Economics 114 1 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m living standards that many countries saw since the 1700s. Standard of living is typically measured by GDP per capita. GDP per capita is simply calculated as – GDP per capita = GDP for the year Country s population Gross domestic product (GDP): the total value of everything produced in a given period, typically a year. Also referred to as gross domestic income. When one looks at the trends that GDP per capita has followed over the past millennium. Economists often describe it as a country’s “hockey stick”, due to the shape that the GDP per capita trend has followed, as illustrated by the figure below. From this figure above, it is thus clear that living standards did not grow in any sustained way, for a very long time. When sustained growth eventually occurred in countries differ drastically, describes vast differences in living standards in different 2 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. The emergence of capitalism was brought forth by the increases in average io ut rib st di e/ al rs global spread of a way of organising an economy, which we call capitalism. fo The capitalist revolution: the emergence in the eighteenth century and the eventual ot .N op Sh s. ie UNIT 1: THE CAPITALIST REVOLUTION countries. For some countries, this growth did not occur until they gained independence from colonial rule or interference by European nations. The emergence of capitalism led to advances in technology and product specialisation in products and tasks, which effectively raised daily productivity figures. 1.1 Income inequality A thousand years ago, income inequality looked a lot different. It was much “flatter” than it is currently, as income inequality was not as pronounced. There were differences in income between the different regions of the world; the differences were small compared to what we have now. Economists can say the following two things with certainty – In every country, the rich have much more than the poor. A handy measure of inequality in a country is called the 90/10 ratio, which we define as the average income of the richest 10% divided by the average income of the poorest 10%. More commonly it is also defined as the income of the 90th percentile divided by that of the 10th percentile. There is a huge difference in income between countries. Income distribution is often illustrated as the figure below. 3 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie The countries that took off economically before 1900 are now rich. They, and countries Once measure of living standards is GDP per capita, as identified above. When using this measure, one limitation jumps out immediately – to add up the millions of services and products in a country, economists need to find some measure of how much each product and service is worth compared to one another. Furthermore, economists must also decide which products and services should be included in the GDP calculation, but also how to give a value to each of these things. In practice, the easiest way to do this is by using their prices. When we do this, the value of GDP corresponds to the total income of everyone in the country. Which explains why GDP is sometimes referred to as gross domestic income, as well. The question remains, however, is GDP per capita the right way to measure living standards, or wellbeing? Disposable income Disposable income: an individual’s income (from all sources) received over a given period, minus any transfers the individual made to others, including taxes paid to the government. Disposable income is considered a good measure of living standard, because it represents the maximum number of products and services a person can afford without having to borrow—that is, without going into debt or selling possessions. Is disposable income a good measure of our wellbeing? An individual’s income majorly influences wellbeing, because it allows them to buy goods and services that they need or enjoy. It is, however, an insufficient measure, because there are aspects of wellbeing that cannot be bought. For example, disposable income leaves out: The quality of an individual’s social and physical environment. The amount of leisure time. Goods and services that are provided by the government. 4 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. 1.2 Measuring income and living standards io ut rib st di e/ al rs “flatlands” (the lowest columns on the left). fo income distribution. The countries that took off only recently, or not at all, are in the ot .N op like them, are now in the “skyscraper” (the highest columns on the right) part of an Goods and services produced within a household, e.g. meals or childcare. Average disposable income and average wellbeing The question remains whether average disposable income a good measure of how well off a specific group is? When considering wellbeing, absolute income matters. Absolute income: the Rand value that an individual earns, e.g. R3 000. Research has also shown, however, that individuals care about their relative position in the general income distribution. Individuals report lower wellbeing if they discover they earn less than others in their group. The same average income may result from very different distribution of income between rich and poor individuals within a group. Accordingly, average income may fail to reflect how well off a group of individuals are by comparison to another group. Valuing government goods and services GDP includes goods and services produced and provided by the government, such as law enforcement. These services do contribute to the wellbeing of an individual, but it is not included in disposable income, but it is included in GDP per capita. Therefore, GDP per capita is a better measure of living standards than disposable income. The problem is that government products and services are difficult to value. Typically, we take the prices of goods and services as a rough measure of their value. Seeing as the goods and services produced by government are typically not sold, the only measure of their value is how much it costs to produce. The gaps between what wellbeing means and what GDP per capita measures, economists should be cautious about the use of GDP per capita to measure how welloff people are. One thing is for sure – GDP per capita is undoubtedly telling us something about the differences in the availability of goods and services. Calculation of GDP When estimating the market value of output in the economy for a given period, statisticians use the prices at which goods and services are sold in the market. Nominal GDP is therefore calculated by multiplying the quantities of different goods and services by their prices. Nominal GDP is therefore given as: 5 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m × ot .N op Sh s. ie nominal GDP = is the quantity of good . GDP is also called the GDP at constant prices. Constant prices: the price of a good or service corrected increases and decreased in prices, enabling a unit of currency to represent the buying power in different periods. The real GDP considers price changes over time in order to determine whether the quantity of products and services increased or decreased. It is not possible to measure real GDP directly. Instead, real GDP is calculated as a derivation of nominal GDP, as defined above. To determine the real GDP, the first step is selecting a base year, e.g. 2010. The simplistic version of Real GDP is the quantity in the current year, e.g. 2011, multiplied by the price of that product in the base year (2010). Keeping prices constant at the base year price, therefore gives an economist the opportunity to determine whether the overall quantity of goods and services has changed. Purchasing power parity To compare information across different countries, it is important to choose a set of prices and apply those prices to both countries in the comparison. When considering the prices of different countries, economists typically estimate the GDP per capita using a common set of prices, known as purchasing power parity (PPP). Purchasing power parity (PPP): a statistical correction that allows for goods and services to be compared in different countries that have different currencies, which attempts to achieve equality in the real purchasing power of different currencies. 1.3 History’s hockey stick: Growth in income A ratio scale is typically used for comparing growth rates, but it can also be used to show how GDP per capita doubles over time. When a ratio scale is used, a series that grows at a constant rate looks like a straight line. This is because the percentage (or proportional growth rate) is constant. A steeper line in the ratio scale chart means a faster growth rate. An example of a ratio scale can be seen below, which is an 6 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. of the quantity of goods and services purchased, which is called the real GDP. Real io However, to gauge whether the economy is growing or shrinking, we need a measure ut rib st di is the price of good , e/ al rs fo Where adaptation of the first figure in the chapter, which showed levels of GDP per capita over time. The data points to the left of the figure is very scarce and far apart. This is because less information about GDP per capita was available before the 1800s. A growth rate can be calculated as: growth rate = − Whether an economist wants to compare absolute levels or growth rates, depends on the question that the economist attempts to answer. 1.4 The permanent technological revolution It was not until the eighteenth century that each new generation could look forward to a different life that was shaped by new technology. Remarkable scientific and technological advances in history often occur at more or less the same time as the upward kink in the “hockey stick” of countries in the middle of the eighteenth century. Specifically, important new technologies were introduced in textiles, energy and 7 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie transportation. The cumulative nature of these advancements led to the industrial .N op ot revolution. io n. industry, the following technological advancement(s) saw the true emergence of the Industrial Revolution: the flying shuttle invented by John Kay in 1733, greatly increased the quantity a weaver could produce in an hour. This led to an increased demand for yarn to the point where it became difficult for spinsters to produce sufficient quantities using the wheel technology. James Hargreaves then introduced the spinning jenny in 1764 as a proposed solution to the aforementioned problem. industrial revolution brought new ideas, discoveries, methods, technologies and machines, which make the existing standard obsolete. This process repeats itself often as new ideas and tools are developed. Technology: a process that takes a set of inputs to produce a specific output. Based on the economic definition of technology, a recipe for baking cake can be considered as technology necessary to produce a cake (the output). Alternatively, the technology necessary to produce a cake can also be large-scale machinery, ingredients and labour (machine operators). ut allowed the same output to be produced with less labour. Most notably, in the textiles The rib The revolution started in Britain in the eighteenth century. The Industrial Revolution saw an extraordinary flowering of radical inventions that st di industrialised countries. e/ al which changed agrarian and craft-based economies into commercial and rs fo Industrial revolution: a wave of technological advances and organisational changes Prior to the Industrial Revolution, technology was updated very slowly. The industrial revolution saw technological progress become much more frequent and significant. This is often referred to as the start of the permanent technological revolution, which saw how the time necessary to produce products reduced from generation to generation. The permanent technological revolution associated with capitalism allowed some countries to make a transition to sustained growth in living standards. (Explained in more details in Unit 2). 8 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. Technological improvements in other areas were equally dramatic, for example James Watt’s steam engine in 1776. These engines were gradually improved over a long period of time and were eventually used in industries across the economy. They are an example of what is termed a general-purpose innovation. General-purpose technologies: technological advances that can be applied to many sectors, and spawn further innovations. Computers and electricity are two common examples. The permanent technological revolution has produced a connected world, which everyone is part of. Being “connected” simply means that virtually the entire economy can be sustained without individuals being physically together. They can still collaborate and cooperate through the internet. Technological progress: the change in technology that reduces the inputs required to produce a set output. Technological progress is a process that continues to this day. Accordingly, the process of innovation has also not stopped at the end of the Industrial Revolution. In a capitalist economy, innovation creates temporary rewards for the innovator, which provide incentives for improvements in technology that reduce costs. These rewards are destroyed by competition once the innovation diffuses throughout the economy. (Explained in more details in Unit 2). Many new industries have seen the implementation and application of new technologies These technological innovations change the way that large parts of the economy work which allows for the growth in living standards. These technological innovations also increase the amount of leisure time, which increases living standards. 1.6 Capitalism defined: Private property, markets and firms The capitalist revolution saw the emergence of a new economic system. Economic system: the institutions that organises the production and distribution of goods and services within an economy. An economic system is made up of different institutions, as mentioned above. Institutions: the laws and social customs that governs the way that individuals interact with one another in a society. 9 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie The economic system that emerged from the capitalist revolution was capitalism. This ot .N op term has grown in large popularity over the past century. st di e/ al rs fo Capitalism: an economic system in which private property, markets and firms play an n. io ut rib important role. Capitalism saw the prominence of private property. Private property: the right and expectation that one can enjoy one’s possessions in ways of one’s own choosing, exclude others from their use, and dispose of them by gift or sale to others who then become their owners. Also referred to as private ownership. Private property made it possible that individuals could enjoy possessions in any way that they wanted. Furthermore, they could dispose of these possessions as they wish, as they were the owners of the possessions. Individuals could also exclude others from using the possession, if they so wished. Private property can be owned by an individual, a family, a business, or some entity other than the government. In some economies in the past, key economic institutions included private property, markets and families, because goods were usually produced by families, rather than by firms. In other societies, the government controls production, and decided on the distribution of goods and services. This is called a centrally planned economic system. Most economies today are capitalist. Over the course of human history, the extent of private property has varied. In a capitalist economy, an important type of private property is capital goods. Capital goods: the equipment, buildings, and other durable inputs used in producing goods and services. Raw materials, however, is not included under capital goods as this is referred to as intermediate inputs. The second important institution in a capitalist economy is markets. Market: a way of connecting people who may mutually benefit by exchanging goods and services through buying and selling. Markets provide a means of transferring goods or services from one person to another, but it excludes methods of transferring goods such as theft, gifting, or a government order. Markets differ from these in three respects: 10 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. 1. They are reciprocated, i.e. one party receives a good or service and the other party receives money, or a promise of a later payment, as in the case of credit. 2. They are voluntary, i.e. both parties need to opt in to partake in the process of buying and selling. 3. Markets are competitive. Private property and markets alone do not define capitalism. These important institutions precede capitalism in many countries. The most recent of the three components of a capitalist economy is the firm. Firm: a way of organising production by directing employees to produce goods and services by using sets of capital goods that are owned by one or more individuals within the economy in exchange for wages and salaries. The produced goods and services become the property of the firm, which then sells the goods and services on markets to generate a profit. Firms that make up a capitalist economy virtually include everything in the economy. Certain productive organisations, such as family businesses, non-profit organizations, employee-owned cooperatives, and government-owned entities are not classified as firms, but they also play lesser roles in a capitalist economy. These organisations are not classified as firms, because they do not make profits, or because the owners are not private individuals who own the assets. Even if an organisation takes in unpaid student interns, it is still classified as a firm. Prior to firms being the predominant organisation that produces goods and services, they still existed and played a lesser role than their current role. The current, expanded role of firms, led to a boom in the labour market, which played a very limited role in the past. Labour market: a market that allows employers to offer wages to individuals who agrees to work under the direction of the employer. Employers are on the demand side of the labour market, because they require individuals to perform work for them. Demand side: the side of a market on which the participants offer money in return for another good or service. 11 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie Employees are on the supply side of the labour market, because they are willing ot .N op rs fo Supply side: the side of a market on which participants are offering a good or a Defining capitalism precisely (economically) Capitalism does not refer to a specific economic system, but rather to a class of systems sharing specific characteristics. The way in which the institutions of capitalism (private property, markets, and firms) combine with one another and with other institutions, also differs greatly across countries. Various debates exist about the “true” meaning of capitalism. It is, however, often not the intention to develop a definitive definition of a word. The definition rather acts as a device that makes it easier for individuals to communicate. 1.7 Capitalism as an economic system The three parts of a capitalist economic system are all nested concepts. The figure below illustrates this. The figure above describes the different resultant systems as we add each of the institutions of a capitalist economy. The left-hand circle describes an economy that has private party, which is essentially an economy of isolated families who own their capital goods and the goods they produce, but there is little to no exchange between 12 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. are successful, and they are typically protected from failure, if they perform poorly. io die. Government bodies also tend to be more limited in their capacity to expand, if they ut A striking characteristic of firms is that they can quickly be born, expand, contract and rib st di e/ al service in return for money. the families. In the middle, the economy has private property and markets, i.e. families still produce goods and services, but they exchange these with one another now, using markets. And finally, on the far right, we have a capitalist economy, where firms are now the main producers of an economy, rather than family-based organisations. The following statements explain the interplay that exists among the different institutions of a capitalist economy: Inputs and outputs of the production system is private property. Firms buy inputs on markets, and they sell outputs on markets. From the above, private property is an essential part of the operations of markets. Furthermore, the private ownership of capital goods is also a distinctive hallmark of a capitalist economic system. Capitalist economies differ from earlier economies in the increased magnitude of capital goods used in production. Capitalism combines centralisation with decentralisation. It concentrates power in the hands of owners and managers who then secures the cooperation of employees in production. It also limits the power of owners and other individuals, due to the competition that they face to buy and sell in the markets. It is exactly this combination of competition among firms, and the concentration of power and cooperation within firms that account for capitalism’s success as an economic system. How could capitalism lead to growth in living standards? The emergence of capitalism brought about two major changes. These changed led to an enhancement in the production of individual workers within the organisation. These changes are given below. Technology Firms did not cause technological change, but the competition among firms gave firms strong incentives to adopt and develop new and more productive technologies, and to invest in capital goods. These technological innovations also increase the amount of leisure time, which increases living standards. Specialization The growth of firms’ number of employees, and the expansion of markets, allowed specialisation in tasks and products that was historically unprecedented. 13 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie 1.8 The gains from specialisation .N op ot Capitalism and specialization n. io ut rib st di range of activities. This is true for the following reasons: e/ al rs fo Economies tend to become better at producing things when they focus on a limited Learning by doing. Employees acquire skills as they produce things. Difference in ability. Some countries are better at producing certain things due to skills or natural factors, such as soil quality. Economies of scale. Producing a large quantity of something is often more cost-effective than producing smaller quantities. Economies of scale: the doubling of all inputs of a production process, results in a more than doubling of the production process’ output. Also known as increasing returns to scale. People do not typically produce the full range of goods and services that they use or consume in their daily life, but instead they specialise in producing one good, while others produce other goods. But individuals are only willing to specialise if they have a way to acquire the other goods they need. For this reason, specialisation poses a problem for society: how are goods and services to be distributed from the producer to the final user? Capitalism has enhanced the opportunities for specialisation by expanding and developing the economic importance of markets and firms, which attempted to provide a solution to the question posed above. The division of labour in firms Adam Smith stated that the greatest improvement in the productive powers of labour has been the effects of the division of labour. Division of labour: the specialisation of producers to carry out different tasks in the production process. Also known as specialisation. Firms employ many individuals, most of which work on specialised tasks under the direction of the owners/managers of the firm. A firm is also a means by which people, each with distinct skills and capacities, contribute to a common outcome, the product(s) or service(s) that the firm delivers. Accordingly, firms facilitate cooperation among specialised producers (other firms) which in turn increases productivity. 14 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. Markets, specialization, and comparative advantage When markets are very small, there is no incentive to specialise. Markets allow everyone to pursue private objectives, to work together in producing and distributing goods and services in a way that is better than the available alternatives, i.e. markets facilitate unintended cooperation on a global scale. When individuals differ in their skills and ability to produce different goods, markets allow them to specialise. All producers can benefit by specialising and accordingly trading, even if this means a producer specialises in something that another producer could produce at lower cost. When economists attempt to establish which producers should specialise in which goods and/or services, they make use of two concepts: absolute advantage and comparative advantage that is illustrated with the following example below. Imagine a world with only two economies and only two goods. Economy A and Economy B can either produce apples or wheat. They differ in how productive they are in growing apples and wheat. The following table indicates the quantities of each good each producer would be able to make, if they dedicated all their available time, for example 2 000 hours per year, on the production of one good. Production if all time was spent on one good Apples Wheat Economy A 1 250 apples 50 tonnes of wheat Economy B 1 000 apples 20 tonnes of wheat Absolute advantage: when the inputs a producer/country uses to produce a good or service is less than that of another producer/country. In this example, the only input into the production process is time. Based on that, Economy A has an absolute advantage in the production of apples and wheat, as Economy A can produce more apples and wheat with the input of 2 000 hours per year than Economy B can. On the flip side then, Economy B has an absolute disadvantage in the production of apples and wheat. When referring to the cost of production, it does not have to be stated in monetary terms. Instead, one can also express the cost of production of one good or service in 15 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie terms of another good or service, for example the cost of producing 1 apple is 0,5 .N op ot tonnes of wheat. This is used in calculating the comparative advantage. io to determine comparative advantage n. table among producers/countries. Cost of an additional apple Cost of an additional tonne of wheat 50 tonnes of wheat Economy A 1 250 apples = 0,04 tonnes of wheat per apple 1 250 apples 50 tonnes of wheat = 25 apples per tonnes of wheat Economy B 20 tonnes of wheat 1 000 apples = 0,02 tonnes of wheat per apple 1 000 apples 20 tonnes of wheat = 50 apples per tonnes of wheat Based on the table above, the following observations can be made – Economy A has a comparative advantage in producing wheat, as an additional tonne of wheat costs Economy A (25 apples), which is less than it costs Economy B (50 apples). Economy B has a comparative advantage in producing apples, as an additional apple costs Economy B (0,02 tonnes of wheat), which is less than it costs Economy A (0,04 tonnes of wheat). Economies have two options for survival – being self-sufficient, i.e. produce both goods that the economy needs to survive or specialising in the production of one good and using markets to acquire the other good necessary for survival. Economy A therefore chooses to use 40% of their time on apple production, and the rest producing wheat. Economy B spends 30% of their time on apple production, and the rest producing wheat. The economies can produce the following if they were to be self-sufficient, i.e. they produce exactly what they need to consume. 16 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. ut following rib the st di additional unit of the same good or service by another producer/country. See e/ al good or service of a producer/country is lower relative to the cost of producing an rs fo Comparative advantage: when the cost of producing an additional unit of a specific Apples Wheat Economy A 1 250 apples × 0,40 = 500 apples 50 tonnes of wheat × 0,60 = 30 tonnes of wheat Economy B 1 000 apples × 0,30 = 300 apples 20 tonnes of wheat × 0,70 = 14 tonnes of wheat 800 apples 44 tonnes of wheat Total Suppose there are in fact (barter) markets where apples and wheat can be bought and sold. 40 apples can be bought for 1 tonne of wheat. If both economies specialise in the goods in which they have a comparative advantage, Economy A will specialise in producing wheat, therefore only producing wheat, while Economy B will specialise in producing apples. Economy A can produce 50 tonnes of wheat. Economy B can produce 1 000 apples. This gives us the figures for the “production” row of each economy as put out in the table on the following page. When both economies specialise, the total production of both crops will be higher than if it was under self-sufficiency, which means that both economies can sell their surplus buy some of the good(s) that they cannot produce. Consider the situation in which Economy A sells 15 tonnes of wheat (the transaction for wheat is indicated in the table with blue figures) for 600 apples from Economy B (the transaction for apples is indicated in the table with red figures). This gives us the figures for the “trade” row of each economy as put out in the table on the following page. The quantity of a specific good that an economy can consume, can be calculated as the sum of the quantities of the good that the economy produces, as well as the quantities of the good that the economy trades on global markets. This gives us the figures for the “consumption” row of each economy as put out in the table on the following page. 17 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m 600 35 Production 1 000 - Trade - 600 + 15 Consumption 400 15 Consumption 1 000 50 Total The opportunity to trade benefited both economies. This is because the economies can produce more apples and wheat of the specialise than under self-sufficiency. One strange thing to note from the table above – Economy A bought 600 apples even though the economy could have produced those apples at a lower cost. The reason why the outcome under specialisation is desirable is because it represents a situation in which time is better spent for both economies. Markets therefore contribute to increasing the productivity of labour by allowing producers to specialise in the production of goods in which they have a comparative advantage! 1.9 Capitalism, causation and history’s hockey stick The institutions associated with capitalism has the potential to make people better off, through specialisation and the permanent technological revolution that coincided with the emergence of capitalism. But can it be concluded that capitalism caused the upward kink in the hockey stick? Economists should be sceptical when anyone claims that something ‘causes’ something else, in this capitalism ‘caused’ the upward kink in the historical “hockey stick”. In science, the statement “X causes Y” is supported by performing experiments to gather evidence of the relationship among X and Y. Causality: a direction from cause to effect, which establishes that a change in one variable brings about a change in another. Correlation is simply an assessment that two variables move together, but causation is a more restrictive concept that accounts for the association among variables. 18 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. Economy B io Consumption ut rib st di - 15 e/ al + 600 Trade rs Economy A fo 50 ot - Production .N op Wheat Sh s. ie Apples In economics, economists with to make causal statements to understand why things happen, or to change things so that the economy can work better. This means making a causal statement that policy X is likely to cause change Y. For example, “If the central bank lowers the interest rate [policy X – monetary policy], more people will buy homes and cars [variable Y – luxurious consumer expenditure].” Unfortunately, an economy is too large to measure and understand all relationships, and it is rarely possible to gather evidence by conducting experiments. So how can economists do science? Consider the following real-world example of how economists gather data. It has been observed that the emergence of capitalism predated, or coincided with, the Industrial Revolution and the upward kink in the historical “hockey stick”. This is consistent with the hypothesis that capitalist institutions (in part) led to the era of continuous productivity growth. The emergence of a free-thinking cultural environment (also known as “The Enlightenment”) also predated or coincided with the upward kink in the historical “hockey stick”. Economists typically tend to narrow the range of things on which they disagree by using facts. A method for doing this is called a natural experiment. Natural experiment: an empirical study exploiting naturally occurring statistical controls in which researchers do not have the ability to assign participants to treatment and control groups, as is the case in conventional experiments. Instead, differences in law, policy, weather, or other events can offer the opportunity to analyse populations as if they had been part of an experiment. The validity of such studies depends on the premise that the assignment of subjects to the naturally occurring treatment and control groups can be plausibly argued to be random. Because economists cannot change the past, even if it were practical to conduct experiments on entire populations, economists still typically rely on natural experiments. 19 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m n. io ut rib st di e/ al An English clergyman, Thomas Robert Malthus, believed that a sustained increase in rs Revolution, and why it started in Britain. fo Economic models help to explain certain phenomena, such as the Industrial ot .N op Sh s. ie UNIT 2: TECHNOLOGY, POPULATION, AND GROWTH income per capita would be impossible. He believed that, even if technology improved and raised the productivity of labour, people would have more children as soon as they were better off. This population growth would continue until living standards fell to subsistence level, which will halt the population increase. Subsistence level: the level of living standards (measured by consumption or income) such that the population will not grow or decline. Malthus’ vicious circle of poverty was widely accepted as inevitable. It is therefore clear that a combination of population, the productivity of labour, and living standards may interact to produce a vicious circle of economic stagnation, called the vicious circle of poverty, as indicated by Malthus. Malthus did not offer an optimistic vision of economic progress. Even if people succeeded in improving technology, in the long run the vast majority would earn enough from their jobs or their farms to keep them alive, and no more. This is more commonly referred to as the Malthusian trap. The Industrial Revolution (as discussed in Unit), however, sprung Britain from the Malthusian trap, and continue to do so for many other countries in the century that followed. One of the main reasons that the Industrial Revolution was sparked in Great Britain was due to the large availability of coal and coal played a central role in the Industrial Revolution. Furthermore, the advances in technology (as descried in Unit 1) and the increased use of non-renewable resources raised productivity, allowing income to rise even as the population was increasing, effectively breaking Malthus’ vicious cycle. Productivity: the amount of something that a person could produce in a given amount of time. If technology continued improving quickly enough, it would be able to outpace the population growth that resulted from the increased income. Living standards, in turn, could then rise. Eventually, Malthus’ vicious cycle was naturally broken as many preferred smaller families, even when they earned enough to afford larger families. 20 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. Index of real wages Index of real wages: a quantitative amount, relative to its value in a reference period (“index”) of the money wage of a worker, adjusted for changes in prices over time (“real”). The result represents the real buying power of the money the workers earned. 2.1 Economists, historians, and the Industrial Revolution Why did the Industrial Revolution happen first in the eighteenth century in Great Britain? Robert Allen, an economic historian, stated the following two factors drove the structural changes of the Industrial Revolution: the relatively high cost of labour the low cost of local energy sources. The Industrial Revolution was more than just the breaking of the Malthusian cycle, rather it was a complex combination of inter-related intellectual, technological, social, economic and moral changes. Historians and economists have wrestled with explanations for why the Industrial Revolution started in Great Britain. Historians tend to focus on peculiarities of time and place. They are more likely to conclude that the Industrial Revolution happened because of a unique combination of favourable circumstances. Often a historian’s argument is not precise enough to make it testable by a model. Economists are more likely to look for general mechanisms that can explain success or failure across both time and space. Often an economist’s model is too simple and ignores important historical facts. Below are some of the main alternative theories for why the Industrial Revolution took off in Great Britain. Joel Mokyr (economist) believed that wages and energy prices merely directed innovation, but Europe’s scientific revolution and its Enlightenment the century was the real source of technological change. This is because the period brought the development of new ways to transfer and transform scientific knowledge into practical advice to be used to build the machines of that time. David Landes (historian) emphasises the political and cultural characteristics of nations. He suggests European countries pulled ahead of China because the 21 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie Chinese state was too powerful and stifled innovation and they favoured .N op Kenneth Pomeranz (historian) believed that Europe’s superior growth after the 1800s was due to the abundance of coal in Britain. He also argued that Britain’s access to agricultural production in its New World colonies fed the expanding class of industrial workers, which helped them to escape the Malthusian trap. The European take-off was most likely the result of a combination of scientific, demographic, political, geographic and military factors. Other scholars also believe that the take-off was partly due to interactions between Europe and the rest of the world, not just due to changes within Europe. This will focus on the economic conditions that contributed to Britain’s take-off, but it is important to note that each economy that did break out of the Malthus’ vicious cycle took a different escape route and had their own set of economic conditions that enabled them to do so. The national trajectories of early followers were largely influenced by the dominant role that Britain had come to play in the world economy. The Industrial Revolution did not lead to (equal) economic growth everywhere. The slow spread of the Industrial Revolution also explains the increase in income inequality between countries. David Landes once asked: “Why are we so rich and they so poor?” By “we”, he meant the rich societies of Europe and North America and by “they” he meant the poorer societies of Africa, Asia and Latin America. Landes suggested that there were basically two answers that explains why “we are so rich and they so poor”: because we are so good and they are so bad, i.e. we are hardworking, knowledgeable, educated, well governed, efficient, and productive, and they are the reverse. 22 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. io sociologist, Max Weber. ut as the home of virtues associated with the “spirit of capitalism", based on the rib Protestant countries of northern Europe, where the Industrial Revolution began, st di on to future generations. Clark’s argument follows a long tradition that sees the e/ al indicated cultural attributes such as hard work and savings, which were passed rs Gregory Clark (economist) also attributes Britain’s take-off to culture. He fo ot stability over change. o This school of thought believes that the Industrial Revolution started in Europe because of the Protestant Reformation, Renaissance, scientific revolution, favourable government policies and/or the development of superior private property rights. because we are so bad and they are so good, i.e. we are greedy, ruthless, exploitative, and aggressive, while they are weak, innocent, virtuous, abused, and vulnerable. o This school of thought believes that the Industrial Revolution started in Europe because of colonialism, slavery and/or the demands of constant warfare. These are all non-economic forces that had important economic consequences. 2.2 Economic models: How see more by looking at less We typically use models to “stand back and look at the big picture”, because it is impossible to describe every detail of how every economic agents acts and interacts. Models come in many forms. To create an effective model, we need to distinguish between the essential features of the economy that are relevant to the question we want to answer, which should be included in the model, and unimportant details that can be ignored. The is a diagrammatic model that illustrates the flows that occur within the economy, and between the economy and the biosphere. It is unrealistic, because that is not what the economy or the biosphere looks like, but nevertheless illustrates the relationships among them. The fact that the model omits many details (is “unrealistic”) is a feature of the model, not a bug. 23 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m n. io ut rib st di e/ al between income and population. rs standards was also based on a model: a simple description of the relationships fo Malthus’ explanation of why improvements in technology could not raise living ot .N op Sh s. ie Flow: A quantity measured per unit of time, such as annual income or hourly wage. Some economists have used physical models to illustrate and explore how the economy works. For example, Irving Fisher designed a hydraulic apparatus that represents flows in the economy. It consisted of interlinked levers and floating cisterns of water to show how the prices of goods depend on the amount of each good supplied, the incomes of consumers, and how much they value each good. How models are used in economics Fisher’s study of the economy illustrates how all models are used: 1. He built a model to capture the relevant elements of the economy that mattered for determining prices. 2. He used the model to show how interactions between elements could result in a set of prices that did not change. 3. He conducted experiments with the model to discover the effects of changes in economic conditions. Fisher’s hydraulic apparatus illustrates an important concept in economics. Fisher’s hydraulic apparatus represented equilibrium in his model economy by equalising water levels, which represented constant prices. Equilibrium: a model outcome that is self-perpetuating. In this case, something of interest does not change unless an outside or external force is introduced that alters the model’s description of the situation. Note that equilibrium means that one or more things in the model remains constant. It does not necessarily mean that nothing changes. An income at subsistence level is also an equilibrium because movements away from subsistence income are self-correcting: they automatically lead back to subsistence income as the population rises. When economists build a model, the following steps are involved in the process: 24 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. 1. Construct a simplified description of the conditions under which people take actions. 2. Describe, in simple terms, what determines the actions that people take. 3. Determine how each of their actions affects each other. 4. Determine the outcome of these actions, which often represents an equilibrium. 5. Try to get more insight by studying what happens to certain variables when conditions change. Economic models A good model has four attributes: It is clear. It helps to better understand something important. It predicts accurately. Its predictions are consistent with evidence. It improves communication. It helps to understand what we agree on. It is useful. It can find ways to improve how the economy works. Economic models often use mathematical equations and graphs as well as words and pictures. Mathematics is part of the language of economics and can help communicate our statements about models precisely to others. The knowledge of economics can only be expressed by using a combination of mathematics and clear descriptions, using standard definitions of terms. A model starts with some assumptions or hypotheses about how people behave, and often gives predictions about what is likely to occur in the economy. Gathering data on the economy, and comparing it with what a model predicts, helps to decide whether the assumptions (what to include and exclude) made when building the model were justified. Any institution who makes policies or forecasts uses some type of model. As such, bad models can result in disastrous policies. To have confidence in a model, it needs to be consistent with evidence. 25 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m io ut rib st di e/ al The following are the four key ideas of economic modelling, that will be used rs which new technologies are chosen, both in the past and in contemporary economies. fo In this unit, an economic model will be “built” to help explain the circumstances under ot .N op Sh s. ie 2.3 Basic concepts, Prices, costs, and innovation rents n. throughout: 1. Ceteris paribus and other simplifications help us focus on the variables of interest. We see more by looking at less. Ceteris paribus: the literal meaning of the expression is ‘other things equal’. In an economic model it means an analysis ‘holds other things constant’. 2. Incentives matter, because they affect the benefits and costs of taking one action as opposed to another. Incentive: economic reward or punishment, which influences the benefits and costs of alternative courses of action. 3. Relative prices help us compare alternatives. Relative price: the price of one good or service compared to another (usually expressed as a ratio). 4. Economic rent is the basis of how people make choices. Economic rent: a payment or other benefit received above and beyond what the individual would have received in his or her next best alternative (or reservation option). Ceteris paribus and simplification Economists often simplify an analysis by setting aside things that are thought to be of less importance to the question of interest, by using the phrase ceteris paribus. It is typically used when economists, for example ask: “what would happen if the price changed, but everything else that might influence the decision stayed the same?”. These ceteris paribus assumptions, when used well, can clarify the picture without distorting the key facts. When studying the way in which a capitalist economic system promotes technological improvements, it is important to look at how changes in wages affect firms’ choice of 26 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. technology. For the simplest possible model other factors affecting firms will be ‘held constant’. Therefore, the assumptions are: Prices of all inputs are the same for all firms. All firms know the technologies used by other firms. Attitudes towards risk are similar among firm owners. Incentives matter All economic models have something that allows movement to happen, and a description of the kinds of movements that are possible. People are free to select different courses of action, rather than simply being told what to do. This is where economic incentives affect the choices that people make. People are motivated, or incentivised, not only by the desire for material gain but also by love, hate, sense of duty, and desire for approval. Material comfort is typically the most important motive, and economic incentives mostly appeal to this motive. Accordingly, prices are typically the important factor that determine decisions. Relative prices In economic models, the focus is often on the ratios of things, rather than their absolute level. Relative prices are simply the price of one option relative to another. It is typically expressed as the ratio of two prices. Reservation positions and rents Consider the following: you figured out a way of doing something, cheaper than anyone else’s method. Your competitors cannot copy you, because they cannot figure out how to replicate your idea, or because you have a patent on the process. They, therefore, continue offering their services at a higher price than yours. If you, then, match their price (charge the same price), or undercut them by just a bit (charge slightly less), you will be able to sell as much as you can produce, making profits that greatly exceed those of your competitors. This is called an innovation rent, which is a form of economic rent. Economic rents occur throughout the economy. The idea of innovation rents will be used to explain some of the factors contributing to the Industrial Revolution. And economic rent is a general concept that will help explain many other features of the economy. 27 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie When taking some action (the option taken; option A) results in a greater benefit to Reservation option: a person’s next best alternative among all options in a particular transaction. Also known as a fallback option. It is “in reserve” in case you do not choose option A. Or, if you are enjoying option A, but someone excludes you from doing it, your reservation option will be your “Plan B”. Therefore, it is also called a fallback option. Economic rent gives us a simple decision rule: If action A would give you an economic rent, and nobody else would suffer – Do it! If you are already doing action A, and it earns you an economic rent – Carry on doing it! This decision rule motivates why a firm may innovate by switching from one technology to another. 2.4 Modelling a dynamic economy: Technology and costs These modelling ideas will now be used to explain technological progress. What is a technology? Different technologies utilise different combinations of inputs in order to produce the same quantity of output. The table on the page below summarises the different combinations of input needed to produce 100 metres of cloth that will be used in the example that follows. 28 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. option. io “next best alternative”, your “reservation position”, or the term we use, your reservation ut The alternative action with the next greatest net benefit (option B), is often called the rib economic rent = benefit from option taken − benefit from next best option st di simply given by the following equation: e/ al something you would like to get, not something you have to pay. Economic rent is rs as the rent for an apartment. To avoid this confusion, remember, an economic rent is fo economic rent. Economic rent is easily confused with everyday uses of the word, such ot .N op yourself than the next best action (option B), we say that you have received an Technology Number of workers Coal required (tonnes) A 1 6 B 4 2 C 3 7 D 5 5 E 10 1 The five points in the table represent five different technologies and graphically illustrated as in the figure to the right. We describe the E-technology as relatively labour-intensive (relying on labour the technology most) as and the relatively A- energy- intensive (relying on energy (coal) the most). If an economy were using technology E and shifted to using technology A or B, we would say that they had adopted a labour-saving technology, because the amount of labour used is less than with technology E. This is what happened during the Industrial Revolution. Firms started adopting labour-saving technologies and become more capital-intensive in their production processes. When looking at the figure above, is it clear which technology will the firm choose? The first step in answering this question is to rule out all technologies that are obviously inferior. A technology is considered inferior when it uses more of both resource inputs the produce the same quantity of outputs. Consider the A-technology. The easiest way to determine inferior technologies is to draw a vertical line upwards from Point A and a horizontal line to the right of point A. This will give you a shaded area that represents all technologies that are inferior to the A-technology. This area of inferiority is clearly illustrated in the figure on the following 29 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie page, where the figure shows that .N op ot the C-technology is clearly inferior fo e/ al rs to the A-technology as it uses io ut rib st di more workers and more coal. n. From this, it can be said that the Ctechnology is dominated by the Atechnology. Dominated: we describe an outcome in this way if more of something that is positively valued can be attained without less of anything else that is positively valued. In short: an outcome is dominated if there is a win-win alternative, for example moving from the C-technology to the A-technology. This process can be repeated with the B-technology, as shown below, which indicates that the D- technology is dominated by the Btechnology. Because it has been established that the C-technology is dominated by the A-technology, and the Dtechnology is dominated by the Btechnology, it is not necessary to test whether they dominate any technologies. This is because any point that is inferior to the C-technology, will automatically also be inferior to the Atechnology. Accordingly, the last step would be to repeat the process for the Etechnology, as shown in the figure on the following page. The E-technology does not dominate any of the other available technologies. We know this because none of the other four technologies are in the area above and to the right 30 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. of point E. Using the information about the inputs, the choice of technology can be narrowed down – the C- and D-technologies will never be chosen. But how does the firm choose between A, B and E? This decision will require an additional assumption about what the firm is trying to do. It can be assumed that the firm’s goal is to make as much profit as possible, which means producing at the least possible cost. Accordingly, to decide about technology also requires economic information about relative prices, i.e. the cost of hiring a worker relative to that of purchasing a tonne of coal. Intuitively, the labour-intensive E-technology would be chosen if labour was very cheap relative to the cost of coal; the energy-intensive A-technology would be preferable in a situation where coal is relatively cheap. An economic model helps us be more precise than this. Isocost lines The firm can calculate the cost of any combination of inputs that it might use by multiplying the number of workers by the wage and the tonnes of coal by the price of coal. We use the symbol w for the wage, L for the number of workers, p for the price of coal and R for the tonnes of coal: cost = (wage × number of workers) + (price of a tonne of coal × number of tonnes) = (w × L) + (p × R) The same logic can be extended to any combination of inputs – cost = (price of input × quantity of input ) + (price of input × quantity of input ) + ⋯ + (price of input × quantity of input ) Suppose that the wage is £10, and the price of coal is £20 per tonne, we can easily calculate the cost of the technologies, as shown in the table below. 31 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m 130 B 4 2 80 E 10 1 120 could also have a calculated cost of £80, for example employing eight workers and zero tonnes of coal, which corresponds to price combination H; or employing four tonnes of coal and zero workers, which corresponds to price combination J. If points J, B, and H were connected with a line, the resulting line would be an isocost line as shown in the figure to the right. Isocost line: a line that represents all combinations of inputs that cost a given total amount. Iso is the Greek word meaning “same”. Isocost lines are drawn on the assumption that fractions of workers and of coal can be purchased. Isocost lines can be drawn through any other set of points within the diagram. They join all possible combinations of workers and coal that cost the same amount. The simplest way to construct an isocost line is to determine the intercepts, i.e. how much workers can £80 employ (eight workers and no tonnes of coal, which represents point H) and how much tonnes of coal can £80 employ (4 tonnes of coal and no workers, which represents point J). Points above an isocost line cost more All points above an isocost line, will cost more than the cost associated with that isocost line, and all points below the isocost line costs less. For example, points A and 32 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. as £80, which corresponds to price combination B. Another combination of inputs io In the table, the cost of employing four workers and two tonnes of coal is calculated ut rib 6 st di 1 e/ al A rs Total cost (£) fo Coal required (tonnes) ot Number of workers .N op Sh s. ie Technology E are above the isocost line JBH, which means that both the A-technology and the Etechnology cost more than the B-technology, which is on the JBH isocost line. From both the table above, as well as the diagram above, it is clearly that the B-technology is the least-cost technology, given the resource input prices. The slope of every isocost line is − The slope of every isocost lines is negative, because all isocost lines will slope downward. The slope of the isocost line represents the rate at which the firm is willing to trade a unit of the resource on the vertical axis, for an additional unit of the resource on the horizontal axis, i.e. it represents the relative price of the resource on the horizontal axis. For example, in the case above, if the firm hired one more worker, they would have to forego 0,5 tonnes of coal. Accordingly, the slope of the isocost line is represented by the negative of the ratio of the price of the resource on the horizontal axis to the price of the resource on the vertical axis, i.e. − , the wage divided by the price of coal. Equation of the isocost line The isocost lines for any wage, w, and coal price, p, can be represented as equations. To do this, we use c for the cost of production. We begin with the cost of production equation, from above: =( × )+( × )= + This represents one way of writing the equation of the isocost line for any value of c. To construct the isocost line, it is easier to express it in the typical linear equation form: = where + is a constant that represents the vertical axis intercept and is the slope of the line. From above, we know that the slop of the isocost line is − , therefore In this instance, =− . refers to the resource on the vertical axis, i.e. coal. Therefore, the equation needs to be expressed in terms of the quantity of coal that the firm will employ, . Therefore, the following steps can be taken to rearrange the formula into the correct format: 33 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie + ot .N op = e/ al rs fo This formula can be rewritten as: equation of: = In this instance, we know when vertical axis intercept of = − = 10 and = 20, the isocost line for = 80 has a = 4, and a negative slope equal to − = − . This means that the isocost line’s equation can be given as: =4− . The generalised equation of any isocost line can be given as follows: = where − represents the resource on the vertical axis, resource on the vertical axis, represents the price of the represents the resource on the horizontal axis, represents the price of the resource on the horizontal axis and represents the total cost associated with the isocost line. 2.5 Modelling a dynamic economy: Innovation and profit Any change in the relative price of two inputs will change the slope of isocost lines. If isocost lines becomes sufficiently steep, it is possible that the firm’s choice of technology might change. The following example will illustrate how a change in relative prices could cause this to happen. Suppose that the price of coal falls to £5 while the wage remains at £10. At these costs, the new total costs will be Technology Number of workers Coal required (tonnes) Total cost (£) A 1 6 40 B 4 2 50 E 10 1 105 34 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. Which can be further rearranged to have a generalised formula for an isocost line’s io ut rib st di = − Based on the table on the previous page, the A-technology now becomes the leastcost technology. Cheaper coal makes each method of production (A, B and E) cheaper, but, intuitively, it makes the most energy-intensive technology the cheapest. The next step is to calculate the gains to the firm who first adopts the least-cost technology (A) when the relative price of coal falls. Initially, all firms are using the Btechnology to minimise its costs. The initial indicated on B-technology the dotted is JBH isocost line, and the new Atechnology is shown on the FAG isocost line, as shown in the figure to the right. The firm’s profits are equal to the revenue it gets from selling its output minus its costs. Whether the new or old technology is used, the same prices are paid for labour and coal, and the same price is received for selling 100 metres of cloth. The change in profit is thus equal to the fall in costs associated with adopting the new technology, and profits rise by £10 (the change in the price of a tonne of coal) per 100 metres of cloth. The change in profit can therefore be calculated as: Profit change in profit from switching from B to A = = change in revenue − change in costs = 0 − (40 − 50) = 10 In this case, the economic rent for a firm switching from B to A is £10 per 100 metres of cloth, which is the cost reduction made possible by the new technology. The decision rule (if the economic rent is positive, do it!) tells the firm to innovate and develop/get the new technology if the price of coal falls. In our example, the A-technology was available, but not in use until a first-adopter firm responded to the incentive created by the increase in the relative price of labour. The first adopter is called an entrepreneur. 35 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie ot organisational forms, and other opportunities. .N op Entrepreneur: a person who creates or is an early adopter of new technologies, Schumpeter, identified the adoption of technological improvements by entrepreneurs as a key part of his explanation for the dynamism of capitalism. Therefore, innovation rents are also often called Schumpeterian rents. Innovation rents will only last as long as it takes for other firms to adopt the new technology, which will also reduce their costs and increase their profits. In this case, with higher profits, the lower-cost firms will thrive. They will be able to increase their output. As more firms introduce the new technology, the supply of cloth to the market will increase and the price will start to fall. This process will continue until all firms adopted the new technology, at which stage prices will have declined to the point where no firm is earning innovation rents. Firms that did not adopt the new technology will be unable to cover their costs at the lower price, and they will go bankrupt. Schumpeter called this creative destruction. Creative destruction: Schumpeter’s name for the process by which firms who do not adopt new technologies, along with the old technologies are swept away by the new technology and those who adopt it, because they cannot compete in the market. In his view, the failure of unprofitable firms is creative because it releases labour and capital goods for use in new combinations. For Schumpeter, creative destruction was an essential fact about capitalism. Furthermore, Schumpeter developed one of the most important concepts of modern economics: creative destruction. He brought to economics the idea of the entrepreneur as the central actor in capitalism. The entrepreneur is the agent of change who introduces new products, new methods of production, and opens new markets, generating innovation rents. Imitators follow, and the innovation is diffused through the economy. A new entrepreneur and innovation launch the next upswing. This decentralised process mentioned above, generates a continued improvement in productivity, which leads to growth, so Schumpeter argued it is virtuous. The slowness of this process creates upswings and downswings in the economy. The branch of economic thought is known as evolutionary economics that has its origins in 36 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. io ut rib st di out new technologies and to start new businesses. The economist, Joseph e/ al rs fo When we describe a person or firm as entrepreneurial, it refers to a willingness to try Schumpeter’s work and is contained in most modern economic modelling that deals with entrepreneurship and innovation. Evolutionary economics: an approach that studies the process of economic change, including technological innovation, the diffusion of new social norms, and the development of novel institutions. 2.6 The British Industrial Revolution and incentives for new technologies The table below indicates the major changes that happened during the Industrial Revolution. Old technology New technology Many workers Few workers Little machinery Lots of capital goods Machinery required only human energy Machinery required requires energy Labour-intensive Labour-saving Capital-saving Capital-intensive Energy-saving Energy-intensive Looking at how relative prices differed among countries, and how they changed over time, can help us understand why certain technologies, such as the spinning jenny, were invented in Great Britain rather than in another country, and why it happened in the eighteenth century, rather than at another time in history. In England, labour was more expensive relative to the cost of energy than other countries. Wages relative to the cost of energy were high in England, because English wages were just typically higher than elsewhere, and because coal was cheaper in coal-rich Britain than in other countries. Furthermore, wages became steadily more expensive relative to the cost of capital goods in after the mid-seventeenth century. In other words, the incentive to replace workers with machines was increasing in England during this time, which was not the case for many other countries. Wages relative to the cost of energy and capital goods rose in the eighteenth century in Britain compared with earlier historical periods. 37 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie Wages relative to the cost of energy and capital goods were higher in Britain ot .N op during the eighteenth century than elsewhere. n. io ut rib st di e/ al in the era of permanent technological change. rs fo Britain was also a very inventive country. There were many skilled workers who aided The relative prices of the 1600s are shown by dotted isocost line JH in the figure to the right, which means that the B-technology was used. At those relative prices, there was no incentive to develop a technology like A, which is above the isocost line JH. In the 1700s, the isocost lines, such as FG, were much steeper, because the relative price of labour to coal was higher, which means that the A-technology was used. To summarise the two scenarios that can take place in the figure above: Where the relative price of labour is high, the energy-intensive technology A, is chosen. Where the relative price of labour is low, the labour-intensive technology B, is chosen. The relative prices of labour, energy and capital can explain why these labour-saving technologies were first adopted in England (during the Industrial Revolution), and why technological advancement occurred more rapidly in Great Britain than elsewhere. The eventual adoption of the technologies in other countries can be explained by further technological progress, because new technology was developed that dominated the existing technology in use. The aforementioned can easily be introduced into the model from before – initially the A-technology was replaced by the B-technology when the relative price of coal 38 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. increased. When a new labour- and energy-saving technology, A′, was developed, it dominated both the A- and B-technologies, as can be seen in the figure to the right. The new A’ technology would be adopted in both economies. As mentioned before, the other major factor that promoted the diffusion of new technologies into other countries was wage growth and falling energy costs. This made isocost lines steeper, which provided countries with an incentive to switch to labour-saving technology, such as the A-technology. The two aforementioned factors led to the spread of the new technologies. The divergence in technologies and living standards was eventually replaced by convergence, especially among the countries where the capitalist revolution took off. Nevertheless, certain countries still use the technologies that were replaced during the Industrial Revolution, most likely due to the relative price of labour being very low, making the isocost line very flat. This could create an alternative situation where HJ isocost line is so flat that the B-technology (labour-intensive technology) could be preferred to the A′technology. 2.7 Malthusian economics: Diminishing average product of labour Malthus provided a model predicted a pattern of economic development that is consistent with (can explain) the flat part of the GDP per capita “hockey stick”. The Malthusian model introduces many important concepts that are widely used in economics, as explained below. Production functions Suppose an agricultural economy that only produces grain. In this hypothetical example, the only factors of production necessary to produce grain is labour and land. Ignore all other things that you know are necessary to produce grain. 39 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie .N op Factors of production: the labour, machinery and equipment (usually referred to as ot capital), land, and other inputs to a production process. n. io ut rib st di production are energy and labour. e/ al rs fo In the model of technological change that has been used this far, the factors of To understand what will happen to the production of grain when the inputs (labour and land) become variable, a production function for farming is necessary. Production function: expresses a graphical or mathematical relationship describing the amount of output that can be produced by any given amount or combination of input(s). The function describes differing technologies capable of producing the same thing. For illustrative purposes, the production function will calculate the amount of grain produced by only considering the number of farmers working on a given amount of land (farm), holding all other inputs constant. A production function indicates a relationship between two quantities, the inputs and outputs. A function is typically expressed mathematically as: = ( ) This labour. means that “ is a function of ”. represents the quantity of represents the grain output that results from the labour inputs. The function ( ) describes the relationship between and . In the previous sections, there has already been a simple production function – for example, the production function for technology A gives us the typical “if-then” statement that is indicative of mathematical functions: if 1 worker and 6 tonnes of coal are the inputs, then 100 metres of cloth will be the output. The grain production function is a similar “if-then” statement, indicating that if there are farmers, then they will harvest grain. A production function can be represented graphically by a production function curve, by plotting the labour input (on the horizontal axis) to the grain output (on the vertical axis). The combinations of labour inputs and grain outputs can be seen in the table below. 40 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. Labour input (number of workers) Grain output (kg) 200 200 000 400 330 000 600 420 000 800 500 000 1 000 570 000 1 200 630 000 1 400 684 000 1 600 732 000 1 800 774 000 2 000 810 000 2 200 840 000 2 400 864 000 2 600 882 000 2 800 894 000 3 000 900 000 Based on the table above, the following production function can be constructed. Another concept that needs to be considered regarding functions production is the average product of specific input. Average product: total output divided by a particular input, for example per worker (divided by the number of workers) or per worker per hour (total output divided by the total number of hours of labour put in). 41 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie To demonstrate, the average product of labour for this example, for point A, for .N op ot example, can be calculated as: = 458. This is the slope of the ray from the point (0,0) to the point B on the production function. This essentially means that an average product of 458kg of grain is produced per farmer when there are 1 600 farmers working the land. As the figure above illustrates, the slope of the ray to point A (625) is steeper than the slope of the ray to point B (458). A pattern can be observed if we calculate the average product of labour for more points along the production function as illustrated in the table on the following page. 42 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. point B is calculated as io point. For example, in the figure below shows that the average product of labour at ut Graphically, the average product is the slope of the ray from the origin to a specific rib The slope of the ray is the average product st di = 625 kg per farmer e/ al total output 500 000kg = total number of farmers 800 farmers rs fo average product of labour = Labour input (number of workers) Grain output (kg) Average product of labour (kg/worker) 200 200 000 1 000 400 330 000 825 600 420 000 700 800 500 000 625 1 000 570 000 570 As more farmers work on a fixed amount of land, the average product of labour falls. Stated otherwise, as the quantity of labour increases, quantity of land kept constant, the average product of labour fails. This feature is called the diminishing average product of labour and is one of the two foundations of Malthus’ model. Diminishing average product of labour: a situation in which, as more labour is used in a given production process, the average product of labour typically falls. The diminishing average product of labour worried Malthus. This worried Malthus because of the real-world negative consequences that it could have on future generations of farmers. One could argue that if the population grows in the real world, more land can be used for farming. But Malthus pointed out that earlier generations of farmers would have picked the best land, so new land would be less productive, which would reduce the average product of labour further. In summary, diminishing average product of labour can be caused by: An increased quantity of labour devoted to a fixed quantity of land; and/or An increased quantity of inferior land bought. Essentially, as the average product of labour diminishes, the incomes of farmers also inevitably fall. 2.8 Malthusian economics: Population grows when living standards rise The diminishing average product of labour cannot be solely responsible for the long, flat portion of the “hockey stick”. This just means that living standards depend on the size of the population. It does not indicate why living standards and population didn’t change much over long periods of time. For this, the other part of Malthus’s model is needed: his argument that increased living standards led to a population increase. 43 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie This is based on Richard Cantillon’s (economist) theory that stated that, “men multiply There is a law of diminishing average product of labour; and The population increases if living standards increase. Malthus reasoned that the human population living in a country with a fixed supply of agricultural land, will be well-fed and would eventually multiply like Cantillon’s mice in a barn; but eventually the population would fill the country. Further population growth would therefore push down the incomes of most people as a result of diminishing average product of labour. The resulting fall in living standards would slow population growth as the mortality rate increases and the birth rates fall. Due to the aforementioned, incomes would ultimately settle at the subsistence level of the economy’s population. The Malthusian model that has been descried thus far results in an equilibrium in which there is an income level just enough to allow a subsistence level of consumption. The variables that stay constant in this Malthusian model equilibrium are: the size of the population; and the income level of the people. If the conditions within the economy change, the population and their incomes may change too, but eventually the economy’s population’s income will equilibrate at the subsistence level. Malthusian economics: The effect of technological improvement Over the centuries prior to the Industrial Revolution, improvements in technology occurred in many countries, but living standards remained constant. The question arises whether the Malthusian model can explain this? 44 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. The main ideas (foundations) of the Malthusian model is therefore: io ut rib st di e/ al rs intellectually). fo Malthus’ belief that people are not that different from other animals (excluding ot .N op like mice in a barn, if they have unlimited means of subsistence” combined with The figure above illustrates how the diminishing average product of labour and the effect of higher incomes on population growth mean that in the very long run, technological improvements will not result in higher income for farmers. In the figure, concepts in the box on the left are causes for concepts in the box on the right. A textual explanation of this figure follows: 1. Beginning in equilibrium, with income at the subsistence level, a new technology raises the income per person on the existing fixed quantity of land. 2. Higher living standards lead to an increase in population. 3. As more people are added to the land, diminishing average product of labour means average income per person falls. 4. Eventually income equilibrates at the subsistence level, with a higher population. Now the question arises why the population is higher at the new equilibrium? This is because the output per farmer is higher for each farmer. The population cannot return to the original level, because then income would be above the subsistence level. A better technology can therefore provide subsistence income for a larger population. Essentially, the Malthusian model predicts that improvements in technology will not raise living standards if: the average product of labour diminishes as more labour is applied to a fixed amount of land; and 45 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m population grows in response to increases in real wages. st di e/ al rs larger population but will not result in higher wages. This conclusion was called fo Due to the aforementioned, in the long run, an increase in productivity will result in a ot .N op Sh s. ie The Malthusian model can be represented graphically as explained below. The downward-sloping line in the left-hand figure on the following page shows that as the population increases, the level of wages decreases, due to the diminishing average product of labour. The upward-sloping line on the right (below) shows the relationship between wages and population growth: as the level of wages increase, the population grows, because of higher living standards that lead to more births and fewer deaths. o This figure shows that when the wages are high, the population growth is positive; while population growth is negative, when wages are low. In the figure on the left (below), the wage’s subsistence level occurs at point A where the population is medium-sized. If this point A is traced across to the figure on the right, it shows a point A′ where population growth is equal to zero. Point A is therefore an equilibrium position where the population stays constant and wages remain at subsistence level. Similarly, point B (from the left) can also be traced to the figure on the right (point B’) which shows that at that higher wage and smaller population, the population will in fact be rising as the population growth rate is positive. 46 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. io ut rib Malthus’ Law. The economy always returns to equilibrium It has been established that as the population rises, the economy moves down the line in the left diagram, while wages fall until they reach the subsistence level at point A. The two figures together explain the Malthusian population trap. Population will be constant when the wage is at subsistence level, it will rise when the wage is above subsistence level, and it will fall when the wage is below subsistence level. Bearing this in mind, the following figure shows how the Malthusian model predicts that even if productivity increases, living standards will not increase in the long run. 1. Initially the economy is in equilibrium in point A, with a medium-sized population and wage at subsistence level. 2. The economy then implements an advance in technology. A technological improvement will raise the average product of labour, and accordingly, the wage will be higher for any level of population. The real wage line shifts (parallel) upward. At the initial population level (point A), the wage increases, and the economy moves to point D. 3. If we trace point D over the figure to the right to point D’, it is clear that as the wage is now high, the population will begin to rise (as population growth is positive). 47 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie 4. The population will then start to increase, which sees a fall in the wage, due to ot .N op the diminishing average product of labour. a. At C, the wage has reached subsistence level again. The population remains constant (point C′). The population is higher at equilibrium C than it was at equilibrium A. 48 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. io ut rib st di e/ al Reaching the new equilibrium at point C with the new technology rs fo 5. The economy therefore starts to move down the real-wage curve again. UNIT 3: SCARCITY, WORK, AND CHOICES Decision making under scarcity is a common problem because we usually have limited means available to meet our objectives. In the modern economy, time is the scarcest resource. Accordingly, the biggest scarcity decision pertains to the division between time spent on leisure and time spent on work. Economists attempt to model these situations by defining all feasible action combinations, then evaluating which combination is the best, given the objectives. When modelling these situations, it is important to consider opportunity costs, which describe the unavoidable trade-offs that occur in the presence of scarcity. From the opening statement, it is clear that an individual therefore has to make a trade-off decision between working more or having more leisure time. This economic model also attempts to explain the differences in the hours that people work in different countries, and the changes in the hours of work throughout history. The appropriate question to ask is therefore whether people have used economic progress to consume more goods, enjoy more free time, or both? The answer is both, but in different proportions in different countries. Some of the trends that have been observed in this regard are given below. In the late nineteenth and early twentieth century, average income approximately trebled, and hours of work fell substantially. During the rest of the twentieth century, income per head rose four-fold, for example A more than six-fold increase in hourly earnings for twentieth century Americans, and a fall in their average annual work time by a little more than one-third. Hours of work continued to fall in the Netherlands and France (albeit more slowly) but levelled off in the US, where there has been little change since 1960. Many countries have experienced similar trends, but there are still vast differences in different countries. Higher-income countries seem to have lower working hours and more free time, but there are also some striking differences between the higher- 49 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie income countries, as well. These differences lead to different scenarios playing out in .N op ot different countries. Some of these scenarios are: st di consumed more. While in other countries people now have much more free time. Countries therefore see a variation of these three aspects depending on the economic conditions within the country. 3.1 Labour and production Labour is work. Work activity is often difficult to measure, which is a concern as employers find it difficult to determine the exact amount of work that employees are doing. Economists also cannot measure the effort required by different activities in a comparable way. Therefore, economists often measure labour simply as the number of hours worked by individuals engaged in production and assume that as the number of hours worked increases, the amount of goods produced also increases. For this unit, we will consider the choices of a student: how many hours to spend studying. There are many factors that influence this choice. Part of the motivation to devote time to studying could come from the belief that more time spent studying, results in higher grades. For the model that will be constructed in this Unit, we will assume a positive relationship between hours worked (studied) and the final grade. Consider the hypothetical student, whom we will call Alex. The positive relationship noted earlier is clearly represented in the table below. Study hours 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15+ Grade 0 20 33 42 50 57 63 69 74 78 81 84 86 88 89 90 The table shows how Alex’s grade will vary if he changes his study hours, if all other factors – his social life, for example – are held constant. It is possible that the final grade might also be affected by unpredictable events, which can be called “luck’”, but these figures refer to studying under normal conditions, i.e. the effect of “luck” is removed. 50 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. In other countries, people have carried on working just as hard as before but io ut rib 1870. e/ al In many countries there has been a huge increase in living standards since rs fo The combinations from the table on the previous page, can be plot on a graph, to illustrate Alex’s production function, as seen to the right. Alex can achieve a higher grade by studying more, so the curve slopes upward. The production function shows that the positive relationship only lasts if Alex studies less than 15 hours, because the maximum grade that Alex is capable of is 90%, which he can obtain if he studies for 15 hours or any amount of time in excess thereof. This is graphically illustrated on the right-side of the production curve where it plateaus (the curve becomes flat) past 15 hours of study per day. As in Unit 2, Alex’s average product of labour can be calculated again, which indicates the slope of a ray from the origin to the curve at any point on the curve. Another important concept is Alex’s marginal product, which refers to the increase in his grade from increasing study time by one hour. Marginal product: the additional amount of output that is produced if a particular input was increased by one unit, while holding all other inputs constant. The marginal product represents the slope of the production function. Comparing average product and marginal product When Alex studies four hours per day, his average product is = 12,5 percentage points, which represents the slope of the ray from that point to the origin. If Alex were to increase his study time from 4 to 5 hours, Alex’s grade raises from 50 to 57. Therefore, at 4 hours of study, the marginal product of an additional hour is approximately 7. More precisely, the marginal product is the slope of the tangent (the rate of change) at that point, which is approximately 7. Tangency: when two curves share one point in common but do not cross. The tangent to a curve at a given point is a straight line that touches the curve at (only) that point but does not cross it. 51 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie In order to get a more precise approximation, the calculation needs to be repeated he studies, i.e. the marginal product of an additional hour of studying falls as Alex studies more. The marginal product is therefore diminishing. Diminishing returns: A situation in which the use of an additional unit of a factor of production results in a smaller increase in output than the previous increase. Also known as diminishing marginal returns in production. The model captures the idea that an extra hour of study helps a lot if you are not studying much, but if you are already studying a lot, then studying even more does not help very much. Especially when Alex reaches his maximum grade (90%) in which case an additional hour of studying would cause no change in his grade, i.e. his marginal product is zero (0). To generalise the, at each point on the production function the marginal product (the slope of the curve) will always be lower than the average product (the slope of the ray), as can be seen below by the tangent at the point (marginal product) being less steep than the ray from the origin to the point (average product). The figure indicates increases to that as the the the right output input increases, but the marginal 52 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. As seen in the figure above, Alex’s production function becomes flatter the more hours io accurate marginal product. ut second of study per day, for example), we would be able to calculate an even more rib If we looked at even smaller changes in study time (the rise in grade for each additional st di 0,124 = 7.44 0,016667 e/ al estimate of the marginal product (the rate of change) would therefore be: rs to the graph, his grade will rise by a very small amount – about 0.124. A more precise fo and studies for 1 minute longer each day (a total of 4,016667 hours). Then, according ot .N op with much smaller increments. Suppose Alex has been studying for 4 hours a day, product falls, which means that the function becomes gradually flatter. A production function with this shape is described as concave. Concave function: a function of two variables for which the line segment between any two points on the function lies entirely below the curve representing the function (the function is convex when the line segment lies above the function). 3.2 Preferences If Alex were to know his production, how many hours would he choose to study per day? His decision depends on his preferences for the things that he cares about. Preferences: a description of the benefit or cost we associate with each possible outcome. If he cared only about his grades, he would study for 15 hours a day. But if Alex also cares about his free time, he faces a trade-off: how many percentage points is he willing to give up in order to spend time on things other than study? If the combinations of time studying and Alex’s final grade are plotted on a set of axes, where free time is on the horizontal axis and Alex’s final grade is on the vertical axis, the downward-sloping result will curve, be a called an indifference curve, which joins all the combinations that provide equal utility or “satisfaction”. Indifference curve: A curve of the points which indicate the combinations of goods that provide a given level of utility to the individual. Utility: A numerical indicator of the value that one places on an outcome, such that higher valued outcomes will be chosen over lower valued ones when both are feasible. From this figure the following assumptions (that can be generalised) can be made: For a given grade, say 84%, Alex would prefer a combination that gives him more free time. Therefore, even though both point A and B corresponds to a grade of 84%, Alex will prefer A because it gives him more free time. 53 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie Similarly, if two combinations have the same amount of free time, Alex will provides Alex with more utility than points B and C. Therefore, higher indifference curves represent higher utility for the individual. To describe preferences, the indifference curve does not have to quantify the exact utility of each option; it only needs to illustrate which combinations an individual provides more or less utility in relation to the others. Typically, indifference curves are drawn for various consumption goods, and we refer to the individual as a consumer. In our model, the consumption goods are Alex’s final grades and his free time. Consumption good: a good or service that satisfies the needs of consumers over a short period. The following are more important characteristics of indifference curves: Indifference curves slope downward due to the trade-off decisions that consumers have to make. Higher indifference curves correspond to higher utility levels. Indifference curves are typically smooth, i.e. small changes in the amounts of goods do not cause big jumps in utility. Indifference curves never cross. As you move to the right along an indifference curve, it becomes flatter. The slope of an indifference curve is determined similar to the way in which we calculated the marginal product. It demonstrates how much of the consumption good 54 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. and point C. The higher indifference curve that point A and point D are on, therefore io C. This is because point A and point D are on a higher indifference curve to point B ut above, we know that Alex prefers point A to point B; and Alex prefers point D to point rib Alex is indifferent between A, E, F, G, H and D. Furthermore, from the two assumptions st di points along the same indifference curve. From the figure above, it is thus clear that e/ al same amount of utility. Accordingly, an individual is therefore indifference between all rs In general, the indifference curve joins all possible outcomes that will give Alex the fo point C), as it gives him the higher grade with the same amount of free time. ot .N op prefer the one with a higher grade. For example, Alex would prefer point D (to on the vertical axis the consumer is willing to forgo for an additional unit of the good on the horizontal axis. This is called the marginal rate of substitution (MRS). Marginal rate of substitution (MRS): the trade-off that a person is willing to make between two goods. At any point, this is the slope of the indifference curve. Intuitively, this makes sense, because it is reasonable to assume that the more free time Alex has, and the lower his grades are, the less willing he will be to sacrifice further percentage points in return for free time, so therefore his MRS will be lower. 3.3 Opportunity costs Alex wants to have the maximum amount of free time and the highest possible final grade, but because of his production function that is not completely possible. He therefore has an opportunity cost to get more free time –the opportunity cost of more time is getting a higher grade. Opportunity cost: when taking an action implies forgoing the next best alternative action, this is the net benefit of the foregone alternative. Opportunity costs need to be considered when consumers make a choice. In the choice to take action A, we cannot take action B. Accordingly, “not taking action B” becomes part of the cost of doing A, which we call the opportunity cost. When determining the cost of taking a particular action, accountants only consider the “out-of-pocket” cost, which means that they do not consider the opportunity cost as a concrete monetary value that is considered a cost. Economists, however, considers the economics cost of a particular action as the “out-of-pocket” cost plus the opportunity cost. Economic cost: the out-of-pocket cost of an action, plus the opportunity cost. Now, the opportunity cost must be considered when deciding whether or not to undertake an action or not. There are two concerts – concert A with an admission cost of R25 and concert B, which is free. These concerts happen at the same time and the consumer will have to make a decision. The following table shows whether a consumer should choose to attend concert A. 55 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m R40 R40 Economic benefit R50 R30 Economic rent R10 -R10 b) The most you would be willing to pay to go to concert B (if it was not free) is R15, which is the cost of the “next best alternative” (concert B). In scenario I, the consumer makes a judgement that the economic benefit (pleasure) they would receive from attending concert A is equal to R50. This would mean that the benefit exceeds the economic cost of attending the concert, which results in a positive economic rent. Accordingly, the consumer should attend concert A. In scenario II, the consumer believes their economic benefit would only be equal to R30. This will result in a negative economic rent. Accordingly, the consumer should not attend concert B. 3.4 The feasible set In Alex’s situation, he does not have an infinite amount of combinations, because there are only 24 hours in a day. If Alex chooses to study for 24 hours, he will receive a final mark of 90%. If he were to spend 24 hours on free time, we can assume that his final mark will be 0%. Based on this, we can construct the following convex feasible frontier, which indicates the highest grade Alex can achieve given the amount of free time he takes. Feasible frontier: the curve made of points that defines the maximum feasible quantity of one good for a given quantity of the other. The feasible frontier graphically illustrates all possible combinations that constitute the feasible set, which is the area inside of the frontier and the frontier itself. Feasible set: all the combinations of the things under consideration that a decisionmaker could choose given the economic, physical or other constraints that he faces. Alex’s feasible frontier can be illustrated by the figure on the following page. 56 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. The monetary cost of attending the concert. io a) ut rib st di Total cost e/ al R15 b) rs R15 b) Opportunity cost fo R25 ot R25 Out-of-pocket cost a) .N op Scenario II Sh s. ie Scenario I As mentioned before, all combinations (points) on and under the feasible frontier, are combinations that are possible for Alex to attain, for example point A, E, C, F and D. Furthermore, the feasible frontier shows the maximum final grade Alex can obtain given the time that he spends studying, for example, if Alex has 20 hours of free time per day, he obtains a final mark of 50%, as indicated by point F. With this amount of free time, it would be impossible for Alex to obtain a final mark of 70%, as indicated by point B. To generalise, any combinations outside (above/to the right) the feasible frontier, such as point B above, are said to be infeasible given Alex’s resource constraints. Furthermore, even though a combination inside of the frontier is feasible, they represent inferior combinations, because at any point inside of the frontier, Alex can either have more free time or obtain a higher final grade without having to make a trade-off decision. By choosing a combination inside the frontier, Alex would therefore be giving up something that is freely available – something that has no opportunity cost. The feasible frontier represents the trade-off he must make between grade and free time. At any point on the frontier, taking more free time has an opportunity cost in terms of grade points foregone, corresponding to the slope of the frontier. In economic terms, the feasible frontier shows the marginal rate of transformation (MRT). 57 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie sacrificed to acquire one additional unit of another good. At any point, it is the slope of ot .N op Marginal rate of transformation (MRT): The quantity of some good that must be fo the frontier. To be more precise, the slope of the feasible frontier at any point can be calculated as the slope of the tangent at that point, which represents the MRT and the opportunity cost at that point. 3.5 Decision making and scarcity To finally determine which combination Alex will choose, we must combine the feasible frontier and the indifference curves from before. Indifference curves indicate what Alex prefers, and their slopes represent the trade-offs that Alex is willing to make; while the feasible frontier is the constraint on his choices, and its slope represents the trade-off he is constrained to make. Accordingly, Alex will want to choose a combination that is on the highest possible indifference curve (to give him the highest amount of utility), while still being on the feasible frontier (to show a combination of free time and final grade that is obtainable). He will make his decision based on the figure below. 58 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. io ut rib The slope of any given ray, for example AE, is only an approximation to the slope of st di e/ al rs the feasible frontier. Alex cannot choose IC4 because no point on IC4 represents a feasible combination. Any combination on the indifference curves IC1 and IC2 will be non-optimal choices, as Alex will be able to increase his utility by switching to a higher indifference curve, IC3. On IC3 the only feasible combination, however, is point E, which represents the feasible combination with the highest attainable utility. To generalise, this is the (only) point where the slope of the indifference curve and the slope of the feasible frontier are equal. In order for a consumer to maximise their utility, is therefore at the point where MRS = MRT. To maximise his utility, the model predicts that Alex will choose to spend 5 hours each day studying, and 19 hours on other activities (free time), while obtaining a final grade of 57%. Alex’s situation that was just studied can also be called a constrained choice problem where a decisionmaker pursues an objective subject to a given constraint. Constrained choice problem: this problem is about how we can do the best for ourselves, given our preferences and constraints, and when the things we value are scarce. 3.6 Hours of work and economic growth We will now apply the model of constrained choice problems to Angela, a self-sufficient farmer. She only produces enough grain for her to eat. Her choice on how to spend her time is therefore divided between producing grain and having free time. Angela therefore faces a problem of scarcity: she must make a choice between consuming grain (to eat) and having free time. To understand her choice, we need to model her production function, and her preferences. Her production function, given her current technology and conditions, is constructed from the table below, and can be seen in the figure on the next page, labelled as PF. Working hours 0 1 2 Grain 9 18 26 33 40 46 51 55 58 60 62 64 66 69 72 0 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 18 24 If a technological improvement were to occur, such as better equipment that makes harvesting quicker, the amount of grain produced in a given number of hours will increase and will be reflected in her production function. The new production function is also shown in the figure on the following page, labelled as PFnew. 59 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m ot .N op Sh s. ie n. io ut rib st di e/ al rs fo Notice that the new production function is steeper than the original one for every given number of hours. Furthermore, the new technology also increased Angela’s marginal product of labour, i.e. at every point, an additional hour of work produces more grain than under the old technology. The figure below shows Angela’s feasible frontier for the original technology (FF), and the new one (FFnew), along with her indifference curves. 60 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. From the figure on the previous page, it is clear that the technological improvement expands the feasible set. Furthermore, it also gives Angela access to indifference curves that were previously not possible, i.e. increases the maximum utility that she can receive. Under the original technology, her optimal choice at point A was to work for 8 hours a day, giving her 16 hours of free time and producing 55 units of grain. After the technological improvement, her optimal choice at point E increased both her consumption of grain (61 units of grain) and her free time (17 hours per day). Technological change makes the production function steeper, i.e. it increases Angela’s marginal product of labour. This also means that the opportunity cost of free time is higher, which gives her a greater incentive to work. But now, since she can have more grain for each amount of free time, she may be more willing to give up some grain for more free time, i.e. reduce her hours of work. These are the two effects that technological improvements have, and clearly it works in opposite directions. In Angela’s case, the second effect dominates, i.e. she chooses to reduce her hours of work, which resulted in more grain. 3.7 Income and substitution effect on hours of work and free time The two effects of technological improvements that we saw work in opposite directions in the previous example, is indicative of the income and substitution effect. Consider the following situation to explain the difference in these effects: you are looking for a job after college and you expect to earn a wage of $15 per hour. The wage and the hours of work will effectively determine how much free time you will have, and your total earnings. We will define the wage as w, and the hours of free time you have as t hours per day, which means you work (24 − t) hours per day. Because your consumption cannot exceed your total earnings, your maximum level of consumption, c, will be given by your number of hours worked multiplied by your wage: = (24 − ) This equation is called your budget constraint and shows what you can afford to buy. Budget constraint: an equation that represents all combinations of goods and services that one could acquire that exactly exhaust one’s budgetary resources. Since we know that the wage is $15, the equation of the budget constraint is: = 15(24 − ) 61 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie We can construct this budget line by simply drawing the straight line graph, or by ot .N op plotting the respective combinations of free time and consumption as indicated in the fo 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 Free time, t 24 22 20 18 16 14 12 10 8 Consumption, c 0 $30 $60 $90 n. io 2 ut 0 rib Hours of work st di e/ al rs table below. The constructed $120 $150 $180 $210 $240 budget constraint is illustrated in the figure to the right. The slope of the budget constraint corresponds to the wage: for each additional hour of free time, consumption must decrease by $15. The shaded area under the budget constraint represents your feasible set. The budget constraint acts very similar to a feasible frontier, except now it is a straight line. Accordingly, your MRT, and therefore the opportunity cost of free time, will be constant and equal to your wage, which is the slope of the budget constraint – $15. Your preferred combination of free time and consumption will therefore still be at the point where your budget constraint is tangential to your highest indifference curve, as this is where MRS = MRT, as before, i.e. point A in the figure above. If you were to receive, say an additional $50 a day for life it will affect your decision. The equation of your new budget constraint will now be: = 15(24 − ) + 50 The extra income will not change your opportunity cost of time, but it will shift your budget constraint parallel to the original budget constraint. This will allow you to consume more per day, for every amount of hours worked, which essentially expand the feasible frontier and enables you to consume on a higher indifference curve, enabling you to increase your maximum utility. Your new ideal combination will be at point B, which increases your consumption, but your hours of free time remains 62 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. constant. The new budget constraint, relative to the original budget constraint is shown below. The effect of the additional income on your choice of free time is called the income effect. Income effect: the effect that the additional income would have if there were no change in the price or opportunity cost. In this case, your income effect was zero, as the extra income did not lead to an increase in free time. An alternative scenario, based on preference, could have also resulted in an income effect that is positive, in which case the additional income does lead to an increase in your free time, as well, as illustrated below. 63 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie It is important to note that the income effect can be positive or zero, but never negative. n. io ut = 25(24 − ) rib st di e/ al rs fo equation of your new budget constraint will then be: ot .N op Consider the alternative scenario where the wage rate increases to $25 per hour. The Your new budget constraint will now be steeper as the wage rate (slope) increased. Similarly, your feasible set will be expanded, and you will be able to achieve a highest level of utility as indifference curves that were previously infeasible, have now become feasible. Your new optimal combination will therefore be point D, as illustrated in the figure on the next page. This results in an increase in your consumption, but you will have fewer hours of free time per day. This is called the substitution effect, which decreases the hours of free time, but increases consumption. Substitution effect: the effect that is only due to changes in the price or opportunity cost, given the new level of utility. When the wage rate increases, two things happen – the opportunity cost of free time increases, but you also have increased income, resulting in an income and substitution effect, as illustrated in the figure on the following page. Initially your optimal combination was at point A on IC₂. The higher wage enables you to reach point D on IC₄. The increase in the wage, will result in a steeper budget constraint and will make 64 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. your new optimal choice point D on IC4. The dotted line shows how you could reach IC4 without an increase in the wage rate, i.e. an exogenous increase an income. The shift from point A to point C shows the income effect of the wage rise, which would increase consumption and free time. The shift from point C to point D shows the substitution effect of the wage increase, which would increase consumption, but decrease free time. The total effect of the wage increase would therefore be from point A to point D. The substitution effect will always be negative – with a higher opportunity cost of free time you choose a point on the indifference curve with a higher MRS, which is a point with less free time (and more consumption). But, tThe overall effect of the wage rise will therefore depend on the sum of the income and substitution effects. In this case, the substitution effect was bigger than the income effect, which explains why you have increased consumption, but less free time. Technological progress If you look back at Section 3.6, you will see that Angela’s response to a rise in productivity was also determined by these two opposing effects: an increased incentive to work produced by the rise in the opportunity cost of free time, and an increased desire for free time when her income rises. In general, the income effect of a higher wage makes workers want more free time, while the substitution effect provides an incentive to work longer hours. If the income effect dominates the substitution effect, workers will prefer to have more free time. 3.8 Is this a good model? This model might seem unrealistic. But, remember from Unit 2 that models help us “see more by looking at less”. The lack of realism in this model is therefore an 65 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie intentional feature, rather than a shortcoming. The question is then: can a model that ot .N op ignores thought, possibly be a good model of how we choose? rs fo think through these calculations each time they decide. Instead, individuals try various choices and then adopt to habits or change our choice, accordingly. Economic theory rather posits that individuals will try different combinations, until they find that a particular combination yields the best results for them, after which they will stick to that combination. This is ultimately the “human” method of trial and error to find the combination that maximises utility, as the model attempts to do mathematically. The influence of culture and politics The second unrealistic aspect of the model is that employers choose working hours, not individuals. Employers will also typically impose longer working days than workers prefer. As a result, working hours are mostly regulated by law, so that beyond some number of hours, neither employee nor employer can choose to work. Effectively, the government has imposed a limitation to the feasible set. Although individual workers often have little freedom to choose their hours, the changes in working hours over time, and differences between countries, may in fact partly reflect the preferences of workers. If many individual workers in a democracy wish to lower their hours, they may “choose” this indirectly as voters. Or, they may bargain as members of a trade union for contracts that pay higher overtime wages for longer working hours. This explanation stresses culture, the changes in preferences or differences in preferences among countries, and politics, the differences in laws, or trade union strength and objectives, as possible explanation to the differences in working hours between countries: But, even on an individual level, we may influence the hours we work. For example, employers who advertise jobs with the working hours that most people prefer may find they have more applicants than other employers offering too many (or too few) hours. Remember, we also judge the quality of a model by whether it provides insight into something that we want to understand. 66 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. io ut rib Milton Friedman (economist) explained that economists do not claim that individuals st di e/ al Trial and error replace calculations UNIT 4: SOCIAL INTERACTIONS Game theory is a way of understanding how people interact based on the constraints that limit their actions, their motives, and their beliefs about what others will do. Game theory: a branch of mathematics that studies strategic interactions, meaning situations in which each actor knows that the benefits they receive depend on the actions taken by all. In most interactions there is some conflict of interest between people, but also some opportunity for mutual gain. The tools of game theory allow economists to model these social interactions. Social interaction: situations in which the actions taken by each person affect other people’s outcomes as well as their own. Self-interest, a concern for others, and a preference for fairness are all important motives that explain how people interact. The pursuit of self-interest can sometimes lead to results that are considered good by all participants, or outcomes that none of the participants would prefer. A concern for others and for fairness allows us to internalise the effects of our actions on others and can also contribute to good social outcomes. This unit will specifically look at situations that result in social dilemmas and how people can sometimes solve them, but sometimes not (or not yet), as in the case of climate change. Social dilemma: a situation in which actions taken independently by individuals in pursuit of their own private objectives result in an outcome which is inferior to some other feasible outcome that could have occurred if people had acted together, rather than as individuals. Not all social interactions lead to social dilemmas, even if individuals act in pursuit of their own interests. Social dilemmas, like climate change, occur when people take inadequate account of the effects of their decisions on others, whether the effects are positive or negative. Social dilemmas occur frequently in our lives. 67 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie A typical example of a social dilemma is something that is common to all of us. If, as Altruism: the willingness to bear a cost in order to benefit somebody else. Altruistic self-sacrifice is not the most important way that societies resolve social dilemmas and reduce free riding. Sometimes the problems can be resolved by government policies. Local communities can also create institutions to regulate behaviour. 4.1 Social interactions: Game theory On which side of the road should you drive? In South Africa, we drive on the right. But suppose we just left the choice to every driver to pursue their self-interest and to select a side of the road. If everyone else was already driving on the right, the self-interest of avoiding a collision could be enough to motivate a driver to drive on the right, as well. In this example, self-interest can promote general wellbeing, but there are cases in which the pursuit of self-interest leads to undesirable results. To analyse this, we will introduce game theory, a way of modelling how people interact. Social and strategic interactions The following four concepts is important throughout this unit: Strategic interactions Strategic interaction: a social interaction in which the participants are aware of the ways that their actions affect others (and the ways that the actions of others affect them). 68 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. called altruistic. io The actions of these individuals willing to do the hard work on behalf of the group, are ut without contributing oneself. rib Free ride: benefiting from the contributions of others to some cooperative project st di sometimes called free riders. e/ al work, bears the cost of having to work. The “others” that did not do the work are rs work for the group, everyone benefits, but it is hard work. Whoever does the most fo effort is individual, yet the benefits go to the whole group. When one person does the ot .N op a student, you have ever done a group assignment, you understand that the cost of Strategy Strategy: an action (or a course of action) that a person may take when that person is aware of the mutual dependence of the results for herself and for others. The outcomes depend not only on that person’s actions, but also on the actions of others. Games Game: a model of strategic interaction that describes the players, the feasible strategies, the information that the players have, and their payoffs. The players of a game refer to who is interacting with whom; the feasible strategies refer to which actions are available to the players; the information refers to what each player knows when making their decision; and the payoffs refer to what the outcomes will be for each player for each of the possible combinations of actions. Game theory To see how game theory can clarify strategic interactions, imagine two farmers – Anil and Bala. Both of them face the same problem – should they grow rice or cassava? We assume that both farmers can grow both types of crop, but each can only grow one crop at a time. Anil’s land is better suited for growing cassava, while Bala’s is better suited for rice. The two farmers must determine who will specialise in which crop, but they do so independently, i.e. they do not meet to discuss a course of action. They both sell whatever crop they produce in a nearby village market. On market day, if they bring less rice to the market, the price will be higher. The same goes for cassava. To simplify the model, we assume that: There are no other people involved or affected in any way. The selection of which crop to grow is the only decision that Anil and Bala need to make. Anil and Bala will interact just once (which is called a “one-shot game”). They decide simultaneously. When a player decides that player doesn’t know what the other person has decided to do. 69 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie This interaction can be represented by the table on the following page. Anil’s choices ot .N op are the rows of the table, which is called the “row player” and Bala’s are the columns, fo st di e/ al rs which is called the “column player”. in such a n. represented io ut rib When an interaction is table, each cell describes the outcome of a hypothetical situation, for example, the upper-left cell should be interpreted as: Suppose Anil and Bala planted rice, what would we see? In this game, there are four situations: hypothetical both players plant rice, Anil plants rice and Bala plants cassava, Anil plants cassava and Bala plants rice, or both players plant cassava. Now that we know what the different outcomes are, we need to assign payoffs to each hypothetical situation, which represents each player’s incomes they would receive if the hypothetical actions were taken. Payoff: the benefit to each player associated with the joint actions of all the players. The payoffs of a game are typically represented in a payoff matrix, as indicated to the right. A matrix is just any rectangular array of numbers. The first number in each box is the reward received by the row player (whose name begins with A as a 70 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. reminder that his payoff is first). The second number is the column player’s payoff. Since the players’ income depends on the market prices, which in turn depend on their decisions, this is called an “invisible hand” game. 4.2 Equilibrium in the invisible hand game Game theory may also be able to provide predictions about what will happen. To predict the outcome of a game, we need another concept, which is the best response of each player. Best response: in game theory, the strategy that will give a player the highest payoff, given the strategies that the other players select. Finding best responses Suppose Anil considers the hypothetical case in which Bala has chosen to grow rice. Anil would decide to grow cassava, as Anil would get a payoff of 4, compared to a payoff of 1 if you decided to grow rice. We indicate this choice by means of a solid black dot in the corresponding block, which represents the row player’s best response. Similarly, if Bala chooses to grow cassava, Anil’s best response would also be to grow cassava, because the payoff will be 3, rather than 2 (if Anil chose to grow rice). Place a solid black dot in the corresponding block. This will yield a payoff matrix that looks like this, thus far. The payoff in this game refers to units of income that the player would receive when they take their crops to sell on the markets. Due to the fact that Anil will choose to grow cassava, regardless of what choice Bala makes, it can be concluded that Anil’s dominant strategy is to grow cassava. Dominant strategy: action that yields the highest payoff for a player, no matter what the other players do. 71 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m the column player’s best response. If Anil instead decided to grow cassava, Bala’s best response will again be to grow rice, because Bala will receive a payoff of 4 rather than 3. Place a circle in the corresponding block. Accordingly, Bala also has a dominant strategy – he will choose to grow rice, regardless of what Anil chooses to do. From the final payoff matrix to the right, it is clear that a row player has a dominant strategy if both solid black dots are in the same row; and a column player has a dominant strategy if both circles are in the same column. This is the case in the game that we just studied. Because both players have a dominant strategy, we have a simple prediction about what each player will do – each player will play their dominant strategy: Anil will grow cassava, and Bala will grow rice. If we find that both players in a two-player game have dominant strategies, the game has a dominant strategy equilibrium. Dominant strategy equilibrium: an outcome of a game in which every player plays his or her dominant strategy. Anil choosing Cassava and Bala choosing Rice is an equilibrium because neither of them would want to change their decision after seeing what the other player chose. In the dominant strategy equilibrium Anil and Bala have specialised in producing the good for which their land is better suited. Simply pursuing their self-interest resulted in an outcome that was: the best of the four possible outcomes for each player; and the strategy that yielded the largest total payoffs for the two farmers combined. 72 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. represents io which ut block, rib means of a circle in the corresponding st di best responses. We indicate this choice by e/ al 2. Circles represent the column player’s rs because they payoff will be 3 rather than fo response will be to also grow Rice, ot .N op Anil chooses to grow rice, Bala’s best Sh s. ie Now we consider Bala’s best responses. If In this example, the dominant strategy equilibrium is the outcome that each would have chosen if they had a way of coordinating their decisions. Although they independently pursued their self-interest, they were guided “as if by an invisible hand” to an outcome that was in both of their best interests. Real economic problems are never this simple, but the basic logic is the same. The pursuit of self-interest without regard for others is sometimes considered to be morally bad, but the study of economics has identified cases in which it can lead to outcomes that are in fact socially desirable. There are other cases, however, in which the pursuit of self-interest leads to results that are not in the self-interest of any of the players, for example the Prisoner’s dilemma. Homo economicus Homo economicus (economic man) is the nickname that is given to the selfish and calculating character that you find in economics textbooks. Have economists been right to imagine homo economicus as the only actor on the economic stage? Adam Smith believed that we were not homo economicus. But most economists since Smith have disagreed. Since the 1990s, in an attempt to resolve the debate on empirical grounds, economists have performed various experiments across the world in which the behaviour of individuals can be observed as they make real choices about sharing, using economic games. In these experiments, we almost always see some self-interested behaviour. But we also observe altruism, reciprocity and aversion to inequality, and other preferences that are different from self-interest. In many experiments, homo economicus is the minority. Reciprocity: a preference to be kind or to help others who are kind and helpful, and to withhold help and kindness from people who are not helpful or kind. Is the debate resolved? Many economists think so and now consider people who are sometimes altruistic, sometimes inequality averse, and sometimes reciprocal, in addition to homo economicus. They point out that the assumption of self-interest is appropriate for many economic settings, but it might not be as appropriate in other settings. 73 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie 4.3 The prisoners’ dilemma players choose to use Terminator, the water contamination becomes a serious problem, and they need to purchase an additional costly water filtering system. The hypothetical scenarios that describe their interactions are shown in the table below. 74 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. If only one of the players choose to use Terminator, the damage is limited, but if both io farm that eats the pests. ut To use integrated pest control (IPC) that introduces beneficial insects to the rib st di e/ al To use an inexpensive chemical called Terminator that kills every insect for miles around, but also leaks into the water supply they both use. rs fo to deal with pests that destroy their crops. Each has two feasible strategies: ot .N op Imagine that Anil and Bala are now facing a different problem – having to decide how Now that both players are aware of the outcomes, they must know their payoffs to make a decisions, which is in part dependent on the other player’s choice. This is an example of a strategic interaction. The payoff matrix for this strategic interaction is illustrated in the payoff matrix to the right. The payoff in this game refers to units of income that the player would receive when they take their crops to sell on the markets, minus the cost of the chosen form of pest control. Using the same method as before (black solid dots and circles), but omitting the illustration thereof, the best responses of both players are given below. Anil’s best responses: If Bala chooses IPC: Anil will choose Terminator. If Bala chooses Terminator: Anil will choose Terminator. Therefore, Anil has a dominant strategy – choose to use Terminator. Bala’s best responses: If Anil chooses IPC: Bala will choose Terminator. If Anil chooses Terminator: Bala will choose Terminator. Therefore, Bala has the same dominant strategy – choose to use Terminator. In this game, both players using insecticide (Terminator) is the dominant strategy equilibrium of the game. Both players will receive a payoff of 2. The problem is that both players would be better off if they both used IPC instead. The predicted outcome is therefore not the best feasible outcome. The pest control game is an example of a game called the prisoners’ dilemma. Prisoners’ dilemma: a game in which the payoffs in the dominant strategy equilibrium are lower for each player, and lower in total, than if neither player played the dominant strategy. 75 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie The name of this game comes from a story about two prisoners (for example Thelma game is given to the right. In a prisoners’ dilemma, both players have a dominant strategy which, when played by both, results in an outcome that is worse for both than if they had both adopted a different strategy. This example might be hypothetical, but the concept of prisoners’ dilemma games applies to many real problems. In economic examples, the mutually beneficial strategy is generally termed Cooperate, while the dominant strategy is called Defect. Cooperate does not mean that players discuss the decisions they will make together. The rules of the game are always that each player decides independently on a strategy. The contrast between the invisible hand game and the prisoners’ dilemma shows that self-interest can lead to a favourable outcome or an outcome that nobody would endorse. Three aspects of the interaction between Anil and Bala caused us to predict an unfortunate outcome in their prisoners’ dilemma game: They did not place any value on the payoffs of the other person, and so did not take account of the costs that their actions inflicted on the other. There was no way anyone could make either player pay for the harm that they caused. 76 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. lower payoff. The payoff matrix for this io means that each player would prefer a ut payoff is the number of years, which rib both get a jail sentence. In this game, the st di whereas the other person gets a long jail sentence. If both chooses to Accuse, they e/ al Accuse the other and one chooses to Deny, the accuser will be freed immediately, rs If both Deny, they are freed after a few days of questioning. If one person chooses to fo prisoners may have committed together or Deny that the other prisoner was involved. ot .N op and Louise) whose strategies are to Accuse (implicate) the other in a crime that the They were not able to make an agreement beforehand about what each would do. If we can overcome one or more of these problems, the outcome preferred by both would sometimes be the result. 4.4 Social preferences: Altruism When students play one-shot prisoners’ dilemma games in experiments, it is common to observe many participants playing the Cooperate strategy, despite mutually choosing Defect being the dominant strategy for players who care only about their own monetary payoffs. One interpretation of these results is that players are altruistic. The economic models we used in Unit 3 assumed self-interested preferences. People generally do not care only about what happens to themselves, but also what happens to others. Then we say that the individual has social preferences. Social preferences: preferences that place a value on what happens to other people, even if it results in lower payoffs for the individual. Altruism is an example of a social preference. Spite and envy are also social preferences, which indicates that social preference can be negative or positive. Altruistic preferences as indifference curves In previous units, we used indifference curves and feasible sets to model consumer’s behaviour. We can do the same to study how people interact when social preferences are part of their motivation. Imagine the following situation. Anil was given some tickets for the national lottery, and one of the tickets won a prize of 10 thousand rupees. Anil can keep all the money for himself, or he can share some of with his neighbour Bala. 77 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie The figure to the right illustrates the situation graphically. The horizontal axis ut rib st di e/ al rs combination of amounts of fo and the vertical one the amount that he gives to Bala. Each point represents a ot .N op represents the amount of money (in thousands of rupees) that Anil keeps for himself, n. io money for Anil and Bala in thousands of rupees. The shaded triangle depicts the feasible choices for Anil. At the corner (10, 0) on the horizontal axis, Anil keeps it all. At the other corner (0, 10) on the vertical axis, Anil gives it all to Bala. The boundary of the shaded area is the feasible frontier. If Anil divides up his prize money, he chooses a point on that frontier, because being inside the frontier would mean throwing away some of the money. The choice among points on the feasible frontier is called a zero sum game because, when choosing point B rather than point A, the sum of Anil’s losses and Bala’s gains is zero, for example, Anil has 3 thousand fewer rupees at B than at A, and Bala has 3 thousand rupees more at B than at A. Zero sum game: a game in which the payoff gains and losses of the individuals sum to zero, for all combinations of strategies they might pursue. If Anil is self-interested, his indifference curves are straight vertical lines, as illustrated in the figure above, because he is indifferent to whether Bala gets a lot or nothing. Given his feasible set, Anil’s best option would be point A, where he keeps all of the money. If Anil were somewhat altruistic, he has downward-sloping indifference curves, as indicated above. This is because Anil will derive utility from Bala’s consumption. In this instance, his best feasible option in this case, is therefore point B. If Anil is self-interested, the best option given his feasible set is A, where he keeps all the money. If he derives utility from Bala’s consumption, he has downward-sloping indifference curves so he may prefer an outcome where Bala gets some of the money. 78 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. 4.5 Altruistic preferences in the prisoners’ dilemma When Anil and Bala wanted to get rid of pests, they found themselves in a prisoners’ dilemma. One reason for the unfortunate outcome was that they did not account for the costs that their actions inflicted on the other. The choice of pest control regime using the insecticide implied a free ride on the other farmer’s contribution to ensuring clean water. If either player cared for the wellbeing of both players, the outcome can be different. In the figure below, the two axes represent Anil and Bala’s payoffs. The diagram shows all feasible outcomes. However, now there are only four feasible combinations of Terminator (T) and IPC (I). If Anil does not care about Bala’s wellbeing, Anil’s indifference curves are vertical, so (T, I) is his most preferred outcome. When Anil cares about Bala’s wellbeing, Anil’s indifference curves will be downward-sloping and (I, I) is his most preferred outcome. This figure demonstrates that when Anil is completely self-interested, his dominant strategy is Terminator, but if Anil cares sufficiently about Bala, his dominant strategy is IPC. If Bala feels the same way, then the two would both choose IPC, resulting in the outcome that both prefer the most. The lesson here is therefore that if people care about the wellbeing of one another, social dilemmas are easier to resolve. 79 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie .N op UNIT 5: PROPERTY AND POWER: MUTUAL GAINS AND CONFLCIT ot 5.1 Institutions and power e/ al rs fo what people do when they interact in a joint project the distribution of the products of their joint effort Institutions provide both constraints and incentives. In the terminology of game theory, institutions are the “rules of the game”, specifying who can do what, when they can do it, and how the players’ actions determine their payoffs. The terms “institutions” and “rules of the game” can be used interchangeably. Unit 4 illustrated that the rules of the game affect: how the game is played; the size of the total payoff available to those participating; and how this total is divided. Since institutions determine who can do what, and how payoffs are distributed, they determine the power individuals must get what they want in interactions with others. Power Power: the ability to do and get the things we want in opposition to the intentions of others. Power in economics takes two main forms: Power can set the terms of an exchange by making a take-it-or-leave-it offer. Power can impose or threaten to impose heavy costs upon a party, unless the other party acts in a way that benefits the person with power. A quick summary of an ultimatum game to understand the terminology used below: A two-person one shot game known as the ultimatum game is often used to study social preferences. It observes the choices of players to investigate their preferences and motives. A typical example is as follows: the players are invited to play a game where they can win some money. How much money they win will depend on how all 80 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. io Institutions are written and unwritten rules that govern: ut rib st di Institutions players choose to play the game. The rules are explained, and each player is randomly assigned to be the Proposer or the Responder. The Proposer is given an amount of money and is instructed to offer the Responder a portion of the money. It is a “take-itor-leave-it offer” hence the name – ultimatum game: the Responder can choose to accept an offer and get some money, or reject the offer and get nothing. The rules of the ultimatum game determine the ability that the players has to obtain a high payoff, which is a form of power called bargaining power. Bargaining power: the extent of a person’s advantage in securing a larger share of the economic rents made possible by an interaction. The power to make a take-it-or-leave-it offer gives the Proposer more bargaining power than the Responder, and usually results in the Proposer getting more than half of the “money”. The Proposer’s bargaining power is still limited because the Responder has the power to refuse. If there are two Responders, the power to refuse of each Responder is weaker, which means the Proposer has increased bargaining power. In real economies, unlike in the ultimatum game, the assignment of power is not random. In the labour market, the power to set the terms of the exchange typically lies with those who propose the wage and other terms of employment. Those seeking employment are like Responders, and since there are many employment seekers, their bargaining power may be low. Also, because the place of employment is the employer’s private property, the employer may be able to exclude a worker by firing them. The power to say no Suppose we allow a Proposer to split the money in any way and the Responder takes whatever he gets, if anything. Under these rules, the Proposer has all the bargaining power and the Responder none. There is an experimental game like this, and it is called the dictator game. In a capitalist economy in a democratic society, institutions exist to protect people against violence and coercion, and to ensure that most economic interactions are conducted voluntarily, which means a dictator game is not likely to occur. 81 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Allocation: a description of who does what, the consequences of their actions, and who gets what as a result. In the ultimatum game, the allocation describes the proposed division of the money by the Proposer, whether it was rejected or accepted, and the resulting payoffs to the two players. The Pareto criterion According to the Pareto criterion, allocation A dominates allocation B if at least one party would be better off with A than B, and nobody would be worse off. We say that A Pareto dominates B. Pareto dominant: allocation A Pareto dominates allocation B if at least one party would be better off with A than B, and nobody would be worse off. Can we say which allocation is better when we compare two possible allocations, A and B, that may result from an economic interaction? This criterion for judging between A and B is called the Pareto criterion after Vilfredo Pareto (economist; sociologist). Pareto criterion: according to the Pareto criterion, a desirable attribute of an allocation is that it be Pareto efficient. Note that when we say an allocation makes someone “better off” we mean that they prefer it, which does not necessarily mean they get more money (wellbeing vs wealth). 82 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. io ut rib st di e/ al We call the outcome of an economic interaction an allocation. rs and have a means of evaluating it – is it better or worse than other potential outcomes? fo When individuals make a decision, we want to be able to both describe what happens ot .N op Sh s. ie 5.2 Evaluating institutions and outcomes: The Pareto criterion Pareto dominance The figure to the right compares the four allocations from the pest control game from Unit 4 by the Pareto criterion. It is important to note that we assume that Anil and Bala are self-interested, so they prefer allocations with a higher payoff for themselves. Now, we use the exact same process to determine Pareto dominance as the process we used in Unit 2 to determine which technology dominated another. The blue rectangle with its corner at allocation (T, T) shows that (I, I) Pareto dominates (T, T), because it lies northeast of the allocation (T,T). Using the shaded areas in the figure to the right, it is possible to make the following conclusions – No allocation Pareto dominates (I,I), but it Pareto dominates (T,T). No allocation Pareto dominates (I,T), but it also does not Pareto dominate any other allocations. No allocation Pareto dominates (T,I), but it also does not Pareto dominate any other allocations. This example illustrates that the Pareto criterion may be of limited help in comparing allocations, as it can only tell us which allocations Pareto dominates other allocations, but it cannot tell us which allocation is better. The diagram also shows that three of the four allocations are not Pareto dominated by any other. An allocation with this property is called Pareto efficient. Pareto efficient: an allocation with the property that there is no alternative technically feasible allocation in which at least one person would be better off, and nobody worse off. 83 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie Pareto efficiency io ut rib st di e/ al rs efficiency is very widely used in economics, but economists should take caution with fo least one party would be better off and nobody worse off. The concept of Pareto ot .N op If an allocation is Pareto efficient, then there is no alternative allocation in which at n. the following: There is often more than one Pareto efficient allocation. The Pareto criterion does not tell us which of the Pareto efficient allocations is better. If an allocation is Pareto efficient, this does not mean we should approve of it. The Pareto criterion tells us which allocation is Pareto efficient and Pareto inefficient, but not which is better. There are many Pareto efficient allocations that we would not evaluate favourably. This is due to the existence of the concept of “fairness” that influences a decision. 5.3 Evaluating institutions and outcomes: Fairness Although the Pareto criterion can help us to evaluate allocations, we will also want to use another criterion: justice. We will ask, is it fair? First and foremost, we can apply the criterion of justice (or the standard of fairness) to the outcomes of the game. Suppose in the ultimatum game, the Proposer offered the Responder one cent from a total of R100. This is clearly an unfair outcome towards the Responder. Consider now the Proposer lost their job and was homeless while the Responder was well off. Now it seems more fair for the Proposer to keep R99.99. Thus, we might apply a different standard of justice to the outcome when we know all the facts. We could also apply a standard of fairness to the rules of the game. Suppose the Proposer offers an equal offer of R50 each to the Responder. It might appear fair, but what if this only occurred because the Responder had a gun to the Proposer’s head? We would probably judge this to be unfair then. The example makes a basic point about fairness. Allocations can be judged unfair because of: 84 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. How unequal they are, in terms of, for example income or subjective wellbeing. These are called substantive judgements of fairness. Substantive judgements of fairness: judgements based on the characteristics of the allocation itself, not how it was determined. How they came about, for example, by force, or by competition on a level playing field. These are called procedural judgements of fairness. Procedural judgements of fairness: an evaluation of an outcome based on how the allocation came about, and not on the characteristics of the outcome itself, (for example, how unequal it is). Substantive and procedural judgements To make a substantive judgement about fairness, you only need to know the allocation itself. However, for procedural evaluations you also need to know the rules of the game and other factors that explain why the allocation occurred. Substantive judgements Substantive judgements are based on inequality in some aspect of the allocation, such as: Income: The reward in money (or some equivalent measure) of the individual’s command over valued goods and services. Happiness: Economists have developed indicators by which subjective wellbeing can be measured. Freedom: The extent that one can do (or be) what one chooses without socially imposed limits. Procedural judgements The rules of the game that brought about the allocation may be evaluated according to aspects, such as: Voluntary exchange of private property acquired by legitimate means: Were the actions resulting in the allocation the result of freely chosen actions by the individuals involved, or was fraud or force involved? 85 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie Equal opportunity for economic advantage: Did people have an equal Proposers and Responders are chosen randomly; The game is played anonymously; Discrimination is not possible; and All actions are voluntary. A substantive judgement would differ per outcome, but if the Proposer took 90%, for example, most would agree that the allocation is unfair. Evaluating fairness The rules of the game in the real economy are a long way from the fair procedures of the ultimatum game, and procedural judgements of unfairness are very important to many people. People’s values about what is fair differ. John Rawls (philosopher) devised a way to clearly evaluate the fairness of an allocation: 1. We adopt the principle that fairness applies to all people. If the roles were to be revered, would each player still think that it is fair? 2. Imagine a veil of ignorance. For example, you do not know if you will be the Proposer or the Responder. 3. From behind the veil of ignorance, we can make a judgement. The veil of ignorance essentially give players an objective lens to view an allocation from. The veil of ignorance invites you, in making a judgement about fairness, to put yourself in the shoes of others quite different from yourself. Rawls argued that you would then be able to evaluate the constitutions, laws, inheritance practices, and other institutions of a society as an impartial outsider. 86 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. procedurally fair, because: io game. The experimental rules of the game will appear to most people’s minds as ut We can apply these differing judgements to evaluate the outcome of an ultimatum rib social norms? st di account of the extent to which an individual worked hard, or otherwise upheld e/ al Deservingness: Did the rules of the game that determined the allocation take rs fo some kind of discrimination or other disadvantages? ot .N op opportunity to acquire a large share of the total to be divided up, or were there There are many disagreements about the questions of value, but economics can clarify the following: How the dimensions of unfairness may be connected. For example, how will special advantages of one group affect the degree of inequality of another. The trade-offs between the dimensions of fairness. For example, do we have to compromise on the equality of income if we also want equality of opportunity? Public policies to address concerns about unfairness. Do the policies compromise other objectives? 5.4 A model of choice and conflict As before, Angela’s harvest depends on her hours of work, through the production function. She works the land and enjoys the remainder of the day as free time. Angela values both grain and free time, which means that she needs to make trade-offs. Angela’s indifference curves and her feasible frontier are shown in the figure to the right. Angela’s optimal combination is at point C. In this unit, we make an assumption about Angela’s preferences that you can see in the shape of her indifference curves that we call quasi-linearity. As she gets more grain, her MRS does not change. So, the curves have the same slope as you move up the vertical line at 16 hours of free time. More grain does not change her valuation of free time relative to grain. Why might this be? Perhaps she does not eat all the grain, but sells some and uses the proceeds to buy other things she needs. Remember: when drawing indifference curves for the model in this unit, simply shift them up and down, keeping the MRS constant at a given amount of free time. 87 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie A new character appears .N op ot Now, Bruno, who is not a farmer, but will rs fo st di e/ al claim some of Angela’s harvest, enters io ut rib the situation. The figure to the right n. indicates Angela and Bruno’s combined feasible frontier. The frontier indicates how many bushels of grain Angela can produce given the amount of free time she takes. The figure also indicates a possible allocation between Angela and Bruno – both receive 5,25 bushels of grain. Point F, G and H also show feasible allocations of this situation. Intuitively, however, point H is an impossible allocation, because at this point Angela gets no bushels of grain, which means she will starve. Of the allocations that are at least possible (Point E, F and G), the one that will occur depends on the rules of the game. 5.5 Technically feasible allocations Initially Angela could consume (or sell) everything she produced. But now Bruno has arrived, and, for example, has a gun with the power to implement any allocation that he chooses (dictator game). Bruno can determine the amount of grain Angela should produce, as well as the grain will be shared among the players. In this model, we assume that Bruno and Angela are entirely self-interested. We now make another important assumption. If Angela does not work, there are no other prospective farmers that Bruno can exploit. This means his reservation option is zero, which means he will consider the future – he has to give Angela some of the crops, otherwise she will die, and he will get nothing thereafter. The first step will now be to determine the set of technically feasible combinations of Angela’s hours of work and the amount of grain she receives. These combinations consider the limitations of technology and biology. Technically feasible: an allocation within the limits set by technology and biology. The technological limitations are easy to determine, because they are introduced by the production function, which is represented by the feasible frontier. Angela’s 88 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. biological survival constraint, however, shows the minimum amount of grain that she needs for each amount of work to survive. Points below this line (biological survival constraint) would leave her undernourished or overworked that she would not survive. This constraint shows what is biologically feasible. The question of biological feasibility only arises because Bruno claims a portion of the output. Biologically feasible: an allocation that can sustain the survival of those involved is biologically feasible. The figure to the right illustrates the feasible frontier, as well as the limitations imposed upon production. Angela’s chances at survival are limited by the productivity of her labour, as well as how much of what she produces is taken by Bruno. If Angela does not work at all, she needs 2,5 bushels of grain to survive, represented by point Z. If she gives up some free time and expends energy working, she needs more food, so the curve is higher when she has less free time. This is the biological survival constraint. The slope of the biological survival constraint is the MRS between free time and grain in securing Angela’s survival. Points below the biological survival constraint are biologically infeasible, while points above the feasible frontier are technically infeasible. This means that the technically feasible set is the intersection of the biologically feasible and the technically feasible set, i.e. the points in the lens-shaped area bounded by the feasible frontier and the biological survival constraint, including the points on the feasible frontier. We can now ask which allocation will occur, and how it depends on the institutions governing the interaction. 5.6 Allocations imposed by force With the help of his gun, Bruno can choose any point in the technically feasible set of allocations. But which will he choose? Bruno’s reasoning is that he should let Angela 89 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m survival constraint at any given number of hours of free time. Using the figure to the right, it is clear that the vertical distance is the greatest when Angela works for 11 hours, in which case Angela will produce 10 bushels and Bruno will get to keep 6 bushels for himself, after feeding Angela. This figure can be used to determine how much Bruno would get for every technically feasible allocation. The figure to the right indicates that the vertical distance is maximised at exactly the point where: ℎ = ℎ New institutions: Law and private property Now we move from a scenario of coercion (slavery) to one in which there is a legal system that prohibits slavery and protects private property and the rights of landowners and workers. We can therefore expect the outcome of the interaction to change. Bruno owns the land, which means that he can exclude Angela if he chooses. How much grain he will get as a result of his private ownership of the land will depend on the extent of his power over Angela in the new situation. When people participate voluntarily in an interaction, they do so expecting economic rents where the outcome is better than their reservation option. Economic rents are also sometimes called gains from exchange. 90 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. biological io the ut and rib frontier st di vertical distance between the feasible e/ al level of output that Bruno gets is the rs to give to Angela for her to survive. The fo into account the amount of grain he needs ot .N op him the maximum level of output, taking Sh s. ie work for the amount of hours that gives Gains from exchange: the benefits that each party gains from a transaction compared to how they would have fared without the exchange. Also known as gains from trade or economic rent. The sum of the economic rents is termed the surplus, or joint surplus to emphasize that it includes all the rents. Joint surplus: the sum of the economic rents of all involved in an interaction. Also known as total gains from exchange or trade. How the joint surplus will be dividing among the players depend on their bargaining power, which in turn depends on the institutions governing the interaction. 5.7 Economically feasible allocations and the surplus Suppose a new situation where there is now a government with laws administered by courts, and professional enforcers called the police. Bruno now owns the land, and Angela must have permission to use his property. He can offer her a contract that allows her to farm the land and give him part of the harvest in return, but the law requires that the exchange between the players is voluntary – Angela can therefore refuse the offer (contract). In this situation, Bruno makes a take-it-or-leave-it offer, like the Proposer in the ultimatum game. Furthermore, he also knows that Angela is entirely self-interested, which means that she will not punish an unfair offer, i.e. if Bruno makes an offer slightly better for Angela than not working and getting subsistence rations, she will accept it. What the offer should be is determined the same way as in the previous example, but now the limitation is not Angela’s survival, but rather her agreement. A consulting economist know that Angela values free time, so the more hours Bruno offers her to work, the more he will have to pay her. The economist therefore suggests that Bruno considers her indifference curve that passes through the point where she does not work at all and barely survives, which will tell him how much is the least he can pay her for each of the hours of free time she would give up to work for you. This point is illustrated by point Z in the figure on the following page. Point Z indicates the allocation in which Angela does no work and gets only survival rations (from an exogenous source). This is her reservation option. If Angela refuses 91 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie Bruno’s offer, she has the option of not working and receiving survival rations as a ot .N op backup. The figure below also indicates Angela’s reservation indifference. n. io ut rib st di e/ al that are as highly (equally) valued as one’s reservation option. rs fo Reservation indifference curve: a curve that indicates allocations (combinations) Below or to the left of the reservation indifference curve, Angela is worse off than in her reservation option. Above and to the right of the curve she is better off. The economically feasible allocations are represented by the points in the shaded area bounded by the reservation indifference curve and the feasible frontier, including the points on the frontiers. The biological survival constraint and the reservation indifference curve have a common point (Z), because at that point, Angela does no work and gets the subsistence rations from the government, which means that she can still survive. Other than that, the two curves differ. The reservation indifference curve is uniformly above the biological survival constraint. The reason is because However hard Angela works along the survival constraint, she barely survives; and the more she works the less free time she has, so she is unhappier. Along the reservation indifference curve, by contrast, she is just as well off as at her reservation option, meaning that being able to keep more of the grain that she produces compensates exactly for her lost free time. We can see that both Angela and Bruno may benefit if a deal can be made. Their exchange makes it possible for both to be better off than if no deal had been struck. All the allocations that represent mutual gains are shown in the economically feasible set in the figure above. Each of these allocations Pareto dominates the allocation that would occur without a deal. In other words, Bruno and Angela could achieve a Pareto improvement. 92 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. Pareto improvement: a change that benefits at least one person without making anyone else worse off. Again, Bruno maximises the amount of grain he can get at the maximum vertical distance between Angela’s reservation indifference curve and the feasible frontier. This will be where the MRT on the feasible frontier is equal to the MRS on the indifference curve, as shown in the figure to the right. Using coercion, Bruno chose allocation B. He forced Angela to work 11 hours and received grain equal to the distance of the line segment AB. With the voluntary exchange from this situation, allocation B is not available. The best that Bruno can do under the voluntary exchange is allocation D, where Angela works for 8 hours, giving him grain equal to the distance of the line segment CD, i.e. 4,5 bushels of grain. He must therefore make a take-it-or-leave-it offer of a contract allowing Angela to work the land, in return for a land rent of 4,5 bushels per day. If Angela must pay 4,5 bushels of grain, then she will choose to produce at point C, because that is where MRS = MRT where she works for 8 hours (irrespective of the land rent), otherwise she would have lower utility if she still had to give Bruno 4,5 bushels of grain, because she would be below her reservation indifference curve. She can achieve her reservation utility by working for 8 hours, so she will accept the contract. Since Angela is on her reservation indifference curve, only Bruno benefits from this exchange, i.e. the joint surplus goes to Bruno. The surplus that Bruno gets will vary with the amount of Angela’s hours worked. You will see that the surplus falls as Angela works more or less than 8 hours. It is humpshaped, like Bruno’s rent in the case of coercion. In this case, the peak is lower when Bruno needs Angela to agree to the proposal than what it was under coercion, in the previous example. This can be seen in the figure on the next page. 93 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m ot .N op Sh s. ie n. io ut rib st di e/ al rs fo 5.8 The Pareto efficiency curve and the distribution of the surplus Angela chose to work for 8 hours, producing 9 bushels of grain, resulting in a surplus of 4.5 bushels when she had to pay land rent and when she did not have to. The two cases differ in who gets the surplus. When Angela had to pay land rent, Bruno took the whole surplus, but when she did not have to pay land rent, she obtained all the surplus. Both allocations have two important properties: All the grain produced is shared between Angela and Bruno. This means that no Pareto improvement can be achieved by changing the amounts of grain each player consume. The MRT on the feasible frontier is equal to the MRS on Angela’s indifference curve. This means that no Pareto improvement can be achieved by changing Angela’s hours of work and hence the amount of grain produced. 94 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. This means that the allocations are Pareto efficient, because Pareto efficiency means that no Pareto improvement is possible. The figure on the following page shows that there are many other Pareto efficient allocations in addition to these two. Point C is the outcome when Angela pays no land rent. Point D is the outcome when Angela has to pay land rent. Point G is a hypothetical allocation, at which MRS = MRT. Angela works for 8 hours, and 9 bushels of grain are produced. Bruno gets grain equal to the distance of CG, and Angela gets the rest (equal to the distance of GD). Allocation G is Pareto efficient. All points making up the line between C and D are in fact Pareto efficient allocations, at which MRS = MRT, in which the surplus of 4,5 of grain is shared between Angela and Bruno. The set of all these Pareto efficient allocations is the Pareto efficiency curve. Pareto efficiency curve: the set of all allocations that are Pareto efficient. Often referred to as the contract curve, even in social interactions in which there is no contract, which is why we avoid the term. Also known as the contract curve. Figure 5.8 shows that in addition to the two Pareto efficient allocations we have observed (C and D), every point between C and D represents a Pareto efficient allocation. CD is called the Pareto efficiency curve. At each allocation on the Pareto efficiency curve Angela works for 8 hours and there is a surplus of 4.5 bushels, but the distribution of the surplus is different ranging between point D where Angela gets none of the surplus, to point C where Angela gets all of the surplus. At any allocation between C and D, both players receive an economic rent, which add up to the joint surplus. 95 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Through firms, the components of goods are produced by different people in the firm and assembled to produce the finished good; or Components are produced by groups of workers in different firms may be brought together through market interactions between firms. By buying and selling goods on markets, the finished good gets from the producer into the pocket of the consumer. The coordination of work The way that labour is coordinated within firms is different to coordination through markets: Firms represent a concentration of economic power. The power is placed in the hands of the owners and managers, who regularly issue directives with the expectation that their employees will carry them out. Markets are characterized by a decentralization of power. Purchases and sales result from the buyers’ and sellers’ autonomous decision. The prices that motivate and constrain people’s actions in a market are the result of the actions of many, not a decision by someone in authority. The idea of private property specifically limits the things a government or anyone else can do with your possessions. In a firm, by contrast, owners or their managers direct the activities of their many employees. The owners, through the board of directors, decide the longterm strategies of the firm concerning how, what, and where to produce. They then direct the manager(s) to implement these decisions. Each manager assigns workers 96 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. The division of labour is coordinated in two major ways: firms and markets. io The economy is made up of people doing and specialising in different things. ut 6.1 Firms, markets, and the division of labour rib may involve outsourcing production to other firms. st di boundaries in which it operates. It can take place within a multinational company or e/ al Offshoring: the relocation of part of a firm’s activities outside of the national rs that are not the main market for the goods produced. fo Many firms, such as Apple, prefer outsourcing (or offshoring) production to countries ot .N op Sh s. ie UNIT 6: THE FIRM: OWNERS, MANAGERS, AND EMPLOYEES to the tasks required for these decisions to be implemented and attempts to ensure that the assignments are carried out. Like any organisation, firms have a decision-making process and ways of imposing their decisions on the people in it. In a firm’s decision-making structure there is often people with power over others. The figure to the right shows a simplified picture of the firm’s actors and decision-making structure. In the figure above, directions or commands are represented by grey arrows and the flow of information is represented by green arrows. The upward green arrows are dashed because groups within the organisational hierarchy often know information that other groups do not, which represents a problem of asymmetric information. Asymmetric information: information that is relevant to the parties in an economic interaction but is known by some but not by others. Contracts and relationships The difference between market interactions and relationships within firms is clear when we consider the differing kinds of contracts that form the basis of exchange. Contract: a legal document or understanding that specifies a set of actions that parties to the contract must undertake. Below are examples of contracts: Sales contracts. The ownership of goods is (permanently) transferred to a new owner who can now use the good and exclude others from its use. Rental contracts. The ownership of goods is not transferred, instead it gives an individual a limited set of rights over the good, including the right to exclude others from its use. Wage labour contracts. An employee gives an employer the right to direct him/her to be at work at specific times, and to accept the authority of the 97 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie employer over the use of his/her time while at work. These contracts temporarily ot .N op transfer authority over a person’s activities from the employee to the manager fo io ut rib Wage labour: a system in which producers are paid for the time they work for their st di e/ al rs or owner. n. employers. Firms differ from markets in that social interactions within firms can extend over decades, while social interactions in markets are typically short-lived and not repeated. One of the reasons for this difference is that working in a firm means acquiring a network of associates who are essential for the job to be done well. Some colleagues might become friends. Managers and employees also acquire both technical and social skills that are specific to the firm they work for. Oliver Williamson (economist) termed these skills, networks, and friendships firm-specific assets, because they are valuable only while the worker remains employed in a firm. Firm-specific asset: something that a person owns or can do that has more value in the individual’s current firm than in their next best alternative. Also known as relationspecific assets. When the relationship (employment) ends, their value is lost to both sides. This social aspect becomes important economically when economic changes disrupt social interactions. The people making up the firm are united in their common interest in the firm’s success, because all of them would suffer if it were to fail. However, they have conflicting interests about how to distribute the profits from the firm’s success amongst themselves and may disagree about other policies such as conditions of work, managerial perks, and who makes the key decisions. 6.2 Other people’s money: The separation of ownership and control The firm’s profits legally belong to the people who own the firm’s assets, including its capital goods. The owners direct the other members of the firm to take actions that contribute to the firm’s profits. This in turn will increase the value of the firm’s assets and improve the wealth of the owners. The owners take whatever remains after revenues are used to pay the firm’s obligations, i.e. the profit is the residual. The owners claim it, which is why they are called residual claimants. Managers and employees are not residual claimants. 98 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. Residual claimant: the person who receives the income left over from a firm or other project after the payment of all contractual costs. This division of revenue has an important implication. If the firm’s revenues increase because managers or employees do their job well, the owners will benefit, but the managers and employees will not, unless they receive promotions, bonuses, or salary increases. In small enterprises, owners are typically also the managers and oversee operational and strategic decisions. In most cases the owner will try to maximise the profits of the enterprise by providing what customers want. In large corporations, there are typically many owners. Most of them play no part in the firm’s management. The owners of the firm are the parties that own the shares issued by the firm. Share: a part of the assets of a firm that may be traded. It gives the holder a right to receive a proportion of a firm’s profit and to benefit when the firm’s assets become more valuable. Also known as a common stock. By issuing shares to the general public, a company can raise capital to finance its growth, leaving strategic and operational decisions to a relatively small group of specialised managers. These decisions include what, where, and how to manufacture the firm’s products, or how much to pay employees and managers. The senior management of a firm is also responsible for deciding how much of the firm’s profits are distributed to shareholders in the form of dividends, and how much is retained to finance growth. The owners benefit from firm growth because they own part of the value of the firm, which increases as the firm grows. When managers decide on the use of other people’s funds, this is referred to as the separation of ownership and control. Separation of ownership and control: the attribute of some firms by which managers are a separate group from the owners. The separation of ownership and control results in a potential conflict of interest. The decisions of managers affect profits, and profits decide the income of the owners, but it is not always in the interest of managers to maximise profits. Managers might choose to take actions that benefit themselves, at the expense of the owners. Even single 99 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie owners of firms are not required to maximise their profits, but when they lose profits ot .N op as a result, the cost comes directly out of their pocket. 1. They can structure contracts so that managerial compensation depends on the performance of the company’s share price. 2. The board of directors, who typically have a substantial share in the firm, can monitor the managers’ performance. They have the authority to dismiss managers, and shareholders in turn have the right to replace members of the board. The owners of large companies with many shareholders rarely exercise this authority, partly because shareholders are a large and diverse group that cannot easily get together to decide something. Occasionally, however, this free-rider problem is overcome and a shareholder with a large stake in a company may lead a shareholder revolt to change or influence senior management. 6.3 Other people’s labour The decision-makers in a firm manage not only other people’s money, but other people’s labour, as well. People participate in firms because they can do better if they are part of the firm than individually, because there are mutual gains. A firm’s profits, before the payment of taxes, depend on the costs of acquiring the inputs necessary for the production process, the output quantities, and the sales revenues received from selling goods or services. Hiring employees, although different from buying other goods and services, is still an input to the process. A firm cannot write an enforceable employment contract that specifies the exact tasks employees have to perform in order to get paid, because: When the firm write a wage labour contract, it cannot know exactly what it will need the employee to do, which will be determined by unforeseen future events. It would be impractical or too costly for the firm to observe exactly how much effort each employee makes in doing the job. 100 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. can incentivise managers to serve their interests. io ut rib st di e/ al interests, rather than those of shareholders. Smith suggested two ways that owners rs fo Adam Smith (economist) observed the tendency of senior managers to serve their own The information can also not be the basis of an enforceable contract, if firms can find this information. Clearly there is contractual incompleteness. Incomplete contract: a contract that does not specify, in an enforceable way, every aspect of the exchange that affects the interests of parties to the exchange (or of others). Why is it not possible for firms just to pay employees according to how productive they are? An example is paying employees for product they finish. This method of payment is known as piece rate, which provides the employee with an incentive to exert more effort. Piece-rate work: a type of employment in which the worker is paid a fixed amount for each unit of the product made. Why do most firms not use this simple method? It is very difficult to measure the amount of output an employee is producing in modern knowledge- and service-based economies. Employees rarely work alone, so measuring the contribution of individual workers is difficult. Just as the owners of the firm protect their interests by linking management pay to the firm’s share price, the manager uses incentives so that employees will work effectively. 6.4 Employment rents There are many reasons why people put in a good day’s work. Once of the main reasons to do a good job is the fear of being fired, or of missing the opportunity to be promoted into a better position. Laws and practices concerning the termination of employment for cause differ among countries. The question is whether workers do care whether they lose their jobs? If firms paid their employees the lowest wages the employee would accept, the answer would be no. But in practice most workers care very much, because there is a difference between the value of the job and the value of the next best option, i.e. being unemployed and having to search for a new job. In other words, there is an employment rent. 101 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie exceeds the net value of her next best alternative (that is, being unemployed). Also ot .N op Employment rent: the economic rent a worker receives when the net value of her job fo n. io ut rib Employment rents can benefit owners and managers in two ways: st di e/ al rs known as cost of job loss. The employee is more likely to stay with the firm, which saves the firm recruitment and training costs. The firm can threaten to fire the employee, implicitly or explicitly, which will motivate the worker to perform better and keep their job. We can use the same reasoning in the employment of managers by the owners of the firm. The main reason owners wield power over managers is that they can fire them, and so eliminate their managerial employment rents. Counting the cost of job loss To calculate employment rent the benefits and costs of working compared with being unemployed and searching for another job needs to be considered. There are some costs of working, such as: The disutility of work, i.e. employees must spend time doing things they would prefer not to do; and The cost of travelling. But there are many benefits, which would be lost if you lost your job: Wage income; Firm-specific assets; Medical insurance; and The social status of being employed. The question now arises how we measure these considerations? 6.5 Determinants of the employment rent To construct a model of how employment rents may be used to motivate employees to work hard, we consider Maria, an employee earning $12 an hour for a 35-hour working week. To determine her economic rent, we need determine how she evaluates two aspects of her job: The pay that she gets, which is something she values; and 102 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. How hard she works, because she would like to do no more work than is necessary due to the disutility of work. Maria’s utility is therefore increased by the goods and services that she can buy with her wage income but is reduced by the disutility of work. Her disutility of work depends on how much effort she puts into her job. Suppose she spends half of her working time working, and the other half doing other things. Her effort level (which can range from zero to one) is therefore 0,5 – the proportion of her working hours in which she exerts effort to do her work. Working this hard is equivalent to a cost of $2 per hour to Maria. To calculate her employment rent we first find her net utility of working and earning $12, compared with being unemployed and earning nothing: net utility per hour = wage − disutility of effort per hour = $12 − $2 = $10 The total employment rent depends on how long she expects to remain unemployed. Let’s suppose that if she loses her job, she will remain unemployed for 44 weeks. The analysis of Maria’s total employment rent is shown in the figure to the right. Maria will continue to receive this $12 an hour for the foreseeable future if she keeps her job, as indicated by the horizontal line at the top of the figure. Maria’s current effort level is 0,5. Working this hard is equivalent to a cost of $2 per hour to Maria, illustrated by the small, bottom rectangle on the figure above. The difference between her wage and disutility of effort is the economic rent per hour ($10) that she receives while employed, illustrated by the blue shaded rectangle at the top of the figure above. If instead Maria were to lose her job at time 0, she would no longer receive her wages. This unfortunate state would persist if she remains unemployed, indicated by the horizontal line at the bottom of the figure. The expected duration of unemployment is 44 weeks, where she would have worked 35 hours per week (a total 103 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie of 1 540 hours), which represents how long she will remain without pay and without = $10 per hour × 1 540 hours = $15 400 People who lose their jobs can typically expect help from family and friends while they are out of work. Also, people who lose their jobs receive unemployment benefit or financial assistance from the government. Unemployment benefit: a government transfer received by an unemployed person. Also known as unemployment insurance. If Maria receives an unemployment benefit or income from any sources, it will partially offset her lost wage income. Let us suppose that while Maria remains unemployed, she will receive an unemployment benefit equivalent to being paid $6 an hour for a 35hour week. This is her reservation wage. Reservation wage: what an employee would get in alternative employment, or from an unemployment benefit or other support, when they are not employed in their current job. In the figure above, Maria’s reservation wage was zero, because she would not have received an unemployment benefit. The employment rent per hour, and accordingly the total employment ret, needs to, however, be recalculated by considering the reservation wage: employment rent per hour = wage − reservation wage − disutility of effort = wage − unemployment benefit − disutility of effort = $12 − $6 − $2 = $4 By taking into account the full duration of the unemployment period of 44 weeks, we see that the new total employment rent will be: total employment rent = employment rent per hour × expected hours of lost work time = $4 per hour × 1,540 hours = $6 160 104 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. total employment rent = employment rent per hour × expected lost hours of work io ut rib st di e/ al rs times the number of hours of work she will lose if her job is terminated, as below: fo weeks. Maria’s total employment rent is calculated as the employment rent per hour ot .N op the disutility of working. Maria expects to find another job at the same wage after 44 The figure below shows how Maria’s employment rent is affected by the unemployment benefit, assuming her effort and disutility of work are unchanged. Unemployment benefits usually run out eventually, which will change the opinion of the employee. If Maria’s eligibility for unemployment benefits of $6 lasted only for 13 weeks, her reservation wage would in fact not be $6. Her employment rent would be higher, and her reservation wage would be lower, because the average level of benefits she could expect over the 44-week period of unemployment would be much less than $6. 6.6 Work and wages: The labour discipline model When the employment rent is large, workers will be willing to work harder in order to reduce the likelihood of losing the job. A firm can increase the employment rent, and therefore the effort exerted by its employees, by raising the employees’ wages. We now represent this social interaction in the firm as a game played by the owners (through their managers) and the employees. The two players in this game is the owner (the employer) and a single worker, Maria. The game is sequential, i.e. one players makes a decision and the other player follows. This game will also be repeated in each period of employment. The following will be the order of play in this game: 105 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie 1. The employer will choose a wage based on the knowledge of how employees given that Maria responds the way she does, their strategies are a Nash equilibrium Nash equilibrium: a set of strategies, one for each player in the game, such that each player’s strategy is a best response to the strategies chosen by the other players. In this situation, we will ignore additional supervision costs and assume that the employer occasionally gets information on how hard employees are working. This is not enough to implement a piece-rate wage, but sufficient to fire a worker. Maria knows that the chance of the employer getting bad news decreases the harder she works. To decide on the wage to set, the employer needs to know how the employee’s work effort will respond to higher wages. We will consider Maria’s decision first. We will assume Maria has a reservation wage of $6. This means that her best response to a wage of $6 would be an effort level of zero. What if she were to be paid a higher wage? For Maria, effort has a cost, which is the disutility of work, but also a benefit: it increases the likelihood of her keeping the job, as well as her employment rent. She therefore needs to find a balance between the benefits and the costs. A higher wage will increase the employment rent, so it will lead Maria to choose a higher level of effort, which means her best response (her effort level) will increase with the level of the wage chosen by the employer. Maria’s best response curve is shown in the figure on the following page. Worker’s best response function (to wage): the optimal amount of work that a worker chooses to perform for each wage that the employer may offer. This is also known as the best response curve. 106 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. to the employer’s offer, and the employer chooses the wage that maximises his profit io considering the disutility of work. If Maria’s chooses her work effort as a best response ut the employer will make. Maria’s payoff is her net value of the wage she receives, rib greater Maria’s effort, the more goods or services she will produce, and the more profit st di The payoff for the employer is the profit made after the deduction of wages. The e/ al considering the costs of losing her job if she does not provide enough effort. rs 2. Maria chooses a level of work effort in response to the wage offered, fo employed in subsequent periods at the same wage, if they work hard enough. ot .N op respond to higher or lower wages and informs the employee that they will be This upward-sloping curve shows the relationship between Maria’s effort level for each level of the wage rate that the employer offers her. When the wage is low, the best response curve is steep, i.e. a small wage increase raises effort by a substantial amount. Furthermore, this curve also indicates diminishing marginal returns. This best response curve was constructed with the reservation being $6 (where the function touches the horizontal axis) and under the assumption that the duration of unemployment is 44 weeks. If the expected duration were to change, the best response function would change too, because Maria’s employment rent would change. The best response curve is the frontier of the employer’s feasible set of combinations of wages and effort that it gets from its employees. The slope of the best response curve is the employer’s MRT of higher wages into more worker effort. The best response curve is concave, i.e. it becomes flatter as the wage and the effort level increase. This is because, as the effort level approaches the maximum possible level, the disutility of effort becomes greater, which means it takes a larger employment rent (and therefore wage) to get effort from the employee. From the standpoint of the owner, the best response curve shows how paying higher wages can elicit higher effort, but with diminishing marginal returns. In other words, the higher the initial wage, the smaller the increase in effort and output the employer gets from an extra $1 per hour in wages. 107 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m face a trade-off. They can get more effort only by paying higher wages. To maximise profits, firms want to minimise the costs of production. They want to pay the lowest possible price for inputs. Accordingly, the employer would like to purchase employment at the lowest possible price. This does not, however, mean paying the lowest possible wage, because the employer knows if they pay the reservation wage, workers will have an effort level of zero. The wage, w, is the cost to the employer of an hour of a worker’s time. The hour does not matter, however, but rather the units of effort, which is the actual input in the production process. If Maria chooses to provide 0,5 units of effort per hour, the cost of a unit of effort to the employer will be 2 . In general, if Maria provides e units of effort per hour, the cost of a unit of effort is: e To maximise profits, the employer should therefore find a feasible combination of effort and wage that minimises . The employer should maximise the number of units of effort, also called efficiency units, that they get per dollar of wage cost, . The upward-sloping straight lines in the figure to the right joins together a set of points that have the same ratio of effort to wages, . We will call these lines isocost line for effort, where the cost of effort will be the 108 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. curve. The fact that the best response curve slopes upwards means that employers io ut rib st di e/ al that they cannot get Maria to provide more effort than is given by her best response rs the conditions under which she makes her choice. The owners and managers know fo Maria can choose how hard she works. The best the employer can do is to determine ot .N op Sh s. ie 6.7 Wages, effort, and profits in the labour discipline model same at any point on the line. These are essentially the indifference curves of the employer. The line slopes upward because a higher effort level must be accompanied by a higher wage for the ratio to remain unchanged. On an isocost line, the slope is , which is also the MRS, but the cost of effort is . A steeper line has a lower cost of effort (hence higher profits for the employer), and a flatter line has a higher cost of effort. The employer is indifferent between points on an isocost line. To minimise costs, the employer will seek to reach the steepest isocost line for effort, where the cost of a unit of effort is lowest. But because he cannot dictate the level of effort, he must pick a point on Maria’s best response curve. As the figure to the right shows, the employer’s best option would therefore be to set the wage rate at $12 on the isocost line that is tangent to Maria’s best response curve (point A), where the isocost line is tangential to the worker’s best response curve. At this point, the MRS (the slope of the isocost line for effort) is equal to the MRT of higher wages into greater effort (the slope of the best response function). Even though a point such as point B would have lower costs for the employer, they are infeasible, as Maria would not work for that combination of hourly wage and effort level. And the employer would also not choose point C, because they would be able to pay more in order to decrease the effort to wage ratio. Therefore $12 is the hourly wage that the employer should set to minimize costs and maximize profits. When wages are set by the employer in this manner, they are sometimes called efficiency wages because the employer is recognising that what matters for profits is , the efficiency units per dollar of wage costs, rather than how much an hour of work costs. 109 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie reservation wage, to motivate the employee to provide more effort on the job than he ot .N op Efficiency wages: the payment an employer makes that is higher than an employee’s fo n. io ut rib What has the labour discipline model told us? st di e/ al rs or she would otherwise choose to make. Labour discipline model: a model that explains how employers set wages so that employees receive an economic rent (called employment rent), which provides workers an incentive to work hard in order to avoid job termination. Equilibrium. In the owner-employee game, the employer offers a wage and the employer provides a level of effort in response, which are strategies that represent a Nash equilibrium. Rent. The employee provides an effort because they receive an employment rent that they might lose if they were to slack off on the job, because they would be fired. Power. The employer can exercise power over the employee, as the employee fear a loss of employment rent, which would incentivise a higher effort level, which contributes to the profits of the employer. Involuntary unemployment When we think about the implications of the labour discipline model for the whole economy, it tells us that there must always be involuntary unemployment. Involuntary unemployment: the state of being out of work but preferring to have a job at the wages and working conditions that otherwise identical employed workers have. Being unemployed involuntarily means not having a job, although you would be willing to work at the wage that other workers similar to you are receiving. In developing our previous model, we assumed that Maria could expect to be unemployed for 44 weeks before receiving another wage offer at the same level. This model was built on the assumption that there must be an extended period of unemployment. To see why, try to imagine an equilibrium where the employer offers Maria a wage of $12 per hour, and if she lost her job, she could immediately find another at the same wage. In this case, Maria’s employment rent would be zero, i.e. she would be indifferent between keeping her job and losing it, which means her best 110 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. response would be an effort level of zero. But this could not be an equilibrium, because the employer would not pay a wage for an employee to do nothing. In the event that there were plenty of jobs available in the economy at $12 per hour, and no one was unemployed, such a situation could not last. Employers would offer higher wages to ensure that their workers had something to lose and would therefore work hard. But with higher wages, they would not be able to offer as many jobs, which means there will definitely be involuntary unemployment. It is therefore important to realise that in equilibrium, both wages and involuntary unemployment must be high enough to ensure that there is enough employment rent for workers to put in effort. 111 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Monopoly rents: a form of economic profits, which arise due to restricted competition in selling a firm’s product. The figure to the right illustrates key decisions that a firm makes. This unit will specifically focus particularly on how a firm chooses the price of a product, and the quantity to produce, which will depend on the demand it faces and its production costs. The demand for a product will depend on its price, and the costs of production may depend on how many units are produced. But a firm can actively influence both consumer demand and costs in more ways than through price and quantity. Innovation may lead to new and attractive products, or to lower production costs. If the firm can innovate successfully it can earn economic rents—at least in the short term until others catch up. Further innovation may be needed if it is to stay ahead. Advertising can increase demand. The firm sets the wage, which is an important component of its cost. 112 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. higher profit margins, and monopoly rents. io through product selection and advertising. Those with fewer competitors can achieve ut employees who can make all these things happen. Firms can also increase profits rib quality than their competitors. They also need to be able to recruit and retain st di choice, their ability to attract customers, and produce at a lower cost and a higher e/ al A firm’s success depends on more than getting the price right, but also on their product rs their profits, considering the product demand curve and the cost function. fo Firms producing differentiated products choose price and quantity to maximise ot .N op Sh s. ie UNIT 7: THE FIRM AND ITS CUSTOMERS 7.1 Breakfast cereal: Choosing a price To decide what price to charge, a firm needs information about demand, i.e. how much potential consumers are willing to pay for its product. Demand curve: the curve that gives the quantity consumers will buy at each possible price. The figure to the right shows the demand curve of a company called Apple-Cinnamon Cheerios. This figure, for example, shows that if the price were $3, customers would demand 25 000 pounds of Apple-Cinnamon Cheerios. For most products, the lower the price, the more customers wish to buy. To choose a price and quantity to produce, the firm needs to consider how this decision will affect their profits, which is the difference between sales revenue and production costs. Suppose that the unit cost of Apple-Cinnamon Cheerios is $2. To maximise their profit, they should produce exactly the quantity they expect to sell, and no more. Total profit is therefore calculated as: profit = total revenue − total costs = price × quantity − unit cost × quantity = = P × Q − 2 × Q = (P − 2) × Q Using this formula, you could calculate the profit for any choice of price and quantity and draw relevant isoprofit curves. Isoprofit curves join points (combinations of price and quantity) that give the same level of total profit. Isoprofit curves can therefore be considered as the firm’s indifference curves, because the firm will be indifferent between combinations of price and quantity that give them the same profit. Isoprofit curves of a different total profit can be seen in the figure on the following page. 113 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m ot .N op Sh s. ie n. io ut rib st di e/ al rs fo The horizontal line in the figure above shows the choices of price and quantity where the profit is zero, because the price of the cereal is exactly equal to the cost of production. To achieve a high profit, the firm would like both price and quantity to be as high as possible, but the prices and quantity of the goods are constrained by the demand curve. If you choose a high price, you will only be able to sell a small quantity; and if you want to sell a large quantity, you must choose a low price. Accordingly, the demand curve also determines a feasible set. To determine the feasible set, it is important to consider the isoprofit curves and the demand curve together, as in the figure below. The firm wants to choose a feasible price and quantity combination that will maximize your profit. 114 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. The firm will always want to choose a point on the highest possible isoprofit curve, while still remaining in the feasible set. In the figure on the previous page, this happens at point E, where the manager should choose P = $4,40, and Q = 14 000 pounds. The optimal combination occurs where MRS = MRT. The slope of the isoprofit curve represents the trade-off you are willing to make between P and Q, the MRS. The slope of the demand curve is the trade-off you are constrained to make between P and Q, the MRT. Even from an economist’s point of view, there are other ways to think about profit maximisation. The lower panel in the figure to the right shows how much profit the firm would make at each point on the demand curve. When the quantity is low, so is their profit. As the quantity demanded increases, profit will rise until it reaches a maximum at point E. Beyond point E, the profit will start to fall. Profits will fall until they are zero where the price is equal to the unit cost of $2. From the figure to the right, it is clear that profits can often be negative, which typically occurs when selling a very high quantity where the price is lower than the unit cost. The graph in the lower panel of the figure above is the profit function, which shows the profit the firm would generate at every quantity, Q. The profit function is based on the highest price that would enable the firm to sell the relevant quantity, according to the demand function. 115 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m n. io ut rib st di Technological advantages. Large-scale production often uses fewer inputs e/ al rs produces its output at lower cost per unit. This may be possible for two reasons: fo An important reason why a large firm may be more profitable is that the large firm ot .N op Sh s. ie 7.2 Economies of scale and the cost advantages of large-scale production per unit of output. Cost advantages. In larger firms, fixed costs often have a smaller effect on the cost per unit. Bargaining power. Large firms often have the ability to purchase their inputs at a negotiated lower cost. Economies and diseconomies of scale If we increase all inputs by a given proportion, and it: increases output more than proportionally, then the technology is said to exhibit increasing returns to scale in production. increases output less than proportionally, then the technology exhibits decreasing returns to scale in production. Diseconomies of scale: these occur when doubling all the inputs to a production process less than doubles the output. Also known as decreasing returns to scale. increases output proportionally, then the technology exhibits constant returns to scale in production. Constant returns to scale: these occur when doubling all the inputs to a production process doubles the output. The shape of a firm’s long-run average cost curve depends both on returns to scale in production and the effect of scale on the prices it pays for its inputs. Economies of scale may result from specialisation within the firm, as it minimises training time by limiting the skill set that each worker needs; or for purely engineering reasons. There also exists built-in diseconomies of scale. Think of the firm’s owners, managers, work supervisors and production workers. 116 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. Cost advantages Cost per unit may fall as the firm produces more output, even if there are constant or even decreasing returns to scale. This happens if there is a fixed cost that is independent on the number of units. Fixed costs: costs of production that do not vary with the number of units produced. Examples of fixed costs include research and development or marketing expenses. Research and development (R&D): expenditures by a private or public entity to create new methods of production, products, or other economically relevant new knowledge. Secondly, large firms can also get cost advantages because they can purchase their inputs on more favourable terms, because they have more bargaining power to negotiate with suppliers. Demand advantages Large firms may also benefit a firm in selling its product. This occurs because people are more likely to buy a product or service if it already has a lot of users. Such demandside benefits of scale are called network economies of scale. Network economies of scale: these exist when an increase in the number of users of an output of a firm implies an increase in the value of the output to each of them, because they are connected to each other. 7.3 Production: The cost function for Beautiful Cars Consider a firm, Beautiful Cars, that manufactures cars, which produces specialty cars and will turn out to be rather small. Think about the costs of producing and selling cars. The firm needs premises equipped with machines to produce car body parts, as well as raw materials and components to produce the relevant car parts, and lastly, also pay employees to operate the equipment. A firm’s owners would usually not be willing to invest in a firm if they could make better use of their money by investing and earning profits elsewhere. What they could receive if they invested elsewhere, per dollar of investment, is called the opportunity cost of capital. 117 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie .N op Opportunity cost of capital: the amount of income an investor could have received ot by investing the unit of capital elsewhere. n. io ut rib st di shareholders to cover the opportunity cost of capital to induce them to continue to e/ al rs fo Part of the cost of producing cars is the amount that the firm has to pay to the invest in the assets that the firm needs to produce cars. The more cars the firm produces, the higher the total costs will be. The upper panel of the figure to the right shows that total costs depend quantity of on the cars, Q, produced per day. This is the firm’s cost function, C(Q). The cost function shows that when the firm does not produce or sell any cars, they still need to cover their fixed costs, F, which is illustrated in the top panel of the figure to the right. From the cost function, the firm can calculate its average cost of a car ( ), and how it changes with Q; the average cost curve (AC) is plotted in the lower panel of the figure to the right. Initially, as output rises, fixed costs are shared between more cars, and the average cost falls. The average cost will then reach a minimum, as illustrated by point B above. Thereafter, the average cost will start to rise again as the increase in variable costs outweigh the benefit of the fixed cost being shared over many cars. 118 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. Marginal cost At each point on the cost function, the marginal cost (MC) can also be calculated, which corresponds to the slope of the cost function. Marginal cost: the effect on total cost of producing one additional unit of output. It corresponds to the slope of the total cost function at each point. If cost increases by ΔC when quantity is increased by ΔQ, the marginal cost can be estimated by: MC = ΔC ΔQ If we calculate marginal cost at every point on the cost function, we can draw the marginal cost curve. The figure below indicates the marginal cost at every quantity, plotted along with the average cost at that quantity. The marginal cost curve is an upward-sloping line as it represents the slope of the total cost curve, which becomes increasingly steeper as the quantity increases. It is this rising marginal cost that eventually causes the average costs to increase and causes the “upswing” in the average cost curve, as shown above. Now if we compare the AC and MC curves, we can draw the following conclusions The AC curve is downward-sloping at values of Q where the AC is greater than the MC; and 119 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m The AC curve is at a minimum at the Q where AC = MC. 7.4 Demand and isoprofit curves: Beautiful Cars Cars are differentiated products. Differentiated product: a product produced by a single firm that has some unique characteristics compared to similar products of other firms. We expect that a firm selling a differentiated product to face a downward-sloping demand curve. For any product that consumers might wish to buy, the product demand curve is a relationship that tells you the number of items (the quantity) they will buy at each possible price. Each consumer has a willingness to pay (WTP) for a Beautiful Car, which depends on how much the customer personally values it. Willingness to pay (WTP): an indicator of how much a person values a good, measured by the maximum amount he or she would pay to acquire a unit of the good. A consumer will buy a car if the price is less than or equal to their WTP. Suppose we line up the consumers in order of WTP, with the highest first, and plot a graph to show how the WTP varies along the line, as illustrated in the figure to the right. Then if we choose say P = $3 any price, 200, the graph shows the number of consumers whose WTP is greater than or equal to P. In this case, 60 consumers are willing to pay $3 200 or more, so the demand for cars at a price of $3 200 is 60. 120 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. produced jointly by a single firm, rather being produced in separate firms. io Economies of scope: cost savings that occur when two or more products are ut rib st di This happens regardless of the shape of the total cost function. e/ al rs fo ot The AC curve is upward-sloping at values of Q where AC is less than MC. .N op Sh s. ie If the price is lower, there are a larger number of consumers willing to buy, so the demand is higher. Demand curves are often drawn as straight lines, as in the figure above, although there is no reason to expect them to be straight in reality. In reality, demand curves are curved as we saw in the demand curve for Apple-Cinnamon Cheerios. The downward slope of the demand curve can be explained by the relationship between price and quantity, which is also known as the Law of Demand. The demand curve determines the feasible set of combinations of P and Q. To find the profit-maximising point, we need to combine the demand curve and the isoprofit curves again and look for the point of tangency. The firm’s profit is the difference between its revenue and its total costs: profit = total revenue − total costs = P × Q − C(Q) This calculation gives us what is known as the economic profit. Economic profit: a firm’s revenue minus its total costs (including the opportunity cost of capital). Remember, the cost function includes the opportunity cost of capital, which is referred to as normal profits. Normal profits: corresponds to zero economic profit and means that the rate of profit is equal to the opportunity cost of capital. Economic profit is the additional profit above the minimum return required by shareholders. Equivalently, profit is the number of units of output multiplied by the profit per unit, which is the difference between the price and the average cost: profit = Q × (P − C(Q)) = Q × (P − AC) From this equation, it is clear that the shape of the isoprofit curves will depend on the shape of the average cost curve. 121 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie The figure to the right .N op ot combines the different fo e/ al rs graphs that we have ut rib st di looked at so far. The n. the io lowest curve shows zero-economic- profit curve, i.e. the combinations of price and quantity for which the firm will make a normal profit, because the P = AC at each quantity. In the figure on the previous page, the MC of Beautiful Cars can be distinguished from the MC curve at ay given quantity. The P is determined by tracing that quantity to the isoprofit curve. Bearing this in mind, we can note that: Isoprofit curves slope downwards at points where P > MC, i.e. the isoprofit curve is above the MC curve. Isoprofit curves slope upward at points where P < MC, i.e. the MC curve is above the isoprofit curve. Profit margin: the difference between the price and the marginal cost. At any point on an isoprofit curve the slope is given by: slope of isoprofit curve = − (P − MC) =− profit margin quantity 7.5 Setting price and quantity to maximise profit To determine the best choice of price and quantity for the firm, the firm needs to consider the demand curve, the isoprofit curves and its MC curve. The only feasible choices are the points on or below the demand curve, shown by the pink shaded area on the diagram. To maximize profit the firm should choose the tangency point E, which is on the highest possible isoprofit curve, as shown in the figure below. 122 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. The profit-maximizing price and quantity are P* = $5 440 and Q* = 32, and the corresponding profit is $63 360. The optimal combination of price and quantity balances the trade-off that the firm would be willing to make between price and quantity for any given level of total profit, against the trade-off the firm is constrained to make by the demand curve. Constrained optimisation The profit-maximisation problem is another constrained choice problem. Each of these problems have the same structure: The decision-maker wants to choose the values of one or more variables to achieve a goal, or objective. The objective is to optimize something. The decision-maker faces a constraint, which limits what is feasible. A decision-maker chooses the values of one or more variables to achieve an objective subject to a constraint that determines the feasible set. This far, the decision-maker’s choice is represented graphically by showing the indifference curves, which relate to the objective (iso-utility, isocost, or isoprofit), as well as the feasible set of outcomes, which is determined by the constraint. The solution of the problem is always at the tangency point where the MRS (slope of the indifference curve) is equal to the MRT (slope of the constraint). 123 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m st di e/ al rs isoprofit curves. Instead, we use the marginal revenue curve. Remember that if Q cars fo Let’s consider a different method of finding the profit-maximising point, without using ot .N op Sh s. ie 7.6 Look at profit maximization as marginal revenue and marginal cost n. io ut rib are sold at a price P, revenue, R, is given by: R = P × Q Calculating the revenue, also allows the firm to determine the marginal revenue of the firm. Marginal revenue: the increase in revenue obtained by increasing the quantity by one unit. The firm can calculate its marginal revenue as: R Q The table below indicates how to calculate the marginal revenue when Q = 20. Quantity Price Revenue Q = 20 P = $6 400 R = $128 000 Q = 21 P = $6 320 R = $132 720 ΔQ = 1 ΔP = $80 MR = $4 720 Gain in revenue (Price of selling the 21st car) $6 320 Loss of revenue ($80 on each of the other 20 sold cars) −$1 600 Marginal revenue $4 720 124 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. The table above shows that the marginal revenue can also be calculated as the difference between the gain of $6,320 and the loss of $1,600. This can also be graphically illustrated by the figure to the right. The figure shows that the firm’s revenue is the area of the rectangle drawn below the demand curve. When Q is increased from 20 to 21, revenue changes for two reasons – the extra car sold at the new price, and the loss of $80 on each of the other 20 cars. The marginal revenue is the net effect of these two changes. The series of figures on the following page illustrate how to find the marginal revenue curve and how it can be it to find the point of maximum profit. The upper panel shows the demand curve, which depicts a series of changes in revenue by means of shaded rectangles as in the figure above. The middle panel shows the marginal cost curve together with the marginal revenue curve, which is constructed from the additional revenue as illustrated by the shaded rectangles in the top panel. The marginal revenue curve is usually downward sloping, but it does not necessarily have to be. 125 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m ot .N op Sh s. ie n. io ut rib st di e/ al rs fo The firm’s profit The lower two panels in the figure above demonstrate that the profit-maximising quantity is found where the MR and MC curves intersect. To understand why, it is important to note that the change in profit if Q was increased by one unit, the marginal profit, would be the difference between the change in revenue, and the change in costs: marginal profit = MR − MC 126 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. Marginal profit is the slope of the profit function. A summary of the figure on the previous page can be given by the following: If MR > MC (Marginal profit > 0), the firm could increase profit by raising Q; If MR = MC (Marginal profit = 0), the firm is at its maximum profit; and/or If MR < MC (Marginal profit < 0), the firm could increase profit by decreasing Q. 7.7 Gains from trade When people engage voluntarily in economic interactions, they do so because they can obtain a surplus called economic rent. The total surplus for the parties involved is a measure of the gains from exchange. We can analyse the outcome of the economic interactions between consumers and a firm just as we did for Angela and Bruno in Unit 5. We judge the total surplus, and the way it is shared, in terms of Pareto efficiency and fairness. We have assumed that the rules of the game for allocating Cheerios and cars to consumers are: 1. A firm decides how many items to produce and sets a price; and 2. Then individual consumers decide whether to buy. These rules reflect typical market institutions for the allocation of consumer goods. In the interactions between Beautiful Cars and its consumers, there are potential gains for both, if the firm can manufacture a car at a cost less than the value of the car to a consumer. Recall, the demand curve shows the WTP of each of the potential consumers. A consumer whose WTP > P will buy the good and receive a surplus, since the value to her of the car is more than she must pay for it. Similarly, the marginal cost curve shows what it costs to make each additional car. And if the marginal cost is lower than the price, the firm receives a surplus too. The figure on the following page will be used to shows how the firm can determine the total surplus for the firm and its consumers, when Beautiful Cars sets the price to maximize its profits. Total surplus: the total gains from trade received by all parties involved in the exchange. It is measured as the sum of the consumer and producer surpluses. total surplus = sum of WTPs of consumers − sum of MCs of producers 127 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie Gains from trade line at the quantity 10. Similarly, the 15th consumer with a WTP of $6 800 will have a surplus of $1 360. To find the total surplus obtained by consumers, we add together the surplus of each buyer, which is shown by the red shaded triangle between the demand curve and the line where price is P*. This measure of the consumers’ gains from trade is the consumer surplus. Consumer surplus: the consumer’s WTP for a good minus the price at which the consumer bought the good, summed across all units sold. consumer surplus = sum of WTPs − sum of prices paid Similarly, the firm makes a producer surplus on each car sold. Producer surplus: the price at which a firm sells a good minus the minimum price at which it would have been willing to sell the good, summed across all units sold. producer surplus = sum of prices received − sum of MCs of each unit 128 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. example, whose WTP is $7 200 makes a surplus of $1 760, as shown by the vertical io ut rib st di e/ al rs means that the particular buyer’s surplus is equal to zero. The 10th consumer, for fo 32nd consumer whose WTP is $5 440 is indifferent between buying a car and not. This ot .N op When the firm sets its profit-maximizing price at $5 440 and sells 32 cars per day, the The marginal cost of the 20th car is $2 000. By selling it for $5 440, the firm gains $3 440, shown by the vertical line in the figure above between P* and the marginal cost curve. To find the total producer surplus we add together the surplus on each car produced, which is shown by the purple-shaded area. We see from the relative size of the two areas in the figure on the previous page, that in this market, the firm obtains a greater surplus share. The producer surplus is closely related to the firm’s profit, but it is not quite the same thing. Producer surplus is the difference between the firm’s revenue and the marginal costs of every unit, but it doesn’t allow for the fixed costs, which are incurred even when Q = 0. The profit is therefore the producer surplus minus fixed costs. Similar to Angela and Bruno’s situation, both parties gain in the market for Beautiful Cars, and the division of the gains is determined by the bargaining power of the players. In this case the firm has more bargaining power than its consumers, which is illustrated by the larger producer surplus. Pareto efficiency The question arises whether the allocation of cars in this market are Pareto efficient? The answer is no, because there are consumers who do not purchase cars at the firm’s chosen price, but who would nevertheless be willing to pay more than it would cost the firm to produce them. The figure to the right (an extension of the one on the previous page) indicates that the firm makes a surplus on the marginal car (the 32nd car), because the price is greater than the marginal cost. The firm could, however, produce another car and sell it to the 33rd consumer at a price lower than $5 440, which is still higher than the production cost. This would be a Pareto improvement, because the firm and the 33rd consumer would be better off. This means that the potential gains from trade 129 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie in the market for this type of car was not exhausted at point E, even though it was the .N op ot profit maximising point. consumers would be willing to pay. At point F, the consumer surplus would be higher than at point E, but the producer surplus is less. Since the firm will choose E, as its producer surplus is higher, there is a loss of potential (consumer) surplus, known as the deadweight loss. Deadweight loss: a loss of total surplus relative to a Pareto efficient allocation. In the figure on the previous page, deadweight loss is equal to the triangular area between Q = 32, the demand curve, and the marginal cost curve. Accordingly, the firm will choose point E, because that is the best it can do given the rules of the game, i.e. selling to all customers at one. This example therefore shows that the allocation that results from price-setting by the producer of a differentiated product is Pareto inefficient. because the firm uses its bargaining power to keep the price higher than the marginal cost by producing a quantity that is too low, relative to the Pareto efficient allocation. Imagine the rules of the game were different, and the firm could charge separate prices to each buyer, which is called perfect price discrimination, the firm would set the price for each consumer just below their WTP. The firm would sell to all potential buyer where their WTP > MC, and as a result all mutually beneficial trades would take place, resulting in the Pareto efficient quantity of cars. To enable perfect price discrimination, the firm would need to know the WTP of every buyer. Here, the deadweight loss would disappear, and the firm would be able to capture the entire surplus, i.e. there would be no consumer surplus. It might be unfair, but the allocation would be Pareto efficient. 7.8 The elasticity of demand A firm’s profit maximisation decision will be affected by the slope of the demand curve, i.e. the sensitivity of consumers’ demand for a good if prices were to change. The price elasticity of demand is a measure of the responsiveness of consumers to a price change. 130 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. because the production cost of another car would exceed how much any remaining io ut rib st di e/ al cost curve crosses the demand curve. This would be a Pareto efficient allocation, rs fo Suppose the firm had chosen point F on the figure above instead, where the marginal Price elasticity of demand: the percentage change in demand that would occur in response to a 1% increase in price. We express this as a positive number. Demand is elastic if this is greater than 1, and inelastic if less than 1. To illustrate, suppose the price of a product increases by 10% and a firm observes a 5% fall in the quantity sold. The elasticity, ε, can then be calculated as follows: =− % ℎ /% ℎ =− % ℎ −5 = 0,5 10 Due to the nature of the demand curve, one variable will always decrease, i.e. if quantity sold increases, the price will fall, or vice versa. The minus sign in the formula therefore ensures that the price elasticity of demand is always a positive number that measures responsiveness. The price elasticity of demand is related to the slope of the demand curve. If the demand curve is quite flat, the quantity changes a lot in response to a change in price, so the elasticity is high. Conversely, a steeper demand curve corresponds to a lower elasticity. But the slope of the demand curve and the price elasticity of demand are not the same thing, and it is important to notice that the elasticity changes as we move along the demand curve, even if the slope doesn’t. If you were to calculate the price elasticity of demand and the marginal revenue at every point on the demand curve, you would be able to make certain general conclusions. These general conclusions are indicated on the figure below. Any point on the demand curve to the right of the of the midpoint (Point C), will have a > 1 and the MR > 0. 131 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie Any point on the demand curve to the left of the of the midpoint (Point C), will = 1 and MR = 0. without losing much on the other cars and total revenue will rise, i.e. MR > 0. Conversely, if demand is inelastic, the firm cannot increase Q without a big drop in P, so MR < 0. This relationship is true for all demand curves. How does the elasticity of demand affect a firm’s decisions? The firm would never want to choose a point where the demand curve is inelastic, because the marginal revenue is negative there. Accordingly, the firm would always choose a point where the elasticity is greater than 1. Furthermore, the firm’s profit margin is also closely related to the elasticity of demand. When the demand curve is relatively flat, the price elasticity of demand is high. In these cases, the profit margin will be relatively small. When the demand curve is relatively steep and the price elasticity of demand therefore low, the profit margin will be high, but maximising the quantity profitwill typically be much lower than the Pareto efficient allocation, which results in a larger deadweight loss, as illustrated by the figure to the right. The aforementioned illustrates that the lower the elasticity of demand, the more the firm will raise the price above the marginal cost to achieve a high profit margin. When demand elasticity is low, the firm has the power to raise the price without losing many 132 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. quantity. So, by producing one extra car, the firm will gain revenue on the extra car io When demand is highly elastic, price will only fall a little if the firm increases its ut when demand is elastic, and MR < 0 when demand is inelastic. Why does this happen? rib < 1. Therefore, MR > 0 st di e/ al > 1, we say that demand is elastic, and inelastic if rs At the midpoint, point C, the fo When < 1 and the MR < 0. ot .N op have a customers, and the markup, which is the profit margin as a proportion of the price, will be high. Price markup: the price minus the marginal cost divided by the price. It is inversely proportional to the elasticity of demand for this good. The price markup is inversely proportional to the elasticity of demand. We can find a formula that shows that the markup is high when the elasticity of demand is low. We know that the firm chooses a point where the slope of the isoprofit curve is equal to the slope of the demand curve, and that the slope of the demand curve is related to the price elasticity of demand: =− × 1 slope By rearranging the formula above, we can get that the: slope of the demand curve = − × 1 From before, we know that the: slope of isoprofit curve = − − The firm will therefore choose a point where: − − =− × 1 By multiplying throughout by − , we get: − = 1 The left-hand side, which is the profit margin as a proportion of the price, is the price markup. Therefore, the firm’s markup is inversely proportional to the elasticity of demand. 133 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m If demand is highly elastic a tax will cause a large reduction in sales, which also reduces potential tax revenue. If a government therefore wishes to raise tax revenue, they should choose to impose a tax on products with inelastic demand. This is the case, for example, with tobacco products and alcoholic beverages, with the so-called sin tax. This is because it would be difficult to deter consumers from buying the products, even with the price increase associated with the imposition of taxes. 7.10 Price-setting, competition, and market power The firm’s pricing decision that we have modelled up until now, applies to all firms that produce and sell differentiated products and is affected by the price elasticity of demand. But what determines the price elasticity of demand product, and why do some firms face more elastic demand than others? Markets with differentiated products reflect differences in the preferences of consumers. People who want to buy a car are looking for different combinations of characteristics. A consumer’s WTP for a model will depend not only on its characteristics, but also on the characteristics and prices of similar products sold by other firms. When consumers can choose between several quite similar producers, the demand for each product is likely to be quite elastic. If the price of product A, for example, were to rise, the demand would fall because consumers would choose to buy one of the other similar product instead. Conversely, if the price of product A were to fall, the demand would increase because consumers would be attracted away from the other similar product. The more similar the products, the more responsive consumers will be to price differences. Only consumers with high brand loyalty and strong preference for a characteristic of a specific product would fail to respond. The firm will then have a relatively low price and profit margin. In contrast, the manufacturer of a very specialised product, very different from any other brand in the market, faces little competition and hence less elastic demand. It can set a price well above marginal cost without losing customers. Such a firm is 134 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. io ut rib st di e/ al paid by the consumers, so the effect of the tax will depend on the elasticity of demand: rs considering the imposition of taxes. This is because a tax on a good will raise the price fo Measuring elasticities of demand is useful to policymakers, especially when ot .N op Sh s. ie 7.9 Using demand elasticities in government policy earning monopoly rents arising from its position as the only supplier of this type of car. Augustin Cournot (economist) identified that differentiated products can lead to the development of a monopoly and therefore a monopolised market. Monopoly: a firm that is the only seller of a product without close substitutes. Also refers to a market with only one seller. In monopolies, firms set prices greater than the marginal production cost. Based on the above definition, it is clear that a firm will be in a strong competitive position if there are few firms producing close substitutes for its own brand, because it faces little competition. Substitutes: two goods for which an increase in the price of one leads to an increase in the quantity demanded of the other. Accordingly, its elasticity of demand will be relatively low. We say that such a firm has market power. Market power: an attribute of a firm that can sell its product at a range of feasible prices, so that it can benefit by acting as a price-setter (rather than a price-taker). The firm will have enough bargaining power in its relationship with customers to set a high price without losing them to competitors. Competition policy Market power allows firms to set high prices, and make high profits, at the expense of consumers. Potential consumer surplus would be lost because few consumers would buy at these high prices, and those who do buy have to pay a high price. The owners of the firm benefit, but overall, there is a deadweight loss. A firm selling a niche product catering for the preferences of a small number of consumers is unlikely to attract the attention of policymakers, despite the loss of consumer surplus. But if one firm is becoming dominant in a large market, governments may intervene to promote competition. A concern is that when there are only a few dominant firms in a market they may form a cartel. Cartel: a group of firms that collude in order to increase their joint profits by keeping prices artificially high. 135 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie By working together and behaving as a monopoly, rather than competing, the firms prices. 7.11 Product selection, innovation, and advertising The profits that a firm can achieve depend on the demand curve for its product, which in turn depends on the preferences of consumers and competition from other firms. The firm may be able to move the demand curve to increase profits by changing its selection of products, or through increased marketing efforts. When deciding what goods to produce, the firm would ideally like to find a product that is attractive to consumers and is differentiated from products sold by other firms. In this case, demand would be high and the elasticity low. This is not likely to be easy. Technological innovation could provide opportunities for firms to get ahead of competitors. If a firm has invented or created a new product, it may be able to prevent competition altogether by claiming exclusive rights to produce it, using patent or copyright laws. This could result in the legal protection of monopolies that limits the gains from trade, but conversely provides other firms with the incentive to conduct R&D to develop new products. Advertising is another strategy that firms can use to influence demand. When products are differentiated, the firm can use advertising to inform consumers about the existence and characteristics of its product, attract them away from its competitors, and create brand loyalty. Advertising is often not used to inform consumers about the product, but rather to increase brand loyalty, and encourage consumers of competing products to switch. 136 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. Dominant firms can also exploit their market position by strategies other than high io cartels. Also known as antitrust policy (in the US). ut Competition policy: government policy and laws to limit monopoly power and prevent rib policy in the US. st di limit market power and prevent cartels is known as competition policy, or antitrust e/ al firms often find ways to cooperate in the setting of prices to maximise profits. Policy to rs producing countries. While cartels between private firms are illegal in many countries, fo Organisation of the Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC), an association of oil- ot .N op within the cartel can increase their profits. A well-known example of a cartel is the 7.12 Prices, costs, and market failures One example of a market failures is when firms set prices above the marginal cost of producing their goods, especially when the elasticity of demand is low. Market failure: when markets allocate resources in a Pareto-inefficient way, resulting in a deadweight loss. Firms set prices above marginal costs when the goods they produce are differentiated from those produced by other firms, so that they serve consumers with different preferences and face limited competition. Firms can benefit from strategies that reduce competition, but without competition the deadweight loss may be high, so policymakers try to reduce the deadweight loss through competition policy. Product differentiation is not the only reason for a price above marginal cost. A second important reason is decreasing average costs, for whatever reason. In such cases, the average cost of production is greater than the marginal cost of each unit, and the average cost curve slopes downward. The firm’s price must be at least equal to average cost to prevent making a loss, which is therefore above the marginal cost. Decreasing average costs mean that firms can produce at lower cost per unit when operating at a large scale. This is common in the provision of utilities, such as supplying watering. If a single firm operates at a large enough scale can supply the whole market at lower average cost than other firms, the industry is said to be a natural monopoly. Natural monopoly: a production process in which the long-run average cost curve is sufficiently downward-sloping to make it impossible to sustain competition among firms in this market. In the case of a natural monopoly, policymakers may not be able to induce firms to lower their prices by promoting competition, since average costs would rise with more firms in the market. Governments may then choose to regulate the firm’s activities, limiting its discretion over prices in order to increase consumer surplus. An alternative solution is public ownership, for example the supply of electricity in South Africa. The price of a differentiated product is above the marginal cost as a direct result of the firm’s response to the absence of competing firms and price-insensitivity of consumers. The source of the problem in the cases of utilities is the cost structure, 137 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie rather than the lack of competition per se. However, the two problems, i.e. limited n. io ut rib Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. st di 138 e/ al scale eliminates other firms and therefore competition. rs winner-takes-all. The first firm to exploit the cost advantages of operating at a large fo competition among firms with downward-sloping average cost curves tends to be ot .N op competition and decreasing average costs, are often closely related because UNIT 8: SUPPLY AND DEMAND: PRICE-TALKING AND COMPETITIVE MARKETS The interaction of supply and demand determines a market equilibrium in which both buyers and sellers are price-takers, called a competitive equilibrium. The prices and quantities in competitive equilibrium change in response to supply and demand shocks. The model of perfect competition describes idealized conditions under which all buyers and sellers are price-takers. Price-taking behaviour ensures that all gains from trade in the market are exhausted at a competitive equilibrium. It is important to acknowledge and evaluate the similarities and differences between price-taking and price-setting firms. The market price of a good is determined by the interaction of supply and demand, but sometimes there is a large excess demand. Excess demand: a situation in which the quantity of a good demanded is greater than the quantity supplied at the current price. The amazing thing about prices being determined by markets is that individuals do not send the messages, but rather the anonymous interaction of sometimes millions of people. And when conditions change nobody has to change the message they are sending. A price change results from a change in firms’ costs. 8.1 Buying and selling: Demand and supply For a simple model of a market with many buyers and sellers, think about the trade of second-hand textbooks. Demand for the book comes from students who are about to begin a specific course, and they will differ in their WTP. No one will pay more than the price of a new copy. Below that price, students’ WTP will differ and depend on various things. When you buy something, you don’t need to think about your exact WTP, because you just decide whether to pay the asking price Figure 8.1 shows the demand curve. As in Unit 7, we line up all the consumers in order of WTP, highest first. The first student is willing to pay $20, the 20th $10, and so on. For any price, P, the graph tells you how many students would be willing to buy: it is the number whose WTP is at or above P. 139 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie The demand curve as we know it, represents the WTP of buyers; similarly, supply ot .N op depends on the sellers’ willingness to accept (WTA) money in return for books. n. io ut rib st di e/ al willing to sell a unit only for a price at least this high. rs fo Willingness to accept (WTA): the reservation price of a potential seller, who will be The supply of second-hand books comes from students who have previously completed a specific course and no longer need the textbook. Each of these suppliers will differ in the amount they are willing to accept, i.e. their reservation price. Reservation price: the lowest price at which someone is willing to sell a good (keeping the good is the potential seller’s reservation option). We can draw a supply curve by lining up the sellers in order of their reservation prices, or their WTAs, as in the figure to the right. Supply curve: the curve that shows the number of units of output that would be produced at any given price. For a market, it shows the total quantity that all firms together would produce at any given price. We put the sellers who are most willing to sell, i.e. those who have the lowest reservation prices, first, so the graph of reservation prices slopes upward. The supply curve slopes upward because the higher the price, the more students will be willing to sell. 8.2 The market and the equilibrium price Traditional market institutions brought buyers and sellers together in one (physical) place. With modern communications, sellers can advertise their goods and buyers can more easily find out what is available, and where to buy it. In some cases, it is still convenient for many buyers and sellers to meet each other. Alfred Marshall (economist) introduced his model of supply and demand. He called the price that equated supply and demand the equilibrium price. If the price was above the 140 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. equilibrium, suppliers would want to sell large quantities of grain, but fewer consumers would be willing to buy. This means there is excess supply. Excess supply: a situation in which the quantity of a good supplied is greater than the quantity demanded at the current price. In this case, even consumers who were willing to pay that much would realise that the suppliers would have to lower their prices. Accordingly, consumers would therefore wait until suppliers lowered their prices. Similarly, if the price was below the equilibrium, there would be an excess demand, so, sellers would rather wait for the price to increase before they sell. If, at any going price, the amount supplied did not equal the amount demanded, Marshall reasoned that some sellers or buyers could benefit by charging another price, i.e. the going price is not a Nash equilibrium. The price would therefore settle at an equilibrium level, where demand and supply were equated. Equilibrium (of a market): a state of a market in which there is no tendency for the quantities bought and sold, or the market price, to change, unless there is some change in the underlying costs, preferences, or other determinants of the behaviour of market actors. Marshall argued that the model of supply and demand can be applied to markets in which all sellers are selling identical goods, which is a different model as opposed to the model implemented for differentiated products in Unit 7. Marshall and Léon Walras (economist) termed the neoclassical school of economics and used calculus to formulate the workings of markets and firms, and express key concepts such as marginal costs and marginal utility, along with others, such as consumer and producer surplus. Marginal utility: the additional utility resulting from a one-unit increase of a given variable. To apply the supply and demand model to the textbook market, we assume that all the books are identical and that a potential seller can advertise a book for sale by announcing its price on a local website. We would expect that most transactions would occur at similar prices, because buyers and sellers can easily observe all the 141 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie advertised prices. The .N op ot equilibrium price can be fo e/ al rs determined by drawing ut rib st di the supply and demand n. io curves on one set of axes, as in the figure to the right. The equilibrium price always occurs at the intersection of the supply and demand curve, as at point A in the figure above. The equilibrium price can also be called the market clearing price. Market-clearing price: at this price there is no excess supply or excess demand. We say that a market is in equilibrium if the actions of buyers and sellers have no tendency to change the price or the quantities bought and sold, unless there is a change in market conditions such as the numbers of potential buyers and sellers, and how much they value the good. At the equilibrium price for textbooks, all those who wish to buy, or sell can do so, so there is no tendency for change. Price-taking Will the market always be in equilibrium? As we have seen, Marshall argued that prices would not deviate far from the equilibrium level, because people would want to change their prices if there were excess supply or demand. In the textbook market that we have described, individual students must accept the prevailing equilibrium price in the market, determined by the supply and demand curves. No one would trade with a student asking a higher price or offering a lower one, because anyone could find an alternative seller or buyer with a better price. The participants in this market are price-takers, because there is enough competition from other buyers and sellers so the best they can do is to trade at the same price. Price-taker: characteristic of producers and consumers who cannot benefit by offering or asking any price other than the market price in the equilibrium of a competitive market. They have no power to influence the market price 142 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. Any buyer or seller is of course free to choose a different price, but they would not benefit by doing so. In this unit, we study market equilibria where both buyers and sellers are price-takers. There are scenarios in which sellers are not price-takers, for example when suppliers sell differentiated products. When buyers and sellers are price-takers, we expect to see price-taking on both sides of the market where there are many sellers selling identical goods, and many buyers wishing to purchase them. On both sides of the market, competition eliminates bargaining power. We will describe the equilibrium in such a market as a competitive equilibrium. Competitive equilibrium: a market outcome in which all buyers and sellers are pricetakers, and at the prevailing market price, the quantity supplied is equal to the quantity demanded. It is a Nash equilibrium, because given the actions of all other players, no player could do any better than to continue with what they are already doing. 8.3 Price-taking firms We will now look at markets where the sellers are firms, instead of individuals as before. If there are many firms producing identical products, and consumers can easily switch from one firm to another, then firms will be price-takers in equilibrium. They will be unable to benefit from attempting to trade at a price different from the prevailing price. To see how price-taking firms behave, consider the figure to the right where there are many small bakeries that produce bread and sell to consumers. The market demand curve, which shows the total daily demand for bread of all consumers in the city, is downward sloping as before. Suppose you are the owner of one of the bakeries and need to decide what price to charge and how many loaves to produce each morning. The neighbouring bakeries are selling identical loaves at €2.35, the prevailing market price. Because there are so many bakeries, you are a price-taking firm. 143 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie As your bread output increases, your marginal cost will increase. When the quantity is fo e/ al rs of loaves per day increases, ut rib st di the average cost will fall, but At n. gradually. io the marginal cost will begin to rise higher quantities the marginal cost is above the average cost, then average costs will start to rise again. The marginal and average cost curves can be seen in the figure to the right. If the price of a loaf of bread were equal to the average cost, the economic profit would be zero, as illustrated by the lowest curve in the figure above. The owner typically generates a normal return on your capital, which means that the average cost curve is the zero-economic-profit curve. The zero-economic-profit curve is just another isoprofit curve. The isoprofit curves in the figure above show the price and quantity combinations at which you would receive higher levels of profit. As explained before, isoprofit curves slope downwards where price is above marginal cost, and upwards where price is below marginal cost, so the marginal cost curve passes through the lowest point on each isoprofit curve. Because the bakery is a price-taker, the price at which a loaf of bread needs to be sold is €2,35, the market prevailing price. Accordingly, the demand curve of price-taking an individual firm is a horizontal line at P*, the market prevailing ot .N op small, the marginal cost is low, but the average cost of a loaf is high. As the number price. The feasible set for the individual baker is therefore any price below the marketprevailing price and any corresponding quantity. 144 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. The quantity that yields the highest profit for the individual firm is indicated as point A in the figure on the previous page. At this point, the individual firm produces 120 loaves per day, sells them at €2,35 each and generates a profit of €80 per day, in addition to the owner’s normal profits. Point A can be determined in two different methods: 1. This is the point where the highest isocost line is tangential to the demand curve; and/or 2. This is the point where MC and the demand curve intersect, i.e. where the marginal cost is equal to the market price. A price-taking firm maximises profit by accepting the market price and choosing its quantity where the marginal cost is equal to the market price and selling it at that price. Consider the situation where the market price changes. If the market price were to rise to €3,20, the individual firm would be able to reach a higher isoprofit curve and accordingly the profit maximising quantity will increase to 163 loaves per day. If the price, however, falls to €1,52 the individual firm can only reach a lower indifference curve and accordingly the profit maximising quality will decrease to 66 loaves, and your economic profit would be zero. In each of these cases, you will choose the point on your marginal cost curve where the marginal cost is equal to the market price. From this, we can also construct the firm’s individual supply curve, as illustrated in the figure below. From the example on the previous page, the marginal cost curve is the supply curve for a price-taking firm. The individual supply curve shows that for each price it shows 145 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie the profit-maximizing quantity, i.e. the quantity that the firm will choose to supply. If the If you expect the price to rise soon, you might be willing to incur some shortterm losses, and it might be worth continuing to produce bread if the revenue helped you to cover the costs of maintaining your premises and retaining staff. 8.4 Market supply and equilibrium The market for bread in a particular city has many consumers and 50 bakeries. Each bakery has a supply curve corresponding to its own marginal cost curve, so we know how much it will supply at any given market price. To find the market supply curve, we have to add up the total amount that all the bakeries will supply at each given price level. In the event that each bakery has the same cost functions, it is easy to calculate the total market supply – determine how each individual bakery would supply at a given price and multiply it by 50 to find the total market supply at that price. The market supply curve has the same shape as the individual firm’s supply curve, as illustrated in the figure below. 146 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. io leave the market. ut If you expect market conditions to remain bad, it might be best to sell up and rib st di happen in the future: e/ al worth continuing to produce bread. Your decision depends on what you expect to rs be minimising your loss. If this happened, you would have to decide whether it was fo below the zero-economic-profit curve. On the supply curve, the individual firm would ot .N op price were to fall below €1,52 the individual firm would be making a loss as you are What if different firms had different costs? If the bakeries had different cost functions, at each given price level, each bakery would produce a different amount of loaves of bread, but we could still add them together to find market supply. The total amount of loaves of bread will then be plotted against the given price level to determine the market supply curve. The demand and supply curve for the bread market can be illustrated as in the figure to the right. In the market equilibrium, each bakery is producing on its marginal cost curve, at the point where its marginal cost is equal to the market price of €2,00, which is where the market supply and market demand curve intersects. 8.5 Competitive equilibriums: Gains from trade, allocation, and distribution Buyers and sellers of bread voluntarily engage in trade because there are mutual benefits in participating in the transaction. Their mutual benefits from the equilibrium allocation can be measured by the consumer and producer surpluses. Any buyer whose WTP is higher than the market price, receives a consumer surplus. Similarly, if the marginal cost of producing a good is below the market price, the producer receives a producer surplus. The figure to the right illustrates that the total surplus in a competitive equilibrium is computed the same as before. The entire shaded area between the demand and supply curve, shows the sum of all gains from trade in this market, known as the total surplus. The allocation between consumer and producer surplus is easy to determine. The red shaded area above the equilibrium price under the demand curve illustrates the consumer surplus. The blue shaded area below the equilibrium 147 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie price above the supply curve illustrates the producer surplus. In a competitive fo e/ al rs than the equilibrium quantity of n. io and ut trade gains rib unexploited st di were produced, there would be accordingly a deadweight loss, as illustrated in the figure to the right. If any quantity more than the equilibrium quantity were produced, the surplus on the extra loaves of bread produced would be negative, because these loaves of bread would cost more to make than consumers were willing to pay. At the equilibrium, all the potential gains from trade are exploited, which means there is no deadweight loss. This property holds in general – if buyers and sellers are pricetakers, the equilibrium allocation will always maximise the sum of the gains achieved by trading in the market, relative to the original allocation. The competitive equilibrium allocation will always be Pareto efficient. Pareto efficiency follows from three assumptions we have made about the bread market. Buyers and sellers are price-takers. The exchange of products in a competitive market is governed by a complete contract between buyer and seller. ot .N op equilibrium, the allocation will always maximise the total surplus. If any quantity lower What happens in the competitive market affects no one except the buyers and sellers. Fairness Even if we think that the market allocation is Pareto efficient, we should not conclude that it is necessarily a desirable one. What can we say about fairness in the case of the bread market? If we examine the distribution of the gains from trade between producers and consumers, it is clear that both consumers and producers obtain a surplus. In the example that we have been studying, the consumer surplus was slightly higher than the producer surplus, because the demand curve was relatively steep compared with the supply curve, which corresponds to a low elasticity of demand. 148 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. Similarly, the slope of the supply curve also corresponds to the elasticity of supply. In the example, the demand was less elastic than supply. In general, the distribution of the total surplus between consumers and producers depends on the relative elasticities of demand and supply. Furthermore, to evaluate the fairness of the allocation, we could also consider the market participants’ standard of living. For example, if the consumers in the bread market were exceptionally poor, it might be fairer to pass a law setting a maximum bread price lower than €2 to achieve a fairer, yet Pareto-inefficient, outcome. The Pareto efficiency of a competitive equilibrium allocation is often interpreted as a powerful argument in favour of markets as a means of allocating resources. But we need to be careful not to exaggerate the value of this result: The allocation may not be Pareto efficient, because we might not have taken everything into account; There are other important considerations, for example fairness; and Price-takers are hard to find in real life. 8.6 Changes in supply and demand An increase in demand In the market for second-hand textbooks, demand comes from new students enrolling in a specific course, and supply comes from students who complete a specific course in previous years. At the original levels of demand and supply, the equilibrium occurs at point A where the price is $8, and 24 books are sold, as illustrated in the figure below. If there more were students enrolling in one year, there would be an increased demand at every given price level. An increase in demand corresponds to a rightward shift of the demand curve. If the price remained at $8, there would be excess demand for books, equal to the distance between the 149 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie original and the new demand curve. The new equilibrium will therefore be at point B itself has not shifted. An increase in supply due to improved productivity In contrast, as an example of an increase in supply, think again about the market for bread in a given city. Suppose that bakeries discover a new technique to bake bread faster, which will lead to a fall in the marginal cost of baking a loaf of bread. Accordingly, the marginal cost curve of each bakery shifts down, which corresponds to a downward shift of each bakery’s supply curve. At the original levels of demand and supply, the equilibrium occurs at point A where the price is $8, and 24 books are sold, as illustrated in the figure to the right. increase leads in to The supply a new equilibrium at point B where the price is $1,60 and 6 000 loaves of bread are sold. The increase in supply has therefore led to a rise in the equilibrium quantity and a fall in the equilibrium price. If the price remained at $2, there would be an excess supply of loaves of breads, equal to the distance between the original and the new supply curve. Such shifts in supply and demand as explained above are often referred to as shocks in economic analysis. Shock: an exogenous change in some of the fundamental data used in a model. In economic analysis, we start by specifying an economic model and find the equilibrium. Thereafter, we look at how the equilibrium position will change when the 150 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. curve, which corresponds to a movement along the supply curve. The supply curve io ut rib st di e/ al rs It is important to note that an “increase in demand” leads to a shift of the demand fo led to a rise in the equilibrium quantity and price. ot .N op where the price is $10 and 32 books are sold. The increase in demand has therefore model receives a shock. These shocks are said to be exogenous, because the model does not explain why the shock happened, i.e. the model shows the consequences of the shock, not the cause. Exogenous: coming from outside the model rather than being produced by the workings of the model itself. An increase in supply: More bakeries enter the market Another reason for a change in the market supply is the entry of more firms, or the exit of existing firms. Typically, if firms that are already in the profit make economic profits, other firms would be incentivised to enter the market for bread. Since there is an opportunity for making economic profits, new bakers may decide to enter the market. If new bakers enter the market, the market supply curve will increase, which means that the price will fall and the quantity of loaves of bread will rise, as we saw before. For bakers to enter the market for bread, there will, however, be some costs of entry. Provided that these are not too high, it would still be worthwhile for new bakers to enter the market for bread. Costs of entry: start-up costs that would be incurred when a seller enters a market or an industry. These would usually include the cost of acquiring and equipping new premises, research and development, the necessary patents, and the cost of finding and hiring staff. The entry of new firms is unlikely to be welcomed by the existing bakeries. Their production costs will not have changed, but the market price will have fallen, which means they will be making less profit than before. 8.7 The effects of taxes As noted before, governments can use taxation to raise revenue or to affect the allocation of goods and services, perhaps because the government considers a good to be harmful. The supply and demand model is a useful tool for analysing the effects of taxation. Using taxes to raise revenue A typical example of how taxation was used to raise revenue was the taxation that was imposed on salt in the past. The figure on the following page illustrates how a salt tax 151 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie would affect the market for .N op ot salt. Initially, the market fo e/ al rs equilibrium is at point A ut rib st di where the price is P* and n. io the quantity of salt traded is Q*. Suppose now a sales tax of 30% is imposed on the price of salt, to be paid to the government by the suppliers. If suppliers have to pay the 30% tax, their marginal cost of supplying a unit of salt increases by 30%, which means the supply curve will shift upwards. The new equilibrium will then be at point B where the higher price of P1 is charged for the lower quantity of Q1. Suppliers will not be happy with this because the price that they receive is P0. The distance from point B to the point on the market supply at that quantity, shows the tax paid to the government on each unit of salt sold. Although the consumer price has risen, it did not raise by 30%. Suppliers receive a lower price than before, they produce less, and their profits will be lower. This illustrates an important feature of taxes – it is not necessarily the taxpayer who feels the main effect of the tax. In this case, although the suppliers pay the tax to the government, the tax incidence falls partly on consumers and partly on producers. Tax incidence: the effect of a tax on the welfare of buyers, sellers, or both. From the figure above, it is clear that the tax led to consumers having to pay higher prices; producers producing less, and producers receiving less, after they have paid the taxes to the government. The figure on the following page, shows how the imposition of taxes affect the consumer and producer surplus. The consumer surplus falls. The producer surplus falls. The total surplus is lower, which causes a deadweight loss. 152 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. The figure to the right shows that consumer the surplus after the imposition of the tax is equal to the area of the red triangle, the producer surplus is equal to the area of the blue triangle, the area of the green rectangle is equal to the tax revenue of (P −P ) ×Q , and the area of the white triangle is equal to the deadweight loss caused by the imposition of the tax, because the quantity of salt traded is no longer at the level that maximises gains from trade. After the tax is imposed on the price of salt, the total surplus from trade in the salt market is given by: total surplus = consumer surplus + producer surplus + government revenue We can think of the total surplus as a measure of the welfare of society, provided that the tax revenue is used for the benefit of society. So, there is a second reason for a government that cares about welfare to prefer taxing goods with low elasticity of demand – the loss of total surplus will be lower. The overall effect of the tax depends on what the government does with the revenues that it collects: If the government spends the revenue on goods and services that enhance the wellbeing of the population, then the tax may enhance public welfare, even though it reduces the surplus in the taxed market. If the government spends the revenues on an activity that does not contribute to wellbeing, then the lost consumer surplus is a reduction in the living standards of the population. Clearly, taxes can either improve or reduce the overall welfare of society. The only thing that can be said without a doubt is that taxing a good whose demand is inelastic is an efficient way to transfer the surplus from consumers to the government. 153 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie The government’s power to impose taxes is similar to the price-setting power of a firm tackling the obesity epidemic. In 2011, the Danish government introduced such a tax on products with high saturated fat content. A tax of 10 Danish kroner (kr) per kg of butter was imposed. This is an example of a specific tax where a tax is levied as a fixed amount per unit of butter. Conversely, the salt tax from before, levied as a percentage of the price, is known as an ad valorem tax. We can illustrate the effects of the butter tax in the same way as we did for the salt tax, using the supply and demand model, assuming that butter retailers are pricetakers. The figure to the right shows the market for butter. In this instance, the supply curve was drawn flatter, which illustrates inelastic an supply curve. The initial equilibrium is at point A where the price of butter is 45 kr per kg and each person consumes 2 kg of butter per year. A tax of 10 kr per kg levied on suppliers, raises their marginal costs by 10 kr at every quantity, which means the supply curve will shift upwards by 10 kr for every kp of butter 154 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. consumption of unhealthy foods with the objective of improving public health and io Policymakers in many countries are interested in the idea of using taxes to deter ut Using taxes to change behaviour rib revenue is accepted as a necessary part of social and economic policy. st di Provided that citizens believe taxes have been implemented fairly, using them to raise e/ al the institutions for tax collection are well-established, usually with democratic consent. rs on the institutions it can use to enforce and collect them. In many modern economies fo and collect revenue, while reducing the quantity sold. Its ability to levy taxes depends ot .N op that sells a differentiated product. The government uses its power to raise the price per person per year. The new equilibrium will then be at point B where the price is 54 kr per kg and each person consumes 1,6 kg of butter per year. This means that the consumer price rises by 9 kr, which is nearly the full amount of the tax and the suppliers’ net revenue per kg of butter falls to 44 kr. In this case, although suppliers pay the tax, the tax incidence is felt mainly by consumers, because of the 10 kr tax per kg of butter, the consumer effectively pays 9 kr per kg of butter, while the producer only pays 1 kr per kg of butter. The price received by the producer, net of tax, is therefore only 1 kr per kg of butter lower. The figure to the right shows that the imposition of taxes reduces the consumer and producer surplus, as well as the total surplus, of course. The consumer surplus is equal to the area of the red triangle, the producer surplus is equal to the area of the blue triangle, the area of the green rectangle is equal to the tax revenue of 10 kr per kg ×1,6 kg = 16 kr per person per year, and the area of the white triangle is equal to the deadweight loss caused by the imposition of the tax. The question remains: how effective was the fat tax? For a full evaluation of the effect on health we should look at all the foods taxed and consider the cross-price effects – the changes in consumption of other foods caused by the tax. The figure above illustrates the following implications of the tax: The consumption of butter products will fall. There was a large fall in surplus, especially in the consumer surplus. The loss of surplus caused by the imposition of the tax represents a deadweight loss, which sounds negative, but policymakers could be seen as a gain if, health-wise, butter is considered “bad” for consumers. One aspect of taxation not illustrated in our supply and demand analysis is the cost of collecting it. Any taxation system requires effective mechanisms for tax collection and 155 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie designing taxes that are simple to administer, and difficult to avoid, is an important st di e/ al rs fo ways of minimising administrative costs, since these costs cannot be eliminated. ot .N op goal of tax policy. Policymakers who want to introduce food taxes will need to find In what kinds of markets would we expect to see price-taking on both sides? To generate competition between sellers that are forced to act as price-takers, we need: Many sellers selling homogenous products to avoid firms having market power. Homogenous products: each firm produces identical product, i.e. products that are exactly the same from one seller to another. Sellers must act independently to prevent the formation of cartels. There must be many buyers who want to buy the product. Buyers know the sellers’ prices, otherwise they cannot choose the lowest price. There must be many buyers, competing with one another, forcing other buyers to be price-takers. A market with all these properties is described as perfectly competitive. Perfectly competitive equilibrium: such an equilibrium occurs in a model in which all buyers and sellers are price-takers. In this equilibrium, all transactions take place at a single price. This is known as the law of one price. At that price, the amount supplied equals the amount demanded: the market clears. No buyer or seller can benefit by altering the price they are demanding or offering. They are both price-takers. All potential gains from trade are realized. Predictably, the equilibrium in a perfectly competitive equilibrium will have the following characteristics: All transactions take place at a single price, which is known as the law of one price. Law of one price: holds when a good is traded at the same price across all buyers and sellers. If a good were sold at different prices in different places, a trader could buy it cheaply in one place and sell it at a higher price in another. At the “single price”, the amount supplied equals the amount demanded. All buyers and sellers are price-takers. 156 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. io ut rib 8.8 The model of perfect competition All potential gains from trade are fully realised. The model of perfect competition describes an idealised market structure. The figure below shows the market for an imaginary product called Choccos, for which there are close substitutes, as many similar products compete in the wider market for chocolate bars. Due to competition from other chocolate bars, the demand curve is nearly flat, as shown in the left-hand panel of the figure below. The narrow range of feasible prices for this firm is determined by the behaviour of its competitors, and the firm chooses a price and quantity where the marginal cost is close to the price. This firm is in a similar situation to a firm in a perfectly competitive market. It is the equilibrium price in the larger market for chocolate bars that determines the feasible prices for Choccos, because Choccos have to be sold at a similar price to other chocolate bars. We can construct the market supply curve for chocolate bars in the right-hand panel by adding the quantities from the individual marginal cost curves of all the chocolate bar producers. If most consumers do not have strong preferences for one firm’s product, we can draw a market demand curve for chocolate bars. 8.9 Looking for competitive equilibria If we look at a market in which conditions seem to favour perfect competition, how can we tell whether it satisfies the conditions for a competitive equilibrium? Economists have used two tests: 157 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m ot 2. Are firms selling goods at a price equal to marginal cost? .N op Sh s. ie 1. Do all trades take place at the same price? useful approximation for economic analysis. Even if the conditions for perfect competition are not all satisfied, the model of supply and demand is a valuable tool for economic analysis, applicable when there is enough competition that individuals have little influence on prices. 8.10 Price-setting and price-taking firms In practice, economies are a mixture of more and less competitive markets, however, firms act the same regardless of the number of firms in the market. Regardless of the aforementioned, there are important differences. Advertising in a competitive market is a public good, because the benefits go to all firms in the industry. Public good: a good for which use by one person does not reduce its availability to others. Also known as a non-rival good. The same is true of expenditures to influence public policy. If a large firm with market power is successful in, for example, relaxing environmental regulations, then it will directly benefit all firms in the industry. Activities like lobbying or contributing money to electoral campaigns, however, will be unattractive to the competitive firm because the result is a public good, and they would not like to benefit all firms in the industry. The differences between price-setting and price-taking firms are given in the table below. Price-setting firm or monopoly Firm in a perfectly competitive market Sets price and quantity to maximize profits (‘price-maker’) Takes market determined price as given and chooses quantity to maximize profits (‘price-taker’) Chooses an output level at which marginal cost is less than price Chooses an output level at which marginal cost equals price Deadweight losses (Pareto inefficient) No deadweight losses for consumers and firms (can be Pareto efficient if no one else in the economy is affected) 158 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. quantifying marginal cost. Nevertheless, the model of perfect competition can be a io ut rib st di e/ al find evidence of perfect competition. One of many reasons for this is the difficulty in rs fo Regardless of the existence of these tests, the crux of the matter is that it is hard to Price-setting firm or monopoly Firm in a perfectly competitive market Owners receive economic rents (profits greater than normal profits) If the owners receive economic rents, the rents are likely to disappear as more firms enter the market Firms advertise their unique product Little advertising: it costs the firm, but benefits all firms (it’s a public good) Firms may spend money to influence elections, legislation and regulation Little expenditure by individual firms on this (same as advertising) Firms invest in research and innovation; seek to prevent copying Little incentive for innovation; others will copy (unless the firm can succeed in differentiating its product and escaping from the competitive market) 159 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m n. io ut rib st di e/ al Property rights and contracts that would reward actors for the positive external effects rs some of the effects of the decision-maker’s actions. fo External effects arise when property rights and legal contracts do not cover ot .N op Sh s. ie UNIT 12: MARKETS, EFFICIENCY, AND PUBLIC POLICY imposed on others, and make them liable to pay damages for the negative effects, are infeasible when the necessary information is not available to one or more of the parties or cannot be used in a court of law. Private property is a key requirement for a market system. If something is to be bought and sold, then it must be possible to claim the right to own it, otherwise the buyer would be hesitant to pay. Governments provide a system of laws and law enforcement that guarantee these property rights and enforce contracts. Policies can address market failures by inducing firms to internalise these external effects. Some of these policies include subsidising a firm’s R&D to the benefit of the industry, or by imposing taxes that raise the price of goods that is environmentally destructive. Other policies can directly regulate the actions of firms and households, for example by banning the use of chemicals such as pesticides that impose costs on others. Private bargaining among parties can sometimes constrain actors to take account of the effect of their actions on others, for example a merger between a firm emitting pollutants and a firm suffering damage as a result. Laws and legal traditions can also help markets function when they provide compensation for individuals who are harmed by the actions of others. For a market to work effectively and to exist, various social institutions and social norms are required. Social norm: an understanding that is common to most members of a society about what people should do in each situation when their actions affect others. Social norms dictate that you respect the property rights of others, even when enforcement is unlikely or impossible. Various economists have argued that these institutions, including social norms, are fundamental for long-run growth in an economic, as well as the proper functioning of economies. 160 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. Whenever you agree with a seller to pay a certain amount of money in exchange for a good you implicitly enter into a contract with the seller. If you have the protection of a legal system, you can expect the contract to be honoured. It is the government that determines the rules of the game in which market trade takes place. Of course, enforcement by a court is rarely necessary because of social norms that motivate both buyers and sellers to play by the rules of the game, even in cases where there is not an actual contract or a transfer of a title of ownership. More complex transactions require explicit written contracts that can be used in court as evidence that the parties agreed to a transfer of ownership. Contracts govern relationships that are to be maintained over a period of time, particularly employment. In the labour market, a court upholds the right of the worker to work no more than the contracted hours and to receive the agreed-upon pay. 12.1 Market failure: External effects of pollution The market allocation of a good is unlikely to be Pareto efficient if the decisions of producers and consumers affect others in ways that they did not adequately consider. This is another cause of market failure. When we analyse gains from trade in such cases, we must consider the consumer and producer surplus, as before, but also the costs or benefits that other parties who are neither buyers nor sellers may experience. In this unit, we will analyse the gains from trade in a case where the production of bananas creates an external cost pollution by use of a pesticide called Weevokil. External effect: a positive or negative effect of a production, consumption, or other economic decision on another person or people that is not specified as a benefit or liability in a contract. It is called an external effect because the effect in question is outside the contract. Also known as an externality. To model the implications of this kind of external effect, we need to consider the costs of producing the bananas. The marginal cost of producing bananas for the growers is the marginal private cost (MPC). Marginal private cost (MPC): the cost for the producer of producing an additional unit of a good, not considering any costs its production imposes on others. The cost of an additional tonne of bananas increases as the land is used more intensively, because more Weevokil is required. The bananas also have a marginal 161 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie external cost (MEC) which includes the costs borne by fishermen whose waters are .N op ot contaminated by the Weevokil. n. io ut rib st di e/ al is incurred by anyone other than the producer of the good. rs fo Marginal external cost (MEC): the cost of producing an additional unit of a good that Adding together the MPC and the MEC, we get the full marginal cost of banana production – the marginal social cost (MSC). Marginal social cost (MSC): the cost of producing an additional unit of a good, considering both the cost for the producer and the costs incurred by others affected by the good’s production. MSC is the sum of the MPC and the MEC. These costs are all illustrated in the figure below. The MPC curve slopes upward because the cost of producing an additional tonne increases as the land is more intensively used, requiring more Weevokil. The MEC is the cost of the reduction in quantity and quality of fish caused by each additional tonne of bananas. The figure above shows that the MSC exceeds the MPC, due to the existence of the MEC. The shaded area is equal to the area between the MSC and MPC curves. We will consider a case in which the market for bananas is competitive, and the market price is $400 per tonne. If the banana plantation owners wish to maximise their profit, they will choose their output such that the price is equal to their marginal cost, i.e. the MPC. The figure on the following page shows that the total output of the market will 162 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. be 80 000 tonnes of bananas, indicated by point A, where the MEC is $270 per tonne per year. Although this quantity maximises the profits for banana producers, it does not include the cost imposed on the fishing industry, which means this allocation is not a Pareto efficient outcome. B If the banana plantations were to produce less, the fishermen would benefit but the owners of the plantations would lose. So, on the face of it, it appears that the allocation is Pareto efficient. If the plantations produced one tonne less, the fishermen would gain $270 by no longer suffering the loss of revenue that is caused by the production of the 80 000th tonne of bananas. The plantations would lose hardly anything. Their revenues would fall by $400, but their costs would also fall by almost exactly this same amount because the MPC of producing the 80 000th tonne of bananas is equal to $400. This means that if the fishermen paid the banana plantations any amount between zero and less than $270, both groups would be better off with 79 999 tonnes of bananas, which proves that producing 80 000 tonnes of bananas is not Pareto efficient This process can be repeated until the MSC is equal to the market price, which in the example above occurs at point B at a quantity of 38 000 tonnes of bananas. At this point, the fishermen would no longer benefit by making further payments to the plantation owners in return for reduced output. If production were lowered further, the loss to the plantations would be greater than the gain to the fishermen, i.e. the maximum payment the fishermen would be willing to make would not be enough to 163 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie induce the plantation owners to cut production further. 38 000 tonnes of bananas is ot .N op therefore the Pareto efficient level of banana output. that rely on environmental resources. 12.2 External effects and bargaining Does the previously mentioned process of bargaining suggest a remedy for this market failure that might be implemented in the real world? It does. The fishermen and the plantation owners could negotiate a private bargain. Solutions of this type are often called Coasean bargaining, after Ronald Coase (economist). He argued that the two parties to the exchange often have more of the information necessary to implement an efficient outcome than the government does. Coase emphasised that his model could not be directly applied to most situations because of the costs of bargaining and other factors that prevent parties from exploiting all possible mutual gains. Establishing each party’s actual costs and benefits is part of the cost of the transaction, and this cost might be too high to make a bargain possible. Costs of bargaining, sometimes called transaction costs, may prevent Pareto efficiency. Transaction costs: costs that impede the bargaining process or the agreement of a contract. They include costs of acquiring information about the good to be traded, and costs of enforcing a contract. Coase suggested that a lack of established property rights, and other factors leading to high transaction costs, may stand in the way of using bargaining to resolve externalities. Coase suggested that the concept of property rights can be extended to other rights, as well, for example the right to make a noise or to have a quiet work environment. Coase believed that these can also be goods that can be bargained over and traded in return for money. Let us consider the private bargaining as a solution to the pesticide problem. The allocation of property rights is such that the plantations have the right to use Weevokil and choose to produce 80 000 tonnes of bananas. This allocation and the 164 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. them, but by damaging the environment they impose external costs on other parties io ut rib st di e/ al called environmental spillovers. They bring private benefits to those who decide to use rs fo In general, pollutants like Weevokil have negative external effects, sometimes associated incomes and environmental effects represent the reservation option of the plantation owners and fishermen, i.e. what they will get if they do not come to some agreement. For the fishermen and the plantation owners to negotiate effectively, they would each have to be organised so that a single person could make agreements on behalf of the entire group. We imagine that a representative of an association of fishermen sits down to bargain with a representative of an association of banana growers. To keep things simple we will assume that, at present, there are no feasible alternatives to Weevokil, so they bargain only over the output of bananas. Both sides should recognise that they could gain from an agreement to reduce output to the Pareto efficient level of 38 000 tonnes of bananas. In the figure below, the situation begins at point A, before bargaining. After bargaining, they end up at the Pareto efficient quantity. Reducing banana production will lead to a loss of profits for the plantation, but it is smaller than the gain (the sum of the loss of profit and the net social gain) that the fisherman receives (from cleaner water). The figure below shows that the fall in profit is smaller than the gain for the fishermen, as there is a net social gain that they could agree to share. Since the gain to the fishermen would be greater than the loss to the plantations, the fishermen would be willing to pay the banana growers to reduce output to 38 000 tonnes if they had the funds to do so. The minimum acceptable offer from the fishermen depends on what the plantations get in the existing situation, which is their reservation profit. 165 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie that will not be rejected by the Responder. Generally applied in bargaining situations loss of profit, the fishing industry would achieve a net gain from the agreement equal to the net social gain, while plantations would be no better, or no worse, off. The maximum the fishing industry would pay is determined by their reservation option, as in the case of the plantations. It is the sum of the blue and green areas. In this case, the plantations would get all the net social gain while the fishermen would be no better off. The compensation they agree on, between these maximum and minimum levels, will be determined by the bargaining power of the two groups. You may think it unfair that the fishermen need to pay for a reduction in pollution. At the Pareto efficient level of banana production, the fishing industry is still suffering from pollution, and it must pay to stop the pollution getting worse. This happens because we have assumed that the plantations have a legal right to use Weevokil. An alternative legal framework could give the fishermen a right to clean water. If that were the case, the plantation owners wishing to use Weevokil could propose a bargain in which they paid the fishermen to give up some of their right to clean water to allow the Pareto efficient level of banana production, which will be a much more favourable outcome for the fishermen. In principle, the bargaining process would result in a Pareto efficient allocation regardless of which party has the initial rights, even though the distribution of the benefits of solving the market failure differs drastically. As Coase acknowledged, practical obstacles to bargaining may prevent the achievement of Pareto efficiency. These practical obstacles include, amongst other things, the following list of obstacles: Impediments to collective action. Private bargaining may be impossible if there are many parties on both sides of the external effect. Each side needs to find a representative to bargain on their behalf. The individuals representing the two groups would be performing a public service that might be difficult to secure. 166 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. io ut rib st di e/ al rs If plantation owners agreed to this minimum payment to compensate them for their fo to mean the least favourable offer that would be accepted. ot .N op Minimum acceptable offer: in the ultimatum game, the smallest offer by the Proposer Missing information. Devising the payment scheme makes it necessary to measure the costs of Weevokil to each fisherman. We also need to establish the exact origin of the pollutant, plantation by plantation. Only when we have this information can we calculate the size of the payment that each fisherman must pay, and how much each plantation should receive. Tradability and enforcement. The bargain involves the trading of property rights, and the contract governing the trade must be enforceable. Both parties must therefore be able to rely on the legal system to facilitate the process towards the Pareto efficient quantity. Limited funds. The pesticide example illustrates that although correcting market failures through bargaining may not require direct government intervention, it does require a legal framework for enforcing contracts so that property rights are tradable and so that all parties stick to the bargains they make. Even with this framework, it might be unlikely that Coasean bargaining alone can address market failures. 12.3 External effects: Policies and income distribution Suppose in the case of our Weevokil example that Coasean bargaining proves to be impractical, and that the fisherman and plantation owners cannot resolve the Weevokil problem privately. We will continue to assume that it is not possible to grow bananas without using Weevokil. What can the government do to achieve a reduction in the output of bananas to the level that considers the costs for the fishermen? There are three ways this might be done: regulation of the quantity of bananas produced; taxation of the production or sale of bananas; and enforcing compensation of the fishermen for the costs imposed on them. Each of these policies has different distributional implications for the fisherman and plantation owners. 167 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie Regulation would lose their surplus on each tonne of bananas between 38 000 and 80 000 tonnes of bananas. Taxation The figure below shows the MPC and MSC curves again. At the Pareto efficient quantity, the MSC is $400 and the MPC is $295. the government puts a tax on each tonne of bananas produced, equal to the MEC: $400 – $295 = $105, then the aftertax price received by plantations will be $295. Now, if plantations maximise their profit, they will choose the point where the after-tax price equals the MPC and produce 38 000 tonnes, the Pareto efficient quantity. The tax corrects the price message, so that the plantations face the full MSC of their decisions. When the plantations are producing 38 000 bananas, the tax is exactly equal to the cost imposed on the fishermen. This approach is known as a Pigouvian tax after Arthur Pigou (economist). Pigouvian tax: a tax levied on activities that generate negative external effects to correct an inefficient market outcome. 168 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. pollution for the fishermen, but it would lower the plantations’ profits, because they io ut rib st di e/ al rs and enforce the right quota for each one. This policy would reduce the costs of fo efficient amount. If plantations differ in size and output, it may be difficult to determine ot .N op The government could limit the total banana output at 38 000 tonnes, the Pareto There are limits to how well governments can implement Pigouvian taxes, regulation and compensation – often for the same reasons as for Coasean bargaining: The government may not know the degree of harm suffered by each party. MSC is difficult to measure. The government may favour the more powerful group, i.e. the group with the most bargaining power. This concept could also be applied to positive external effects. If the marginal social benefit of a decision is greater than the marginal private benefit, this becomes a Pigouvian subsidy, which can ensure that the decision-maker takes this external benefit into account. External benefit: A positive external effect: that is, a positive effect of a production, consumption, or other economic decision on another person or people that is not specified as a benefit in a contract. Also known as external economy and/or positive externalities. The distributional effects of taxation are different from those of regulation. The costs of pollution for fishermen are reduced by the same amount, but the reduction in banana profits is greater, since the plantations pay taxes as well as reducing output, and the government receives tax revenue. Enforcing compensation The government could require the plantation owners to pay compensation for costs imposed on the fishermen. The compensation required for each tonne of bananas will be equal to the MEC. Once compensation is included, the marginal cost of each tonne of bananas will be the MSC. Now, plantations will maximise profits by choosing point P₂ in the figure on the following page and produce 38 000 tonnes, the Pareto efficient quantity. The shaded area shows the total compensation paid. The fishermen are fully compensated for pollution, and the plantations’ profits are equal to the true social surplus of banana production. 169 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m ot .N op Sh s. ie n. io ut rib st di e/ al rs fo The effect of this policy on the plantations’ profits is similar to the effect of the tax, but the fishermen do better because they, rather than the government, receive payment from the plantations. Diagnosis and treatment in the case of chlordecone If alternatives to Weevokil were available, it would be inefficient to restrict output to 38 000 tonnes, because if the plantations could choose a different production method and the corresponding profit-maximising output, they could be better off, and the fishermen no worse off. In this situation, a policy of requiring the plantations to compensate the fishermen would have given them the incentive to find production methods that caused less pollution and could, in principle, have achieved an efficient outcome. The other two policies would not do so. Rather than taxing or regulating banana production, it would be better to regulate or tax the sale or the use of chlordecone, to motivate plantations to find the best alternative to intensive chlordecone use. In theory, if the tax on a unit of chlordecone was equal to its MEC, the price of chlordecone for the plantations would be equal to its MSC, so it would be sending the right message. The firms could then choose the best production method considering the high cost of chlordecone, which would involve reducing its use or switching to a different pesticide and determine the respective profit-maximising output. The profits of the plantations and the pollution costs for the fishermen would fall, but the outcome 170 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. would be better for the plantations, and possibly the fishermen also, if chlordecone rather than bananas were taxed. 12.4 Property rights, contracts, and market failures In taking action to maximise profits, the plantation owners did not take account of the external costs they imposed on the fishermen. And they had no reason to take account of them, because they had the right to pollute the fisheries. The same is true for the overuse of antibiotics. A self-interested person has no reason to use antibiotics sparingly, because the superbug that may be created will probably infect someone else. If the prices of chlordecone and the antibiotic were high enough, there would be no overuse. But the prices of these goods were based on the costs of production and excluded costs that their use would inflict on others. As you have seen, the private cost to the user fell short of the social cost for this reason. Costs inflicted on others are termed external diseconomies or negative externalities, while uncompensated benefits conferred on others are external economies or positive externalities. External diseconomy: a negative effect of a production, consumption, or other economic decision, that is not specified as a liability in a contract. Also known as external cost and negative externality. Legal systems often fail to provide compensation for the benefits that one’s actions confer on others and fails to incorporate the costs that one’s actions confers to others. Market failures occur in these instances because the external benefits and costs of a person’s actions are not owned by anyone. This is purely indicative of incomplete contracts. The external effects of a person’s actions are effects that are not governed by contracts. Another way to express the problem is to say that there is no market in which these external effects can be compensated. So economists also use the term missing markets to describe problems like this. Missing market: a market in which there is some kind of exchange that, if implemented, would be mutually beneficial. This does not occur due to asymmetric or non-verifiable information 171 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m Sh s. ie Why don’t countries just rewrite their laws to reward people for the benefits they confer There can be no contract or property rights ensuring that external effects will be compensated. Some of the social costs or benefits of the decision-maker’s actions will not be included, or will not be sufficiently important, in the decision-making process. 12.5 Public goods The defining characteristic of a public good is that if it is available to one person it can be available to everyone at no additional cost. Public goods are typically provided by governments rather than the market. Once the good is available at all, the marginal cost of making it available to additional people is zero. Goods with this characteristic are also called non-rival goods. A good is termed public if once available to one person, it can be available to everyone at no additional cost and its use by one person does not reduce its availability to others. This character of a public good is called being non-rival because potential users are not in competition with each other for the good. Some economists add that others cannot be excluded from the goods’ use. These goods are called non-excludable public goods. Non-excludable public good: a public good for which it is impossible to exclude anyone from having access. We consider the non-rival character of a public good to be its defining characteristic, whether others can be excluded or not. For some public goods, it is possible to exclude additional users, even though the cost of their use is zero, for a copyrighted book. 172 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. is non-verifiable or asymmetric information. io Some information that is of concern to someone other than the decision-maker ut rib The reason why uncompensated external costs and benefits occur is: st di Verifiable information: information that can be used to enforce a contract. e/ al contract, or there may be no legal system to enforce the contract. rs effects are too complex or difficult to measure to be written into an enforceable fo because the necessary information is either not available or not verifiable, the external ot .N op on others, and make decision-makers pay for the costs they inflict on others? This is Copyright: ownership rights over the use and distribution of an original work. Public goods for which it is feasible to exclude others are sometimes called artificially scarce. Artificially scarce good: a public good that it is possible to exclude some people from enjoying. Also known as club goods. The opposite of a non-excludable public good is a private good. Private good: a good that is both rival, and from which others can be excluded. Markets typically allocate private goods. But for the other three kinds of good, markets are either not possible or likely to fail. There are two reasons: When goods are non-rival, the marginal cost is zero. Setting a price equal to marginal cost will not be possible unless the provider is subsidised. When goods are not excludable there is no way to charge a price for them, because the provider cannot exclude people who have not paid. We have seen many examples of private goods, for example loaves of bread, dinners in restaurants, and boxes of breakfast cereal. All these goods are both rival and excludable. There is a fourth kind of good that is rival, but not excludable, called a common-pool resource. Common-pool resource: a rival good that one cannot prevent others from enjoying. Also known as common property resource. The user of a common-pool resource imposes an external cost on other users. By driving your car on a busy road, for example, you contribute to the congestion experienced by other drivers. The table on the following page summarises the four kinds of goods explained in this Section. 173 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m bads that affect many people simultaneously, for example polluted air. Public bad: the negative equivalent of a public good. It is non-rival in the sense that a given individual’s consumption of the public bad does not diminish others’ consumption of it. Whether a good is private or public depends not only on the nature of the good itself, but on legal and other institutions. When goods are not private, public policy may be required to allocate them. National defence is a responsibility of the government in all countries, or environmental policy. Governments also adopt a range of policies to address the problem of knowledge as a public good, such as issuing patents to give firms an incentive to undertake R&D. Patent: a right of exclusive ownership of an idea or invention, which lasts for a specified length of time. During this time, it effectively allows the owner to be a monopolist or exclusive user. Market failure in the case of public goods is closely related to the problems of external effects, absent property rights and incomplete contracts. 174 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. household waste. These are private bads. Analogously, we can define public bads as io things that people do not want, and might be willing to pay to not have, such as ut “Goods” in economics are things that people want to use or consume, but “bads” are rib additional users is not completely zero, but instead very small. st di excludability in goods is a matter of degree. For some kinds of goods, the cost of e/ al The table above shows the four distinct categories of goods. The extent of rivalry or rs Non-excludable public goods and Common-pool resources (fish bads (view of a lunar eclipse, public Nonstocks in a lake, common grazing broadcasts, rules of arithmetic or excludable land) calculus, national defence, noise and air pollution) fo (food, Public goods that are artificially scarce (subscription TV, clothes, uncongested toll roads, knowledge subject to intellectual property rights) ot Private goods houses) .N op Excludable Non-rival Sh s. ie Rival The table on the following page summarises cases of market failure – some that were discussed in this unit, some not. The table also includes remedies for these market failures. 175 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. um tS en ud St ar m external cost Other firms can exploit Private the innovation cost, external benefit overproduction of the crop for which it is used Taxes, quotas, bargaining, bans, common ownership of all affected assets Overuse of air travel Taxes, quotas Tolls, quotas, subsidized Overuse of cars public transport Publicly funded research, Too little R&D subsidies for R&D, patents More effective monitoring, An employee on a fixed wage decides how hard to work Hard work raises Private employer’s profits cost, external benefit Too little effort; wage above performance-related reservation pay, wage; reduced conflict of interest unemployment between employer and employee Someone who knows he has a serious health problem buys insurance Mandatory Loss for company purchase of insurance Private benefit, Too little insurance offered; health insurance, public external cost insurance premiums too high provision, mandatory health information sharing 176 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. n. cost, and io road users other Private pesticide ut for external cost of rib A firm invests in R&D Congestion external cost global Private benefit, carbon emissions You travel to work by car Private benefit, Overuse Possible remedies st di flight in of resources) e/ al You take an international Increase benefit rs runs off into waterways Downstream damage Market failure (misallocation fo A firm uses a pesticide that Cost or ot How it affects others .N op Sh s. ie Decision Decision Someone How it affects others who has purchased car insurance decides how carefully to drive Borrower devotes insufficient prudence or effort to the project in which the loan is invested Prudent driving contributes to insurance company’s profits Project more likely to fail, resulting in non- repayment of loan Cost or Market failure (misallocation benefit of resources) Private cost, Too little insurance offered; Installing driver monitoring external benefit insurance premiums too high A monopoly, bank fails a or a firm wealth; Private benefit, Excessive risk; too few loans common responsibility for external cost issued to poor borrowers repayment of loans (Grameen Bank) external cost Excessively risky lending Regulation of banking practices firm producing a differentiated good, devices Redistribute Bank that is ‘too big to fail’ Taxpayers bear costs if Private benefit, makes risky loans Possible remedies with declining AC sets P > MC Price is too high for Private benefit, some potential buyers external cost Competition policy, public Too low a quantity sold (Unit 7) 177 Customer: Danica Potgieter, danicapotgieter12@gmail.com, May 9, 2021, 0765764553. Please report unauthorized use to help@studentsummaries.co.za. ownership monopolies of natural