The SAGE Handbook of Globalization Sustainable Economic Systems Contributors: Póciennik Sebastian Edited by: Manfred B. Steger, Paul Battersby & Joseph M. Siracusa Book Title: The SAGE Handbook of Globalization Chapter Title: "Sustainable Economic Systems" Pub. Date: 2014 Access Date: September 30, 2016 Publishing Company: SAGE Publications Ltd City: London Print ISBN: 9781446256220 Online ISBN: 9781473906020 DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.4135/9781473906020.n48 Print pages: 853-868 ©2014 SAGE Publications Ltd. All Rights Reserved. This PDF has been generated from SAGE Knowledge. Please note that the pagination of the online version will vary from the pagination of the print book. SAGE Editorial arrangement © Paul Battersby, Joseph M. Siracusa and Manfred B. Steger 2014 SAGE Reference Sustainable Economic Systems PóciennikSebastian Introduction The first decade of the twenty-first century witnessed the strong impression that the global economy had become a sphere of extreme uncertainty and risk. Considering the dimension of the crisis, which started in 2007, this was not very surprising. The crisis didn't look like another business cycle setback, a temporary overheating or a sectoral bubble such as the previous ‘dot-coms crash’ of 2000. This was a profound breakdown, strong enough to question the foundations of modern approaches to the creation of welfare. Symptoms were numerous. Apart from collapsing financial markets there were rising unemployment, deeper inequalities, a shrinking middle class, extreme indebtedness, and inability of governments to force through reforms. In addition, there were the increasing challenges of climate change and availability of resources, which are necessary to develop new technologies and keep economies growing. This was exactly what many years ago was predicted by the German sociologist Ulrich Beck, who coined the term ‘risk society’ (Beck, 1986). This essay asserts that the main reason for the current problems has been the inability of modern societies to produce enough stability and sustainability. These two elements have been produced so far in a rather fragmented way and not always efficiently. In fact, we can now observe a fascinating and globally conducted discussion on how to make the future economic system free from previous deficiencies. The first part of the chapter is devoted to previous developments and approaches to stability and sustainability until the last crisis started. The second part focuses on analysis of areas, which are crucial for reforms and the emergence of a new, less risky and more responsible art of capitalism. Stability Firmness in position, permanence and resistance to change, especially in a disruptive way – these are general associations connected with the term ‘stability’. In an economic sense this association was more specific. The International Monetary Fund (IMF) describes it as ‘avoiding large swings in economic activity, high inflation, and excessive volatility in exchange rates and financial markets’ (International Monetary Fund, 2012). This definition refers to indexes, which describe the economy in short-term categories. Headline news saying that the ‘economy is stable’ means actually that the system is in one of the calm phases of the business cycle, neither heading towards boom nor towards depression. The overall pattern has been known at least since the analysis of the French economist Jean Charles Leonard de Sismondi in 1819 and also the works of Joseph Schumpeter. It says that within a few years every economy moves through periods of rapid growth with rising demand, higher inflation and dropping unemployment, followed by depression with reversal phenomena (Knoop, 2009). The challenge is that excessive highs and lows should be avoided. In other words, extreme bubbles of economic activity must be calmed down before they burst. The fluctuations themselves are unavoidable – like the business cycle – but a clever stabilization policy could flatten and shorten them without changing significantly long-term trends of growth. The idea Page 2 of 18 The SAGE Handbook of Globalization SAGE Editorial arrangement © Paul Battersby, Joseph M. Siracusa and Manfred B. Steger 2014 SAGE Reference of an anti-cyclical policy sounds very modern, but is in fact very old. Tomas Sedlacek, the Czech author of an influential book on the history of economics, reminds us in this context of the bible parable about pharaoh's bad dream, in which seven plump and healthy cows get devoured by seven lean cows. Joseph said to the pharaoh that this dream was a prophecy showing seven affluent years and seven bad years. The only way to react, then, is to save and store food in the time of plenty in order to react when people will be in need during the dreary years (Sedlacek, 2011: 63). This point of view has become clear since the Great Depression of 1929, when the economy collapsed in a dramatic way after long years of post-war prosperity and overproduction. In fact during this disaster governments did not feel that it was their place to intervene. Classical economists of this epoch believed in the self-regulation ability of economic systems and, in their view, an unrestricted price mechanism should be enough to restore stability – at least in the long term. John Maynard Keynes commented on this approach in 1923 with his famous, sardonic sentence, that ‘in a long term we all will be dead’ (Ball and Bellamy, 2003: 63). A decade later Keynes published his seminal work The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, reviewed after 75 years in Cate, 2012, in which he designed a theoretical framework proving why it makes sense to raise government spending in harsh times in order to prevent long-lasting depressions. In the next half-century, the capitalist world followed Keynes' hints, and economists refined them by developing sophisticated models of fiscal and monetary policy. The global crisis in the 1970s, the time of surprising stagflation (rise in inflation and unemployment), opened the gates for new economic ideas. One of them was monetarism and its premise that stabilization could be produced control of amount of money in circulation. This approach, whose prominent face was Milton Friedman, started to dominate global capitalism. It fitted well with neo-liberalism, which expanded with the free market reforms of Ronald Reagan in the USA and Margaret Thatcher in the United Kingdom. After two decades of quite successful application of this policy, the self-confidence of economists and politicians became resolute. Ben Bernanke, a member of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve (USA), spoke about the time of ‘Great Moderation’ in which sophisticated stabilization policy measures could guarantee high growth without upsetting volatilities known from the past (Bernanke, 2004). Business cycles and crises appeared to many to belong to the past. From a wider, global perspective this optimism was exaggerated. The 1990s still saw many collapses in the world economy, among them the Asian financial crisis in 1997, the Russian crisis, followed by the disaster in Argentina, which began in 1999. They were caused mainly by major political mistakes, but particularly alarming were their contagion effects. Many countries got dragged into the turmoil. The global interconnectedness, which was very advantageous to the world economy because of exchange, showed its other, less appealing face. Another problem was that new technologies made economic process faster and less predictable. This argument concerned in particular the financial markets, which got boosted by the speed and complexity of internet backed transactions. Many dangers of this process for stability could have been identified first by the so-called internet bubble with its climax in 2000. The reaction based on belief in the Great Moderation led governments to adopt a lax stabilization policy driven by an overly optimistic trust in rationale of markets. After a couple of years of bubbling, markets crashed and then the crisis came. Since 2007 many countries had been trying to restore stabilization with expensive spending programmes and generous monetary policy. Effects were ambiguous. Imbalances in the world economy and complex interdependencies made it difficult to target precisely. The try-and-try-again desperate attempts to revive economic growth contributed to the persistence of extreme public debt in Page 3 of 18 The SAGE Handbook of Globalization SAGE Editorial arrangement © Paul Battersby, Joseph M. Siracusa and Manfred B. Steger 2014 SAGE Reference many countries and the zero-bound trap by the monetary policy. Production of stability is now jammed and this, together with grim prospects for the world economy in the coming decade, is perhaps the most severe symptom of the crisis. Sustainability Sustainability should be seen as different from stability, although at the first sight the overlap seems obvious. It considers the longterm capacities of a system to exist, not its short-term resistance to change. A well known definition of sustainability, which emphasizes its economic notion, comes from the Bruntland Report (World Commission on Environment and Development, 1987) prepared for the United Nations in 1987. It says that ‘development that meets the needs of the present without compromising the ability of future generations to meet their own needs’ deserves the label of sustainability. In other words, it is about responsible use of resources. Economics had had a certain problem with sustainability, analyzing mainly the questions of long-term growth. It was hard to discern the issue of possible depletion of resources in economic theories, because price mechanisms in market economies would translate scarcity into higher costs and reduced consumption of the good. This is why the branch devoted more attention to the problem of what combination of resources could induce growth. At a certain stage of development of economic theories technology became a fantastic escape from the sustainability dilemma. The message was both simple and convincing: new techniques of production help to expand size of output without raising necessary input. One of the most popular longterm growth concepts, the Solow-Swan model from the 1950s, saw the only chance for it in innovations. A sheer increase of the amount of resources added to input could lead to diminishing marginal returns only. New ideas in technology and organization made it possible to overtake the steady state of zero growth and induce development without increasing resources. In the 1980s another powerful theory of Paul Romer and Robert Lucas strengthened this way of thinking (called the new growth theory). The endogenous factors, like human capital and education, were recognized as crucial for growth and their application was free from the steady state problem of classical resources. From this perspective sustainability played a marginal role, because it was better to think primarily about new technologies making a better use of resources instead of literally saving resources. There was also another factor that contributed to the easy approach to sustainability in the past. At its very beginning, the capitalist system faced open/waste spaces of the globe, and was free to expand and exploit resources. The only problem was to reach them before other competitors did. This environment created the imperialism of the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries and an even more vital culture of externalization of negative side effects of growth. For a long time the earth seemed to be a space able to deliver an unlimited number of chances and goods, and simultaneously adopt unlimited pollution, slavery, and violence. This illusion is over, but the externalization bias is still strong. Even today if a society wants a cleaner environment, it can always shift its ‘dirty’ production abroad to other, usually poorer countries, and enjoy unchanged patterns of consumption. It would be, however, too much to say that the issue of sustainability was none-xistent. The pioneer was the British scholar Thomas Malthus, who published in 1798 a book on the grim consequences of a rising population, which consumes all surplus food production and thus prevents a rise in living standards. The solution was found in increased productivity of Page 4 of 18 The SAGE Handbook of Globalization SAGE Editorial arrangement © Paul Battersby, Joseph M. Siracusa and Manfred B. Steger 2014 SAGE Reference agriculture, which culminated more than two centuries later in the Green Revolution in places such as India and Bangladesh. In the nineteenth century the issue of sustainability considered mainly social conditions in early industrial capitalism. The German social state, and also the Victorian welfare state, Marxist movements, brought their own interpretations of, and solutions to, the question. For example, Bismarck forced his social insurance reforms not because he liked the idea very much, but because the German army was horrified with the quality of recruits who spent their childhood as workers in factories and also because of industry moguls who realized that more sophisticated production and political peace require a more affluent society. This has created the fundamentals for social sustainability of the postwar welfare states in Europe. Modern debate on sustainability, focused mainly on environmental questions, came later. In 1968 Garret Hardin wrote his famous work ‘Tragedy of the commons’, in which he analyzed how public goods got exhausted by actors in a free market economy (Hardin, 1968). His arguments helped to explain why, for example, non-regulated access to fishery can quickly lead to empty seas and collapse of the fishery industry in many countries. A few years later, in 1972, the Club of Rome published ‘The limits to growth’, a groundbreaking study which dealt precisely with the connection between economic growth and scarcity of resources. Its conclusions, based on a computer simulation, were very pessimistic and echoed strongly in the public debate around the world. For an update of this study, see Meadows et al. (2006). The book launched an extensive area of research and political activity around environmental questions, food production and energy policy. In many countries green parties established themselves as powerful factors in domestic policy. Rising awareness of the sustainability problem in environmental issues and resources translated also into international cooperation. So far there have been many conferences on climate change and framework agreements (e.g. the Kyoto Protocol on reduction of greenhouse gases), but their effectiveness is not very high. Many countries see such global actions against climate change as endangering their vital economic interests, among them particularly developing economies. According to the study published by the Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency, since 1990 to 2011 the most populous countries in the world and rising industrial powers, China and India, increased their emission of CO2 at 227% and 100% respectively. China's emission was in 2011 with 9700 million tonnes of CO2 almost three times higher than in the EU27 (3790 tonnes) (Olivier, et al., 2012, p. 29). This is why it is hard to say much about success in the area and why the risks have not yet been reduced. Figure 48.1 Top 20 of the highest public debt ratio (% to GDP) Page 5 of 18 The SAGE Handbook of Globalization SAGE Editorial arrangement © Paul Battersby, Joseph M. Siracusa and Manfred B. Steger 2014 SAGE Reference Sustainability perspective started to be visible not only in the environmental area. For many years the theme of overpopulation occupied an important place in the debate. However, the process of ageing of societies in Europe, Japan and China brought slightly different arguments, seeing dangers for the sustainability of pension and health-care systems. It is argued that the current structure incurs huge public debt in favour of current consumption of the older generation and at the expense of the shrinking, youngersector of society. A similar way of thinking can be seen in the discussion of the global financial system and level of indebtedness or food production and consumption. Even if in all these areas progress is unquestionable, there is still no consequent governance on both national and global level. In fact, the expansion of sustainability culture in the current economic system is based on bench-marking of good practices. It is not enough to stop rising imbalances. Towards a Sustainable (and More Stable) Economic Model It is time to elaborate on what kind of economic governance can deal efficiently with problems of stability and sustainability. Where are new approaches necessary? In my opinion, there are three areas of economic models that should be re-thought and redesigned. Firstly, the issue of what is an ‘efficient market’ needs some new clarification. Secondly, we must accept the fact that there might be many different institutional ways to efficient economic systems, but it Page 6 of 18 The SAGE Handbook of Globalization SAGE Editorial arrangement © Paul Battersby, Joseph M. Siracusa and Manfred B. Steger 2014 SAGE Reference does not necessarily mean that some of them are a priori more efficient, stable and better for sustainability, then the others. Thirdly, a redesign needs a wider look at what is economic growth and what kind of growth is compatible with the idea of sustainability. Table 48.1 CO2 emissions in 2011 (million tonnes CO2) and CO2 emissions change in %, 1990–2011 Emissions 2011 Change 1990–2011 in % United States 5420 -12 EU 273790 -18 Germany 810 -23 United Kingdom 470 -27 Italy 410 -11 France 360 -17 Poland 350 11 Spain 300 29 Netherlands 160 2 Russian Federation 1830 -25 Japan 1240 7 Canada 560 24 Australia 430 57 Ukraine 320 -58 China 9700 227 India 1970 100 South Korea 610 110 Indonesia 490 122 Saudi Arabia 460 62 Brazil 450 53 Mexico 450 5 Iran 410 49 South Africa 360 -1 Taiwan 270 90 Thailand 230 Source: (Olivier et al., 2012: 29) 106 Complexity Approach to Markets Markets are the most substantial, constructional element of economies. However, nowadays we are dealing with biases which make understanding their functioning puzzling. As a consequence there are difficulties with efficient economic policy and, obviously with providing stability and sustainability. Page 7 of 18 The SAGE Handbook of Globalization SAGE Editorial arrangement © Paul Battersby, Joseph M. Siracusa and Manfred B. Steger 2014 SAGE Reference One of them is surely the formal concept of markets which dominates modern economics. It is based on strong assumptions which make building theoretical models easier, but, like many authors have concluded even before the crisis stated, only partly coincide with reality (Fulbrook, 2004; Keen, 2011). Individual actors in such models are generally driven by a onedimensional motivation of profit, are able to calculate precisely costs and gains, take advantage of access to all necessary information and are actually not disturbed by other actors who have more power over the market. Another strong assumption is that markets tend always to a state of equilibrium set out by forces of demand and supply. If there is a situation of imbalance caused by external shocks, these forces push markets ‘automatically’ towards an efficient equilibrium level of price, no matter what kind of shock caused them. There is a famous ‘rocking-horse’ metaphor of the Swedish economist Knut Wicksell referring to this feature of markets (Louçã, 2001: 29): no matter the reason, a horse with blinkers will move in an expected way. This mechanistic paradigm has dominated economics since the nineteenth century, both in academia and economic policy. It created a strong body of many valuable and sophisticated theories. However, if we consider the fact the it failed with providing enough insights into the grounds and mechanism of the last economic crisis, the overall assessment of the state of economics must be cautious. The crisis wasn't after all an effect of a ‘black swan’ in the sense expressed by of Nassim Nicolas Taleb: an unexpected event with dramatic consequences (Taleb, 2007). It was a classical bubble which had not been perceived because the formal concept of markets has had problems with explaining e.g. how irrational behaviour impacts economic processes, how imbalances can become persistent and why economies can stuck by a suboptimal equilibrium for a long time. Thus they had not been able to explain why stability and sustainability were not provided in the system. If one looks for a central term embracing all the problems mentioned above, it is complexity, or, to be more precise, quickly rising levels of complexity in modern economies. More commodities, more diversified preferences and needs of actors, more suppliers and more buyers, faster communication between them, more sophisticated, global relations between markets, etc.: all these did not fit into relatively simple models anymore and also challenged traditional, sectoral and nationally oriented regulation. For example, financial markets behave to a certain level as a kind of shock buffer fulfilling an extremely important role in the economy. If shocks get bigger, however, they quickly switch to a shock booster and find a new equilibrium at a very inefficient level. When, how, over which mechanisms – this is still a vague supposition. The Wicksell metaphor of “rocking horses” may sound well, but a a picture of a herd of wild horses, from which everyone reacts differently on incoming impulses and often runs into a different direction can be more convincing nowadays. What should be done? There is a huge need for a more holistic and organic approach to economies. This social system should be considered as a dynamic, non-linear, self-organizing one with intelligent, flexible actors, rather than a set of structurally similar markets, which all tend towards equilibrium (Beinhocker, 2007). For economics, which so far enjoyed selfisolationism (or methodological imperialism) (Milonakis and Fine, 2009: 149–71) it can mean integration of interdisciplinary approaches into the mainstream, including psychology, political science (crucial actors and interest), sociology, but also biology with its evolutionary elements and neuro-economics, as well as physics to explain problems of imbalances and bubbles in complex systems. More attention must be paid to empirical studies, even in a manner of ‘Freakonomics’ (Levitt and Dubner, 2011), and economic history. Economic historians were after all among few researchers, who signalled the approaching crisis and belong today, like Nigel Roubini (Roubini and Mihm, 2010), to luminaries of the branch. This interdisciplinary Page 8 of 18 The SAGE Handbook of Globalization SAGE Editorial arrangement © Paul Battersby, Joseph M. Siracusa and Manfred B. Steger 2014 SAGE Reference approach should lead to the collection of knowledge, which helps to create a digital surrogate of reality. These ‘would-be-worlds’ (Beinhocker, 2007) could emulate economic systems and say much more about conditions for stability and sustainability. Economic policy and regulation must also draw consequences from the newest developments – and this is actually happening. Public agencies try to collect more specific data about markets in order to deal with complexity challenge. This includes for example identification of crucial actors in the financial system with the ‘too-big-to-fall’ potential and of criteria for their ‘stress-tests’ or redundancies stopping domino effects. It resembles, in part, an approach towards super-spreaders in epidemic prevention. Some governments consider also reduction of speed of computer systems connecting international financial markets (so called HFT, high frequency trading) in order to diminish the number of transactions and risk of bubbles (Arnuk and Saluzzi, 2012). The next years will be surely devoted to application of stabilization criteria in many areas of economic systems. There is a very serious problem with imposing such new rules on more and more globally oriented markets. Fragmented regulation of national markets is insufficient since externalities have global dimension and produce unequal distribution of costs among countries. If only some of them will be covered with it, actors will try to avoid costs of rules and search for exit options. This is why any supranational solutions must be connected with universal acceptance and credible sanction. How difficult is it can be seen in the example of global climate change regulation (Dessler and Parson, 2010) There have been so far experiments with market solutions (emission rights), benchmarking and elements of regulation. None of these has been efficient enough so far. This is why it is more sensible to prepare for a less romantic, but relatively effective option known from studies on complex systems. Not a covering agreement, but decisions and actions of crucial and powerful actors in the system are decisive. In the global reality this principle translates into regional agreements where it is easier to deal with distribution of costs (like e.g. in the European Union which has been trying to achieve its local climate change agreement between ‘old’ members pushing towards restrictions and new members who try to protect their industries). At a further stage this approach will enable a global regulation. This process is happening not only in the climate change area. A good example is also in the policy against tax evasion. Since it is extremely difficult to set a common denominator, Germany decided to acquire data with tax evaders in Switzerland or Liechtenstein and started to sustain pressure on them in order to block this exit option. In addition to that Berlin pushes countries to change their financial regulation. It is a highly controversial, unilateral method of action, but probably the only efficient one so far. Pluralism of Development Models How Convergence Failed The years after 1980 put into the economic debate the issue of convergence of national economic models. The source of this consideration was the rapid expansion of neoliberal ideology, which saw markets as the most efficient way of social coordination and true growthcreating machines. Spectacular expansion of the globalization process, economic reforms in the USA, United Kingdom and Latin America, the collapse of communism combined with shock therapies of previously state-led economies – all these created an ‘end of history’ atmosphere. It seemed that the only way to grow and develop was a liberal agenda formulated in the most lucid way in the Washington Consensus. Economic policies of national states started to be evaluated under the criterion, how small are governments and how much freedom is granted to market actors (e.g. the Economic Index of Freedom by the Heritage Page 9 of 18 The SAGE Handbook of Globalization SAGE Editorial arrangement © Paul Battersby, Joseph M. Siracusa and Manfred B. Steger 2014 SAGE Reference Foundation). It wasn't a big challenge to find arguments for the hypothesis that all economic models would drift gradually to the Anglo-Saxon solutions (Gilpin, 2001). Crisis in Japan, the weakness of Germany and to some extent also the Scandinavian economies in the 1990s seemed to confirm this supposition. The neo-liberal agenda brought, however, some problems. Firstly, it increased exposition of the world economic systems on crisis and contagion effects since most reforms were aiming at national deregulation which was not àreplaced' by efficient global regulation. This issue became quite clear when local collapses in the 1990s, like the Asian crisis or the Russian crisis, turned to be global events with extremely dangerous potential. International economic organizations created to help countries in trouble, like the International Monetary Fund and the World Bank, were conditioning their aid measures with even deeper deregulation of crisisridden economies. This strategy provoked many controversies (Serra and Stiglitz, 2008) since it sharpened some stability problems instead of solving them and was actually finally abandoned. Also development policy of these institutions based on the market priority has been harshly criticized (Head, 2008). The second problem concerned efficiency. The tacit and wide-spread assumption on superiority of free market solutions has some flaws. There are issues with shorttermism, high volatility and inability to deal with externalities (costs and benefits affecting third persons), which are directly connected with the challenge of sustainability. The efficiency assumption is also criticized in the context of social inequalities. They are produced by the free market game, but in neoliberal approaches, the less affluent “losers” have incentives to become more efficient and should catch up winning the next round of the game. This is exactly the content of the founding myths of the American capitalism: ‘from a shoe cleaner to a millionaire’. However, inequalities can become lasting producing “constant losers’ and in this case, as newer publications show, economic efficiency suffers a lot. Poverty trap destroys capacities of human capital and make domestic demand unstable. (Banerjee and Duflo, 2011; Stiglitz, 2012; Wilkinson and Pickett, 2009). And last but not least: the success of economies like Japan, South Korea and China is proof that not only market strategies can work well but also highly interventionists ones. The third problem is legitimacy of market based solutions. The market itself is not able to produce legitimacy, but it needs acceptance of all actors (Rodrik, 2007: 237–42). However, while starting with distribution of welfare and power over the competition mechanisms, the neo-liberal agenda has to have not only a good idea of what to do with the winners (it certainly does), but also what to do with the losers. If there is no feasible solution of this challenge – a clear and accepted definition of social justice – a market economy endangers its political sustainability by making alternatives more attractive. This is why markets need to be propped up by other means of coordination: state, family, associations, which are able to formulate such justifications. During the last crisis it has been easy to find examples of this clash. Greek people put under the pressure of very neo-liberal market reforms after 2009 tend to vote more for extremist parties because they do not accept distribution of social burdens and its official grounds. On the other hand, equally harsh market reforms in Poland or the Baltic states after the communist era, enjoyed acceptance due to widespread hopes in their societies that in a long term they will be beneficiaries of changes. The above arguments can be summed up with a metaphor of the American economist Dani Rodrik: ‘Markets are the essence of a market economy in the same sense that lemons are the Page 10 of 18 The SAGE Handbook of Globalization SAGE Editorial arrangement © Paul Battersby, Joseph M. Siracusa and Manfred B. Steger 2014 SAGE Reference essence of lemonade. Pure lemon juice is barely drinkable. To make good lemonade, you need to mix it with water and sugar’ (Rodrik, 2011). This means that the market must be ‘mixed’ with other mechanisms of social coordination. The open question is – what should be the proportion of this mix? The answer can be delivered by the varieties of capitalism approach (VoC), which has produced for a decade many interesting publications in political economy, explaining why diversity is possible and is better than homogeneity. It will be elaborated in the next paragraphs. Varieties of Capitalism This VoC is posited on a couple of basic assumptions. Firstly, it considers firms as the most important actors for welfare creation in national economies, since they provide innovations and new products. To achieve their goals they need access to resources, to mention the most fundamental ones – capital, labour and skills. This access is not always easy due to risk and uncertainty which concern almost every transaction in an economy. Very helpful in this context can be institutions defined as rules of the game, which structure social interactions. They create a minimum of certainty and enable transactions. It is easy to imagine that in different countries across the world institutions have very diversified characters. Some of them are more market oriented, others put into transactions more hierarchy, rules of associations, networks, government regulation or even religious norms. These institutional arrangements can be decisive for competitive profiles of national economies, since they decide how dynamic or stable access to resources will be. VoC authors use in this context the term ‘institutional comparative advantage’, clearly referring to the traditional Ricardo's theory (Hall and Soskice, 2001: 1–71). They might have been right: institutions are among the few things in globalization that cannot be bought and transplanted. From the variety of systems we can distinguish two outermost, theoretical models: liberal market economy (LME) and coordinated market economy (CME). The first type, LME, can be characterized by dynamic access to resources, which means, that it is relatively inexpensive to change conditions of transactions or resign from it. We can see this feature in design of markets for capital, labour and skills. Capital in LMEs is derived often from stock markets, where assets can quickly change owners and their value is estimated by price mechanisms. The labour market is also shaped by dynamic relations, where hire and fire is relatively easy thanks to limited regulation. If firms perceive the market situation bad they simply lay off workers, but if prospects are promising they quickly employ. In the third area – skills – individuals and potential workers – invest in their knowledge and then sell it to firms. However, due to flexibility of the labour market they tend to choose transferable skill profiles, since they must consider their chances and balance the promise of getting a high salary for unique skills with the risk of remaining unemployed. This kind of system, if well designed and transmitting right incentives, produces radical innovations, since it is very open to new ideas and new products. It creates a good environment for new branches, like telecommunication technologies, biotechnology, and media. A classic example is the USA. The second outermost model is coordinated market economy (CME). Transactions are more stable and long term oriented. Capital is provided by banks which create loyalty based relations with firms, thus the access is ‘patient’. The labour market is characterized by long term contracts and relatively low differences in wage levels. Skills are produced rather in companies, which invest their own capital in order to create a set of specific, rare qualifications fitting ideally into their product profile. Since workers get employed for a longer time this kind of an investment makes sense. Japan and Germany have been considered as typical examples of CME. Their institutional comparative advantage is found in branches, which Page 11 of 18 The SAGE Handbook of Globalization SAGE Editorial arrangement © Paul Battersby, Joseph M. Siracusa and Manfred B. Steger 2014 SAGE Reference demand very specialized skills and are based on incremental innovations. They do not compete with low costs, but rather high quality. This is something that we can easily observe in German and Japanese factories for cars or sophisticated machines. These two systems are of course extreme examples, and between them there are many possible combinations. Scandinavian models mix free market with a generous social insurance that encourages people to invest in rare, specific skills. Other models apply strong coordination of the state, other religion or families. What is important, however, is that neither of them is per se more efficient than the other. Local institutions can create very unique institutional comparative advantage and provide by the way more legitimacy. What is important is rather the quality of institutions: if they communicate enough with each other, if they do not contribute to power asymmetries, and if they have a credible sanction. It sounds like an idea for a more stable and sustainable solution. There is also another argument for more diversity, important from the global perspective. Some authors argue that LMEs and CMEs are in the world economy like pedals in vehicles (Acemoglu et al., 2012). In fact, they are rarely in the same state. At beginning of innovation cycles, LMEs drive the global system with their new technologies and rising productivity and CMEs lag behind. It is a time of immigration to LMEs, which offer higher salaries. Later on, when the wave of innovations calms, CMEs make their own job by integrating the latest technologies into sophisticated production regimes and providing the global market with mature, high quality products and also well-educated workers. This enables LMEs to shift resources to new experiments and prepare a new wave of innovations. It looks a bit like the case of USA and Europe and their coexistence in the global economy. This coexistence is definitely not disadvantageous for stability of development: a bicycle with only one pedal is not a safe machine. Approaches to Growth The Roll-Over Effect Modern capitalism developed in the last 200 years based itself on the assumption of growth and expansion. The more products we are able to deliver, the better for everybody. Expression of this attitude is the domination of the GDP index in measurements of performance of national economies. It shows the output in a given year and expresses it in monetary value (national currency). It has many advantages. First of all the GDP offers statistical precision and comparative perspective, since it is relatively easy to apply similar techniques of collecting and converting data in countries across the world. In this way GDP creates also a kind of competitive environment for nations: it is evident who has the highest GDP growth or the highest GDP per capita. However, the GDP is not flawless. Its beguilingly clear numbers can show only one dimension of growth, hiding others. In all we can get a distorted picture of economic development. Just to quote some examples: A dinner prepared at home by family members and friends is worse for the economy than a dinner ordered in a restaurant. If there is no transaction, there is simply no growth measured. On the other hand, a heavy smoker of cigarettes is a true GDP driver. Not only can the single transaction of buying cigarettes be supportive, but also later visits to physicians and purchase of medicaments. In a similar way one can look at divorces, which can make real estate markets grow, give a boost to furniture factories, not to mention the demand for lawyers. On a more general level doubts about quality of growth versus sheer size of GDP can be analyzed in the context of stability and sustainability of economic systems. A high number of Page 12 of 18 The SAGE Handbook of Globalization SAGE Editorial arrangement © Paul Battersby, Joseph M. Siracusa and Manfred B. Steger 2014 SAGE Reference goods delivered in a national economy translates to short term growth, which combined with other short term indicators like inflation or unemployment rates can say a lot about stability. However, it essentially overlooks many long term indica tors of development, for example accessibility resources and their ability to regenerate, and also social issues like health, education and security. To put it simply: costs of current growth considered as a GDP rising can be rolled-over to a less ‘visible’ long term or, as it happened in the past, to other coun tries and regions of the world. There are many examples of the roll-over problem. Longer working time can quickly boost the supply of labour, but in the longer term it can cause lower birth rates, a higher propensity of diseases, in particular, burnout syndrome, depression and cardiovascular diseases – all in all, challenges for the labour market. An even more outspoken example concerns the debt issue. Easy and inexpensive access to loans can make selling numbers explode and so, too, the GDP rates. Perhaps, then, this is one of the reasons why modern capitalism has such a loud culture of overconsumption and capacities to make it popular. The effect might be, however, a rising level of debt, which must be ‘solved’ later, by subsequent generations. The same scheme is about resources. Today's growth and consumption are ‘innocent’ in terms of GDP, but they flourish due to ignoring the future; and this future can bring not only scarce, more expensive resources, but a catastrophe of the entire system. This is not an abstract scenario: it happened many times in the past as was shown very pointedly in the book of Jarred Diamond titled ‘The Collapse’ (Diamond, 2005). Awareness about this problem has dramatically risen in the last 20 years. This is attributed to the fact that the roll-over has gotten much more difficult in the first decade of the twenty-first century. The world has now more visible ‘limits’ and exporting consequences of exponential growth and deficiencies in sustainability cannot be made so easily. However, there is no clear, common view, on how to meet this challenge. More Growth There is a strong voice in favor of continuation of the existing, dominating path. Economies should still take care about their output level, so the GDP remains the most important point of reference. How should sustainability be achieved then? Well, by adjustment of economies to market forces, which make some scarce resources simply more expensive and thus enforce a more sustainable, responsible exploitation. This principle refers not only to natural resources. If for example capital is more expensive, a more responsible approach to debt would be an expected reaction leading to financial sustainability. Another assumption is a strong belief in technological progress. It will increase productivity and, in particular, save resources. Hybrid or electric cars, bio-agriculture, recycling techniques, communication that reduces travelling, etc. – all should contribute to faster, and simultaneously, better quality of growth. There are no illusions, however, that this will happen immediately. This will be a gradual way, with temporary use, for example, of alternative gas resources from controversial fracking methods. Such a way is considered as safe for economies, since it does not exert a push to reduce energy consumption too quickly. This idea deserves, if necessary, some interventionism. Nicolas Stern, a British economist and former chief economist of the World Bank, who prepared in 2006 a report on climate change prospects, treated the ecological challenges for sustainability as classical economic externalities, which must be regulated, taxed and if necessary also balanced by direct spending of 1–2 per cent of GDP annually in order to prop up the non-carbon technologies (Stern, 2007). In this sense, there is much more acceptance for regulation and the Page 13 of 18 The SAGE Handbook of Globalization SAGE Editorial arrangement © Paul Battersby, Joseph M. Siracusa and Manfred B. Steger 2014 SAGE Reference government intervening, but the logic of growth remains the same: the more goods, the better. Amended Growth The second approach to growth is a more sceptical one. It sees the GDP index as an important measure of human achievements, but it has to be combined with additional indexes which refer to several aspects of quality of life and sustainability. The only problem is that it is still not very clear what aspects are important. This is why there are many more or less complicated indexes in the market, which compete against each other. The only globally accepted measure of ‘amended’ growth and its quality is the Human Development Index (HDI). It was created in 1990 by Mahbub ul Haq, the Pakistani economist, and then developed by the Indian Nobel Prize Laureate Amartya Sen and used by the United Nations Developing Programme for comparative studies. Its idea is to combine income, life expectancy and education (see: http://hdr.undp.org/en/humandev/) It is of course not an ideal measurement It is criticized particularly for lack of ecological perspective and focusing on formal aspects of education (school attendance), not really a level of acquired knowledge. Another interesting group comprises indexes developed and applied at country level. Sometimes they build up reputation and become popular at the global level. A good example is the Gross National Happiness, coined by the king of Bhutan Jigme Singye Wangchuck in 1972. In the last decade it has been supplemented by a new generation of happiness measurements (‘well being’), but their problem is very similar to those of HDI. Interest in the issue of happiness has been rising; however, so we can expect further amendments and profound studies (Frey, 2010). Possibily they can count on political support. For instance, the president of France Nicolas Sarkozy announced in early 2008 that we need to measure also happiness instead of GDP only. A similar idea was supported by the British prime minister David Cameron. What is interesting is that neither of these politicians is a socialist who have usually been promoters of alternatives to GDP. Some countries are pretty much advanced in application of their own indexes. One of the best known examples is the Canadian Index of Wellbeing, which includes arts, culture and recreation, community vitality, democratic engagement, education, environment, healthy populations, living standards and time use (see: https://uwaterloo.ca/canadian-indexwellbeing/). Also Germany is a provider of similar experiments with measuring qualitative development. Stefan Bergheim, an economist and founder o f t h e Z e n t r u m f u e r Gesellsschaftlichen Fortschritt, developed the Progress Index. It analyzes income, health, education and environment, a so called ecologic footprint. It provides also a promising statistical approach (Bergheim and Barth, 2012). These and many other initiatives cannot drown out the fact that a universal, globally used and renowned index connecting level production with quality of life is still not available. End of Growth The search can be speeded up by the economic crisis and cassandric voices that our global economic system is now at the end of its known shape. Many of its current axioms, among them steady and fast growth of production and ‘obvious’ rise of welfare, will be some of the first victims of the process. Tyler Cowen, professor at George Mason University in Virginia, prophesies that the world economy is moving towards a time of a ‘great stagnation’. The close-to-recession statistical footprint of Japan in the 1990s, called the lost decade, should be Page 14 of 18 The SAGE Handbook of Globalization SAGE Editorial arrangement © Paul Battersby, Joseph M. Siracusa and Manfred B. Steger 2014 SAGE Reference perceived as ‘a new normality’ (Cowen, 2011). What are the arguments for this scenario? Cowen says that there are no ‘low hanging fruits’ anymore. He means by this that the day of inexpensive access to resources is over. One can also say that extreme increase of productivity following from migration of the labour force and global competition is also close to exhaustion. The most important argument is, however, a slower pace of innovation – a crucial point for explaining lower rates of productivity rise. It is worth stressing that until the eighteenth century the average growth of the world economy was very low (1–1.5 per cent annually), because real innovations were simply lacking. The last 200 years of growth followed from an extreme, unprecedented wave of new techniques of production: from steam engine and mass manufacturing to the internet. However, maybe there are no new sources of revolutionary innovations and the old ones have reached their limits. In this context, the scathing statement of the Nobel Prize winner in economics, Robert Solow (known as the Solow's computer paradox) that ‘you can see the computer age everywhere but in the productivity statistics’ (Gordon, 2004: 11), sounds like a warning. The above arguments are of course speculations, and it is not difficult to find opposite, optimistic views (see e.g. Brynjolfsson and McAfee, 2014). However, dreary visions contain enough credibility to encourage ideas about a new concept of growth and development, and thus new concepts of sustainability and stability. Dennis Meadows seems to be on their side while saying that ‘sustainable development is a pointless word, like peaceful war’ (in an interview for the German magazine Zeit, in 2012). Innovations and production growth should be entirely subordinated to the balance account of the system, including resources, energy, consumption biases, and debt. Such opinion is expressed also by Tim Jackson, British economist, who criticized a ‘soft’ conciliation approach to growth represented by current green parties. From his point of view switching to electric cars is just another bypass to save the old habits. He thinks that the world must leave the traditional growth logic and search for progress in quality of life, development of services, provision of local goods, shortened working time, end of consumerism and higher public investment (Jackson, 2009). Such a scenario sounds tempting, but is politically not possible. It could work in developed economies, but would be fiercely rejected in developing, currently booming economies, whose citizens dream about a similar level of material GDP measured affluence. This urge is difficult to reconcile with radical development ideas. Proponents of the new approach mean, however, that it is not a matter of ‘if’, but rather ‘when and how’ the human civilization moves to a new concept of growth. It can move actively via reasonable consideration of facts and new policies (maybe through amended growth), or reactively, adjusting to crisis and disasters caused by despairing attempts to save the old, good world of exponential growth and quick advance of material status. Conclusion It is not an exaggeration to say that the first part of the twenty-first century will be devoted to a search for a new balance between old ambitions to grow quickly now and new fears of losing chances for growth in the future. This is a revolutionary time for the human civilization, comparable with the industrial revolution of the nineteenth century. We still do not have a proper name for the process, and we aren't perhaps able to specify all features of the change. But villagers who moved 200 years ago to emerging cities must have had a similar perception process. What can we assume now? Firstly, the issue of sustainability will expand to all fields of Page 15 of 18 The SAGE Handbook of Globalization SAGE Editorial arrangement © Paul Battersby, Joseph M. Siracusa and Manfred B. Steger 2014 SAGE Reference economic life and merge with stability. Short term policies will be evaluated under their long term impact. Secondly, we are moving towards a new economic model. It will still be market economy; there are few symptoms suggesting that totally new alternatives have any chances to become viable. It will be based on the efficient markets approach, which means no tolerance for asymmetries of information and power, and much better knowledge about their behaviour in complex environments. The third element will be the pluralism of institutional arrangements which can create unique competitive profiles of national economies and a more stable global system. The fourth and the last element, is a corrected goal and measure of development. The very focus on growth of production is not sustainable, although still informing well about a state of economy. However, it will be supplemented with long term development factors, like social coherence, energy coherence and environmental coherence. It is a matter of time, then, when this integrated approach to growth and development becomes reality. Discussion Questions 1 Since we all agree that sustainability will be a major challenge in the future, it is still unclear how to deal with it. Is the free market approach a better way to sustainability or do we need more regulation and government interference in this area? 2 How is it possible to design global governance on access to recourses in order to avoid a roll-over of negative externalities to poorer countries? Is it better to transfer power over the issue to some exclusive groups like G20 or to invest in democratic approaches via e.g. UN? 3 How to convince developing countries that it is a good idea to invest in ecological and financial sustainability, even if it means a temporary slowdown in current GDP growth rates? References AcemogluD, RobinsonJA and VerdierT (2012) Can't we all be more like Scandinavians? Asymmetric growth and institutions in an interdependent world. MIT Department of Economics Working Paper, Issue 12-22. http://dx.doi.org/10.3386/w18441 ArnukS and SaluzziJ (2012) Broken Markets. How High Frequency Trading and Predatory Practices on Wall Street are Destroying Investor Confidence and your Portfolio. s.l. New Jersey: FT Press. BallT and BellamyR (eds) (2003) Twentieth-century Political Thought. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/CHOL9780521563543 BanerjeeAV and DufloE (2011) Poor Economics. A Radical Rethinking of the Way to Fight Global Poverty. s.l. New York: Public Affairs. BeckU (1986) Das Risikogesellschaft. Auf dem Weg in eine andere Moderne. Frankfurt am Main: Suhrkamp. BeinhockerE (2007) The Origin of Wealth. Evolution, Complexity and the Radical Remaking of Economics. London: Random House Business Books. BergheimS a n d BarthV (2012) Fortschrittsindex 2011. Lebensqualitaet neu vermessen. Frankfurt am Main: Zentrum fuer Gesellschaftlichen Fortschritt. BernankeB (2004) The great moderation. Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke at the m e e t i n g s o f t h e E a s t e r n E c o n o m i c Association, Washington, DC. A v a i l a b l e a t : http://www.federalreserve.gov/BOARDDOCS/SPEECHES/2004/20040220/default.htm (accessed 5 December 2012). BrynjolffsonE and McAfeeA (2014) The Second Mashine Age. Work, Progress and Prosperity in a Time of Brilliant Technologies.: W.W. Norton&Company. Page 16 of 18 The SAGE Handbook of Globalization SAGE Editorial arrangement © Paul Battersby, Joseph M. Siracusa and Manfred B. Steger 2014 SAGE Reference CateT (ed.) (2012) Keynes's General Theory. Seventy-five Years Later. Northampton: Edward Elgar Publishing Limited. CowenT (2011) The Great Stagnation: How America Ate All The Low-Hanging Fruit of Modern History, Got Sick, and Will (Eventually) Feel Better. New York: Dutton Adult, Penguin Group. DesslerA and ParsonEA (2010) The Science and Politics of Global Climate Change: A Guide t o t h e D e b a t e. C a m b r i d g e , U K: C a m b r i d g e U n i v e r s i t y P r e s s. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511819506 DiamondJ (2005) Collapse. How Societies Choose to Fail or Succeed. New York: Viking. Die Zeit (2012) Interview with Dennis Meadows: Gruene Industrie ist reine Phantasie, 12 December. FreyBS (2010) Happiness: A Revolution in Economics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. FulbrookE (2004) A Guide to What's Wrong with Economics.: Anthem Press. GilpinR (2001) Global Political Economy: Understanding the International Economic Order. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. GordonRJ (2004) Productivity, Growth, Inflation and Unemployment. The Collection of Essays of Robert J. Gordon. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. HallP a n d SoskiceD (2001) Varieties of Capitalism. The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. Oxford: Oxford University Press. HardinG (1968) The tragedy of the commons. Science3859(162): 1243–8. HeadJW (2008) Losing the Global Development War: A Contemporary Critique of the IMF, the World Bank and the WTO.: BRILL. http://dx.doi.org/10.1163/ej.9789004161887.i-344 International Monetary Fund (2012) How the IMF Promotes Global Economic Stability. Available at: http://www.imf.org/External/np/exr/facts/pdf/globstab.pdf (accessed 13 December 2012). JacksonT (2009) Prosperity without Growth: Economics for a Finite Planet. s.l.: Routledge. KeenS (2011) Debunking Economics - Revised and Expanded Edition: The Naked Emperor Dethroned?London: Zed Books. KnoopTA (2009) Recessions and Depressions: Understanding Business Cycles: Understanding Business Cycles. Santa Barbara, CA: ABC Clio. LevittSD and DubnerSJ (2011) Freakonomics: A Rogue Economist Explores the Hidden Side of Everything. London: Harper Collins. LouçãF (2001) Intriguing pendula: Founding metaphors in the analysis of economic fluctuations. Cambridge Journal of Economics25 (1): 25–55. MeadowsD, RandersJ and MeadowsD (2006) The Limits to Growth: The 30-year Update. London: Earthscan. MilonakisD, FineB (2008) From Economics Imperialism to Freakonomics. The shifting Boundaries between Economics and other Social Sciences, Abingdon, New York: Routledge. OlivierJG, Janssens-MaenhoutG and PetersJA (2012) Trends in global CO2 emissions; 2012 Report. The Hague/Bildhoven: PBL Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency. RodrikD (2007) One Economics, Many Recipes: Globalization, Institutions, and Economic Growth. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. RodrikD (2011) Milton Friedman's magical thinking. Available at: http://www.projectsyndicate.org/commentary/milton-friedman-s-magical-thinking (accessed 15 December 2012). RoubiniN and MihmS (2010) Crisis Economics: A Crash Course in the Future of Finance. New York: Penguin Books. SedlacekT (2011) Economics of Good and Evil: The Quest for Economic Meaning from Gilgamesh to Wall Street. Oxford: Oxford University Press. SerraN and StiglitzJE (2008) The Washington Consensus Reconsidered: Towards a New G l o b a l G o v e r n a n c e: Oxford University Press. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199534081.001.0001 Page 17 of 18 The SAGE Handbook of Globalization SAGE Editorial arrangement © Paul Battersby, Joseph M. Siracusa and Manfred B. Steger 2014 SAGE Reference SternN (2007) The Economics of Climate Change: The Stern Review. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511817434 StiglitzJ (2012) The Price of Inequality. How Today's Divided Society Endangers our Future. New York: WW Norton and Company. TalebNN (2007) The Black Swan: The Impact of the Highly Improbable. New York: Random House. WilkinsonR and PickettK (2009) The Spirit Level: Why More Equal Societies Almost Always Do Better. London: Alan Lane. World Commission on Environment and Development (1987) Our Common Future. Oxford: Oxford University Press. sustainability gross domestic product stabilization markets and economies economy stability world economy http://dx.doi.org/10.4135/9781473906020.n48 Page 18 of 18 The SAGE Handbook of Globalization