•The financial crisis of 2007-2010; was it simply the result of lax regulation, or were a range of factors at play? (50 marks). In its analysis of what went wrong during the financial crisis of 2007-2010, the Turner review determined that it was a global story of macro trends mixing with financial innovation to create an explosive mix of growing debt, sophisticated credit securitisation and cavalier behaviour in the major Western banking systems. It raises fundamental theoretical issues around market efficiency and rationality and given that it is a global financial market and that there is no global government, it is difficult to assert that it is simply the result of lax regulation. Nonetheless, the radical deregulation process that began in the late 1970s led to the integration of modern financial markets. There are key structural flaws in this New Financial Architecture (NFA)1 that certainly helped generate the crisis. This essay intends to outline the key deregulatory acts in the US that facilitated the enormous growth of the financial markets. Rather than examine the ideological shift that has occurred over the past half-century, it will analyse how the deregulation and lax regulation fuelled three critical, structural developments; unhealthy financial innovation, perverse incentives and dangerously high, system-wide leverage. The financial crisis was created by this “new world” of leverage, deregulation and ‘financial innovation’. With sufficient regulation these developments would not have mutated into the chronic problems that they became, and therefore lax regulation was to blame for the crisis. The process of deregulation In the aftermath of the Great Depression, it was universally believed that unregulated financial markets were inherently fragile, subject to manipulation and corruption by insiders and capable of triggering deep economic crises and political and social unrest. Commercial banks were accused of being too speculative in the pre-depression era. Banking became greedy, sloppy and objectives became blurred. A strict financial regulatory system worked effectively to protect the USA from these dangers. This framework was based on the financial market theories of endogenous Crotty, James, Structural causes of the global financial crisis: a critical assessment of the ‘new financial architecture’ Cambridge Journal of Economics 2009, 33, p567 1 financial instability advocated by John Maynard Keynes. His theories propelled the shift from light to tight financial regulation. The Glass-Steagall Act (Banking Act) and Securities Act of 1933 were passed to address the failures of the financial system.2 These set up a regulatory firewall between commercial and investment bank activities. Financial giants, such as JP Morgan, were seen as a problem and, as a consequence, forced to cut their services and a large source of their income. The Securities Exchange Act of 1934, along with the Investment Company Act of 1940 and the Investment Advisers Act of 1940, created a regulatory framework that successfully held off abuses and boom-and-bust financial cycles.3 Combined, this regulatory framework limited the commercial banks securitising activities and limited the affiliation between commercial banks and investment banks. For instance, only 10% of commercial banks’ total income could stem from securities- however an exception allowed them to underwrite government-issued bonds. It was prudent and sensible regulation to protect the consumer from the risks of the banking sector. The economic crises of the 1970s and early 1980s led to both a paradigm and a policy regime shift. Efficient financial market theory began to dominate economic thinking and this eventually facilitated the transition to a new globally-integrated, deregulated, neoliberal, capitalist environment. The limitations the Glass-Steagall Act (GSA) imposed on the financial sector sparked intense debate over how much restriction was healthy. The Federal Reserve, under Alan Greenspan’s control, engineered the whole deregulation of the US banking and financial system. Simultaneously, laws preventing the merger of banks in different states were repealed, as was the insurance/banking split. “Merger Mania” finally pushed the GSA to its very limits and consequently, in November of 1999 Congress repealed the GSA with the introduction of the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act (GLBA).This was a critical development because it eliminated restrictions against affiliations between commercial and investment banks. Furthermore, it allowed the banking institutions to provide a broader range of services, including underwriting and other dealing activities. It is widely regarded as the most pivotal and historic act of Gilani, Shah, How Deregulation Eviscerated the Banking Sector Safety Net and Spawned the US Financial Crisis. Money Morning, 13th January 2009 2 3 http://www.huffingtonpost.com/mitchell-bard/one-lesson-from-the-1930s_b_216901.html deregulation in the ‘modern economy’, and many trace this single moment as the beginning of the financial crisis of 2007-20104. A year later, the Clinton administration introduced the Commodity Futures Modernisation Act (CFMA) that was designed to exempt futures and derivatives from regulation. In particular, credit default swaps (CDS), which are contracts that require one party to pay the other in the event that a third party defaults on some obligation, could no longer be regulated by states as insurance or gambling. In addition, capital requirements for investment banks were also significantly weakened. In 2004 the SEC unanimously voted to permit the net capital rule change that allowed investment banks to significantly increase their leverage5. At the same time as the Federal Reserve was introducing fairly drastic deregulation, the Bush administration was expanding mortgage lending and increasing homeownership across the USA. The American Dream Down payment Act of 2003 implemented many of Bush’s recommendations, and subprime lending, financed by mortgage securities, dramatically increased. Paul Mason, economics editor at the BBC, describes the knock-on-effect. “In the space of twelve months, Gramm’s legislation laid the basis for four crucial developments in US finance that would, within a decade, sink the system: deregulated investment banks, expanded subprime mortgage lending to the poor and ethnic minorities, a planet sized derivatives market, and the fusion of banking and insurance” The introduction of the GLBA, CMFA and the net capital rule had distinct implications for financial institutions across the USA. This report will analyse the emergence of 3 critical developments in the structure of the banking industry; financial innovation; high system-wide leverage and perverse incentives. It will conclude that these structural flaws in the environment resulted in the financial collapse of 2007-2010. Financial Innovation. 4 Mason, Paul Meltdown, The end of the Age of Greed 2009 p56-57 http://newsandinsight.thomsonreuters.com/Securities/Insight/2012/07_-_July/ Is_deregulation_to_blame_for_the_financial_crisis_/ 5 The years prior to the crisis saw an extraordinary acceleration in financial innovation which developed new instruments and systems to be used in the lending and borrowing of funds. These changes, which include innovations in technology, risk transfer and credit increased available credit for borrowers and gave banks new and less costly ways to raise equity capital6. These fuelled the bubble that caused the collapse, partly because they actually increased the availability of credit and partly because they hid the risk that was inherent in the system. This innovation could have been regulated. The very low interest rates of 2001-2006 were hugely lucrative to the banks. Combined with a falling stock market in the early 2000s, banks became awash with cheap money. Shah Gelani described how “Wall Street went to work manufacturing all manner of products to squeeze extra yield out of this ultra-low-interest-rate environment”7. Banks became more creative and enticed new and less creditworthy home-buyers into the market with exotic mortgages, such as “interest-only” loans and “optionadjustable rate” mortgages.8 Secondly, freed by deregulation, the banks found new business by converting consumer debt into tradeable securities and then selling these securities on. This work resulted in a huge distribution of derivatives; particularly mortgage-backed loans, that increased the instability of the entire system before 2007. And two new financial products; CDOs and CDSs grew enormously and their complexity allowed them to avoid the safeguards in the system. The Financial Times, at the end of 2007, explained the situation well: “A plethora of opaque institutions and vehicles have sprung up in America and European markets this decade, and they have come to play an important role in providing credit across the system”.9 The deregulation of CDSs meant that banks could effectively buy insurance against a mix of subprime and prime loans, called a Collateralised Debt Obligation. This process meant that risks were bundled together, averaged out, reduced and then finally, moved off balance sheet. According to Source 1A 6 http://www.investopedia.com/terms/f/financial-innovation.asp 7 http://moneymorning.com/2009/01/13/deregulation-financial-crisis/ CDO issuance in billions($) Whalen, Charles. The US Credit Crunch of 2007. A Minsky Moment. The Levy Economics Institute of Bard College No,92, in billions($) 2007 p14. 8 Gillian Tett and Paul. J Davies Out of the shadows: How banking’s secret system broke down. December 16 2007. Financial Times Article (http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/42827c50-abfd-11dc-82f0-0000779fd2ac.html#axzz2QdvioNXN) 9 CDO issuance Borio, “the main manifestation had been the extraordinary expansion of credit risk transfer instruments, which permitted the transfer, hedging and active trading of credit risk as a separate asset class”10 Essentially, the CDS became an risky process that allowed investment banks to expand their lending business without violating any regulation. Demand for CDOs was strong in the boom because buyers could borrow money cheaply, house prices were rising, returns were high for banks and the products carried top ratings11. The global market for CDOs had been $271billion in 2005, growing to $370billion in the early months of 200712. Similarly, CDS’s grew rapidly during the years before the crisis; by 2007 their coverage exceeded $60trillion. As trillions of dollars in risky mortgage-related securities spread through the US financial system, and into much of the global financial system, in the mid 2000s, the financial system became ever more vulnerable to a deflation of the housing bubble.13 This vulnerability could have been avoided if there had been stronger regulation of the new banking methods, or indeed, if the stronger regulation of previous decades had been maintained. Unfortunately, the party stopped, and the consequences of financial innovation and deregulation came home to roost. The prices of subprime mortgage CDOs fell dramatically in 2006, indicating higher perceived default risk of the underlying assets. New York University’s Nouriel Roubini observed that CDOs “were new, exotic, complex, illiquid and misrated by the rating agencies. Who could ever be able to correctly price or value a CDO model?”14 Unease, panic and defaults plagued the credit system. Suddenly, Structured Investment Vehicles (SIVs), set up to handle CDOs, were calling on their parent banks to make good their losses. Next, the credit ratings agencies unleashed a spate of downgrades15. Eventually, by February 2009 it Borio, Claudio, The Financial turmoil of 2007-?: a preliminary assessment and some policy considerations. Monetary and Economic Department, BIS Working Papers, March 2008 10 Crotty, James, Structural causes of the global financial crisis: a critical assessment of the ‘new financial architecture’ Cambridge Journal of Economics 2009, 33, p567 11 12 Mason, Paul Meltdown, The end of the Age of Greed 2009 p96 David M, Kotz (2009) The Financial and Economic Crisis of 2008: A systemic Crisis of Neoliberal Capitalism. Review of Radical Political Economics 2009 41: 305 13 14 Roubini, N. 2008. ‘How will financial institutions make money now that the securitization food chain is broken?’ 15 Blackburn, Robin, The Subprime Crisis New Left Review. March 2008, p68 is estimated that almost half of all CDOs issued had defaulted16. The high ever Source 1B default rate of CDOs had an enormous impact on credit Default rates of CDO assets protection firms like AIG, who had insured investment banks like Lehman’s against default on CDOs on massive scale, not understanding the true underlying risk. Suddenly, what began as a housing crisis plagued other markets. Financial innovation, before the financial crisis, proceeded to the point where important structured financial products were so complex that they became inherently non-transparent and dangerous. Gillian Tett, of the Financial Times, contrasted the myth and the reality of these complex financial innovations during this era: “Innovation became so intense that it outran the comprehension of most ordinary bankers- not to mention regulators. As a result, not only is the financial system plagued with losses on a scale that nobody foresaw, but the pillars of faith on which this new financial capitalist were built have all but collapsed.”17 Not all financial innovation is destructive. Many of the new financial instruments have been introduced to increase credit and homeownership across the US in particular and this is a desirable goal. But some of these products were misleading and designed to be so. It is clear that better regulation could have been applied. Deregulatory acts meant that banks developed innovative ways to make more money, and they appeared attractive and safe because it was difficult to ascertain the real level of risk. Regulators should have ensured that these new products made both cost and risk transparent if the catastrophic bubble was to be avoided. High system-wide leverage In a speech in June 2009, Barack Obama described how a “culture or irresponsibility” was an important cause of the crisis and it is difficult to see how culture could have 16 Financial Times. 2009. Half of all CDOs of ABS failed. 10 February. 17 Tett, G. 2009. ‘Lost through destructive creation, Financial Times, 10 March 2009. been controlled by regulation18. But this culture manifest itself in an unprecedentedly high level of corporate and consumer borrowing, and this level of borrowing could have been limited or regulated. The Federal Reserve slashed interest rates from 6.5% to 3.5% in the first 8 months of 2001, and the in the aftermath of the 9/11, pushed them down to 1%. As Paul Mason described, “money, if you could borrow it, was effectively free”19. US household consumption grew disproportionately to US household income and as a result, US household debt grew significantly before the collapse (illustrated below by Source C). This dramatically increased the vulnerability of the financial system Easy credit conditions combined with Source 1C governmental homeownership policies contributed to a substantial increase in subprime borrowing. Subprime mortgages are, by definition, higher risk lending as there is a higher chance of default. So, the dramatic expansion in these mortgages, particularly 2004-2006, inherently meant that the financial system became vulnerable to toxic/riskier debts. Research by Raghuram Rajan indicated that: “Starting in the early 1970s, advanced economies found it increasingly difficult to grow...the shortsighted political response to the anxieties of those falling behind was to ease their access to credit. Faced with little regulatory restraint, banks overdosed on risky loans". Subprime lending had risen from less than 5% of mortgage lending in the US in 1994 to more than 20% by 2006. 20 This is important because this meant there was substantially more risky borrowing throughout the system. Arguably, more destructive risk taking behaviour took place in the banks themselves. As already discussed, the “Net Capital Rule” replaced the 1977 net capitalization rule’s 12-to-1 leverage limit. In its place, it allowed unlimited leverage for Goldman 18 http://www.cbsnews.com/8301-503544_162-5093760-503544.html 19 Mason, Paul Meltdown, The end of the Age of Greed 2009 http://www.nytimes.com/2012/10/17/business/economy/income-inequality-may-take-toll-on-growth.html? pagewanted=all&_r=0 20 Sachs, Morgan Stanley, Merrill Lynch, Lehman Brothers and Bear Stearns. These banks ramped leverage to multiples of 20-, 30-, even 40-to-1. Stephen Labaton of the New York Times declared: “The exemption would unshackle billions of dollars held in reserve as a cushion against losses on their investments. Those funds could then flow up to the parent company, enabling it to invest in the fast-growing but opaque world of mortgage-backed securities; credit derivatives, a form of insurance for bond holders; and other exotic instruments.”21 In loosening the capital requirements, which are supposed to provide a cushion during turbulent economic times, the agency also decided to allow the big investment firms to use their own computer models to evaluate the riskiness of investments, “essentially outsourcing the job of monitoring risk to the banks themselves”. Over the following years, all the big investment banks of USA took advantage of these looser requirements. This extreme leverage leaves very little room for error. By 2007, the financial system had become, to use Hyman Minsky’s famous phrase, ‘financially fragile’22. Leverage is a double-edged sword that is a powerful ally during boom times, but can quickly become your worst enemy during the ensuing bust. The collapse or bailouts of some of the most highly regarded financial institutions –Fannie Mae, AIG , Lehman Brothers and Merrill Lynch- was principally due to leverage and the reduced capital requirements. Infectious leverage, therefore, became one of the root causes of the financial crisis. So whilst the culture and behaviour cannot be directly regulated, the environment of credit, which encourages that risk-taking behaviour, could have been. It should have been possible to manage the gap between consumption and earnings in the Western world by reducing the availability of credit. Instead, the regulators reduced the capital burdens on banks, allowed interest rates to reduce and eventually created the credit boom which delivered the subprime crisis. Perverse Incentives 21 New York Times. 2008. Agency’s ’04 Rule Let Banks Pile Up New Debt. Published: October 2, 2008 by Stephen Labaton Crotty, James, Structural causes of the global financial crisis: a critical assessment of the ‘new financial architecture’ Cambridge Journal of Economics 2009, 33, 563-580 22 It is reasonably clear that the sustained period of economic growth immediately preceding the crisis led the leading players to become significantly less cautious, and this risk taking behaviour was incentivised, encouraging innovative new products to leverage balance sheets to the limit. This was a third contributory factor that could have been avoided if regulation had been stronger. Barack Obama has joined eminent economists, in claiming that the problem was precisely that bankers knowingly took excessive risks, pushed by two perverse features of the system. Firstly, banks were considered too big and too important to fail, and secondly, the short-term nature of the pay systems meant long term risk was broadly ignored. These perverse incentives often resulted in imprudent business decisions. Firstly, the advocates of the NFA had declared that financial institutions would instinctively be risk-averse because failure would result in losses and bankruptcy. However, in the build up to the 2007 financial crisis, a situation of moral hazard emerged whereby financial institutions had a tendency to take risk, knowing that the potential burden of this risk would be borne by others. As a consequence, compensation structures of the banks gave bankers an incentive to disregard risk. In good years, they stood to make huge amounts of money; in bad years, even if the bank lost money, they would still make healthy sums. This gave employees the incentive to take excessive risks because they could shift their potential losses to shareholders. This disconnect between compensation and bank performance results in a “heads I win” and “tails you lose” bonus system.23 This hazardous environment began with the Federal Reserve’s bailout of Long-Term Capital Management (LTCM) in 1998. With around $126billion in assets and widely regarded as too big to fail, LTCM set the precedent for the Federal Reserve’s bailouts of Bear Stearns, AIG, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac during the crisis. The LTCM was an early warning signal of the same problems that plagued during the 2008 financial crisis. Martin Wolf (2008a) aptly put it, no other industry but finance “has a comparable talent for privatising gains and socialising losses.”24 It has therefore been Kirshnan Sharma, (2012) Financial Sector Compensation and excess risk taking- a consideration of the issues and policy lessons. DESA Working Paper No.115 23 24 http://www.cato.org/sites/cato.org/files/serials/files/cato-journal/2009/1/cj29n1-12.pdf argued that the banks did not act responsibly because they believed they did not have to bear the consequences of their risky actions. Thus, inadequate control of moral hazards often leads to socially excessive risk-taking —and excessive risk-taking is certainly a recurring theme in the current financial crisis.25 It would clearly have been better to control the banks through regulation rather than to pay for their failure. Secondly, the short-term pay structures also played a prominent role in creating an environment that focused on short-term goals and profits. The compensation structures of many of the world’s largest investment banks institutionalised shorttermism and undermined the incentive to take a more responsible longer-term view. The absence of any delayed compensation structure only gives managers an incentive to focus only on the period to their next bonus.26 Record breaking profits 2004-2007 in the financial industry meant more bonuses and incentivised more risk-taking behaviour. Raghuram Rajan argued that “by paying huge bonuses on the basis of short-term performance….banks create gigantic incentives to disguise risk-taking as value creation”.27 Therefore, the global financial crisis of 2007 can also be partly blamed on the remuneration policies within financial institutions. According to Turner (2009) “There is a strong prima facie case that inappropriate incentive structures played a role in encouraging behaviour which contributed to the financial crisis”. Executive pay linked short-term profits to bonuses, had no consideration for exposure to risktaking28. There is little doubt that pay levels incentivised executives to pursue high risk strategies. Since the crisis, there is a widespread view that whilst pay linked to performance is vital, it is also necessary for rewards to be withheld until the risk taken in the short term is fully understood. If the high street element of banks had been either separated or secured, the “casino” element of banks could have been allowed to suffer the consequences of failure. If banker’s bonuses were affected by later losses, the risk taking would reduce. 25 http://www.cato.org/sites/cato.org/files/serials/files/cato-journal/2009/1/cj29n1-12.pdf 26 Kevin Dowd Moral Hazard and the Financial Crisis page 144 27 Financial Times (2008) Regulators should intervene in banker’s pay by Martin Wolf. Published 15th January 2008 28 P.Gregg, S.Jewell et al. 2011. Executive Pay and Performance: Did banker’s bonuses cause the crisis? P5 Conclusion There was nothing simple about the financial crisis of 2007-2010 and there were a wide range of factors at play. The explosive combination of enormous and growing debt level, new financial product which was complex and poorly understood, and lucrative and unrestrained reward for risk taking meant that a crisis was inevitable. But each of these ingredients could have been controlled by regulation and if credit control had been tighter, products made simpler and reward more moderate, the boom and bust of the period would have been much reduced. Instead, dazzled by a belief that the free market solution would protect itself and deliver growth, the regulators stepped aside and the conditions for the crisis were left uncontrolled. Therefore, the root of the crisis began in the 1970s with the introduction of the neoliberal, freemarket capitalism which consequently pursued intense deregulation. b)In light of your discussion in part a), answer the following question: Could Lehman Bros.’ collapse have been avoided if it had followed a different business model? (50 marks). Lehmans Historic Share Price (h p:// bespokeinvest.type pad.com/bespoke/ 2008/06/lehmanleh-the.html) The financial crisis of 2007/8 had a devastating effect on all of the Worlds banks and most of the world’s major economies, and it is clear that regardless of the business model which might have been adopted by Lehman Bros, it would have been unable to avoid serious consequences. But the fact is, Lehman Bros collapsed in the same environment in which other similar banking operations survived, and it is illogical to believe that this collapse could not have been avoided. This section is going to analyse how Lehman Brothers’ business strategy resulted in its own demise. The business model adopted by Lehmans from 2002, under the leadership of Chief Executive Richard S.”Dick” Fuld meant that it was in the worst possible position as the environment changed. Its business model focused on a ruthless growth strategy that invested in illiquid, innovative assets on an enormous scale primarily through unsustainable leverage. And it had a corporate pay structure that incentivised risk- tt taking behaviour like no other player. If the cause of the crisis, as discussed, was increased and unsustainable credit driven by highly leveraged banks finding innovative ways to take greater risk, then it is entirely unsurprising that Lehman Bros fell first and fell hardest. This report concludes that there were 2 structural flaws to Lehman’s business strategy. I plan to explain how Lehman became more highly leveraged than its competitors and pursued financial innovation more rigorously primarily because of a prideful, disillusioned management incentivised by short-term pay structures. Financial Innovation This following section will analyse how Lehman’s business model aimed at achieving rapid growth, but the banks investments were primarily weighted towards illiquid assets such as mortgages29. By not investing so heavily in financially innovative products, that have proven lethal since the collapse, Lehman Brothers may have avoided bankruptcy. Traditionally an investment bank, Lehman Brothers rapidly advanced into new areas, including asset management services, proprietary trading and capital market. It quickly expanded into new products that boosted income at the expense of taking on substantially more risk30. It was the higher leverage, allied to the more significant use of new, innovative and ultimately high-risk product that created the fatal flaws in the Lehman strategy. In particular, Lehman’s strategy was to invest heavily in 2 markets which have proven to be deadly and illiquid; Mortgage-Backed Securities and Credit Default Swaps. When housing prices were booming, mortgage-backed securities were one of the hottest investments on Wall Street. The ravenous appetite for these securities, and the rich commissions reaped by those selling them, encouraged the underwriting of everriskier loans that failed when the housing bubble popped.31 Recognising the opportunities of MBS trading, Lehman rapidly expanded these activities from 2000-2009. Lehman’s acquisition of BNC Mortgage and Aurora Loan services eventually resulted in Lehman securitizing $146,000,000,000 in MBSs in 29 http://jenner.com/lehman/docs/debtors/LBEX-DOCID%201401225.pdf 30 Lehman Brothers Case Pack 31 http://articles.latimes.com/2012/apr/27/business/la-fi-compensation-20120427 2006 alone32. This was a dramatic 10% increase from 2005 and dramatically more than rivals. Eventually in 2007, Lehman Brothers would become America’s largest underwriter of property loans Another factor adding to Lehman’s catastrophe was their involvement in the CDS markets. Lehman was accused of packaging MBSs into Collateralised Debt Obligations, performing Credit Default Swaps with insurers such as AIG and therefore effectively self-eroding the value of these securities. Paul Mason explained how CDSs “never worked as an insurance policy against default; but they did work as a new way of moving liabilities off-balance sheet”.33 CDSs are notoriously illiquid, complicated, and non-transparent and widely represent what Warren Buffet described as “weapons of financial mass destruction.”34 As interest rates rapidly increased and house prices dropped, a substantial decline in the subprime market set in. By 2006, default rates on subprime mortgages became dangerously high; increasing to 7.5% from lows of 2.4%. Lehman’s wide exposure to the MBS and CDS markets meant that the investment bank suffered cataclysmically as defaults on subprime mortgages became problematic Lehman’s exposure to subprime defaults is well demonstrated by source 2b. In 2008, Lehman’s assets were substantially more vulnerable to a housing collapse compared to competitors. Mortgages accounted for 60% of their asset portfolio. Lehman’s subprime lending arm, BNC mortgage, quickly shut down in 2007and its toxic lending quickly unravelled. In 2008, Lehman announced a $2.5billion write-down due to defaults on commercial real estate- substantially greater losses than rival.35 Lehman’s executive decisions focused on unprecedented growth that eventually meant Lehman was critically exposed to innovative markets that have, in hindsight, proven illiquid, unstable and hazardous. Unfortunately, their decisions to actively trade in the CDS market, insuring their risky and toxic CDOs, eventually had catastrophic consequences in other markets. High(er) Leverage 32 Duncan, Sawyer. 2012. Causes of Collapse: The Failure of Lehman Brothers Holdings, Inc. The University of Georgia, page8 33 Mason, Paul. Meltdown. The end of the age of greed. Page 87 34 http://www.creditwritedowns.com/2008/10/lehman-brothers-primer-on-credit.html 35 Why Lehman Brothers Collapsed. Cliff D’Arcy on 14 September 2009. ARTICLE Another deadly element to Lehman’s business strategy was its increasing leverage in the run up to the crisis. Lehman Brothers' bankruptcy was a direct result of its highrisk and aggressive leverage policy. As already discussed in part a) leverage for the industry increased significantly and was a key driver of improved profitability before the crash. So, in the run up to the financial crisis of 2007, Lehman substantially increased their leverage ratio in order to increase their lending activities and, in turn, increase their profits. Following the SEC amendment governing investment bank leverage in 2004, Lehman retained significantly less capital on reserve to protect against losses or defaults.36 The Net Capital Rule meant a “relaxation of the leverage limit for investment banks from $12 to $30 per $1 of capital”37. Lehman’s business model focused primarily on unprecedented, rapid growth. This meant expanding the net balance sheet and leverage. Therefore, a destructive element of Lehman’s ambitious strategy was that it became too highly leveraged compared to the financial industry. Before 2007, for instance, Lehman swelled its balance sheet by almost $300 billion through the purchase of securities often backed by residential and commercial real estate loans. But in the same period, the firm added a miniscule $6 billion in equity.38 As a result, Lehman’s leverage ratio increased 28% from 2004-2007, consistently retaining a higher leverage than competitors. 39 Another element of Lehman’s financial policy that proved destructive was their short-term debt financing. In the period leading up to the company’s bankruptcy filing, Lehman was relying on up to $200billion of short-term financing per day.40 By Feb 2008, Lehman were operating a short term debt ratio of up to 54.59%, so any minor depreciation in their assets was going to have an enormous impact on the efficacy of the firm.41 Lehman Brothers had extremely high quantities of subprime mortgages in their securitisation pipelines and once doubts 36http://clubs.cob.calpoly.edu/~cmiller/552/cases%20without%20teaching%20notes/Lehman%20on%20the%20brink.pdf 37 Duncan, Sawyer. 2012. Causes of Collapse: The Failure of Lehman Brothers Holdings, Inc. The University of Georgia, page11 38http://money.cnn.com/2008/09/15/news/companies/lehman_endofwallstreet_tully.fortune/ 39 http://jenner.com/lehman/docs/debtors/LBEX-DOCID%201401225.pdf Lehman Brothers Holdings Inc, et al, Debtors, Chapter 11 Case No. 08-13555(JMP). United States Bankruptcy Court, Southern District of new York (2010) 40 41 http://www.slideshare.net/rakeshsancheti/fall-of-lehman-brother were raised about the accuracy of the ratings and about their value, short-term lending to Lehman dried up- literally overnight. Lehmans also manipulated statements and accounts to deceive investors and used techniques to reduce its reported leverage. Lehman used a scheme called Repo 105 to deliberately undervalue its liabilities, and this also had an impact on their leverage ratio. It was a trick allowing Lehman to sell packages of mortgages, Treasury bonds, Eurobonds, even Canadian government instruments, on a temporary basis at the end of an accounting quarter, with an obligation to buy them back a few weeks later. It made Lehman’s balance sheet look healthier than it was. This allowed Lehman to hide almost $50billlion worth of assets.42 Other investment banks did not actively partake in Repo 105 transactions as persistently as Lehman Brothers, and this strategic decision made Lehmans much more vulnerable to a credit or liquidity crisis. In fact, Goldman Sachs and Morgan Stanley, competitors with Lehman who survived the financial sollapse, said they have never used any such transactions.43 Ultimately, Lehmans high leverage ratio meant that the company was insufficiently protected from the collapse of the subprime market. Regulation limiting leverage ratios may have lessened the magnitude of the subprime crisis as this essay has already argued. But in the absence of regulation, Lehman’s chose a strategy that delivered higher leveraged debt than its competitors, when it would have been better protected had it chosen to maintain a better capital positions. Unfortunately, because of its extraordinary growth strategy, Lehman had primarily weighted most of this enormous leverage towards illiquid assets such as mortgage backed securities and CDSs44. This next section will analyse how these executive decisions were directly encouraged by Lehman’s executive pay structure. Perverse Incentives As part a) discovered, perverse incentives were a major cause of excessive risk taking behaviour. This section is going to analyse how Lehman’s executive pay structures incentivised their management, under Dick Fuld, to pursue a ruthless growth strategy 42 http://www.guardian.co.uk/business/2010/mar/12/lehman-brothers-repo-105-enron 43 Financial Times (March 13, 2010) Lehman File Rocks Wall-Street. By Francesco Guerrera and Henny Sender 44 http://jenner.com/lehman/docs/debtors/LBEX-DOCID%201401225.pdf that was highly leveraged and that invested heavily in risky markets. The executive decisions to increase issuance of MBSs and to increase leverage were directly the consequence of a pay structure that incentivised Lehman’s leadership to take much more risk in a much more dangerous environment. Therefore the underlying weakness of Lehman’s business strategy was that its direction was too strongly influenced by a prideful, incentivised executive. Of course, there is nothing unusual about outrageous pay structures in the financial industry. What was unique to Lehman was the effect that their pay structures had on their management’s business decisions. The huge bonuses meant that their executive management mercilessly pursued short-term growth in fragile markets. Wide exposure to the subprime collapse and unsustainable leverage were directly the consequence of pay packages that incentivised Lehman’s management to pursue short-term, limited growth. The structure of executive compensation at Lehman, from 2000-2008, shows executives were incentivised to improve short-term earnings at the cost of excessively high risk of large losses in the medium term.45 As a result of prosperous times, Lehman Brothers paid out around $1billion to their top executive team in cash bonuses and equity sales between 2000 and 2008 which they did not pay back following the collapse. The top executives at Lehmans almost expected to earn between $8million-$51million each through cash, stock and other compensation in 2007, months before the bankruptcy of their company. Between 2000 and 2007, Lehman paid Dick Fuld a total of $350 million, an astounding sum for a company Lehman's size.46 Lehman pursued a rapid growth strategy from 2006. Driven by huge bonus structures, Lehmans management sought 13% annual growth in revenues supported by “an even faster increase in the firm’s balance sheet, total capital base and risk appetite”. Lehman’s management quickly ramped up its illiquid investment portfolio manipulating their risk tests, raising and exceeding all types of risk limits.47 As already discussed, in the run up to the financial crisis, Lehman became one of the largest underwriters of illiquid securities. This allowed greater revenues, greater profits and greater bonuses. Kentaro Umezaki illustrated Lehman’s risk taking- “the Bebchuk, L.A., Cohen, A & Spamann, H. (2009) The Wages of Failure: Executive Compensation at Bear Stearns and Lehman 2000-2008. The Harvard John M. Olin Discussion paper Series, pp1-27 45 46 Kevin Dowd Moral Hazard and the Financial Crisis page 151 47 Anton Valukas Report majority of the trading business’s focus is on revenues, with balance sheet, risk limit, capital or cost implications being a secondary concern.”48. Lehmans decision to ramp up leverage was only to continue with excessive, unsustainable growth that guaranteed profits and bonuses, for the executives, in times of prosperity. There have been numerous studies suggesting that pay arrangements at the large investment banks incentivised their executives to take excessive risk. In particular, a 2009 study by Harvard University, looked at the pay structure at Lehmans “Although there is a possibility that the executives decisions could be due to their failure in recognizing risks, the role of their pay arrangements in influencing excessive risktaking behaviour cannot be dismissed.”49 Therefore, this essay argues that Lehman’s executives were incentivised to pursue a higher risk strategy, by taking a more aggressive view of the risk than its competition. Implementing short-term pay structures meant that Lehman’s executive had no incentive to consider long-term risks which eventually encouraged enormous leverage and dangerous financial engineering. Conclusion The short answer to the question of what caused Lehman’s collapse is to lay blame at the feet of Ben Bernanke and Henry Paulson. As representatives of the Federal Reserve and US Treasury, they held the fate of Lehman in their hands. It is undeniable that a bailout would have saved Lehman. In 2006, they had found a way to bail out Bear Stearns from a similar position, so if the will to support Lehman was there, they could have also helped Lehman.50 Of course it is true that the collapse of Lehman Brothers was avoidable if a different strategy had been adopted. There are numerous examples of investment banks recognising and avoiding the “credit-fuelled craziness”. JP Morgan for example took prudent actions and resisted the temptation to leverage up meanwhile some investment banks such as Lazard and Evercore Partners in the US did not participate 48 http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2010-06-11/lehman-probe-lesson-avoid-big-trouble-by-shunning-stupid-e-mail-terms.html Bebchuk.L, Cohen et al “The Wages of Failure: Executive Compensation at Bear Stearns and Lehman 2000-2008” Yale Journal on Regulation, Vol. 27, 2010, pp. 257-282 49 Rikard Smistad (2011) The Failure of Lehman brothers: Was it preventable? If so, How? Recommendations for going forward. SMC University 50 in the securitisation of mortgages at all.51 Whilst the first part of this paper rightly concludes that the crisis itself could have been avoided if stronger regulation had been in place to control credit, complexity and reward, it is clearly true Lehman could have avoided bankruptcy because many causes of the Lehmans collapse stem from Lehman’s own internal management decisions. The moral hazard environment embedded at Lehman Brothers was out of control. Instead of “creating value” the practices of financial engineering/innovation, huge leverage, aggressive accounting and dodgy credit rating have enabled the executives at Lehman to walk away with the loot. Being unconstrained by risk management and a lot of the time plainly ignoring it, corporate governance and financial regulation, Lehman’s executive pursued an unsustainable growth strategy that resulted in the collapse of one of the world’s fourth largest investment bank. Lehman’s business model, more so than the rest of Wall Street, relied on leveraging up equity and using all the debt to accumulate a giant portfolio of securities. Its failure was the result of an antiquated, risky strategy that depended on macroeconomic luck. That strategy was self-serving as it grossly overcompensated greedy employees for being in the right place at the right time.52 Lehman’s collapse was the result of 2 factors; the change of the economic environment and the risky business model adopted. Assisted by the lack of financial regulation it was an enormous oversight of the risks involved. Lehman pursued a business model that was more highly leveraged, more innovative and rewarded risk taking more generously than all its competition at a time and in a market in which all these things were already overheating. Fuld’s business approach even advocated accounting malpractice similar to the Enron scandal of 2001.Nothing was to stand in the way of the success he expected. Even as the market collapsed, he was convinced of the veracity of a counter cyclical growth strategy. Lehman Brothers were operating a policy that meant that they were the Lemming at the front. It is therefore unsurprising that they were the first to go over the cliff. Jeffrey Friedman (2009) A Crisis of Politics, not economics: Complexity, Ignorance and Policy Failure. Critical Review 21(2-3): 127-183. 51 52http://money.cnn.com/2008/09/15/news/companies/lehman_endofwallstreet_tully.fortune/ Anton Valukas Lehman’s Bankruptcy Report. United States Bankruptcy Court, Southern District of New York. Last accessed Tuesday, 30th April 2013(h p://jenner.com/lehman/) Bard. (2009). One Lesson from the 1930s: Financial Regula on Has to Be Bold. Available: h p://www.hu ngtonpost.com/mitchell-bard/one-lesson-from-the-1930s_b_216901.html. Last accessed 29th March 2013 Barker, D. (2012). Is Deregula on to Blame for the nancial crisis.Available: h p:// newsandinsight.thomsonreuters.com/Securi es/Insight/2012/07_-_July/ Is_deregula on_to_blame_for_the_ nancial_crisis_/. Last accessed 12th April 2013. Bebchuk.L, Cohen et al “The Wages of Failure: Execu ve Compensa on at Bear Stearns and Lehman 2000-2008” Yale Journal on Regula on, Vol. 27, 2010, pp. 257-282 Blackburn, Robin, The Subprime Crisis New Le Review. March 2008 Borio, Claudio, The Financial turmoil of 2007-?: a preliminary assessment and some policy considera ons. Monetary and Economic Department, BIS Working Papers, March 2008 Callan. (2008). Lehman Brothers Leverage Analysis. Available: h p://jenner.com/lehman/ docs/debtors/LBEX-DOCID%201401225.pdf. Last accessed 20th March 2013. Caplan, Du a and Marchinko. (2012). Lehman on the Brink of Bankruptcy: A Case about Aggressive Applica on of Accoun ng Standards. Available: h p://clubs.cob.calpoly.edu/ ~cmiller/552/cases%20without%20teaching%20notes/Lehman%20on%20the%20brink.pdf. Last accessed April 3rd 2013. Clark, A. (2010). Lehman Brothers: Repo 105 and other accoun ng tricks. Available: h p:// www.guardian.co.uk/business/2010/mar/12/lehman-brothers-repo-105-enron. Last accessed 21st April 2010. Cro y, James, Structural causes of the global nancial crisis: a cri cal assessment of the ‘new nancial architecture’ Cambridge Journal of Economics 2009, 33, 563-580 David M, Kotz (2009) The Financial and Economic Crisis of 2008: A systemic Crisis of Neoliberal Capitalism. Review of Radical Poli cal Economics 2009 41: 305 Dowd, K. (2009). Moral Hazard and the Financial Crisis. Cato Journal. 29 (1), 141-166. Duncan, Sawyer. 2012. Causes of Collapse: The Failure of Lehman Brothers Holdings, Inc. The University of Georgia, Financial Times (2008) Regulators should intervene in banker’s pay by Mar n Wolf. Published 15th January 2008 Financial Times (2010) Lehman File Rocks Wall-Street. By Francesco Guerrera and Henny Sender. Published 15th March 2010 Financial Times, Te , G. 2009. ‘Lost through destruc ve crea on. Available: h p:// www. .com/cms/s/0/0d55351a-0ce4-11de-a555-0000779fd2ac.html#axzz2S2hzPyj8 Last accessed: 10th March 2009. tt tt tt ti ti ti tt ti tt tt ti ti ti ti fi ft fi ti ti ti fi ti ti ti tt ffi ti tt ti ft tt Financial Times. (2009). Half of all CDOs of ABS failed. Published 10th February 2009. tt fi Bibliography Financial Times. Gillian Te and Paul. J Davies Out of the shadows: How banking’s secret system broke down. December 16 2007. Last accessed (h p://www. .com/cms/s/ 0/42827c50-abfd-11dc-82f0-0000779fd2ac.html#axzz2QdvioNXN) Gilani, Shah, How Deregula on Eviscerated the Banking Sector Safety Net and Spawned the US Financial Crisis. Money Morning, 13th January 2009. Last accessed (h p:// moneymorning.com/2009/01/13/deregula on- nancial-crisis/) Gregg, P and Jewell, S. (2011). Department of Economics; London School of Economics & Poli cal Science (LSE). Execu ve Pay and Performance: Did Bankers’ Bonuses Cause the Crisis?. 1 (1), 1-45. Hamilton. (2012). Lehman Bros. elite stood to get $700 million.Available: h p:// ar cles.la mes.com/2012/apr/27/business/la- -compensa on-20120427. Last accessed 20th April 2013. Harrison. (2008). Lehman Brothers: a primer on Credit Default Swaps.Available: h p:// www.creditwritedowns.com/2008/10/lehman-brothers-primer-on-credit.html. Last accessed 13th April 2013. Je rey Friedman (2009) A Crisis of Poli cs, not economics: Complexity, Ignorance and Policy Failure. Cri cal Review 21(2-3): 127-183. John Lanchaster (2010). Whoops; Why Everyone owes and no one can pay. Washington: Penguin. 1-256. Kirshnan Sharma, (2012) Financial Sector Compensa on and excess risk taking- a considera on of the issues and policy lessons. DESA Working Paper No.115 Lehman Brothers Holdings Inc, et al, Debtors, Chapter 11 Case No. 08-13555(JMP). United States Bankruptcy Court, Southern District of new York (2010) Lowrey. (2012). Income Inequality May Take Toll on Growth. Available: h p:// www.ny mes.com/2012/10/17/business/economy/income-inequality-may-take-toll-ongrowth.html?pagewanted=all&_r=1&. Last accessed 15th March 2013. Montopoli. (2009). Obama on Fixing 'Culture of Irresponsibility'.Available: h p:// www.cbsnews.com/8301-503544_162-5093760-503544.html. Last accessed 3rd April 2013. New York Times. 2008. Agency’s ’04 Rule Let Banks Pile Up New Debt. Published: October 2, 2008 by Stephen Labaton Paul Mason (2011). Meltdown; The End of the Age of greed. 2nd ed. London: Verso. 1-256 Rikard Smistad (2011) The Failure of Lehman brothers: Was it preventable? If so, How? Recommenda ons for going forward. SMC University Roubini, N. 2008. ‘How will nancial ins tu ons make money now that the securi za on food chain is broken’ 1-29 Sandler, L. (2010). `Stupid' Lehman E-Mails Didn't Stay `Just Between Us. Available: h p:// www.bloomberg.com/news/2010-06-11/lehman-probe-lesson-avoid-big-trouble-byshunning-stupid-e-mail-terms.html. Last accessed 1st May 2013. ti tt tt ti tt tt tt tt ft ti tt ti tt fi fi ti ti ti ti ti ti fi tt ti ti ti ti ti ti ti ff Tully, S. (2008). The End of Wall Street. Available: h p://money.cnn.com/2008/09/15/news/ companies/lehman_endofwallstreet_tully.fortune/. Last accessed 15th March 2013. ti Whalen, Charles. The US Credit Crunch of 2007. A Minsky Moment. The Levy Economics Ins tute of Bard College No,92, 2007 p14.