FINANCIAL MARKETS AND NPV – FIRST PRINCIPLES OF FINANCE THE FINANCIAL MARKET ECONOMY Individuals and institutions have different income streams and different intertemporal consumption preferences. This has led to the creation of financial markets. Financial markets intermediate between agents with different intertemporal consumption preferences. THE FINANCIAL MARKET ECONOMY: EXAMPLE Consider a dentist who earns $200,000 per year and chooses to consume $80,000 per year. She has $120,000 in surplus money to invest. She could loan $30,000 to each of 4 college seniors. They each promise to pay her back with interest after they graduate in one year. $30,000×(1+r) $30,000 Student #1 $30,000 Student #2 $30,000 Student #3 $30,000 Student #4 $30,000×(1+r) Dentist $30,000×(1+r) $30,000×(1+r) THE FINANCIAL MARKET ECONOMY: EXAMPLE Rather than performing the credit analysis 4 times, she could loan the whole $120,000 to a financial intermediary in return for a promise to repay the $120,000 in one year with interest. The intermediary in turn loans $30,000 to each of the 4 college seniors. $30,000×(1+r) $120,000 $30,000 Student #1 $30,000 Student #2 $30,000 Student #3 $30,000 Student #4 $30,000×(1+r) Dentist Bank $30,000×(1+r) $120,000×(1+r) $30,000×(1+r) THE FINANCIAL MARKET ECONOMY Financial intermediation can take three forms: Size intermediation In the example above, the bank took a large loan from the dentist and made small loans to the students. Term intermediation Commercial banks finance long-term mortgages with short-term deposits. Risk intermediation Financial intermediaries can tailor the risk characteristics of securities for borrowers and lenders with different degrees of risk tolerance. MARKET CLEARING The job of balancing the supply of and demand for loanable funds is taken by the money market. When the quantity supplied equals, the quantity demanded, the market is in equilibrium at the equilibrium price. The price of money is the interest rate. Consumption at t+1 INTERTEMPORAL CONSUMPTION OPPORTUNITY SET A person with $95,000 who faces a 10% interest rate has the following opportunity set. $120,000 $104,500 One choice available is to consume $40,000 now; invest the remaining $55,000; consume $60,000 next year. $100,000 $80,000 move consumption from one period to another $60,000 = $55,000 (1.10)1 $60,000 $40,000 $20,000 $95,000 $0 $0 $20,000 $40,000 $60,000 $80,000 $100,000 $120,000 Consumption today Consumption at t+1 TAKING ADVANTAGE OF OPPORTUNITIES $120,000 $100,000 A person’s preferences will tend to decide where on the opportunity set, they will choose to be. Patience slope=0, perfect competitive $80,000 Slope = - (1+r) $60,000 $40,000 Impatience $20,000 $0 $0 $20,000 $40,000 $60,000 $80,000 $100,000 $120,000 Consumption today Consumption at t+1 CHANGING OPPORTUNITIES $120,000 $100,000 Consider an investor who has chosen to consume $40,000 now and to consume $60,000 next year. slope steeper, one more dollar today= more tomorrow A rise in interest rates will make saving more attractive … $80,000 $60,000 …and borrowing less attractive. $40,000 $20,000 $0 $0 $20,000 $40,000 $60,000 $80,000 $100,000 $120,000 Consumption today THE COMPETITIVE MARKET Three things characterize the competitive market Costless trading - Access to financial markets is free Information is readily available –No information asymmetry All participants are price takers – No market power There can be only one equilibrium interest rate in a competitive market —otherwise arbitrage opportunities would arise. D=P=MR=MC=AR=AC slope =0 THE BASIC PRINCIPLE The basic financial principle of investment decision-making is this: An investment must be at least as desirable as the opportunities available in the financial markets. HOW TO COMPARE?use market rate to calculate MPV PRACTICING THE PRINCIPLE: A LENDING EXAMPLE Consider an investment opportunity that costs $50,000 this year and provides a certain cash flow of $54,000 next year. $54,000 Cash inflows Time 0 Cash outflows 1 -$50,000 Is this a good deal? It depends on the interest rate available in the financial markets. The investment has an 8% return, if the interest rate available elsewhere is less than this, invest here. ILLUSTRATING THE INVESTMENT DECISION Consider an investor who has an initial endowment of income of $40,000 this year and $55,000 next year. Suppose that she faces a 10-percent interest rate and is offered the following investment. $30,000 Cash inflows 0 Time Cash outflows 1 -$25,000 Consumption at t+1 ILLUSTRATING THE INVESTMENT DECISION Our investor begins with the following opportunity set endowment of $40,000 today, $55,000 next year and a 10% interest rate. $99,000 One choice available is to consume $15,000 now; invest the remaining $25,000 in the financial markets at 10%; consume $82,500 next year. $82,500 $55,000 $0 25000(1.1)=27500 55000(1.1)=60500 C1=88000 C0=(15000+88000)/1.1 $0 $15,000 $40,000 $90,000 Consumption today Consumption at t+1 ILLUSTRATING THE INVESTMENT DECISION A better alternative would be to invest in the project instead of the financial markets. She could consume $15,000 now; invest the remaining $25,000 in the project at 20%; consume $85,000 next year. $99,000 $85,000 $82,500 With borrowing or lending in the financial markets, she can achieve any pattern of cash flows she wants—any of which is better than her original opportunities at time t $55,000 25000(1.2)=30000 + 60500 = 90500 90500-88000=2500 2500/1.1=2273 $0 $0 $15,000 $40,000 $90,000 Consumption today Consumption at t+1 ILLUSTRATING THE INVESTMENT DECISION Note that the investor is better off in that she can command more consumption today or next year. $15,000 + $85,000 ÷(1.10) = $92,273 Today $101,500 $99,000 $85,000 $82,500 $15,000×(1.10) + $85,000 = $101,500 Next year $55,000 $0 $0 $15,000 $40,000 $90,000 $92,273 Consumption today TWO IMPORTANT QUESTIONS How much more money we need to give our investor today to make her just as well off as she is with the investment? Or How much more money we need to give our investor next year to make her just as well off as she is with the investment? LET’S EVALUATE THIS INVESTMENT OPPORTUNITY We can calculate how much better off in today’s dollars the investment makes our investor by calculating the Net Present Value: $30,000 0 1 -$25,000 $30,000 NPV = −25,000 + = $2,272.73 1.10 CORPORATE INVESTMENT DECISION-MAKING Corporations that invest in positive NPV investments will increase the value of the firm by the NPV. Negative NPV investments should be rejected Shareholders will be united in their preference for the firm to undertake positive net present value decisions, regardless of their personal intertemporal consumption preferences. Financial markets allow for these personal differences Consumption at t+1 CORPORATE INVESTMENT DECISION-MAKING Positive NPV projects shift the shareholder’s opportunity set out, which is unambiguously good. All shareholders agree on their preference for positive NPV projects, whether they are borrowers or lenders. Consumption today CORPORATE INVESTMENT DECISION-MAKING We may view firms as means by which many investors pool their resources to make large scale investment decisions. Shareholders will be united in their preference for the firm to undertake positive net present value decisions, regardless of their personal intertemporal consumption preferences. This is because the value of their investment in the firm increases proportionally with the value of the firm. CORPORATE INVESTMENT DECISION-MAKING Unlike individuals, firms have no consumption endowment. It starts at origin in our diagram. Consumption next year (future value) Slope = -(1+r) B $-25,000 $33,000 0 C NPV=$5,000 Assume Investment Opportunity B, cost $25,000 and has a future value of $33,000. If the interest rates are 10%, the NPV is $5,000. Consumption this year (present value) CORPORATE INVESTMENT DECISION-MAKING Shareholders do not vote on every investment decision faced by a firm and the managers of firms need decision rules to operate by. All shareholders of a firm will be made better off if managers follow the NPV rule—undertake positive NPV projects and reject negative NPV projects. THE SEPARATION THEOREM The separation theorem says that all investors will want to accept or reject the same investment projects by using the NPV rule, regardless of their personal preferences. Why? Only because the financial markets exist!! Separating investment decision-making from the shareholders is a basic requirement of the modern corporation.