Uploaded by Sumeet Gupta

essay on neuroeconomics and bellman equation in the context of economics

advertisement
ECC3800 Essay
Abstract
Richard Bellmans main contribution to the field of economics was the Bellman equation. It is a
crucial condition of optimisation that enables the method known as dynamic programming. This
revolutionised game theory and is extensively used in recursive economics, being used to calculate
the expected cumulative reward over time. There has been recent discussion around the usefulness
of the equation given its computational difficulties and its assumptions like perfect knowledge and
rationality. However, via the use of other mathematical techniques and the rise of heterodox
economics, this equation has seen even more use and utility.
Assignment
Richard Bellman's key idea is the Bellman equation. It states that the value of a decision problem at a
time period is equal to the maximum of the payoff from initial choices and the value of the
remaining decision problem that results from those initial choices. It is a condition for the
optimization method dynamic programming. In this method, the value of a decision in a time period
is written in terms of pay off from the value of initial choices, with the value of the remaining
decisions resulting from the initial choices. In doing so, a multi-period planning optimisation problem
is broken into a series of simpler problems. The Bellman equation can be used to calculate an agents
expected reward if it follows optimal policy and study optimal behavior of agents such as firms and
consumers.
There are three components to the bellman equation. The objective function is the optimisation
problem that describes the main objective. This objective may be utility maximisation, cost
minimisation etc. Given that dynamic programming reduces multi time period problems into simpler
steps at different time periods, it is necessary to track how the problem evolves over time. The
information about the situation in any time period is called the state variable. As an example, todays
cost of labour would be one of many state variables for a company deciding how much expansion in
operations is needed. Control variables are factors that influence the state variable, chosen at any
given time period. As an example, labour supply is one of many control variables that will influence
the state variable cost of labour.1 The Bellman Equation demonstrates an optimisation problem can
be stated in a recursive form known as backward induction, stating the relationship between the
value function in one period and the next. Starting from the last time period, work backwards until
the first time period rule is derived. The Bellman equation can be expressed:
V(s) = max_a [R(s, a) + γ V(s')]
where:
V(s) is the value of state s
a is an action
R(s, a) is the immediate reward for taking action a in state s
γ is a discount factor, typically between 0 and 1
V(s') is the value of the next state s', which is reached by taking action a in state s
1
Bellman, R.E. (2003) [1957]. Dynamic Programming. Dover.
The discount factor γ is used to balance the importance of immediate rewards versus future
rewards. A higher discount factor will place more weight on immediate rewards, while a lower
discount factor will place more weight on future rewards.
The Bellman equation has been modified by contemporary debate. As economics moved away from
the neoclassical assumptions of perfectly rational and knowledgeable agents, some fundamental
criticisms of the bellman equation arose:
A) It assumes that the agent knows the state of the world with certainty, in other words, the
agent has perfect knowledge of their environment.
B) It assumes that the environment in which the agent is stationary, i.e the reward/utility
function and probabilities do not change over time.
C) It assumes agents can perfectly optimise their behaviour under high stress or rapidly
changing conditions, meaning it assumes that an agent will be able to formulate optimal
solutions to every problem.
D) It assumes that there is a single decision-maker who is trying to maximize their own utility
even though its multiple decision-makers interacting with each other.
E) It relies on the agent making optimal decisions in every step of the way.
F) Using dynamic programming to solve concrete problems is complicated by informational
difficulties, such as choosing the unobservable discount rate. There are computational issues
due to the volume of of possible actions and potential state variables which have not been
resolved.
These criticisms lead to economists using other tools in conjunction with the bellman equation, thus
modifying the way the bellman equation is used. Some of the major tools that are used by
economists in tandem with the bellman equation include:
A) Stochastic programming: Since stochastic dynamic programming deals with problems where
the current and future period states are random, it is used where the decision-maker faces
uncertainty. The Bellman equation can be modified to incorporate uncertainty using
stochastic dynamic programming by taking the expectation over the possible future states of
the world. 22
B) Game theory: The Bellman equation can be modified to incorporate the interaction of
multiple decision-makers using game theory by formulating the dynamic optimization
problem as a sequential game. 4
The Bellman equation and its consequential formulation of the dynamic programming method of
solving optimisation problems has been transformative, being used by many contemporary
economists. Lars Ljungqvist and Thomas Sargent use dynamic programming to study many
theoretical questions in monetary policy, fiscal policy, taxation, economic growth and labor
economics.5 Avinash Dixit and Robert Pindyck also used it to theoretically analyse capital budgeting.6
2
Başar, Tamer; Olsder, George J. (1999) Stochastic Dynamic Games: Foundations and Applications. SIAM.
Stokey, Nancy; Lucas, Robert E.; Prescott, Edward (1989). Recursive Methods in Economic Dynamics. Harvard
University Press.
4 Stokey, Nancy; Lucas, Robert E.; Prescott, Edward (1989). Recursive Methods in Economic Dynamics. Harvard
University Press.
5 Ljungqvist, Lars; Sargent, Thomas (2012) Recursive Macroeconomic Theory (3rd ed.). MIT Press.
6 Dixit, Avinash; Pindyck, Robert (1994) Investment under Uncertainity. Princeton University Press.
2
Accounting for irrationality in economic decision making is difficult as expressing irrational behaviour
in mathematical formalism makes for complex (or even impossible) modelling. Though the bellman
equation has furthered our understanding of the “rational” agent, modelling actual economic agents
accurately has seen significantly slower progress. Even so, emerging heterodox fields like
neuroeconomics (study of the relationship between the nervous system and economic decision
making) that are more grounded in the analysis of behaviour have made great use of the bellman
equation, reinforcing its applicability and differing interpretations. One use of the Bellman equation
in neuroeconomics is to model the neural basis of intertemporal choice. Researchers have used the
Bellman equation to develop models of how the brain represents and evaluates the value of
intertemporal choices including changes in brain's response to intertemporal choices with
development and effect of neurological disorders on brain's response to intertemporal choices.
In a study by Montague et al. (2004), functional magnetic resonance imaging (fMRI) was used to
measure the brain activity of participants during intertemporal choices. The researchers found that
the activity in the brain region ventromedial prefrontal cortex (VMPFC) was correlated with the
value of the participants' intertemporal choices. The researchers developed a computational model
of intertemporal choice based on the Bellman equation, finding that the model could accurately
predict the activity in the VMPFC. This suggests that the VMPFC may play a role in representing and
evaluating the value of intertemporal choices.7
REFERENCE LIST
1. Bellman, R.E. (2003) [1957]. Dynamic Programming. Dover.
2. Başar, Tamer; Olsder, George J. (1999) Stochastic Dynamic Games: Foundations and Applications.
SIAM.
3. Stokey, Nancy; Lucas, Robert E.; Prescott, Edward (1989). Recursive Methods in Economic Dynamics.
Harvard University Press.
4. Ljungqvist, Lars; Sargent, Thomas (2012) Recursive Macroeconomic Theory (3rd ed.). MIT Press.
5. Dixit, Avinash; Pindyck, Robert (1994) Investment under Uncertainity. Princeton University Press.
6. Montague, P. R., Hyman, S. E., & Cohen, J. D. (2004). Computational dopamine and the mesolimbic
system. Neuron, 43(2), 759-767.
7. Peter J. Hammond. Rationality in Economics
https://web.stanford.edu/~hammond/ratEcon.pdf
7
Montague, P. R., Hyman, S. E., & Cohen, J. D. (2004). Computational dopamine and the mesolimbic system.
Neuron, 43(2), 759-767.
Download