Environmental Economics Sareh Vosooghi Department of Economics, KU Leuven Climate Change 1/60 Earth’s annual mean energy balance IPCC AR4, Working Group 1, Main Report 2/60 CO2 emissions and global warming Source: IPCC 6AR, 2021 There is a near-linear relationship between cumulative CO2 emissions and the increase in global surface temperature. 3/60 History of global temperature change Source: IPCC 6AR, 2021 Human influence has warmed the climate at a rate that is unprecedented. 4/60 Global CO2 emissions Source: Nordhaus (2021, Markus Academy Webinar) 5/60 Multi-model averages and assessed ranges for surface warming Source: IPCC 6AR, 2021 Human activities affect all the major climate system components, with some responding over decades and others over centuries. Alarming variables include: global surface temperature; Arctic sea ice area; global ocean surface pH; global mean sea level change. 6/60 Impacts of Climate Change from no risk (white) to irreversible risk (purple) Source: IPCC 6AR, 2021 7/60 Safe Carbon Budget and Mitigation Options Available Safe carbon budget is about 400-500 GtCO2 to stay below 1.5 degrees Celsius: less than 12 years at current use of fossil fuel use left. Clock is ticking fast! There are two ways to move towards a goal of reducing the rate of growth of atmospheric greenhouse-gas concentrations: • Increase the capacity of sinks that sequester carbon dioxide and other greenhouse gases from the atmosphere. • Decrease emissions of greenhouse gases below business as usual (thereby reducing GHG inflows to the atmosphere). 8/60 The costs of attaining mitigation targets 1. The cost of achieving any given target increases as the magnitude of the emissions or concentration target declines. 2. Other things being equal, the cost of achieving any given target increases the higher are baseline (i.e. uncontrolled) emissions over the time period in question. 3. The cost of achieving any given target varies with the date at which targets are to be met, but does so in quite complex ways. 4. Abatement costs will be lower, the more cost-efficiently that abatement is obtained. 5. Climate-change decision-making is essentially a sequential process under uncertainty. 9/60 Integrated Assessment Models of Climate Change 10/60 Structure of IAMs DICE: Economic Components DICE: Geophysical Model DICE Criticism Stern Review Weitzman: Damage Function, Uncertainty and Extreme Events Post-Weitzman Perspectives on Damage Function Environmental goods and IAMs Structure of the Integrated Assessment Models (IAMs) IAMs comprise: • A simple climate model • A simple economic model • An emission abatement cost, by which economic decisions affect the climate. • A damage function, by which the climate affects the economy. • Optimisation under either Business-as-usual or socially-optimal scenario 11/60 Conceptual Structure Conceptual Structure of IAMof IAM Land use Emissions Climate Cycle Fossil Stocks Abatement Fossil Fuel Use Production Investment General Capital Technology Labour Consumption 12/60 An Example: Dynamic Integrated Climate Economy (DICE), Nordhaus (2014) • Simple economic & simple geophysical models. Linked via: • Emission abatement cost • ‘Damage function’ • Evaluate outcomes using social welfare function • Choose optimal path, starting at i = 0, for • savings rate • GHG emissions I’ll use notation which matches Faulwasser et al. (2018) and so matches the Matlab code. 13/60 Economic Components Social welfare is Wi W= T X U(C(i), L(i)) (1 + ρ)i−1 i=1 where i is the time period, C(i) and L(i) are total consumption and population in period i, and ρ is the pure rate of time preference. The utility function is “morally” L(i) where c(i) is per-capita consumption c(i)1−α 1−α C(i) L(i) . In the Matlab code it’s given by U(C(i), L(i)) = L(i) 1−α ( 1000C(i) L(i) ) 1−α In real modelling environments you sometimes need factors of 1000 as your units aren’t as consistent as they should have been. 14/60 Population Population growth is exogenous L(i + 1) = L(i)( La lg ) Li This is a neat trick to have a functional form which works a bit like exponential growth, but with the growth rate declining as L(i) gets bigger, tending towards a maximum value of 10.5 billion. It’s calibrated to match UN projections. 15/60 Production In DICE, the damage and abatement functions both act on output. So in each period: • There’s a production function for the output you would have got • This is then reduced by the action of damages • And it’s reduced by what is spent on abatement. The resulting net output goes into savings and consumption. Gross output itself is just Cobb-Douglas Y G (i) = A(i)K(i)γ ( L(i) 1−γ ) 1000 where A(i) is technology, K(i) is capital. (Note that Faulwasser et al. (2018) unhelpfully notate this as Y .) 16/60 Net Output Now net output is Y(i) = 1 − Λ(i) G Y (i) 1 + Ω(i) where Λ(i) is emission abatement costs and Ω(i) is economic damages from climate change. (Faulwasser et al. (2018) don’t give this a letter, they just leave as a function of their Y ). DICE 2016R (and so Faulwasser et al., 2018 ) use Y(i) = [1 − Λ(i) − Ω(i)]Y G (i) For small Ω, the two damage forms of 1 − Ω and 1 1+Ω are approximately equal. 17/60 Abatement costs A fraction µ(i) of emissions are abated, which costs the fraction of output Λ(i) = θ1 (i)µ(i)θ2 Note that when µ(i) = 1, i.e. emissions have been eliminated, we have Λ(i) = θ1 (i). So θ1 (i) is the fraction of output we would need to spend to eliminate emissions. So it represents a “backstop” technology. Its price comes down over time. The fraction µ(i) is one of our two key “control variables”, which are chosen in each period to maximise welfare. 18/60 Damages Damages are determined by atmospheric temperature change TAT above pre-industrial levels, according to the function Ω(i) = a2 (TAT )a3 Nordhaus uses a2 = 0.00267 and a3 = 2. This has been standard for a long time but has become controversial. we don't know what a world with +3°C would be like Given either specifications of the net output, damages reduce consumption because there is less output to consume. This reduction in consumption is supposed to give a compensating variation of all welfare losses from climate change. 19/60 Technology Total-factor productivity growth is exogenous in DICE. A(i + 1) = A(i)(1 + gA (i)) where gA (i) is TFP growth, which declines over time, so that gA (i) = gA (i − 1) 1 + δA with δA being the rate of this decline over time. 20/60 Capital and Savings Capital stock evolves K(i + 1) = (1 − δk )K(i) + Y(i)s(i) where δk is depreciation and s(i) is the savings rate. s(i) is our other key “control variable” that, we choose for each time period to maximise welfare. Output which isn’t saved, is consumed: C(i) = Y(i)(1 − s(i)) 21/60 Emissions Emissions E(i) = Eland (i) + Eind (i) come from the land and from output. Land-use emissions are just declining over time: Eland (i + 1) = Eland0 (1 − δEL )i Industrial emissions are the carbon intensity of output σ(i), times the unabated fraction of gross output: Eind (i) = σ(i)(1 − µ(i))Y G (i) The carbon intensity of output σ(i) also declines over time. There is a constraint Ē ≥ X Eind (i) i on total available industrial emissions. 22/60 Social Cost of Carbon The social cost of carbon, SCC, in period i is the marginal effect of one more ton of CO2 in period i, in terms of period-i money. SCC(i) = ∂W ∂E − ∂Wi ∂Ci marginal This is our marginal external benefit (MEB) of abating GHGs. The minus sign reflects the fact that the marginal effect of emissions is negative, but we want to measure a positive cost. In MPC-DICE, the SCC(i) is multiplied by 1000. The factor of 1000 reflects a units miss-match. The numerator is evaluated in the model by comparing the value of the objective function at the ‘optimum’, with its value when a small impulse of emissions have been added. 23/60 SCC and Optimal Carbon Tax As defined on the previous slide, the SCC clearly depends on: • path of economy, esp savings rate; • emissions pathway before and after period i. Recall that an IAM will choose these factors to optimise social welfare. Particularly important is the SCC when the savings rate and emissions pathway are both optimised. Some economists refer to this as “the” social cost of carbon. This is also equal to the optimal carbon tax. 24/60 SCC and Marginal Economic Benefits from GHG emissions SCC and Marginal Economic Benefits from GHG emissions However, we can think of the in any period a function of However, we can alsoalso think of the SCCSCC in any one one period as aasfunction of total total cumulative emissions (before and after that period). cumulative emissions (before and after that period). Though Though both theboth SCC and the SCC and emission abatement will depend on trajectorythis of is a useful emission abatement will really depend onreally the trajectory ofthe emissions, emissions, this is a useful shorthand. shorthand. Price MB M EC q⇤ q̄ q In this way, conceptually the same as we’ve seen before. In this way, conceptually the same as we’ve seen before. Clear that the Pigouvian tax is equal to the SCC at the optimum quantity. Clear that the Pigouvian tax is equal to the SCC at the optimum quantity. 25/60 Structure of IAMs DICE: Economic Components DICE: Geophysical Model DICE Criticism Stern Review Weitzman: Damage Function, Uncertainty and Extreme Events Post-Weitzman Perspectives on Damage Function Environmental goods and IAMs Carbon Boxes There are three “boxes” of carbon, represented by • MAT (i): carbon in the atmosphere • MUP (i): carbon in the upper ocean • MLO (i): carbon in the lower ocean Emissions flow in the atmosphere. Carbon flows in both directions between the atmosphere and the upper ocean, and between the upper ocean and the lower ocean. 26/60 Carbon Cycle M_AT(i+1) = zeta11*M_AT(i) + zeta12*M_UP(i) + zeta2(F_i) M_UP(i+1) = zeta21*M_AT(i) + zeta22*M_UP(i) + zeta23*M_LO M_LO(i+1) = zeta32*M_UP(i) + zeta33*M_UP(i) The flow from one box to the next is linear. e.g. at point i there is • ζ21 MAT (i) flowing from the atmosphere to the upper ocean • ζ12 MUP (i) flowing from the upper ocean to the atmosphere. So there’s a net flow from atmosphere to ocean of ζ21 MAT (i) − ζ12 MUP (i) This means that carbon sink in the upper ocean could become saturated, slowing down re-absorption until enough has sunk down to the lower ocean. In fact, it is considered that the DICE carbon cycle absorbs carbon into the ocean too easily. 27/60 Heat “Boxes” There are two “boxes” of heat, in the atmosphere temperature (TAT ) and in the lower ocean temperature (TLO ). Atmospheric forcings warm the upper ocean. Similarly to the carbon cycle, heat then diffuses down to the lower ocean, cooling the climate. Again, these parts of the DICE model are criticised by scientists - it’s too easy for the temperature to come back down again. These parts of the model are described using matrices by Faulwasser et al. (2018). If you can’t read matrix equations, go over to Phaneuf and Requate (2016), who don’t use them. 28/60 Radiative forcing “Radiative forcings” describe the planet’s energy balance. If the inflow of energy from the sun is greater than the amount being radiated into space, the planet will gradually be “forced” to a higher temperature. In DICE, F(i) = ηlog2 ( MAT (i) ) + FEX (i) MAT,1750 Here FEX (i) is forcings from other greenhouse gases, which DICE treats as exogenous. And MAT,1750 is pre-industrial concentrations of CO2 . So the first term equals η when atmospheric concentrations have doubled relative to the pre-industrial level. 29/60 Temperature equations Now DICE has linear equations for the effect of forcings on temperature TAT (i + 1) = ϕ11 TAT (i) + ϕ12 TLO (i) + ξ1 F(i) So temperature is a function of MAT (i). TLO (i + 1) = ϕ21 TAT (i) + ϕ22 TLO (i) As with carbon, temperature can flow from the atmosphere to the ocean – but the net flow will slow down if the ocean is warmer. 30/60 Climate sensitivity Suppose we double concentrations of CO2 from pre-industrial levels, and hold them constant, and ignore exogenous forcings. So F(i) = η. Eventually atmospheric and ocean temperatures will stabilise. Write these as TAT and TLO . Now find TAT using simultaneous equations: T_AT(i) = T_AT(i+1) (1 − ϕ11 )TAT = ϕ12 TLO + ξ1 η (1 − ϕ22 )TLO = ϕ21 TAT The value of TAT we get out from this is called the “equilibrium climate sensitivity (ECS)”. Higher climate sensitivity means greater temperature change for the same CO2 content. So ECS depends on the ϕ parameters, η and ξ1 . But MPC-DICE allows you to start by setting ECS – it’s the parameter called “t2xco2” – and will reset the ϕ values to account for this. 31/60 Results for a range of scenarios Results for a range of scenarios Global temperature change AtmosphericTemperature (degC above preindustrial) 7 6 5 Base Opt Lim2t Stern SternCalib Copen 4 3 2 1 0 2000 2020 2040 2060 2080 2100 Year 2120 2140 2160 2180 2200 Global temperature increase ( C from 1900) under alternative policies, Global temperature increase (◦ C from 1900) under alternative policies, DICE-2013R DICE-2013R model. Source: Nordhaus and Sztorc (2013) model. Source: Nordhaus and Sztorc (2013) 32/60 Major Results from DICE • Efficient emissions reductions follow a “policy ramp” in which policies involve modest rates of emissions reductions in the near term, followed by sharp reductions in the medium and long terms. • For the efficient climate-change policy, the net present-value global benefit of the optimal policy is $3 trillion relative to no controls. This total involves $2 trillion of abatement costs and $5 trillion of reduced climatic damages. • The economically optimal carbon price or carbon tax would be $27 per metric ton in 2005 in 2005 prices. The optimal carbon price would rise steadily over time, at a rate between 2 and 3 percent per year in real terms, to reflect the rising damages from climate change. • The upper limit on the carbon price is determined by the price at which all uses of fossil fuels can be economically replaced by other technologies. This is cost of the backstop technology. DICE estimates this to be around $1,000 per ton of carbon over the next half century or so, falling thereafter at an unknown rate. 33/60 Structure of IAMs DICE: Economic Components DICE: Geophysical Model DICE Criticism Stern Review Weitzman: Damage Function, Uncertainty and Extreme Events Post-Weitzman Perspectives on Damage Function Environmental goods and IAMs What is the economic impact of climate change, and what are the costs and benefits of taking action now? The Stern Review (2006): • Commissioned by the UK government to evaluate a proactive response to climate change. • Collaboration between renowned scientists and philosophers. • Countered the popular view (led by figures like Nordhaus) advocating for a permissible temperature rise of 3-3.5°C by 2100. • Central finding: Stabilizing CO2 levels between 500-550ppm would cost about 1% of global GDP, given immediate decisive action. Aiming for 450ppm CO2 would be challenging and more expensive. • A pivotal distinction from DICE was in the choice of the discount rate. 34/60 Nordhaus Stern 35/60 Discounting in DICE vs Stern William Nordhaus (Yale University) vs Nicholas Stern (LSE). Stern chose a much lower discount rate than is standard in the literature (e.g. any of the versions of DICE). ... and just choosing different discount rates has huge consequences in IAMs. 36/60 Global temperature of DICE results under different scenarios Source: Nordhaus and Sztorc (2013) 37/60 Output of DICE under different scenarios Source: Nordhaus and Sztorc (2013) 38/60 Output of DICE under different scenarios • Economic growth remains consistent across all model scenarios. • Minimal variance observed between climate change impacts and mitigation. • Use of a low discount rate magnifies differences. • The Stern run initially lags behind the Lim2t, but surpasses in later years. WHY? low discount rate induces a higher savings rate. • Marginal difference observed between Lim2t and DICE’s optimal run. • Question to ponder: If the impact on welfare is this minimal, why is climate change such a big deal? 39/60 Structure of IAMs DICE: Economic Components DICE: Geophysical Model DICE Criticism Stern Review Weitzman: Damage Function, Uncertainty and Extreme Events Post-Weitzman Perspectives on Damage Function Environmental goods and IAMs Weitzman’s Perspective on Stern Review • Stern Review’s distinct low discount rate sparked debates on optimal emission policies and the Social Cost of Carbon (SCC). Debate about discounting. • Marty Weitzman (1942-2019) posited Stern was on track but emphasized different reasons. Stern was right, but for “the wrong reasons”. • Weitzman’s stance: urgent climate action is crucial to mitigate the minor risk of severe future consequences. • Key elements to Weitzman’s view: the damage function and uncertainty. 40/60 Weitzman’s Analysis of DICE’s Damages • DICE (2014) quantifies output loss using the function: Ω(T) = 1 1 + a2 T a3 • Concerns arise regarding the model’s treatment of damages from extreme temperature changes. • Higher temperatures, e.g., 10◦ C, show only a 19% output loss — a perspective Weitzman finds unconvincing. • The DICE model isn’t calibrated for this range, but should be if we consider the implications of uncertainty and irreversibility. 41/60 Damage functions in most IAMs Source: McCarthy et al. (2001) 42/60 • After the release of the IPCC’s AR4 report, studies began to emerge highlighting the more severe damages associated with rising global mean temperatures. Source: IPCC (2014) 43/60 What do we know about 3 degrees of warming? Nordhaus and Sztorc (2013): • The damage function has been calibrated for damage estimates in the range of 0 to 3◦ C. In reality, estimates of damage functions are virtually non-existent for temperature increases above 3◦ C [...] The damage function needs to be examined carefully or re-specified in cases of higher warming or catastrophic damages. 44/60 Understanding Equilibrium Climate Sensitivity (ECS) • Defined as the temperature change resulting from a doubled CO2 concentration, post-equilibrium, i.e., ∆TAT when we double CO2 concentration, and let the climate reach equilibrium. • Precise value of ECS remains uncertain. • Scientists prefer not to assign a specific probability distribution function (pdf) to the value. Instead, they provide ‘likely’ and ‘very unlikely’ ranges, backed by varying confidence levels. Hence, the latest IPCC reports refrain from specifying a pdf for ECS. 45/60 pdf of ECS 46/60 “Thin Tails” versus “Fat Tails” and Extreme events Thin-Tails versus Fat-Tail pdfs The normal distribution is an example of a thin tailed distribution. As we The ‘normal distribution’ an example of a thinoftailed distribution. As we move move away from theismedian, probabilities events become extremely away from small.the median, probabilities of events become extremely small. The ‘Pareto distribution’ is fat tailed. decline decline for more The “Pareto distribution” is fatProbabilities tailed. Probabilities forextreme more events, Fat-Tailed Uncertainty in the Economics of Catastrophic Climate Change 279 but not nearly so fast. extreme events, but not nearly so fast. Table 1 Prob½S # S^$ for fat-tailed Pareto and thin-tailed Normal distributions S^ ¼ ^ ProbP ½S # S $ ProbN ½S # S^ $ 3!C 4.5!C 6!C 8!C 10!C 12!C 0.5 0.5 0.15 0.15 0.06 0.02 0.027 0.003 0.014 7 % 10&7 0.008 3 % 10&10 Source: Weitzman (2011) Source:sensitivity Weitzmanstudies (2011)into one overarching probability density function (PDF), and there is much controversy about how it might be done. But for what it is worth (perhaps very little), the median upper 5 percent probability level over all 22 climate sensitivity PDFs cited in IPCCAR4 is 6.4!C, which fits with the Pareto PDF in Table 1 above.4 Table 2 presents some values of probabilities of eventual increased global mean surface 47/60 Fat Tails and Expectations Suppose X is a random variable with pdf f(x), and g is a function of X. Then expectation of g(g) is calculated as, Z ∞ “Fat tails” andE(g(g)) Infinite = Expectations g(g)f(x)dx −∞ • If X has a thin-tail distribution (like Normal), any ‘reasonable’ g, gives a finite expectation. We have a race between the pdf going down, and the thing whose • But if Xexpectation has pdf likewe’re below, and ggoing grows taking, up.rapidly, the product of these two does not have a finite integral necessarily. probability density 48/60 Uncertainty and Damage in IAM since Weitzman Weitzman (2007, and ...) argued that: • The pdf of ECS (or more generally a bad climate outcome) is fat tailed. • Climate damage grows rapidly as climate outcomes get worse: the curve is much steeper than quadratic (as were in DICE 2014). Thus, from the interaction of these two, you would get an infinite expectation. Weitzman’s Dismal Theorem: SCC varies very sensitively on the worst possible outcome. One shoudl cap how bad the ‘worst possible outcome’ can be, and find a finite expectation subject to that cap, and then show that the SCC → ∞ as the cap is relaxed. 49/60 Uncertainty and Damage of Weitzman in DICE • Weitzman’s arguments are made without using a full IAM, and don’t necessarily take account of the fact that a higher ECS means that it takes longer for the climate to reach equilibrium. • Introducing uncertainty in climate sensitivity has a negligible effect on DICE model outcomes, unless the damage function is modified. WHY? • Damages rise quadratically with temperature shifts. • Higher ECS leads to a delayed equilibrium. Result: SCC in DICE is roughly linear in ECS, making uncertainty’s inclusion relatively inconsequential. Thus our stance on the damage function also shapes our perspective on uncertainty. 50/60 Structure of IAMs DICE: Economic Components DICE: Geophysical Model DICE Criticism Stern Review Weitzman: Damage Function, Uncertainty and Extreme Events Post-Weitzman Perspectives on Damage Function Environmental goods and IAMs An Alternative Damage Function (Weitzman (2012)) Ω(T) = 1 T a2 1 + a1 + a3 T a4 with a2 = 2 as in DICE, and a3 , a4 chosen so that damages are 50% of world GDP at 6◦ C and 99% at 12.5◦ C. Golosov et al. (2014): Y_,t = exp(C*T_t)*A_t *K_t^alpha*L_t^beta *E_t^(1-alpha-beta) Y: total output T: global T (°C) C: cst. A: total factor productivity K: kapital L: E: composite energy t: time 51/60 Dietz and Stern (2015) and Capital Stock Damages • Dietz and Stern (2015) stress the role of capital stock knowledge spillovers in economic growth, echoing thoughts from Arrow (1962) and Romer (1986). ENDOGENOUS GROWTH MODELS. • They theorize that climate change might adversely impact capital stocks, subsequently hampering growth. ↑ TAT → ↓ K → ↓ Y • The capital stock damages by climate change include: Damages due to storms or wildfires; abandoned coastal areas; reduced productivity of capital; high depreciation of capital due to climate change damage 52/60 Dietz and Stern (2015) So they suggest two modifications to DICE-2014: Y(i) = (1 − Ω(i))(1 − Λ(i))A(i)K(i)γ+β L(i)1−γ when one firm invests more, there are positive spillovers to the whole economy (β > 0). K(i + 1) = (1 − DK (i))(1 − δ K )Kt + It DK is the climate change damage that directly affects capital. They deliver results under four scenarios: • Standard DICE • Weitzman damage function with 50% damages at 6◦ C • ‘High damage’ function with 50% damages at 4◦ C • Weitzman damage function with ECS (‘S’ here) of 6 instead of 3 53/60 Results: Per Capita Consumption with no climate policy Dietz and Stern (2015) 2015] GROWTH, CONVEX DAMAGES AND CLIMATE RISK K Model 100 Consumption Per Capita (US $2005) 90 80 585 Standard S = 3, Quardratic Damage S = 3, Weitzman Damage S = 3, High Damage S = 6, Weitzman Damage 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 2000 Elizabeth Baldwin 2050 2100 Environmental Economics and Climate Change 2150 Hilary Term, 2020 2200 77 / 92 54/60 Weitzman damage, S = 6 High damage 0.432 0.396 Dietz and Stern (2015) 0.584 0.538 0.722 0.663 0.868 0.783 1 0.891 1 0.984 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 Table 2 Optimal Carbon Prices (2005 US$/tC), 2015–2105. S = 3 Unless Otherwise Indicated Standard 2015 44.4 2025 57.0 2035 71.2 2045 87.8 2055 106.2 2065 127.1 2075 150.0 2085 175.8 2095 204.6 2105 236.6 Capital models Quadratic damage Weitzman damage Weitzman damage, S = 6 High damage 76 91 196 178 129 156 337 309 182 226 495 455 245 310 684 617 316 405 895 774 393 506 1097 909 476 609 1074 1017 563 711 1052 1052 656 812 1032 1032 752 912 1012 1012 Productivity models Quadratic damage Weitzman damage Weitzman damage, S = 6 High damage 118 133 271 233 196 222 456 393 272 313 653 559 363 420 888 738 466 541 1121 911 580 670 1097 1066 705 806 1074 1074 840 945 1052 1052 984 1032 1032 1032 1012 1012 1012 1012 55/60 Structure of IAMs DICE: Economic Components DICE: Geophysical Model DICE Criticism Stern Review Weitzman: Damage Function, Uncertainty and Extreme Events Post-Weitzman Perspectives on Damage Function Environmental goods and IAMs Sterner and Persson (2008) and Environmental Goods • Applying insights from Krutilla-Fisher model (using a lower discount rate on environmental goods) in IAMs. • Assume there are two goods: material consumption C; and environmental amenities E. Utilities are: h (1 − γ)C σ−1 σ + γE σ−1 σ σ σ−1 i1−α U(C) = 1−α E and C are imperfect substitutes (0 < ρ < 1). Why? for example: loss of agricultural output reduces global GDP. So, MRSCE should be diminishing dramatically. • Assume temperature affects environmental quality by E(i) = E0 (1 + aT(i)2 ) where a is a constant and E0 is level of environmental amenities in year 2005. 56/60 70 Upshot: Optimal Emission Paths Sterner and Persson (2008) T. Sterner and U. M. Persson rising over time (middle line—labeled Relative price effects). See text for further explanation. Downloaded from http://reep.oxfordjournals.org a Figure 1. Optimal carbon dioxide emission paths in amended version of the DICE model, showing how conclusions concerning depend crucially on assumptions regarding discounting and relative ‘Relative price effect’ is abatement run under high discount rate, but where the relative price of prices. Note: Emissions paths are shown for three different cases: a high discount rate case (upper line— the environmental good rises over time. labeled Nordhaus discounting), a case utilizing the lower discount rate argued for in the Stern Review (the Similarlower to Krutilla-Fisher, this model a high justification a lower line—labeled Stern discounting), and provides a run with the discount rate,for but using where the nonmarket impacts are attributed to the consumption of a representative environmental good whose relative price is discount rate on environmental goods. 57/60 References I [1] R. Perman, Y. Ma, M. Common, D. Maddison, and J. McGilvray, “Natural resource and environmental economics,”, 2011. [2] N. Stern, “The structure of economic modeling of the potential impacts of climate change: Grafting gross underestimation of risk onto already narrow science models,” Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 51, no. 3, pp. 838–859, 2013. [3] T. Faulwasser, C. M. Kellett, and S. R. Weller, “Mpc-dice: An open-source matlab implementation of receding horizon solutions to dice,” IFAC-PapersOnLine, vol. 51, no. 5, pp. 120–125, 2018. [4] S. Dietz and N. Stern, “Endogenous growth, convexity of damage and climate risk: How nordhaus’ framework supports deep cuts in carbon emissions,” The Economic Journal, vol. 125, no. 583, pp. 574–620, 2015. 58/60 References II [5] J. J. McCarthy, O. Canziani, N. Leary, D. Dokken, and K. White, Climate change 2001: Impacts, adaptation, and vulnerability report of ipcc working group ii, 2003. [6] W. Nordhaus and P. Sztorc, “Dice 2013r: Introduction and user’s manual,” Yale University and the National Bureau of Economic Research, USA, 2013. [7] A. Rezai and F. Van Der Ploeg, “Second-best renewable subsidies to de-carbonize the economy: Commitment and the green paradox,” Environmental and Resource Economics, vol. 66, no. 3, pp. 409–434, 2017. [8] N. H. Stern, The economics of climate change: the Stern review. cambridge University press, 2007. [9] T. Sterner and U. M. Persson, “An even sterner review: Introducing relative prices into the discounting debate,” Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 2008. 59/60 References III [10] M. L. Weitzman, “A review of the stern review on the economics of climate change,” Journal of economic literature, vol. 45, no. 3, pp. 703–724, 2007. [11] M. L. Weitzman, “Fat-tailed uncertainty in the economics of catastrophic climate change,” Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 2011. [12] M. L. Weitzman, “Ghg targets as insurance against catastrophic climate damages,” Journal of Public Economic Theory, vol. 14, no. 2, pp. 221–244, 2012. [13] D. J. Phaneuf and T. Requate, A course in environmental economics: theory, policy, and practice. Cambridge University Press, 2016. 60/60