See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.net/publication/227371372 Sports Economics Article in Australian Economic Review · September 2009 DOI: 10.1111/j.1467-8462.2009.00562.x · Source: RePEc CITATIONS READS 3 9,561 1 author: Ross Booth Monash University (Australia) 19 PUBLICATIONS 199 CITATIONS SEE PROFILE All content following this page was uploaded by Ross Booth on 04 September 2018. The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file. The Australian Economic Review, vol. 42, no. 3, pp. 377–85 For the Student Sports Economics Ross Booth Department of Economics, Faculty of Business and Economics, Monash University 1. Introduction When I am asked which sort of economics I teach, most people express surprise when I tell them that I specialise in sports economics. The follow-up question is usually: What do you do in sports economics? The primary purpose of this article is to give you, the student, a sense of some of the topics covered in several Australian courses in sports economics and the lessons that can be learned by applying economic principles to analyse sport. Some of these lessons have a wider application beyond sport. There are basically two schools of thought on the value of teaching sports economics. The first is that, as many students like sport more than economics, the combination of the two is likely to be appealing and you will learn some economics ‘almost as an aside’, as it were: it is a way of engaging you with economics, of reinforcing and applying some key economic concepts. The other school of thought is that it is an industry worth studying on its own merits and, as it is datarich, it also can provide a useful test of economic theory. Of course, both views are not mutually exclusive. Sports economics typically cuts across several fields of economics, involving microeconomic concepts applied to sport and industrial organisation, labour economics, and public finance. As examples of applied microeconomics in sport, I discuss the use of the principle of comparative advantage in team selection, the economic welfare implications of several methods of ticket distribution and some sources of market power of sports teams and the ways in which they are used. C Television broadcasting rights revenue has changed drastically the landscape of sport in recent decades, with leagues often able to exercise their market power in their negotiations with television networks. Hence, this is a topic that has come to be of significant interest to sports economists; here, I will review briefly some aspects that have been addressed recently. A special feature of sports leagues is that teams in different leagues do not necessarily have the same objectives. Therefore, an important contribution of sports economics has been to show how the behaviour of sports leagues and teams only can be fully understood if we examine the ownership structure of the league and its constituent clubs, as this will affect whether the objective is to maximise profit or to maximise some other objective, such as winning (subject to a budget constraint). Different sports are in competition with other sports and leisure activities, so competitive balance—how even is the competition?— probably matters to sports leagues. Sports economics can shed light on which, if any, of the three major approaches to increasing competitive balance in a professional team sports league (locating teams in similarly sized revenue markets, intervening in the players’ labour market with player drafts and/or salary caps, and revenue-sharing) are likely to be successful. Finally, I will describe how sports economics can give us some insight into a hotly debated topic in the wider community: the real economic impact of mega-sports, the construction of sporting facilities or the presence of a sporting team. 2009 The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research Published by Blackwell Publishing Asia Pty Ltd 378 The Australian Economic Review 2. Applied Microeconomics—Comparative Advantage: Ticket Pricing, Scalping and Economic Welfare The one-semester prerequisite in microeconomics provides the foundation for some interesting applications of microeconomics to the sporting industry and the opportunity to reinforce concepts learnt in the first year. Sports economics can be a useful way of illustrating comparative advantage, a concept that is sometimes baffling to students new to economics. You might be aware of examples of disputes between fans about the best position on the field for a particular player. For example, I can recall some disgruntled supporters of the Western Bulldogs (a team in the Australian Football League (AFL)) querying the wisdom of the coach when playing Chris Grant, arguably the Bulldogs’ best forward at the time, in defence. The answer to this question might be explained by applying the principle of comparative advantage to team selection. Although Chris Grant clearly might be both the best forward and the best defender in the team (an absolute advantage in both positions), Grant will have a position in which his absolute advantage is greatest. It is better for the coach to play Grant in the position where he has a comparative advantage—where his net contribution of goals scored minus goals saved for the team is maximised—that is, where his opportunity cost (in terms of the net goal contribution to the team) is lowest. The coach was not necessarily a fool, but was simply being astute in playing Grant where his comparative advantage lay, even though the coach would not explain it in those terms. In switching Grant from playing in the forward line to the back line, the coach might have been responding to a change in comparative advantage over time (such as a change in Grant’s abilities and/or the development of other small forward options that reduced Grant’s value as a forward and/or the loss of key tall defenders that increased Grant’s value as a defender). In short, perhaps it was the coach who was knowledgeable and the supporters who were ignorant of a basic tenet of economics: the principle of comparative advantage. C September 2009 Achieving economic efficiency in the allocation of resources—or maximising economic welfare by maximising the sum of consumer and producer surpluses—is a key concept in economics, and another that many students find difficult to grasp. The issue of rationing scarce tickets by either a random ballot or a queuing process can be used to illustrate the loss of economic welfare to reinforce the concept. Efficiency requires that tickets are allocated to those who value them the most. A random ballot will mean that the tickets are not allocated necessarily to those willing to pay the most, which therefore will not be efficient. Queuing also results in a loss of consumer surplus as, for some fans, the opportunity cost of the amount of time spent in the queue will not be worth the wait, even if they are prepared to pay the most. The question is posed as to why, if these distribution processes result in economic welfare not being maximised, would the authorities allow this to happen? Moreover, if ‘scalping’ were to increase economic efficiency, why would some authorities be so keen to make it illegal? The answer, of course, is that economic efficiency might not be their only objective. The authorities might have another objective: seeking ‘equity’ in the distribution of tickets. Sports leagues provide good examples of what can give firms considerable market/ monopoly power; that is, there is no close substitute for the product they offer. This can stem from fans’ attachment to a particular team (supporting Carlton is not the same as supporting Collingwood), the geographical location can give a team some monopoly power (it is easier for a fan in the Western District of Victoria to follow Geelong than a team in Melbourne) and often there are significant barriers to entry to a league, such as a licence to be obtained from the league or having a stadium to play in. This market power that is enjoyed by sports teams can explain why a profitmaximising team might prefer to play in front of a less-than-capacity crowd, rather than have a pricing regime that would fill the stadium. Sports teams’ market power also allows them to practise price discrimination. First-degree price discrimination is difficult to achieve, but there are examples of second-degree price 2009 The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research Booth: Sports Economics discrimination in sport, where the price charged depends on the quantity of tickets purchased, a means by which the team can acquire some of the consumers’ surplus. Third-degree price discrimination is also common in sport, where different groups of consumers are charged different prices, thereby exploiting the differences in demand elasticities in order to maximise profit. In the AFL, for example, there are different general admission prices for adults, children aged 6–14 years, and concession holders (such as pensioners and full-time students). 3. Sports Broadcasting Sports broadcasting rights have been fundamental to the growth in earnings in the sports industry. As such, it is interesting to examine the economics of sports broadcasting. It is helpful first to understand the importance of TV ratings to TV networks: advertisers are willing to pay large amounts of money for advertising slots in very popular sports broadcasts and, as a result, the TV networks compete with one another to secure these valuable broadcast rights for millions of dollars. The leagues are typically in strong bargaining positions because they have a sporting product that is very popular and for which there is no close substitute, whilst often there are several networks bidding against one another for the broadcast rights. For long the poor cousin of Australia’s four football codes, soccer has struggled for free-to-air TV coverage. Despite its recent revival, with the new A-League in 2005–2006 and the World Cup qualification in 2006, it still only is broadcast on pay TV. In circumstances where there is a TV network bidding for the first time (Nine and Ten networks for AFL following Seven’s long reign) or a new league environment (such as a new league and/or a change of playing season, as happened in soccer), the costs and revenues might be quite uncertain and it is possible that a network could end up paying too much for the media rights and suffer ‘the winner’s curse’. The impact of the big TV revenues is plain to see in the escalation of salaries for coaches, players and administrators—the high demand for labour being derived from the high demand by TV viewers for sport. The most C 379 lucrative Australian TV contract was for the AFL 2007–2011, where the Seven and Ten networks paid $780 million for 5 years ($156 million per year). A further increase in broadcast rights is one of the key motivations in the AFL’s push to expand into the Gold Coast and western Sydney. In the United States and Europe, the sports broadcasting landscape is much different and, therefore, might impact differently on the structure of various sports. For example, in US baseball, most of the TV revenue is from local TV stations rather than from a shared national contract negotiated by the league on behalf of the teams. As a result, the media revenues for the teams in baseball are much more dispersed than they are in the National Football League in the United States, which only has a national TV contract. Thus, this impacts competitive balance in the respective leagues. There are other issues with big money in sport, such as the TV coverage intruding on the play, whether the big money makes it more difficult for clubs to manage the behaviour of some players, whether the big money overly encourages players to invest in sporting careers (only a few succeed but many fail) or whether the big money encourages risk-taking behaviour that can result in serious long-term injury. There is no doubt, however, that the big money in sport has resulted in more sport being broadcast on TV, while a more professional approach by athletes and administrators has resulted in a ‘better’ quality of play, which is appreciated by most, if not all, fans. 4. Behaviour of Sports Leagues The sporting industry is an excellent one to contrast the different motivations that different types of firms can possess. In the Australian context, there are many sporting organisations that do not pursue profit maximisation, be they either private or public not-for-profit sports organisations. Examples of public not-for-profit organisations in Australia would be the Australian Sports Commission and the Australian Institute of Sport. Examples of private notfor-profit sports organisations are the Victorian Amateur Football Association (VAFA) and 2009 The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research 380 The Australian Economic Review many of its member clubs, such as the Monash Blues Football Club. The key point here is that the behaviour of these sporting organisations cannot be explained in terms of profit maximisation. This provides a point of departure for the analysis of some Australian sports leagues. For example, the A-League in soccer and the National Basketball League (NBL) might be analysed in terms of profit-maximisation principles dominating the incentives of the privately owned teams (and hence leagues), but it would not make sense to try to analyse the behaviour of the AFL clubs in terms of profit maximisation, given that the teams are member-owned and essentially operate to win-maximise (subject to a budget constraint). Indeed, we would expect the behaviour of the AFL, given the nature of the ownership of the teams and their management by an independent commission, to differ from the NBL and the A-League. The National Rugby League (NRL) is an interesting mix, with some of the teams being privately owned and some of the teams being more like member-owned AFL clubs. Another big difference is that the NRL is owned partly by the private sector (News Limited) and partly by the rugby league industry through Australian Rugby League Limited. By way of example, simple two-team league models, based on Fort and Quirk (1995), are a very effective teaching tool that can be used to demonstrate that the distribution of talent between teams will be different just because of a difference in team ownership. The basic point is that there is a limit to the amount of talent that a profit-maximising team owner will hire. But, in the same position, a win-maximising owner would be willing to sacrifice profit and instead hire more talent. In terms of the location of teams, it is much easier for a private owner of a team to move a team from one city to another than it is for a member-owned team to agree to move. The profit-maximising private owner primarily will consider whether the move will increase profits, but member-owners do not get a financial dividend and typically will be reluctant to have their team move because they will no longer be able to watch their own team’s home games ‘live’. Merger is another option, but is viewed by many supporters C September 2009 as a fate worse than death. Thus, leagues comprised of privately owned, profit-maximising teams are more likely to see changes in market location by the relocation/merger of teams than are leagues comprised of memberowned, win-maximising clubs. For these latter leagues, judicious expansion, as currently planned by the AFL, is most likely to be the best strategy. 5. Competitive Balance in Professional Sports Leagues in Australia It is agreed generally by most sports economists that competitive balance matters. The more uncertain the outcome of any single game, the more even the home-and-away season and the more uncertain who will be the champion/ premier team, the more likely that fans will attend matches or watch on TV. However, being contrary, one could point to the English Premier League as one of the world’s most popular and successful competitions, but in which only a few (of the same) teams at the start of each season are thought to have any real chance of taking out the championship. A large part of many sports economics courses in Australia is an analytical comparison of different Australian sports leagues. Often, this involves a focus on the effectiveness of labour market devices and revenue-sharing rules in increasing the competitive balance in leagues comprised of win-maximising clubs (such as in the AFL), as compared with profit-maximising teams in other sports leagues in Australia (such as the NBL and the ALeague) and in sports leagues in Europe and North America. 5.1 Increasing Competitive Balance Assuming that competitive balance is important to a league, what are the policies that a league can adopt to try to increase competitive balance, and will they work? What does economic theory say about their likely success, and is this supported by the empirical evidence? There are three major approaches used by professional sports leagues to try to increase 2009 The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research Booth: Sports Economics competitive balance. They all are aimed, one way or another, at trying to achieve similar amounts of player talent at all teams so that the league will have a higher level of competitive balance than it would otherwise. The first approach is to try to locate the teams in markets of approximately equal size. This should mean that the teams are able to generate approximately the same amounts of revenue from the gate and membership and so be able to afford approximately the same amount of player talent. This can be achieved by careful expansion and contraction of the league. Some leagues use an automatic promotion and relegation system, such as in the English Premier League and in the VAFA. The second approach is to use labour market devices, such as a player draft and/or team salary cap, to try to achieve approximately equal amounts of player talent at each team. In the case of the player draft, the teams usually get access to new talent in the reverse order to which they finished on the ladder at the end of the home-and-away premiership season. The team salary cap imposes a maximum aggregate amount that a club can pay its list/roster of players. The third approach is to use revenue-sharing rules to try to lessen the differences in the clubs’ revenues and, therefore, the differences in the amount of talent that the clubs can afford. Note that revenue-sharing also might be important for clubs’ financial stability as, without it, some clubs might not be financially sustainable. Many authors have spent a considerable amount of time trying to explain different levels of competitive balance in different sports, both in Australia and overseas. There is an especially large amount of literature on the impact of intervention in player labour markets and of the effect of revenue-sharing rules in different institutional settings. In this sense, the analysis of some Australian sporting leagues requires a different set of assumptions to those used overseas and the outcomes of the effects of different policies will be different, depending on different institutional arrangements—notably, the ownership of clubs and the differing objectives that follow—typically, profit maximisation for privately owned clubs and win-maximisation C 381 (subject to a budget constraint) for memberowned or industry-owned clubs. 5.2 Case Study: Player Drafts and Team Salary Caps Economic literature in the United States concludes that player drafts do not work. The socalled ‘Invariance Principle’ is an application of the Coase Theorem to sport: that is, the allocation of resources will be invariant to the ownership of property rights. In other words, the (final) distribution of player talent will be unaltered by a player draft as the talent will move to where its value is highest (as under free agency/free market) through either the cash sales of (net) player talent or the trade of (net) player talent. But, the Invariance Principle does not always hold! In theoretical models, it can be shown that whether or not the Invariance Principle works depends on the objectives of the teams, the wage levels relative to the revenues, whether sales or trades are allowed, and whether a draft is combined with a team salary cap. Suppose the bottom team drafts the best player. As an example, a profit-maximising owner would be willing to sell that player to another team owner in a larger market for more than the small market owner could earn from that player in the small market. But, if the owner were a winmaximiser, then subject to meeting the budget constraint, the win-maximising owner would have no interest in selling or trading the best player to another team as the objective is to winmaximise, not to profit-maximise. Team salary caps are another device often used to increase competitive balance, but this device has the obvious problem of enforcement. If a team salary cap system is difficult to enforce, then at least a player draft system provides some restriction to the accumulation of talent at wealthy clubs. One of the interesting issues in the winmaximising case is whether there is a need for a minimum team salary, as usually is argued in the profit-maximising case. Prima facie, if a club is a win-maximiser and has the revenue to pay the full amount of the team salary cap, then a minimum team salary would not be necessary. Indeed, its imposition by a league in 2009 The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research 382 The Australian Economic Review such circumstances might only force the club into a loss-making situation. A burning issue at present is whether some form of limited free agency would affect adversely competitive balance. If a team salary cap exists and is enforced, there should be no serious adverse effect of its introduction. 6. Economic Impact of Sports Events, Facilities and Teams A contentious issue in many cities is whether a government can justify subsidising either a sporting event, such as the Olympic Games or the Formula 1 (F1) Grand Prix, or a sporting team, either directly or indirectly by way of building a new stadium, such as the ‘rectangular stadium’ for both the Melbourne Storm NRL team and the Melbourne Victory A-League team. The usual justification put forward by governments for any subsidy is that the ‘event’ generates a significant economic impact. But, studies by economists usually conclude that the ‘net’ economic impact of such events is very small and usually are exaggerated by the authorities. The reason for a small net economic impact is that there are usually substitution effects. First, there is the opportunity cost of the government funding of the event. What would the economic impact have been if the funds had been spent on some other public activity, such as a school, hospital or on transport infrastructure? For the private sector, consumer spending on the Grand Prix simply might be a substitute for some other consumption spending in the city. Second, there also might be leakages: many Melburnians might flee the city on the weekend of the F1 Grand Prix, thereby offsetting the positive impact of tourism, and the licence fee charged by overseas F1 boss, Bernie Ecclestone, to stage the Grand Prix does not impact the Victorian economy. However, there could be beneficial ‘qualityof-life’ issues associated with such events, a consumer surplus over and above the ticket price that contributes to economic welfare. Positive externalities and public good aspects of some events—non-rival and non-excludable— C September 2009 might mean that the private sector is reluctant to finance such events because it is unable to capture all the benefits, such as the ‘feel good’ and ‘common bond’ factors provided by the event. For example, even if you are not a F1 fan, you might feel ‘proud’ that Melbourne is able to attract such an event and/or that the race provides an opportunity to ‘connect’ with some people with whom you might not otherwise. The problem is that these benefits are not easy to measure. Moreover, in the case of the producer surplus, most of it accrues to the F1 owner and does not contribute to economic welfare in Victoria. In addition, there are significant negative externalities, in terms of noise, traffic and sporting disruption leading up to, during and after the event. The movement of the starting time to twilight might attract more TV viewers overseas but that is likely to be of benefit mostly to the owners of the F1 Grand Prix through higher broadcast rights revenue. 7. Concluding Remarks Many students love sport; thus, sports economics provides a wonderful opportunity to reinforce and apply some key economic concepts learnt in first-year undergraduate microeconomics to the sports industry. Key concepts can be used to analyse and understand the role that economic incentives play in determining the behaviour of controlling bodies, leagues, clubs, players, fans, sponsors, the media and government. This economic analysis then can be applied to the development of appropriate policies to address economic problems in the sports industry in Australia. 8. Notes on Resources Although there have been many books written on the economics of sports, only in recent years have any suitable broadly based, analytical textbooks become available for use in the classroom for students with a one-semester introduction to microeconomics. The two most suitable textbooks are from the United States: The Economics of Sport by Leeds and von Allmen, first published in 2002, and Sports 2009 The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research Booth: Sports Economics Economics by Fort, first published in 2003. Sandy, Sloane and Rosentraub (2004) take a less analytical view in their textbook, The Economics of Sport: An International Perspective, as do Eschenfelder and Li (2007) in Economics of Sport. The English textbook by Downward and Dawson (2000), The Economics of Professional Team Sports, is more technically advanced and is designed to cater for third-year undergraduates, whilst The Economic Theory of Professional Team Sports: An Analytical Treatment, by Késenne (2007), also is more suited to advanced undergraduate or postgraduate students of sports economics. For Australian sports economics classes, the UScentric nature of the textbooks by Leeds and von Allmen and Fort can be problematic, as much of the detail is not of interest to Australian students. Thus, there is a need to provide additional reference material on Australian and non-US sports. Moreover, much of the US textbook analysis needs to be adapted to the Australian institutional setting. This is not without challenge, but it can make for some interesting differences between some sports in Australia and the rest of the world. To the best of my knowledge, courses in sports economics can be found at Monash, Deakin, La Trobe, Adelaide, Griffith and Queensland universities. However, the number of students taking such courses is still too few to make ‘economic’ the writing of an Australianbased text on sports economics; hence, the reliance on US texts. Despite the absence of an Australian sports economics textbook, the judicious use of an overseas sports economics text, combined with articles by Australian authors, can produce a course that, given the subject matter, will excite some students, whilst at the same time make economics ‘come alive’ for others. Other contributions to the sports economics literature that might be included in a course in sports economics could be from Australian authors, such as Jeff Borland, Braham Dabscheck, Liam Lenten, Robert Macdonald, Mark Stewart and Bob Stewart. A list of some key journals and other key references, particularly from an Australian viewpoint, follows. These are not exhaustive and a search of other books and C 383 journals will bring forth much material that is sure to excite students of sports economics. May 2009 Key Journals European Sport Management Quarterly International Journal of Sport Finance International Journal of Sport Management Journal of Sport Management Journal of Sports Economics Sport Management Review Key References Booth, R. 2004a, ‘The economics of achieving competitive balance in the Australian Football League, 1897–2004’, Economic Papers, vol. 23, pp. 325–44. Booth, R. 2004b, ‘Labour market intervention, revenue sharing and competitive balance in the Australian Football League, 1897–2002’, in International Sports Economics Comparisons, eds R. Fort and J. Fizel, Praeger, Westport, Connecticut. Booth, R. 2005, ‘Comparing competitive balance in Australian sports leagues: Does a salary cap and player draft measure up?’, Sport Management Review, vol. 8, pp. 119– 43. Booth, R. 2006, ‘The economic development of the Australian Football League’, in Handbook on the Economics of Sport, eds W. Andreff and S. Szymanski, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, United Kingdom. Borland, J. 1987, ‘The demand for Australian Rules Football’, Economic Record, vol. 63, pp. 220–30. Borland, J. 2006a, ‘Economic design and professional sporting competitions’, Australian Economic Review, vol. 39, pp. 435– 41. Borland, J. 2006b, ‘Production functions for sporting teams’, in Handbook on the Economics of Sport, eds W. Andreff and S. Szymanski, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, United Kingdom. Borland, J. 2006c, ‘The production of professional team sports’, in Handbook on the 2009 The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research 384 The Australian Economic Review Economics of Sport, eds W. Andreff and S. Szymanski, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, United Kingdom. Borland, J., Chicu, M. and Macdonald, R. D. 2009, ‘Do teams always lose to win? Performance incentives and the player draft in the Australian Football League’, Journal of Sports Economics, viewed March 2009, <http://jse.sagepub.com>. Borland, J. and Lye, J. 1992, ‘Attendance at Australian Rules Football: A panel study’, Applied Economics, vol. 24, pp. 1053–8. Borland, J. and Macdonald, R. 2004, ‘Demand for sport’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, vol. 19, pp. 478–502. Dabscheck, B. 2004, ‘Australian professional team sports in a state of flux’, in International Sports Economics Comparisons, eds R. Fort and J. Fizel, Praeger, Westport, Connecticut. Fort, R. 2000, ‘European and North American sports differences(?)’, Scottish Journal of Political Economy, vol. 47, pp. 431–55. Fort, R. 2006, Sports Economics, Pearson Prentice Hall, Upper Saddle River, New Jersey. Hone, P. and Silvers, R. 2006, ‘Measuring the contribution of sport to the economy’, Australian Economic Review, vol. 39, pp. 412– 19. Lenten, L. 2008a, ‘Is the decline in the frequency of draws in Test match cricket detrimental to the long form of the game?’, Economic Papers, vol. 27, pp. 364–80. Lenten, L. 2008b, ‘Unbalanced schedules and the estimation of competitive balance in the Scottish Premier League’, Scottish Journal of Political Economy, vol. 55, pp. 488–508. Lenten, L. 2009a, ‘Towards a new dynamic measure of competitive balance: A study applied to Australia’s two major professional “football” leagues’, Economic Analysis and Policy, vol. 39, forthcoming. Lenten, L. 2009b, ‘Unobserved components in competitive balance and match attendances in the Australian Football League, 1945–2005: Where is all the action happening?’, Economic Record, vol. 85, pp. 181– 96. Macdonald, R. and Booth, R. 2007, ‘Around the grounds: A comparative analysis of C September 2009 football in Australia’, in The Political Economy of Football in Australia, ed. B. Stewart, Melbourne University Press, Melbourne. Macdonald, R. and Borland, J. 2004, ‘Professional sports competitions in Australia’, in International Sports Economics Comparisons, eds R. Fort and J. Fizel, Praeger, Westport, Connecticut. Siegfried, J. and Zimbalist, A. 2006, ‘The economic impact of sports facilities, teams and mega-events’, Australian Economic Review, vol. 39, pp. 420–7. Stewart, B. 2005, ‘The Australian Football League’s recent progress: A study in cartel conduct and monopoly power’, Sport Management Review, vol. 8, pp. 95– 118. Stewart, B. 2007, The Games Are Not the Same: The Political Economy of Football in Australia, Melbourne University Press, Melbourne. Stewart, M. and Mitchell, H. 2007, ‘A competitive index for international sport’, Applied Economics, vol. 39, pp. 587–603. Stewart, M., Stavros, C. and Mitchell, H. 2007, ‘“Moneyball” applied: Econometrics and the identification and recruitment of elite Australian footballers’, International Journal of Sports Finance, vol. 2, pp. 231– 48. Szymanski, S. 2009, Playbooks and Checkbooks: An Introduction to the Economics of Modern Sports, Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey. Szymanski, S. and Zimbalist, A. 2006, National Pastime: How Americans Play Baseball and the Rest of the World Plays Soccer, Brookings Institution Press, Washington, DC. References Downward, P. and Dawson, A. 2000, The Economics of Professional Team Sports, Routledge, London. Eschenfelder, M. and Li, M. 2007, Economics of Sport, Fitness Information Technology, Morgantown, West Virginia. Fort, R. and Quirk, J. 1995, ‘Crosssubsidisation, incentives and outcomes in 2009 The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research Booth: Sports Economics professional team sports leagues’, Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 33, pp. 1265– 99. Késenne, S. (ed.) 2007, The Economic Theory of Professional Team Sports: An Analytical Treatment, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, United Kingdom. C View publication stats 385 Leeds, M. and von Allmen, P. 2008, The Economics of Sports, Pearson Addison Wesley, Boston. Sandy, R., Sloane, P. and Rosentraub, M. S. 2004, The Economics of Sport: An International Perspective, Palgrave MacMillan, Basingstoke, United Kingdom. 2009 The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research