Investments The McGraw Hill Series in Finance, Insurance, and Real Estate Financial Management Block, Hirt, and Danielsen Foundations of Financial Management Eighteenth Edition Brealey, Myers, and Allen Principles of Corporate Finance, Concise Second Edition Brealey, Myers, Allen, and Edmans Principles of Corporate Finance Fourteenth Edition Ross, Westerfield, Jaffe, and Jordan Corporate Finance: Core Principles and Applications Sixth Edition Saunders and Cornett Financial Institutions Management: A Risk Management Approach Tenth Edition Ross, Westerfield, and Jordan Essentials of Corporate Finance Eleventh Edition Saunders and Cornett Financial Markets and Institutions Eighth Edition Ross, Westerfield, and Jordan Fundamentals of Corporate Finance Thirteenth Edition Brealey, Myers, and Marcus Fundamentals of Corporate Finance Eleventh Edition Shefrin Behavioral Corporate Finance: Decisions That Create Value Second Edition Brooks FinGame Online 5.0 Investments Bruner Case Studies in Finance: Managing for Corporate Value Creation Eighth Edition Cornett, Adair, and Nofsinger Finance: Applications and Theory Sixth Edition Cornett, Adair, and Nofsinger M: Finance Fifth Edition DeMello Cases in Finance Third Edition Grinblatt (editor) Stephen A. Ross, Mentor: Influence through Generations Grinblatt and Titman Financial Markets and Corporate Strategy Second Edition Bodie, Kane, and Marcus Essentials of Investments Twelfth Edition Bodie, Kane, and Marcus Investments Thirteenth Edition Hirt and Block Fundamentals of Investment Management Tenth Edition Jordan and Miller Fundamentals of Investments: Valuation and Management Ninth Edition Stewart, Piros, and Heisler Running Money: Professional Portfolio Management Sundaram and Das Derivatives: Principles and Practice Second Edition Financial Institutions and Markets Higgins Analysis for Financial Management Thirteenth Edition Rose and Hudgins Bank Management and Financial Services Ninth Edition Ross, Westerfield, Jaffe, and Jordan Corporate Finance Thirteenth Edition Rose and Marquis Financial Institutions and Markets Eleventh Edition International Finance Eun and Resnick International Financial Management Ninth Edition Real Estate Brueggeman and Fisher Real Estate Finance and Investments Seventeenth Edition Ling and Archer Real Estate Principles: A Value Approach Sixth Edition Financial Planning and Insurance Allen, Melone, Rosenbloom, and Mahoney Retirement Plans: 401(k)s, IRAs, and Other Deferred Compensation Approaches Thirteenth Edition Altfest Personal Financial Planning Second Edition Kapoor, Dlabay, and Hughes Focus on Personal Finance: An Active Approach to Help You Develop Successful Financial Skills Seventh Edition Kapoor, Dlabay, and Hughes Personal Finance Fourteenth Edition Walker and Walker Personal Finance: Building Your Future Second Edition Investments T H I R T E E N T H E D I T I O N ZVI BODIE Boston University ALEX KANE University of California, San Diego ALAN J. MARCUS Boston College Final PDF to printer INVESTMENTS, THIRTEENTH EDITION Published by McGraw Hill LLC, 1325 Avenue of the Americas, New York, NY 10019. Copyright ©2024 by McGraw Hill LLC. All rights reserved. Printed in the United States of America. Previous editions ©2021, 2018, and 2014. No part of this publication may be reproduced or distributed in any form or by any means, or stored in a database or retrieval system, without the prior written consent of McGraw Hill LLC, including, but not limited to, in any network or other electronic storage or transmission, or broadcast for distance learning. Some ancillaries, including electronic and print components, may not be available to customers outside the United States. This book is printed on acid-free paper. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 LWI 28 27 26 25 24 23 ISBN 978-1-264-41266-2 (bound edition) MHID 1-264-41266-5 (bound edition) ISBN 978-1-266-83638-1 (loose-leaf edition) MHID 1-266-83638-1 (loose-leaf edition) Portfolio Manager: Tim Vertovec Product Developer: Allison McCabe-Carroll Marketing Manager: Sarah Hurley Content Project Managers: Jeni McAtee, Jamie Koch Manufacturing Project Manager: Laura Fuller Content Licensing Specialist: Traci Vaske Cover Image: double A/Shutterstock Compositor: Straive All credits appearing on page or at the end of the book are considered to be an extension of the copyright page. Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Names: Bodie, Zvi, author. | Kane, Alex, 1942- author. | Marcus, Alan J., author. Title: Investments / Zvi Bodie, Boson University, Alex Kane, University of California, San Diego, Alan J. Marcus, Boston College. Description: Thirteenth edition. | New York, NY : McGraw Hill LLC, [2024] | Includes index. Identifiers: LCCN 2022048517 (print) | LCCN 2022048518 (ebook) | ISBN 9781264412662 (hardcover) | ISBN 9781266837227 (ebook) Subjects: LCSH: Investments. | Portfolio management. Classification: LCC HG4521 .B564 2024 (print) | LCC HG4521 (ebook) | DDC 332.6—dc23/eng/20221024 LC record available at https://lccn.loc.gov/2022048517 LC ebook record available at https://lccn.loc.gov/2022048518 The Internet addresses listed in the text were accurate at the time of publication. The inclusion of a website does not indicate an endorsement by the authors or McGraw Hill LLC, and McGraw Hill LLC does not guarantee the accuracy of the information presented at these sites. mheducation.com/highered bod12665_fm_i-xxviii.indd iv 10/26/22 04:10 PM About the Authors ZVI BODIE Boston University Zvi Bodie is Professor ­Emeritus at Boston University. He holds a PhD from the ­Massachusetts Institute of Technology and has served on the finance faculty at the Harvard Business School and MIT’s Sloan School of ­Management. He has ­published widely in scholarly and professional journals on pension investment strategy and life-cycle asset-liability matching. In 2007 the ­Retirement Income Industry Association gave him its ­Lifetime Achievement Award for applied research. ALEX KANE University of California, San Diego Alex Kane holds a PhD from the Stern School of Business of New York University and has been Visiting ­Professor at the Faculty of Economics, University of Tokyo; Graduate School of Business, Harvard; Kennedy School of Government, Harvard; and Research Associate, National Bureau of Economic Research. An author of many articles in finance and management ­journals, Professor Kane’s research is mainly in corporate finance, portfolio management, and capital markets. ALAN J. MARCUS Boston College Alan Marcus is the Mario J. Gabelli Professor of Finance in the Carroll School of Management at Boston ­College. He received his PhD in economics from MIT. Professor Marcus has been a visiting professor at the Athens Laboratory of Business Administration and at MIT’s Sloan School of Management and has served as a research associate at the National Bureau of Economic Research. Professor Marcus has published widely in the fields of capital markets and portfolio management. He also spent two years at the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation (Freddie Mac), where he developed models of mortgage pricing and credit risk. He currently serves on the Research Foundation Advisory Board of the CFA Institute. Special Contributor Nicholas Racculia, Saint Vincent College Nicholas Racculia holds a PhD from Princeton University and serves as Professor of Finance at St. Vincent ­College. Professor Racculia teaches a wide range of classes in Corporate Finance and Investments. He has ­significantly participated in the expansion of Chapter 26 on Alternative Assets. His contributions also play a key role in the development of online content for the text. v Brief Contents Preface xvi PART III Equilibrium in Capital Markets 283 PART I Introduction 1 9 1 The Investment Environment The Capital Asset Pricing Model 1 10 2 Asset Classes and Financial Instruments 3 How Securities Are Traded Arbitrage Pricing Theory and Multifactor Models of Risk and Return 315 31 11 61 The Efficient Market Hypothesis 4 Behavioral Finance and Technical Analysis 381 13 PART II Empirical Evidence on Security Returns Portfolio Theory and Practice 125 5 Risk, Return, and the Historical Record 6 Capital Allocation to Risky Assets 7 Efficient Diversification Index Models 341 12 Mutual Funds and Other Investment Companies 99 8 283 409 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities 439 125 14 Bond Prices and Yields 167 439 15 The Term Structure of Interest Rates 201 16 Managing Bond Portfolios 251 vi 509 481 Brief Contents PART V PART VII Security Analysis 551 Applied Portfolio Management 827 17 Macroeconomic and Industry Analysis 18 551 24 Portfolio Performance Evaluation Equity Valuation Models 583 19 Financial Statement Analysis 25 International Diversification 629 26 Alternative Assets The Theory of Active Portfolio Management 935 Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives 673 20 Options Markets: Introduction 21 Option Valuation 715 Futures Markets 763 22 23 28 Investment Policy and the Framework of the CFA Institute 959 673 Futures, Swaps, and Risk Management 867 895 27 PART VI 827 REFERENCES TO CFA PROBLEMS 995 GLOSSARY G-1 NAME INDEX I SUBJECT INDEX I-4 791 NOTATION, FORMULAS F-1 vii Contents Preface xvi Chapter 2 Asset Classes and Financial Instruments PART I Introduction 2.1 1 The Investment Environment 1 Real Assets versus Financial Assets 1.2 Financial Assets 3 1.3 Financial Markets and the Economy 2 2.2 The Investment Process 1.5 Markets Are Competitive 2.3 The Players 10 11 2.4 2.5 54 End of Chapter Material The Financial Crisis of 2008–2009 19 56–60 Chapter 3 Antecedents of the Crisis / Changes in Housing Finance / Mortgage Derivatives / Credit Default Swaps / The Rise of Systemic Risk / The Shoe Drops / The Dodd–Frank Reform Act How Securities Are Traded 61 3.1 How Firms Issue Securities 61 Privately Held Firms / Publicly Traded Companies / Shelf Registration / Initial Public Offerings / SPACs versus ­Traditional IPOs Outline of the Text 27 End of Chapter Material Derivative Markets Options / Futures Contracts Robo Advice / Blockchains / Cryptocurrencies / Digital Tokens / Digital Currency 1.8 Stock and Bond Market Indexes 47 Stock Market Indexes / Dow Jones Industrial Average / The Standard & Poor’s 500 Index / Russell Indexes / Other U.S. Market-Value Indexes / Equally Weighted Indexes / Foreign and International Stock Market Indexes / Bond Market Indicators 13 Financial Intermediaries / Investment Bankers / Venture Capital and Private Equity / Fintech, Financial Innovation, and Decentralized Finance 1.7 Equity Securities 44 Common Stock as Ownership Shares / Characteristics of Common Stock / Stock Market Listings / Preferred Stock / Depositary Receipts The Risk–Return Trade-Off / Efficient Markets 1.6 The Bond Market 37 Treasury Notes and Bonds / Inflation-Protected Treasury Bonds / Federal Agency Debt / International Bonds / Municipal Bonds / Corporate Bonds / Mortgage and Asset-Backed Securities 5 The Informational Role of Financial Markets / Consumption Timing / Allocation of Risk / Separation of Ownership and Management / Corporate Governance and Corporate Ethics 1.4 The Money Market 31 Treasury Bills / Certificates of Deposit / Commercial Paper / Bankers’ Acceptances / Eurodollars / Repos and Reverses / Federal Funds / Brokers’ Calls / LIBOR and Its Replacements / Yields on Money Market Instruments / Money Market Funds Chapter 1 1.1 31 27–30 viii Contents 3.2 How Securities Are Traded 67 4.6 Exchange-Traded Funds 112 4.7Mutual Fund Investment Performance: A First Look 115 Types of Markets Direct Search Markets / Brokered Markets / Dealer ­Markets / Auction Markets 4.8 Information on Mutual Funds End of Chapter Material Types of Orders 116 119–124 Market Orders / Price-Contingent Orders PART II Trading Mechanisms Portfolio Theory and Practice 125 Dealer Markets / Electronic Communication Networks (ECNs) / Specialist/DMM Markets 3.3 The Rise of Electronic Trading 3.4 U.S. Markets 72 74 Chapter 5 NASDAQ / The New York Stock Exchange / ECNs 3.5 New Trading Strategies Risk, Return, and the Historical Record 125 76 Algorithmic Trading / High-Frequency Trading / Dark Pools / Internalization / Bond Trading 3.6 Globalization of Stock Markets 3.7 Trading Costs 3.8 Buying on Margin 3.9 Short Sales 5.1Measuring Returns over Different Holding Periods 126 Annual Percentage Rates / Continuous Compounding 5.2 Interest Rates and Inflation Rates 129 Real and Nominal Rates of Interest / The Equilibrium Real Rate of Interest / Interest Rates and Inflation / Taxes and the Real Rate of Interest / Treasury Bills and Inflation, 1926–2021 5.3 Risk and Risk Premiums 133 Holding-Period Returns / Expected Return and Standard Deviation / Excess Returns and Risk Premiums / The Reward-to-Volatility (Sharpe) Ratio 5.4 The Normal Distribution 137 5.5 Deviations from Normality and Tail Risk 140 Value at Risk / Expected Shortfall / Lower Partial Standard Deviation and the Sortino Ratio / Relative Frequency of Large, Negative 3-Sigma Returns 5.6 Learning from Historical Returns 143 Time Series versus Scenario Analysis / Expected Returns and the Arithmetic Average / The Geometric (TimeWeighted) Average Return / Estimating Variance and Standard Deviation / Mean and Standard Deviation Estimates from Higher-Frequency Observations 5.7 Historic Returns on Risky Portfolios 147 A Global View of the Historical Record 5.8 Normality and Long-Term Investments 156 Short-Run versus Long-Run Risk / Forecasts for the Long Haul End of Chapter Material 160–166 80 81 82 85 3.10 Regulation of Securities Markets 89 Self-Regulation / The Sarbanes-Oxley Act / Insider Trading End of Chapter Material 93–98 Chapter 4 Mutual Funds and Other Investment Companies 99 4.1 Investment Companies 4.2 Types of Investment Companies 99 100 Unit Investment Trusts / Managed Investment Companies / Exchange-Traded Funds / Other Investment Organizations Commingled Funds / Real Estate Investment Trusts (REITs) / Hedge Funds 4.3 Mutual Funds 104 Investment Policies Money Market Funds / Equity Funds / Sector Funds / Bond Funds / International Funds / Balanced Funds / Asset Allocation and Flexible Funds / Index Funds How Funds Are Sold 4.4 Costs of Investing in Mutual Funds 107 Chapter 6 Fee Structure Capital Allocation to Risky Assets Operating Expenses / Front-End Load / Back-End Load / 12b-1 Charges 6.1 Fees and Mutual Fund Returns 4.5 Taxation of Mutual Fund Income 167 Risk and Risk Aversion 168 Risk, Speculation, and Gambling / Risk Aversion and Utility Values / Estimating Risk Aversion 111 ix Contents 6.2Capital Allocation across Risky and Risk-Free Portfolios 173 6.3 8.5Portfolio Construction Using the Single-Index Model 268 The Risk-Free Asset 176 Alpha and Security Analysis / The Index Portfolio as an Investment Asset / The Single-Index Model Input List / The Optimal Risky Portfolio in the Single-Index Model / The Information Ratio / Summary of Optimization Procedure / An Example / Correlation and Covariance Matrix 6.4Portfolios of One Risky Asset and a Risk-Free Asset 176 6.5 Risk Tolerance and Asset Allocation 179 Non-normal Returns 6.6 Passive Strategies: The Capital Market Line 185 End of Chapter Material Risk Premium Forecasts / The Optimal Risky Portfolio / Is the Index Model Inferior to the Full-Covariance Model? 187–195 Appendix A: Risk Aversion, Expected Utility, and the St. Petersburg Paradox 196 End of Chapter Material Chapter 7 PART III Efficient Diversification 201 7.1 Diversification and Portfolio Risk 202 7.2 Portfolios of Two Risky Assets 203 7.3 Asset Allocation with Stocks, Bonds, and Bills 211 7.4 The Markowitz Portfolio Optimization Model 216 Equilibrium in Capital Markets 283 Chapter 9 Asset Allocation with Two Risky Asset Classes The Capital Asset Pricing Model 283 Security Selection / Capital Allocation and the Separation Property / The Power of Diversification / Asset Allocation and Security Selection 9.1 Risk Sharing versus Risk Pooling / Time Diversification 9.2 228–238 Appendix B: Review of Portfolio Statistics 243 9.3 Chapter 8 8.1 9.4 251 A Single-Factor Security Market The Single-Index Model 252 Issues in Testing the CAPM 304 The CAPM and the Investment Industry 305 306–314 Arbitrage Pricing Theory and Multifactor Models of Risk and Return 315 254 10.1 Multifactor Models: A Preview 316 Factor Models of Security Returns 10.2 Arbitrage Pricing Theory Estimating the Single-Index Model 261 318 Arbitrage, Risk Arbitrage, and Equilibrium / Diversification in a Single-Factor Security Market / Well-Diversified Portfolios / The Security Market Line of the APT The Security Characteristic Line for U.S. Steel / The Explanatory Power of U.S. Steel’s SCL / The Estimate of Alpha / The Estimate of Beta / Firm-Specific Risk Individual Assets and the APT Well-Diversified Portfolios in Practice Typical Results from Index Model Regressions 8.4 294 Chapter 10 The Regression Equation of the Single-Index Model / The Expected Return–Beta Relationship / Risk and Covariance in the Single-Index Model / The Set of Estimates Needed for the Single-Index Model / The Index Model and Diversification 8.3 Assumptions and Extensions of the CAPM End of Chapter Material The Input List of the Markowitz Model / Systematic versus Firm-Specific Risk 8.2 283 Identical Input Lists / Risk-Free Borrowing and the Zero-Beta Model / Labor Income and Other Nontraded Assets / A Multiperiod Model and Hedge Portfolios / A Consumption-Based CAPM / Liquidity and the CAPM Appendix A: A Spreadsheet Model for Efficient Diversification 238 Index Models The Capital Asset Pricing Model The Market Portfolio / The Passive Strategy Is Efficient / The Risk Premium of the Market Portfolio / Expected Returns on Individual Securities / The Security Market Line / The CAPM and the Single-Index Market 7.5Risk Pooling, Risk Sharing, and Time Diversification 225 End of Chapter Material 277–282 The Industry Version of the Index Model 265 10.3 The APT and the CAPM 326 Predicting Betas 10.4 A Multifactor APT x 326 Contents 10.5 The Fama-French (FF) Three-Factor Model 329 Limits to Arbitrage Estimating and Implementing a Three-Factor SML / Extensions of the Three-Factor Model: A First Look / Smart Betas and Multifactor Models End of Chapter Material Fundamental Risk / Implementation Costs / Model Risk Limits to Arbitrage and the Law of One Price “Siamese Twin” Companies / Equity Carve-Outs / Closed-End Funds 334–340 Bubbles and Behavioral Economics / Evaluating the Behavioral Critique Chapter 11 The Efficient Market Hypothesis 341 12.2 Technical Analysis and Behavioral Finance 394 11.1 Random Walks and Efficient Markets 342 Trends and Corrections Competition as the Source of Efficiency / Versions of the Efficient Market Hypothesis 11.2 Implications of the EMH Momentum and Moving Averages / Relative Strength / Breadth 346 Machine Leaning and Technical Analysis / Sentiment Indicators Technical Analysis / Fundamental Analysis / Active versus Passive Portfolio Management / The Role of Portfolio Management in an Efficient Market / Resource Allocation 11.3 Event Studies Trin Statistic / Confidence Index / Short Interest / Put/ Call Ratio 351 11.4 Are Markets Efficient? A Warning 354 End of Chapter Material The Issues 401–408 Chapter 13 The Magnitude Issue / The Selection Bias Issue / The Lucky Event Issue Empirical Evidence on Security Returns 409 Weak-Form Tests: Patterns in Stock Returns 13.1 Two-Pass Tests of Asset Pricing Returns over Short Horizons / Returns over Long Horizons 410 Testing the Single-Factor SML Predictors of Broad Market Returns / Semistrong Tests: Market Anomalies Setting Up the Sample Data / Estimating the SCL / Estimating the SML The Small-Firm Effect / The Neglected-Firm and Liquidity Effects / Book-to-Market Ratios / Post– Earnings-Announcement Price Drift / Other Predictors of Stock Returns 13.2 Tests of the Multifactor Models Strong-Form Tests: Inside Information / Interpreting the Anomalies 13.3 Fama-French-Type Factor Models The Market Index / Measurement Error in Beta 13.4 Liquidity and Asset Pricing 427 Bubbles and Market Efficiency 13.5 The Equity Premium Puzzle 11.5 Mutual Fund and Analyst Performance 368 429 Expected versus Realized Returns / Survivorship Bias / Extensions to the CAPM May Mitigate the Equity Premium Puzzle / Liquidity and the Equity Premium Puzzle / Behavioral Explanations of the Equity Premium Puzzle Stock Market Analysts / Mutual Fund Managers / So, Are Markets Efficient? 374–380 Chapter 12 End of Chapter Material Behavioral Finance and Technical Analysis 381 12.1 The Behavioral Critique 419 Size and B/M as Risk Factors / Behavioral Explanations / Momentum: A Fourth Factor / The Factor Zoo Risk Premiums or Inefficiencies? / Anomalies or Data Mining? / Anomalies over Time End of Chapter Material 415 Labor Income / Private (Nontraded) Business / Macroeconomic Risk Factors 435–438 PART IV Fixed-Income Securities 439 382 Information Processing Chapter 14 Limited Attention, Underreaction, and Overreaction / Overconfidence / Conservatism / Confirmation Bias / Extrapolation and Pattern Recognition Bond Prices and Yields 14.1 Bond Characteristics Behavioral Biases 439 440 Treasury Bonds and Notes Framing / Mental Accounting / Regret Avoidance / Affect and Feelings / Prospect Theory Accrued Interest and Quoted Bond Prices xi Contents 16.2 Convexity Corporate Bonds Call Provisions on Corporate Bonds / Convertible Bonds / Puttable Bonds / Floating-Rate Bonds Preferred Stock / Other Domestic Issuers / International Bonds / Innovation in the Bond Market 16.3 Passive Bond Management 527 Maturity / Inverse Floaters / Asset-Backed Bonds / Catastrophe Bonds / Indexed Bonds 14.2 Bond Pricing Bond-Index Funds / Immunization / Cash Flow Matching and Dedication / Other Problems with Conventional Immunization 446 16.4 Active Bond Management Bond Pricing between Coupon Dates 14.3 Bond Yields 536 Sources of Potential Profit / Horizon Analysis 451 End of Chapter Material Yield to Maturity / Yield to Call / Realized Compound Return versus Yield to Maturity 14.4 Bond Prices over Time 14.5 Default Risk and Bond Pricing Security Analysis 551 463 Chapter 17 Junk Bonds / Determinants of Bond Safety / Bond Indentures Macroeconomic and Industry Analysis Sinking Funds / Subordination of Further Debt / ­Dividend Restrictions / Collateral 17.1 The Global Economy 551 551 17.2 The Domestic Macroeconomy Yield to Maturity and Default Risk / Credit Default Swaps / Credit Risk and Collateralized Debt Obligations End of Chapter Material 539–550 PART V 458 Yield to Maturity versus Holding-Period Return / ZeroCoupon Bonds and Treasury Strips / After-Tax Returns 554 Key Economic Indicators Gross Domestic Product / Employment / Inflation / Interest Rates / Budget Deficit / Sentiment 474–480 Chapter 15 17.3 Demand and Supply Shocks 556 17.4 Federal Government Policy 557 Fiscal Policy / Monetary Policy / Supply-Side Policies The Term Structure of Interest Rates 481 15.1 The Yield Curve 519 Why Do Investors Like Convexity? / Duration and Convexity of Callable Bonds / Duration and Convexity of Mortgage-Backed Securities 17.5 Business Cycles 560 481 The Business Cycle / Economic Indicators Bond Pricing 15.2 The Yield Curve and Future Interest Rates 17.6 Industry Analysis 564 484 Defining an Industry / Sensitivity to the Business Cycle / Sector Rotation / Industry Life Cycles The Yield Curve under Certainty / Holding-Period Returns / Forward Rates 15.3 Interest Rate Uncertainty and Forward Rates 489 Start-Up Stage / Consolidation Stage / Maturity Stage / Relative Decline 15.4 Theories of the Term Structure Industry Structure and Performance 491 The Expectations Hypothesis / Liquidity Preference Theory / Market Segmentation 15.5 Interpreting the Term Structure 495 Threat of Entry / Rivalry between Existing Competitors / Pressure from Substitute Products / Bargaining Power of Buyers / Bargaining Power of Suppliers 15.6 Forward Rates as Forward Contracts 498 End of Chapter Material End of Chapter Material 500–508 Chapter 18 Equity Valuation Models Chapter 16 Managing Bond Portfolios 509 16.1 Interest Rate Risk 574–582 18.1 Valuation by Comparables 583 583 Limitations of Book Value 510 18.2 Intrinsic Value versus Market Price 585 Interest Rate Sensitivity / Duration / What Determines Duration? 18.3 Dividend Discount Models Rule 1 for Duration / Rule 2 for Duration / Rule 3 for Duration / Rule 4 for Duration / Rule 5 for Duration 587 The Constant-Growth DDM / Convergence of Price to Intrinsic Value / Stock Prices and Investment xii Contents Opportunities / Life Cycles and Multistage Growth Models / Multistage Growth Models 18.4 The Price–Earnings Ratio 601 The Price–Earnings Ratio and Growth Opportunities / P/E Ratios and Stock Risk / Pitfalls in P/E Analysis / The Cyclically Adjusted P/E Ratio / Combining P/E Analysis and the DDM / Other Comparative Valuation Ratios Price-to-Book Ratio / Price-to-Cash-Flow Ratio / Price-to-Sales Ratio / Be Creative 18.5 Free Cash Flow Valuation Approaches 611 Comparing the Valuation Models / The Problem with DCF Models 18.6 The Aggregate Stock Market 615 End of Chapter Material 617–628 The Options Clearing Corporation / Other Listed Options Index Options / Futures Options / Foreign Currency Options / Interest Rate Options 20.2 Values of Options at Expiration 20.3 Option Strategies 20.4 The Put-Call Parity Relationship 20.5 Option-like Securities 691 694 Callable Bonds / Convertible Securities / Warrants / Collateralized Loans / Levered Equity and Risky Debt 20.6 Financial Engineering 700 Financial Statement Analysis 629 20.7 Exotic Options 19.1 The Major Financial Statements 629 The Income Statement / The Balance Sheet / The Statement of Cash Flows 19.2 Measuring Firm Performance 634 19.3 Profitability Measures 635 Return on Assets, ROA / Return on Capital, ROC / Return on Equity, ROE / Financial Leverage and ROE / Economic Value Added 19.4 Ratio Analysis 639 Decomposition of ROE / Turnover and Other Asset Utilization Ratios / Liquidity Ratios / Market Price Ratios: Growth versus Value / Choosing a Benchmark 19.5 An Illustration of Financial Statement Analysis 650 19.6 Comparability Problems 652 Inventor y Valuation / Depreciation / Inflation and Interest Expense / Fair Value Accounting / Quality of Earnings and Accounting Practices / International Accounting Conventions 19.7 Value Investing: The Graham Technique 658 702 Asian Options / Barrier Options / Lookback Options / Currency-Translated Options / Digital Options End of Chapter Material 703–714 Chapter 21 Option Valuation 21.1 Option Valuation: Introduction 715 715 Intrinsic and Time Values / Determinants of Option Values 21.2 Restrictions on Option Values 719 Restrictions on the Value of a Call Option / Early Exercise and Dividends / Early Exercise of American Puts 21.3 Binomial Option Pricing 722 Two-State Option Pricing / Generalizing the Two-State Approach / Making the Valuation Model Practical 659–672 21.4 Black-Scholes Option Valuation 730 The Black-Scholes Formula / Implied Volatility / Dividends and Call Option Valuation / Put Option Valuation / Dividends and Put Option Valuation PART VI Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives 673 21.5 Using the Black-Scholes Formula 738 Hedge Ratios and the Black-Scholes Formula / Portfolio Insurance / Option Pricing and the Financial Crisis / Option Pricing and Portfolio Theory / Hedging Bets on Mispriced Options Chapter 20 Options Markets: Introduction 673 20.1 The Option Contract 683 Protective Put / Covered Calls / Straddle / Spreads / Collars Chapter 19 End of Chapter Material 679 Call Options / Put Options / Option versus Stock Investments 673 21.6 Empirical Evidence on Option Pricing 750 Options Trading / American versus European Options / Adjustments in Option Contract Terms / End of Chapter Material xiii 751–762 Contents Chapter 22 Risk-Adjusted Performance Measures / The Sharpe Ratio for Overall Portfolios Futures Markets 763 The M2 Measure and the Sharpe Ratio 22.1 The Futures Contract 763 The Basics of Futures Contracts / Existing Contracts 22.2 Trading Mechanics 769 The Clearinghouse and Open Interest / The Margin Account and Marking to Market / The Convergence Property / Cash versus Actual Delivery / Regulations / Taxation 22.3 Futures Markets Strategies 773 Hedging and Speculation / Basis Risk and Hedging 22.4 Futures Prices 777 The Spot-Futures Parity Theorem / Spreads / Forward versus Futures Pricing 22.5 Futures Prices versus Expected Spot Prices 784 Expectations Hypothesis / Normal Backwardation / Contango / Modern Portfolio Theory End of Chapter Material 786–790 The Treynor Ratio / The Information Ratio / The Role of Alpha in Performance Measures / Implementing Performance Measurement: An Example / Realized Returns versus Expected Returns / Selection Bias and Portfolio Evaluation 24.2 Style Analysis 839 24.3Performance Measurement with Changing Portfolio Composition 841 Performance Manipulation and the Morningstar RiskAdjusted Rating 24.4 Market Timing 845 The Potential Value of Market Timing / Valuing Market Timing as a Call Option / The Value of Imperfect Forecasting 24.5 Performance Attribution Procedures Chapter 23 850 Asset Allocation Decisions / Sector and Security Selection Decisions / Summing Up Component Contributions Futures, Swaps, and Risk Management 791 End of Chapter Material 23.1 Foreign Exchange Futures 791 The Markets / Interest Rate Parity / Direct versus Indirect Quotes / Using Futures to Manage Exchange Rate Risk 23.2 Stock-Index Futures 799 The Contracts / Creating Synthetic Stock Positions: An Asset Allocation Tool / Index Arbitrage / Using Index Futures to Hedge Market Risk 23.3 Interest Rate Futures 804 Hedging Interest Rate Risk 23.4 Swaps 806 Swaps and Balance Sheet Restructuring / The Swap Dealer / Other Interest Rate Contracts / Swap Pricing / Credit Risk in the Swap Market / Credit Default Swaps 23.5 Commodity Futures Pricing 813 Pricing with Storage Costs / Discounted Cash Flow Analysis for Commodity Futures End of Chapter Material 817–826 855–866 Chapter 25 International Diversification 867 25.1 Global Markets for Equities 867 Developed Countries / Emerging Markets / Market Capitalization and GDP / Home-Country Bias 25.2Exchange Rate Risk and International Diversification 871 Exchange Rate Risk / Investment Risk in International Markets / International Diversification / Are Benefits from International Diversification Preserved in Bear Markets? 25.3 Political Risk 882 25.4International Investing and Performance Attribution 885 Constructing a Benchmark Portfolio of Foreign Assets / Performance Attribution PART VII End of Chapter Material Applied Portfolio Management 827 889–894 Chapter 26 Alternative Assets 895 26.1 Alternative Assets 896 Chapter 24 The Alternative Asset Universe Portfolio Performance Evaluation 827 Hedge Funds / Private Equity / Real Assets / Structured Products 24.1The Conventional Theory of Performance Evaluation 827 Alternative Assets versus Traditional Assets Average Rates of Return / Time-Weighted Returns versus Dollar-Weighted Returns / Adjusting Returns for Risk / Transparency / Investors / Investment Strategies / Liquidity / Investment Horizon / Fee Structure xiv Contents 27.4Treynor-Black versus Black-Litterman: Complements, Not Substitutes 951 Role of Alternative Assets in Diversified Portfolios / Growth of Alternative Assets 26.2 Hedge Funds 900 The BL Model as Icing on the TB Cake / Why Not Replace the Entire TB Cake with the BL Icing? Hedge Fund Strategies / Statistical Arbitrage / HighFrequency Strategies / 27.5 The Value of Active Management Electronic News Feeds / Cross-Market Arbitrage / Electronic Market Making / Electronic “Front Running” Portable Alpha 26.3 Venture Capital and Angel Investors 27.6 Concluding Remarks on Active Management 905 End of Chapter Material Angel Investors / Venture Capital / Venture Capital and Investment Stages / Fund Life Cycle / Private Equity Valuation / Venture Syndication / Venture Capital and Innovation 26.4 Leveraged Buyout Funds Appendix B: The General Black-Litterman Model 957 Chapter 28 913 Investment Policy and the Framework of the CFA Institute 959 26.5Performance Measurement for Alternative Investment Funds 916 28.1 The Investment Management Process 960 28.2 Investor Objectives 962 Liquidity and Performance Individual Investors Liquidity and Hedge Fund Performance / Liquidity and Private Equity Personal Trusts / Mutual Funds / Pension Funds / Endowment Funds / Life Insurance Companies / Non–Life Insurance Companies / Banks Survivorship Bias and Backfill Bias / Tail Events / Historical Hedge Fund Performance / Style Analysis / Historical Performance of Private Equity 28.3 Investor Constraints 966 Liquidity / Investment Horizon / Regulations / Tax Considerations / Unique Needs Grandstanding / Industry Specialization Efficient Frontier 26.6 Fee Structure in Alternative Investments 28.4 Policy Statements 926 28.5 Asset Allocation 973 Top-Down Asset Allocation for Institutional Investors / Monitoring and Revising the Portfolio 928–934 28.6 Managing Portfolios of Individual Investors 975 Chapter 27 Investment in Residence / Saving for Retirement and the Assumption of Risk / Retirement Planning Models / Target Date Funds / Tax Sheltering and Asset Allocation The Theory of Active Portfolio Management 935 The Tax-Deferral Option / Tax-Protected Retirement Plans / Deferred Annuities / Variable and Universal Life Insurance 935 Forecasts of Alpha Values and Extreme Portfolio Weights / Restriction of Tracking Risk 28.7 Pension Funds 981 27.2The Treynor-Black Model and Forecast Precision 942 Defined Contribution Plans / Defined Benefit Plans / Pension Investment Strategies Adjusting Forecasts for the Precision of Alpha / Distribution of Alpha Values / Organizational Structure and Performance 27.3 The Black-Litterman Model 969 Sample Policy Statements for Individual Investors Incentive Fees / Private Equity Chasing Waterfalls / Funds of Funds 27.1 Optimal Portfolios and Alpha Values 955 955–956 Appendix A: Forecasts and Realizations of Alpha 956 Leveraged Buyout Firm Structure / The Deal / Exits / Leveraged Buyouts and Innovation End of Chapter Material 953 A Model for the Estimation of Potential Fees / Results from the Distribution of Actual Information Ratios / Results from Distribution of Actual Forecasts Investing in Equities End of Chapter Material 984–994 946 Black-Litterman Asset Allocation Decision / Step 1: The Covariance Matrix from Historical Data / Step 2: Determination of a Baseline Forecast / Step 3: Integrating the Manager’s Private Views / Step 4: Revised (Posterior) Expectations / Step 5: Portfolio Optimization REFERENCES TO CFA PROBLEMS 995 GLOSSARY G-1 NAME INDEX I SUBJECT INDEX I-4 NOTATION, FORMULAS F-1 xv Preface T he past three decades witnessed rapid and profound change in the investments industry as well as a financial crisis of historic magnitude. The vast expansion of financial markets during this period was due in part to innovations in securitization and credit enhancement that gave birth to new trading strategies. These strategies were in turn made feasible by developments in communication and information technology, as well as by advances in the theory of investments. Yet the financial crisis of 2008–2009 also was rooted in the cracks of these developments. Many of the innovations in security design facilitated high leverage and an exaggerated notion of the efficacy of risk transfer strategies. This engendered complacency about risk that was coupled with relaxation of regulation as well as reduced transparency, masking the precarious condition of many big players in the system. Of necessity, our text has evolved along with financial markets and their influence on world events. Investments, Thirteenth Edition, is intended primarily as a textbook for courses in investment analysis. Our guiding principle has been to present the material in a framework that is organized by a central core of consistent fundamental principles. We attempt to strip away unnecessary mathematical and technical detail, and we have concentrated on providing the intuition that may guide students and practitioners as they confront new ideas and challenges in their professional lives. This text will introduce you to major issues currently of concern to all investors. It can give you the skills to assess watershed current issues and debates covered by both the popular media and more-specialized finance journals. Whether you plan to become an investment professional, or simply a sophisticated individual investor, you will find these skills essential, especially in today’s rapidly evolving environment. Our primary goal is to present material of p­ ractical value, but all three of us have spent our careers as researchers in financial economics and find virtually all of the material in this book to be of great intellectual interest. The capital asset pricing model, the arbitrage pricing model, the efficient markets hypothesis, the option-­pricing model, and the other centerpieces of modern financial theory are as much intellectually engaging subjects as they are of immense practical importance for the sophisticated investor. In our effort to link theory to practice, we also have attempted to make our approach consistent with that of the CFA Institute. In addition to fostering research in finance, the CFA Institute administers an education and certification program to candidates seeking designation as a Chartered Financial Analyst (CFA). The CFA curriculum represents the consensus of a committee of distinguished scholars and practitioners regarding the core of knowledge required by the investment professional. Many features of this text make it consistent with and relevant to the CFA curriculum. Questions adapted from past CFA exams appear at the end of nearly every chapter, and references are listed at the end of the book. Chapter 3 includes excerpts from the “Code of Ethics and Standards of Professional Conduct” of the CFA Institute. Chapter 28, which discusses investors and the investment process, presents the CFA Institute’s framework for systematically relating investor objectives and constraints to ultimate investment policy. End-of-chapter problems also include questions from test-prep leader Kaplan Schweser. In the Thirteenth Edition, we have continued our systematic presentation of Excel spreadsheets that will allow you to explore concepts more deeply. These spreadsheets, available in Connect and on the student resources site (www.mhhe.com/Bodie13e), provide a taste of the sophisticated analytic tools available to professional investors. UNDERLYING PHILOSOPHY While the financial environment is constantly evolving, many basic principles remain important. We believe that xvi Preface fundamental principles should organize and motivate all study and that attention to these few central ideas can simplify the study of otherwise difficult material. These principles are crucial to understanding the securities traded in financial markets and in understanding new securities that will be introduced in the future, as well as their effects on global markets. For this reason, we have made this book thematic, meaning we never offer rules of thumb without reference to the central tenets of the modern approach to finance. The common theme unifying this book is that security markets are nearly efficient, meaning most securities are usually priced appropriately given their risk and return attributes. Free lunches are rarely found in markets as competitive as the financial market. This simple observation is, nevertheless, remarkably powerful in its implications for the design of investment strategies; as a result, our discussions of strategy are always guided by the implications of the efficient markets hypothesis. While the degree of market efficiency is, and always will be, a matter of debate (in fact we devote a full chapter to the behavioral challenge to the efficient market hypothesis), we hope our discussions throughout the book convey a good dose of healthy skepticism concerning much conventional wisdom. a bank account, only then considering how much to invest in something riskier that might offer a higher expected return. The logical step at this point is to consider risky asset classes, such as stocks, bonds, or real estate. This is an asset allocation decision. S ­ econd, asset allocation is the primary determinant of the risk–return profile of the investment portfolio, and so it deserves primary attention in a study of investment policy. 3. This text offers a broad and deep treatment of futures, options, and other derivative security ­markets. These markets are both crucial and integral to the financial universe. Your only choice is to become conversant in these markets—whether you are to be a finance professional or simply a sophisticated individual investor. NEW IN THE THIRTEENTH EDITION The following is a guide to changes in the Thirteenth Edition. This is not an exhaustive road map, but instead is meant to provide an overview of substantial additions and changes to coverage from the last edition of the text. Chapter 1 The Investment Environment The chapter addresses recent controversies about stakeholder capitalism and ESG investing. It also further expands its treatment of Fintech, cryptocurrencies, and other digital assets. Distinctive Themes Investments is organized around several important themes: 1. The central theme is the near-informational-efficiency of well-developed security markets, such as those in the United States, and the general awareness that competitive markets do not offer “free lunches” to participants. A second theme is the risk–return trade-off. This too is a no-free-lunch notion, holding that in competitive security markets, higher expected returns come only at a price: the need to bear greater investment risk. However, this notion leaves several questions unanswered. How should one measure the risk of an asset? What should be the quantitative trade-off between risk (properly measured) and expected return? The approach we present to these issues is known as modern portfolio theory, which is another organizing principle of this book. Modern portfolio theory focuses on the techniques and implications of efficient diversification, and we devote considerable attention to the effect of diversification on portfolio risk as well as the implications of efficient diversification for the proper measurement of risk and the risk–return relationship. 2. This text places great emphasis on asset ­allocation. We prefer this emphasis for two important r­ easons. First, it corresponds to the procedure that most i­ ndividuals actually follow. Typically, you start with all of your money in Chapter 2 Asset Classes and Financial Instruments The chapter addresses changes in markets, most notably the replacement of LIBOR with new rates such as SOFR. Chapter 3 How Securities Are Traded New sections on SPACs, order internalization, and the GameStop squeeze have been added to the chapter. Chapter 5 Risk, Return, and the Historical Record In addition to thorough updating, this chapter has been extensively reorganized to improve flow and understanding. Chapter 10 Arbitrage Pricing Theory and Multifactor Models of Risk and Return The discussion of multifactor models has been updated and expanded, with a focus on the adoption of new variants such as the Fama-French five-factor model. Chapter 11 The Efficient Market Hypothesis The debate on efficient markets has been further developed. The chapter now includes a discussion of Shiller’s fads hypothesis, as well as new material on extra-market risk factors, and a discussion of the challenges posed by xvii Preface data snooping for the interpretation of empirical evidence on risk and return. an overview of the types of securities traded in those markets, and explain how and where securities are traded. We also discuss in depth mutual funds and other investment companies, which have become an increasingly important means of investing for individual investors. Perhaps most important, we address how financial markets can influence all aspects of the global economy, as in 2008. The material presented in Part One should make it possible for instructors to assign term projects early in the course. These projects might require the student to analyze in detail a particular group of securities. Many instructors like to involve their students in some sort of investment game, and the material in these chapters will facilitate this process. Parts Two and Three contain the core of modern portfolio theory. Chapter 5 is a general discussion of risk and return, making the general point that historical returns on broad asset classes are consistent with a risk–return trade-off and examining the distribution of stock returns. We focus more closely in Chapter 6 on how to describe investors’ risk preferences and how they bear on asset allocation. In the next two chapters, we turn to portfolio optimization (Chapter 7) and its implementation using index models (Chapter 8). After our treatment of modern portfolio theory in Part Two, we investigate in Part Three the implications of that theory for the equilibrium structure of expected rates of return on risky assets. Chapter 9 treats the capital asset pricing model and Chapter 10 covers multifactor descriptions of risk and the arbitrage pricing theory. Chapter 11 covers the efficient market hypothesis, including its rationale as well as evidence that supports the hypothesis and challenges it. Chapter 12 is devoted to the behavioral critique of market rationality. Finally, we conclude Part Three with Chapter 13 on empirical evidence on security pricing. This chapter contains evidence concerning the risk–return relationship, as well as liquidity effects on asset pricing. Part Four is the first of three parts on security valuation. This part treats fixed-income securities—bond pricing (Chapter 14), term structure relationships (Chapter 15), and interest-rate risk management (Chapter 16). Parts Five and Six deal with equity securities and derivative securities. For a course emphasizing security analysis and excluding portfolio theory, one may proceed directly from Part One to Part Four with no loss in continuity. Finally, Part Seven considers several topics important for portfolio managers, including performance evaluation, international diversification, active management, and practical issues in the process of portfolio management. This part also contains a chapter on alternative assets, with an emphasis on hedge funds and private equity. Chapter 12 Behavioral Finance and Technical Analysis The material on behavioral finance now includes confirmation bias. The section on technical analysis includes a new discussion of machine learning. Chapter 13 Empirical Evidence on Security Returns This chapter has been extensively rewritten. Older material has been replaced with treatments of issues such as the so-called factor zoo, appropriate criteria for accepting a new risk factor, and the implications of disaster risk for the equity risk premium. Chapter 15 The Term Structure of Interest Rates Market segmentation is now included as another potential explanation of the term structure. Chapter 17 Macroeconomic and Industry Analysis The discussion of the macroeconomy has been updated to include lessons learned during the COVID-19 pandemic, particularly the implications of supply side and supply chain issues for inflation. Chapter 23 Futures, Swaps, and Risk Management The treatment of interest rate swaps has been updated to account for the transition away from the LIBOR rate. Chapter 26 Alternative Assets This chapter, originally entitled Hedge Funds now has a wider focus on Alternative Assets. It includes substantial coverage of private equity, including angel investing, venture capital, and leveraged buyouts. Chapter 28 Investment Policy and the Framework of the CFA Institute This chapter has been substantially reorganized, in particular, its treatment of tax sheltering and top-down asset allocation. ORGANIZATION AND CONTENT The text is composed of seven sections that are fairly independent and may be studied in a variety of sequences. Because there is enough material in the book for a ­two-semester course, clearly a one-semester course will require the instructor to decide which parts to include. Part One is introductory and contains important institutional material focusing on the financial environment. We discuss the major players in the financial markets, provide xviii Distinctive Features This book contains several features designed to make it easy for students to understand, ­absorb, and apply the concepts and techniques presented. Confirming Pages 288 CONCEPT CHECKS PART V Data from the last 95 years for the broad U.S. equity market yield the following statistics: average excess return, 8.9%; standard deviation, 20.3%. a. To the extent that these averages approximated investor expectations for the period, what must have been the average coefficient of risk aversion? Confirming Pages b. If the coefficient of risk aversion were actually 3.5, what risk premium would have been consistent with the market’s historical standard deviation? Expected Returns on Individual Securities The CAPM is built on the insight that the appropriate risk premium on an asset will be determined by its contribution to the risk of investors’ overall portfolios. Portfolio risk is what matters to investors and is what governs the risk premiums they demand. Remember that in the CAPM, all investors use the same input list, that is, the same estimates of expected returns, variances, and covariances, and, therefore, all end up using the market as their optimal risky portfolio. To calculate the variance of the market portfolio, we use the bordered covariance matrix with the market portfolio weights, as discussed in Chapter 7. We highlight GE in this depiction of the n stocks in the market portfolio so that we can measure the contribution of GE to the risk of the market portfolio. Recall that we calculate the variance of the portfolio by summing over all the elements of the covariance matrix, first multiplying each element by the portfolio weights from the row and the column. The contribution of one stock to portfolio variance therefore can be expressed as the sum of all the covariance terms in the column corresponding to the stock, where each covariance is first multiplied by both the stock’s weight from its row and the weight from its column.5 Security Analysis Example 18.3 Equilibrium in Capital Markets Concept Check 9.2 A unique feature of this book! These selftest questions and problems found in the body of the text enable the students to determine whether they’ve understood the preceding material. Detailed solutions are provided at the end of each chapter. 590 PART III The Constant-Growth DDM NUMBERED EXAMPLES High Flyer Industries has just paid its annual dividend of $3 per share. The dividend is expected to grow at a constant rate of 8% indefinitely. The beta of High Flyer stock is 1.0, the risk-free rate is 6%, and the market risk premium is 8%. What is the intrinsic value of the stock? What would be your estimate of intrinsic value if you believed that the stock was riskier, with a beta of 1.25? Because a $3 dividend has just been paid and the growth rate of dividends is 8%, the forecast for the year-end dividend is $3 × 1.08 = $3.24. The market capitalization rate (using the CAPM) is 6% + 1.0 × 8% = 14%. Therefore, the value of the stock is are integrated throughout chapters. Using the worked-out solutions to these Portfolio Weights w w . . . students w ... wlearn examples as models, can w Cov(R , R ) Cov(R , R ) ... Cov(R , R ) ... Cov(R , R ) how to solve specific problems step-byw Cov(R , R ) Cov(R , R ) ... Cov(R , R ) ... Cov(R , R ) .. .. .. .. .. well as gain insight into general .step as . . . . w Cov(R , R ) Cov(R , R ) ... Cov(R , R ) ... Cov(R , R ) by ... seeing how they are applied ..principles .. .. ... . . . w Cov(R , R ) Cov(R , R ) ... Cov(R , R ) ... Cov(R , R ) to answer concrete questions. 1 $3.24 D1 V0 = _____ = _______ = $54 k − g .14 − .08 If the stock is perceived to be riskier, its value must be lower. At the higher beta, the market capitalization rate is 6% + 1.25 × 8% = 16%, and the stock is worth only $3.24 _______ = $40.50 2 GE n 1 1 1 1 2 1 GE 1 n 2 2 1 2 2 2 GE 2 n GE GE n n 1 1 GE n 2 2 GE n GE GE GE n n n Thus, the contribution of GE’s stock to the variance of the market portfolio is .16 − .08 w GE[w 1Cov(R 1, R GE) + w 2Cov(R 2, R GE) + · · · + w GE Cov(R GE, R GE) + · · · + w nCov(R n , R GE)] (9.3) 5 WORDS FROM THE STREET BOXES What Level of Risk Is Right for You? No risk, no reward. Most people intuitively understand that they have to bear some risk to achieve an acceptable return on their investment portfolios. But how much risk is right for you? If your investments turn sour, you may put at jeopardy your ability to retire, to pay for bod12665_ch09_283-314.indd 288 your kid’s college education, or to weather an unexpected need for cash. These worst-case scenarios focus our attention on how to manage our exposure to uncertainty. Assessing—and quantifying—risk aversion is, to put it mildly, difficult. It requires confronting at least these two big questions. First, how much investment risk can you afford to take? If you have a steady high-paying job, for example, you have greater ability to withstand investment losses. Conversely, if you are close to retirement, you have less ability to adjust your lifestyle in response to bad investment outcomes. Second, you need to think about your personality and decide how much risk you can tolerate. At what point will you be unable to sleep at night? To help clients quantify their risk aversion, many financial firms have designed quizzes to help people determine whether they are conservative, moderate, or aggressive investors. These quizzes try to get at clients’ attitudes toward risk and their capacity to absorb investment losses. Here is a sample of the sort of questions that can shed light on an investor’s risk tolerance. Short articles and financial coverage 1. The larger its expected dividend per share. adapted from business periodicals, such 2. The lower the market capitalization rate, k. 3. The Wall higher the expectedJournal, growth rate ofare dividends. as The Street included Another implication of the constant-growth model is that the stock price is expected to ingrow boxes throughout the text. The articles at the same rate as dividends. To see this, suppose Steady State stock is selling at its intrinsic value of for $57.14, so that V0 = P0.relevance Then are chosen real-world and D1 clarity of presentation. P0 = _____ k−g An alternative approach would be to measure GE’s contribution to market variance as the sum of the elements in the row and the column corresponding to GE. In this case, GE’s contribution would be twice the sum in Equation 9.3. The approach that we take allocates contributions to portfolio risk among securities in a conConfirming Pages venient manner in that the sum of the contributions of each stock equals the total portfolio variance, whereas the alternative measure of contribution would sum to twice the portfolio variance. This results from a type of double-counting because adding both the rows and the columns for each stock would result in each entry in the matrix being added twice. Using either approach, GE’s contribution to the variance of the market return would be directly proportional to the covariance of its returns with the market. WORDS FROM THE STREET The constant-growth DDM is valid only when g is less than k. If dividends were expected to grow forever at a rate faster than k, the value of the stock would be infinite. If an analyst derives an estimate of g greater than k, that growth rate must be unsustainable in the long run. The appropriate valuation model to use in this case is a multistage DDM such as those discussed below. The constant-growth DDM is so widely used by stock market analysts that it is worth exploring some of its implications and limitations. The constant-growth rate DDM implies that a stock’s value will be greater: Notice that price is proportional to dividends. Therefore, next year, when the dividends paid to Steady State stockholders are expected to be higher by g = 5%, price also should increase by 5%. To confirm this, we can write D2 = $4(1.05) = $4.20 D2 $4.20 P1 = _____ = ________ = $60.00 k − g .12 − .05 MEASURING YOUR RISK TOLERANCE Circle the letter that corresponds to your answer. 1. The stock market fell by more than 30% in 2008. If you had been holding a substantial stock investment in that year, which of the following would you have done? which is 5% higher than the current price of $57.14. To generalize, a. Sold off the remainder of your investment before it had the chance to fall further. D2 D1(1 + g) _____ D1 = _________ = (1 + g) = P0(1 + g) P1 = _____ k−g k−g k−g b. Stayed the course with neither redemptions nor purchases. c. Bought more stock, reasoning that the market is now cheaper and therefore offers better deals. 2. The value of one of the funds in your 401(k) plan (your primary source of retirement savings) increased 30% last year. What will you do? a. Move your funds into a money market account in case the price gains reverse. 4. At the end of the month, you find yourself: a. Short of cash and impatiently waiting for your next paycheck. b. Not overspending your salary, but not saving very much. 06/07/22 01:25 PM c. With a comfortable surplus of funds to put into your savings account. 5. You are 30 years old and enrolling in your company’s retirement plan, and you need to allocate your contributions across 3 funds: a money market account, a bond fund, and a stock fund. Which of these allocations sounds best to you? a. Invest everything in a safe money-market fund. b. Split your money evenly between the bond fund and stock fund. c. Put everything into the stock fund, reasoning that by the time you retire, the year-to-year fluctuations in stock, returns will have evened out. 6. You are a contestant on Let’s Make a Deal, and have just won $1,000. But you can exchange the winnings for two random payoffs. One is a coin flip with a payoff of $2,500 if the coin comes up heads. The other is a flip of two coins with a payoff of $6,000 if both coins come up heads. What will you do? a. Keep the $1,000 in cash. b. Choose the single coin toss. c. Choose the double coin toss. 7. Suppose you have the opportunity to invest in a start-up firm. If the firm is successful, you will multiply your investment by a factor of ten. But if it fails, you will lose everything. You think the odds of success are around 20%. How much would you be willing to invest in the start-up? a. Nothing b. 2 months’ salary c. 6 months’ salary 8. Now imagine that to buy into the start-up you will need to borrow money. Would you be willing to take out a $10,000 loan to make the investment? a. No b. Maybe c. Yes b. Sit tight and do nothing. bod12665_ch18_583-628.indd 590 06/30/22 10:27 AM xix c. Put more of your assets into that fund, reasoning that its value is clearly trending upward. 3. How would you describe your non-investment sources of income (e.g., your salary)? a. Highly uncertain b. Moderately stable c. Highly stable SCORING YOUR RISK TOLERANCE For each question, give yourself one point if you answered (a), two points if you answered (b), and three points for a (c). The higher your total score, the greater is your risk tolerance, or, equivalently, the lower is your risk aversion. Confirming Pages Confirming Pages EXCEL APPLICATIONS The Thirteenth Edition features Excel Spreadsheet Applications with Excel513 C H A P T E R 1 6 Managing Bond Portfolios questions. A sample spreadsheet is Duration presented in the text with an interactive To measure the effective maturity of a bond making many payments, we average over the maturity of each of the bond’s cash flows. Frederickavailable Macaulay called in this Connect average the version and on the duration of the bond. Macaulay’s duration equals the weighted average of the times to each coupon or principal payment, with student weights relatedresources to the “importance”site of thatat pay-www.mhhe ment to the value of the bond. Specifically, the weight applied to each payment time is the .com/Bodie13e. proportion of the total value of the bond accounted for by that payment, that is, the present eXcel APPLICATIONS: Two–Security Model T Table 7.1. This spreadsheet is available in Connect or through your course instructor. he accompanying spreadsheet can be used to analyze the return and risk of a portfolio of two risky assets. The model calculates expected return and volatility for varying weights of each security as well as the optimal risky and minimum-variance portfolios. Graphs are automatically generated for various model inputs. The model allows you to specify a target rate of return and solves for optimal complete portfolios composed of the risk-free asset and the optimal risky portfolio. The spreadsheet is constructed using the two-security return data (expressed as decimals, not percentages) from A B C D E 3 1. Suppose your target expected rate of return is 11%. a. What is the lowest-volatility portfolio that provides that expected return? b. What is the standard deviation of that portfolio? c. What is the composition of that portfolio? value of the payment divided by the bond price. We define the weight, wt , associated with the cash flow made at time t (denoted CFt) as F CF t / (1 + y)t w t = __________ Bond price Asset Allocation Analysis: Risk and Return 2 Expected Standard Correlation Return Deviation Coefficient Covariance 0.08 0.12 0.3 0.0072 Expected Standard Reward to 3 4 Security 1 5 Security 2 0.13 0.2 T-Bill 0.05 0 8 Weight Weight 9 Security 1 6 7 Security 2 Return Deviation Volatility 10 1 0 0.08000 0.12000 0.25000 11 0.9 0.1 0.08500 0.11559 0.30281 12 0.8 0.2 0.09000 0.11454 0.34922 13 0.7 0.3 0.09500 0.11696 0.38474 14 0.6 0.4 0.10000 0.12264 0.40771 Expected Return (%) 1 Excel Question 11 5 0 0 5 10 where y is the bond’s yield to maturity. The numerator on the right-hand side of this equation is the present value of the cash flow occurring at time t while the denominator is the value of all the bond’s payments. These weights sum to 1.0 because the sum of the cash flows discounted at the yield to maturity equals the bond price. Using these values to calculate the weighted average of the times until the receipt of each of25the 30 bond’s payments, we obtain Macaulay’s duration formula: 15 20 35 Standard Deviation (%) T D = ∑ t × wt (16.1) t=1 Confirming Pages Spreadsheet 16.1 uses Equation 16.1 to find the durations of an 8% coupon and zeroor 5% per 1. Specify the return characteristics of all securities (expected returns, variances, coupon bond, each with two years to maturity and yield to maturity of 10%, covariances). 2. Establish the risky portfolio (asset allocation): a. Calculate the optimal risky portfolio, P (Equation 7.13). A B C D E H A P T EPRusing 5 the Risk, Return,determined and the Historical 161 b. Calculate the properties ofCportfolio weights in step Record (a) 1 Time until PV of CF and Equations 7.2 and 7.3. (Discount rate 2 Payment 3. Allocate funds between the risky portfolio and the risk-free asset (capital Period Cash Flow 3 (Years) 5% per period) allocation):risk-free rate expected shortfall (ES) effective annual rate (EAR) 1 40 0.5 38.095 4 A. 8% coupon bond KEY TERMS conditional tail expectation annual percentage ratea. (APR) 2 Calculaterisk thepremium fraction of the complete portfolio allocated to portfolio P (the risky 40 1.0 36.281 5 (CTE) 7.14). nominal interest rate portfolio)excess and toreturn T-bills (the risk-free asset) (Equation 3 40 1.5 34.554 6 lower partial standard risk aversion real interest rate 4 2.0 855.611 1040 b. Calculate the share of the complete portfolio invested in each asset and in 7 deviation (LPSD) dividend yield T-bills. normal distribution Sum: 964.540 8 Sortino ratio skew scenario analysis 9 lognormal distribution mean rate of return Recall that ourkurtosis two risky assets, the bond and stock mutual funds, are already diversi1 0.5 0.000 0 10 B. Zero-coupon taildiversification risk variance fied portfolios. The within each of these portfolios must be credited for a 2 1.0 0.000 0 11 valuereduction at risk (VaR) standard deviation good deal of the risk compared to undiversified single securities. For example, 3 1.5 0.000 0 12 the standard deviation of the rate of return on an average stock in the last 10 years has 4 2.0 822.702 1000 13 been about 28% (see Figure 7.2). In contrast, the standard deviation of the S&P 500 in this Sum: 822.702 14 period was considerably lower, around 17%. This is evidence of the importance of diversiArithmetic average of n returns: (r1 + r2 + · · · + rn ) / n KEY EQUATIONS 15 fication within each asset class. 16 Semiannual int rate: 0.05 Geometric average of n returns: [(1 + r1) (1 + r2) · · · (1 + rn)]1/n − 1 17 Continuously compounded rate of return, rcc = ln(1 + Effective annual rate) 215 18 *Weight = Present value of each payment (column E) divided by the bond price. Expected return: ∑ [prob(Scenario) × Return in scenario] F EXCEL EXHIBITS Selected exhibits are set as Excel spreadsheets, and the accompanying files are available in Connect and on the student resources site at www.mhhe .com/Bodie13e. ________ bod12665_ch07_201-250.indd 1 + Nominal return Real rate of return: ________________ − 1 1 + Inflation rate Column sums 06/07/22subject 01:17 PM to rounding error. 3 Frederick Macaulay, Some Theoretical Problems Suggested by the Movements of Interest Rates, Bond Yields, and Stock Prices in the United States Since 1856 (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1938). Real rate of return (continuous compounding): rnominal − Inflation rate 1. The Fisher equation tells us that the real interest rate approximately equals the nominal rate minus the inflation rate. Suppose the inflation rate increases from 3% to 5%. Does the Fisher equation imply that this increase will result in a fall in the real rate of interest? Explain. 2. You’ve just stumbled on a new dataset that enables you to compute historical rates of return on U.S. stocks all the way back to 1880. What are the advantages and disadvantages in using these data to help estimate the expected rate of return on U.S. stocks over the coming year? 3. The Narnian stock market had a rate of return of 45% last year, but the inflation rate was 30%. What was the real rate of return to Narnian investors? PROBLEM SETS PROBLEM SETS bod12665_ch16_509-550.indd 308 513 PART III 4. You have $5,000 to invest for the next year and are considering three alternatives: a. A money market fund with an average maturity of 30 days offering a current yield of 3% per year. b. A 1-year savings deposit at a bank offering an interest rate of 4%. c. A 20-year U.S. Treasury bond offering a yield to maturity of 5% per year. What role does your forecast of future interest rates play in your decisions? 5. Use Figure 5.1 in the text to analyze the effect of the following on the level of real interest rates: 161 06/25/22 08:50 AM 1.5 1.0 What would be the fair return for each company according to the capital asset pricing model (CAPM)? EXAM PREP QUESTIONS bod12665_ch05_125-166.indd Confirming Pages We strongly believe that practice in solving problems is critical to understanding investments, so each chapter provides a good Equilibrium in Capital Markets variety of problems. Select problems and 4. Here are data on two companies. The T-bill rate is 4% and the market risk premium is 6%. algorithmic versions $1are assignable within Company Discount Store Everything $5 Forecasted return 12% 11% Connect. Standard deviation of returns 8% 10% Beta a. Businesses become more pessimistic about future demand for their products and decide to reduce their capital spending. b. Households are induced to save more because of increased uncertainty about their future Social Security benefits. c. The Federal Reserve Board undertakes open-market purchases of U.S. Treasury securities in order to increase the supply of money. ® Practice questions for the CFA exams provided by Kaplan Schweser, A Global Leader in CFA® Education, are available in selected chapters for additional test practice. Look for the Kaplan Schweser logo. Learn more at www.schweser.com. 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 2.0000 2.0000 Calculating the duration of two bonds 215 E(rP) − rf Portfolio risk premium Sharpe ratio: _____________________________ = _________ Standard deviation of excess return σP 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 1.0000 1.0000 Spreadsheet 16.1 Variance: ∑[prob(Scenario) × (Deviation from mean in scenario)2] Standard deviation: √Variance Weight* 0.0395 0.0376 0.0358 0.8871 1.0000 G Column (C) times Column (F) 0.0197 0.0376 0.0537 1.7741 1.8852 5. Characterize each company in the previous problem as underpriced, overpriced, or properly priced. 6. What is the expected rate of return for a stock that has a beta of 1.0 if the expected return on the market is 15%? a. 15%. b. More than 15%. c. Cannot be determined without the risk-free rate. 7. Kaskin, Inc., stock has a beta of 1.2 and Quinn, Inc., stock has a beta of .6. Which of the following statements is most accurate? 06/07/22 01:40 PM eXcel Please visit us at www.mhhe.com/Bodie13e xx a. The expected rate of return will be higher for the stock of Kaskin, Inc., than that of Quinn, Inc. b. The stock of Kaskin, Inc., has more total risk than the stock of Quinn, Inc. c. The stock of Quinn, Inc., has more systematic risk than that of Kaskin, Inc. 8. You are a consultant to a large manufacturing corporation that is considering a project with the following net after-tax cash flows (in millions of dollars): Years from Now After-Tax Cash Flow 0 −40 1–10 15 The project’s beta is 1.8. a. Assuming that rf = 8% and E(rM) = 16%, what is the net present value of the project? b. What is the highest possible beta estimate for the project before its NPV becomes negative? 9. Consider the following table, which gives a security analyst’s expected return on two stocks in two particular scenarios for the rate of return on the market: expected rate of return? c. In what sense does the discount bond offer “implicit call protection”? 31. A newly issued bond pays its coupons once annually. Its coupon rate is 5%, its maturity is 20 years, and its yield to maturity is 8%. a. Find the holding-period return for a 1-year investment period if the bond is selling at a yield to maturity of 7% by the end of the year. b. If you sell the bond after one year, what taxes will you owe if the tax rate on interest income is 40% and the tax rate on capital gains income is 30%? The bond is subject to original-issuediscount tax treatment. c. What is the after-tax holding-period return on the bond? d. Find the realized compound yield before taxes for a 2-year holding period, assuming that (i) you sell the bond after two years, (ii) the bond yield is 7% at the end of the second year, and (iii) the coupon can be reinvested for one year at a 3% interest rate. e. Use the tax rates in part (b) to compute the after-tax 2-year realized compound yield. Remember to take account of OID tax rules. CFA PROBLEMS 1. Leaf Products may issue a 10-year maturity fixed-income security, which might include a sinking fund provision and either refunding or call protection. a. Describe a sinking fund provision. b. Explain the impact of a sinking fund provision on: We provide several questions adapted for this text from past CFA examinations in applicable chapters. These questions represent the kinds of questions that professionals in the field believe are relevant to the “real world.” Located at the back of the book is a listing of each CFA question and the level and year of the CFA exam it was included in for easy reference. i. The expected average life of the proposed security. ii. Total principal and interest payments over the life of the proposed security. c. From the investor’s point of view, explain the rationale for demanding a sinking fund provision. 2. Bonds of Zello Corporation with a par value of $1,000 sell for $960, mature in five years, and have a 7% annual coupon rate paid semiannually. a. Calculate the: i. Current yield. ii. Yield to maturity to the nearest whole percent (i.e., 3%, 4%, 5%, etc.). iii. Realized compound yield for an investor with a 3-year holding period and a reinvestment rate of 6% over the period. At the end of three years, the 7% coupon bonds with two years remaining will sell to yield 7%. b. Cite one major shortcoming for each of the following fixed-income yield measures: i. Current yield. ii. Yield to maturity. iii. Realized compound yield. 3. On May 30, 2023, Janice Kerr is considering one of the newly issued 10-year AAA corporate bonds shown in the following exhibit. Description bod12665_ch14_439-480.indd Coupon Price Callable Call Price Sentinal, due May 30, 2033 4.00% 100 Noncallable Colina, due May 30, 2033 4.20% 100 Currently callable CHAPTER 3 478 NA 102 Pages Confirming How Securities Are Traded 95 06/20/22 10:49 AM 8. Consider the following limit-order book for FinTrade stock. The last trade in the stock occurred at a price of $50. Limit Buy Orders EXCEL PROBLEMS Selected chapters contain problems, denoted by an icon, specifically linked to Excel templates that are available in Connect and on the student resource site at www.mhhe.com/Bodie13e. Limit Sell Orders Price Shares Price $49.75 500 $50.25 Shares 100 49.50 800 51.50 100 49.25 500 54.75 300 49.00 200 58.25 100 48.50 600 a. If a market buy order for 100 shares comes in, at what price will it be filled? b. At what price would the next market buy order be filled? c. If you were a security dealer, would you want to increase or decrease your inventory of this stock? 9. You are bullish on Telecom stock. The current market price is $50 per share, and you have $5,000 of your own to invest. You borrow an additional $5,000 from your broker at an interest rate of 8% per year and invest $10,000 in the stock. eXcel Please visit us at www.mhhe.com/Bodie13e a. What will be your rate of return if the price of Telecom stock goes up by 10% during the next year? The stock currently pays no dividends. b. How far does the price of Telecom stock have to fall for you to get a margin call if the maintenance margin is 30%? Assume the price fall happens immediately. 10. You are bearish on Telecom and decide to sell short 100 shares at the current market price of $50 per share. a. How much in cash or securities must you put into your brokerage account if the broker’s initial margin requirement is 50% of the value of the short position? b. How high can the price of the stock go before you get a margin call if the maintenance margin is 30% of the value of the short position? 11. Suppose that Xtel currently is selling at $20 per share. You buy 1,000 shares using $15,000 of your own money, borrowing the remainder of the purchase price from your broker. The rate on Confirming Pages the margin loan is 8%. CHAPTER 5 Risk, Return, and the Historical Record 1. The OECD regularly publishes its economic outlook for the G20 countries as well as the world as a whole. You can find a recent report at www.oecd.org/economic-outlook. What is the forecast for U.S. inflation for the next year? Please visit us at www.mhhe.com/Bodie13e a. What is the percentage increase in the net worth of your brokerage account if the price of Xtel immediately changes to: (i) $22; (ii) $20; (iii) $18? What is the relationship between your percentage return and the percentage change in the price of Xtel? b. If the maintenance margin is 25%, how low can Xtel’s price fall before you get a margin 165 call? c. How would your answer to (b) change if you had financed the initial purchase with only $10,000 of your own money? d. What is the rate of return on your margined position (assuming again that you invest $15,000 of your own money) if Xtel is selling after 1 year at: (i) $22; (ii) $20; (iii) $18? What is the relationship between your percentage return and the percentage change in the price of Xtel? Assume that Xtel pays no dividends. e. Continue to assume that a year has passed. How low can Xtel’s price fall before you get a margin call? 3. What is the expected real rate based on your answers to (1) and (2)? 4. What is the real rate of interest on one-year inflation-protected T-bonds (TIPS)? You can also find this at the St. Louis Fed site, or from the online version of The Wall Street Journal, online. wsj.com. Look for the tab for Markets, then Market Data. 5. Is the value for the expected real rate that you found in (3) consistent with the value you found in (4)? 6. How does the current real rate compare to its historical average? bod12665_ch03_061-098.indd 1. a. EAR = (1 + .01)12 − 1 = .1268 = 12.68% b. EAR = e.12 − 1 = .1275 = 12.75% Choose the continuously compounded rate for its higher EAR. 2. a. 1 + rnom = (1 + rreal )(1 + i ) = (1.03)(1.08) = 1.1124 rnom = 11.24% b. 1 + rnom = (1.03)(1.10) = 1.133 rnom = 13.3% 3. Number of bonds bought is 27,000/900 = 30 Higher Unchanged Lower Expected rate of return eXcel These exercises provide students with simple activities to enhance their experience using the Internet. Easy-to-follow instructions and questions are presented so students can utilize what they have learned in class and apply it to today’s data-driven world. 2. What is the one-year nominal interest rate on 1-year Treasury securities? You can find this at the St. Louis Fed data site fred.stlouisfed.org. Interest Rates Please visit us at www.mhhe.com/Bodie13e E-INVESTMENTS BOXES E-INVESTMENTS EXERCISES SOLUTIONS TO CONCEPT CHECKS eXcel Probability Year-End Bond Price HPR End-of-Year Value 0.2 0.5 0.3 $850 915 985 (75 + 850)/900 − 1 = 0.0278 0.1000 0.1778 0.1089 (75 + 850)30 = $27,750 $29,700 $31,800 xxi 95 06/06/22 08:58 AM Instructors Student Success Starts with You Tools to enhance your unique voice Want to build your own course? No problem. Prefer to use an OLC-aligned, prebuilt course? Easy. Want to make changes throughout the semester? Sure. And you’ll save time with Connect’s auto-grading, too. 65% Less Time Grading A unique path for each student In Connect, instructors can assign an adaptive reading experience with SmartBook® 2.0. Rooted in advanced learning science principles, SmartBook 2.0 delivers each student a personalized experience, focusing students on their learning gaps, ensuring that the time they spend studying is time well-spent. mheducation.com/highered/connect/smartbook Laptop: Getty Images; Woman/dog: George Doyle/Getty Images Affordable solutions, added value Solutions for your challenges Make technology work for you with LMS integration for single sign-on access, mobile access to the digital textbook, and reports to quickly show you how each of your students is doing. And with our Inclusive Access program, you can provide all these tools at the lowest available market price to your students. Ask your McGraw Hill representative for more information. A product isn’t a solution. Real solutions are affordable, reliable, and come with training and ongoing support when you need it and how you want it. Visit supportateverystep.com for videos and resources both you and your students can use throughout the term. Students Get Learning that Fits You Effective tools for efficient studying Connect is designed to help you be more productive with simple, flexible, intuitive tools that maximize your study time and meet your individual learning needs. Get learning that works for you with Connect. Study anytime, anywhere Download the free ReadAnywhere® app and access your online eBook, SmartBook® 2.0, or Adaptive Learning Assignments when it’s convenient, even if you’re offline. And since the app automatically syncs with your Connect account, all of your work is available every time you open it. Find out more at mheducation.com/readanywhere “I really liked this app—it made it easy to study when you don't have your textbook in front of you.” - Jordan Cunningham, Eastern Washington University iPhone: Getty Images Everything you need in one place Your Connect course has everything you need—whether reading your digital eBook or completing assignments for class, Connect makes it easy to get your work done. Learning for everyone McGraw Hill works directly with Accessibility Services Departments and faculty to meet the learning needs of all students. Please contact your Accessibility Services Office and ask them to email accessibility@mheducation.com, or visit mheducation.com/about/accessibility for more information. Supplements connect.mheducation.com ∙ Test Builder provides a secure interface for better protection of content and allows for just-in-time updates to flow directly into assessments. ∙ Instructor’s Manual The Manual has been revised and improved for this edition. Each chapter includes a Chapter Overview, Learning Objectives, and Presentation of Material. ∙ PowerPoint Presentation These presentation slides contain figures and tables from the text, key points, and summaries in a visually stimulating collection of slides that you can customize to fit your lecture. I NSTR U CTO R L IBRARY The Connect Instructor Library is your repository for additional resources to improve student engagement in and out of class. You can select and use any asset that enhances your lecture. The Connect Instructor Library includes all of the instructor supplements for this text. ∙ Solutions Manual Updated by Nicholas Racculia, Saint Vincent College, in close collaboration with the authors, this Manual provides detailed solutions to the end-of-chapter problem sets. ∙ Test Bank The Test Bank has been revised to improve the quality of questions. Each question is ranked by level of difficulty, which allows greater flexibility in creating a test and also provides a rationale for the solution. ∙ Test Builder Available within Connect, Test Builder is a cloud-based tool that enables instructors to format tests that can be printed or administered within an LMS. Test Builder offers a modern, streamlined interface for easy content configuration that matches course needs, without requiring a download. Test Builder allows you to: ∙ Access all test bank content from a particular title. ∙ Easily pinpoint the most relevant content through robust filtering options. ∙ Manipulate the order of Questions or scramble questions and/or answers. ∙ Pin questions to a specific location within a test. ∙ Determine your preferred treatment of algorithmic questions. ∙ Choose the layout and spacing. ∙ Add instruc tions and configure default settings. STUD E N T STUDY CE N TE R The Connect Student Study Center is the place for students to access additional resources. The Student Study Center: ∙ Offers students quick access to the recommended study tools, Excel files and templates, a listing of related Web sites, lectures, eBooks, and more. ∙ Provides instant practice material and study questions, easily accessible on the go. Students can also access the text resources at www.mhhe. com/Bodie13e. STUD E N T P RO G RE S S TRACKIN G Connect keeps instructors informed about how each student, section, and class is performing, allowing for more productive use of lecture and office hours. The progresstracking function enables you to: ∙ View scored work immediately and track individual or group performance with assignment and grade reports. xxiv Supplements ∙ Access an instant view of student or class performance relative to learning objectives. ∙ Collect data and generate reports required by many accreditation organizations, such as the AACSB and AICPA. our services don’t stop after you purchase our products. You can email our product specialists 24 hours a day to get product training online. Or you can search our knowledge bank of frequently asked questions on our support site. For customer support, call 800-331-5094 or visit www.mhhe.com/support. One of our technical support analysts will be able to assist you in a timely fashion. MCG RAW HILL CUSTO MER CA RE CON TACT INFO RMAT IO N At McGraw Hill, we understand that getting the most from new technology can be challenging. That’s why xxv Acknowledgments Throughout the development of this text, experienced instructors have provided critical feedback and suggestions for improvement. These individuals deserve a special thanks for their valuable insights and contributions. The following instructors played a vital role in the development of this and previous editions of Investments: James Cotter Wake Forest University Jeremy Goh Washington University L. Michael Couvillion Plymouth State University Richard Grayson Loyola College Anna Craig Emory University John M. Griffin Arizona State University Elton Daal University of New Orleans Weiyu Guo University of Nebraska at Omaha J. Amanda Adkisson Texas A&M University David C. Distad University of California at Berkeley Mahmoud Haddad Wayne State University Sandro Andrade University of Miami at Coral Gables Craig Dunbar University of Western Ontario Greg Hallman University of Texas at Austin Tor-Erik Bakke University of Wisconsin David Durr Murray State University Robert G. Hansen Dartmouth College Richard J. Bauer Jr. St. Mary’s University Bjorn Eaker Duke University Joel Hasbrouck New York University Scott Besley University of Florida John Earl University of Richmond Andrea Heuson University of Miami John Binder University of Illinois at Chicago Michael C. Ehrhardt University of Tennessee at Knoxville Eric Higgins Drexel University Paul Bolster Northwestern University Venkat Eleswarapu Southern Methodist University Shalom J. Hochman University of Houston Phillip Braun University of Chicago David Ellis Babson College Stephen Huffman University of Wisconsin at Oshkosh Leo Chan Delaware State University Andrew Ellul Indiana University Eric Hughson University of Colorado Charles Chang Cornell University John Farlin Ohio Dominican University Delroy Hunter University of South Florida Kee Chaung SUNY Buffalo John Fay Santa Clara University A. James Ifflander A. James Ifflander and Associates Xiang (Shawn) Chi Wesleyan University Ludwig Chincarini Pomona College Stephen Ciccone University of New Hampshire Greg Filbeck University of Toledo Robert Jennings Indiana University James Forjan York College of Pennsylvania George Jiang University of Arizona David Gallagher University of Technology, Sydney Richard D. Johnson Colorado State University xxvi Acknowledgments Susan D. Jordan University of Kentucky Dimitris Papanikolaou Northwestern University G. Andrew Karolyi Ohio State University Dilip Patro Rutgers University Ajay Khorana Georgia Institute of Technology Robert Pavlik Southwest Texas State Anna Kovalenko Virginia Tech University Marianne Plunkert University of Colorado at Denver Josef Lakonishok University of Illinois at Champaign/Urbana Jeffrey Pontiff Boston College Malek Lashgari University of Hartford Andrew Prevost Ohio University Dennis Lasser Binghamton SUNY Herbert Quigley University of the District of Columbia Hongbok Lee Western Illinois University Bruce Lehmann University of California at San Diego Jack Li Northeastern University Larry Lockwood Texas Christian University Christopher K. Ma Texas Tech University Anil K. Makhija University of Pittsburgh Davinder Malhotra Philadelphia University Steven Mann University of South Carolina Deryl W. Martin Tennessee Technical University Jean Masson University of Ottawa Ronald May St. John’s University William McDonald University of Notre Dame Rick Meyer University of South Florida Bruce Mizrach Rutgers University at New Brunswick Mbodja Mougoue Wayne State University Kyung-Chun (Andrew) Mun Truman State University Ahmad Sohrabian California State Polytechnic University–Pomona Eileen St. Pierre University of Northern Colorado Laura T. Starks University of Texas Mick Swartz University of Southern California Manuel Tarrazo University of San Francisco Steve Thorley Brigham Young University Ashish Tiwari University of Iowa Nicholas Racculia Saint Vincent College Jack Treynor Treynor Capital Management Murli Rajan University of Scranton Charles A. Trzincka SUNY Buffalo Speima Rao University of Southwestern Louisiana Yiuman Tse Binghamton SUNY Rathin Rathinasamy Ball State University Joe Ueng University of St. Thomas William Reese Tulane University Gopala Vasuderan Suffolk University Craig Rennie University of Arkansas Joseph Vu DePaul University Maurico Rodriquez Texas Christian University Qinghai Wang Georgia Institute of Technology Leonard Rosenthal Bentley College Richard Warr North Carolina State University Anthony Sanders The Ohio State University Simon Wheatley University of Chicago Gary Sanger Louisiana State University Marilyn K. Wiley Florida Atlantic University James Scott Missouri State University James Williams California State University at Northridge Don Seeley University of Arizona Michael Williams University of Denver John Settle Portland State University Tony R. Wingler University of North Carolina at Greensboro Edward C. Sims Western Illinois University Robert Skena Carnegie Mellon University Guojun Wu University of Michigan Hsiu-Kwang Wu University of Alabama Carol Osler Brandeis University Steve L. Slezak University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill Gurupdesh Pandner DePaul University Keith V. Smith Purdue University Thomas J. Zwirlein University of Colorado at Colorado Springs Don B. Panton University of Texas at Arlington Patricia B. Smith University of New Hampshire Edward Zychowicz Hofstra University xxvii Geungu Yu Jackson State University Acknowledgments For granting us permission to include many of its examination questions in the text, we are grateful to the CFA Institute. In addition, we would like to thank Nicholas Racculia, whose authoring efforts on Chapter 26 as well as our Connect online content will greatly assist both students and instructors. Much credit is due to the development and production team at McGraw Hill Education: our special thanks go to Allison McCabe-Carroll, Senior Product Developer; Jeni ­McAtee, Core Project Manager; and George Theofanopoulos, Assessment Project Manager. xxviii Finally, we thank Judy, Hava, and Sheryl, who contribute to the book with their support and understanding. Zvi Bodie Alex Kane Alan J. Marcus 1 CHAPTER AN INVESTMENT IS the current commitment of money or other resources in the expectation of reaping future benefits. For example, you might purchase shares of stock anticipating that the future proceeds will justify both the time your money is tied up as well as the risk of the investment. The time you will spend studying this text (not to mention its cost) also is an investment. You are forgoing either current leisure or the income you could be earning at a job in the expectation that your future career will be sufficiently enhanced to justify this commitment of time and effort. While these two investments differ in many ways, they share one key attribute that is central to all investments: You sacrifice something of value now, expecting to reap the benefits later. This text can help you become an informed practitioner of investments. We will focus on investments in securities such as stocks, bonds, or derivatives contracts, but much of what we discuss will be useful in the analysis of any type of investment. The text will provide you with background in the organization of various securities markets; will survey the valuation and risk management principles useful in particular markets, such as those for bonds or stocks; and will introduce you to the principles of portfolio construction. PART I The Investment Environment Broadly speaking, this chapter addresses several topics that will provide perspective for the material that is to come later. First, before delving into the topic of “investments,” we consider the role of financial assets in the economy. We discuss the relationship between securities and the “real” assets that actually produce goods and services for consumers, and we consider why financial assets are important to the functioning of a developed economy. Given this background, we then take a first look at the types of decisions that confront investors as they assemble a portfolio of assets. These investment decisions are made in an environment where higher returns usually can be obtained only at the price of greater risk and in which it is rare to find assets that are so mispriced as to be obvious ­bargains. These themes—the risk–return trade-off and the efficient pricing of financial assets—are central to the investment process, so it is worth pausing for a brief discussion of their implications as we begin the text. These implications will be fleshed out in much greater detail in later chapters. We provide an overview of the organization of security markets as well as its key participants. Finally, we discuss the financial crisis that began playing out in 2007 and peaked in 2008. The crisis dramatically illustrated the c­onnections between the financial system and the “real” (continued) 1 (concluded) side of the economy. We look at the origins of the crisis and the lessons that may be drawn 1.1 about systemic risk. We close the chapter with an ­overview of the remainder of the text. Real Assets versus Financial Assets The material wealth of a society is ultimately determined by the productive capacity of its economy, that is, the goods and services its members can create. This capacity is a function of the real assets of the economy: the land, buildings, machines, and knowledge that can be used to produce goods and services. In contrast to real assets are financial assets such as stocks and bonds. Such ­securities historically were no more than sheets of paper (and today, are far more likely to be, ­computer entries), and they do not contribute directly to the productive capacity of the economy. Instead, these assets are the means by which individuals in well-developed economies hold their claims on real assets. Financial assets are claims to the income generated by real assets (or claims on income from the government). If we cannot own our own auto plant (a real asset), we can still buy shares in Ford or Toyota (financial assets) and thereby share in the income derived from the production of automobiles. While real assets generate net income to the economy, financial assets simply define the allocation of income or wealth among investors. When investors buy securities issued by companies, the firms use the money so raised to pay for real assets, such as plant, equipment, technology, or inventory. So investors’ returns ultimately come from the income produced by the real assets that were financed by the issuance of those securities. The distinction between real and financial assets is apparConcept Check 1.1 ent when we compare the balance sheet of U.S. households, shown in Table 1.1, with the composition of national wealth Are the following assets real or financial? in the United States, shown in Table 1.2. Household wealth includes financial assets such as bank accounts, corporate a. Patents stock, or bonds. However, these securities, which are finanb. Lease obligations cial assets of households, are ­liabilities of the issuers of the c. Customer goodwill securities. For example, a bond that you treat as an asset d. A college education because it gives you a claim on interest income and repaye. A $5 bill ment of principal from Toyota is a liability of Toyota, which is obligated to make these p­ ayments. Your asset is Toyota’s liability. Therefore, when we aggregate over all balance sheets, these claims cancel out, leaving only real assets as the net wealth of the economy. National wealth consists of structures, equipment, inventories of goods, and land.1 1 You might wonder why real assets held by households in Table 1.1 amount to $44,599 billion, while total real assets in the domestic economy (Table 1.2) are far larger, at $86,282 billion. A big part of the difference reflects the fact that real assets held by firms, for example, property, plant, and equipment, are included as financial assets of the household sector, specifically through the value of corporate equity and other stock market investments. Also, Table 1.2 includes assets of noncorporate businesses. Finally, there are some differences in valuation ­methods. For example, equity and stock investments in Table 1.1 are measured by market value, whereas plant and equipment in Table 1.2 are valued at replacement cost. 2 CHAPTER 1 Assets $ Billion % Total Liabilities and Net Worth Real assets Real estate Consumer durables Other Total real assets $37,558 6362 679 $44,599 24.4% 4.1% 0.4% 28.9% Liabilities Mortgages Consumer credit Bank and other loans Other Total liabilities Financial assets Deposits and money market shares Life insurance reserves Pension reserves Corporate equity Equity in noncorp. business Mutual fund shares Debt securities Other Total financial assets TOTAL $17,374 1,854 29,876 28,285 13,114 11,661 5,772 1,626 $109,562 $154,161 11.3% 1.2% 19.4% 18.3% 8.5% 7.6% 3.7% 1.1% 71.1% 100.0% Net worth $ Billion % Total $11,331 4,163 1,125 624 $17,244 7.4% 2.7% 0.7% 0.4% 11.2% 136,917 $154,161 88.8% 100.0% Table 1.1 Balance sheet of U.S. households Note: Column sums may differ from total because of rounding error. Source: Flow of Funds Accounts of the United States, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, June 2021. Assets $ Billion Commercial real estate Residential real estate Equipment & intellectual property Inventories Consumer durables TOTAL $20,842.9 45,816.3 10,316.2 2,944.5 6,361.9 $86,282 Table 1.2 Domestic net worth Note: Column sums may differ from total because of rounding error. Source: Flow of Funds Accounts of the United States, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, June 2021. We will focus almost exclusively on financial assets. But keep in mind that the ­successes or failures of these financial assets ultimately depend on the performance of the underlying real assets. 1.2 3 The Investment Environment Financial Assets It is common to distinguish among three broad types of financial assets: fixed income, equity, and derivatives. Fixed-income or debt securities promise either a fixed stream of income or a stream of income determined by a specified formula. For example, a corporate 4 PART I Introduction bond typically promises the bondholder a fixed amount of interest each year. Other socalled floating-rate bonds promise payments that depend on current i­nterest rates. For example, a bond may pay an interest rate fixed at 2 percentage points above the rate paid on U.S. ­Treasury bills. Unless the borrower is declared bankrupt, the payments on these securities are either fixed or determined by formula. For this reason, the investment performance of debt securities typically is least closely tied to the financial condition of the issuer. Fixed-income securities come in a tremendous variety of maturities and payment ­provisions. At one extreme, money market securities are short term, highly marketable, and generally of very low risk, for example, U.S. Treasury bills or bank certificates of deposit (CDs). In contrast, the fixed-income capital market includes long-term securities such as Treasury bonds, as well as bonds issued by federal agencies, state and local municipalities, and corporations. These bonds range from very safe in terms of default risk (e.g., Treasury securities) to relatively risky (e.g., high-yield or “junk” bonds). They also are designed with extremely diverse provisions regarding payments provided to the investor and protection against the bankruptcy of the issuer. We will take a first look at these securities in Chapter 2 and undertake a more detailed analysis of the debt market in Part Four. Unlike debt securities, common stock, or equity, represents an ownership share in the corporation. Equityholders are not promised any particular payment. They receive any dividends the firm may pay and have prorated ownership in the real assets of the firm. If the firm is successful, the value of equity will increase; if not, it will decrease. The performance of equity investments, therefore, is tied directly to the success of the firm and its real assets. For this reason, equity investments tend to be riskier than investments in debt securities. Equity markets and equity valuation are the topics of Part Five. Finally, derivative securities such as options and futures contracts provide payoffs that are determined by the prices of other assets such as bond or stock prices. For example, a call option on a share of Intel stock might turn out to be worthless if Intel’s share price remains below a threshold or “exercise” price such as $50 a share, but it can be quite valuable if the stock price rises above that level.2 Derivative securities are so named because their values derive from the prices of other assets. For example, the value of the call option will depend on the price of Intel stock. Other important derivative securities are futures and swap contracts. We will treat these in Part Six. Derivatives have become an integral part of the investment environment. One use of derivatives, perhaps the primary use, is to hedge risks or transfer them to other parties. This is done successfully every day, and the use of these securities for risk management is so commonplace that the multitrillion-dollar market in derivative assets is routinely taken for granted. Derivatives also can be used to take highly speculative positions, however. Every so often, one of these positions blows up, resulting in well-publicized losses of hundreds of millions of dollars. While these losses attract considerable attention, they are in fact the exception to the more common use of such securities as risk management tools. Derivatives will continue to play an important role in portfolio construction and the financial system. We will return to this topic later in the text. Investors and corporations regularly encounter other financial markets as well. Firms engaged in international trade regularly transfer money back and forth between dollars and other currencies. In London alone, over $2 trillion of currency is traded each day and worldwide trading volume exceeds $6 trillion. 2 A call option is the right to buy a share of stock at a given exercise price on or before the option’s expiration date. If the market price of Intel remains below $50 a share, the right to buy for $50 will turn out to be valueless. If the share price rises above $50 before the option expires, however, the option can be exercised to obtain the share for only $50. CHAPTER 1 The Investment Environment Investors also might invest directly in some real assets. For example, dozens of commodities are traded on exchanges such as the New York Mercantile Exchange or the Chicago Board of Trade. You can buy or sell corn, wheat, natural gas, gold, silver, and so on. Commodity and derivative markets allow firms to adjust their exposure to various business risks. For example, a construction firm may lock in the price of copper by buying copper futures contracts, thus eliminating the risk of a jump in the price of its raw materials. Wherever there is uncertainty, investors may be interested in trading, either to speculate or to lay off their risks, and a market may arise to meet that demand. 1.3 Financial Markets and the Economy We stated earlier that real assets determine the wealth of an economy, while financial assets merely represent claims on real assets. Nevertheless, financial assets and the markets in which they trade play several crucial roles in developed economies. Financial assets allow us to make the most of the economy’s real assets. The Informational Role of Financial Markets Stock prices reflect investors’ collective assessment of a firm’s current performance and future prospects. When the market is more optimistic about the firm, its share price will rise. That higher price makes it easier for the firm to raise capital and therefore encourages investment. In this manner, stock prices play a major role in the allocation of capital in market economies, directing it to the firms and applications with the greatest perceived potential. For example, in 2021, big investors poured huge investments into startup firms focusing on new battery technologies that could store energy created by renewables such as wind or solar power.3 The prospect of big profits if this technology pans out prompted investors to allocate their funds toward these ventures. This dynamic was a good example of market incentives directing capital to applications where there is the prospect of a large payoff. Do capital markets actually channel resources to the most efficient use? At times, they appear to fail miserably. Companies or whole industries can be “hot” for a period of time (think about the dot-com bubble that peaked and then collapsed in 2000), attract a large flow of investor capital, and then fail after only a few years. The process seems highly wasteful. But we need to be careful about our standard of efficiency. No one knows with certainty which ventures will succeed and which will fail. It is therefore unreasonable to expect that markets will never make mistakes. The stock market encourages allocation of capital to those firms that appear at the time to have the best prospects. Many smart, well-trained, and well-paid professionals analyze the prospects of firms whose shares trade on the stock market. Stock prices reflect their collective judgment. You may well be skeptical about resource allocation through markets. But if you are, take a moment to think about the alternatives. Would a central planner make fewer mistakes? Would you prefer that Congress make these decisions? To paraphrase Winston Churchill’s comment about democracy, markets may be the worst way to allocate capital except for all the others that have been tried. 3 Scott Patterson, “Investors Hunt for Battery Advances,” The Wall Street Journal, September 10, 2021, p. B1. 5 6 PART I Introduction Consumption Timing Some individuals are earning more than they currently wish to spend. Others, for example, retirees, spend more than they currently earn. How can you shift your purchasing power from high-earnings to low-earnings periods of life? One way is to “store” your wealth in financial assets. In high-earnings periods, you can invest your savings in financial assets such as stocks and bonds. In low-earnings periods, you can sell these assets to provide funds for your consumption needs. By so doing, you can “shift” your consumption over the course of your lifetime, thereby allocating your consumption to periods that provide the greatest satisfaction. Thus, financial markets allow individuals to separate decisions concerning current consumption from constraints that otherwise would be imposed by current earnings. Allocation of Risk Virtually all real assets involve some risk. When Toyota builds its auto plants, for example, it cannot know for sure what cash flows those plants will generate. Financial markets and the diverse financial instruments traded in those markets allow investors with the greatest taste for risk to bear that risk, while other, less risk-tolerant individuals can, to a greater extent, stay on the sidelines. For example, if Toyota raises the funds to build its auto plant by selling both stocks and bonds to the public, the more optimistic or risk-tolerant investors can buy shares of its stock, while the more conservative ones can buy its bonds. Because the bonds promise to provide a fixed payment, the stockholders bear most of the business risk but reap potentially higher rewards. Thus, capital markets allow the risk that is inherent to all investments to be borne by the investors most willing to bear it. This allocation of risk also benefits the firms that need to raise capital to finance their investments. When investors are able to select security types with the risk-return characteristics that best suit their preferences, each security can be sold for the best possible price. This facilitates the process of building the economy’s stock of real assets. Separation of Ownership and Management Many businesses are owned and managed by the same individual. This simple organization is well suited to small businesses and, in fact, was the most common form of business organization before the Industrial Revolution. Today, however, with global markets and large-scale production, the size and capital requirements of firms have skyrocketed. For example, at the end in 2021, Chevron listed on its balance sheet about $156 billion of property, plant, and equipment and total assets of $240 billion. Corporations of such size simply cannot exist as owner-operated firms. Chevron actually has tens of thousands of stockholders with an ownership stake in the firm proportional to their holdings of shares. Such a large group of individuals obviously cannot actively participate in the day-today management of the firm. Instead, they elect a board of directors that in turn hires and supervises the management of the firm. This structure means that the owners and managers of the firm are different parties. This gives the firm a stability that the owner-managed firm cannot achieve. For example, if some stockholders decide they no longer wish to hold shares in the firm, they can sell their shares to other investors, with no impact on the management of the firm. Thus, financial assets and the ability to buy and sell those assets in the financial markets allow for easy separation of ownership and management. How can all of the disparate owners of the firm, ranging from large pension funds holding hundreds of thousands of shares to small investors who may hold only a single share, agree on the objectives of the firm? Financial markets can provide some guidance. The overwhelming orthodoxy in the business community since the 1970s was that the goal of the firm should be to maximize value and that corporate governance, for example, incentive packages for top management, should be designed to encourage that goal. The idea is that when value is maximized, we will all be in a better position to pursue our personal goals including, if we wish, support for “good causes.” But in 2019, America’s Business Roundtable, a group of CEOs of the country’s largest corporations, advocated for broader corporate goals that address the interests of other stakeholders, including employees, customers, and the communities in which firms operate. Their argument is that firms need to recognize and respond to ethical and societal considerations beyond their private pursuit of profit, in other words, that there is a built-in tension between shareholder capitalism and stakeholder capitalism. The critics of value maximization argue that it does not provide incentives to firms to respond to important societal and economic challenges and that if firms concern themselves only with their own interests, they will ignore potential value-reducing impacts of their actions on other players. For example, should a firm increase its value by a trivial amount if it thereby increases unemployment for a large number of workers? Should it increase its value by gutting pension plans established for its former employees? Should it increase profits by evading the costs of clean production even if that would pollute the environment? These critics argue that firms should be encouraged and perhaps forced to take a broader view of their obligations to their many stakeholders. They argue further that enlightened strategies can actually be financially beneficial, and that long-term value maximization requires sustainable investment strategies compatible with a healthier and more resilient economy in the future. These sustainability criteria are commonly grouped under the umbrella of environmental, social, and governance, or ESG, investing. In fact, the ESG sector has exploded in the last few years, with ESG-oriented mutual and exchange-traded funds in the United States capturing about one-fourth of new investments in 2020. On the other hand, traditionalists are wary of an unfocused commitment to many competing and unspecified interests that could impede accountability. Should the firm, for example, offer a better service to its customers if doing so makes the company a less attractive place to work? Given these sorts of conflicting objectives, how should one judge whether managers have performed well? Who will set these goals, and how much power is it appropriate to give to nonshareholders with little skin in the game? What incentives will remain for innovation and risk taking if corporate goals are set in the political arena? Is it right to downplay the importance of monetary success? After all, many institutions devoted to the public good and the economic security of individuals rely on the success of the endowment funds and pension funds that help pay for their activities. Finally, regardless of their preferences, competition may force firms to pursue value-maximizing strategies—if they don’t, they run the risk that competitors who do will put them out of business. How might one thread this needle? One middle-ground approach focuses on encouraging enlightened self-interest. It can be value maximizing to establish a reputation as a good place to work if that helps the firm attract and retain good employees. It can be value maximizing to avoid scandal, disruption, and fines. It can also be value maximizing to provide products and treat customers in a manner that encourages repeat business. And if customers want goods produced by well-treated workers using environmentally responsible practices, it will be in the firm’s interest to design production processes with those goals in mind. Consumers also vote with their feet, and firms that wish to do well may face pressure to do good. Of course, it would be naïve to believe that there will never be conflicts between value maximization, even maximization of long-term value, and other social considerations. Potential conflicts may call for government intervention to nudge incentives in one direction or the other. For example, governments may tax polluting activities to make it value maximizing to reduce emissions. They may set and enforce antitrust rules to foster competition and prevent any one firm from becoming powerful enough to ride roughshod over the interests of customers and employees. They can demand transparency to allow outsiders to make informed judgments of how the company is behaving. The world is full of slippery slopes and competing goals, and no economic system will at all times and in all places arrive at the best compromise between narrow self-interest and broader social impact. Enlightened capitalism that recognizes that long-term success is compatible with, and in fact may demand, consideration of the wider implications of corporate actions may strike as good a balance as one can hope for. While the particular goals of each corporation’s many investors may vary widely, all shareholders will be better able to achieve those personal goals when the firm acts to enhance the value of their shares. For this reason, value maximization has for decades been widely accepted as a useful organizing principle for the firm. More recently, some observers have questioned this goal, arguing that the firm should attempt to balance the interests of its many stakeholders, for example, employees, customers, suppliers, and communities. The nearby box examines this debate. 7 WORDS FROM THE STREET Stakeholder Capitalism 8 PART I Introduction Do managers really attempt to maximize firm value? It is easy to see how they might be tempted to engage in activities not in the best interest of shareholders. For example, they might engage in empire building or avoid risky projects to protect their own jobs or overconsume luxuries such as corporate jets, reasoning that the cost of such perquisites is largely borne by the shareholders. These potential conflicts of interest are called agency problems because managers, who are hired as agents of the shareholders, may pursue their own interests instead. Several mechanisms have evolved to mitigate potential agency problems. First, compensation plans tie the income of managers to the success of the firm. A major part of the total compensation of top executives is often in the form of shares or stock options, which means that the managers will not do well unless the stock price increases, benefiting shareholders. (Of course, we’ve learned that overuse of options can create its own agency problem. Options can create an incentive for managers to manipulate information to prop up a stock price temporarily, giving them a chance to cash out before the price returns to a level reflective of the firm’s true prospects. More on this shortly.) Second, while boards of directors have sometimes been portrayed as defenders of top management, they can, and in recent years, increasingly have, forced out management teams that are underperforming. Third, outsiders such as security analysts and large institutional investors such as mutual funds or pension funds monitor the firm closely and make the life of poor performers at the least uncomfortable. Such large investors today hold about half of the stock in publicly listed firms in the United States. Finally, bad performers are subject to the threat of takeover. If the board of directors is lax in monitoring management, unhappy shareholders in principle can elect a different board. They can do this by launching a proxy contest in which they seek to obtain enough proxies (i.e., rights to vote the shares of other shareholders) to take control of the firm and vote in another board. Historically, this threat was usually minimal. Shareholders who attempt such a fight have to use their own funds, while management can defend itself using corporate coffers. However, in recent years, the odds of a successful proxy contest have increased along with the rise of so-called activist investors. These are large and deep-pocketed investors, often hedge funds, that identify firms they believe to be mismanaged in some respect. They buy large positions in shares of those firms and then campaign for slots on the board of directors and/or for specific reforms. Example 1.1 Activist Investors and Corporate Control Here are a few of the better-known activist investors, along with a sample of their more notable initiatives: • Nelson Peltz, Trian. Trian gained a seat on General Electric’s board of directors and pressured the company to cut costs, to return capital to shareholders, for example, through stock buybacks, and to downsize the firm. • William Ackman, Pershing Square. Took 8.3% stake in software company ADP, where he pushed for management changes. • Dan Loeb, Third Point. Took large position in Royal Dutch Shell and pressed the company to split into two independent firms, one focusing on its legacy business lines, such as oil exploration and refining, and the other on low-carbon and renewable energy sources. CHAPTER 1 The Investment Environment • Carl Icahn. One of the earliest and most combative of activist investors. Pushed HP to accept a takeover bid made by Xerox. • Christer Gardell, Cevian Capital. Cevian is the largest activist firm in Europe. In 2021, it built up a 5% stake in the insurer Avian and then pressured the company to ­commit to deeper cost reductions and to pay out £5 billion in dividends or stock repurchases. • Paul Singer, Elliott Management. Built up a large stake in the U.K. drug manufacturer Glaxo­ SmithKline after GSK’s disappointing performance in the development of a Covid vaccination. Elliott is now expected to demand a large say in the firm’s future management. • Engine No. 1. A newcomer to the field, this formerly little-known fund gained the backing of large institutional investors like BlackRock and Vanguard and won three seats on the board of ExxonMobil, filling them with candidates with backgrounds in green energy and operational expertise. Aside from proxy contests, the real takeover threat is from other firms. If one firm observes another underperforming, it can acquire the underperforming business and replace management with its own team. The stock price should rise to reflect the prospects of improved performance, which provides an incentive for firms to engage in such takeover activity. Corporate Governance and Corporate Ethics We’ve argued that securities markets can play an important role in facilitating the deployment of capital to the most productive uses. But market signals will help to allocate capital efficiently only if investors are acting on accurate information. We say that markets need to be transparent for investors to make informed decisions. If firms can mislead the public about their prospects, then much can go wrong. Despite the many mechanisms to align incentives of shareholders and managers, the three years from 2000 through 2002 were filled with a seemingly unending series of scandals that collectively signaled a crisis in corporate governance and ethics. For ­example, the telecom firm WorldCom overstated its profits by at least $3.8 billion by improperly classifying expenses as investments. When the true picture emerged, it resulted in the largest bankruptcy in U.S. history, at least until Lehman Brothers smashed that record in 2008. The next-largest U.S. bankruptcy was Enron, which used its now-­notorious “­special-purpose entities” to move debt off its own books and similarly ­present a misleading picture of its financial status. Unfortunately, these firms had plenty of company. Other firms such as Rite Aid, HealthSouth, Global Crossing, and Qwest Communications also manipulated and misstated their accounts to the tune of billions of dollars. And the scandals were hardly limited to the United States. Parmalat, the Italian dairy firm, claimed to have a $4.8 billion bank account that turned out not to exist. These episodes suggest that agency and incentive problems are far from solved, and that transparency is far from complete. Other scandals of that period included systematically misleading and overly optimistic research reports put out by stock market analysts. (Their favorable analysis was traded for the promise of future investment banking business, and analysts were commonly 9 10 PART I Introduction compensated not for their accuracy or insight, but for their role in garnering investment banking business for their firms.) Additionally, initial public offerings were allocated to corporate executives as a quid pro quo for personal favors or the promise to direct future business back to the manager of the IPO. What about the auditors who were supposed to be the watchdogs of the firms? Here too, incentives were skewed. Recent changes in business practice had made the consulting businesses of these firms more lucrative than the auditing function. For example, Enron’s (now-defunct) auditor Arthur Andersen earned more money ­consulting for Enron than by auditing it. Given Arthur Andersen’s incentive to protect its consulting profits, we should not be surprised that it was overly lenient in its auditing work. In 2002, in response to the spate of ethics scandals, Congress passed the S ­ arbanes– Oxley Act, commonly referred to as SOX, to tighten the rules of corporate governance and disclosure. For example, the act requires corporations to have more independent directors, that is, more directors who are not themselves managers (or affiliated with managers). The act also requires each CFO to personally vouch for the corporation’s accounting statements, provides for an ­ ­ oversight board to oversee the auditing of public companies, and prohibits auditors from providing various other services to clients. 1.4 The Investment Process Investors’ portfolios are simply their collections of investment assets. Once a portfolio is established, it is updated or “rebalanced” by selling existing securities and using the proceeds to buy new securities, by investing additional funds to increase the overall size of the portfolio, or by selling securities to decrease the size of the portfolio. Investment assets can be categorized into broad asset classes, such as stocks, bonds, real estate, commodities, and so on. Investors make two types of decisions in constructing their portfolios. The asset allocation decision is the choice among these broad asset classes, while the security selection decision is the choice of which particular securities to hold within each asset class. “Top-down” portfolio construction starts with asset allocation. For example, an individual who currently holds all of his money in a bank account would first decide what proportion of the overall portfolio ought to be moved into stocks, bonds, and so on. In this way, the broad features of the portfolio are established. For example, while the average annual return on the common stock of large firms since 1926 has been about 12% per year, the average return on U.S. Treasury bills has been less than 4%. On the other hand, stocks are far riskier, with annual returns (as measured by the Standard & Poor’s 500 index) that have ranged as low as –46% and as high as 55%. In contrast, T-bills are effectively risk-free: You know what interest rate you will earn when you buy them. Therefore, the decision to allocate your investments to the stock market or to the money market where Treasury bills are traded will have great ramifications for both the risk and the return of your portfolio. A top-down investor first makes this and other crucial asset allocation decisions before turning to the decision of the particular securities to be held in each asset class. CHAPTER 1 The Investment Environment Security analysis involves the valuation of particular securities that might be included in the portfolio. For example, an investor might ask whether Merck or Pfizer is more ­attractively priced. Both bonds and stocks must be evaluated for investment attractiveness, but valuation is far more difficult for stocks because a stock’s performance usually is far more sensitive to the prospects of the issuing firm. In contrast to top-down portfolio management is a “bottom-up” strategy in which the portfolio is constructed from securities that seem attractively priced without as much concern for the resultant asset allocation. Such a technique can result in unintended bets on one or another sector of the economy. For example, it might turn out that the portfolio ends up with a very heavy representation of firms in one industry, from one part of the country, or with exposure to one source of uncertainty. However, a bottom-up strategy does focus the portfolio on the assets that seem to offer the most attractive investment opportunities. 1.5 Markets Are Competitive Financial markets are highly competitive. Thousands of intelligent and well-backed analysts constantly scour securities markets searching for the best buys. This competition means that we should expect to find few, if any, “free lunches,” securities that are so underpriced that they represent obvious bargains. This no-free-lunch proposition has several implications. Let’s examine two. The Risk–Return Trade-Off Investors invest for anticipated future returns, but those returns rarely can be predicted precisely. There will almost always be risk associated with investments. Actual or realized returns will almost always deviate from the expected return anticipated at the start of the investment period. For example, in 1931 (the worst calendar year for the market since 1926), the S&P 500 index fell by 46%. In 1933 (the best year), the index gained 55%. You can be sure that investors did not anticipate such extreme performance at the start of either of these years. Naturally, if all else could be held equal, investors would prefer investments with the highest expected return.4 However, the no-free-lunch rule tells us that all else cannot be equal. If you want higher expected returns, you will have to pay a price in terms of accepting higher investment risk. If any particular asset offered a higher expected return imposing without extra risk, investors would rush to buy it, with the result that its price would be driven up. Individuals considering investing in the asset at the now-higher price will find the investment less attractive. The price will rise until expected return is no more than commensurate with risk. At this point, investors can anticipate a “fair” return relative to the asset’s risk, but no more. Similarly, 4 The “expected” return is not the return investors believe they necessarily will earn, or even their most likely return. It is instead the result of averaging across all possible outcomes, recognizing that some outcomes are more likely than others. It is the average rate of return across possible economic scenarios. 11 12 PART I Introduction if returns were independent of risk, there would be a rush to sell high-risk assets and their prices would fall. The assets would get cheaper (improving their expected future rates of return) until they eventually were attractive enough to be included again in investor portfolios. We conclude that there should be a risk–return trade-off in the securities markets, with higher-risk assets priced to offer higher expected returns than lower-risk assets. Of course, this discussion leaves several important questions unanswered. How should one measure the risk of an asset? What should be the quantitative trade-off between risk (properly measured) and expected return? One would think that risk would have something to do with the volatility of an asset’s returns, but this guess turns out to be only partly correct. When we mix assets into diversified portfolios, we need to consider the interplay among assets and the effect of diversification on the risk of the entire portfolio. ­Diversification means that many assets are held in the portfolio so that the exposure to any particular asset is limited. The effect of diversification on portfolio risk, the implications for the proper measurement of risk, and the risk–return relationship are the topics of Part Two. These topics are the subject of what has come to be known as modern portfolio theory. The development of this theory brought two of its pioneers, Harry Markowitz and William Sharpe, Nobel Prizes. Efficient Markets Another implication of the no-free-lunch proposition is that we should rarely expect to find bargains in the security markets. We will spend all of Chapter 11 examining the theory and evidence concerning the hypothesis that financial markets process all available information about securities quickly and efficiently, that is, that the security price usually reflects all the information available to investors concerning its value. According to this hypothesis, as new information about a security becomes available, its price quickly adjusts so that at any time, the security price equals the market consensus estimate of the value of the security. If this were so, there would be neither underpriced nor overpriced securities. One interesting implication of this “efficient market hypothesis” concerns the choice between active and passive investment-management strategies. Passive management calls for holding highly diversified portfolios without spending effort or other resources attempting to improve investment performance through security analysis. Active ­management is the attempt to improve performance either by identifying mispriced securities or by timing the performance of broad asset classes—for example, increasing one’s commitment to stocks when one is bullish on the stock market. If markets are efficient and prices reflect all relevant information, perhaps it is better to follow passive strategies instead of spending resources in a futile attempt to outguess your competitors in the financial markets. If the efficient market hypothesis were taken to the extreme, there would be no point in active security analysis; only fools would commit resources to actively analyze securities. Without ongoing security analysis, however, prices eventually would depart from “correct” values, creating new incentives for experts to move in. Therefore, even in ­environments as competitive as the financial markets, we may observe only near-­efficiency, and profit opportunities may exist for especially diligent and creative investors. In Chapter 12, we examine such challenges to the efficient market hypothesis, and this motivates our discussion of active portfolio management in Part Seven. Nevertheless, our discussions of security analysis and portfolio construction generally must account for the likelihood of nearly efficient markets. CHAPTER 1 1.6 The Investment Environment The Players From a bird’s-eye view, there would appear to be three major players in the financial markets: 1. Firms are net demanders of capital. They raise capital now to pay for investments in plant and equipment. The income generated by those real assets provides the returns to investors who purchase the securities issued by the firm. 2. Households typically are net suppliers of capital. They purchase the securities issued by firms that need to raise funds. 3. Governments can be borrowers or lenders, depending on the relationship between tax revenue and government expenditures. Since World War II, the U.S. government typically has run budget deficits, meaning that its tax receipts have been less than its expenditures. The government, therefore, has had to borrow funds to cover its budget deficit. Issuance of Treasury bills, notes, and bonds is the major way that the government borrows funds from the public. In contrast, in the latter part of the 1990s, the government enjoyed a short-lived budget surplus and was able to retire some ­outstanding debt. Corporations and governments do not sell all or even most of their securities directly to individuals. For example, about half of all stock is held by large financial institutions such as pension funds, mutual funds, insurance companies, and banks. These financial institutions stand between the security issuer (the firm) and the ultimate owner of the security (the individual investor). For this reason, they are called financial intermediaries. Similarly, corporations do not market their own securities to the public. Instead, they hire agents, called investment bankers, to represent them to the investing public. Let’s examine the roles of these intermediaries. Financial Intermediaries Households want desirable investments for their savings, yet the small (financial) size of most households makes direct investment difficult. A small investor seeking to lend money to businesses that need to finance investments doesn’t advertise in the local newspaper to find a willing and desirable borrower. Moreover, an individual lender would not be able to diversify across borrowers to reduce risk. Finally, an individual lender is not equipped to assess and monitor the credit risk of borrowers. For these reasons, financial intermediaries have evolved to bring the suppliers of capital (investors) together with the demanders of capital (primarily corporations and the ­federal government). These financial intermediaries include banks, investment companies, insurance companies, and credit unions. Financial intermediaries issue their own securities to raise funds to purchase the securities of other corporations. For example, a bank raises funds by borrowing (taking deposits) and lending that money to other borrowers. The spread between the interest rates paid to depositors and the rates charged to borrowers is the source of the bank’s profit. In this way, lenders and borrowers do not need to contact each other directly. Instead, each goes to the bank, which acts as an intermediary between the two. The problem of matching lenders with borrowers is solved when each comes independently to the common intermediary. Financial intermediaries are distinguished from other businesses in that both their assets and their liabilities are overwhelmingly financial. Table 1.3 presents the aggregated balance sheet of commercial banks, one of the largest sectors of financial intermediaries. Notice that the balance sheet includes only very small amounts of real assets. Compare Table 1.3 to the aggregated balance sheet of the nonfinancial corporate sector in Table 1.4, for which 13 14 PART I Introduction Assets Real assets Equipment and premises Other real estate Total real assets Financial assets Cash Investment securities Loans and leases Other financial assets Total financial assets Other assets Intangible assets Other Total other assets TOTAL $ Billion $ % Total 187.5 4.4 191.9 0.8% 0.0% 0.9% $ 3,628.6 5,479.3 10,610.7 1,371.4 $21,090.1 16.1% 24.3% 47.0% 6.1% 93.5% $ $ 392.0 890.2 $ 1,282.2 $22,564.2 1.7% 3.9% 5.7% 100.0% Liabilities and Net Worth $ Billion % Total $18,458.8 595.6 297.8 959.1 $20,311.2 81.8% 2.6% 1.3% 4.3% 90.0% $ 2,253.0 $22,564.2 10.0% 100.0% Liabilities and Net Worth $ Billion % Total Liabilities Debt securities Bank loans & mortgages Other loans Trade debt Other Total liabilities $ 7,387 1,772 2,077 3,121 10,319 $24,676 14.5% 3.5% 4.1% 6.1% 20.3% 48.5% $26,181 $50,856 51.5% 100.0% Liabilities Deposits Debt and other borrowed funds Federal funds and repurchase agreements Other Total liabilities Net worth Table 1.3 Balance sheet of FDIC-insured commercial banks and savings institutions Note: Column sums may differ from total because of rounding error. Source: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, www.fdic.gov, June 2021. Assets $ Billion % Total Real assets Equipment & intellectual property Real estate Inventories Total real assets $ 8,428 14,859 2,687 $25,974 16.6% 29.2% 5.3% 51.1% Financial assets Deposits and cash Marketable securities Trade and consumer credit Other Total financial assets TOTAL $ 2,326 4,032 4,296 14,229 $24,883 $50,856 4.6% 7.9% 8.4% 28.0% 48.9% 100.0% Net worth Table 1.4 Balance sheet of U.S. nonfinancial corporations Note: Column sums may differ from total because of rounding error. Source: Flow of Funds Accounts of the United States, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, June 2021. CHAPTER 1 The Investment Environment real assets are about half of all assets. The contrast arises because intermediaries simply move funds from one sector to another. In fact, the primary social function of such intermediaries is to channel household savings to the business sector. Other examples of financial intermediaries are investment companies, insurance companies, and credit unions. All these firms offer similar advantages in their intermediary role. First, by pooling the resources of many small investors, they are able to lend considerable sums to large borrowers. Second, by lending to many borrowers, intermediaries achieve significant diversification, so they can accept loans that individually might be too risky. Third, intermediaries build expertise through the volume of business they do and can use economies of scale and scope to assess and monitor risk. Investment companies, which pool and manage the money of many investors, also arise out of economies of scale. Here, the problem is that most household portfolios are not large enough to be spread across a wide variety of securities. In terms of brokerage fees and research costs, purchasing one or two shares of many different firms is very expensive. Mutual funds have the advantage of large-scale trading and portfolio management, while participating investors are assigned a prorated share of the total funds according to the size of their investment. This system gives small investors advantages they are willing to pay for via a management fee to the mutual fund operator. Investment companies also can design portfolios specifically for large investors with particular goals. In contrast, mutual funds are sold in the retail market, and their investment philosophies are differentiated mainly by strategies that are likely to attract a large number of clients. Like mutual funds, hedge funds also pool and invest the money of many clients. But they are open only to institutional investors such as pension funds or endowment funds, or to wealthy individuals. They are more likely to pursue complex and higher-risk strategies. They typically keep a portion of trading profits as part of their fees, whereas mutual funds charge a fixed percentage of assets under management. Economies of scale also explain the proliferation of analytic services available to investors. Newsletters, databases, and brokerage house research services all engage in research to be sold to a large client base. This setup arises naturally. Investors clearly want information, but with small portfolios to manage, they do not find it economical to personally gather all of it. Hence, a profit opportunity emerges: A firm can perform this service for many clients and charge for it. Investment Bankers Just as economies of scale and specialization create profit opportunities for financial ­intermediaries, these economies also create niches for firms that perform specialized ­services for businesses. Firms raise much of their capital by selling securities such as stocks and bonds to the public. Because these firms do not do so frequently, however, investment bankers that specialize in such activities can offer their services at a cost below that of maintaining an in-house security issuance division. In this role, they are called underwriters. Investment bankers advise the issuing corporation on the prices it can charge for the securities issued, appropriate interest rates, and so forth. Ultimately, the investment banking firm handles the marketing of the security in the primary market, where new issues of securities are offered to the public. Later, investors can trade previously issued securities among themselves in the so-called secondary market. For most of the last century, investment banks and commercial banks in the U.S. were separated by law. While those regulations were effectively eliminated in 1999, the industry 15 WORDS FROM THE STREET Separating Commercial Banking from Investment Banking Until 1999, the Glass-Steagall Act had prohibited banks in the United States from both accepting deposits and underwriting securities. In other words, it forced a separation of the investment and commercial banking industries. But when GlassSteagall was repealed, many large commercial banks began to transform themselves into “universal banks” that could offer a full range of commercial and investment banking services. In some cases, commercial banks started their own investment banking divisions from scratch, but more frequently they expanded through merger. For example, Chase Manhattan acquired J.P. Morgan to form JPMorgan Chase. Similarly, Citigroup acquired Salomon Smith Barney to offer wealth management, brokerage, investment banking, and asset management services to its clients. Most of Europe had never forced the separation of commercial and investment banking, so their giant banks such as Credit Suisse, Deutsche Bank, HSBC, and UBS had long been universal banks. Until 2008, however, the standalone investment banking sector in the U.S. remained large and apparently vibrant, including such storied names as Goldman Sachs, Morgan-Stanley, Merrill Lynch, and Lehman Brothers. But the industry was shaken to its core in 2008, when several investment banks were beset by enormous losses on their holdings of mortgage-backed securities. In March, on the verge of insolvency, Bear Stearns was merged into JPMorgan Chase. On September 14, 2008, Merrill Lynch, also suffering steep ­mortgage-related losses, negotiated an agreement to be acquired by Bank of America. The next day, Lehman Brothers entered into the largest bankruptcy in U.S. history, having failed to find an acquirer able and willing to rescue it from its steep losses. The next week, the only two remaining major independent investment banks, Goldman Sachs and Morgan Stanley, decided to convert from investment banks to traditional bank holding companies. In doing so, they became subject to the supervision of national bank regulators such as the Federal Reserve and the far tighter rules for capital adequacy that govern commercial banks. The firms decided that the greater stability they would enjoy as traditional banks, particularly the ability to fund their operations through bank deposits and access to emergency borrowing from the Fed, justified the conversion. These mergers and conversions marked the effective end of the independent investment banking industry—but not of investment banking. Those services are now supplied by the large universal banks. The debate about the separation between commercial and investment banking that seemed to have ended with the repeal of Glass-Steagall has come back to life. The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act places new restrictions on bank activities. For example, the Volcker Rule, named after former chair of the Federal Reserve Paul Volcker, prohibits banks from “proprietary trading,” that is, trading securities for their own accounts, and restricts their investments in hedge funds or private equity funds. The rule is meant to limit the risk that banks can take on. While the Volcker Rule is less restrictive than Glass-Steagall had been, they both are motivated by the belief that banks enjoying federal guarantees should be subject to limits on the sorts of activities in which they can engage. Proprietary trading is a core activity for investment banks, so limitations on this activity for commercial banks reintroduces a separation between these business models. However, these restrictions elicited pushback from the industry, which argued that it resulted in a brain drain of top traders from banks to hedge funds. In 2018, the Dodd-Frank bill was in effect partially repealed when new legislation granted all but the largest banks exemptions from some of its regulations. known as “Wall Street” until 2008 was still composed of large, independent investment banks such as Goldman Sachs, Merrill Lynch, and Lehman Brothers. But that stand-alone model came to an abrupt end in September 2008, when all the remaining major U.S. investment banks were absorbed into commercial banks, declared bankruptcy, or ­reorganized as commercial banks. The nearby box presents a brief introduction to these events. Venture Capital and Private Equity While large firms can raise funds directly from the stock and bond markets with help from their investment bankers, smaller and younger firms that have not yet issued securities to the public do not have that option. Start-up companies rely instead on bank loans and investors who are willing to invest in them in return for an ownership stake in the firm. The equity investment in these young companies is called venture capital (VC). Sources of venture capital are dedicated venture capital funds, wealthy individuals known as angel investors, and institutions such as pension funds. Most venture capital funds are set up as limited partnerships. A management company starts with its own money and raises additional capital from limited partners such as pension funds. That capital may then be invested in a variety of start-up companies. 16 CHAPTER 1 The Investment Environment The management company usually sits on the start-up company’s board of directors, helps recruit senior managers, and provides business advice. It charges a fee to the VC fund for overseeing the investments. After some period of time, for example, 10 years, the fund is liquidated and proceeds are distributed to the investors. Venture capital investors commonly take an active role in the management of a start-up firm. Other active investors may engage in similar hands-on management but focus instead on firms that are in distress or firms that may be bought up, “improved,” and sold for a profit. Collectively, these investments in firms that do not trade on public stock exchanges are known as private equity investments. Fintech, Financial Innovation, and Decentralized Finance Surveying the major actors on the financial scene highlighted in this section, it is clear that when the needs of market participants create profit opportunities, markets tend to evolve to provide those desired services. Sometimes, those innovations are spurred by technological advances that make possible previously infeasible products. Fintech is the application of technology to financial markets, and it has changed many aspects of the financial landscape. While we have focused on financial intermediaries, technology allowing individuals to interact directly has led to some financial disintermediation. This trend toward the elimination of the intermediary has been dubbed decentralized finance or DeFi. Peer-to-peer lending is a good example of a technology that can be used to link l­ enders and borrowers directly, without need of an intermediary like a commercial bank. One of the major players in this market is LendingClub, whose Web site allows borrowers to apply for personal loans up to $40,000 or business loans up to $300,000. The potential borrower is given a credit score, and then lenders (which the company calls investors) can decide whether to participate in the loan. LendingClub does not itself lend funds; instead, its platform provides information about borrowers and lenders and allows them to interact directly. Robo Advice While the very wealthy can afford to hire financial advisors, most investors do not have enough assets to justify that inevitably expensive guidance. Robo advisors seek to bring affordable advice to a wide swath of investors. You begin by filling out an online questionnaire about your financial situation and risk tolerance. A computer algorithm then recommends an investment portfolio, which usually will consist of low cost mutual or exchange-traded funds. It may also periodically rebalance your account as the value of each fund fluctuates. Blockchains We are all accustomed to financial transactions that are recorded in a centralized ledger. For example, your credit card company maintains a record, or database, of all of the purchases and payments you make through its network. Your bank maintains a ledger of deposits and withdrawals. Stock exchanges maintain a ledger of who has bought and sold stocks. These ledgers are centralized in the sense that they are administered by a particular trusted party running and hosting the database. By their nature, they do not allow for anonymity, and they can be targets of hackers. This is why the administrator must be trusted—in terms of both honesty and efficiency. In contrast, blockchains provide a record of transactions that is distributed over a network of connected computers. No single administrator controls it, so there is no single target for potential hackers to attack. Instead, the network sets up a protocol by which new transactions can be securely added to a public distributed ledger. The identities of 17 18 PART I Introduction each party to the transaction can be masked, allowing for anonymity. The ledger is essentially a list of transactions recorded in a “blockchain,” and each transaction results in a time-stamped update to the block. Distributing the blockchain across a dispersed network makes it harder for any hacker to attack its integrity. When the ledger is public, it is difficult to either bypass or manipulate the historical record of agreed-to transactions, and crucially, there is no need for the trusted administrator that lies at the heart of a centralized ledger. Blockchain technology is most associated with cryptocurrency such as Bitcoin (see following discussion), but it is ideally suited for a wider range of secure digital transactions. For example, they might include secure sharing of medical data or supply chain monitoring. Blockchains are probably best thought of more generally as databases that allow verification of information by a decentralized network of participants. As such, they can play a potentially large role in facilitating decentralized finance, providing data and enabling “smart contracts” in which software can authorize transactions in response to a particular triggering event without human intervention. Another recent blockchain innovation is the NFT, or non-fungible token, which is proof of ownership of a digital asset such as a digital work of art or even an original video of a sports event. Cryptocurrencies Cryptocurrencies, for example, Bitcoin or Ethereum, use blockchain technology to create payment systems that bypass traditional channels such as credit cards, debit cards, or checks. This alternative system offers greater security and anonymity for financial transactions. Bitcoin was introduced in 2009, but it has since been joined by many other digital currencies; in 2021, there were approximately 4,000 different cryptocurrencies. But many of these have essentially no or negligible trading volume and almost all are far smaller (in terms of total outstanding value) than Bitcoin or Ethereum. Cryptocurrency’s promise as an alternative to traditional currencies and payment systems still remains unclear. One challenge is price volatility, making it a problematic store of value. In 2021, for example, the dollar value of one bitcoin ranged from below $30,000 to more than $63,000. Another challenge is that transactions require enormous amounts of costly energy for the computers that validate those transactions. Moreover, the rate at which transactions can be validated remains miniscule compared to that offered by the traditional credit card network. These problems limit the efficacy of cryptocurrency as a means of exchange. A more recent innovation in this regard is the stablecoin. This is a cryptocurrency that the issuer pledges to redeem for a conventional currency (e.g., the U.S. dollar) on demand. The largest stablecoin today is Tether. Stable-dollar cryptocurrencies typically are backed by holdings of dollars, often held by a third-party custodian, which ensures the ability to convert into dollars. In other cases, the collateral might be other assets or cryptocurrencies, but that generally requires overcollaterization to compensate for the risk of fluctuations in the value of the collateral. Without adequate collateralization, stable coins are vulnerable to “runs” in which a wave of investors attempt to withdraw their money at once. The Fed and other regulators have expressed concern with the potential for runs and are considering new regulatory approaches to limit that risk. Governments are also concerned about the use of anonymous transactions to avoid taxes, enable trade in illegal items, or facilitate ransomware and have begun to step up their regulation of these markets. Notwithstanding these challenges, the technology is still new, and enthusiasts predict it will upend today’s financial landscape, allowing participants to avoid the fees and costs of dealing with more traditional centralized exchanges. CHAPTER 1 The Investment Environment Digital tokens A variation on cryptocurrency is the digital token issued in an initial coin offering, or ICO. The ICO is a source of crowdfunding in which start-up firms raise cash by selling digital tokens. The token is a form of cryptocurrency that can eventually be used to purchase products or services from the start-up. However, once issued, the coins can be bought or sold among investors like other digital currencies, thus allowing for speculation on their value. Given this potential, some have argued that these coins are in fact securities issued by the firm, and thus should be subject to SEC regulation. Some countries, for example China and South Korea, have banned ICOs altogether. It seems safe to predict that the legal status of these coins will evolve considerably in coming years. Digital currency As cryptocurrencies have become more familiar, sovereign governments have begun to contemplate developing digital currencies issued by their own central banks. For example, a government might pay tax refunds directly into its citizen’s digital wallets (rather than mailing checks or arranging for direct deposit into a conventional bank account). Similarly, citizens could pay bills by transferring funds from their wallets directly into those of their creditors. Like cryptocurrencies, this system would bypass the traditional financial system, as well as its associated fees and relatively slow clearing mechanisms. But unlike them, it would not be subject to the problem of fluctuating value. China is already running trials of a digital yuan, and the Fed announced in 2021 that it would study the feasibility of a digital currency for the United States. Some of the major unanswered questions for digital currency surround security, privacy, and government access to financial activity. Nevertheless, it seems possible that digital currencies will soon become part of the financial landscape. 1.7 The Financial Crisis of 2008–2009 This chapter has laid out the broad outlines of the financial system, as well as some of the links between the financial side of the economy and the “real” side in which goods and services are produced. The financial crisis of 2008 illustrated in a painful way the intimate ties between these two sectors. We present in this section a capsule summary of the crisis, attempting to draw some lessons about the role of the financial system as well as the causes and consequences of what has become known as systemic risk. Some of these issues are complicated; we consider them briefly here but will return to them in greater detail later in the text once we have more context for analysis. Antecedents of the Crisis In early 2007, most observers thought it inconceivable that within two years, the world financial system would be facing its worst crisis since the Great Depression. At the time, the economy seemed to be marching from strength to strength. The last significant macroeconomic threat had been from the implosion of the high-tech bubble in 2000–2002. But the Federal Reserve responded to an emerging recession by aggressively reducing interest rates. Figure 1.1 shows that Treasury bill rates dropped drastically between 2001 and 2004, and the LIBOR rate, which was the interest rate at which major money-center banks at the time loaned to each other, fell in tandem.5 These actions appeared to have been successful, and the recession was short-lived and mild. 5 LIBOR stands for London Interbank Offer Rate. It was until 2021 the major rate charged in an interbank lending market outside of the U.S. See Chapter 2 for a discussion of the phase-out of the LIBOR market. 19 20 PART I Introduction 8 3-month LIBOR 3-month T-Bill TED Spread 7 6 Percent 5 4 3 2 1 Jan-21 Jan-20 Jan-19 Jan-18 Jan-17 Jan-16 Jan-15 Jan-14 Jan-13 Jan-12 Jan-11 Jan-10 Jan-09 Jan-08 Jan-07 Jan-05 Jan-06 Jan-04 Jan-03 Jan-02 Jan-01 –1 Jan-00 0 Figure 1.1 Short-term LIBOR and Treasury-bill rates and the TED spread By mid-decade the economy was apparently healthy once again. Although the stock market had declined substantially between 2001 and 2002, Figure 1.2 shows that it reversed direction just as dramatically beginning in 2003, fully recovering all of its ­post-tech-meltdown losses within a few years. Of equal importance, the banking sector seemed healthy. The spread between the LIBOR rate (at which banks borrow from each other) and the Treasury-bill rate (at which the U.S. government borrows), a common measure of credit risk in the banking sector (often referred to as the TED spread 6), was only around .25% in early 2007 (see the bottom curve in Figure 1.1), suggesting that fears of default or “counterparty” risk in the banking sector were extremely low. Indeed, the apparent success of monetary policy in this recession, as well as in the last 30 years more generally, had engendered a new term, the “Great Moderation,” to describe the fact that recent business cycles—and recessions in particular—seemed so mild compared to past experience. Some observers wondered whether we had entered a golden age for macroeconomic policy in which the business cycle had been tamed. The combination of dramatically reduced interest rates and an apparently stable economy fed a historic boom in the housing market. Figure 1.3 shows that U.S. housing prices began rising noticeably in the late 1990s and accelerated dramatically after 2001 as interest rates plummeted. In the 10 years beginning in 1997, average prices in the U.S. approximately tripled. But the newfound confidence in the power of macroeconomic policy to reduce risk, the impressive recovery of the economy from the high-tech implosion, and particularly the housing price boom following the aggressive reduction in interest rates may have sown the seeds for the debacle that played out in 2008. On the one hand, the Fed’s policy of reducing interest rates had resulted in low yields on a wide variety of investments, and investors were hungry for higher-yielding alternatives. On the other hand, low volatility and optimism about macroeconomic prospects encouraged greater tolerance for risk in the 6 TED stands for Treasury–Eurodollar spread. The Eurodollar rate in this spread is in fact LIBOR. CHAPTER 1 The Investment Environment Cumulative value of a $1 investment 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 2022 2019 2016 2013 2010 2007 2004 2001 1998 1995 1992 1989 1986 1983 1980 0 Figure 1.2 Cumulative returns on the S&P 500 index Index (January 2000 = 100) 300 250 200 150 100 50 Figure 1.3 The Case-Shiller index of U.S. housing prices Source: Case Shiller Composite Housing Price Index, www.us.spindices.com. search for these higher-yielding investments. Nowhere was this more evident than in the exploding market for securitized mortgages. Changes in Housing Finance Prior to 1970, most mortgage loans would come from a local lender such as a neighborhood savings bank or credit union. A homeowner would borrow funds for a home purchase 2021 2019 2017 2015 2013 2011 2009 2007 2005 2003 2001 1999 1997 1995 1993 1991 1989 1987 0 21