to achieve. In this way, the permit system uses the market to address the externality problem – in contrast to direct regulation of environmental standards, which tries to solve pollution by overriding the market. A second advantage is that the overall level of pollution can be controlled by this system, as the authorities control the total amount of permits that are issued. After all, the objective of the policy is to control the overall level of pollution, and a mixture of ‘clean’ and ‘dirty’ firms may produce the same amount of total emissions as uniformly ‘slightly unclean’ firms. Disadvantages However, the permit system may not be without its problems. In particular, there is the question of enforcement. For the system to be effective, sanctions must be in place for firms that pollute beyond the permitted level, and there must be an operational and cost-effective method for the authorities to check the level of emissions. Furthermore, it may not be a straightforward exercise for the authorities to decide on the appropriate number of permits to issue in order to produce the desired reduction in emission levels. Some alternative regulatory systems share this problem, as it is not easy to measure the extent to which marginal private and social costs diverge. One possible criticism that is unique to a permit form of regulation is that the very different levels of pollution produced by different firms may seem inequitable – as if those firms that can afford to buy permits can pollute as much as they like. On the other hand, it might be argued that those most likely to suffer from this are the polluting firms, whose public image is likely to be tarnished if they acquire a reputation as heavy polluters. This possibility might strengthen the incentives of such firms to clean up their production. Taking the strengths and weaknesses of this approach together, it seems that on balance such a system could be effective in regulating pollution. 21 21 Government policies to achieve efficient resource allocation and correct market failure KEY TERM Earlier in the chapter the possibility of using a tax to tackle pollution was discussed. A problem with this approach is that it may be difficult to quantify the size of the tax needed to reduce pollution to a desirable level, or to identify the main culprit firms that are causing the problem. Furthermore, the cost of implementing and monitoring such a scheme is high. An example is the EU Emissions Trading System (EU ETS), which has been in operation since 2005. It now operates in 31 countries, and limits carbon emissions from more than 11,000 energy-using installations. The system works on a ‘cap and trade’ system. A cap is set on the total amount of greenhouse gases that can be emitted by installations that are part of the scheme, with the cap being reduced over time. Companies in the scheme receive or buy emission allowances that can then be traded with other firms. The scheme is seen as having had success in reducing emissions. By 2020 they were expected to be 21% lower compared with 2015. 321 308275_C21_CAM_IASAL ECO_310_328.indd 321 17/02/21 5:25 PM A LEVEL PART 8 GOVERNMENT MICROECONOMIC INTERVENTION 21 SUMMARY: POLLUTION PERMITS » Under a pollution permit scheme, the government » This enables the market to allocate the permits to issues (or sells) permits to firms that allow them to emit pollution up to a certain level. » These permits can then be traded. where they are most needed, while controlling the overall level of pollution. » This reduces the cost and improves the effectiveness of controlling pollution. 21.5 Property rights and information provision KEY TERM property rights: the social framework that gives individuals legal control or ownership of goods Property rights Nobel prize winner Ronald Coase argued that the existence of property rights and transaction costs is key to understanding how markets work. In other words, the existence of a system of secure property rights is essential as an underpinning for the economy. The legal system exists in part to enforce property rights, and to provide the set of rules under which markets operate. When property rights fail, there is a failure of markets. In this view of the world, one of the reasons underlying the existence of some externalities is that there is a failing in the system of property rights. For example, think about the situation in which a factory is emitting toxic fumes into a residential district. One way of viewing this is that the firm is interfering with local residents’ clean air. If those residents could be given property rights over clean air, they could require the firm to compensate them for the costs it was inflicting. However, the problem is that with such a wide range of people being affected to varying degrees (according to prevailing winds and how close they live to the factory), it is impossible in practical terms to use the assignment of property rights to internalise the pollution externality. This is because the problem of coordination requires high transaction costs in order for property rights to be individually enforced. Therefore, the government effectively takes over the property rights on behalf of the residents, and acts as a collective enforcer. Ronald Coase thus argued that externality effects could be internalised in conditions where property rights could be enforced, and where the transaction costs of doing so were not too large. Test yourself 21.9 What is meant by the notion of asymmetric information? LEARNING LINK The notion of asymmetric information was discussed in Chapter 15. Information provision Market failure can arise from information failure, especially where there is asymmetric information or where economic agents lack information or the capacity to process the information available. In such circumstances, the solution would seem to be to find a way of providing the information to remedy the situation. One example discussed in Chapter 15 was that of second-hand cars, where car dealers may find that they cannot find buyers for good-quality cars at a fair price if potential buyers cannot distinguish quality. The solution here may be to tackle the problem at its root, by finding a way to provide information about quality. In the case of secondhand cars, inspection schemes or the offering of warranties may be a way of improving the flow of information about the quality of cars for sale. Buyers may then have confidence that they are not buying a lemon. Similarly, in the case of the insurance market, the asymmetric information problem helps to explain why insurance companies try to cover themselves by insisting on comprehensive health histories of those who take out health insurance, and include exclusion clauses that entitle them to refuse to pay out if past illnesses have not been disclosed. It also helps to explain why banks may insist on collateral to back up loans. Information problems may also be present in respect of some demerit goods. Think back to the tobacco example discussed earlier. Tobacco is seen by government as a demerit good on the grounds that smokers underestimate the damaging effects of smoking. There may 322 308275_C21_CAM_IASAL ECO_310_328.indd 322 17/02/21 5:25 PM also be negative externalities caused by passive smoking. At first, taxes were used to try to discourage smoking in the UK, but given the inelastic demand for tobacco, this proved ineffective. The taxes were reinforced by extensive campaigns to spread information about the damaging effects of smoking. When even this did not solve the problem, the government had to introduce regulation by prohibiting smoking in public buildings. 21 SUMMARY: PROPERTY RIGHTS AND INFORMATION PROVISION » Information failure can be tackled by ensuring that important underpinning of the operation of markets. » In the case of pollution and other issues, the difficulty of coordinating action when property rights are held by many different individuals may dilute its effectiveness. economic agents have access to the information that they need. » However, economic agents may not always respond to being given information. 21.6 Behavioural insights and nudge theory One of the key insights of economics concerns the importance of incentives in influencing the behaviour of economic agents. This is crucial for the design of microeconomic policy, and governments need to understand how people respond to different types of incentive. The use of indirect taxes to correct market failure rests on the assumption that people respond to prices, so that an increase in the price of a good will tend to lead to a reduction in demand. Behavioural economics is a branch of economic analysis that blends ideas from psychology with microeconomic analysis, and suggests that people do not always act rationally as traditional economic analysis tends to assume. One aspect of this is that people may not always react solely to price signals in their decision making. They may make decisions based on habit or buy goods on impulse. Indeed, they may take decisions based on humanitarian motives, or through a sense of loyalty. KEY TERM nudge theory: a notion based on behavioural theory suggesting that people can be encouraged to adopt behaviour that is beneficial for society Test yourself 21.10 Give an example of how a sense of social responsibility may influence behaviour. From a government perspective, this analysis may offer new ways of inducing people to take decisions that are beneficial for society. This is sometimes known as nudge theory, under which governments may be able to nudge people towards taking decisions and adopting behaviour that the authorities want to encourage. One example of this is where shops are encouraged to display healthy foods in more prominent positions to promote impulse buying. The idea has also been used to develop campaigns that foster good social behaviour: for example, displaying signs that say ‘Take your litter home – other people do’, or reminding people that there are CCTV cameras overlooking them. This tries to persuade people that it is their responsibility to behave in certain ways. During the Covid-19 pandemic the British government persistently encouraged people to comply with official recommendations about behaviour because it was socially responsible to do so. 21 Government policies to achieve efficient resource allocation and correct market failure » The existence of secure property rights is an Another example of nudge theory is where legislation is passed that allows people to opt out, rather than opt in to some desirable action: for example, the rules under which individuals are automatically enrolled in workplace pension schemes unless they consciously opt out. Research has shown that people are more likely to remain opted in than to take the trouble to opt out. Robert Thaler was awarded the Nobel Prize for Economic Sciences in 2017 for his work in this area. SUMMARY: BEHAVIOURAL INSIGHTS AND NUDGE THEORY » Behavioural economics is a branch of economic » It suggests that people do not always act rationally analysis that blends ideas from psychology with microeconomic analysis. as traditional economic analysis tends to assume. » Governments can use nudge theory to encourage individuals to adopt behaviour that benefits society. 323 308275_C21_CAM_IASAL ECO_310_328.indd 323 17/02/21 5:25 PM A LEVEL PART 8 GOVERNMENT MICROECONOMIC INTERVENTION 21 21.7 Government failure in microeconomic intervention KEY TERM government failure: a misallocation of resources arising from government intervention to correct a market failure that causes a less efficient allocation of resources and imposes a welfare loss on society Most governments see it as their responsibility to try to correct some of the failures of markets to allocate resources efficiently. This has led to a wide variety of policies being devised to address issues of market failure, such as taxes on polluting firms, levies to enable funding of public goods, and campaigns to combat information gaps. However, some policies have effects that may not culminate in successful elimination of market failure. Indeed, in some cases government intervention may introduce new market distortions, leading to a phenomenon known as government failure. The remainder of this chapter examines some examples of such government failure. Causes of government failure Many of the situations in which government failure arises stem from the interrelationships between markets in an economy. This means that taking action in one area can have spillover effects elsewhere in an economy. Some roles are critical for a government to perform if a mixed economy is to function effectively. A vital role is the provision by the government of an environment in which markets can operate effectively. There must be stability in the political system if firms and consumers are to take decisions with confidence about the future. And there must be a secure system of property rights, without which markets could not be expected to work. However, there are sources of market failure that require intervention. This does not necessarily mean that governments need to substitute markets with direct action. However, it does mean that they need to be more active in markets that cannot operate effectively, while at the same time performing an enabling role to encourage markets to work well whenever this is feasible. Interventions to address market failure can cause problems if they are not carefully implemented, or if the government itself does not have sufficient information to take good decisions. For example, in the case of externalities, the government may choose to tackle pollution by a tax, or by regulation. However, if it is not possible to identify the appropriate amount of the tax that is needed to correct the market failure, or if it is not known how much pollution represents the optimum outcome for society, then it will not be possible to get the policy exactly right. Similar implementation problems may arise with other attempts to deal with market failure. The consequences can impose costs on society, which may exceed the benefits gained from the intervention. Consequences of government failure This chapter has explored a range of government policies designed to achieve improved resource allocation and to address market failure. In evaluating these interventions, several issues have been highlighted that show areas in which government failure could arise. Sales taxes Governments need to raise funds to finance the expenditure that they undertake. One way of doing this is through expenditure taxes such as value added tax (VAT) or excise duties on such items as alcohol or tobacco. You might think that raising money in this way to provide goods and services such as healthcare that would otherwise be underprovided would be a benefit to society. But there is a downside to this action, even if all the funds raised by a sales tax are spent wisely. The effects of a sales tax can be seen in a demand and supply diagram such as in Figure 5.2 on page 75. Such a tax is paid by the seller, so it affects the supply curve for a product, shifting it to the left and leading to a higher equilibrium price but lower quantity traded. 324 308275_C21_CAM_IASAL ECO_310_328.indd 324 17/02/21 5:25 PM To what extent is this good for society? The government has raised revenue as a result of the tax, so we might argue that the funds raised can be used in a way that benefits society as a whole. However, the picture is not quite so straightforward. Recall from Chapter 4 that an efficient allocation of resources is achieved when a market reaches an equilibrium such that the price of a product is equal to the marginal cost of producing it. This suggests that the imposition of a sales tax moves a market away from this ideal state of affairs. It may arise that by imposing a tax to raise funds for correcting market failure in one part of the economy, the government introduces a misallocation of resources elsewhere. Sales taxes Is it possible to identify how a sales tax will affect total welfare in society? Consider Figure 21.7, which shows the market for games consoles. Suppose that the government imposes a specific tax on games consoles. This would have the effect of taking market equilibrium from the free-market position at P* with quantity traded at Q* to a new position, with price now at Pt and quantity traded at Qt. Remember that the price rises by less than the amount of the tax, implying that the incidence of the tax falls partly on buyers and partly on sellers. In Figure 21.7 consumers pay more of the tax (the area P*PtBE) than the producers (who pay FP*EG). The effect on society’s overall welfare will now be examined. Remember that the total welfare that society receives from consuming a product is the sum of consumer and producer surplus. The situation before and after the sales tax is as follows. Before the tax, consumer surplus is given by the area AP*C and producer surplus is given by the triangle P*CH. How about afterwards? Consumer surplus is now the smaller triangle APtB, and producer surplus is FGH. The area PtBGF is the revenue raised by the government from the tax, which should be included in total welfare on Price EXTENSION MATERIAL A Supply + tax Supply B Pt P* F E C G H Demand Qt Q* Quantity of games consoles ▲ Figure 21.7 A sales tax and economic welfare the assumption that the government uses this wisely. The total amount of welfare is now ABGH. If you compare these total welfare areas before and after the tax, you will realise that they differ by the area BCG. This triangle represents a deadweight loss that arises from the imposition of the tax. It is sometimes referred to as the excess burden of the tax. So, even where the government intervenes to raise funding for its expenditure – and spends it wisely – a distortion is introduced to resource allocation, and society must bear a loss of welfare. 21 Government policies to achieve efficient resource allocation and correct market failure Of course, it may be that in this particular market, the government has some other reason for wanting to reduce the consumption of tobacco. However, if a sales tax is levied on all goods and services in an economy, this argument cannot be applied. 21 Information failure A tax on pollution An issue arose in considering how a tax on pollution might tackle the negative externality associated with a production process. It was pointed out that setting the appropriate value for the tax required good information about the extent of the externality, which would be costly to get. If the tax were to be set at the wrong level, the consequence would be that resources would not be best allocated. The administrative cost of setting the appropriate tax and of monitoring firms’ behaviour might not justify imposing the tax. A subsidy A similar issue can arise when setting the level of a subsidy to encourage higher production of a good. Setting the subsidy will again be costly to the government, and 325 308275_C21_CAM_IASAL ECO_310_328.indd 325 17/02/21 5:25 PM 21 it may be difficult to find the appropriate level for the subsidy that will produce the ideal outcome. In order to cover the cost of the subsidy, funds will need to be raised elsewhere in the economy, which may affect taxpayers, or other markets. A LEVEL PART 8 GOVERNMENT MICROECONOMIC INTERVENTION Price controls If the government intervenes to set prices in a market, whether it be a minimum wage or rent controls, a distortion is introduced to resource allocation. A minimum wage may cause an increase in unemployment in some markets, and rent controls may end up reducing the amount of rental housing available and increasing homelessness. Any direct control of prices may interrupt the role of prices as signals in allocating resources in society. Prohibition Regulating production of undesirable demerit goods through prohibition may encourage smuggling activities. Nationalisation and privatisation The nationalisation of natural monopolies has been seen to be affected by the principal– agent problem, leading to inefficiencies through limited accountability of management. The regulation of privatised natural monopolies has also created some problems, and has been costly to administer. One problem is that of regulatory capture, whereby a regulator may champion the cause of the regulated enterprise, rather than ensuring compliance. EXERCISE 21.2 The markets for rented and owner-occupied dwellings are likely to be interrelated, at least to some extent. Use demand and supply diagrams to examine how a rent control policy would affect the two markets in the short and long runs. SUMMARY: GOVERNMENT FAILURE IN MICROECONOMIC INTERVENTION » Government failure can occur when often well-meaning interventions by government have unintended effects. » In tackling one problem, the government may introduce distortions in resource allocation that affect another part of the economy. » For example, imposing a sales tax across all goods and services can lead to a deadweight welfare loss, even if all the revenues from the tax are used to benefit society. » Price controls can create disequilibrium in a market. END OF CHAPTER QUESTIONS Multiple choice 1 A government changed the indirect tax on a product from specific to ad valorem. What can be concluded with certainty? A The tax is now a fixed amount regardless of the value of the product. B The tax is now a fixed percentage of the value of the product. C Richer individuals now pay a higher tax rate. D There would be more tax avoidance. 326 308275_C21_CAM_IASAL ECO_310_328.indd 326 17/02/21 5:25 PM 2 What advantage do property rights have over indirect taxes as a method to deal with negative externalities? A The extension of private property rights cannot result in government failure. B Unlike indirect taxes, effective property rights incentivise firms to reduce pollution rather than penalising them for polluting. C Property rights, if adequately managed, have the potential to generate more government revenue. D Property rights can be used at both central and local levels. 1 Read the following extract and then answer the questions that follow. What pollutes the air in central Asia? The government of Uzbekistan is planning to sell off state shares in over 1,000 enterprises. Among the plans is the radical privatisation and upgrading of Uzbekistan’s energy industry to include renewables and nuclear sources. This is partly to help improve the economic efficiency of the sector, which is 5 characterised by high costs and low productivity, and partly to address the issue of air pollution. In most cities, air quality decreases during November to March when households increase the use of their heating systems. Air in Tashkent (the capital of Uzbekistan) was harmful for 80% of the days in 2019. 10 Exhaust emissions from vehicles are a common cause of air pollution in central Asian cities. For example, there are 420,000 cars registered in Bishkek (the capital of Kyrgyzstan), while the city is designed for a maximum of 50,000 cars. Dust storms present the main danger to the population of Dushanbe (the capital of Tajikistan), where their number has increased in recent years. The main 15 reason for more frequent dust storms is desertification. This has resulted from the destruction of 700,000 hectares of forest that were in common rather than private ownership. Scientists argue that the trees had previously stood in the way of the wind, filtering the dust from the air. Emissions from heating systems that provide heat to apartment ­buildings also 20 reduce air quality. Authorities in Bishkek claim that powerful filters installed in the heating systems of the Kyrgyzstan capital successfully purify p ­ articulate emissions by 97%. In order to pay for these filters, the government of Kyrgyzstan is considering raising revenue through the introduction of sales taxes. Percentage of people who intend to make certain decisions based on climate change in 2020 Buy fewer plastic products Heat home less in winter Boycott carbon negative companies 98 81 Fly less Protest or march for climate change 91 94 95 93 79 75 69 66 78 75 76 56 52 USA 21 Government policies to achieve efficient resource allocation and correct market failure Data response 21 China Europe Source: European Investment Bank ▲ Figure 21.8 Climate change: a key factor in decision making in 2020 327 308275_C21_CAM_IASAL ECO_310_328.indd 327 17/02/21 5:25 PM a Explain how the privatisation of the energy industry in Uzbekistan might encourage an increase in efficiency. b The extract states that ‘Authorities in Bishkek claim that powerful filters installed in the heating systems of the Kyrgyzstan capital successfully purify particulate emissions by 97%’ (lines 20–22). Despite increasing social welfare through the installation of the air filters, government failure could be created if the filters are paid for through the introduction of a sales tax. To what extent do you agree with this statement? c The extract refers to ‘700,000 hectares of forest that were in common rather than private ownership’ (lines 16–17). Explain how the existence of private property rights over the forest could have helped to prevent any subsequent market failure. d In order to alter behaviour that affects climate change, the governments of all three areas represented in Figure 21.8 employ policies based on nudge theory. Explain what is meant by nudge theory and, with reference to Figure 21.8, comment on the relative effectiveness of such policies in the regions identified. A LEVEL PART 8 GOVERNMENT MICROECONOMIC INTERVENTION 21 Essay style 2 Assess the view that indirect taxation is the best solution to reducing environmental pollution caused by production externalities. CASE STUDY Plastic oceans The contamination of the natural marine environment by plastics has been increasing, causing a range of negative effects. These include endangering marine life, damaging maritime industries and infrastructure, and potentially having an impact on human wellbeing. This has received prominent coverage in the media, with a succession of studies seeking to analyse the impact of plastics on the environment. A prime source of the contamination is litter – about 70% of litter in the oceans is made of plastic. In particular, much of this litter comprises single-use packaging, as well as rope, netting and sewage-related debris. A UK government report published in 2017 noted that if plastic litter continued to enter the marine environment at the then-current rates, this will far exceed the possibility of its removal. ▲ Plastics pollution Packaging goods has become part of everyday life, as any visit to a supermarket will demonstrate. It is cheap and convenient, and firms under pressure to keep their costs low in order to remain competitive are naturally reluctant to use more expensive but more environment-friendly materials. This leads to a divergence between private and social costs. Follow-up questions a Draw a diagram to show the economic effect of plastic pollution on society. b Discuss the difficulties in tackling this problem, given that plastic in the ocean is occurring on a global scale. 328 308275_C21_CAM_IASAL ECO_310_328.indd 328 17/02/21 5:26 PM A LEVEL PART 8 Government microeconomic intervention 22 Equity and redistribution of income and wealth ★ the distinction between equity and equality ★ the difference between equity and efficiency ★ absolute poverty and relative poverty ★ policies that can be adopted towards equity and inequality ★ the poverty trap In all countries, there is inequality in the distribution of income and wealth. In this chapter, we explore ways in which a government can attempt to influence the way in which resources are allocated among different groups in society, particularly in response to the presence of poverty. 22.1 Equity and inequality KEY TERMS inequality: where different groups within society receive differing amounts of income and/or wealth equity: where people in the same situation receive equal treatment Some degree of inequality in the distribution of income within a society is inevitable. Individuals have different innate talents and abilities, and choose to undertake different types and levels of education and training. This means that they acquire different sets of skills, which open up different income-earning opportunities. Inequality also arises because of the pattern of ownership of assets. In other words, complete equality of income in a society (whereby everyone receives the same amount of income and wealth) can never be achieved. 22 Equity and redistribution of income and wealth What this chapter covers LEARNING LINK Chapter 5 introduced some key concepts related to inequality in the distribution of income in a society, and ways in which the degree of inequality can be measured. It also explained the distinction between income and wealth. Test yourself 22.1 Provide another example of how some groups receive unequal treatment compared with others in your country. A separate issue is whether there can be equity in the way that people are treated. One aspect of this is whether individuals face equal opportunities, and whether identical people receive identical treatment in economic terms. Many people would acknowledge that people in identical circumstances and with identical skills, abilities and experience should receive identical income. There are situations in which such equal treatment is not achieved. One example is that male and female workers receive unequal treatment in many societies. In looking at a society, the notion of equity is about whether or not the distribution of income and wealth among the citizens of a country is fair. This idea of fairness underlies the question of whether the government needs to intervene to influence the way in which resources are distributed between individuals and groups. SUMMARY: EQUITY AND EQUALITY » Inequality in the distribution of income and wealth » Equity is where people in the same situation occurs in all societies. » This results from differences in talents, abilities and experience, and from differences in the ownership of assets. receive equal treatment. » Inequity is also present in societies to some degree. 329 308275_C22_CAM_IASAL ECO_329_336.indd 329 17/02/21 10:57 AM 22.2 Equity and efficiency 22 A LEVEL PART 8 GOVERNMENT MICROECONOMIC INTERVENTION STUDY TIP It is important to remember that efficiency and equity do not necessarily go together. A resource allocation may be efficient, but this does not mean that it will always be equitable. In discussing ways in which markets may fail to lead to an optimal allocation of resources, the focus has been primarily on questions of efficiency. In particular, it has been noted that allocative efficiency will not be reached when there is a divergence between private and social costs or benefits. However, even if a society achieves allocative efficiency, this does not guarantee that this is really the ideal outcome for society. It was noted in Chapter 15 that there is no unique overall equilibrium for a society, and that a different distribution of income between individuals will lead to a different Pareto optimum position. What this suggests is that an economy may settle into an equilibrium in which allocative efficiency has been reached, but the distribution of resources is seen to be unfair. In other words, there may be times when there is a trade-off between efficiency and equity in policy design. A policy designed to promote allocative efficiency may not offer sufficient protection to the poor. A tax on tobacco intended to correct a market failure may fall disproportionately on low-income groups within society. Here again, balance is needed to ensure that policy offers sufficient protection for the poor without compromising the efficiency with which markets are able to work in allocating resources. 22.3 Poverty All societies are characterised by some inequality – and some poverty. Although the two are related, they are not the same. Indeed, poverty might be regarded as one aspect of inequality. KEY TERMS absolute poverty: situation of a household whose income is insufficient to purchase the minimum bundle of goods and services needed for survival relative poverty: situation in which household income falls below a specified percentage of median adjusted household income headcount ratio: a measure of the percentage of a country’s population living below a poverty line International Poverty Line: an agreed measure that defines the absolute poverty line based on international prices, set at PPP$1.90 from October 2015 If there is a wide gap between the richest and poorest households, it is important to evaluate just how poor those poorest households are, and whether they should be regarded as being officially ‘in poverty’ and in need of assistance. This requires a definition of poverty. One approach is to define a basket of goods and services that is regarded as being the minimum required to support human life. Households that are seen to have income that falls short of allowing them to purchase that basic bundle of goods would be regarded as being in absolute poverty. Poverty can also be defined in relative terms. If a household has insufficient income for the members of the household to participate in the normal social life of the country, then they are said to be in relative poverty. This is also defined in terms of a poverty line. The line is defined relative to the median adjusted household disposable income (the median is the income of the middle-ranked household). For example, in European countries, the line is set at 60% of median income. A common way of measuring the poverty rate in a country is to estimate the percentage of the population living below a poverty line, known as a headcount ratio. The poverty line in this context is an estimate of the income needed to ensure basic human survival. People living below this level are perceived to be in absolute poverty. To enable international comparisons of poverty levels, the World Bank has defined an International Poverty Line. This is based on 2011 prices, and from October 2015 it was set at $1.90 (in internatonal (PPP) dollars). The line has to be reset every few years in line with changing prices over time. The World Bank estimated that around 736 million people worldwide were living beneath this level in 2015 (down from 1.9 billion in 1990). Some individual countries also set their own national poverty line to reflect local conditions. Progress has been made to reduce the number of people living in absolute poverty on this definition, except in sub-Saharan Africa, where the number continues to rise. However, there was concern that poverty remained a problem, with people living on incomes that were not significantly higher than the International Poverty Line. In October 2018 the World Bank launched additional poverty lines to reflect typical 330 308275_C22_CAM_IASAL ECO_329_336.indd 330 17/02/21 10:57 AM national poverty lines in lower- and upper-middle-income countries. It was estimated that in 2015, over a quarter of the world’s population was surviving on less than $2.20 per day, and almost a half on less than $5.50 per day. 22 Figure 22.1 shows estimates of the poverty headcount ratio for a range of countries around the world. For most developed economies, the headcount ratio at this level is zero or close to it. Italy is unusual in appearing on this graph, as relatively few highincome countries have poverty on this measure. This distinction between absolute and relative poverty is an important one. Absolute poverty is almost entirely confined to the less developed countries, but relative poverty can exist in any society, even in the more developed nations. 0 10 20 30 50 40 60 70 80 % of population Source: based on data from World Development Indicators ▲ Figure 22.1 Poverty headcount ratio at $1.90 (% of population) 22 Equity and redistribution of income and wealth STUDY TIP China Sri Lanka Italy Pakistan Brazil Indonesia Bangladesh Nepal South Africa India Zimbabwe Tanzania Zambia Uzbekistan Madagascar In Europe (including the UK), estimates of poverty are based on a regular survey of households conducted in EU member states and some other selected countries. In 2017, the UK’s threshold for poverty was set at £12,597 per year. This is based on adjustments for household size and composition. Households with income below this are described as being in relative income poverty (or being ‘at risk of poverty’); households that experience this in the current year and at least 2 of the 3 preceding years are said to be in persistent poverty. Explain why it is necessary to recalibrate the poverty line on a regular basis. % Test yourself 22.2 Figure 22.2 presents some data for a range of European countries in 2017. The proportion of people below the relative poverty line varies substantially across these countries, from 11.5% in Finland to 23.6% in Romania. 25 Relative income poverty Persistent poverty 20 15 10 5 ia m an n Ro ai Sp ly Ita ce re e G UK y an G er m en ed ce Sw la er th Ne Fr an s nd k ar nm De nd 0 la Calculate the median adjusted household disposable income level for the UK in 2017, based on the fact that the UK relative poverty threshold is 60% of the median. Fin Test yourself 22.3 Source: based on data from Eurostat as cited by ONS ▲ Figure 22.2 Relative and persistent poverty: selected countries, 2017 331 308275_C22_CAM_IASAL ECO_329_336.indd 331 17/02/21 10:57 AM The percentage falling below the poverty line is not a totally reliable measure, as it is also important to know how far below the poverty line households are falling. The income gap (the distance between household income and the poverty line) is useful to measure the intensity of poverty as well as its incidence. 22 A LEVEL PART 8 GOVERNMENT MICROECONOMIC INTERVENTION LEARNING LINK There is further discussion of poverty and how it is measured in Chapter 30. EXERCISE 22.1 Imagine that you are the Minister for Poverty Alleviation in a country in which the (absolute) poverty line is set at $500 per year. Of the people living below the poverty line, you know that there are two distinct groups, each made up of 50 individuals. The people in group 1 have an income of $450, whereas those in group 2 have only $250. Suppose that your budget for poverty alleviation is $2,500. a Your prime concern is with the most needy: how would you use your budget? b Suppose instead that your prime minister instructs you to reduce the percentage of people living below the poverty line: do you adopt the same strategy for using the funds? c How helpful is the poverty line as a strategic target of policy action? SUMMARY: POVERTY » Absolute poverty measures whether individuals or households have sufficient resources to maintain a reasonable life. » Relative poverty measures whether individuals or households are able to participate in the life of the country in which they live: this is calculated as having 60% of median adjusted household disposable income. 22.4 Policies towards equity and inequality LEARNING LINKS You may find it helpful to look back at the earlier discussion of policies to address inequality on pages 81–85. Chapter 5 introduced some of the policy instruments that a government can use to influence the distribution of income and wealth in a country. Policies towards equity Equity is about fairness, and is probably one of the most difficult areas for governments to influence. It is one thing to state the principle that everyone should be treated fairly and equally, but quite another thing to persuade all economic agents to put that into practice. In the UK, the Equality Act of 2010 attempts to provide a legal framework to ensure equal treatment of individuals in employment. This is an attempt to outlaw discrimination against individuals on the grounds of nine protected characteristics, including age, gender, race and disability. This means that all individuals should have: » an equal chance to apply and be selected for posts pre-employment » an equal chance to be trained and promoted while employed with the organisation » an equal chance to have their employment terminated equally and fairly (www.eoc.org.uk) There has been some success in raising the profile of what is meant by equity and the dimensions of diversity, but in the UK there remains a gender gap in pay between men and women, and proving discrimination can be problematic in some cases. 332 308275_C22_CAM_IASAL ECO_329_336.indd 332 17/02/21 9:02 PM Policies to address inequality A negative income tax KEY TERMS transfer payment: occurs where the government provides benefits (in cash or in kind) to poor households; hence there is a transfer from taxpayers to the recipients of the benefits means-tested benefit: a benefit (in cash or kind) paid to people or households whose income falls below a certain level universal benefit: a benefit (in cash or kind) paid without reference to the income of the receiving person or household Test yourself 22.4 Why would a UBI scheme be less costly to implement than a means-tested benefit system? Benefits Governments can make direct transfer payments from rich to poor households as a way of redistributing income. Such transfers can be paid in monetary terms, or as benefits in kind (such as free education or healthcare). Some benefits may be means tested, that is paid only to those whose income falls below a certain level. For example, in the UK, households whose income falls below a certain level are entitled to housing benefit, that is, assistance in paying their rent. Means testing is designed to make benefits fairer, but these benefits are costly to administer and monitor. Other benefits may be universal, that is paid to all, regardless of income. Some of these benefits are funded through contributions. For example, in Pakistan a pension is paid to those above the retirement age who have made at least 15 years of contributions to the social insurance system. This is a universal benefit, in the sense that anyone who has met the contribution level is entitled to the pension regardless of their income or asset holdings. However, any shortfall must be covered by the government, partly through tax revenues. 22 22 Equity and redistribution of income and wealth negative income tax: a combined system of taxes and benefits under which individuals receive benefits through the tax system when on low incomes, but these are phased out as their incomes rise One possible solution that has been proposed is to introduce a negative income tax. Under such a system, people with a certain level of income would pay no tax, and the tax rate would increase as their income grew above that level. People with incomes below that level would receive payment through the tax system. This would guarantee that low-income households would receive a minimum level of subsistence income. Although such a system has been discussed by economists in the UK and the USA, no such system has yet been implemented because of logistical and political problems. Universal basic income (UBI) There have been proposals to establish a guaranteed safety net for all by paying a universal basic income (UBI) to everyone, regardless of their economic circumstances. It is argued that this would give people currently unemployed time to search and apply for a job. Those at the higher end of the income distribution would receive the UBI, but in practice would pay it back through higher tax rates. It has been suggested that such a scheme would be less costly to implement than the rather complicated welfare schemes operating in some countries. Others have argued that it would simply discourage individuals from seeking employment. Finland was the first country to put such a scheme into practice, albeit on a trial basis. A pilot scheme was introduced in 2017. The income payment was made to 2,000 randomly selected people who were receiving unemployment benefits to see how they would react. The scheme ran until the end of 2018, but the results were mixed. The recipients claimed that as a result of the payments, they were happier – but there was no evidence that they were more likely to find jobs than those who were not in the scheme. Similar schemes are being piloted elsewhere – for example, in Kenya, Italy and the Netherlands. During the Covid-19 pandemic, some commentators argued for the introduction of a UBI in the USA and the UK. The poverty trap Problems can arise when a system of means-tested benefits co-exists with a progressive income tax structure. Consider the incentives facing a person who is receiving welfare benefits because of unemployment or low pay. Such an individual may find that there is no incentive to take a job or to work more hours because the 333 308275_C22_CAM_IASAL ECO_329_336.indd 333 17/02/21 10:57 AM A LEVEL PART 8 GOVERNMENT MICROECONOMIC INTERVENTION 22 KEY TERM poverty trap: a situation in which an individual has no incentive to take a job or work longer hours because the loss of benefits and/or increase in tax payments outweighs the gain from increased earnings gain in terms of earnings would be lower than the loss of benefit payments or the increase in tax liability. This is known as the poverty trap. This creates a dilemma for the authorities, who would like to provide protection for the poor, but also want to offer incentives for people to work. Finding the right balance between these two policies can be challenging. A negative income tax scheme could offer a possible solution by guaranteeing a minimum subsistence level of income. However, proposals to introduce a universal basic income scheme have been criticised because of the existence of the poverty trap. Taxation It was noted in Chapter 5 that direct taxes such as income tax are designed to be progressive, as tax rates rise as income rises. This means that they are progressive, as richer households pay more in tax than those with low incomes. Income tax is therefore one way in which the government can influence the distribution of income. However, it was also pointed out that indirect taxes, such as taxes on expenditure, tend to be regressive. This is because lower-income households spend a higher proportion of their income, and may also be more likely to spend on products such as tobacco on which the tax is often higher than on other goods. This means that achieving a balance of taxation between direct and indirect taxes is an important aspect of the government’s redistributive policy. A switch in the balance from direct to indirect taxes will tend to increase inequality in a society. It is also important to be aware that taxation may have intergenerational effects. High taxation today in order to fund expenditure on today’s generation may leave future generations struggling for resources. This is related to the notion of sustainable economic growth and development. On the other hand, high taxation today in order to provide improved living conditions for future generations may increase poverty in the current generation. There is thus a need to maintain a careful balance across the generations, which requires the government to be able to take a long-term view. In this context, having a stable political environment is significant, as without such stability, governments may be tempted to take a short-run view. LEARNING LINKS The concept of sustainable economic growth and development is explained in Chapter 25 and there is more discussion of the macroeconomic impact of taxation on the distribution of income in Chapter 28 in the context of the effectiveness of fiscal policy. SUMMARY: POLICIES TOWARDS EQUITY AND INEQUALITY » Policy towards equity needs to promote fairness » Proposals have been discussed whereby a in the way that people are treated: for example, through encouraging equal opportunities. » One approach to tackling inequality is to implement a negative income tax, but there are problems in terms of logistical and political problems. » Transfers from rich to poor households in the form of monetary benefits or benefits in kind are one of the most important ways of tackling inequality. » Such benefits can be universal (provided to all) or means tested. guaranteed safety net would be provided in the form of a universal basic income (UBI) that would be paid to everyone. » Pilot schemes have been launched in a number of countries around the world. » Problems can arise if benefit levels are set so high that individuals have little incentive to work – this is known as the ‘poverty trap’. » The balance between (progressive) direct taxation and (regressive) indirect