https://www.sciencedirect.com/topics/social-sciences/human-capital-theory Diversity, Democracy, and Social Justice in Education Chazz Robinson, Raechele Pope, in International Encyclopedia of Education(Fourth Edition), 2023 Human capital in the knowledge economy To fully analyze the knowledge economy a careful look at the theoretical underpinnings in necessary. The theoretical underpinnings of the knowledge economy highlight several theories; however, human capital theory appears to be driving the main discourse on the knowledge economy within the US and globally, with top organizations like the World Bank and the OECD using it in tandem with the knowledge economy to shape practical uses within society (Takayama, 2013; Weber, 2011). Harvard economist Claudia Goldin (2016) explains that the human capital definition centers on the idea that investments in people, such as education, increase workers' productivity and skillsets. This theory relates to the knowledge economy because it highlights the common assertion that the more educated a person becomes the more, they will be desired for their specific knowledge and increase their human capital. Korres (2008) argued that, “a lack of investment in human capital … prevents poor countries from catching up with rich ones. Educational attainment and public spending on education are correlated positively to economic growth” (p. 714). This connection directly places economic value on knowledge obtained. The connection between human capital theory and the knowledge economy becomes more evident when exploring the assumptions within the theory of human capital. Human capital theory assumes that investment in education is necessary to acquire skills and training which, in turn, will increase individual capital (Blundell et al., 1999). Tan (2014) adds, These knowledges and skills will increase his or her productivity in the workplace. This increased productivity will bring a higher salary to the individual since the wage of a person, in the ideal labor market, is determined by the person's productivity. Therefore, people would invest in education up to the point where the private benefits from education are equal to the private cost (p. 413). This conceptualization of the knowledge economy is being globalized, with organizations indicating that human capital is accumulated by investing in education so that individuals can compete in the new society and poverty can be ended (World Bank, 2018). While the World Bank has aligned their organizational goals around the knowledge economy and has developed a metric system to examine how countries are meeting their practical goals in the knowledge economy, they acknowledge that before and even more so during COVID season, low-income societies, and gender minoritized people are struggling within the knowledge economy (World Bank, 2018). While the World Bank made references to gender minoritized individuals such as women, missing were also the experiences of sexual minoritized people. Similar, there have been reports that students in the United States who identify as low income, international, and/or racially minoritized have been most impacted by COVID restrictions (Means and Neisler, 2021). These initial findings could explain why knowledge economy and its theoretical underpinnings to human capital theory both have been criticized for lacking a cultural perspective on how people navigate the knowledge economy (Weber, 2011). Connecting this critique to today's time shows the inconsistences in the knowledge economy regarding minority groups. View chapterExplore book Higher Education Market Felix Maringe, in International Encyclopedia of the Social & Behavioral Sciences (Second Edition), 2015 The Investment Theory of HE Human Capital Theory (e.g., Schultz, 1961; Becker, 1993; Mincer, 1974) presents HE as both a public and private investment decision for governments and its people. As a public investment, the fundamental argument is that investing in education leads to economic growth through increased productivity, social stability, and healthier lifestyles. On the other hand, as a private investment choice, investing in education leads to increased lifetime earnings for those with more years of schooling; access to better paying jobs; reduced time spent in the unemployment market; and speedier transitions to enhanced career prospects (Wahrenburg and Weldi, 2007). In the context of contemporary HE markets, evidence does not always lend full support to these claims. For example, there are imbalances and inconsistencies related to returns to investment in HE. Psacharopoulos (1994), for example, identifies such imbalances and inconsistencies in areas of gender, degrees, and subjects studied, and levels of qualifications obtained among others. In addition, the employment market does not always behave in a fair way. For example, although there is some evidence which shows that those with higher qualifications and those who have spent more years in education tend to accumulate higher earnings across the life course, there is much less evidence which shows that investing in a highly priced degree program offers higher financial returns to the graduates. Financial returns in the professions are more closely related to the reputation of the university attended. For the same job, a Harvard graduate is likely to start off at a higher salary than one from a less well known university. In addition, graduates from community colleges in the USA tend to have limited career entry opportunities compared to their counterparts from the more reputable 4-year degree offering institutions. Community college graduates also tend to earn lower aggregate salaries over the life course compared to graduates from other more prestigious universities (see, e.g., Nagler, 2007). Others have concluded that institutions in the lower ranks of prestige and reputation in HE markets only serve to reproduce social and economic inequalities in the society (e.g., Brint and karabel, 1989; Dougherty, 1994; Karabel, 1986; Weis, 1985). View chapterExplore book The Political Economy of Adult Education G. Rees, in International Encyclopedia of Education (Third Edition), 2010 Human Capital in the KBE Theories of the KBE adapt HCT to what are construed as the essential characteristics of contemporary economic life. On this view, the globalization of trade and investment has intensified competitive pressures, especially for those national economies which are unable to compete on the basis of low-cost production. In these economies, competitiveness can be maintained only by enhancing the productivity of capital and labor. This implies continuous innovation, developing new goods and services and more effective processes for producing, marketing and distributing them, and applying the most efficient patterns of work organization. Hence, the creation and – critically – the application in production of new forms of knowledge become the key factor in shaping the prosperity of individual enterprises and economic development more widely. This valorization of knowledge production and innovation also has critical implications for the operation of labor markets. The KBE offers expanding opportunities for the so-called knowledge workers who have the very high-level skills required to operate in professional, managerial, scientific, and creative jobs in the upper echelons of the new occupational hierarchy. Equally, even workers who do not attain the very highest occupational levels require, at a minimum, high-quality general education and cutting-edge intermediate skills, so that they can engage actively in driving up productivity. However, the corollary of these new occupational opportunities is the sharp decrease in unskilled or partly skilled occupations, which formerly comprised significant segments of the workforce. Some of these occupations have been relocated to the low-cost economies, reflecting patterns of globalization more widely. Others have simply disappeared because of changes in the industrial structure and transformations in product and process technologies. The implication is, therefore, that, in the KBE, employment opportunities for those individuals who do not have significant amounts of human capital are bleak. Education and Inequality* J. Blanden, S. Machin, in International Encyclopedia of Education (Third Edition), 2010 Causality The empirical study of education-related earnings differentials was developed in tandem with human capital theory (see inter alia Becker, 1964); the idea is that educational attainment has a casual impact on labor market outcomes through improved productivity. Of course, the fact that more educated workers tend be more productive does not prove that education is the cause of their higher productivity. Indeed, many commentators have noted that interpretation of positive earnings differentials for the more educated as a causal impact of education may not be correct due to differential selection into HE by more able individuals and those from higher-income families. As such, it may be that higher-ability/income people select into education more so that the positive coefficient on education in a wage equation is actually upward biased. The existence of ability bias of this form has been studied in detail, from the highly influential work of Griliches (1977) onward, and confirmed in research since. Empirically, it is the case that the education coefficient falls once ability proxies are included (this is because ability is positively correlated with both earnings and education). Conversely, one may think that the education variable included in the earnings function may not be measured perfectly. This causes a downward bias in the estimated coefficient of education variables in earnings equations. Card (1999, 2001) considers the impact of ability bias and measurement error on estimated returns to education. In particular, Card carefully considers the interpretation of instrumental variables estimates, which are designed to purge endogeneity and measurement error bias. In the recent literature addressing these issues, a number of what Card (2001) refers to as supply-side instruments are used to identify the causal impact of education, where researchers try and ensure that variations in education are driven by factors that do not directly impact on wages. Estimated returns from this approach are above the basic uncorrected differentials. (Examples are changes in compulsory school leaving laws and differences in the accessibility of schools. Formally, these enter an education equation, but not the earnings equation, and so their impact on earnings is assumed to operate only through education acquisition.) Table 4 summarizes some of the key papers in the field that identify the causal impacts. Moreover, differences between the basic and causal returns are of similar magnitudes for the studies considered in this table (they, of course, differ across studies owing to different data, different countries, and so on). Hence, there is robust cross-country evidence that the more educated get higher monetary rewards in the labor market