Text for Ferro, E., J. Wilson and P. McConaghy (2015), Building the infrastructure for trade: developments in trade facilitation and aid-for-trade, Chapter 4 in O. Morrissey, R. Lopez and K. Sharma (Eds) Handbook on Trade and Development, Edward Elgar (pp. 62-86) Chapter 4 Building the Infrastructure for Trade: Developments in Trade Facilitation and Aid-for-Trade Esteban Ferro, John S. Wilson, and Peter McConaghy 4.1 Trade Facilitation: Components, Context, and Policy Priorities Over the past few years, a wealth of empirical evidence has been gathered on the relative effects of implementing policies designed to simplify and standardize trade. Moving goods from the farm or factory gate to markets overseas often involves a long and complicated supply chain, with the risk that a single bottleneck along the way can seriously affect the entire process. Connecting efficiently to markets is particularly critical for developing countries, whose firms and farmers typically do not enjoy a sufficient margin of international competitiveness to absorb high transaction costs. A firm’s ability to move its products across borders quickly, reliably, and cheaply can mean the difference between its success and failure in integrating into the global economy. Trade facilitation is associated with the reduction of at-the-border transaction costs other than tariffs, which essentially involves the simplification and standardization of customs formalities and administrative procedures related to international trade (Portugal-Perez and Wilson 2012). In the past few years there has been renewed interest in trade costs and trade facilitation for two main reasons. The first is that today’s international trade landscape is increasingly characterized by global value chains that span national boundaries. Intermediate inputs now represent more than half of the goods imported by OECD countries and close to three-fourths of the imports of large developing economies, such as China and Brazil (Draper et al. 2012). The rise of global value chains and trade in intermediate inputs is connected to the 1 decreases in traditional tariff barriers across all countries. Now the focus has moved to reducing costs of trade elsewhere. The second reason for the renewed interest in trade facilitation is the realization that trade liberalization has not had the expected positive impact on developing countries’ exports. The Uruguay Round of the WTO successfully reduced tariff rates in both developed and developing countries alike. Even with preferential treatment negotiated in the Uruguay Round, least developed countries have not been able to increase their exports to foreign markets. On the contrary, least developed countries now have a lower share of total trade than they did a decade ago (UNCTAD 2011). Trade costs are falling faster in developed than developing countries, which makes integrating poorer countries into the world economy even more challenging (Arvis et al, 2013). Trade liberalization creates opportunities for development. However, other factors including trade costs (see Chapter 4 this volume) determine the extent to which trade opportunities are realized. Within this context, expanding trade through lowering transaction costs and providing developing countries with technical assistance on implementing reforms to lower trade costs have become prominent in the trade policy dialogue. With increased attention placed on the importance of lowering trade costs, there has been increased emphasis on enabling and financing trade facilitation reforms. These efforts have coalesced around global aid-for-trade initiatives which are part of the Doha Development Round of the World Trade Organization (WTO). Aid-for-trade aims at helping developing countries, particularly least-developed countries, establish the trade-related skills and infrastructure that is needed to implement and benefit from WTO agreements and to expand their trade (WTO 2011). Aid-for-trade commitments have increased steadily, from USD 15 billion in 2000 to USD 45 billion in 2010. However, as will be addressed later in this chapter, the impact of this aid is debatable. This chapter presents an overview of key concepts associated with trade facilitation in the context of current economic conditions, shifts in the global economy, and movements in the broader international trade policy agenda. The chapter covers definitions (Section 4.2), analytical and conceptual frameworks measuring trade facilitation and the effects (Section 4.3) and assesses global aid-for-trade efforts (Section 4.4). It also provides a survey of the empirical 2 literature for both topics, providing a snapshot of where data and theory stands in explaining trade facilitation and aid-for-trade interventions. Empirical analysis presented gives particular attention to the proposed gains from implementing trade facilitation reform. Empirical evidence and analytical concepts are presented in the following areas of trade facilitation: customs procedures and border protection, transport and transit costs, information and communications technology, and the role of product standards and technical regulations on trade flows. The chapter concludes in Section 4.5 with a discussion of policy priorities for developing countries moving forward. The literature presented here should assist policymakers, development practitioners, researchers, and public and private officials to understand core concepts and key developments related to trade facilitation and global aid-for-trade initiatives. This information should help stakeholders prioritize trade facilitation reform, structure global aid-for-trade interventions, and better understand what works and why. This knowledge will prove increasingly important as trade costs and trade facilitation play an ever larger role in the global trade policy arena, and as global economic structures continue to shift towards greater integration and a heavier reliance on supply chains. 4.2 Defining Trade Facilitation There is no single definition of trade facilitation, contributing to the complexity of understanding and measuring the costs associated with it. The term can be widely defined as any policy measure set to diminish trade costs. The WTO refers to trade facilitation as “the simplification and harmonization of international trade procedures.” Wilson et al. (2003) offer an early review of the definition. In a narrow sense, trade facilitation simply addresses the logistics of moving goods through ports or customs at the border. A broader definition includes the environment in which trade transactions take place, including the transparency of regulatory environments, harmonization of standards, and conformance to international or regional regulations (Wilson et al. 2003). More recently, trade facilitation has been thought of along two dimensions: investment in “hard” versus “soft” infrastructure. Hard infrastructure refers to tangible infrastructure such as 3 roads, highways, ports, and railroads while soft infrastructure refers to dimensions related to transparency, customs management, the business environment, and other, less tangible institutional variables (Portugal-Perez and Wilson 2012; see Figure 4.1). Defining trade facilitation along the lines of its hard and soft dimensions makes it easier to compare the benefits and costs of investment and policy reform. Figure 4.1 about here The various definitions of trade facilitation share common elements of simplification, harmonization, and transparency of procedures associated with international trade. As an example of the links between transparency and trade facilitation, two of the three GATT articles on trade facilitation (Article VIII and Article X) explicitly promote transparency in the application and publication of trade policy instrument (Helble et al. 2007). Another element common to the definitions is that of customs management. Customs management refers to a broad array of procedures and techniques including the aims of simplifying, harmonizing, and providing due process for such procedures. Trade facilitation definitions also generally highlight regulatory issues that underpin a country’s trading system with the highlight being on developing a regulatory environment that promotes efficient and transparent trading structures. 4 Box 4.1 The Evolving Definitions of Trade Facilitation Community of Eastern and Southern Africa (COMESA): Trade facilitation means the coordination and rationalization of trade procedures and documents relating to the movement of goods from their place of origin to their destination [and] trade procedures means activities related to the collection, presentation, processing and dissemination of data and information concerning all activities constituting international trade (COMESA Treaty 1994, Chapter 2 Article 2). Asia Pacific Economic Cooperation (APEC): The use of technologies and techniques which will help members to build up expertise, reduce costs and lead to better movement of goods and services (APEC Economic Committee 1999). Trade facilitation generally refers to the simplification, harmonization, use of new technologies, and other measures to address procedural and administrative impediments to trade (APEC Principles on Trade Facilitation 2002). World Trade Organization (WTO) and United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD): Simplification and harmonization of international trade procedures, including activities, practices, and formalities involved in collecting, presenting, communicating, and processing data required for the movement of goods in international trade (WTO website and UNCTAD, E-Commerce and Development Report 2001, p 180). Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD): Simplification and standardization of procedures and associated information flows required to move goods internationally from seller to buyer and to pass payments in the other direction (OECD, TD/TC/WP(2001)21 attributed to John Raven). United Nations Economic Commission for Europe (UNECA): A comprehensive and integrated approach to reducing the complexity and cost of the trade transaction process, and ensuring that all these activities can take place in an efficient, transparent, and predictable manner, based on internationally accepted standards, and best practices (UNECA draft document 3/13/2002). Sources: Wilson et al. (2002) and authors 5 4.3 Measuring Trade Facilitation Measuring trade costs and the associated benefits to trade facilitation remains an evolving challenge for researchers. Direct measures of trade costs are available for a few components such as transportation and insurance costs, and policy barriers such as tariffs, but not for other components such as bureaucratic red tape (Chen and Novy 2012)) and non-tariff barriers. In addition, data coverage is often limited to a few countries, industries, products or years (Anderson and van Wincoop, 2004). With this being said, in recent years there has been significant progress made in collecting relevant data and in applying innovative empirical techniques to measure the impact of trade facilitation on trade flows. Data Sources to Measure Trade Facilitation Although researchers are still limited by data availability, there is an increasingly large set of data available to measure the trade costs that can be reduced by trade facilitation. Data generally captures the complexity and cost of trading, from the time and cost of moving product through customs to the quality of infrastructure such as ports and roads needed to support trading measures. The World Bank Doing Business Surveys and the Logistics Performance Index are two data sources commonly used to measure trade facilitation. Other sources include indicators compiled from the World Economic Forum’s Global Competitiveness Report, the World Bank’s World Development Indicators, governance indicators from Transparency International, national level customs data, and increasingly, firm-level data. The Doing Business Surveys rank economies on the ease of doing business based on the simple average of the percentile rankings on ten topics including starting a business, dealing with construction permits, registering property, getting credit, protecting investors, and paying taxes. Recent data from the World Bank’s 2012 Doing Business Report dataset show the wide variety of national experiences in this area, both in terms of procedural complexity and cost. As can be seen from Figures 4.2 and 4.3, OECD countries generally impose fewer barriers (i.e., number of documents or border procedures required for export) and are more efficient (i.e., number of days) at exporting goods than developing countries. Among the developing regions, it is Latin America and the Caribbean which comes closest to the procedure and cost levels observed in the OECD. 6 Sub-Saharan Africa tends to have the weakest performance both on cost and the number of procedures. Figures 4.2 & 4.3 about here The Logistics Performance Index (LPI) is based on a worldwide survey of operators on the ground (global freight forwarders and express carriers), providing feedback on the logistics “friendliness” of the countries in which they operate and those with which they trade. They combine in-depth knowledge of the countries in which they operate with informed qualitative assessments of other countries with which they trade. The LPI is the weighted average of the country scores on six key dimensions: efficiency of the clearance process, quality of trade and transport-related infrastructure, ease of arranging competitively priced shipments, competence and quality of logistics services, ability to track and trace consignments, and timeliness of shipments in reaching a destination within the scheduled or expected delivery time. As demonstrated by Figure 4.4, infrastructure has been a key area of progress for countries across income levels since 2007. Figure 4.4 about here Regarding the methodology used to measure the impact of trade facilitation on trade the gravity model first developed by Tinbergen (1962) is generally the theoretical foundation for much of the empirical work being done on trade facilitation. The traditional gravity model drew on analogy with Newton's Law of Gravitation. A mass of goods or labor or other factors of production supplied at origin i, Yi, is attracted to a mass of demand for goods or labor at destination j, Ej, but the potential flow is reduced by the distance between them, dij. Strictly applying the analogy, bilateral trade is defined as Xij = YiEj/dij and is modelled accordingly. Anderson (1979) and Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) developed the theoretical framework for the gravity model based on microeconomic foundations which gave the model even more popularity for empirical applications. To date, the gravity model is the workhorse for the empirical literature on trade facilitation and trade costs (see Chapter 4 this volume). Most of the studies described in the following section make use of the gravity model in one way or another. 7 4.4 Quantifying the Effects of Trade Facilitation Empirical research assessing the impact of trade facilitation has to address three issues: defining and measuring trade facilitation indicators; choosing an econometric methodology to estimate the impact of trade facilitation on trade flows; and designing a scenario to estimate the effect of improved trade facilitation on trade flows (Portugal-Perez and Wilson 2012). In order to review the existing trade facilitation literature we will break up the studies based on how they define trade facilitation. Most studies take a narrow view of trade facilitation and concentrate on analyzing the impact of one specific aspect of trade facilitation on trade flows. For example, Hummels (2007) has a series of papers that analyze the impact of transportation costs; Freund and Weinhold (2004) analyze the impact of ICT; and Wilson with several co-authors analyze the impact of product standards on trade flows. These are reviewed below under the respective narrow concepts used. A number of studies make use of a broader definition of trade facilitation and build these and other variables — such as institutional quality — into their frameworks. These are reviewed in the second part of this section. Transport and Transit Costs Given the importance of complex modern supply chains, the cost of transport features heavily in international trade. Whenever it is necessary to move goods physically from one place to another, there are transport costs to be borne. There are three primary factors that influence transport costs. First, the availability and quality of underlying infrastructure influences the overall cost of transport services. For example, deficient road infrastructure adds time and cost to moving goods. Second, the level of competition in the transport sector can affect the price that end users pay for transport services. In a market with limited competition and high barriers to entry, service providers can drive a wedge between the prices they charge and the costs they incur. Increasing competition and promoting transparent regulation can help reduce rents incurred by providers and decrease overall transport costs. Third, economies of scale and positive network externalities are important factors to consider, especially for poor and small countries. Economies of scale are accrued by many users relying on transport infrastructure and can help decrease costs. Ensuring compatibility with international standards can act as a positive 8 network externality and can help bring down overall transport costs. Developing regional transport hubs can have the same effect. Hummels (2007) shows that air transport has become significantly cheaper compared with sea transport, which has remained at a fairly constant cost level over recent decades. As a result, trade via air freight has increased rapidly, both in absolute terms and relative to trade via ocean shipping. Hummels (2007) also shows that although some transport costs have fallen, they have not gone down as quickly as other costs affecting international trade, such as tariffs. Hummels’ work is essential to explaining how advancements in technology have significantly contributed to declining transport costs which in turn promote trade and integration. Geography can play an important role in determining overall transport and transit costs. For example, there is strong evidence that shows that being geographically landlocked greatly increases the costs of transporting goods. MacKellar et al (2002) find that the cost of shipment for a landlocked country is double that of other countries. Similarly, according to Limao and Venables (2001) being landlocked reduces exports by 30%. MacKellar et al (2002) find that being landlocked lowers economic growth by 1.5% per year on average. Policy measures can greatly influence the overall cost of being landlocked. Mattoo et al (2012) found a troubling pattern: many landlocked African countries restrict trade in the very services that connect them with the rest of the world. On average, telecommunications and airtransport policies are significantly more restrictive in landlocked countries than elsewhere. Lack of or poor policy decisions compound the cost of transit, resulting in inadequate transport infrastructure, absent or ineffective insurance policies and trade finance (in particular at regional level), weak border infrastructure which creates queues and bottlenecks, lack of cooperation between customs authorities of neighboring countries and among government agencies at the border, and weak institutions and cooperation with the private sector along transit corridors. Customs Procedures and Border Protection National customs administrators can significantly impact the overall level of trade costs facing importers and exporters. Delays can translate into additional trade expenses. Customs administrators have responsibilities that can greatly impact trade costs. They apply the correct rate of duty based on an analysis of product characteristics and origin, in addition to respecting any non-tariff barriers that may be relevant. In cooperation with health and quarantine 9 authorities, national customs agencies are usually also involved in ensuring that imported goods do not violate certain national standards. They will often also cooperate with law enforcement agencies in an effort to detect and deal with shipments of contraband, or potential security threats. Moreover, customs and other border agencies sometimes levy service fees that must be paid by traders, in addition to the usual direct charges of loading and unloading merchandise at the port. Economies that have made significant improvements to the customs environment have streamlined customs procedures through adopting electronic data interchange systems. This allows traders to exchange information with customs and other control agencies electronically. For example, procedural improvements in East Africa have reduced the average clearance time for cargo crossing the Kenya-Uganda border from almost two days to only seven hours (qtd. In Al-Madani et al 2012). Electronic processing of customs documentation saves time and money, and decreases bureaucratic obstacles and opportunities for graft by reducing interactions with officials. Economies are also linking agencies through an electronic single window, which allows traders to file standard information and documents through a single entry point to fulfill all import, export, and transit-related regulatory requirements. Other steps to maximize efficiency of customs procedures include promoting transparency through prompt publication and providing easy access to documentation requirements. Similarly, customs administrations are increasingly moving to risk-based inspection systems whereby physical inspections are conducted based on the potential risk of consignments. This enhances efficiency by focusing customs examinations on the set of products deemed to be most risky. Customs Procedures and Border Protection: Empirical Evidence A number of studies have examined the effect of improved customs procedures on trade flows. Yang (2008) examines developing countries that have hired private firms to conduct preshipment inspections of imports and finds that countries implementing such inspection programs subsequently experience large increases in import duty collections. He finds these programs are often cost effective, with improvements in import duty collections in the first five years of a typical inspection program amounting to 2.6 times the program’s costs. Although his findings speak to the effectiveness of pre-shipment inspections, he finds the growth rate of tax revenues 10 does not change appreciably with the introduction of private firms conducting pre-shipment inspections. Arson, Cadot, and Olarreaga (2006) build a model highlighting the contribution of private surveillance firms to the generation of information. Their model describes how incentives for under-invoicing and collusive behavior between importers and customs are affected by the introduction of pre-shipment inspections (PSI). Theoretically the introduction of PSI has an ambiguous effect on the level of fraud. Empirically, however, econometric results suggest that the introduction of PSI services increased under-invoicing in Argentina and Indonesia and reduced it in the Philippines. Overall the authors’ findings suggest surveillance and monitoring and procedural streamlining are an important component of implementing PSI systems. Other studies show the detrimental effects of time delays on trade flows. Using a dataset on the days it takes to move standard cargo from the factory gate to the ship in 98 countries, Djankov et al. (2010) used a difference gravity equation to estimate the effects of trade costs on trade. The difference gravity equation evaluates the effect of time delays on the relative exports of countries with similar endowments and geography and facing the same tariffs in importing countries. Comparing exports from similar countries to the same importer allows them to difference out importer effects, such as remoteness and tariffs, which are important to trade. For example, they examine whether Brazilian/Argentine exports to the United States are decreasing in Brazilian/Argentine time costs of trade, after controlling for the standard determinants of trade, such as relative size, relative distance, and relative income. The authors find that for every additional day that a product is delayed, trade is reduced by at least one per cent. Sadikov (2007) finds that signatures and registration procedures reduce overall exports by increasing transaction costs although the impact varies across goods as differentiated products are more sensitive to trade procedures than export volumes of homogeneous goods (Martinez-Zarzoso and MarquezRamos (2008) find similar results). Using detailed data on transit, documentation, and ports and customs delays on Africa’s exports collected by Doing Business at the World Bank, Freund and Rocha (2010) examine the effects of transit, documentation, and ports and customs delays on Africa’s exports. The authors find that transit delays have the most economically and statistically significant effect on exports: a one-day reduction in inland travel time leads to a seven per cent increase in exports. Put 11 another way, a one day reduction in inland travel time translates to a 1.5 percentage point decrease in all importing-country tariffs. Information and Communications Services Telecommunication services are crucial to ensuring that traders can effectively develop and share information required to trade. Advances in technology including the internet, mobile and landline phone use, and IT-enabled services (broadcasting, radio) have significantly altered how firms trade and exchange information, and how governments create enabling and regulatory environments for trade. Over the past decade developing countries have seen rapid growth in their use of information and communications technology (ICT), particularly in the proliferation of mobile telephony, broadband connectivity, and IT-enabled services (broadcasting, radio). For example, mobile phone access has increased to 30.9 billion people in 2010 (a 68% penetration rate) up from 0.3 billion (a 4.4% penetration rate) in 2000 (World Bank 2011). Hummels (2007) suggests that the rapid proliferation of ICT has created a third era in cross-border trade, whereby people across great distances are being connected, altering both trading patterns and the way in which countries integrate. By enhancing efficiencies and promoting access to markets and capital, ICT has the opportunity to improve delivery of both public and private services to the underserved. It also has the potential to make trading cheaper because it is now easier than before to obtain information on foreign market conditions, product standards, and consumer preferences. Freund and Weinhold (2004) provide the first empirical evidence in support of this dynamic. They find that a 10% increase in the number of a country’s web hosts is associated with an export gain of around 0.2%. Although this effect is statistically significant, it is relatively small in economic terms. The authors also find that the development of the internet does not seem to have brought about any significant changes in the impact of distance on trade. This finding is in line with the scenario in which the internet helps facilitate information exchange and makes it easier for firms to enter a market, but cannot alter variable costs as captured by distance (Wilson and Maur (2011) and Ferro (2011)). Fink, Mattoo and Neagu (2005) seek to provide empirical evidence for the intuition that communication costs contribute to trade costs. The authors also seek to examine whether the inclusion of the magnitude and variation of communication costs across partner countries can 12 add value to existing explanations of the pattern of trade. The authors develop a simple multisector model of "impeded" trade that generates hypotheses in a gravity-type estimation framework. The authors find that international variations in communication costs have a significant influence on bilateral trade flows. Using the Rauch classification of product heterogeneity, the estimates suggest that the impact of communication costs on trade in differentiated products is as much as one-third larger than on trade in homogenous products. Product Standards and Technical Regulations The importance of standards and technical barriers to trade (TBT) on international trade patterns has increased in recent years, in large part because of increasing consumer concerns surrounding food and product safety, greater participation in global value chains by emerging markets, and decreases in traditional tariff barriers across all countries. Standards and TBT include technical regulations, conformity assessment procedures, and compliance restrictions. They can help facilitate trade by promoting interoperability and ensuring product safety and environmental stewardship. Outdated and overly burdensome standards-related measures, however, can reduce competition, limit innovation, and increase trading costs. They can impose additional costs on exporters to the extent that it is necessary to alter production processes in order to comply with such rules in the importing country. What is the impact of standards on trade flows? Chen et al. (2006) draw on the World Bank Technical Barriers to Trade Survey database, which includes 619 firms in 17 developing countries. Their results suggest that technical regulation of industrial countries have a negative effect on the propensity of developing country firms to export. They estimate that testing procedures and lengthy inspections cause exports from the developing countries included in the sample to drop by nine percent and three percent respectively. It is also estimated that standards – in particular standards that differ across foreign countries – reduce developing country firms’ propensity to export, impeding market entry, and lowering the likelihood that these firms will export to more than three markets by seven percent. Results presented by Kee et al. (2009) suggest that poor countries (and those with the highest poverty headcount) tend to be more restrictive, but they also face the highest trade barriers on their export bundle. This is partly explained by the fact that agriculture protection is generally larger than manufacturing protection. Non-tariff barriers including TBTs contribute more than 70 percent on average to 13 world protection, underlying their importance for any study on trade protection. More recently, Ferro et al. (2013) similarly find that stricter standards on agricultural imports decrease the propensity to trade. This detrimental effect is greater for exports originating in developing countries compared to those from developed and middle income countries. Other research focused on the effect of standards and TBT has found they can have trade enhancing effects. Portugal-Perez, Reyes, and Wilson (2010) used a database of European standards for electronic products collected by the World Bank to estimate the net impact of internationally harmonized European standards on European Union (EU) imports of electronics. Their main finding is that internationally harmonized EU standards expand EU imports of electronic products. Conversely, European standards that are not aligned with international norms have a lower effect on EU imports, or even a negative one. Overall, these results suggest that standards harmonization is an important element of coordinating international trade and promoting compatibility and quality assurance. Chen and Mattoo (2008) have investigated the relationships between regional agreements, standards, and trade. Using a constructed panel data that identifies the different types of agreements at the industry level and applying it using a modified Heckman two-stage estimator with the control of multiple fixed effects, the authors find that regional agreements increase the trade between participating countries but not necessarily with the rest of the world. Harmonizing standards may reduce the exports of excluded countries, especially in markets that have raised the stringency of standards. Mutual recognition agreements, on the other hand, are more uniformly trade promoting unless they contain restrictive rules of origin, in which case intraregional trade increases at the expense of imports from other countries. A topic of increasing attention is the effects of imposing domestic versus internationally recognized standards on trade. Mangelsdorf, Portugal-Perez, and Wilson (2012) examines how food safety standards set domestically affect China’s export performance. The results show that one additional international harmonized standard leads to a 0.38 to 0.64 percent increase in food exports, equivalent to $114 to $193 million. The results also suggest that standards in China that are harmonized to international ones have a larger impact on exports than purely domestic Chinese standards. The larger impact of international standards over domestic ones can in part be explained by the fact that international standards signal certain common quality and safety 14 guarantees that domestic standards may not. This finding is also echoed in Czubala, Shepherd, and Wilson (2009), where the authors use a sample-selection gravity model to examine the impact of EU standards on African textiles and clothing exports. The authors find robust evidence that non-harmonized standards reduce African exports of these products. EU standards which are harmonized to ISO standards are less trade restricting, suggesting that efforts to promote African exports on manufacturers may need to be complemented by measures to reduce the cost of harmonizing standards. Studies with a Broad Definition of Trade Facilitation The methodology proposed by Wilson, Mann, and Otsuki (2003) was the first to measure the impact of trade facilitation on trade performance using a gravity model. Thus, their work has highlighted the overall economic importance of trade facilitation in the process of further international economic integration. They developed an approach estimating the gains to reform in the area of trade transaction costs, focusing on four dimensions of trade facilitation: port infrastructure, customs environment, regulatory environment, and e-business infrastructure. They constructed four indicators for Asia Pacific Economic Cooperation (APEC) countries for a single year by applying single averages to 13 primary variables, which were mostly collected from the World Economic Forum. Using model estimates, the authors find that intra-APEC trade could increase by US$254 billion, or 21% of intra- APEC trade flows, if APEC members with belowaverage indicators improved capacity halfway to the average for all members, about half the increase being derived from improved port efficiency. Table 4.1 presents country-specific gains from the gravity model analysis in Wilson et al. (2003). Table 4.1 about here Subsequently, Wilson, Mann, and Otsuki (2005) repeat this methodology for 75 countries worldwide using a more robust set of indicators. Each of the four trade facilitation measures is constructed from two survey data inputs to avoid depending too heavily on any one survey question or source. Using simulations based on their gravity model, they find that the total gain 15 in trade flows in manufacturing goods from improvements in trade facilitation halfway to the global average level yields an increase in global trade of $US377 billion. Developing adequate institutions to facilitate trade has been the focus of recent research. Francois and Manchin (2007) examine the influence of infrastructure, institutional quality, colonial and geographic context, and trade preferences on the pattern of bilateral trade. They use principle components to construct two indicators on infrastructure and two indicators on institutional quality from various primary indicators, and find that infrastructure and institutional quality are significant determinants not only of export levels, but also of the likelihood exports will take place at all. Their results support the notion that export performance, and the propensity to take part in the trading system, depends on institutional quality and access to well-developed transport and communications infrastructure. Finally, Portugal-Perez and Wilson (2012) estimate the impact on the export performance of developing countries of trade facilitation measures along a “hard” and “soft” dimension first outlined in Wilson, Mann, and Otsuki (2005). The authors construct four new aggregate indicators related to trade facilitation from a wide range of primary indicators using factor analysis, a statistical modeling technique that explains the correlation among a set of observed variables through unobserved “common factors” (Figure 4.1). Estimates show that trade facilitation reforms do improve the export performance of developing countries. This is particularly true with investment in physical infrastructure and regulatory reform to improve the business environment. The findings provide evidence that the marginal effect of the transport efficiency and business environment improvement on exports appears to be decreasing in per capita income. In contrast, the impact of physical infrastructure and information and communications technology on exports appears increasingly important the richer a country becomes. The authors also find statistical evidence on the complementarity between hard infrastructure and soft infrastructure. Trade Facilitation and the Extensive Margin of Trade All the above studies concentrate on the impact of trade facilitation on the intensive margin of trade (or the amount of trade by value or volume). There are few studies that investigate the effects of trade facilitation on the extensive margin of trade (or the breadth of trade in terms of 16 number of exporting firms, export diversity, or destination markets). Research reveals considerable developmental benefits from broadening an economy’s extensive margin of trade through export diversification – from insulating an economy from external demand shocks to facilitating movement up the value chain. With specific regard to trade facilitation, Dennis and Shepherd (2011) and Persson (2012), use the number of exported products as a measure of the extensive margin. Both studies find that inefficient trade procedures are associated with fewer export products. Persson (2012) further finds that this negative effect is more pronounced for differentiated products than it is for homogeneous goods. Shepherd (2010) focuses on geographical diversification rather than product diversification, and concludes that trade facilitation also has the potential to increase the number of export markets. 4.4 Aid for Trade The previous sections demonstrated the extensive evidence of the benefits of a responsive, predictable and simple trade environment. The impact of improved ports, modernized customs, and reduced red tape on the trade intensity of countries is clear. Better trade facilitation results in greater trade, and allows more firms to reach more destinations with more products. Thus, trade facilitation provides policies necessary for export-led growth and diversification, an important component of overall economic development for developing countries. It comes as no surprise then that development agencies all over the world have been pushing for public investment and foreign aid to target trade facilitation. Aid for trade, thus, is financial and technical assistance that facilitates the integration of developing countries into the global economy through initiatives that expand trade (Wilson and Hoekman 2010). Aid for trade is an integral part of regular official development assistance (ODA). Donors have been providing substantial amounts of aid to trade-related programs for many years. However, the scope of aid for trade has expanded considerably. During the 1986-1994 Uruguay Round of trade negotiations, trade related assistance was mainly aimed at technical support to help developing countries negotiate and implement trade agreements. Subsequently, the scope expanded to include building supply-side capacities, for instance in private sector development and trade-related infrastructure. Now the agenda also includes trade-related structural adjustment programs and other trade-related needs (OECD/WTO 2006). 17 The Doha Round of World Trade Organization (WTO) negotiations that started in 2001 were based on the recognition that trade liberalization alone was not enough for the development prospects of many low-income countries. Some developing countries could not benefit from a multilateral liberalization based on reciprocal market access, or even from preferential market access, because they would need to incur additional costs in order to realize the full benefits of new market opportunities. In many cases they lack the necessary exporting infrastructure (e.g. efficient ports, adequate roads, reliable electricity and communications) or lack the necessary technology and knowledge to meet product standards prevailing in high value markets (sanitary measures, technical barriers, certification, etc.). To benefit from liberalization developing countries would need to make public investments in infrastructure and institutions as well as private investment in productive capacity. During the 2005 Hong Kong Ministerial Conference of the Doha Development Agenda, the World Bank (WB) and the International Monetary Fund (IMF) led a taskforce that proposed the “Aid for Trade” initiative. The initiative was aimed at supporting the development of trade in developing countries. The aid for trade agenda stemmed from two considerations. First, the need for adequate trade related assistance to mitigate the detrimental effects of further multilateral trade liberalization from the Doha Round. Liberalization incurs adjustment costs as resources are moved from one sector to another in the process of reform. Whereas it may take decades for multilateral trade reform to deliver gains to developing countries, the adjustment costs are automatic and usually upfront. Several developing countries, most notably preference receiving and net food importing countries, are likely to face further costs to adjust to a more liberalized trading system (e.g., increase in food imports, loss of tariff revenues, increased import competition). The second consideration was that for developing countries, the necessary investments to develop their trade environment to overcome supply-side constraints are particularly large and the faculty to meet them is particularly small. Within this enlarged framework, G8 countries at Gleneagles committed to doubling 2005 volumes of Aid for Trade before the year 2010; furthermore they agreed that the initiative had to be used as a complement to the Doha Round, not as a substitute for market access during negotiations. Since its inception, aid for trade has been integrated into broader development strategies, with objectives focusing on competitiveness, economic growth and poverty reduction. Donors are harmonizing their 18 procedures and aligning their support around these strategies. Aid-for-trade flows continue to grow and reached USD 40 billion in 2009 – an increase of 60% since 2005. Scope of Aid for Trade Trade is not a sector – it covers a wide range of activities and encompasses both goods and services. Thus, the scope of aid for trade is likewise broad and difficult to define. The WTO Task Force concluded that for the purposes of measuring the volume of aid-for-trade flows and assessing additionality ODA includes aid for the following categories: i) Technical assistance for trade policy and regulations: for example, helping countries to develop trade strategies, negotiate trade agreements, and implement their outcomes; ii) Trade-related infrastructure: for example, building roads, ports, and telecommunications networks to connect domestic markets to the global economy; iii) Productive capacity building (including trade development): for example, supporting the private sector to exploit their comparative advantages and diversify their exports; iv) Trade-related adjustment: helping developing countries with the costs associated with trade liberalization, such as tariff reductions, preference erosion, or declining terms-oftrade; and, v) Other trade-related needs: if identified as trade-related development priorities in partner countries’ national development strategies. Within each category there can be great diversity in program or project types as well as in feasible valuation approaches and metrics (OECD, 2007). Some donors adopt a narrow definition of the aid-for-trade agenda (e.g. only trade policy and regulation and trade development), while for others it consists of a broader subset of activities identified by the Task Force. Basing the monitoring of aid for trade on the OECD Creditor Reporting System (CRS) implies that all aidfunded investments in transport, energy and telecommunications are considered to be traderelated. However, such investments have or could have outcomes that are not primarily traderelated. This raises the question of how to evaluate programs and projects that are not primarily trade-related, but are part of the broader aid-for-trade agenda as depicted in Figure 4.5. Some 19 assistance from multilateral and regional development banks (i.e. investments in the tradable sector and trade finance) takes the form of non-concessional lending or low concessional financing, which have a development impact but are not counted as aid for trade. Figure 4.5 about here The key issue is how to differentiate between an aid-for-trade agenda on the one hand and the general economic development agenda, on the other. It is clear that domestic productivity will be crucial in determining developing countries’ capacity to benefit from further trade liberalization. Building supply-side capacity could extend as far as expenditures on education, health and environment expenditure that may be crucial to competitiveness. Some countries have indeed built their export capacity around educated labor force or environmentally-sound tourism. Infrastructure is clearly essential to building export capacity and while in theory it would be useful to distinguish trade-related infrastructure as a category in itself, in practice such a distinction is not feasible both because all infrastructure in the end contributes to productivity and the ability to compete (e.g. water for irrigation, sanitation for meeting SPS standards). Aid for Trade: Facts and Figures The Aid-for-Trade Initiative has achieved remarkable progress in a short time: partner countries are increasingly prioritizing trade in their development strategies and clarifying their needs by developing operational plans. Donors are improving aid-for-trade delivery and scaling up resources. In 2006, aid for trade grew by more than 3% per annum, and more than 20% in 2007. In 2008 commitments for aid for trade had a further increase of 41%; however, with the onset of the 2008 financial crisis, commitments in 2009 fell by 1%. The latest available data shows that aid for trade has regained momentum and commitments in 2010 reached USD 44.7 billion, an increase of around 14% from 2009 levels (Figure 4.6). The volume of aid for trade in 2010 has roughly doubled since the beginning of the initiative in 2005. Furthermore, calculations suggest high disbursements of commitments – i.e. pledges are honored as money is spent. 20 Figures 4.6 and 4.7 about here The largest share of aid for trade continues to go to Asia (with 44%), although flows to Africa (with 35%) are also increasing steadily (Figure 4.7). Overall, the distribution of aid over the different trade-related categories has remained relatively stable over this period: economic infrastructure and productive capacity-building showed similar increases, with strong support going to trade development programs and technical assistance for human and institutional capacity-building in trade policy and regulations. Even though the objective of aid for trade is being met in terms of volumes of aid, its impact on exports, welfare, and growth of recipient countries is not as clear. The following sub-section will review the literature on the impacts of aid on the recipient country’s overall economy and the followed by a detailed examination of the existing evidence of the impact of aid on trade. Empirical Evidence on the Impact of Aid and Trade Foreign aid can affect a recipient country’s overall economy in three main ways. The first is the obvious income effect and beyond this direct income effect, an international transfer between two countries is likely to have important relative price effects between donor and recipient and on factors of production inside the recipient’s economy. A fair summary of the vast literature on the macro relationships between aid and growth is that there is no robust evidence of either a positive or a negative correlation. This is not a surprise considering the different opposing channels in which aid interacts with the overall economy, as discussed above. Furthermore, the impact of aid might depend on other domestic economic policies, institutions, and other conditions. Bourguignon and Sundberg (2007) argue that the mixed impact of aid and growth found in the literature is to be expected considering the heterogeneity of aid motives and the complex causality chain linking foreign aid to final project outcomes.1 The objective for the aid for trade initiative is to improve trade facilitation that will results in greater global trade. This is a direct objective that is simpler to analyze than the impact of aid on growth. The studies presented in the following section summarize the existing literature on aid for trade. 1 Ferro and Wilson (2011) analyze whether aid objectives are accomplished by analyzing the firm perception’s of the areas that aid is expected to improve. 21 We concentrate on the limited empirical literature on aid for trade, the handful of studies that analyze the effect of aid on developing countries’ exports. Gamberoni and Newfarmer (2009) aim to detect countries that are under-performing in trade and that receive less Aid for Trade than their potential demand. The authors construct a trade performance indicator which is assimilated to the potential Aid for Trade demand of each developing country. This index includes trade variables and internal capacity constraints related to institutions, infrastructure and trade policy. Finally, to identify countries that receive less Aid for Trade than expected, they introduce this index of trade performance into a cross-sectional estimation explaining Aid for Trade per recipient GDP, controlling for the level of development and the potential effectiveness of assistance. This work highlights the need to raise aid to countries that are under-receiving and can be used as a benchmark for monitoring the trade performance of recipients. Nevertheless, it does not assess the key question of the effectiveness of these flows on trade outputs. Brenton and Uexkull (2009) analyze the effectiveness of export development programs. Using a difference in difference approach, they aim at isolating the impact of the policy interventions and draw four main conclusions. First, most export development programs have coincided with or predated stronger export performance. Second, such programs appear to be more effective where there is already significant export activity. Third, there is some concern about the “additionality” of the programs as support may be channeled to sectors that would have prospered anyway. Finally, conclusions strongly depend on what one postulates would have happened in the absence of the policy intervention, so the definition of a credible counterfactual is of utmost importance for the evaluation of technical assistance for exports. Lederman et al. (2010) evaluate the effectiveness of Export Promotion Agencies (EPAs) on exports. It should be noted that these agencies are mostly financed by foreign assistance in the poorest developing countries. They find that these institutions have, on average, a positive and significant impact on exports, but with heterogeneous effects across regions and with Africa particularly lagging behind. The authors also note that private-sector EPAs (but receiving a large share of public sector funding) are the best performers. Brenton and von Uexkull (2009) also find that technical assistance for exports targeted to some specific products enhances, on average, export performance. Nevertheless, using a difference-by difference approach, they conclude that this effect is not entirely due to the export development program, and that the allocation of funds should be directed more to sectors that remain behind. 22 Helble, Mann, and Wilson (2011) make one of the first attempts to analyze how foreign aid spent on trade facilitation increases trade flows in developing countries. The authors use a gravity model of bilateral trade and find that the bulk of the relationship between aid and trade appears to come from a narrow set of aid flows directed toward trade policy and regulatory reform, rather than broader aid-for-trade categories directed toward sectoral trade development or infrastructure development. Based on elasticities estimated over 16 years of trade and aid data for 40 donor countries and about 170 country trading pairs, the results suggest that a 1% increase in aid-for-trade facilitation is associated with $290 million of additional exports from the aid receiving countries. Cali and te Velde (2010) found similar positive results and evaluate whether aid for trade has improved export performance. They find that aid for trade facilitation, and to some extent aid for trade policy and regulations, helps reduce the cost of trading (both in terms of exports and imports). In addition, their results suggest that aid to economic infrastructure increases exports, whereas aid to productive capacity appears to have no significant impact on exports. The authors correctly point out that aid for trade is possibly endogenous to exports; particularly aid to productive capacity. For instance, if better performing sectors tend to receive more aid for trade than other sectors, it would generate an upward bias in the aid coefficient. To address this endogeneity, the authors instrument aid for trade with the degree of respect for civil and political liberties measured by the Freedom House Index and with an index proposed by Gartzke (2009) that measures the “affinity of nations”. The authors argue that many donors choose recipients based upon development and democratic measures like these which make these indicators correlated with aid but not with exports. However, the authors acknowledge that their instruments are not appropriate for sectoral analysis, as they only vary across country-year and not across country-sector-year. An important limitation prevalent in any econometric assessment is the potential reverse causality between aid and trade. Indeed, aid for trade is expected to have an impact on exports, however, aid may also be determined by export performance. If, for instance, better performing countries are rewarded with more aid, estimates of aid for trade coefficients would be biased upward. Ferro, Portugal, and Wilson (2010) propose an identification strategy that helps to overcome the reverse causality of the trade-aid relationship. Using input-output data, the authors exploit the differential service-intensities of manufacturing sectors to evaluate the impact of aid in five service sectors (transport, communications, energy, banking/financial services, and 23 business services) on exports of downstream manufacturing sectors for 132 countries between 2002 and 2008. The estimates, in general, show a positive effect of aid to services on downstream manufacturing exports of developing countries. Aid to transport, energy, and banking sectors have consistently a significant and positive impact on downstream manufacturing exports. The effectiveness of aid to transportation in terms of exports growth diminishes for country groups with higher income, whereas the effectiveness of aid to energy and business services increases with the income of the group. There is a clear evidence of the benefits on trade of improving the trade facilitation environment in a country. There also seems to be strong evidence that aid for trade is having a positive impact on exports of developing countries. However, it is important to keep in mind that this does not necessarily mean that aid for trade is generating growth and reducing poverty in recipient countries; research is required to provide robust evidence. 4.6 Conclusion: Empirical Analysis informing Policy Priorities The analytical and empirical framework presented here outlines what trade facilitation is and how it impacts trade flows and broader economic development. The chapter has also provided an overview of the global aid-for-trade movement, including size and scope of aid-for-trade as well as empirical insight into its effectiveness. Through this analysis, it is possible to identify policy priorities with regards to both trade facilitation and aid-for-trade moving forward that takes into account the global trade and economic environment. A review of existing literature almost uniformly indicates that trade facilitation has a significant and positive effect on trade flows. Research has repeatedly found that policies aimed to make trade less costly and complex – through improving infrastructure, modernizing customs and border procedures, and strategic investments in information and communications services have resulted in tangible increases to trade flows. This has been found in research looking at specific components of trade facilitation such as customs procedures (Arson, Cadot, and Olarreaga 2006 and Djankov et al 2010), information and communications services (Freund and Weinhold 2004) and product standards (Ferro et al. 2013; Chen and Mattoo 2008; Mangelsdorf et al. 2012). Empirical analysis using composite indicators to construct broader views of trade facilitation have also found positive trade effects to targeted improvement in trade facilitation 24 policies (Francois and Manchin 2007; Portugal-Perez and Wilson 2012;). On the cost-side, research has determined that inefficient trading procedures stemming from geography or trading delays consistently results in lost trade (Freund and Rocha 2010). Much of the research to date has provided policymakers with information about the effectiveness of possible interventions, and has helped national and international stakeholders prioritize potential trade-related interventions. Overall, empirical evidence suggests a consensus that policies aiming to reduce the cost and complexity of trading will result in tangible benefits in the form of additional trade. These policies are of particular importance given that many developing countries have inefficient border procedures that make traders suffer from delayed and unreliable delivery, costly customs clearance, and missed business opportunities. Empirical and analytical knowledge regarding trade facilitation will no doubt continue to remain important as developing countries continue to play an expanded role in international supply chains and international efforts at trade liberalization continue to move forward. Looking forward, further research that analyzes the relative costs and benefits of implementing particular trade facilitation reform program would be particularly valuable. This detailed analysis may allow for a heightened understanding of which trade facilitation reforms deliver the most effective results in terms of export growth and why. Aid-for-trade – the financial and technical assistance that facilitates the integration of developing countries into the global economy through initiatives that expand trade - is a rapidly growing component of overall development assistance. It is an important tool to ensure developing countries develop the technical expertise needed to realize benefits of trade liberalization and global integration. This emergence is in part due to a perceived inability of developing countries to benefit from existing and prospective market access opportunities that the trading system or specific countries/regions offer – such as preferential (duty-free, quotafree) market access (Hoekman and Wilson 2010). Although constituting a broad section of activities, aid-for-trade initiatives have generally focused on technical assistance for trade policy and regulations, developing trade-related infrastructure (ports, roads, and telecommunications), productive capacity building, and helping with adjustment costs associated with trade liberalization. 25 With empirical evidence supporting the positive economic effects of aid-for-trade, donors and recipient governments alike will remain interested in expanding and further understanding how to maximize ongoing aid-for-trade efforts. The importance of aid-for-trade is made even stronger given the slow recovery from the ongoing financial crisis and the stalled Doha Development Round of WTO trade negotiations. Future research and policy analysis should center on identifying the relative effects of specific aid-for-trade interventions with the goal of prioritizing the most effective aid-for-trade related interventions, given country and regionalspecific characteristics. This prioritization may prove particularly important as donors face increasingly difficult choices as to where to place limited financial and technical resources. Overall, while evidence supports the view that both trade facilitation policies and aid for trade is having a positive impact on exports of developing countries, it is important to keep in mind that this does not necessarily imply these measures are generating growth and reducing poverty in recipient countries. The connections between trade facilitation and aid-for-trade with growth and poverty reduction, among other dynamic interactions, are worthy focuses of future research. The trade literature is evolving from studying how countries trade to trying to understand how firms trade. The trade facilitation and the aid-for-trade literature must also move in the same direction. Understanding the needs of firms and what their constraints are to open to foreign markets is essential for countries’ trade strategies. Clearly, it is also imperative to understand these needs to ensure the efficient use of aid-for-trade resources. Further, the literature on trade facilitation and aid-for-trade should move away from the existing workhorse model of trade—the gravity model—to better understand causality rather that simple correlations. Finally, the use of impact evaluation in trade is challenging but not impossible. Policy makers and donors must come to understand the necessity of these types of studies to precisely determine the effect of both aid and any project intended to reduce trade costs. 26 References Al-Madani, A. M., D. Kaberuka, H. Kuroda, T. Miro, and L. A. Moreno (2012), How to Make Trade Easier, Project Syndicate, June 27, http://www.project-syndicate.org/. Anderson J. and E. Van Wincoop (2003), Gravity with Gravitas: A solution to the Border Puzzle, American Economic Review, 93, 170-192 Anderson, J. E., and D. Marcouiller (2002), Insecurity and the Pattern of Trade: An Empirical Investigation, Review of Economics and Statistics, 84 (2), 342-52. Anderson, J. E., and E. Van Wincoop(2004), Trade Costs, Journal of Economic Literature, 42 (3), 691751. Anderson, J. E., and P. Neary (1994), Measuring the Restrictiveness of Trade Policy, World Bank Economic Review, 8 (2), 151-169. Anson, J., O. Cadot, A. Estevadeordal, J. de Melo, A. Suwa-Eisenmann, and B. Turmurchudur (2005), Rules of Origin in North-South Preferential Trading Arrangements with an Application to NAFTA, Review of International Economics, 13 (3), 501-517. Anson, J., O. Cadot and M. Olarreaga (2006), Tariff Evasion and Customs Corruption: Does PreShipment Inspection Help?, Contributions in Economic Analysis & Policy 5 (1): n. pag. Arvis, J-F., G. Raballand and J-F. Marteau (2007), The Cost of Being Landlocked: Logistics Costs and Supply Chain Reliability, Washington, DC: The World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper No. 4258. Arvis, J-F., M. Mustra, L. Ojala, B. Shepherd, and D. Saslavsky (2012), Connecting to Compete: Trade Logistics in the Global Economy. Washington, DC: The World Bank. Arvis, J-F., Y. Duval, B. Shepherd, and C. Utoktham (2013), Trade Costs in the Developing World: 1995-2010, Washington, DC: The World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper Series No 6309. Borchert, I., B. Gootiiz, A. Grover and A. Mattoo (2012), Landlocked or policy locked? How services trade protection deepens economic isolation, Washington, DC: The World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper Series No 5942. Bourguignon, F. and M. Sundberg (2007), Aid effectiveness: opening the black box. American Economic Review, 97 (2), pp. 316-321. Brenton P., and E. von Uexkull (2009), Product specific technical assistance for exports – has it been effective? Journal of International Trade and Economic Development, 18 (2), pp. 235- 254. Calì, M. and D. W. te Velde (2011), Does Aid for Trade Really Improve Trade Performance?, World Development, 39(5), pages 725-740. Chen, M. X. and A. Mattoo (2008), Regionalism in standards: good or bad for trade?, Canadian Journal of Economics, 41(3), pages 838-863. Chen, M. X., T. Otsuki and J. S. Wilson (2006), Do standards matter for export success?, Washington, DC: The World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper Series No 3809. Chen, N. and D. Novy (2012), On the Measurement of Trade Costs: Direct vs. Indirect Approaches to Quantifying Standards and Technical Regulations, World Trade Review 11 (3), pp.401-414. COMESA (1994), Treaty Establishing the Common Market of Eastern and Southern Africa, http://www.comesa.int/attachments/article/28/COMESA_Treaty.pdf. 27 Czubala, W., B. Shepherd, and J.S. Wilson (2009), Help or Hindrance? The Impact of Harmonised Standards on African Exports, Journal of African Economies, 18, 711-44. Dennis, A. and B. Shepherd (2011), Trade Facilitation and Export Diversification, The World Economy 34 (1), 101-22. Djankov, S., C. Freund, and C. S. Pham (2008), Trading on Time, The Review of Economics and Statistics, 92 (1), 166-73. Djankov, S., O. Hart, C. McLiesh, and A. Shleifer (2008), Debt Enforcement around the World, Journal of Political Economy 116 (6), 1105-149. Draper, Peter, Uri Dadush, Gary Hufbauer, James Bacchus, and Robert Lawrence (2012), The Shifting Geography of Global Value Chains: Implications for Developing Countries and Trade Policy. Geneva: World Economic Forum. Ferro, E., A. Portugal-Perez and J. S. Wilson (2011), Aid to the Services Sector: Does it Affect Manufacturing Exports?, Washington, DC: The World Bank Policy Research Working Paper Series No. 5728. Ferro, E. and J. S. Wilson (2011), Foreign aid and business bottlenecks : a study of aid effectiveness, Washington, DC: The World Bank Policy Research Working Paper Series No 5546. Ferro, E., J. S. Wilson and T. Otsuki (2013), The Effect of Standards on Developing Countries Agricultural Exports, Washington, DC: The World Bank Policy Research Working Paper Series No 6518. Francois, J. and M. Manchin (2007), Institutions, infrastructure, and trade, Washington, DC: The World Bank Policy Research Working Paper Series No 4152. Fink, C., A. Mattoo, and C. Naugu (2005), Assessing the impact of communication costs on international trade, Journal of International Economics, 67(2), pages 428-445. Freund, C. and N. Rocha (2010), What Constrains Africa's Exports? Washington, DC: The World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No 5184. Freund, C. and D. Weinhold (2004), The effect of the Internet on international trade, Journal of International Economics, 62(1), pages 171-189. Gamberoni, E. and R. Newfarmer (2009), Aid for trade: matching supply and demand. Washington, DC: The World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 4991. Gartzke, E. (2009), The Affinity of Nations Index, 1946–2002, version 4.0 and related documents. <http://dss.ucsd.edu/~egartzke/htmlpages/data.html>. Helble, M., C. Mann and J. S. Wilson (2012). Aid-for-trade facilitation, Review of World Economics, 148(2), pp. 357-376. Helble, M., B. Shepherd and J. S. Wilson (2007), Transparency and Trade Facilitation in Asia Pacific: Estimating the Gains from Reform, Canberra: World Bank & Australian Department of Foreign Affairs and Trade. Helpman, E., M. Melitz and Y. Rubinstein (2008), Estimating trade flows: Trading partners and trading volumes. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123 (2), 441–487. Hoekman, B. and S. Wilson (2010), Aid for Trade: Building on Progress Today for Tomorrow’s Future, Washington, DC: The World Bank Policy Research Working Paper Series No 5361. Hufbauer, G., J. S. Wilson and J. Muir (2012), Aid for Trade: An Effective Strategy. Washington, DC: Peterson Institute for International Economics / World Bank Research Group. 28 Hummels, D. L., (2007), Transportation Costs and International Trade in the Second Era of Globalization, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21(3), 131-154. Lederman D., M. Olarreaga and L. Payton (2010), Export Promotion Agencies: Do They Work?, Journal of Development Economics, 91 (2), pp. 257-65. Limão, N. and A. J. Venables (2001), Infrastructure, Geographical Disadvantage, Transport Costs, and Trade, World Bank Economic Review, 15 (3), 451-479. Kee, H., A. Nicita, and M. Olarreaga (2009), Estimating Trade Restrictiveness Indices, The Economic Journal 119 (534), 172-99. Mackellar L., A. Wörgötter and J. Wörz (2002), Economic Growth of Landlocked Countries, in G. Chaloupek, A. Guger, E. Nowotny and G. Schwödiauer (eds), Ökonomie in Theorie und Praxis, Springer, Berlin, pp.213-226. Mangelsdorf, A., A. Portugal-Perez, and J. S. Wilson (2012), Food Standards and Exports: Evidence for China, World Trade Review 11 (3), pp 507-526. Martinez-Zarzoso, I. and L. Marquez-Ramos (2008), The Effect of Trade Facilitation on Sectoral Trade, The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy, 8 (1), pages 42-55. Mattoo, A., I. Borchert, B. Gootiz and A. Grover (2012), Landlocked or Policy Locked? How Services Trade Protection Deepens Economic Isolation, Washington, DC: The World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No 5942. Maur, J-C. and J. S. Wilson (2011), Trade Costs and Facilitation: Open Trade and Economic Development. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. McCallum, J. (1995), Borders Matter: Canada-U.S. Regional Trade Patterns. The American Economic Review 85(3): 615-23. Minor, P., T. Orliac and E. Moise (2011), Trade Facilitation Indicators: The Impact on Trade Costs, Paris: OECD, Trade Policy Working Papers No. 118. OECD (2012), Development: Aid to Developing Countries Falls Because of Global Recession. News release, April 4, Paris: OECD http://www.oecd.org/newsroom/developmentaidtodevelopingcountriesfallsbecauseofglobalrecession. htm. OECD/WTO (2011), Aid for Trade at a Glance 2011, Paris: OECD. OECD/WTO (2009), Aid for Trade at a Glance 2009, Paris: OECD. OECD/WTO (2007), Aid for Trade at a Glance 2007, Paris: OECD. OECD/WTO (2006), Aid for Trade: making it effective, Paris: OECD. Peng, B. (2008), Trade Facilitation Provisions in Regional Trade Agreements in Asia and the Pacific, New York: UNESCAP Trade and Investment Division Staff Working Paper no. 01/08. Persson, M. (2012), From Trade Preferences to Trade Facilitation: Taking stock of the Issues, The OpenAccess, Open-Assessment E-Journal, 6, 2012-17, pp. 1-33. Portugal‐Perez, A., J. Reyes and J. S. Wilson (2010), Beyond the Information Technology Agreement: Harmonisation of Standards and Trade in Electronics, The World Economy, 33 (12), pages 18701897. Portugal‐Perez, A., and J. S. Wilson (2012), Export Performance and Trade Facilitation Reform: Hard and Soft Infrastructure, World Development, 40 (7), pp: 1295-1307. 29 Sadikov, A. (2007). Border and Behind-the-Border Trade Barrier and Country Exports. Washington, DC: IMF Working Paper WB/07/292. Staples, B. (1998). Trade Facilitation, http://www.acp-eu-trade.org/library/files/Staples%20%20October%201998%20-%20Trade%20Facilitation.pd.f. Suwa-Eisenmann, A. and T. Verdier (2007), Aid and trade, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 23 (3), pp. 481-507. Tinbergen, J. (1962), Shaping the World Economy: Suggestions for an International Economic Policy. New York: Twentieth Century Fund. UNCTAD (2011), The Least Developed Countries Report 2011: The Potential Role of South-South Cooperation for Inclusive and Sustainable Development. Geneva: UNCTAD United Nations (2012), World Economic Situation and Prospects 2012. New York: UN-DESA, United Nations Publication. Wilson, J. S., C. Mann and T. Otsuki (2003), Trade Facilitation and Economic Development: A New Approach to Quantifying the Impact, World Bank Economic Review 17(3): 367-89. Wilson, J. S., C. Mann, and T. Otsuki (2005), Assessing the Benefits of Trade Facilitation: A Global Perspective, The World Economy, 28(6): 841-871. Wilson, J. S., C. Mann, Y. P. Woo, N. Assanie, and I. Choi (2002), Trade Facilitation: A Development Perspective in the Asia-Pacific Region. Singapore: Report to APEC Secretariat. Wilson, J. S., and T. Otsuki (2004), Standards and Technical Regulations and Firms in Developing Countries: New Evidence from a World Bank Technical Barriers to Trade Survey, Washington, DC: The World Bank, Mimeo. World Bank (2005), Global Economic Prospects: Trade, Regionalism, and Development, Washington, DC: The World Bank. World Bank (2012), Doing Business 2012: Doing Business in a More Transparent World. Washington, DC: The World Bank. World Bank Independent Evaluation Group (2011), Capturing Technology for Development. Washington, DC: World Bank. Yang, D. (2008), Integrity for Hire: An Analysis of a Widespread Customs Reform, Journal of Law and Economics, 51(1), pages 25-57. 30 Figure 4.1 Aggregate Trade Facilitation Indicators (Portugal-Perez and Wilson 2012) HARD INFRASTRUCTURE INDICATORS Quality of port Infrastructure Availability of latest ICT Technology ICT Level of technical absorption Physical Infrastructure Quality of airports infrastructure Extent of Business Internet Use Quality of roads infrastructure Government prioritization of ICT Quality of railroad infrastructure SOFT INFRASTRUCTURE INDICATORS Government Transparency Business Environment Public Trust for Government Irregular Payments in Exports and Imports Measures to Combat Corruption Number of Documents to Export Border and Transport Efficiency Number of Days to Export Number of Documents to Import Number of Days to Import 31 Figure 4.2 Number of documents required to export 2007 and 2012 Source: World Bank Doing Business (2007 and 2012) Figure 4.3 Time to Export 2007 and 2012 Source: World Bank Doing Business (2007 and 2012) 32 Figure 4.4 Percentage change in LPI component as measured against the highest performer, 2007-2012 Table 4.1 Trade Facilitation and Trade Flows early 2000s Country Chile China Indonesia Korea Mexico Peru Philippines Russia Thailand Customs Environment Δ exports (%) Δ imports (%) 2 9 1 21 1 3 2 8 0 5 1 13 1 25 5 8 1 Port Efficiency Δ exports (%) Δ imports (%) 21 20 74 2 51 9 15 14 37 1 98 5 100 3 73 36 15 5 Source: Wilson et al. (2003) 33 Figure 4.5 Aid-for-Trade Scope Source: OECD/WTO 2011 Figure 4.6 Aid-for-Trade, 1995-2010 (USD millions) 50,000 40,000 30,000 20,000 10,000 - Trade Policies & Regulations & Adjustments Productive Capacity Economic Infrastructure Source: Own calculations using OECD CRS data. 34 Figure 4.7 Global Aid for Trade Flows 2008-2010: Regional Analysis 50,000 45,000 USD (millions) 40,000 35,000 30,000 2008 25,000 2009 20,000 2010 15,000 10,000 5,000 0 America Africa Oceania Europe Asia Source: Own calculations using OECD CRS data. 35