How to Make Boards Work This page is intentionally left blank How to Make Boards Work An International Overview Edited by Andrew Kakabadse Henley Business School, University of Reading, UK and Lutgart Van den Berghe University of Ghent, Belgium Selection, introduction and editorial matter © Andrew Kakabadse and Lutgart Van den Berghe 2013 Individual chapters © Respective authors 2013 Softcover reprint of the hardcover 1st edition 2006 978-1-137-27569-1 All rights reserved. No reproduction, copy or transmission of this publication may be made without written permission. No portion of this publication may be reproduced, copied or transmitted save with written permission or in accordance with the provisions of the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988, or under the terms of any licence permitting limited copying issued by the Copyright Licensing Agency, Saffron House, 6–10 Kirby Street, London EC1N 8TS. Any person who does any unauthorized act in relation to this publication may be liable to criminal prosecution and civil claims for damages. The authors have asserted their rights to be identified as the authors of this work in accordance with the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988. First published 2013 by PALGRAVE MACMILLAN Palgrave Macmillan in the UK is an imprint of Macmillan Publishers Limited, registered in England, company number 785998, of Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire RG21 6XS. Palgrave Macmillan in the US is a division of St Martin’s Press LLC, 175 Fifth Avenue, New York, NY 10010. Palgrave Macmillan is the global academic imprint of the above companies and has companies and representatives throughout the world. Palgrave® and Macmillan® are registered trademarks in the United States, the United Kingdom, Europe and other countries ISBN 978-1-349-44633-9 ISBN 978-1-137-27570-7 (eBook) DOI 10.1057/9781137275707 This book is printed on paper suitable for recycling and made from fully managed and sustained forest sources. Logging, pulping and manufacturing processes are expected to conform to the environmental regulations of the country of origin. A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library. A catalog record for this book is available from the Library of Congress. Contents List of Figures vii List of Tables x Notes on Contributors xi Introduction Andrew Kakabadse and Lutgart Van den Berghe Part I 1 2 3 The ‘Outside In’ Perspective Exposing the 20th Century Corporation: Redesigning 21st Century Boards and Board Performance Nadeem Khan and Nada K. Kakabadse Corporate Income Inequality and Corporate Performance: Any Correlations? Filipe Morais, Andrew Kakabadse, Nada K. Kakabadse and Adrian Pryce How Chinese Styled Executive Remuneration Works: Evidence from Chinese Red-Chips Jessica Hong Yang and Nada K. Kakabadse 4 The Secret to Boards in Reinventing Themselves Ouarda Dsouli, Nadeem Khan and Nada K. Kakabadse 5 Reinventing Board Effectiveness: From Best Practice to Best Fit Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau 6 Fine-tuning Board Effectiveness Is Not Enough Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau Part II 7 1 11 44 75 95 137 153 The ‘Inside Out’ Perspective An Effective Board Makes the Necessary Trade-offs Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau v 187 vi 8 Contents Promoting Effective Board Decision-Making, the Essence of Good Governance Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau 9 The Appropriate Board Chair: A Reality Check Abigail Levrau and Lutgart Van den Berghe 10 The Leadership Attributes of the Chairman of the Board: An International Study Andrew Kakabadse, Nada K. Kakabadse, Chris Pierce and Frank Horwitz 11 CEO/Chairman Role Duality Desire: Resistance to Separation Irrespective of Effect Nada K. Kakabadse, Andrew Kakabadse and Reeves Knyght 211 268 292 311 12 High-Performing Chairmen: The Older the Better Nada K. Kakabadse, Reeves Knyght and Andrew Kakabadse 342 13 Aligning the Board: The Chairman’s Secret Nada K. Kakabadse, Reeves Knyght and Andrew Kakabadse 360 Index 381 List of Figures 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 2.1 2.2 2.3 2.4 2.5 2.6 2.7 2.8 4.1 4.2 5.1 5.2 5.3 6.1 6.2 Towards a new charter for the eco-corporation Global industrial corporate change – patterns of innovation for sustainability Closed trust relational networks of corporations in society (1900–2012) Diverse open trust networks of corporations in society (2012–2050) Executive pay, 2007 as per the ILLS estimates based on the annual reports of 15 of the largest corporations in the respective countries Percentage of all income obtained by shop floor employees as a percentage of all employees (Domestic Operations only) Ratio of average executive board compensation (R6) to average and median shop floor employee pay (R1) (2007–2010) Company (domestic operations) CGI** & Ratio Rank 6/ Rank 1* (2007–2010) Investors’ performance measures: CGI, EPS & SP (2007–2010) Employee performance measures: CGI, TURN and ABS (2007–2010) Financial and accounting performance measures (Domestic Operations): CGI, SAL, EBITDA (2007–2010) Financial and accounting performance measures (Group of Companies): CGI, SAL, EBITDA (2007–2010) How to make boards work Selection criteria Extract from the Walker Report (2009) Top 5 drivers for an active board of directors in unlisted companies (Required) evolution in board evaluation A congruence model for board effectiveness Board effectiveness tool vii 21 24 27 33 46 59 61 63 64 65 66 66 117 119 141 143 149 154 155 viii 6.3 6.4 6.5 6.6 6.7 6.8 6.9 6.10 6.11 6.12 6.13 8.1 8.2 8.3 8.4 8.5 8.6 8.7 8.8 8.9 8.10 8.11 8.12 8.13 8.14 8.15 8.16 8.17 8.18 8.19 8.20 8.21 8.22 8.23 8.24 8.25 List of Figures A systems framework for board effectiveness assessment A congruent and best fit board role Board typologies in function of relationship with management Board typologies in function of decision-making role Reflection questions Evaluation process of executive management Conceptual model of the strategy cycle Aspects of the strategic decision-making process Reflection questions on strategy Reflection questions on M&As A board’s strategic role in practice The guidance on good decision-making, given by the Belgian Corporate Governance Code Effective board decision-making thanks to group dynamics (2.2) Benefits of group decision-making Suggestions for board decision-making Standard flow of activities in the decision-making process Extract from the Walker Report regarding pressure for conformity A recipe for constructive dissent Extract from the Walker Report regarding the lack of challenge Steps for effective and constructive decision-making Recipe for managing conflict in the boardroom Reflection question on board dynamics The minimum requisite behaviours Reflection questions on altering board behaviour Methods for individual director assessment Attitude elements Effective non-executive director behaviour Director types Flaws in board meetings Tips for a director regarding board information Ten key questions on the company’s business Some business reflection questions Recommendations for the use of outside board advisors Extract from the Walker Report regarding director education Elements of a board (vacancy) profile Individual and group-oriented selection criteria 156 157 161 162 167 169 171 172 172 173 175 212 213 214 215 216 217 220 221 224 225 228 230 232 232 233 235 236 239 242 244 244 246 247 258 259 List of Figures 9.1 9.2 9.3 9.4 9.5 9.6 9.7 10.1 12.1 13.1 Extract from the OECD guidelines on board leadership The role of the chairman Extract from the Walker Report regarding board leadership Decision-making styles of chairpersons of BEL-20 and BEL MID companies Ten tips and tricks for a non-executive chairman Selection criteria for the chairman Extract from the Walker Report regarding time investment by the board chair South African chairman performance Performance: the chairman Boardroom behaviour ix 269 273 276 279 286 287 287 307 352 371 List of Tables 1.1 1.2 2.1 2.2 2.3 Internal corporate characteristics Externalities of the corporation Dominant theories on executive pay Key academic contributions Evolution of dividends, average executive compensation and average and median shop floor employee pay 2.4 Summary of significant Pearson correlations 4.1 Females on boards across continents 4.2 Average age of boards 4.3 Boards structures across regions 4.4 Characteristics for making boards work 4.5 Sample for model testing 4.6 Results 5.1 Types of monitoring 8.1 Individual director types 8.2 Competencies in function of the nature of the company 8.3 Competencies in function of the company’s strategy 8.4 Competencies grid 9.1 Comparison of board chairperson and CEO leadership 9.2 Board structure in Belgian listed companies 9.3 Chairman nomenclature 10.1 South African response segmentation 10.2 Age and board position of respondents in South Africa 12.1 Chairman’s attributes for effective performance x 13 15 53 54 60 67 98 100 105 118 120 121 139 236 255 255 256 270 271 271 300 301 348 Notes on Contributors Ouarda Dsouli, PhD, Postgraduate Researcher, University of Reading, UK. Jessica Hong Yang, Lecturer, Henley Business School, University of Reading, UK. Frank Horwitz, Director of School, Cranfield School of Management, UK. Andrew Kakabadse, Professor of Governance and Leadership, Henley Business School, University of Reading, UK. Nada K. Kakabadse, Professor of Policy, Governance and Ethics, Henley Business School, University of Reading, UK Nadeem Khan, PhD Researcher, University of Reading, UK. Reeves Knyght, Managing Partner, Mayfair Investment Management Ltd, UK. Abigail Levrau, Doctor Assistant, Member of the Management Committee, University of Gent, Vlerick Business School/GUBERNA, Belgium. Filipe Morais, Postgraduate Researcher, Henley Business School, University of Reading, UK. Chris Pierce, CEO, Global Governance Services Ltd, UK. Adrian Pryce, Senior Lecturer, Northampton Business School, University of Northampton, UK. Lutgart Van den Berghe, Professor of Corporate Governance and Executive Director, University of Gent, Vlerick Business School/ GUBERNA, Belgium. xi Introduction Andrew Kakabadse and Lutgart Van den Berghe Corporate governance challenges have increasingly been gaining societal attention and attracting media coverage. In parallel, the academic world as well as numerous service providers have heavily invested in researching governance practice and subsequently have questioned what value has been gained from such emphasis. The upgrading of the quality of governance knowledge and insight has undoubtedly positively impacted on the quality of governance implementation. Yet still there remains the critique that the attention given to governance has not sufficiently been capable of addressing fundamental societal and corporate concerns. Business leaders in particular have criticised researchers and commentators alike for drawing on overly simplistic assumptions of a complex reality and equally not sufficiently understanding the inside workings of boards of directors and the impact it has on governance practice. To a certain extent such critique has foundation. A greater proportion of research undertaken is based on secondary data, limited to publicly available disclosure of issues of governance application. Indeed, most academic researchers remain at a considerable distance from board practise and rely on governance characteristics which can easily be retrieved and assessed from external sources. Moreover governance publications, although robust from an academic research perspective, have a somewhat limited and narrow scope in addressing the complex interactions between board directors. The academic tradition of singly focusing on one or other input factor (often due to the lack of sufficient access to board directors), such as a separation of the roles of CEO and board chair, or on the effect of number of independent directors sitting on the board, does not provide sufficient insight into what is happening behind ‘closed’ boardroom doors. 1 2 Andrew Kakabadse and Lutgart Van den Berghe In reaction to such a minimalist approach, this book stands out. It offers a distinct collection of penetrating views into boardroom practice and governance application. The editors of this book themselves have decades of board experience, whilst concurrently working as academics in universities and business schools. They and the authors invited to contribute to this collection of original works have pursued practiceoriented and doctoral research concurrently, and this has resulted in academic publications as well as the development of numerous practical tools. In fact, this book is built upon the virtuous circle of ‘practice inspiring theory’, emphasising that the philosophy of theory through action improves governance application. What this book brings is a fresh look at the ‘thinking and doing’ of governance. Although politicians and corporations increasingly ‘pay more attention’ to corporate governance, there still remains the global challenge of reinventing governance structures and processes in order to cope with the breach of trust in business world over this last decade. The need for repositioning traditional governance thinking and a reconstruction of what value boards bring to the complex corporation of the 21st century, is here given due attention. This book tackles the twin challenges of insightful governance thinking and board value from two different but complementary angles. First, governance and the role of the board is examined from an ‘outside-in’ perspective. Based on international expertise and research, governance is scrutinised within a broader framework of cultural diversity and social and political complexity. In effect, Part 1 presents a macro and holistic framework that combines the basic questions concerning the purpose of the corporation with the geo-political phenomena that confront boards of directors. The authors raise existential questions on the role of corporations in society and emphasise the need for reinventing boards. In Part 2 the view offered is that of ‘inside-out’ with the focus on examining the optimal functioning and interaction of boards of directors with the management, the company, the shareholders and other relevant stakeholders. The purpose behind the exploration is to highlight ways to make governance and boards more effective in the interest of long-term value creation. The perspective taken is that governance is not an end in itself, but a means to an end. The book’s path-breaking contribution is to question the belief that governance codes and public monitoring can alone bring about the necessary improvements to board functioning. The need emphasised is for more granular fine tuning of board practice to the challenges at Introduction 3 hand, rather than a cut-and-paste of international best practices. Rather than reiterating what boards and their directors should do, the contributions to this collection take into deep consideration the processes and qualities necessary for effective board decision-making and their crucial impact on board effectiveness. Chapter 1, by Nadeem Khan and Nada Korac-Kakabadse, examines the challenge facing boards now and into the 21st century. Particular attention is given to examining the purpose of the corporation in a global environment where the ever greater ownership of wealth lies in the hands of an ever diminishing minority, all this set against concerns of sustainability and of social and human rights. The question is asked what will the world be like in 2040 and specifically what will be the role of boards by that same year. This chapter sets the scene for the rest of the book by emphasising the need for board dialogue as a primary requirement for innovation and sustainability. Having raised such a question, Chapter 2 focuses on a particular issue of boardroom debate, remuneration. Filipe Morais and colleagues report a study examining whether the ever greater inequality of remuneration in corporations impacts on corporate performance. The authors constructed a corporate GINI index (CGI), which highlights that increased sales (a measure of corporate performance) leads to increased remuneration inequality between staff and middle management, on the one hand, and top management, on the other. The chapter questions for how long boards can continue to ignore such trends especially when key government agencies such as the Central Intelligence Agency (CIA) are predicting social unrest as a result of greater social inequality. The theme of executive remuneration is continued but with a particular focus on China. Chapter 3, Jessica Hong Yang and Nada Kakabadse, reports the results of a qualitative study of board influence and executive remuneration practice in Chinese state-owned enterprises (SOEs). The results highlight the power of the CEO in determining levels of executive remuneration. The stated position is that SOE executives should be on a comparable scale with other state officials. In practice, however, CEOs of SOEs are reported to be wielding substantial influence over the board, shaping executive compensation according to their desires. Similar to findings in other studies, this preliminary study indicates that increased SOE executive remuneration is not linked to increased organisational performance. Instead non-transparent, personalised and idiosyncratic, executive-determined remuneration is the order of the day. The recommendation made is that government has to improve the 4 Andrew Kakabadse and Lutgart Van den Berghe Chinese legal and supervisory mechanisms, as leaving that to boards is unlikely to address concerns of income inequality. Having raised fundamental questions about board capability to address sensitive governance concerns, Ouarda Dsouli, Nadeem Khan and Nada Kakabadse in Chapter 4 explore how boards could reinvent themselves in order to more efficiently address the governance challenges being faced. The chapter identifies four critical characteristics determining board performance, diversity, leadership, cultural dynamics and sustainable innovation. A study of how boards fare along these four scorecard dimensions is reported for the 100 most sustainable global companies. The findings offer interesting insights into boardroom practice, largely determined by regulatory and cultural differences. In particular, European firms seem more concerned with board diversity and leadership than do their Anglo-American counterparts. However, the key message from this chapter is that board directors need to stand above their context and innovatively emerge with sustainable solutions that deliver value to their firm and society at large. Regretfully few boards are identified as being able to do just that. The theme of value continues in Chapter 5 by posing the question of whether board effectiveness can solely rely on attending to governance codes. The authors Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau acknowledge that a plethora of governance codes have induced a box ticking mentality amongst board directors. It is acknowledged that governance codes are a useful first step, but the need is to move beyond that taking account of all relevant contextual factors. The message is, adopt a holistic and systematic approach. Chapter 6 by Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau further pursues that holistic perspective by identifying a systems framework that can act as a board effectiveness assessment tool. External contrasting factors, such as regulation and societal norms, are integrated with corporate contingency factors, where the leadership of the board is recognised as the primary influence. This highly insightful chapter uniquely offers a balanced discussion between the twin outputs of governance, namely monitoring and mentoring. Having viewed governance from the outside, Part 2 analyses the main functioning of the board and discusses how these impact on the external world. Chapter 7 by Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau examines the tensions and trade-offs that occur on boards. The chapter emphasises that reaching consensus amongst directors is fundamental to effective board performance. However, consensus is not just about agreement but much more about how independent, free thinking Introduction 5 individuals meaningfully engage by challenging each other and yet still emerge as a collective body. Working through such contrasts requires trade-offs. Based on research and long experience, the chapter identifies the six cultural trade-offs that board directors need to consider. Through so doing, the reader is better able to determine the difference between negative, destructive board dynamics and positive negotiation and trade-offs in order to emerge as a more harmonious board. The capability to continuously lead through contrast and contradiction draws attention to the need for board leadership, particularly through the role of Chairman. In fact, the remaining six chapters of this book examine the role, contribution and required leadership capabilities of the Chairman of the Board. Chapter 8 by Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau reports the results of an international survey examining four key propositions, namely role, responsibilities, the nature of performance effectiveness and the need to encourage open debate amongst board members. In terms of role and responsibilities a fairly consistent picture emerges of chairmen across the world being attentive to their duties. However, in terms of communication, engagement and the softer side to board functioning, a more variable picture emerges. The overall conclusion is that the Chairman is pivotal in terms of influencing board and organisational outcomes and the area that most requires greatest attention is that of soft skills. Chapter 9 by Abigail Levrau and Lutgart Van den Berghe scrutinises the role of the Chairman differentiating between the internal facing and the external facing aspects of the role. It is clear that the roles of Chairman and CEO overlap and clear differentiation needs to be made between the two, particularly from the perspective of effective decision making. The authors offer a decision making grid contrasting the need for decision adoption against the concern for commitment to decisions made. The point emphasised is that board decision-making style is distinctly correlated to the Chairman’s personality, disposition and values. Recognising the importance of the board chair, the authors conclude the chapter by offering 10 tips for chairmen on how to enhance their performance and in so doing, the performance of the CEO. Chapters 10 through 13 continue with the theme of what it takes to make the Chairman the effective leader of the board. Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau have already made the point that clear separation needs to be made between the role of the CEO and that of Chairmen in order that the leading of the firm and leading the governance oversight process can be allowed to function. In Chapter 10, Chris Pierce and colleagues examine the particular case of South Africa and 6 Andrew Kakabadse and Lutgart Van den Berghe identify the Chairman of the Board as an isolated individual constantly rating their performance much higher than their other board members. The authors draw attention to the perceived social distance between the chair and other board roles and emphasise this as an area of concern that requires serious attention if boards are to be respected in South Africa. Along the same lines, Nada and Andrew Kakabadse and Reeves Knyght (Chapter 11) examine the particular circumstance of the USA. To this day, 75% of corporations have the same person as Chairman/ CEO/President. The authors question why this continues to be the case particularly in a governance climate of role separation. The qualitative study conducted by the authors concludes that the American psyche is Presidential. The one man making the key decisions is deeply interwoven into the fabric of the nation. Whatever governance wisdom prevails for the rest of the world, role unity is likely to continue in corporate America. Chapter 12 focuses on one particular characteristic of the highperforming Chairman, age. The study reported by Nada Kakabadse, Reeves Knyght and Andrew Kakabadse concludes the ‘older the better’. The reason? The wisdom that comes with age! The older Chairman exhibits a high level of reasoning and intellectual discourse but combined with a native intelligence on how to work through cultural and social dilemmas and conflicts. The outcome – ‘effective engagement’ – as opposed to the younger who are quick, mentally sharp and display how good they are, but in reality end up simply completing transactional deals. ‘Prophenisis’, in effect, practical wisdom, is a vital characteristic of the high performing Chairman. Bearing in mind that the United Kingdom has about 360,000 directors who are of pensionable age, the need to respect the particular contribution of the elderly director is now a pressing concern. The final chapter, Chapter 13, examines the particular skills of how high-performing Chairman align the varying interests of the board in order that shared and meaningful decisions emerge from the debate. The study reported highlights that the secret lies in the sharing of both positive and negative experiences with board members. In effect the legitimisation of boardroom encounters is fundamental to board members gaining the confidence to enter into open dialogue. The study emphasises that the Chairman’s balancing of powerful penetrative inquiry against nurturing a comfort of camaraderie, generates the positive culture necessary for open conversation. The challenge lies in surfacing inhibiting tensions, a cathartic experience, freeing up board conversations. Introduction 7 From an overview of governance and why have boards, to the particular value-adding skills of the Chairmen, this book offers a unique collection of contributions that are not only intellectually insightful but are also practically useful for board directors and chairmen. From why boards, to what to do on boards, this original collection is the board members guide to making boards work. Part I The ‘Outside In’ Perspective 1 Exposing the 20th Century Corporation: Redesigning 21st Century Boards and Board Performance Nadeem Khan and Nada K. Kakabadse Introduction Governance oriented boards are prevalent across different economic systems (Hall and Soskice, 2001), cultures (Hofstede et al., 2010) and national boundaries (single/dual structure) in which they are the leading clique within private, not-for-profit, public and hybrid organisations (Hermalin and Weisbach, 2003). Their purpose goes beyond regulation (Aguilera and Jackson, 2003), ameliorating the agency problem (Fama and Jensen, 1983; Berle and Means, 2009/1932) or shareholder wealth maximisation (Friedman, 1962) to balancing society’s needs and wants in a virtuous and accountable manner (Aristotle, 384–322 BCE; Smith, 1759). However, the emerging wider impacts of the corporation suggest deep concerns about the performance and management of boarddirected organisations with respect to market dominance (Kim, 2012), lobbying dynamics (Child et al., 2012), board remuneration (GregorySmith and Main, 2012), financial management (Berger et al., 2012), competitive behaviour (Porter, 2009) and political power struggle issues (Cutting and Kouzmin, 2002). In this regard, we know very little about boards themselves, as they have operated largely behind closed doors (Useem, 2003) and have traditionally had little active involvement in a corporation’s daily affairs (Scherrer, 2003). More importantly, we cannot understand boards in isolation (Useem, 1980). We require a holistic lens to critically appreciate the historical development, ongoing selective influences (Lewin and Volberda, 2003) and geo-political factors at play before peering into the boardroom itself to understand the detailed processes and issues that make a board work. 11 12 Nadeem Khan and Nada K. Kakabadse An overview of the corporation Take care of Fire, learn from Water, co-operate with Nature. Motto of Hoshi Ryokan, 718 A.D. World’s oldest currently operating company (46 generations) The world’s oldest continuously operating family firm, Buddhist temple builder Kongo Gumi, closed in 2006 after 1,400 years. The firm had succumbed to an excessive $314 million debt, which resulted from the 1980s property bubble, coupled with social change in Japan (The Economist, 2004). Takamatsu Corporation purchased the assets. Thus, the prestige of this title has been passed to Hoshi Ryokan (718 A.D.). In this regard, family businesses have outlasted governments, nations and cities (O’Hara and Mandel, 2004) and contribute 70% to global GDP (Family Firm Institute, 2012). However, only 16% survive beyond a generation (Davis, 2012). In the 20th century, some of the survivors have emerged as corporations benefitting from financially liberal market forces (Useem, 1980). In this regard, the world’s leading 2,000 corporations currently employ 83 million people, have $149 trillion in assets and generate $36 trillion in revenue (Forbes, 2012). However, although these corporations represent 46% of global GDP (Economy Watch, 2010), one-third of the Fortune 500 corporations that existed in 1970 disappeared by 1983 (Investopedia, 2011). The term ‘corporation’ derives from corpus, the Latin word for body or body of people, or corparoe, the Latin word for physical embodiment. The essence of body of people infers communities, shared collaborative understanding and common purpose. We can recognise the holistic embodied form whereby the parts contribute to the whole. In the historical business context (Hickson and Turner, 2005), Roman law (500 B.C.) recognised a range of corporate entities which included state and private bodies (universitas; corpus; collegium) in commenda form, or simply stated, a form of trust in which one delivered goods to another for a particular enterprise. We associate the modern context of the origins of the corporation (Brown, 2003) more so with feudal and monarchist governments that introduced legislation to enable shareholding. Mercantilism was alive and well. An example is Russia. In 1557, this nation granted monopoly rights for trade functions and risk management. The British East India Company was an English and later (from 1707) a British joint-stock company and megacorporation that pursued trade with the East Indies, but which ended up trading mainly with Exposing the 20th Century Corporation 13 the Indian subcontinent. The American government enacted the first limited liability law in New York (1811). This concept eventually spread to the UK in the form of the Limited Liability Act of 1855, and further across much of Europe. As such, Stora Kopparberg is one of the oldest industrial corporations. Established in a copper mining community in Sweden in 1288, it merged with Stora Enso, the Finnish integrated group of companies, in 1992. The historic mine has become a UNESCO World Heritage Site in 2001. We note that Adam Smith wrote his Wealth of Nations (1776) not long after the East Indian Company’s 1772 collapse. By the beginning of the 19th century, the US and UK governments had granted increasing rights and progression of legislation in their charters along with associated governance of these bodies. Interestingly, Berle and Means published their seminal work, The Modern Corporation and Private Property (2009/1932), not long after Black Tuesday (29 October 1929). Thus, over time, the corporate charter has developed, while the essence of collaborative purpose and communities has degenerated, leaving the corporation to become an artificial, transferable and immortal legal entity separate from human form along with its accountability and regulation of behaviour. The recent 2008 Global Financial Crisis (GFC) may provide us with an opportunity to reconsider The Wealth of Nations (Smith, 1776) and the board’s role (Berle and Means, 2009/1932) from a new perspective as the characteristics of the corporation (Table 1.1) appear to be at odds with its purposeful function in society. Table 1.1 Internal corporate characteristics Characteristics Purposeful function Twentieth-century corporation Board structure Human entity Legal entity Cultural dynamics Collaborative within society Monarchist/ feudal Diversity Stakeholders Shareholders Leadership Accountability to society Control of society Sustainability Beneficial trade Risk management Innovation Purposeful value Financial enhancement Source: Designed by authors. 14 Nadeem Khan and Nada K. Kakabadse Corporate cyclical change Merck is the oldest chemical and pharmaceutical company which dates back to 1668 (Germany), whilst in the United States, some of the oldest companies include General Electric (1876), Bank of New York (1784), Cigna Insurance (1792), JP Morgan (1799) and Dupont (1802). Interestingly, a recent Japanese database survey by Tokyo Shoko Research (2009) of 2 million companies determined that 21,666 companies are older than 100 years. Further, according to the Bank of Korea, firms older than 200 years include 3,146 Japanese firms, 837 German firms, 222 Dutch firms and 196 French firms. Notable UK firms include the Royal Mail (1516), Bank of Scotland (1695), Oxford University Press (1586), Schweppes (1783) and Harrods (1835). This makes today’s household corporate names such as Microsoft (1975) and Facebook (2003), which boasts 1 billion users in 2012, the new chariots of global cyclical technological change in society. We may ask, had it not been for those years ago, teenagers Bill Gates or Mark Zuckerman, would we be just replacing the names or the phenomena? What forms will these or new emerging corporations take in a hundred years from today? Nevertheless, our society’s corporate elders, such as the China Gas Company (1862), Nestle (1866), Hong Kong and Eu Yan Sang (1873), Unilever (1885), Great Eastern Life Assurance (1908), IBM (1911) and Rolls Royce (1914) and their extended economic supply chains and networks across the globe are continuously challenged to innovate and renew their value to society (Schumpeter, 1934) or suffer the ecological inevitability of systemic rebalancing (Adner and Kapoor, 2010; Kapoor and Lee, 2012). In the 21st century post-GFC era (Knyght et al., 2011), this is evident in the nationalisation and collapse of the banking sector. Take for example, the Royal Bank of Scotland, which is now 82% owned by the UK government, whilst Lehman Brothers became the largest bankruptcy filing in US history and Northern Rock had a bank run on 14 September 2007 as news spread that it was seeking emergency funding from the Tripartite Authorities. Lloyds TSB, founded in Birmingham, UK, in 1765, and the US-based Citibank, which began in New York in 1812, are both among the wounded. Since the financial crisis implosion from within the United States in 2008, 457 Banks just within the United States have failed (Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, 2012). Beyond the corporate institution, in highly regulated, educated and developed 21st century societies (Table 1.2), it seems very odd that Exposing the 20th Century Corporation Table 1.2 15 Externalities of the corporation Board externalities Firm impact Country Political culture and nature Industry Competitive innovation Source: Designed by authors. government institutions can freely create excessive debt (The Economist, 2012) without society questioning the decision makers about where the money is coming from and under what terms. Take for example, Greece, Ireland, Italy and Spain, who in recent months have all sought extended bailout funds from the European Central Bank (ECB). The United States recently announced its third quantitative easing programme (Katasonov, 2012) and critics have pointed to Greece’s recent bailout as the nation continues to maintain a proportionally large defence budget (Lendmenl, 2012; Smith, 2012). Whilst neo-liberal governments continue to increasingly burden the next generation’s tax payers, forecasts suggest that just to reduce national debt to 60% of GDP, which economists regard as a manageable level, will take Japan until 2084, Italy until 2060, France until 2029 and the UK until 2028 (Ventura and Aridas, 2012). The deeper question is whether democracy is working – considering that start-up businesses cannot obtain loans, but bank bailouts and government debts are spiralling. Further, it appears that the only real dialogue of value in competitive democracies takes place just before an election. As such, during 2008–2012, governments spent an extra $2.4 trillion due to the GFC, of which $1.9 trillion went to developed countries (twothirds of this to banks). In contrast, the $500 billion that governments spent in developing countries went to manufacturing, education and health industries. In the East, although the Chinese and Indian economies have recently benefited from the extended forces of neo-liberalism (Xu, 2011) and mass consumerism (Gerth, 2010), the concern is whether capitalistic history is repeating itself within these highly populated regions of the world. Is the East learning from the West’s sharing of ecological/technological advanced lessons? What are the far-reaching global impacts as the current growths of these economies slow down to reveal a new reality? In 2010 the developing countries China, India, Thailand, Indonesia and Malaysia received greatest inflows of capital and grew by an average of 8.4% (Forbes, 2012). We note the ongoing global economic hubs’ transition towards the East (Wolfensohn, 2010) 16 Nadeem Khan and Nada K. Kakabadse as evident by Petro China becoming the first $1 trillion corporation (Seattle Times, 2012) and the world’s largest global corporation in 2007 (Stainburn, 2012). In contrast, the US debt is officially at $16 trillion (2012) and a recent report has posited that it may more realistically be $50 trillion (Campbell et al., 2012). The corporate geo-political phenomena For us to have a deeper understanding of these social, natural and scientific phenomena, we must appreciate that the catalysts for 20th century corporations to develop have been major global events such as European feuds (World War I), emerging nationalistic tendencies (World War II) and apartheid in South Africa (1848). Over the centuries, these events have crystallised from within the complex Anglo-American bilateral relationship (1607–present) and European colonial intentions towards resources (Dutch, French, UK), among other geo-political shifts within society (Useem, 1980). However, the associated costs have been considerable and long-lasting. We have seen 160 million war casualties in the 20th century (Scaruffi, 2009). At the same time, renewed industries such as textiles, railways, coal mining and information technology have spawned and expanded. The academic literature in Western management commonly refers to the corporation (Drucker, 1972) and its internationalisation patterns, exemplified by the East Indian Company (1602–1778), from an economic shareholder perspective (Friedman, 1962). In this respect, the more open-minded and liberated scholars have appreciated and progressed the more meaningful notion of stakeholders (Freeman et al., 2010), whilst corporate spokespersons have adopted politically engaged terms such as corporate social responsibility (CSR) (Carroll, 1999, 2008; Matten and Moon, 2008) and citizenship (Palazzo and Scherer, 2008) to their advantage. Stewardship (Davis et al., 1997; Donaldson and Davis, 1991) has compounded the natural tension of the agency problem (Berle and Means, 1932; Jensen and Meckling, 1976). This has resulted in an epistemological and predominantly quantitative interpretation of competition (Porter, 2009) by corporate boards and their resulting compounded structures. Therefore, at the dawn of the 21st century, incentivisation has become a sophisticated numbers game where targets and league tables measure performance (Forbes 2000; Fortune 500; IMD, 2012). More importantly, society’s capitalistic culture fosters an agenda of class division that is based on material wealth and segregation. Although capitalistic and socialist systems offer opportunities, they are also inherently Exposing the 20th Century Corporation 17 open to cronyism and corruption which limits life-changing and worldimpacting opportunities. Perhaps an equitable balanced system which avoids extremes may offer an integrated way forward. The intensification towards extreme environments coupled with the competitive nature of corporations has contributed to the deeprooted oligopolistic practices (Akehurst, 1984) we observe. The corporation engages networks to protect her interests against societal pressures. This is exemplified by the formation of the National Foreign Trade Council (NFTC), founded in 1914 for the political lobbying of American corporations. In extreme cases, or hostile environments where lobbying may not work, corporations have engaged private independent agents in support of their agendas. Recently, Stiglitz and Bilmes (2007) identified that private security guards working for Blackwater and DynCorp earn $445,000/year compared with an American Army sergeant who receives $69,350/year. In this regard, the Business and Human Rights Resource Centre (2012) has expressed growing concern about human rights abuses by corporations such as Pepsi in Honduras and Shell in Nigeria. These are only two examples of a long list of cases. Analysts have also closely linked corporations such as Halliburton, Chevron and Lockheed Martin to politicians such as Dick Cheney and Condoleezza Rice. In consideration, we note that the dominant ideologies of the 20th century have been capitalism and communism (Marr, 2012) whilst at the same time, the largest exporters within the global arms business in 2009 were America (31%) and Russia (20%) (Singh et al., 2011). Thus far, throughout economic cyclical changes (Schumpeter, 1934) and societal impacting geo-political shifts, corporations seem to emerge ever stronger. As of 2000, 51% of the largest global economies were corporations (Anderson and Cavanagh, 2000). One of the major events in the early 21st century was the 2008 GFC. Legislative reform beyond the financial crisis emerged in the form of the Dodd-Frank Act (Obama, 2009/2010b), which in the United States included the Volcker Rule (Obama, 2010a). This Act has brought significant changes to financial regulation in America where the Volker Rule specifically aims to minimise conflict of interest between banks and their clients. In the UK, this has translated in the ring-fencing of retail banks from investment banking (Vickers, 2011). Ring-fencing occurs when a company financially separates a portion of its assets without necessarily operating as a separate entity. This could occur for regulatory reasons, for creating asset protection schemes with respect to financing arrangements or segregating separate income streams for taxation purposes. 18 Nadeem Khan and Nada K. Kakabadse In this respect, interestingly, from the late 19th century until the 1970s, bank assets as a percentage of GDP in the UK remained steady at around 50%. However, by 2006, this had climbed to over 500% of GDP (Prieg, 2011). Therefore, UK financial sector assets in relation to GDP were and are higher than most other countries. Further, in 2009, the UK pledged 101% of GDP in support of the banking sector, which is the dominant service sector fiscal contributor, whereas other nations such as the United States (42%), Germany (27%) and Japan (21%) contributed less. Simultaneously, over 50% of donations to the Conservative Party during 2009 and 2010 came from the City (Watt et al., 2011). Irrespective of financial restructuring in Anglo-American capitalistic environments (Hall and Soskice, 2001), corporations have extended their dominance whereby 95 out of the top 150 economies (63%) are corporations (Butler, 2005) and the question arises, ‘Are corporations more powerful than countries’ (Faroohar, 2012)? More worryingly, it seems as though corporate scandals such as Enron (2000) and News Corp (2011) are more a costly media justification of unaccounted events, whereas politicians seem to be embroiled in the web themselves (Expenses scandal; Watt and Newall, 2012), which is extending to new money markets (Bo Xilai scandal, 2012). In this regard, the corporate elites’ or business aristocracies’ interlocked networks are passing to the next generation (Useem, 1980). Thus, in 2012, the language of corporations is transitioning into renewed notions of sustainability (IMD, 2012), the green agenda (United Nations, 2012) and globalisation (Hopkins, 2011) as the Davos dilemma of whether nations can bridge the divide of the world’s political and economic forces unfolds (Khan et al., 2012). In this respect, the current geo-political forces (World Economic Forum, 2012) have emerged in the so-called democratisation of Iraq (Selim, 2012), Egypt (Harvey, 2012) and Libya (Van Genugten, 2011), which was encapsulated within the Arab Spring (Peters, 2012). As the conflict of Afghanistan is in demise (Pierce, 2011), an increasingly intensified conflict is unfolding and escalating within Syria (Brown, 2012; Ryan, 2012). Within Europe, a forced integration of countries, as a result of the Eurozone, is seeking to protect the Euro from collapsing (Moravcsik and Sangiovanni, 2003; Ryvkin, 2012) as disorientated societies such as Greece remain frustrated (Krugman, 2011). Further, the divide between the richest (Qatar) and poorest (Democratic Republic of Congo) nations on earth remains high (Pasquali and Aridas, 2012). Simultaneously, ecological natural phenomena continue to impact larger pockets of humanity. Most recently we have seen the 2011 Tohuku earthquake and tsunami in Japan, the Exposing the 20th Century Corporation 19 2010 Canterbury earthquake in England and the 2012 Hurricane Sandy, which hit the United States’ East coast with significant destruction in New York and New Jersey. The purpose of the corporation The global challenges in the second decade of the 21st century include rebalancing the corporate firm within society (McKelvey, 1997) where we ask, ‘What really is the corporation’s purpose within our society?’ At a global level, current unemployment has reached 200 million (International Labour Organisation, 2012), of which 75 million are youth (under 24). The International Labour Organisation forecasts the necessity of 600 million jobs in the next decade. The risk is that each corporate giant employs hundreds of thousands of people. The global retailer, Walmart, employs 2 million in the United States alone, whilst the largest employers in the world are currently the US Department of Defence with 3.2 million employees and the Chinese Army with 2.3 million. Seven out of the top ten employers are state companies and half of them are from China. There are also one in three workers who live on less than $2 a day (International Labour Organisation, 2012), in comparison with the six-figure salaries that board executives of corporations enjoy (FTSE 100; Dow Jones 30). The deeper concern here is that this is not restricted to developing / developed nations as 1.5 million American families with 2.8 million children are among the $2 a day bracket (Luhby, 2012). In contrast, the largest corporate salary in 2011 was $137 million for the CEO of Simon Property Group (Business Insider, 2012b). Looking through a wider lens further indicates that resources such as water will become scarce in parts of the world if we do not urgently take action (Scheffran and Battaglini, 2011). Our destruction of the planet has reduced tropical rainforests by 50% and increasingly urbanised cities are consuming 75% of global energy and 80% of CO2 emissions, which we can attribute to just 19 countries (Earth Observation Handbook, 2012). Presently, only 2 billion people have access to adequate energy and 1.3 billion have no electricity (Schnieder Electric, 2012). Scholars cite the 1920s depression in an attempt to explain the phenomena of dwindling resources and financial collapses (Thirwell, 2010; Skidelsky, 2011). Whilst the Gates Foundation points to population control (MacAskill, 2012), other organisations and bodies focus on environmental costing such as carbon taxes or competitive indices, such as the Yale based Environmental Performance Index (EPI), American 20 Nadeem Khan and Nada K. Kakabadse DowJones sustainability index or UK FTSE4Good index, to rebalance human life on planet Earth. However, systemic failure is apparent, as most recently the techno-giant Apple paid less than 2% taxes on its profits outside the United States despite an earnings surge of 50% to $37 billion in 2012 (BBC News, 2012). Thus, the current fiscal structure oddly continues to favour corporation against society. Therefore, the fundamental question for us is, ‘What is the corporate firm’s purpose?’ To achieve a more holistic understanding of the social phenomena which we call the corporation in the 21st century (McKelvey, 1997), we propose an alternative and innovative lens through which we should view it. This must include all global societies where we reverse the pyramid and give the base priority. In this way, our planet’s weakest societies benefit from the most investment. Second, we need to understand the corporation substantively (Kakabadse and Steane, 2010), whereby rationality includes ethics (MacIntyre, 1981; Dsouli et al., 2012) and the corporation is a work entity that consists of humans (Heidegger, 1927). In this respect human communities have a responsibility to other human societies and to the well-being of the planet itself. Therefore, people conducting business activities have virtuous purpose (Malloch, 2008) in supporting ecological and human flourishing (Karn, 2011). Third, history is situational (Irwin and Winterton, 2011) and offers insight into understanding experiences as social phenomena (qualitative) in a predictive capacity whereby developing history will be the judge of actions. Pivotal to this is the notion of public trust within relational exchange environments (between corporations and society), which has deteriorated to low levels globally (Bolton et al., 2009; Edelman Trust Barometer, 2012). This is a timely opportunity for societies to renew their charters and trust with corporations with respect to the practice and the conduct of business. In Figure 1.1, the left side represents tangible physical and economic forms which we can attribute to the corporation. The right side represents intangible values such as morals, ethics and well-being. The board has responsibility to the development of the firm along with a wider commitment to societal obligations. In this respect, the board of directors of the eco-corporation must provide sustainable solutions for which they are accountable to society. There also is opportunity to reconstruct how corporations create boards’ incentives based on a combination of performance measuring factors which will drive eco-competition. Societal corporate governance may foster better transparency and planning of the renewal process where the existing corporation may fulfil its purpose as a cash cow for innovation. The benefit for Exposing the 20th Century Corporation Eco-Form 21 Eco-Value Board of Directors Resources Population Distribution of Wealth Employment What is the Purpose of the Eco-Corporation? Globally Inclusive Ethical Behaviour Collaboration Societal Value Eco-Sustainability Trust Substantively Rational Human Entity History as Value Figure 1.1 Towards a new charter for the eco-corporation Source: Designed by authors. society is a structured transition of existing networks towards improved resilient environments that support infrastructure and employment / talent skills management for firm and societal value creation. Thus, the combination of form and value offers the board structured life-cycle renewal pathways towards achieving the longer term corporate vision. Importantly, in Figure 1.1, the term ‘eco’ seeks the longer term (30 years) and inclusive benefits for a global society. This consists of diverse market environments of many local societies. The corporation will thus be contracted by national charters where it engages in activities. More importantly, local societies may attract or disapprove of trading activities within their communities through unique governance mechanisms (Judge, 2010). Re-aligning the role of global governance structures The upper echelons of global governance come into play when re-aligning governance structures. The post-World War II global bodies such as the World Bank (WB), World Health Organisation (WHO) and International Monetary Fund (IMF) need to develop sustainable fair and pro-active policies and governance mechanisms that foster collaborative and beneficial partnerships at a global level. Currently, the fractured approach and political nature of these beasts does not allow this as exemplified by the recent ongoing instability in Syria. Instead, we see innocent populations suffer and politicians pursuing their own agendas. Interestingly, 22 Nadeem Khan and Nada K. Kakabadse Castells (2011) cites recent events of social change such as the Arab Spring or London riots that have lead to a crisis of trust between politics and finance and a restructuring of society. The technology-supported pockets of resistance consist of younger like-minded individuals who find common purpose in opposing dominance. Scholarly contributions also provide limited insight and understanding of these phenomena as many datasets are Western influenced and more importantly, dataset infrastructure and availability from the poorest nations remains elusive or vague at best. Exposing board structures and corporate cultures In order to expose board structures and corporate cultures, the longitudinal and globally encompassing lens must extend beyond the 21st century and modern colonial understandings of the corporation (e.g. Dutch, French and British) whereby patterns recognise that the inherent human appetite for control and power includes the rise and fall of empires such as the Spanish (1740), the Ottoman (1683), the Mongol (1309), the Roman (65 A.D.), the Greek (150 B.C.), the Egyptian (1450 B.C.) and the Chinese Zhou Dynasty (1122 B.C.). Dominant elites and their personal desires for change (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2012) have empowered largely the transcending and deeper interpretation of global trade’s cyclical development and its associated industries. In this regard, the West African 14th century king Mansa Musa I (1280–1331 A.D.), ruler of the Malian Empire (Ghana, Mali, Timbuktu), tops the list of the richest people in history, adjusted for inflation. Further, the top 25 people on the list are worth $4.317 trillion (Fleming, 2012), of which three are alive today. In 2012, this has translated into the elite corporate boards within our societal structures that determine human progression. Most recently, the Swiss Federal Institute (SFI) has posited that 147 international corporations control 40% of global wealth (Vitali et al., 2011). Thus, the boards of these corporations comprise no more than a few hundred people within a global population of 7 billion (WorldOmeter, 2012). More worryingly, these elites maintain their class stratum (Mills, 1956) and inter-personal relationships (Useem, 1980). The global lens further shows us that the eco-development of different industries varies geographically and globally. For example, the market research report for Global Retailing (Deloitte, 2012b) notes that the food industry has grown steadily over the century, supported by a growing global population. In this respect, no more than 140 people (Welch, 2012) within the UK control the top five food company boards. This Exposing the 20th Century Corporation 23 represents a 70% market share (Institute of Grocery and Distribution, 2010). Comparatively, the mobile communication or technological industries experience much more dramatic cyclical development over shorter timeframes as innovation impacts progress. Take, for example, the digital music industry. Another example is Nokia’s 92% fall in market share since the launch of Apple’s iPhone in 2007 (Moritz and Aaron, 2012). Back in 1997, Apple was facing bankruptcy and has since then increased its value 80-fold in the last decade (Moritz and Aaron, 2012). We have seen also the corporate cases of Google in China (Thompson, 2006) and the legal battle between Apple and Samsung over intellectual property (Albanesius, 2012; BBC News, 2012), which involve ever increasing amounts of US dollars where national regulation and corporate global values collide (Heineman, 2010). Within this web, critics are increasingly questioning the role of media (Bailey, 2004) and technology. Examples include the Leveson Inquiry (2011) where the culture, practice and ethics of the British press were called into question and victims included politicians, sportspersons and public figures (Tsaliki et al., 2011; Rojek, 2012). In 2011, we saw the News of the World scandal in which the newspaper’s editor and a private investigator were charged for hacking the phone of members of the Royal Family (Carney, 2012). The combination of these information streams has compounded where technological regulation and surveillance is fast replacing older mobile and web monitoring systems. Privacy International’s survey (2007) identifies China, Malaysia, Russia, the UK and the United States as endemic surveillance societies, with monitoring bodies such as the 1994 US Communications Assistance for Law Enforcement Act and the 2005 European Data Retention Directive. There is also growing concern that governments across the globe have introduced a raft of new legislation for monitoring following 9/11. For example, the UK has 1.85 million surveillance cameras (Thompson and Gerrard, 2011), most of which are privately owned (92%). Here, the grey area between private and public information has become an uncomfortable balance of risk and safety. The point remains that technology ownership and the control that drives multimedia outlets still lie in a few hands (Leys, 2003): ones that are, therefore, in a position to utilise media as a central instrument for advancing private, as opposed to public, interests. Therefore, those who control the opinion-moulding media, which includes television, radio, newspapers, magazines, books and film, speak with a single voice, each reinforcing the other and, in turn, eroding democracy, individual liberty, educational and personal freedoms for a diverse society (Bagdikian, 2004; Kakabadse et al., 2007, 2010). 24 Nadeem Khan and Nada K. Kakabadse However, this collision of state and corporation or public and private is not new and has previously occurred where American corporations such as GE, IBM, Dupont and Kodak had interests in Hitler’s Germany during 1933–1939, or in South Africa during apartheid. In the 21st century, scholarly contribution posits that national governance mechanisms (Aguilera and Jackson, 2003) which have traditionally protected industries like the Indian retail sector are being challenged by global corporations. We may better understand the relationship of country governance and corporate governance in new ways such as national governance bundles (Zattoni and Judge, 2012). However, regardless of how one interprets this relationship, the corporate behaviour of firms remains individualistic and profit-biased. This is exemplified by Suncor Energy, which is one of Canada’s largest resource companies and dominates in the Global 100 clean capitalism sustainable companies list (Global 100 List, 2012). Yet it has production fields in both Syria and Libya (Suncor, 2012). Thus, at a global level, industry innovation patterns (Figure 1.3) are deeply connected across nations and transformation in one part of the world triggers change on a large scale. In the current climate, it is the financial, technologically driven media and food industries that are at the forefront of social structures (see Figure 1.2). In the context of the increasingly interconnected and highly populated global environment, the connection between capital and innovation within the legal corporation (Morck, 2012) does not appear to be fulfilling societal needs-creating value as performance. In the 20th century scholars have theorised, explained and analysed the firm (Coase, 1937) in terms of behaviour (Cyert and March, 1963), transaction costs 10 8 6 4 2 0 1960 1970 Food 1980 Technology 1990 Financial 2000 Media 2010 Population Figure 1.2 Global industrial corporate change – patterns of innovation for sustainability Source: Compiled by authors. Exposing the 20th Century Corporation 25 (Williamson, 1975) and more recently as resources and capabilities (Wernfelt, 1984). However, the range of alternative approaches concludes no clear holistic understanding of the firm. We assume the reason to understand the firm has been to enhance contribution of positive value through innovation (Pitelis and Teece, 2009) in some way. However, underlying corporate concerns have persisted into the 21st century. Take for example, the audit fraud of Enron in United States, the accusations of bribery against Walmart in Mexico, the exposure to sub-prime lending which caused the international collapse of Lehman Brothers, the phone hacking scandal of Newscorp and most recently the conduct of employees within the BBC in the UK which has led to the resignation of the Director General. More so, in today’s dynamic (Mintzberg et al., 2009), chaotic global environment, politicians are constantly at odds with (Halliday, 2011) or in the pockets of financially incentivised corporate boards (Peltz, 1995). These observed behaviours indicate lack of trust, inadequate transparency and self-motivated purpose at a time when there is an urgent need for firms to deliver value. One of the ways to restore trust is through improving the skills and talents of potential future board members. The role of educational establishments is critical and a wider diversification of talent selection processes by corporations is warranted. The grooming of future board members is not just about having knowledge, but more so about the application of knowledge to change behaviour. Higher level academic institutions also collaborate with industry on research projects, but many critics argue that scholarly research is disengaged in bridging the gaps between society and firm (McKelvey, 1997). The volatile changes to school curricula (BBC, 2012), pressures of league tables (The Guardian, 2012), systemic standard teaching models and tiered grading criteria seem focused on the detail, but not on the broader understanding in bridging industry needs and innovation (Etzkowitz and Leydesdorff, 2000). More concerning are lower educational standards (Hurt, 2012) and increased student plagiarism. Most recently, 125 students at Harvard in a class of 250 are facing joint disciplinary action in a cheating scandal (Business Insider, 2012a). Meanwhile, African countries including Mali, Niger and Ethiopia have some of the lowest global literacy rates (Rehman, 2011). Among the scholarly circles, many of the corporate board elites seem to be honorary graduates or involved in some capacity with high-fee institutions (Harvard, Oxford). Consequently, instead of focusing on teaching agendas and behaviour of students, the universities are treating students as consumers (Kuchler, 2012) or increasingly fostering private finance which raises the potential for a conflict of 26 Nadeem Khan and Nada K. Kakabadse interests within research output. Educational establishments need to foster innovation for social reform and boards need to adopt diversified open networks. Within the current closed networks, passing political legislation (Vickers, 2011) and industry regulations such as the Cadbury Code and its revisions (1992, 2010) or the Sarbanes Oxley Act of 2002 fosters corporate cultures to anticipate, pre-empt and manipulate practices such as protectionism, oligopolistic behaviour and ethical reporting more effectively and efficiently. Most recently, US corporations are rising once again to new levels with the top 14 companies earning $248 billion in the last 12 months and their market value is more than Germany’s GDP (Moritz and Aaron, 2012). Thus, the corporation’s purpose in productive utilisation of capital has deteriorated to that of hoarding and building capital (Apple has more than $100 billion cash; banks are not lending capital) in riskier environments and within more complex and digitally disguised network structures. As a result, the notion of innovation becomes diluted to profit maximisation (Friedman, 1962) rather than societal value (Morck, 2012) and the corporation fosters a culture of self-worth rather than societal benefit in which the innovators are more likely to lose out or be exploited. When capital and innovation meet, the outcomes are global. Look at consumer goods such as cars, electricity, mobile phones, Internet and nanotechnology. In this regard, the innovators have a purposeful approach to providing a solution to a problem. Did Henry Ford (1863– 1947) or Thomas Edison (1847–1931) know the impact of their innovations on society and were they motivated by profit? What would they say if they were in the world today and most importantly, what skill sets and behaviours would enable them to successfully contribute? Corporate boards today appear concerned with self-interest as they work in an environment that must cater to agency and shareholder mindsets. This can be observed in the recent News of the World scandal in 2011 and the Barclays interest rate scandal of 2012. Consequently, the flow of trust between these interlocking groups of relational exchange networks has fractured and requires urgent restructuring (Figure 1.3). Further, the political, corporate, media and scholarly board members’ teleological engagement within society has exacerbated existing tensions to an extent whereby lack of trust has alienated society (Figure 1.3). Consequently, outsider stakeholders across individual and regional societies such as Egypt, Greece, Libya, Ireland and Spain are calling for reform within and beyond the highly urbanised megacities. Over 50% Exposing the 20th Century Corporation Private and PPP Corporations 1 Industrialists 2 Financial Structures Governments National Society 4 Scholarly Research Techno-Media Journalists and Broadcasters 3 Academic Institutions TRUST 1) Lobbying and Regulation 27 Geo-Political Competitive Global Environment 2) Production and Consumerism 3) Propaganda 4) Justification and Planning Flow of Broken Trust TOP DOWN STRUCTURE Figure 1.3 Closed trust relational networks of corporations in society (1900–2012) Source: Designed by authors. of the global population lives in cities. Human life spans are increasing, with the average age rising to 44 globally and resources are becoming scarce, with 40% of land used for food production. We require new technological or scientific solutions to support basic human and ecological survival (United Nations Millennium Declaration, 2000). The increasing divergence of wealth and its protectionism suggests that incentives such as salaries, bonuses and shares for corporate board members are failing to deliver for societies which suggests that eco-pressures including NGOs, global warming, poverty and war may implode further. This culminates in a scenario where the politicians understand their nation or region as a non-human, corporate legal entity which the governing boards will allow to collapse. We have witnessed this recently in Ireland and Greece. Making boards respect diversity At the heart of this dialogue is that society has progressed through global cycles over the ages (Schularick and Taylor, 2009). Yoshikawa’s (2012) analysis of director behaviour and institutional effect suggests that Eastern societies have longer, culturally richer, but slow moving traditional environments driven by personal human relations and informal institutional logic, whereas Western innovation and technological advancement has impacted society more in the 20th century driven by organised structured systems and formal institutional logic. Therefore, it has been the dominance and expansion of Western capitalistic forces 28 Nadeem Khan and Nada K. Kakabadse over the last century that have enabled the Anglo-American corporate model to grow. We also see that the global human population increased from 275 million in 600 A.D. to 1 billion by 1900, followed by a drastic rise to 7 billion in 2012 (WorldOmeter, 2012). East Asia has most of the population (India/China), whilst the West maintains its status quo. Thus, stable systems have allowed boards to make the link between capital and innovation, but more so to induce economic activity (Friedman, 1962). As a result, where companies once took pride in manufacturing products ‘to last a lifetime’, in the 21st century products and services are more a commodity of the day as the pace of renewal is so fast. More concerning is that it seems as though life itself is fast becoming a commodity. To speak to someone on the other side of the world in 600 A.D. was unthinkable, whilst in 2012, we can communicate globally within seconds. Thus, it is intelligence (Gardener, 1993) and self-awareness (behaviour) that allows humanity to survive and adapt. In the 21st century there is scope for a shared vision of the future that respects diversity of nations within a collaborative balanced global environment. However, for this to become a fruitful reality, corporations must restructure their compounding globalisation agendas so that diverse societies are able to determine their position through each society’s governance of trade and corporate structures, starting at the grassroots level. Therefore, social reform innovators may better link themselves to productive capital (Morck, 2012). The current development cycle posits weakened governmental control against increasingly economically dominant corporations (Kakabadse et al., 2006). It is therefore no surprise that Walmart’s global revenue is greater than the GDP of 174 nations (Forbes, 2012) and each of the top corporations is highly networked based on employment, suppliers and customers. When renewal occurs the impact is beyond any geographic or economic border, making the collapse of a corporation uncontrolled by regulatory pressure. Similar to the 1920s, pre-colonial empires and individualistic cultures are seeing that the time for change is once again pressing. It is paramount that boards, in an attempt to create social well-being, globally respect others and call for urgent corporate reform to enable 200 nations to rebalance and harmonise society. We cannot allow history to repeat itself. We have endured enough wars. Instead, we must foster behavioural change for the future. The difficult task is to respectfully change corporate boards’ mindsets in the currently competitive geo-political environment in which humanity may face risk (World Economic Forum, 2012). Exposing the 20th Century Corporation 29 Confucius (551–479 BCE) emphasised personal and governmental morality, the correctness of social relationships and justice within his philosophical teachings (Quiyum and Salimullah, 2005). More so, it was the patient and persistent route to bringing change to China’s existing feudal aristocratic system towards a governed and legalised state system which history acknowledges and appreciates today (Cheung, 2012). Thus, China stands as a collective populous and geographically large single country (Zheng, 2012). Where Western societies are close to self-destruction, it is the Chinese (communist), Indian (democratic) and emerging economies that are the engine rooms of current growth and economic activity (World Economic Outlook, 2012). In the post-GFC era, it is the emerging markets that represent a rising contribution to GDP (30%) (Prasad and Prasad, 2006; Evans, 2010). The headquarters of many of the largest global corporations remain within the developed countries, where procedures and practices of boards are to some extent regulated. Within these societies individuals are more knowledgeable about their rights and their ability to protest or complain. The corporate board’s behaviour has to react and respond to society. Unfortunately, when weaker or poorer communities oppose the board the economically stronger stakeholder wins. This is exemplified by cases where the indigenous populations in Queensland (Australia), Chaco (Bolivia) and Chad face adversity as a result of resource extraction (Le Billion, 2001; Sawyer and Gomez, 2012). What will become of the Aborigines, African tribes and American Indians? Rather than being reactive and protectionist, the board should behave proactively and in collaboration with local societies. The rights and freedoms of knowledgeable societies have to extend to unregulated environments if they are to achieve collective balance. Instead, there is a distinct lack of diversity in corporate elite representation and an increased pounding of geo-political forces in the quest for resources such as energy and food. Thus, Adam Smith’s (1776) call for ethical/moral substantive understanding resonates in Stiglitz’s (2010) discomfort between rich and poor. We sometimes forget that the East Indian Company was governmentbacked (The Economist, 2011). Similarly, 80% of China’s, 60% of Russia’s and 35% of Brazil’s stock markets consist of state-backed companies today. State-backed enterprises have thrived in the post-GFC climate (2008–2012) and represent 20% of the top global companies and 28% of emerging market economies. China Mobile has 600 million customers. Saudi Arabia’s SABIC, founded in 1976, is the world’s most profitable chemical company. Russia’s Gazprom is the world’s largest natural gas 30 Nadeem Khan and Nada K. Kakabadse company. Russia has proposed a new super state-backed corporation for the development of Siberia’s natural resources and many of the listed corporations in the Middle East (Forbes, 2012) are government/kingdom supported, such as Emirates Airlines. Many of the more recently established emerging markets from the 1960s onwards, even in neo-liberal markets, have established flourishing public private partnerships (PPPs) (Deloitte, 2012a). Under austerity programmes, the UK government has cut drastically public sector expenditure in areas such as health, education and city councils. Experts forecast economic growth at 1–2% at best, whereas emerging markets forecast 5–6% as an average (The Economist, 2012). The advantage of the PPP model is that the corporation benefits from limited liability as opposed to unlimited liability and further has political support in entrepreneurial activities. If there is trust and dialogue (Shaoul et al., 2012), innovation drives the politicians to change and govern in the company’s favour. Looking back on history, the East Indian Company is responsible for much innovation in the UK (Bowen et al., 2002). Furthermore, one-third of foreign direct investment in emerging markets from 2003 to 2010 has come from hybrid statebacked corporations. The risk or downside of this approach is that these national hybrid corporations can be too big and can monopolise the marketplace unfairly (Hwang et al., 2012). Deloitte (2012a) further identified maintaining political support and structuring finance for development projects as current challenges to this corporate format. Thus, corporations require a critically balanced strategic approach to regulate and incentivise trade in favour of sustainable innovation, as we see in Singapore (Hwang et al., 2012; Shaoul et al., 2012). What will the world be like in 2040? The ice has melted in the Poles (Lemke, 2012), sea levels have risen (Schaeffer et al., 2012), global population has increased towards 9 billion (United Nations, 2004), the Chinese Communist Party becomes a two-tiered structure (Lee, 2012), BRIC (Brazil, Russia, India and China) nations are economically strong and the average age of the global citizen will be 44 (United Nations, 2012). New industries will have emerged such as space travel with Virgin, and we will use water-based petrol as fuel for transport (Trott, 2012). There will be applications of technohuman integrated chips within robotics and virtual environments. Scientists will harness new forms of energy such as ethanol, hydrogen Exposing the 20th Century Corporation 31 and mobile power units. Alternative fiscal structures will have emerged such as carbon taxing, virtual taxes and individual residence taxes rather than household taxation. At the forefront of societal renewal will be underwater cities and holidays on floating pods at sea. The alternative scenario may also be one of mass migrations of society around the globe based on age rather than family structures. Thus, employment will be mechanistic and fixed based on life cycles. De-humanisation will foster new hybrid digital forms, which may inhibit or enhance freedom and understanding within birth-implanted neuro-networks. The fall of China and India will have replenished the rise of Africa as the capitalistic corporate dominant continent in the world making Europe the less developed continent. Humanity may realise the reality of world peace or alternatively, humanity may be recovering from global disease, another war or ecological catastrophe. In this regard, the optimistic lens provides a hybrid ecologically balanced utopia, which may actually offer less stressful and more enriched lives for humanity. It becomes clear that critical to behaviour is education and innovation which have historically, naturally, scientifically and socially benefitted humanity throughout the ages. Thus, the social unique selling point (USP) will be value-based knowledge systems. A reinvigorated form of competition for good and fair aspirations will support and inform this hybrid sustainable holistic system. At the command centre of this social phenomena will be the highly respected role of boards. What will be the role of boards in the corporations of 2040? What type of corporation do we want in 2040? What types of people do we want running our corporations? How should we conduct trade? Which will be the lead industries? How can we best connect innovation and productive capital? How do we understand the well-being of society and the function of the corporation within it? Is competition healthy? What will be the geo-political and regulatory frameworks of tomorrow? Will we see a single corporation in the future or will preservation of culture, diversity and freedom remain important to humanity? Is the media’s portrayal of society transparent and trustworthy? What will be family, moral and social norms in 2040? These are some of the legitimate questions that emerge and central to these questions is the function and role of boards of corporations in directing and leading firms as guardians and propagators of change in society. 32 Nadeem Khan and Nada K. Kakabadse A recent in-depth American study of boards as interlocking inner circles (Useem, 1984) with multi-board directorships amongst friends (Chu, 2012) may suggest an unravelling of elitism or it may posit a shift in economic base from the United States to new markets such as China and India. However, looking through a wider lens, we can appreciate that beyond Anglo-American capitalism (Hall and Soskice, 2001) there are alternative single- and dual-tier structures and modes of governance, for example in China, Malaysia or Europe, that may offer insight into the role of boards, their governance and interaction with society in a more balanced way. In this transitory phase, another study has identified that the role of chairman (or chairperson) within the board should adopt a more vocal and visible role within and beyond the corporation (Grant Thornton, 2012). There also appears to be an emerging trend towards a more ethical basis in directing the firm (Grant Thornton, 2012). With this in mind, we may adopt a global exploratory lens to investigate the patterns, practices and issues of making boards work within the globally diverse context with a view to establishing attributes that may offer eco-balanced and cohesive societal transformation in the 21st century. We spend much of our lives learning and then contributing to society. However, in 100 years from today what will the history books report about the legacy that this generation left on planet Earth? More so, will the next generation of elites renew the 20th century economic war in a virtual context or are they prepared to take a risk and legitimise broader control? This insatiable appetite for competitive control is odd as history suggests that we do not take our worldly possessions with us beyond the end of life and what we leave behind was never actually in the destiny of the individual to have or use. After all, what use and value is a large bank balance to a dead man? The legacy that will remain will be embedded in the lessons of history and in the trust and character of the behaviours of the next generation. Reflecting on history and understanding the current social phenomena, corporate boardrooms may offer opportunities to renew charters and rebuild trust with society beyond the 20th century’s divide-andrule hierarchical syndrome towards an inclusive and innovative respectful future for all to share. In society’s globally diverse strata, let us open the doors to the boardrooms and rebuild transparency through open networks and trust with society (Figure 1.4). In Figure 1.4, we may redesign the current Charters of Corporation (Figure 1.3) and reflect a new social solidarity (Useem, 1980) in directing corporate structures based on common ideology. Consequently, Exposing the 20th Century Corporation Private and PPP Corporations Financial Structures Industrialists Governments 2 1 2) Globally Unique Industries 4 3) Informative and High Quality News National Society 3 Techno-Media Scholarly Research Journalists and Broadcasters Academic Institutions TRUST 1) Diverse regulation and transparent structures for capital/innovator 33 Globally Collaborative Interdependent Societies 4) Innovative and Sustainable Research. Trusted Transparency SOCIETAL DRIVEN STRUCTURE Figure 1.4 Diverse open trust networks of corporations in society (2012–2050) Source: Designed by authors. ownership, directorship and management strata align within the triple innovative helix (Etzkowitz and Leydesdorff, 2000) as society shifts from centralised closed networks (Mills, 1956) to diverse open board structures and cultures with purposefully operating boards. Therefore, we will base the way in which boards work and in which we understand them on the renewable talent and skill structures consisting of human and social capital (Yoshikawa, 2012), which will engage resources and values (Figure 1.1) for tomorrow’s diverse and self-sustainable societies. References Adner, R. and Kapoor, R. (2010) Value creation in innovation eco-systems: how the structure of technological independence effects firm performance in new technology generations. Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 31, No. 3, pp. 306–333. Aguilera, R.V. and Jackson, G. (2003) The cross-national diversity of corporate governance: dimensions and determinants. The Academy of Management Review, Vol. 28, No. 3, pp. 447–465. Akehurst, G. (1984) Checkout: The analysis of oligopolistic behaviour in the UK grocery retail market. The Service Industries Journal, Vol. 4, No. 2, pp. 189–242. Albanesius, C. (2012) Judge denies Apple request for ban on Samsung products. 18 December. http://www.pcmag.com/article2/0,2817,2413334,00.asp Anderson, S. and Cavanagh, J. (2000) The top 200: The rise of corporate global power. Institute for Policy Studies. http://s3.amazonaws.com/corpwatch.org/ downloads/top200.pdf, accessed 8 November 2012. Aristotle (384–322 BCE/1984) in Barnes, J. (ed.) The Complete Works of Aristotle. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, revised Oxford Translation, Vols 1–2. 34 Nadeem Khan and Nada K. Kakabadse Bagdikian, B.H. (2004) The Media Monopoly, revised and updated version. Beacon Press, Boston, MA. Bailey, G.J. (2004) Short-circuiting democracy? The paradox of competition in news papering and why we can’t get ‘there’ from ‘here’. Unpublished PhD thesis, Simon Fraser University, Vancouver. http://summit.sfu.ca/item/7680 BBC (2012) GCSE exam changes to be announced by Michael Gove. 16 September. http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/education-19614839 BBC News (2012) Apple paid only 2% corporation tax outside US. 4 November. http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/business-20197710. Berger, A.N., Imbierowicz, B. and Rauch, C. (2012) The roles of corporate governance in bank failures during the recent financial crisis. 26 July. http://ssrn. com/abstract=2021799 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2021799. Berle, A.A. and Means, G.C. (2009) The Modern Corporation and Private Property, with a new introduction by Weidenbaum, M. and Jensen, M. Transaction Publishers, Rutgers, NJ. Originally published in 1932 by Harcourt, Brace and World. Bolton, R., Freeman, R., Harris, J., Moriarty, B., Nash, L. and Wing, M. (2009) The dynamics of public trust in business – emerging opportunities for leaders, www.darden.virginia.edu/corporate-ethics/pdf/public_trust_in_business.pdf, accessed 8 November 2010. Bowen, H.V., Lincoln, M. and Rigby, N. (eds) (2002) The Worlds of the East India Company. Boydell & Brewer, Woodbridge, Suffolk. Brown, B. (2003) The History of the Corporation, Volume One. God Demon Master Parasite or Provider – What is a Corporation? BF Communications, Boston, MA. Brown, C. (2012) Difficult decisions lie ahead over Syria. But these decisions are mainly for the Turkish leadership rather than the British Cabinet. British Politics and Policy at LSE. Business and Human Rights Resource Centre (2012) http://www.business-humanrights.org/, accessed 18 December 2012. Business Insider (2012a) Harvard is investigating 125 undergrads in Massive Cheating Scandal. 30 August. http://www.businessinsider.com/harvardcheating-scandal-2012–8. Business Insider (2012b) 50 highest paid CEOs in America. 25 May. http://www. businessinsider.com/the-50-highest-paid-ceos-in-america-2012–5 Butler, R.A. (2005) Corporations among largest global entities, rank above many countries. 18 July. http://news.mongabay.com/2005/0718-worlds_largest.html Campbell, R.N., Byler, D., Schumann, M. and Eggers, W.D. (2012) The Untold Story of America’s Debt. A Deloitte Series of Making America Stronger. Deloitte Publication, London. http://www.deloitte.com/assets/Dcom-UnitedStates/Local%20Assets/ Documents/Federal/us_fed_Election_Series_DEBT_010612.pdf Carney, D. (2012) Fear and Loathing: Media Accountability after the Phone-hacking Affair. In: The Phone Hacking Scandal: Journalism on Trial. Abramis. ISBN 1845495330 Carroll, A.B. (1999) Corporate social responsibility: evolution of a definitional construct. Business and Society, Vol. 38, pp. 268–295. Carroll, A.B. (2008) A history of corporate social responsibility: concepts and practices, in Crane, A., McWilliams, A., Matten, D., Moon, J. and Siegel, D. (eds) The Oxford Handbook of Corporate Social Responsibility. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp. 19–46. Exposing the 20th Century Corporation 35 Castells, M. (2011) The Rise of the Network Society: The Information Age Economy, Society and Culture, 2nd edition. Wiley Blackwell, New York. Cheung, K. Chi-Kin (2012) Away from socialism, towards Chinese characteristics: Confucianism and the futures of Chinese nationalism. China Information, Vol. 26, No. 2, pp. 205–218. Child, J., Rodrigues, S.B. and Tse, K.K.-T. (2012) The dynamics of influence in corporate co-evolution. Journal of Management Studies, Vol. 49, pp. 1246–1273, doi: 10.1111/j.1467–6486.2012.01057.x. Chu, J.S.G. (2012) Who killed the inner circle? The end of the era of the corporate interlock network. 26 May. http://ssrn.com/abstract=2061113 or http:// dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2061113. Coase, R.H. (1937) The nature of the firm. Economica (London School of Economics) New Series, Vol.4, No. 16, pp. 386–405. Cutting, B. and Kouzmin, A. (2002) Evaluating corporate board cultures and decision making. Corporate Governance, Vol. 2, No. 2, pp. 27–45. Cyert, R.M. and March, J.G. (1963) A Behaviour Theory of the Firm, 2nd edition. Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ, reprinted 1992. Davis, J. (2012) Trade secrets of the oldest family firms in U.S., Harvard Business School interview. http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/business-18261045. Accessed August 2013. Davis, J.H., Schoorman, F.D. and Donaldson, L. (1997) Towards a stewardship theory of management. Academy of Management Review, Vol. 22, No. 1, pp. 20–47. Deloitte (2012a) The global PPP market 2012. A PPP bulletin and partnership bulletin survey. http://www.deloitte.com/assets/Dcom-UnitedKingdom/ Local%20Assets/Documents/Industries/uk-icp-global-ppp-market-2012-report.pdf. Accessed November 2012. Deloitte (2012b) Global powers of retailing reports. http://www.deloitte.com/ view/en_GX/global/f9f6b21f1d464310VgnVCM1000001a56f00aRCRD.htm. Accessed November 2012. Donaldson, L. and Davis, J. (1991) Stewardship theory or agency theory: CEO governance and shareholder returns. Academy of Management Review, Vol. 20, No. 1, pp. 65–91. Drucker, P. (1972) The Concept of the Corporation. The John Day Company, New York. Dsouli, O., Khan, N. and Kakabadse, N. (2012) Spiritual capital: the co-evolution of an ethical framework based on Arabic religious values in the Islamic tradition. Journal of Management Development, Vol. 31, No. 10, pp. 1058–1076. Earth Observation Handbook (2012) How the world has changed in twenty years, http://www.eohandbook.com/eohb2012/informing_international_how_the_ world_has_changed.html. Accessed November 2012. Economy Watch (2010) Forbes 2000 company and list of Forbes 2000 companies. http://www.economywatch.com/companies/forbes-list/. Accessed August 2013. Edelman Trust Barometer (2012) Trust barometer global results. http://trust. edelman.com/trust-download/global-results/ Accessed November 2012. Etzkowitz, H. and Leydesdorff, L. (2000) The dynamics of innovation: from national systems and “mode 2” to a triple helix of university–industry–government relations. Research Policy, Vol. 29, No. 2, pp. 109–123. Evans, J. (2010) Pioneering on the frontier: the possibilities and perils of emerging markets. Wall Street Journal, 5 October. 36 Nadeem Khan and Nada K. Kakabadse Fama, E.F. and Jensen, M.C. (1983) Separation of ownership and control. Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 26, No.2, pp. 301–325. Family Firm Institute (2012) Global data points. http://www.ffi.org/?page= GlobalDataPoints, accessed 8 November 2012. Faroohar, R. (2012) Are companies more powerful than countries? The curious capitalist. 27 January. Time Magazine, Business and Money. http://business. time.com/2012/01/27/are-companies-more-powerful-than-countries/ Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) (2012) List of bank failures in United States. http://www.fdic.gov/ and http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/List_of_ bank_failures_in_the_United_States_(2008%E2%80%93present), accessed 8 November 2012. Fleming, O. (2012) Meet the 14th century African King who was richest man in the world of all time (adjusted for inflation). 15 October. http://www.dailymail. co.uk/news/article-2218025/Meet-14th-Century-African-king-richest-manworld-time-adjusted-inflation.html?openGraphAuthor =%2Fhome%2Fsearch. html %3Fs%3D%26authornamef%3DOlivia%2BFleming. Forbes (2012) The world’s biggest companies. http://www.forbes.com/sites/scottdecarlo/2012/04/18/the-worlds-biggest-companies/, accessed 8 November 2012. Fortune Magazine (2012) Annual ranking of American corporations. http://money. cnn.com/magazines/fortune/fortune500/2012/full_list/. Accessed April 2013. Freeman, R.E., Harrison, J.S., Wicks, A.C., Parmer, B.L., and de Colle, S. (2010) Stakeholder Theory: The State of the Art. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Friedman, M. (1962) Capitalism and Freedom. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL. Gardener, H. (1993) Multiple Intelligences: The Theory in Practice. Basic Books, New York. Gerth, K. (2010) Lifestyles of the rich and infamous: The creation and implications of China’s new aristocracy. Comparative Sociology, Vol. 10, No. 4, pp. 488–507. Global 100 List (2012) http://www.global100.org/. Accessed November 2012. Grant Thornton (2012) Governance Insights: The Tone of Governance. Grant Thornton Governance Institute, London. Gregory-Smith, I. and Main, B. (2012) Heads I win, tails you lose? A career analysis of executive pay and corporate performance. University of Edinburgh Business School, http://homepages.ed.ac.uk/mainbg/Files/WP2_Heads_I_ win_Tails_you_lose.pdf. Hall, P.A. and Soskice D. (2001) Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism. Oxford University Press, New York. Halliday, J. (2011) News Corp Boss linked to leak of Vince Cable’s Rupert Murdoch comments. The Guardian. 22 July. http://www.guardian.co.uk/media/2011/ jul/22/willlewis-telegraphmediagroup Harvey, M. (2012) Egypt wrestles with democracy: expectations versus realities. Pepperdine Policy Review, Vol. 5, No. 1, article 2. Heidegger, M. (1927) Sein und Zeit (English translation (1996) Being and Time). Translated by Macquarrie, J. and Robinson, E. (1962) Harper and Row, New York. Heineman, B.W. Jr. (2010) The Google case: when law and ethics collide. The Atlantic. 13 January. http://www.theatlantic.com/politics/archive/2010/01/ the-google-case-when-law-and-ethics-collide/33438/. Exposing the 20th Century Corporation 37 Hermalin, B.E. and Weisbach, M.S. (2003) Boards of directors as an endogenously determined institution: A survey of the economic literature. Economic Policy Review, Vol. 9, No. 1, pp. 7–26. Hofstede, G., Hofstede, G.J. and Minkov, M. (2010) Cultures and Organizations: Software of the Mind, 3rd edition. McGraw-Hill, New York. Hopkins, A.G. (2011) Globalisation in World History. EBook edition of original Random House, Pimlico (2002), London. Hickson, C. and Turner, J. (2005) Corporations or limited liability company, in McCusker, J., Engerman, S., Fischer, L., Hancock, D. and Pomeranz, K. (eds), Encyclopedia of World Trade since 1450. Macmillan, New York. Hurt, E. (2012) The marketization of higher education. College Literature, Vol. 39, No. 2, pp. 121–132. Hwang, B.G., Zhao, X. and Gay, M.J.S. (2012) Public private partnership projects in Singapore: factors, critical risks and preferred risk allocation from the perspective of contractors. International Journal of Project Management. Corrected Proof available online November 2012. http://www.sciencedirect.com/ science?_ob=ArticleListURL&_method=list&_ArticleListID=-80682835&_ sort=r&_st=13&view=c&_acct=C000228598&_version=1&_urlVersion=0&_us erid=10&md5=bc9b774d6e83af45fe05d49da4ae69ed&searchtype=a . IMD (2012) The World Competitiveness Scoreboard: World Competitiveness YearBook. http://www.imd.org/research/publications/wcy/World-CompetitivenessYearbook-Results/#/. Institute of Grocery and Distribution (2010) http://www.igd.com/index. asp?id1&fid=6, accessed 8 November 2012. International Labour Organisation (2012) Global employment trends 2012: World faces 600 million jobs challenge. 24 January. http://www.ilo.org/global/about-the-ilo/newsroom/news/WCMS_171700/lang – en/index.htm. Investopedia (2011) Five of the world’s oldest companies. http://www.investopedia.com/financial-edge/0711/5-of-the-worlds-oldest-companies.aspx, accessed 8 November 2012. Irwin, S. and Winterton, M. (2011) Qualitative secondary analysis in practice: an extended guide (with reference to context and knowledge claims). Timescapes Working Paper 7, www.timescapes.leeds.ac.uk/events-dicemination/publications.php. Accessed August 2013. Jensen, M.C. and Meckling, W.H. (1976) Theory of the firm: managerial behaviour, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 3, No. 4, pp. 305–360. Judge, W. (2010) Corporate governance mechanisms throughout the world. Corporate Governance: An International Review, Vol. 18, No. 3, pp. 159–160. Kakabadse, A. and Kakabadse, N. (eds) (2012) Global Elites: The Opaque Nature of Transnational Policy Determination. Palgrave, London. Kakabadse, A., Kakabadse, N.K. and Barratt, R. (2006) Chairman and chief executive officer (CEO): that sacred and secret relationship. Journal of Management Development, Vol. 25, No. 2, pp. 134–150. Kakabadse, N. and Steane, P. (2010) Meaning and interpretation: insights and discourse. Journal of Management History, Vol. 16, No. 3, pp. 346–366. Kakabadse, N., Kakabadse, A. and Kouzmin, A. (2007) Designing balance into the democratic project: Contrasting Jeffersonian democracy against 38 Nadeem Khan and Nada K. Kakabadse Bentham’s panopticon centralisation in determining ICT adoption. Problems and Perspectives in Management, Vol. 5, No. 1, pp. 2–28. Kakabadse, N., Kakabadse, A., Kalu K. and Kouzmin, A. (2010) Calling on Jefferson: the ‘custodiary’ as the forth estate in the democratic project. Contemporary Politics, Vol. 15, No. 3, pp. 279–299. Kapoor, R. and Lee, J.M. (2012) Coordinating and competing in ecosystems: how organizational forms shape new technology investments. Strategic Management Journal, doi: 10.1002/smj.2010. Karn, G.L. (2011) Stewardship: a new vision for the purpose of business. Corporate Governance, Vol. 11, No. 4, pp. 337–347. Katasonov, V. (2012) Quantitative easing as outrageous corruption. Strategic Culture Foundation. 20 October. http://www.strategic-culture.org/news/2012/ 09/25/quantitative-easing-as-outrageous-corruption.html. Khan, N., Dsouli, O. and Kakabadse, N. (2012) Mitigating the Davos dilemma: towards a co-evolutionary framework for global sustainable development. Presented at EABIS Sustainability Conference, IMD, July. Kim, S.Y. (2012) Sorry, Apple: Samsung is winning the war on 4G platforms. Australian Broadcasting Corporation: Technology and Games. 4 September. http://www.abc.net.au/technology/articles/2012/09/04/3582283.htm. Knyght, R., Kakabadse, N., Kouzmin, A. and Kakabadse, A. (2011) Chronic failure in globalised, oligopolistic markets: an urgent case for socialised capital. Society and Business Review, Vol. 6, No. 1, pp. 7–26. Krugman, P. (2011) Can Europe be saved? New York Times Magazine, 12 January, p. 1. Kuchler, H. (2012) Academics oppose UK university reforms. Financial Times, 14 November. Le Billion, P. (2001) The political ecology of war: natural resources and armed conflicts. Political Geography, Vol. 20, No. 5, pp. 561–584. Lee, M. (2012) Too big to succeed? Three China scenarios to 2050. Prometheus, Institute of Futurology, http://www.futurology.co.za/code/docs/2050China. pdf. Lemke, P. (2012) Arctic processes and the global climate in Wasum Rainer, S. Winkelman, I. and Tirich, K. (2012) Arctic Science, International Law and Climate Change, Vol. 235, pp. 45–53. Lendmenl, S. (2012) Greece: profile of a failed state. 9 November. http://www. indybay.org/newsitems/2012/11/09/18725345.php, accessed 10 November 2012. Leveson Inquiry (2011) What we’ve learned so far. The Guardian, 30 November. Lewin, A.Y. and Volberda, H.W. (2003) Co-evolution dynamics within and between firms: from evolution to co-evolution. Journal of Management Studies, Vol. 40, No. 8, pp. 2111–2136. Leys, C. (2003) Market-driven Politics: Neo-liberal Democracy and the Public Interest. Verso Press, London. Luhby, T. (2012) Living on less than $2 a day. CNN Money. 7 March. available at http://economy.money.cnn.com/2012/03/07/living-on-less-than-2-a-day/. MacAskill, E. (2012) Global summit aim to reverse years of family planning neglect. The Guardian. 10 June. http://www.guardian.co.uk/globaldevelopment/2012/jun/10/global-summit-family-planning Exposing the 20th Century Corporation 39 MacIntyre, A. (1981) After Virtue. Bloomsbury Academic and Notre Dame University Press, Indiana. Malloch, T. (2008) Spiritual Enterprises: Doing Virtuous Business. Encounter Books, New York. Marr, A. (2012) History of the world. http://www.bbc.co.uk/iplayer/episode/ p00xnvvn/Andrew_Marrs_History_of_the_World_Age_of_Industry/, accessed 8 November. Matten, D. and Moon, J. (2008) Implicit and explicit CSR: a conceptual framework for a comparative understanding of corporate social responsibility. Academy of Management Review, Vol. 33, No. 2, pp. 404–424. McKelvey, W. (1997) Quasi-natural organisational science. Organisational Science, Vol. 8, No. 4, pp. 352–380. Mills, C.W. (1956) The Power Elite. Oxford University Press, New York. Mintzberg, H. Ahlstrand, B. and Lampel, J. (2009) Strategy Safari: Your Complete Guide Through the Wilds of Strategic Management, 2nd edition. Pearson Education Limited, Harlow. Moravcsik, A. and Sangiovanni, A. (2003) On democracy and the ‘public interest’: in the European Union. CES Working Paper, No. 93. http://www.researchgate. net/publication/29998717_On_Democracy_and_the_Public_Interest_in_the_ European_Union._CES_Working_Paper_no._93_2003 Morck, R. (2012) The social value of shareholder value. Presented at the 20th Anniversary of CGIR Conference, University of Cambridge, 28 September. Moritz, S. and Aaron, D.B. (2012) Nokia US future at risk as AT&T sales, seen below Millio. 5 April. http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2012–04–05/nokiau-s-future-at-risk-as-at-t-debut-sales-seen-below-million.html O’Hara, W.T. and Mandel, P. (2004) The World’s Oldest Family Companies: Convincing Evidence that Smaller Firms Usually Outlast Larger Ones. Bryant College’s Institute for Family Enterprise, Smithfield. Obama, B.H. (2010a) President Obama proposes Volker Rule to reign in Big Banks. 21 January. http://www.dailykos.com/tv/w/002488/. Accessed August 2013. Obama, B.H. (2010b) Frank Dodd Act signed into U.S. law. 21 July. http:// www.natlawreview.com/article/president-obama-signs-dodd-frank-act-law. Accessed August 2013. Obama, B.H. (2009) Remarks by the president on 21st century financial regulatory reform. 17 June. The White House. http://www.whitehouse.gov/the_ press_office/Remarks-of-the-President-on-Regulatory-Reform/ Palazzo, G. and Scherer, A.G. (2008) The future of global corporate citizenship: Towards a new theory of the firm as a political actor, in Scherer, A.G. and Palazzo, G. (eds) Handbook of Research on Global Corporate Citizenship. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, pp. 577–590. Pasquali, V. and Aridas, T. (2012) The world’s richest and poorest countries. Global Finance. http://www.gfmag.com/tools/global-database/economicdata/11934-richest-poorest-countries.html#axzz2FbQ727gC Peltz, J. (1995) Lockheed agrees to pay record fine: Aerospace Calabasas firm pleads guilty in connection with bribing an Egyptian politician. Los Angeles Times. 28 January. http://articles.latimes.com/1995–01–28/business/fi-25231_1_egyptianpolitician. 40 Nadeem Khan and Nada K. Kakabadse Peters, J. (ed.) (2012) The European Union and the Arab Spring: Promoting Democracy and Human Rights in the Middle East. Lexington Books, Plymouth. Pierce, D.A. (2011) Succeed or fail: the implications for the government of Afghanistan following US phased troop withdrawl. Master’s dissertation, http://www.lampmethod.org/eCommons/Pierce2011.pdf. Accessed November 2012. Pitelis, C.N. and Teece, D.J. (2009) The (new) nature and essence of the firm. European Management Review, Vol. 6, No.1 pp. 5–15. Porter, M.E. (2009) Why Do Good Companies Set Bad Strategies? Wharton’s SEI Centre Distinguished Lectures Series. Wharton Business School: Emerald Group Publishing. Prasad, A. and Prasad, P. (2006) Global transitions: the emerging new world order and its implications for business and management. Business Renaissance Quarterly, Vol. 1, No. 3, pp. 91–114. Prieg, L. (2011) The banks are not only too big to fail, they’re too big for the economy. The Guardian. 12 September. http://www.guardian.co.uk/ commentisfree/2011/sep/12/banks-too-big-fail-economy Privacy International (2007) World’s top surveillance societies : National Privacy Rankings. https://www.privacyinternational.org/sites/privacyinternational. org/files/file-downloads/phrcomp_sort_0.pdf Quiyum, M.J. and Salimullah, A.H.M. (2005) Confucius (551–479 B.C.) and his philosophy on education, society and politics. Pakistan Journal of Social Sciences, Vol. 3, No. 6, pp. 880–888. Rehman, Z. (2011) Top ten countries with the lowest literacy rates. 24 December, http://www.amodmag.com/top-ten-countries-with-the-lowest-literacy-rates. php. Rojek, C. (2012) Fame Attack: The Inflation of Celebrity and its Consequences. Bloomsbury Academic, London. Ryan, C. (2012) The new Arab cold war and the struggle for Syria. Middle East Report, MER 262, pp. 28–31. http://www.merip.org/mer/mer262/new-arabcold-war-struggle-syria?utm_source=twitterfeed&utm_medium=twitter. Ryvkin, B. (2012) Saving the Euro: tensions with European treaty law in the European Union’s efforts to protect the common currency. Cornell International Law Journal, Vol. 45, pp. 227–254. Sawyer, S. and Gomez, E.T. (2012) The Politics of Resource Extraction: Indigenous Peoples, Multinational Corporations and the State. United Nations Research Institute for Social Development (UNRISD), Palgrave Macmillan, London. Scaruffi, P. (2009) Wars and casualties of the twentieth and twenty first centuries, http://www.scaruffi.com/politics/massacre.html, accessed 8 November 2012. Schaeffer, M., Hare, W., Rahmstorf, S. and Vermeer, M. (2012) Long-term sealevel rise implied by 1.5°C and 2°C warming levels. Nature Climate Change, http://ssi.ucsd.edu/scc/images/Schaeffer%20SLR%20at%20+1.5%20+2%20 NatCC%2012.pdf. Scheffran, J. and Battaglini, A. (2011) Climate and conflicts: The security risks of global warming. Regional Environmental Change, Vol. 11, No. 1, pp. 27–39. Scherrer, P.S. (2003) Directors’ responsibilities and participation in the strategic decision making process. Corporate Governance, Vol. 3, No. 1, pp. 86–90. Exposing the 20th Century Corporation 41 Schnieder Electric (2012) ‘Schnieder Electric – a responsible corporate citizen’, Sustainable Development, http://www.schneider-electric.com/documents/ sustainable-development/sustainability-investors-analysts/schneider-electricaccess-to-energy.pdf, Accessed 21 November 2012. Schularick, M. and Taylor, A.M. (2009) Credit booms gone bust: monetary policy, leverage cycles and financial crisis, 1870–2008. NBER Working Paper No. 15512. NBER, Cambridge, MA. Schumpeter, J. (1934) The Theory of Economic Development. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA. Seattle Times (2012) Apple sets record for company value at $624bn. 20 August. http://seattletimes.com/html/localnews/2018957719_apustecapplebiggestcompany4thld writethru.html. Selim, G.M. (2012) The impact of post-Saddam Iraq on the cause of democratization in the Arab world. International Journal of Contemporary Iraqi Studies, Vol. 6, No. 1, pp. 53–87. Shaoul, J., Stafford, A. and Stapleton, P. (2012) Accountability and corporate governance of public private partnerships. Critical Perspectives on Accounting, Vol. 23, No. 3, pp. 213–229. Singh, P.P., Roy, S.K. and Dey, D. (2011) World’s largest arm’s exporters: Interactive map. http://www.businessnbeyond.com/, accessed 8 November 2012. Skidelsky, R. (2011) The Keynes Hayek re-match. 19 August. http://www.relooney. info/0_New_11249.pdf. Smith, A. (1759) The Theory of Moral Sentiments. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Smith, A. (1776) The Wealth of Nations. Millar, London. Smith, H. (2012) German hypocrisy over Greek military spending has critics up in arms. The Guardian. 19 April. http://www.guardian.co.uk/world/2012/ apr/19/greece-military-spending-debt-crisis, accessed 8 November 2012. Stainburn, S. (2012) PetroChina surpasses Exxon Mobil as the world’s largest publicly-traded oil producer. Global Post. 29 March. http://www.globalpost. com/dispatch/news/regions/asia-pacific/china/120329/petrochina-surpassesexxon-mobil-largest-oil-producer, accessed 8 November 2012. Stiglitz, J.E. (2010) Freefall: Free Markets, America and the Sinking of the World Economy. WW Norton, New York. Stiglitz, J.E. and Bilmes, L. (2007) The Three Trillion Dollar War. The True Cost of the Iraq Conflict. Allen Lane Penguin, Melbourne. Suncor (2012) Annual report. http://www.suncor.com. The Economist (2004) The world’s oldest companies. The business of survival – what is the secret to corporate longevity? 16 December. http://www.economist. com/node/ 3490684, accessed 8 November 2012. The Economist (2011) The company that ruled the waves. 17 December. http:// www.economist.com/node/21541753. The Economist (2012) Global debt clock. http://www.economist.com/content/ global_debt_clock, accessed 8 November 2012. The Guardian (2012) University guide 2013: university league tables. 21 May. http://www.guardian.co.uk/education/table/2012/may/21/university-leaguetable-2013. Watt, H. and Newall, C. (2012) MPs expenses scandal: Denis MacShane resigns. The Telegraph. 2 November. http://www.telegraph.co.uk/news/newstopics/ 42 Nadeem Khan and Nada K. Kakabadse mps-expenses/9651978/MPs-expenses-scandal-Denis-MacShane-resigns. html. Thirwell, M.P. (2010) Our Post GFC World Economy. Lowy Institute for International Policy, Sydney. Thompson, C. (2006) Google’s China problem (and China’s Google problem). New York Times. 23 April. http://www.nytimes.com/2006/04/23/magazine/23 google.html. Thompson, R. and Gerrard, G. (2011) 4.2 million cameras? That’s what we’ve been told but research paints a different picture. CCTV Image Winter 2011. http://www.securitynewsdesk.com/wp-content/uploads/2011/03/CCTVImage-42-How-many-cameras-are-there-in-the-UK.pdf Tokyo Shoko Research (2009) Special project: survey of companies nationwide more than 100 years’ longevity companies nationwide, Inc. 20 000 1000. http://www.tsr-net.co.jp/news/analysis /2009 /1199565_1623.html. Trott, F. (2012) Petrol produced from air and water. BBC News. 19 October. http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/business-20003704. Tsaliki, L., Frangonikolopoulos, C.A. and Huliaras, A. (eds) (2011) Transnational Celebrity Activism in Global Politics: Changing the World? Intellect Limited, Chicago. United Nations (2012) Earth Summit 2012 Rio 20: Setting the Green Agenda. Brazil, 13–22 June. United Nations (2004) World Population to 2300. Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Population Division, New York. http://www.un.org/esa/population/publications/longrange2/WorldPop2300final.pdf United Nations Millennium Declaration (2000) Resolution 55/2 adopted by the General Assembly. http://www.un.org/millennium/declaration/ares552e.htm Useem, M. (1980) Corporations and the corporate elite. Annual Review of Sociology, No. 6, pp. 41–77. Useem, M. (1984) The Inner Circle. Oxford University Press, Oxford. Useem, M. (2003) Corporate governance is directors making decisions: reforming the outward foundations for inside decision making. Journal of Management and Governance, Vol. 7, No. 3, pp. 241–253. Van Genugten, S. (2011) Libya after Gadhafi. Survival, Vol. 53, No. 3, pp. 61–74. Ventura, L. and Aridas, T. (2012) Public debt as a percentage of GDP 2006– 2013. Global Finance. http://www.gfmag.com/tools/global-database/economic-data/10394-public-debt-by-country.html#axzz2BehbFo8l, accessed 8 November 2012. Vickers, J. (2011) Independent commission on banking report, September 2011. http://bankingcommission.s3.amazonaws.com/wp-content/uploads/2010/ 07/ICB-Final-Report.pdf, accessed 8 November 2012. Vitali, S., Glattfelder, J.B. and Battison, S. (2011) The network of global corporate control. Swiss Federal Technology Institute, http://arxiv.org/PS_cache/arxiv/ pdf/1107/1107.5728v2.pdf, accessed 8 November 2012. Watt, N., Goodley, S. and Treanor, J. (2011) ‘Nick Clegg warns state-owned banks off “irresponsible” bonus payouts’, The Guardian, 19 December, http://www. theguardian.com/business/2011/dec/19/nick-clegg-warns-banks-off-bonus Accessed 20 October 2012. Exposing the 20th Century Corporation 43 Watt, N. and Treanor, J. (2011) Revealed: 50% of Tory funds come from City. The Guardian. 8 February. http://www.guardian.co.uk/politics/2011/feb/08/toryfunds-half-city-banks-financial-sector Welch, D. (2012) Ethical buyers guide to supermarkets. Ethical Consumer Report, http://www.ethicalconsumer.org/buyersguides/food/supermarkets.aspx. Wernfelt, B. (1984) A resource based view of the firm. Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 5, pp. 246–250. Williamson, O.E. (1975) Markets and Hierarchies. Analysis and Anti-Trust Implications. Free Press, New York. Wolfensohn, J.D. (2010) Big shift coming. Stanford School of Business. http:// www.youtube.com/watch?v= 6a 0zh cly_Ns. World Economic Forum (2012) Global Risks: An Initiative of the Risk Response Network, 7th edition. World Economic Outlook (2012) Coping with high debt and sluggish growth. International Monetary Fund. http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/ 2012/02/pdf/text.pdf WorldOmeter (2012) Current population count. http://www.worldometers.info/ world-population/ Xu, X. (2011) Neoliberalism and governance in China. St Anthony’s College Oxford. http://www.sant.ox.ac.uk/esc/docs/XibaiXuNeoliberalismandGovernance inChina.pdf Yoshikawa, T. (2012) Complementarities in institutions, director capital and director behaviours: a contingency model of outside directors efficacy. Presented at the 20th Anniversary of CGIR Conference, University of Cambridge, July. Zattoni, A. and Judge, W. (eds) (2012) Corporate Governance and Initial Public Offerings: An International Perspective. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Zheng, D. (2012) On modern Chinese nationalism and its conceptualization. Journal of Modern Chinese History, doi:10.1080/17535654.2012.708233. 2 Corporate Income Inequality and Corporate Performance: Any Correlations? Filipe Morais, Andrew Kakabadse, Nada K. Kakabadse and Adrian Pryce Introduction Income inequality has been an important concern for scholars and practitioners alike. Concerns about income inequality contributed to both the Magna Carta of 1215 and the Bill of Rights in 1689. Despite steady progress over the centuries towards the equality ideal, which has continued to be elusive, income inequality has increased significantly in the past 30 years. Shareholder dominance through the encroachment of Anglo-American style globalisation and its corresponding model of corporate governance has led to a meteoric rise of executive compensation as well as the 2008 global financial meltdown, resulting in economic depression affecting billions of ordinary citizens around the globe (Kakabadse et al., 2004; Clarke, 2009; Pryce et al., 2011; Tse, 2011). At the centre of the global financial crisis (GFC) spawned by the prevalence of the Anglo-Saxon shareholder model is the explosion of executive compensation, which in addition to generating debate in both academic and political circles has triggered public anger as exemplified by the Occupy Wall Street (OWS) rallies during the last quarter of 2011 and the associated citizens’ ‘actions’ in over 600 cities across the Americas, Africa, Europe, Asia and Australia (Rushe, 2011). Over the past three decades or so, executive pay has been rising, particularly in the United States, but also in Europe and elsewhere. Several studies and authors show that in the United States the rewards of enterprise have been to capital as well as to labour, but in the case of employees, income gains have been skewed to the very top levels of organisations (IPS and UFE, 2006; Jacoby, 2007). A critical examination of the theories underpinning executive pay arrangements (Festinger, 1957 Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Lazear and Rosen, 1981; and Westphal, 44 Corporate Income Inequality and Corporate Performance 45 1994; Bebchuk and Fried, 2006; Clarke, 2009; Fulmer, 2009) shows the inability to explain current trends and practice. This chapter starts by reviewing current trends on executive compensation and by critically discussing the main theories underpinning executive pay. It also discusses the relationship between executive compensation and corporate performance along with the contribution of mainstream academics and the regulatory response to the GFC. It follows a discussion of inequality trends from both a macro and microeconomic perspective and suggests how a corporate Gini index (CGI) can be a useful measure to understand how corporate income inequality affects company performance and macroeconomic inequality. The chapter then presents a description of the study methodology along with presentation and analysis of the findings. The chapter ends with conclusions and indicates future avenues of research. The explosion of executive pay Executive pay has been rising rapidly across the globe in past decades, with more velocity in the United States, but increasingly in the UK and Europe (Pryce et al., 2011). In 2007, the EPI reported that US CEOs earned more in one working day than the average worker earned in a year (Mishel et al., 2007). Executive pay in the United States took off in the 1990s and between 1990 and 2005 increased 298% on average, whereas corporate profits went up for the same period at less than half (+141%). Over the same period, the average production worker’s pay had a real increase of 4.3% and the Federal minimum wage saw a real decrease of 9.3% (IPS and UFE, 2006). According to a more recent IPS study ‘after adjusting for inflation, CEO pay in 2009 more than doubled the CEO pay average for the decade of the 1990s, more than quadrupled the CEO pay average for the 1980s, and ran approximately eight times the CEO average for all the decades of the mid-20th century’ (IPS, 2010, p. 3). IDS (2010) reports that the UK pay gap between shop floor and executive directors almost doubled in the past decade, whilst the average total compensation of FTSE100 chiefs soared from 69 to 145 times the average worker earnings (High Pay Commission, 2011). Another study shows that executive pay varies between 71 and 183 the income of the average worker and between 103 and 523 times if share-based payments are included (ILO, 2008). 46 Filipe Morais, Andrew Kakabadse, Nada K. Kakabadse and Adrian Pryce 200 150 100 148 135 10,3 104 2,7 71 3,6 Germany Hong kong Netherlands 6 4 1,4 Australia 10 8 6,8 6 50 0 12 183 160 South Africa United States 2 0 CEO pay/Average employee pay Average executive/Average employee pay CEO pay (1) Average executive pay (1) Figure 2.1 Executive pay, 2007 as per the ILLS estimates based on the annual reports of 15 of the largest corporations in the respective countries Source: Adapted from ILLS (2008). Figures in millions of US dollars. The growth in executive compensation is not uniformly distributed globally and further this phenomenon is viewed differently in the varying parts of the world. In July 2010, The Washington Post emphasised the case of Japan, reporting that despite Japanese Securities Exchange authorities on the 30 June 2010 ‘requiring Japanese companies to disclose pay for executives making more $1.1 million … the (Japanese) government said that “fewer than 300 people at Japan’s 3,813 plc’s earned enough in 2009 to require disclosure”’ (Klein, 2010). It concluded that ‘(…) CEOs aren’t just paid what the market will bear; they’re paid what the culture will accept’ (Klein, 2010). Think Progress (2009) questions CEO pay levels in 2008 and inquires why Carl-Henric Svanberg, the CEO of the Swedish firm Ericsson (289th position on Fortune 500) took home in 2008 a total of just over US$2.5 million and Leif Johansson CEO of Volvo (the largest Swedish firm) just US$1.9 million, whilst the CEO of US company Aetna ranked (300th position on Fortune 500) took home US$38.12 million. It is evident that US CEOs are remunerated considerably more when compared to Swedish and Japanese executives managing similar or even larger firms (Klein, 2010; Think Progress, 2009). The question that remains unanswered is whether US CEOs are overrated. Most members of the society perceive executive compensation as excessive. Certainly in the absence of any rationale for the levels whether they are economic or any other kind, this leaves executive pay vulnerable to accusations of being flawed, profoundly unfair and contributing directly to the widening income inequality within corporations and, in turn, within Corporate Income Inequality and Corporate Performance 47 societies, with all the associated negative consequences for health and social well-being. Theories of pay: any reasonable explanation? According to Kakabadse et al. (2004, p. 561) ‘the question as to where fair pay ends and over-compensation begins – and what that means for the community – is rarely raised’. For others, little has been done in ‘explaining the remuneration’s magnitude, structure and sensitivity to the long-term impact on stakeholders and the wider community’ (Bowen, 1953, cited in Kakabadse et al., 2004, p. 561) and theoretical frameworks do not provide much of an explanation for these current trends. In this chapter we explore contrasting models of governance, all of which capture distinct but contrasting notions of executive remuneration. These are agency theory, the power perspective approach, tournament theory, economics-based theories and socio-comparative theories (Table 2.1). The agency theory Agency theory is based on the assumption that executive actions are more effective if they are aligned with shareholders’ interests. It is under this rationale that companies justify remuneration packages as the mechanism to forge that alignment (Berle and Means, 1932; Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Kakabadse et al., 2004, Fulmer, 2009). Interestingly, agency costs have been increasing rapidly over the past three decades or so, whilst shareholder value has been following the opposite trend (Martin, 2010). Given the average share ownership of US CEOs and their immediate relatives, Clarke (2010, p. 16) goes as far as to consider that ‘separation between ownership and control is now in reverse’. These are only some of the growing body of voices that claim that executive elite has been able to claim an ever increasing share of wealth of the enterprise and have been awarded inordinate power at the expense of shareholders and the workforce. In this sense, scholars also have criticised agency theory for being too narrow and outdated and that it does not account for changing contextual and/or environmental forces (Teubner, 1996; Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2003; Aguilera et al., 2008; Christopher, 2010; Rowe and Liu, 2010). The power perspective approach Clarke (2009) argues that ‘out of control CEO power and reward concentrated in Anglo-American firms is correlated closely with the recent 48 Filipe Morais, Andrew Kakabadse, Nada K. Kakabadse and Adrian Pryce Table 2.1 Dominant theories on executive pay Author(s) Theory Assumption Explanation Berle and Means (1932); Jensen and Meckling (1976) Agency Theory Executive actions are more effective if aligned with shareholder interests through generous compensation packages (especially equity-based). Explains CEO size and structure by the need to align executive and shareholder interests, defending that stockbased payments are the most effective in forging such alignment. Lazear and Rosen (1981); Rosen (1986); Huang and Sharma (2010) Tournament Sufficiently large Theory pay gaps between consecutive executive ranks create competition amongst managers for higher financial rewards, which leads to better corporate performance. The market defines the ‘price’ of a CEO. Explains size of pay by the fact that the CEO is the ultimate position to strive for, thus pay needs to be substantially greater so as to encourage managers below to compete for this role. Bebchuk and Fried (2006); Clarke (2010); Wiseman and Severance (2007) SocioPolitical Perspective (Power) CEO power over boards induces limitations of an economic, social and psychological nature on other board directors. Executive compensation size and structure is explained by the inordinate power awarded to the CEO over the board, resulting in “structural defects” that allow CEOs to define their own remuneration packages with little opposition. Khurana (2002); Kroll (2005); Bebchuk and Fried (2006) Economics Based Executive compensation is a supply and demand phenomenon, where the CEO should receive compensation according to his/her marginal revenue product. Executive compensation is determined by the limited talent pool of CEO’s, informed sellers and difficulties in calculating the CEO’s marginal revenue product. Continued Corporate Income Inequality and Corporate Performance Table 2.1 49 Continued Author(s) Theory Assumption Festinger (1957); Hosseini and Brenner (1992) SocioExternal peer comparative comparison (of director’s performance) in a variety of industries determines executive compensation size and structure. Explanation The prevalence of external peer comparison explains executive compensation. Source: Compiled by the authors. financial crisis’ and states that the increasing share of wealth going to CEOs ‘impacts upon relationships with other employees, shareholders and wider community’ (Clarke, 2010, p. 2). The point that Clarke challenges is the convergence theory of Anglo-American corporate governance. He contends that this Anglo-Saxon model produces far higher levels of inequality, and yet is this same model of governance that is gaining ground across the globe promoted by executives, institutional investors and international bodies such the OECD and the IMF (Clarke, 2009). Bebchuk and Fried (2006) highlight that executive compensation ‘has strayed far from the arm’s length model’ in publicly traded companies (Bebchuk and Fried, 2006, p. 5). They argue that the dominance of CEOs over boards, due to a number of ‘underlying governance structural defects’, has allowed distorted pay arrangements to continue and there have been ‘perverse consequences to investors by reducing firms’ long-term value, ultimately to the whole of the economy’ (Bebchuk and Fried, 2006, p. 6). In fact, numerous authors recognise that there are psychological and social factors that impede efficiency in executive pay setting processes (Bebchuk and Fried, 2006; Wiseman and Severance, 2007; Clarke, 2009). The tournament theory The central assumption of tournament theory concerns its internal focus in that managers will exert extra effort if the firm allows them to compete for higher financial rewards than that they obtain through promotion (Lazear and Rosen, 1981; Rosen, 1986). The presumption is 50 Filipe Morais, Andrew Kakabadse, Nada K. Kakabadse and Adrian Pryce that pay gap differences in the corporate hierarchy improves corporate performance (Huang and Sharma, 2010). Hayward and Hambrick (1997) pointed to the large pay gaps that exist between the CEO and the next highest executive ranks, averaging 30–50%, and sometimes reaching 100% of a difference. In support, Huang and Sharma (2011) have argued that pay spreads between executive ranks have a negative impact on firm performance, concluding that ‘the greater the pay spreads the more likely firm value is damaged’ (Huang and Sharma, 2001, p. 7). Further, Professor Bloom from the University of Notre Dame concluded that from 29 US baseball teams, those with the narrowest pay spreads yielded the best results in terms of overall team performance (Bloom, 1999). In contrast to Bloom’s (1999) work, most studies have concentrated on examining pay differentials between executive ranks and between these and shareholders (Bender and Moir, 2005), whilst simultaneously paying little attention to the consequences of inequality. The economics-based theories Alternatively, economic theory explains executive pay levels in terms of supply and demand. The marginal revenue product theory assumes that well-functioning labour markets have informed buyers and sellers, whose negotiations lead to rationally determined competitive prices prevailing in the market (Kroll, 2005). On this basis, the company should pay the CEO his/her marginal revenue product. However, a CEO’s marginal product is hard to calculate as many factors affecting the company’s performance are outside the CEO’s control. Thus, identifying what is and what is not a consequence of CEO actions remains the challenge with economics-based theories of remuneration (Khurana, 2002; Wiseman and Severance, 2007). Within this line of thought, Lloyd (2009) rejects the cult of the CEO superman, arguing that there is no link between shareholder value and executive pay. He goes as far as to question whether corporations really need the traditional figure of CEO. He argues that the CEO market is imperfect and that ‘the market rate for a CEO is very far from clear’ (Lloyd, 2009, 2012). The socio-comparative theories Socio-comparative theory holds that the dynamics of external peer comparison mainly influence executive pay (Festinger, 1957; Hosseini and Brenner, 1992). Hence, comparison of directors’ performance across a variety of industries determines executive compensation size Corporate Income Inequality and Corporate Performance 51 and structure. Building on these theories, Bizjaka et al. (2011, p. 538) found that peer groups are constructed ‘in a manner that biases compensation upwards, particularly in firms outside the Standard and Poor’s (SandP) 500’. Executive pay and corporate performance: any correlation? The relationship between executive pay and corporate performance gained considerable academic and media attention after the GFC. A growing number of investigations concur that there is little relation between corporate performance and executive compensation (BIS, 2011; EU Commission, 2011), and that board evaluation practices are far from desirable (Heidrick and Struggles, 2011). Recent regulations on governance practices both for private and public sectors highlight the need to increase the transparency between executive pay and company performance (CMVM, 2010a, b; Coffee, 2010; FCR, 2010; AFG, 2011; EU Commission, 2011; Hutton, 2011; SEV, 2011). This is because several commentators highlight that a number of factors impact on company performance that are not the result of CEO action (Khurana, 2002; Wiseman and Severance, 2007). Khurana (2002) emphasises that we can attribute 10–20% of firm performance to economic climate, 30–45% to industry performance and 35–60% to management, of which the CEO is just one player. Wiseman and Severance (2007) question the value of the uncontrolled used of share-based payments. They argue that four main causes for the rise in the prices of stocks exist: ● ● ● ● a general increase in demand for all products in the prosperity phase of the business cycle; a rise in world demand for a particular industry’s products causing a concomitant increase in the market price of the stock of all companies in that industry; private-equity firm’s purchase or offer to buy all of a company’s stock which can cause a 15% or more share price increase overnight; and the buyback of shares by the company. None of these options are related to CEO performance. A study conducted by Supanvanij (2008) for the period 1994–2005 across 191 firms revealed that EVA (economic value added), a short-run performance measure, was related to some forms of CEO compensation 52 Filipe Morais, Andrew Kakabadse, Nada K. Kakabadse and Adrian Pryce increase for both the short-term and long-term. However, MVA (market value added), a long-run performance measure, showed no significant relation to long-term compensation. Further, McGuire et al. (2003) showed that a negative correlation exists between executive incentives and social performance, particularly that salary and long-term incentives induce weak social performance. Mainstream perspective Academics have long addressed the contentious issue of governance and executive pay, but the most influential papers seem to have remained within the principal–agent framework which has demonstrated an inability to recognise changing contextual, and particularly, social and environmental forces. Writing in 1990, well before the 2008 GFC, Jensen and Murphy (1990) published a large longitudinal study in Harvard Business Review, favourably concluding for increase in the size of CEO rewards and a revision of the structure of compensation packages. Displaying a dogmatic belief in the shareholder value mantra and of principal–agent theory, Jensen and Murphy (1990) suggested an increase in stock options as a mean to reward talent and increase shareholder value. They believed that more aggressive pay for performance systems and meaningful penalties for poor performance would mean that in time more able and motivated individuals who would perform better would replace less able CEOs, successfully engage in high-risk–high-gain activities and thus increase corporate value. Not only Jensen and Murphy (1990) championed such options. Scandals concerning companies such as Apple, Mercury, Interactive Corp and others over employee stock options (ESOs) had companies taking actions such as firing top executives, taking charges against earnings amounting to billions of dollars, paying fines and civil damages and sending written confessions to outside shareholders admitting that they has misrepresented exactly how and when ‘grant dates’ were fixed by the board in its annual proxy statement. (Wiseman and Severance, 2007, p. 13). The 2008 GFC showed the extent to which stock-based payments provided incentives for short-term action at the expense of long-term sustainability and value, as well as at the expense of shareholders, employees and the wider society (Wiseman and Severance, 2007; Clarke, 2010; Pryce et al., 2011). Bebchuk and Fried (2006) argued that there was an evident decoupling between pay and performance, especially in the form of equity Corporate Income Inequality and Corporate Performance 53 but also non-equity pay such as bonuses, further aggravated by poor board monitoring of the drivers of executive performance. They do not view the use of subjective criteria, ‘golden parachutes’, more than normal severance payments (which provide incentives to bear the risk of failure), pension arrangements and post-retirement consulting Table 2.2 Key academic contributions Authors Contribution Issues Jensen and Murphy (1990) Introduces the idea of meaningful penalties for poor performing CEOs for strengthening the pay-for-performance. Does not depart from the narrow agency theory or consider other stakeholders into the equation. Openly defended the rise on stock-based pay and the engagement of executives on high-risk–high-gain activities with a view of increasing shareholder value. Bebchuk and Fried (2006) Introduces several measures to weaken CEO power in appointing NEDs, setting their pay package and suggests the revision and/or elimination of several pay components not related to performance as condition for a better application of the arms length contracting model. Remains fixed within the agency theory and the idea of maximising shareholder value. It does recognises that CEO power over board is the main driver of inordinate CEO compensation, but by remaining fixed within principal–agency does not provide a geopolitical perspective to balance-out CEO power with other stakeholders. Wiseman and Severance These authors show that (2007); Clarke (2010) the Anglo-American model of governance produce more inequality primarily driven by CEO power over board. Do not depart from the idea of shareholder value maximisation nor from the principal–agent framework. Source: Compiled by the authors. 54 Filipe Morais, Andrew Kakabadse, Nada K. Kakabadse and Adrian Pryce contracts and perks, as not related to performance (Bebchuk and Fried, 2006). The authors also recommended improvements in transparency requiring all firms to disclose in a comprehensive way pay amounts and structure (Bebchuk and Fried, 2006). They further recommended reducing the incentives for expansion via acquisitions, a dividendneutral approach to executive pay and a rethink of pension plans (Bebchuk and Fried, 2006). In effect, an increasing number of commentators highlight that the whole structure of executive pay is not related to performance which, in conjunction with poor corporate performance measurement systems and relaxed board oversight, lead to executives engaging in short-term strategies, some broaching the unethical and criminal, in pursuit of selfinterest. The possible solutions still remain concentrated on principal– agent theory fundamentals and ignore geopolitical perspectives applied to governance and pay concerning adopting sustainable, long-term measures. Regulatory action The UK corporate governance code (FCR, 2010) issued in June 2010 has set the standard for adjustments on corporate governance codes around the globe. New regulations suggest a better link between pay and performance by recommending or enforcing board evaluations by independent parties every 1 and 3 years; enhancing the independence of remuneration committees; the introduction of the shareholder ‘more-or-less binding vote’ on remuneration policy and the transparency of that vote; and, remuneration policies with appropriate incentives to foster long-term growth (CMVM, 2010a, b; Coffee, 2010; FCR, 2010; AFG, 2011; BIS, 2011; EU Commission, 2011; Hutton, 2011; SEV, 2011). The code also suggests or enforces the increase of transparency via disclosure of multiples of CEO pay to median employee earnings (Coffee, 2010; Hutton, 2011). There is, however, little discussion on how employees will benefit from a fairer governance of corporations, through a more equitable, fairer distribution of the rewards of the enterprise. The code briefly mentions the importance of ‘employee share ownership’ or ‘gain-sharing’, but with little attention on how a firm is to implement it (EU, 2011; Hutton, 2011). The question we must raise is how can governance protocol and ruling continue to remain within the existing narrow principal–agent framework (Teubner, 1996; Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2003; Aguilera Corporate Income Inequality and Corporate Performance 55 et al., 2008) without changing the actual root of the problem – the framework itself ? Measuring corporate income inequality: the corporate Gini index Multiples of CEO pay to median pay has been the officially proposed measure to monitor executive pay and pay differentials (Dodd-Frank Act, 2010; AFG, 2011; Hutton, 2011). However, some consider this insufficient and propose that an additional, more comprehensive and holistic measure is required to take account of income differential impacts on wider society (Pryce et al., 2011). Outside of the boundaries of the corporation, the Gini index is the most popular measure of income inequality (De Maio, 2007; Pryce et al., 2011) and has been the measure which the International Labour Organisation (ILO) has used in the most recent study on income inequality (2008). The Gini index is derived from the Lorenz curve of cumulative income distribution (Gini, 1921). A Gini coefficient of zero indicates perfect equality, where everyone has the same income; whereas, a Gini coefficient of one is perfect inequality, where one person has all the income. Thus, the Gini index measures the extent to which income distribution deviates from a perfectly equal distribution (Bellú and Liberati, 2006, p. 4). Kawachi and Kennedy (1997) conducted a study in the United States which compared six different indicators of income inequality including the Gini coefficient (Gini, 1921). They concluded that the results of the health effects of income inequality were not significantly influenced by the choice of income inequality measure. Researchers have identified certain limitations to the Gini index, namely that this measure is differentiating between income inequalities in the middle part of the distribution (De Maio, 2007). Thus, some view the Gini Index as ‘not neutral’ or value free (Atkinson, 1975; De Maio, 2007). Despite these concerns, many have used the Gini index widely as the statistic to generate a single measure of whole income distribution. Supported in Litchfield (1999) and Cowell and Jenkins (1995), Pryce et al. (2011) summarise the five criteria for ‘the appropriateness of any given measure of income inequality’, arguing that the Gini index meets at least four of five stated requirements: ● The transfer principle: the measurement in question should fall (rise) with the redistribution of income from (to) a richer to (from) a poorer person, or at least should remain unchanged. 56 ● ● ● ● Filipe Morais, Andrew Kakabadse, Nada K. Kakabadse and Adrian Pryce Income scale independence: when all income changes proportionally, there is no change in the measurement of inequality. Population principle: merging two distributions will not alter the measure of inequality. Anonymity or symmetry: only individual incomes are taken into account in the construction of the measure. Decomposability: the overall measure and changes are consistent with changes at every level, so that increases in inequality within population subgroups will result in overall increases in inequality. Thus, we can cross-reference a corporate Gini index (CGI) to the ‘macroeconomic Gini’ which the vast majority of countries and NGOs use. Overall, income inequality trends as measured by the Gini index reveal a steady increase in incomes across Europe in the last 14 years, even in historically more equally distributed income countries. An analysis of the average Gini index for selected European countries shows that the Portuguese average for the period 1995–2009 was 0.367, the highest in the EU, closely followed by the UK and Spain with 0.329 and 0.324 respectively (PORDATA, 2011). On the opposite side are the Scandinavian countries, such as Denmark at 0.214, Sweden at 0.233 and Finland at 0.249. Whilst Portugal and Spain remained highly unequal, the Scandinavian countries have seen their inequality rising to unprecedented levels. For example, in Denmark, the Gini index increased from 0.200 in 1995 to 0.270 in 2009. There are signs that income inequalities may increase even further as government austerity measures impact on households’ disposable income in several countries. For example, an IFS Report (2011) predicted that the UK household income will have a 3% drop, not seen since 1981, thus taking UK households to 2004–2005 income levels. The latest internal report from the Banco de Portugal (2011) predicts a permanent staggering 11% drop of Portuguese household income between 2011 and 2013. The World Economic Forum (WEF) Global Risks Report 2012, surveying 469 experts in various fields from all five continents (academia, business, NGOs, etc.), placed income inequality as one of the top risks that societies face over the next 10 years which, if unattended, will result in devastating consequences (WEF, 2012). Providing a supporting argument, Hsing (2005) emphasises that high Gini index scores hurt economic growth. Other studies have linked higher income inequality to higher rates of obesity in Israel and the United States (Kahn et al., 1998; Gross et al., 2008), infant mortality and mortality rates in general Corporate Income Inequality and Corporate Performance 57 (Kaplan et al., 1996; Schell et al., 2007) and violent crime (Fajnzylber et al., 2002). Further, Wilkinson and Pickett’s (2009b) recent review, for example, compared the ratio of incomes of the poorest to the richer 20% of the population for each of the 50 richest countries with at least 3 million inhabitants, through an Index of Health and Social Problems1 and concluded that the lower the income differentials the better countries performed. The most unequal countries, such as the United States, UK and Portugal, rated very poorly in most of the key indices, with greater health and social problems strongly correlating with income inequality (Wilkinson and Pickett, 2009a). The study The study in this chapter is as an exploratory case study (Ghauri and Gronhaug, 2002) on ‘Income Inequality and Corporate Performance’. The motivation for the study emanates from the fact that limited enquiry has considered Gini-type variables at the corporate level. We have selected a predominantly ‘quantitative’ method, drawing on a holistic single case study (Yin, 2003). In particular, this study uses real data, both quantitative and qualitative, from a multinational retail listed company. The study further draws on secondary data relating to: ● ● ● income distributions for the food retail company in domestic operations; corporate performance indicators for the domestic operations and for the companies within the group’s structure; and data from semi-structured interviews with the Chairman, majority controlling shareholder and the HR Corporate Director. We collected income distribution data from the company’s IT systems with the support of the corporate HR department. The study uses the concept of total compensation defined as ‘the monetary and nonmonetary rewards offered to employees’, including ‘(…) all forms of financial payments and a variety of employee benefits’ (Jackson et al., 2008, p. 356) and includes only full-time employees (FTEs) and any other equivalent under an employment contract. Following Pryce et al.’s suggestion (2011), we collected income distribution for six generic pay bands for the domestic company over the period of study: Executive Board, Top Management, Regional Directors/ Deputy Directors, District Managers, Store Managers and equivalent 58 Filipe Morais, Andrew Kakabadse, Nada K. Kakabadse and Adrian Pryce and shop floor employees. For each generic pay band we used headcount and average income to calculate the CGI. Additionally, we used three categories of corporate performance: Shareholders, Accounting and Financial and Employees in this study. For Shareholder and Accounting/Financial categories we used Share Price (SP), Earnings per Share (EPS), Sales (SAL) and Earnings Before Interest, Taxes, Depreciation and Amortisation EBIDTA, with agreed and consistent calculation formulas (where applicable) for each year of the study (Watson and Head, 1998; Brigham and Houston, 2009). For ‘Employees’, the chosen indicators were absenteeism (ABS) and turnover (TURN) relating to the domestic operations. We measured turnover and absenteeism as per the Chartered Institute of Personnel and Development Annual Survey Reports (CIPD, 2007a,b). The study gathers qualitative information on key themes such as income inequality, executive compensation and governance. We conducted two semi-structured interviews with the Chairman and the HR Corporate Director (chosen for convenience given the research background) with the purpose of understanding the underpinning thinking and perceptions of key actors within the company regarding pay inequality and perhaps establishing a relation of whether our quantitative results are a by-product of such thinking. We devised a more comprehensive measure of inequality that accounts for the wider workforce and society and correlated it with corporate performance. We computed a standard Gini index using Bellú and Liberati’s covariance formula (2006) as follows: G = cov(y, f(y))*2/y– where cov is the covariance between income level y and the cumulative distribution of the same income f(y) and y– the average income. We used average incomes for each income level and then correlated CGI results with corporate performance measures as we described above using SPSS 20.0. We performed and controlled one- and two-tailed Pearson correlations for size using the ratio of total executive compensation expenditure to total assets (TECETASS). We did not use any particular content analysis technique for the interviews as the interviewees’ full statements have, in the authors’ view, a research value per se. Interviews allowed us to position the company’s management thinking within the Corporate Income Inequality and Corporate Performance 59 main theories of reference helping to better understand the quantitative results. Results and discussion A preliminary analysis of the 2007–2010 income distributions for the company’s domestic operations shows that overall, the income distribution is quite equal due mainly to the large base of shop floor employees (Figure 2.2). Absolute trends on wealth distribution show that the wealth generated by the company is clearly oriented to the remuneration of the shareholder with year-on-year increases from 2007–2010. Shareholders have been enjoying increases on dividends paid of 8.3% in 2008, 12.7% in 2009 and 23.1% in 2010, whilst executives have seen their total compensation increasing at a slower rate with 17.8% in 2008, 5.1% in 2009 and 11.7% in 2010. As to the average pay of shop floor employees, we can see a decrease of 4.8% in 2008, an increase of 20.1% in 2009 and a decline of 55.5% in 2010. We observe a similar trend for the median shop floor employee pay (Table 2.3). We could not find an answer for the sudden 20.1% for average pay and 43.2% for the median shop floor employee pay increases in 2009. Our analysis indicates that (i) changes on the company’s remuneration policy or results; (ii) increases of headcount for shop floor employees starting on the lowest pay grade; (iii) employee turnover where replacements would start on lowest pay grade, do not vary 100% 88.9 87.9 88.9 88.3 96.9 95.9 96.0 96.4 2007 2008 2009 2010 50% 0% % Total employees % Total income Figure 2.2 Percentage of all income obtained by shop floor employees as a percentage of all employees (Domestic Operations only) Source: Income distributions collected directly from the company’s IT systems. 11.732 8.966 Average worker comp. Median worker comp. –4.8 –10.1 8.144 17.8 8.3 11.196 791.767 60.330.000 % Change 2008 Value (€) Source: HRIS Company Data and Governance Reports. 650.937 55.302.000 Value (€) 2007 Average exec. comp. Dividends paid Wealth distribution 14.348 14.008 834.470 69.128.000 Value (€) 43.2 20.1 5.1 12.7 % Change 2009 8.419 9.011 944.919 89.866.000 Value (€) –70.4 –55.5 11.7 23.1 % Change 2010 Table 2.3 Evolution of dividends, average executive compensation and average and median shop floor employee pay Corporate Income Inequality and Corporate Performance 61 so significantly as to provide an explanation for the 2009 and 2010 values. Data suggests that the company had definitely distributed its increased wealth to shareholders and executives, whereas average and median employee pay has decreased. Comparing average and median employee earnings from 2007 to 2010, we can observe that average earnings went from €11,732 to just €9,011 (a decrease of 23.2%) whereas, median pay went from €8,966 to €8,419 (a decrease of 6.1%). These trends in wealth distribution at the company are partially in line with the findings for the United States, where between 1990 and 2005, executive compensation increased on average over 298%, whilst the average production worker’s pay had a real compound increase of 4.3% and the Federal minimum wage saw a real compound decrease of 9.3% (IPS and UFE, 2006). Analysis for the domestic operations shows that except for 2007– 2008, the growth in average executive compensation was below the growth on dividends and company stock performance. However, analysis does display a similar trend for growth in executive compensation and a decrease for the average and median shop floor employee earnings over the period. In effect, the ratio for the average board executive compensation in comparison to the average shop floor employee nearly doubled when comparing 2007 with 2010 (Figure 2.3). The ratios indicate a growth of 55 times the average worker in 2007 to 104 times in 2010 and nearly 73 times the median shop floor employee 150.0 104.9 97.2 100.0 72.6 55.5 70.7 112.2 59.6 58.2 50.0 0.0 2007 2008 R6/R1 Average 2009 2010 R6/R1 Median Figure 2.3 Ratio of average executive board compensation (R6) to average and median shop floor employee pay (R1) (2007–2010) Source: Income distributions collected directly from the company IT systems. 62 Filipe Morais, Andrew Kakabadse, Nada K. Kakabadse and Adrian Pryce to 112 times in 2010, to CEO pay. According to the Chairman of the Portuguese company: If you say you are comparing the compensation of the General Director of the domestic Operations to the minimum salary paid in our units in the country, I accept the comparison. But comparing the compensation of a Senior Manager, say, the HR Director of the Group, I cannot. It’s false. It is distorting the truth. The HR Director is responsible for three countries, more than 60,000 people and 10 billion euros of sales! On the other hand, the average salary of our manufacturing firm is a lot higher than retail because the operating margins are greater. The group’s HR Director expressed a similar idea: I believe that these kinds of ratios can cause a lot of controversy, many times unjustified because (the ratio) compares things that are not comparable. I consider that if we don’t introduce clear criteria in relation to these ratios such as sector of activity, company size, type and profile of the workforce, we incur the risk of creating significant deviations to these ratios without adding any value. These statements are in line with the idea that companies perceived ‘fairness between different hierarchical levels as less significant as fairness to executives and shareholders (Bender and Moir, 2005, p. 19). It is on this basis that certain commentators (Hosseini and Brenner, 1992; Bizjaka et al., 2011) argue that peer group pressure ratchets pay upwards. Studies have linked pay differentials to a deterioration of company performance (Huang and Sharma, 2010), and also team performance (Bloom, 1999). Equally, other studies have linked low pay differentials with improved corporate performance (Hutton, 2011). However, the company under scrutiny in this chapter has enjoyed continued accelerated growth and thus does not fall into the category of growing pay differentials and deterioration of company performance. Corporate Gini index and corporate performance The results for the CGI and the ratio R6/R1 in Figure 2.4 indicate that both measures have a similar behaviour which seems to suggest that the R6/R1 ratio may be a predictor of a growth or fall on the CGI. This is explained largely by the weight of shop floor employee base as a percentage of total population and total income and to a lesser extent by Corporate Income Inequality and Corporate Performance 63 31.5 24.9 20.1 16.45 62.2 2007 104.9 70.7 58.2 2008 Ratio R6/R1* 2009 2010 CGI Figure 2.4 Company (Domestic Operations) CGI** and Ratio Rank 6/ Rank 1* (2007–2010) Source: Company data and corporate governance reports. * Rank 6 = Average Executive Board Compensation; Rank 1 = Average Shop Floor Employee Earnings. ** CGI is expressed between 0–100 to facilitate comparison. the observed growth on executive compensation. In fact, both measures are equally affected by changes on average (median) incomes of the large shop floor employee base. Overall, the CGI for the company’s domestic operations shows an increase almost doubling between 2007 and 2010, soaring from 0.1645 to 0.315 (Figure 2.4). We can explain the CGI decline for 2009 through an increase of 43.2% on average shop floor employee earnings to €14,008, when compared to 2008. To a lesser extent the CGI was also influenced in 2009 by an increase of 5.1% on average executive compensation. However, this layer of total payroll accounts for only approximately 0.00017 % of the total. Interestingly, the company’s corporate governance model changed from a Latin model (concentration of ownership) in operation until 2006, to an Anglo-Saxon model (dispersed ownership) of governance since 2007. Differences of ownership structure determine the nature of these two models of governance (Van Hulle, 1997). We can characterise the Latin model, a variation of the continental model by greater shareholder power through an extensive concentration of ownership, conflicts of interests between shareholders and executives due to the concentration of the voting power. Limited financial resources also play a role as shareholders tend to offer less equity than management needs and there is a movement of cash flows between well performing and badly performing companies (Van Hulle, 1997). On the contrary, the Anglo-Saxon model, with a 64 Filipe Morais, Andrew Kakabadse, Nada K. Kakabadse and Adrian Pryce dispersed ownership structure, awards greater power to the management team which encourages free riding, but that reflects in the shortterm orientation of the management in their striving to meet quarterly targets (Van Hulle, 1997). Commentators argue that the Anglo-Saxon governance model is linked to increased inequality (Clarke, 2010). Our results are consistent with this view, particularly when accounting for the changes of ownership structure. There were no changes on ownership structure. Whilst the company claims to have changed to an Anglo-American governance model since 2007, the fact is that shareholder structure did not change. More than 50% is concentrated in the hands of the Chairman and his family, hence ownership concentration is not consistent with the Anglo-American model. Figure 2.5 plots the CGI results for selected corporate performance measures for the period of the study. Investors’ measures for Earnings per Share (EPS) do follow a similar trend as we observed for the CGI. The CGI increases when the EPS increases, except for the year 2009 for the unknown reasons which we already discussed, that impacted the CGI. Overall, whilst Share Price (SP) decreased for 2007–2009, CGI increased, but we cannot observe the same for 2010. However, we can clearly attribute the decline in SP 0.9000 12.00 11.40 0.4472 0.8000 10.00 0.7000 0.6000 8.00 6.99 0.3188 0.5000 0.2089 0.2597 0.4000 5.40 6.00 3.97 0.3000 4.00 0.3150 0.2000 0.1000 0.2490 2.00 0.2010 0.1645 0.0000 0.00 2007 2008 CGI Figure 2.5 2009 EPS(€ ) 2010 SP(€ ) Investors’ performance measures: CGI, EPS and SP (2007–2010) Corporate Income Inequality and Corporate Performance 65 to the impact of the 2008 financial meltdown which stock markets felt worldwide, as the sovereign debt crisis unfolded. Data for employee performance measures show that absenteeism (ABS) has been growing steadily from 6.4% in 2007 to 7.5% in 2010, whereas turnover (TURN) increased from 44.8% in 2007 to reach 54.8% by 2009, but then declined sharply in 2010 to 37.72% (Figure 2.6). The general trend for the CGI is steady year-on-year growth, discounting for the 2009 unexplained growth of average shop floor employee earnings. One possible explanation offered for the decline in TURN in 2010 was that people, conscious of the difficult situation in the employment market, tried harder to keep their jobs. However, the overall trend is that ABS and TURN increase as CGI increases. According to the CIPD (2009) Recruitment, Retention and Turnover Report, UK-based turnover figures for retail are 17.4% and voluntary leavers 9.7%. In comparison, the retailer on study displays much higher rates. This raises the question of whether this is due to the large pay disparity. Accounting and financial measures for both the domestic operations and for the whole group (Figure 2.8) display similar behaviour concerning CGI (Figure 2.7). Overall, discounting for 2009, the trend seems to be that a growth in CGI is accompanied by a growth in Sales and EBITDA. In particular, it is evident that between 2007 and 2010, whilst 0.3500 0.3000 54.76% 0.3150 48.96% 60.00% 50.00% 44.82% 0.2500 37.72% 0.2490 40.00% 0.2000 0.2010 0.1500 0.1000 30.00% 0.1645 7.16% 6.54% 6.40% 7.55% 10.00% 0.0500 0.00% 0.0000 2007 2008 CGI Figure 2.6 20.00% 2009 ABS(%) 2010 TURN (%) Employee performance measures: CGI, TURN and ABS (2007–2010) 66 Filipe Morais, Andrew Kakabadse, Nada K. Kakabadse and Adrian Pryce 0.3500 3,500,000 0.3000 3,000,000 0.2500 2,500,000 0.2000 2,000,000 0.1500 1,500,000 0.1000 1,000,000 0.0500 500,000 0.0000 0 2007 2008 CGI 2009 Sales (€ billions) 2010 EBITDA (€ millions) Figure 2.7 Financial and accounting performance measures (Domestic Operations): CGI, SAL, EBITDA (2007–2010) 10,000,000 0.3500 9,000,000 0.3000 8,000,000 0.2500 7,000,000 6,000,000 0.2000 5,000,000 0.1500 4,000,000 0.1000 3,000,000 0.0500 2,000,000 1,000,000 0.0000 2007 CGI 2008 2009 Sales (€ billions) 2010 EBITDA (€ millions) Figure 2.8 Financial and accounting performance measures (Group of Companies): CGI, SAL, EBITDA (2007–2010) group sales doubled to nearly €10 billion, the CGI nearly doubled from 0.1645 to 0.3150 (Figure 2.8). We undertook Pearson partial correlation analysis between CGI and corporate performance, controlling for size and using the ratio of total executive compensation expenditure to group total assets. We also included the R6/R1 ratio, a further measure of inequality, to test for Corporate Income Inequality and Corporate Performance 67 effects similar to that of CGI. Table 2.4 presents the Pearson correlations between CGI, R6/R1 and corporate performance measures. Results show that after controlling for size, there was no statistically significant correlation between the CGI and the performance measures. We found a significant correlation at the 0.05 level (2-tailed; p = .35) for the R6/R1 ratio and the EBITDA for the domestic operations, which indicates that the ratio of average executive compensation to average employee earnings depends on EBITDA. In effect, when the domestic operation’s EBITDA grows so does R6/R1 grow, indicating that a growth in EBITDA increases top to bottom inequality. We also found significant correlations at the 0.05 level (1-tailed) between the CGI and R6/R1 ratio (p = .026), EPS (p = .048), Group EBITDA (p = .048) and Group Sales (p = .044). The correlation between CGI and R6/R1 adds weight to the perspective that a higher R6/R1 may be a predictor of an increase in company CGI. The correlations between EPS, Group EBITDA and Group Sales with the CGI are contrary to our research hypothesis that a higher CGI will have a negative impact on corporate performance. However, note that we conducted the study for Table 2.4 Summary of significant Pearson correlations CGI CGI 1 R6R1 .947* .026 R6R1 .947* 1 .026 EPS EBITDA_DOM EBITDA_GR SAL_GR .904* .835 .048 .083 –,.842 –.965* .079 .017 .903* .767 .048 .116 .912* .765 .044 .118 Notes: * Correlation is significant at the 0.05 level (1-tailed); ** Correlation is significant at the 0.01 level (1-tailed). Source: Compiled by authors. R6R1 –.965* EBITDA_DOM .035 * Correlation is significant at the 0.05 level (2-tailed). ** Correlation is significant at the 0.01 level (2-tailed). 68 Filipe Morais, Andrew Kakabadse, Nada K. Kakabadse and Adrian Pryce only four years when the company was experiencing strong growth. Therefore, it is not possible to comment on whether growth in the CGI will have any lagged effects, and whether a different pattern would have emerged had we examined the company for a longer time period. Conclusion and further research The emerging logic from this study for paying executives and worker suggests that ‘fairness’ for executives is more important than ‘fairness’ for the average employee. Whilst average executive compensation saw an aggregate increase of 31% from €650.937 in 2007 to €944.919 in 2010, average worker earnings showed a decrease of 23.2% from €11.732 to just €9.011 whereas median shop floor decreased by 6.1% to €8.419 in 2010. This has had an impact on both the rationale of executive board compensation to average and median worker pay and on the CGI. The increase of CGI for the company nearly doubled from 2007 to 2010 from 0.1645 to 0.315. We found a correlation between the R6/R1 ratio and the CGI, which suggests that R6/R1 is a predictor of the company CGI behaviour (p = .026). Both measures are useful to track inequality and excessive executive compensation within companies. The wealth distribution within the company is unbalanced, with the highest share going to shareholders, followed by executive board members, whereas the average employee earnings remain stagnant or have tended to decrease, which is in line with US trends and elsewhere. Correlations between CGI and EPS, Group Sales and Group EBITDA suggest that a growth in company performance and shareholder value is accompanied by a growth on the CGI. This, however, does not seem to have had a negative effect on company performance when we observed it at the macroeconomic level. The four years between 2007 and 2010 that we used in our analysis corresponds to probably the ‘golden years’ of the company in terms of performance and should the CGI continue to rise, the company may feel the effects in the future. It may be that there is an inflexion point after which continued and increased inequality and pay dispersion harms performance, as is the case with the Central Intelligence Agency (CIA), which draws on a 0.45 Gini coefficient or above as a predictor of social unrest (CIA, 2010). Future research needs to focus on extending the study of income inequality and corporate performance to a wider range of companies from different industries and governance traditions and for a longer Corporate Income Inequality and Corporate Performance 69 period in order to establish clearer trends and relationships between the variables. We could consider other soft performance indicators such as number of hours lost for sick leave (proxy for health effects at the macroeconomic level), number of disciplinary and grievance events, labour disputes, strikes (proxy for social unrest, crime, violence), unionisation of employees, employee participation, engagement and satisfaction (proxies for social capital and quality of community life). Note 1. The authors developed the index from several official sources and included: life expectancy; maths and literacy scores; infant mortality; homicides; imprisonment; teenage births; trust; obesity; mental illness, including drug and alcohol abuse; and social mobility. References AFG (2011). Recommendations on Corporate Governance, Industry SelfRegulation and Guidance. Association Française de Gestion Financiere, France. Retrieved 3 February 2011 from http://www.ecgi.org/codes/documents/cg_recommendations_afg_2011_en.pdf. Aguilera, R.V., Filatotchev, I., Gospel, H. and Jackson, G. (2008). Costs, contingencies and complementarities in governance models. Organization Science, 19(3), 475–494. Atkinson, A.B. (1975). The Economics of Inequality. Oxford University Press, London. Banco de Portugal (2011). Autumn Economic Bulletin. Department of Economic Studies. Retrieved 15 January 2012 from http://www.bportugal. pt/pt-PT/EstudosEconomicos/Publicacoes/BoletimEconomico/BEAnteriores/ Documents/bol_outono11_p.pdf. Bebchuk, L.A. and Fried, J.M. (2006). Pay without Performance: Overview of the Issues (Discussion Paper No. 528). Harvard Law School: John M. Olin Center for Law, Economics and Business. Bellú, L.G. and Liberati, P. (2006). Inequality Analysis: The Gini Index. Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations. Retrieved 10 October 2011 from http://www.fao.org/easypol/output/advanced_search.asp. Bender, R. and Moir, L. (2005). Does “best practice” in setting executive compensation pay in the UK encourage ‘good’ behavior? Paper presented at the 27th Annual Congress of the European Accounting Association, Cranfield School of Management, Gothenburg. Berle, A. and Means, G. (1932). The Modern Corporation and Private Property. Macmillan, New York. Bizjaka, J., Lemmonb, M. and Nguyend, T. (2011). Are all CEO’s above average? An empirical analysis of compensation peer groups and pay design. Journal of Financial Economics, 100(3), 538–555. Brigham, E.F. and Houston, J.F. (2009). Fundamentals of Financial Management (12th ed.). Cengage Learning, London. 70 Filipe Morais, Andrew Kakabadse, Nada K. Kakabadse and Adrian Pryce BIS (British Department of Business Innovation and Skills) (2011). Summary of Responses – A Long Term Focus for Corporate Britain, UK. Retrieved 5 April 2011 from http://www.bis.gov.uk/. Bloom, M. (1999). Listen Up, Managers: Fat Paychecks Don’t always Guarantee Success [Op-ed]. Wall Street Journal, 23 March. Retrieved 11 November 2010 from http://search.proquest.com/docview/398634142/136FFB13F0A5F2D3649 /1?accountid=12834. Bowen, H.R. (1953). Social Responsibilities of the Businessman. Harper and Row, New York. Christopher, J. (2010). Corporate governance – a multitheoretical approach to recognizing the wider influencing forces impacting on organizations. Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 21, 683–695. CIA (The Central Intelligence Agency) (2010). CIA – The World Factbook. Retrieved 20 July 2011 from https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/theworld-factbook/. CIPD (Chartered Institute of Personnel and Development) (2007a). Recruitment, Retention and Turnover, Annual Survey Report 2007, UK. Retrieved 7 March 2011 from http://www.cipd.co.uk/NR/rdonlyres/746F1183–3941–4E6A-9EF6– 135C29AE22C9/0/recruitretntsurv07.pdf. CIPD (Chartered Institute of Personnel and Development) (2007b). Measuring, Reporting and Costing Absence, UK. Retrieved 7 March 2011 from http://www. cipd.co.uk/NR/rdonlyres/3A208F80 –3484–4CE7-B8DD-907FFE660850/0/ Wellbeing_sample_chapter_02.pdf. CIPD (Chartered Institute of Personnel and Development) (2009). Recruitment, Retention and Turnover, Annual Survey Report 2009, UK. Retrieved 7 March 2012 from http://www.cipd.co.uk/binaries/recruitment_retention_turnover_ annual_survey_2009.pdf. Clarke, T. (2009). A critique of the Anglo-American model of corporate governance. Comparative Research in Law and Political Economy (CLPE), Research Paper No. 15, 5(3), 1–30. Clarke, T. (2010). Out of Control? The Impact of CEO Power and Reward on Economic Relationships and Inequality. European Academy of Management (EURAM), 1–37. CMVM (Comissão do Mercado de Valores Mobiliários) (2010a). Regulamento n.º1/2010. Comissão do Mercado de Valores Mobiliários, Portugal. Retrieved 10 January 2011 from http://www.cgov.pt/images/stories/ficheiros/regulamento12010governodassociedadescotadas.pdf. CMVM (Comissão do Mercado de Valores Mobiliários) (2010b). Código do Governo das Sociedades – Recomendações. Comissão do Mercado de Valores Mobiliários, Portugal. Retrieved 10 January 2011 from http:// w w w.c mv m.pt/C M V M/ Recomendacao/ Recomendacoes/ Doc u ments/ CodigodeGovernodasSociedadesCMVM2010.pdf. Coffee, J.C. (2010). The litigation and corporate governance impact of the DoddFrank Act. TCGD Conference, Brussels. Cowell, F.A. and Jenkins, S.P. (1995). How much inequality can we explain? A methodology and an application to the USA. Economic Journal, 105, 421–430. De Maio, F.G. (2007). Income inequality measures. Journal of Epidemial Community Health, 61, 849–852. Corporate Income Inequality and Corporate Performance 71 Dodd-Frank Act (2010), H.R.4173 – Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, Library of Congress, http://thomas.loc.gov/cgi-bin/ query/D?c111:6:./temp/~c1110y62av, (Accessed 5 February 2013). European Union Commission (2011). Green Paper. The EU Corporate Governance Framework: Brussels. Retrieved 15 March 2011 from http://eur-lex.europa. eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=COM:2011:0164:FIN:EN:PDF (accessed: 15.11.2012). Fajnzylber, P., Lederman, D. and Loyaza, N. (2002). Inequality and violent crime. Journal of Law and Economics, 45, 1–39. FCR (Financial Reporting Council) (2010). The UK Corporate Governance Code. Financial Reporting Council, UK. Retrieved 9 May 2011 from http://www. frc.org.uk/documents/pagemanager/corporate_governance/uk%20corp%20 gov%20code%20june%202010.pdf (accessed: 15 November 2012). Festinger, L. (1957). A Theory of Cognitive Dissonance. Stanford University Press, Palo Alto, CA. Fulmer, I.S. (2009). The elephant in the room: labour market influences on CEO compensation. Personnel Psychology, 62(4), 659–695. Ghauri, P. and Gronhaug, K. (2002). Research Methods in Business Studies: A Practical Guide (2nd ed.). Prentice Hall, London. Gini, C. (1912/1921). Measurement of inequality of incomes. The Economic Journal, 31(121), 124–126. Gross, R., Brammli-Greenberg, S., Gordon, B., Rabinowitz, J. and Afek, A. (2008). Population-based trends in male adolescent obesity in Israel 1967–2003. Journal of Adolescent Health, 44, 195–198. Hayward, M. and Hambrick, D. (1997). Explaining the premium paid for large acquisitions: evidence of CEO hubris. Administrative Science Quarterly, 42, 103–127. Heidrick and Struggles (2011). European Governance Report 2011: Challenging Board Performance. Retrieved 10 May 2011 from http://www.heidrick.com/ PublicationsReports/PublicationsReports/HS_EuropeanCorpGovRpt2011.pdf (accessed: 15 November 2012). High Pay Commission (2011). More for less: what happened to pay at the top and does it matter? High Pay Commission Interim Report. Retrieved 18 June 2011 from http://highpaycommission.co.uk/wp-content/uploads/2011/09/HPC-IR. pdf (accessed 15 November 2012). Hosseini, J. and Brenner, S. (1992). The stakeholder theory of the firm: a methodology to generate value matrix weights. Business Ethics Quarterly, 2(2), 99–119. Hsing, Y. (2005). Economic growth and income inequality: the case of the US. International Journal of Social Economics, 32(7), 539–547. Huang, W. and Sharma, Z. (2010). Do pay spreads generate incentives? Retrieved 20 October 2011 from http://ssrn.com/abstract=1572719 (accessed: 15 February 2012). Hutton, W. (2011). Hutton Review of fair pay in the public sector: Final Report. Retrieved 19 July 2011 from http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/d/hutton_fairpay_review.pdf (accessed 20 November 2012). IDS (2010). IDS directors’ pay report. Retrieved 27 April 2011 from http://www. incomesdata.co.uk/(accessed: 20 February 2012). IFS (Institute for Fiscal Studies) (2011). Biggest three year fall in household incomes since early 1990s. Institute for Fiscal Studies, UK. Retrieved 29 April 2011 from http://www.ifs.org.uk/pr/pr_210311.pdf (accessed: 20 November 2012). 72 Filipe Morais, Andrew Kakabadse, Nada K. Kakabadse and Adrian Pryce ILO (International Labour Organization) (2008). World of work report 2008: income inequalities in the age of financial globalization. ILO, Geneva. Retrieved 3 March 2011 from http://www.ilo.org/public/english/bureau/inst/ download/world08.pdf (accessed: 20 November 2012). ILO (International Labour Organization) (2009) ‘Income Inequalities in the Age of Financial Globalisation’, World of Work Report 2008, ILO Geneva’ IPS (2010). Executive excess: CEO pay and the great recession. 17th Annual Executive Compensation Survey. Retrieved 16 April 2011 from http://www. ips-dc.org/files/2433/EE-2010-web.pdf (accessed: 20 November 2012). IPS and UFE (2006). Executive excess: defence and oil executives cash in on conflict. 13th Annual CEO Compensation Survey. Retrieved 16 April 2011 from http://www.faireconomy.org/files/ExecutiveExcess2006.pdf (accessed: 20 November 2012). Jackson, S.E., Schuler, R.S. and Werner, S. (2008). Managing Human Resources (10th ed.). Cengage Learning, London. Jacoby, S.M. (2007). Finance and Labour: Perspectives on Risk, Inequality and Democracy. UCLA, Los Angeles, 1–42. Jensen, M.C. and Meckling, W. (1976). Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 305–360. Jensen, M.C. and Murphy, K.J. (1990). CEO incentives – it’s not how much you pay, but how. Harvard Business Review, 3, 138–153. Kahn, H.S., Tatham, L.M., Pamuk, E.R. and Heath, C.W. Jr. (1998). Are geographic regions with high income inequality associated with risk of abdominal weight gain?. Social Science and Medicine, 47, 1–6. Kakabadse, N. and Kakabadse, A. (2003). Polylogue as a platform for governance: integrating people, the planet, profit and prosperity. Corporate Governance, 3(1), 5–38. Kakabadse, N.K., Kakabadse, A. and Kouzmin, A. (2004). Director’s remuneration, the need for a geo-political perspective. Personnel Review, 33(5), 561–582. Kaplan, G.A., Pamuk, E.R., Lynch, J.W., Cohen, R.D. and Balfour, J.L. (1996). Inequality in income and mortality in the United States: analysis of mortality and potential pathways. British Medical Journal, 312, 999–1003. Kawachi, I. and Kennedy, B.P(1997). The relationship of income inequality to mortality: does the choice of indicator matter?. Social Science and Medicine, 45, 121–127. Khurana, R. (2002). Searching for a Corporate Savior: The Irrational Quest for Charismatic CEOs. Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey. Klein, E. (2010). CEO pay in Japan. The Washington Post. Retrieved 12 March 2012 from http://voices.washingtonpost.com/ezra-klein/2010/07/ceo_pay_in_ japan.html (accessed: 20 November 2012). Kroll, M. (2005). CEO pay rates: US vs. foreign nations. Management 510. Retrieved 17 October 2010 from http://www.pdfio.com/k-451040.html/(accessed: 20 November 2012). Lazear, E.P. and Rosen, S. (1981). Rank-order tournaments as optimum labor contracts. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 841–864. Litchfield, J.A. (1999). Inequality: method and tools. The World Bank, Washington D.C. Retrieved 22 April 2011 from http://www.worldbank.org/ poverty/inequal/index.htm (accessed: 20 November 2012). Corporate Income Inequality and Corporate Performance 73 Lloyd, T. (2009). Business at a Crossroads: The Crisis of Corporate Leadership. Palgrave, London. Lloyd, T. (2012). The market rate for a CEO is very far from clear. Financial Times. Retrieved from http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/cb3bdde4–84ba-11e1-b4f5– 00144feab49a.html#axzz2651uVdgo (Accessed: 20 January 2012). Martin, R. (2010). The age of consumer capitalism. Harvard Business Review, 88(1–2), 58–65. McGuire, J., Dow, S. and Argheyd, K. (2003). CEO incentives and corporate social performance. Journal of Business Ethics, 45(4), 341–359. Mishel, L., Bernstein, J. and Allegretto, S. (2007). The State of Working America, 2006/2007. EPI, Economic Policy Institute, USA. PORDATA (2011). Base de Dados Portugal Contemporâneo. Retrieved 2 February 2011 from http://www.pordata.pt/ (accessed: 20 November 2012). Pryce, A., Kakabadse, N.K. and Lloyd, T. (2011). Income differentials and corporate performance. Corporate Governance, 11(5), 587–600. Rosen, S. (1986). Prizes and incentives in elimination tournaments. American Economic Review, 76, 701–715. Rowe, A. and Liu, L.S. (2010). Exploring the remuneration ‘black box’: establishing an organizational learning insight into changing remuneration committee ‘social worlds’. Warwick Business School. Retrieved 19 September 2011 from http://go.warwick.ac.uk/wrap. Rushe, D. (2011). Occupy Wall Street: NYPD attempt media blackout at Zuccotti Park: journalists report aggressive treatment as media blocked from protest camp during surprise. The Guardian, 15 November 2011, http://www.guardian.co.uk/world/2011/nov/15/occupy-journalists-media-blackout. Schell, C.O., Reilly, M., Rosling, H., Peterson, S. and Ekstron, A.M. (2007). Socioeconomic determinants of infant mortality: a worldwide study of 152 low, middle and high-income countries. Scandinavian Journal of Public Health, 35, 288–297. SEV (Helenic Federation of Enterprises) (2011). SEV corporate governance code for listed companies. Helenic Federation of Enterprises, Greece. Retrieved 11 November 2011 from http://www.sev.org.gr/Uploads/pdf/SEV_CGC_ ENG_2011_FINAL%20_MARCH_2011.pdf . Supanvanij, J. (2008). Performance measurement and executive compensation. Review of Business Research, 8(3), 158–166. Teubner, G. (1996). Global Law Without a State: Studies in Modern Law and Policy. Dartmouth Publishing Co., New York. Think Progress (2009). CEO pay in Sweden. Retrieved 12 March 2012 from http://thinkprogress.org/yglesias/2009/06/25/193455/ceo-pay-in-sweden/. Tse, T. (2011). Shareholder and stakeholder theory: after the financial crisis. Journal of Qualitative Research on Financial Markets, 3(1), 51–63. Van Hulle, C. (1997). Is het systeem van corporate governance belangrijk? Op zoek naar de impact van verschillen in modellen. Report referaat Vlaams Wetenschappelijk Economisch Congres, 287–331. Watson, D. and Head, T. (1998). Corporate Finance: Principles and Practice. Financial Times, Pitman Publishing, London. WEF (World Economic Forum) (2012). Global risks report (7th ed.). Retrieved 30 March 2012 from http://www3.weforum.org/docs/WEF_GlobalRisks_ Report_2012.pdf. 74 Filipe Morais, Andrew Kakabadse, Nada K. Kakabadse and Adrian Pryce Wilkinson, R. and Pickett, K. (2009a). The Spirit Level: Why Equality is Better for Everyone. Penguin, London. Wilkinson, R. and Pickett, K. (2009b). Income inequality and social dysfunction. Annual Review of Sociology, 35, 493–511. Wiseman, M.S. and Severance, G.B. (2007). Is public concern over growing executive compensation justified? A study of income and wealth inequality. Forum on Public Policy, 3, 1–32. Yin, R.K. (2003). Case Study Research: Design and Method (3rd ed.). Sage, London. Zajac, E.J. and Westphal, J. (1994). The costs and benefits of managerial incentives and monitoring in large U.S. corporations: When is more not better? Strategic Management Journal, 15, 121–142. 3 How Chinese Styled Executive Remuneration Works: Evidence from Chinese Red-Chips Jessica Hong Yang and Nada K. Kakabadse Introduction Executive remuneration has attracted much attention from both academics and practitioners in the past two decades (Murphy, 1985; Bebchuk and Fried, 2003). A well-designed executive remuneration is significant to a firm’s performance, especially during financial crisis (Bebchuk and Weisbach, 2010). An astonishing survey shows that the average executive pay of Standard & Poor 500 firms increased more than four times from $3.5 million to $14.7 million and the granted stock options to CEOs increased nearly nine-fold from 1992 to 2000 (Bebchuk and Fried, 2003). The design of executive remuneration therefore attracts a great attention in the world. Issues of concern, especially in the banking field, include poor remuneration packages, enormous executive salaries and excessive short-term risk-taking. An unprecedented number of financial firms suffered extensive collapse during the 2008 global financial crisis. When companies struggle during a financial crisis, corporate governance plays a vital role to save firms, particularly with regard to adjusting executive remuneration (Erkens et al., 2012). Each company has its own remuneration package for executives in accordance with the company’s objective and risk tolerance (Bebchuk and Fried, 2005). Bebchuk and Spamann (2010) contend that reasonably designed executive remuneration not only prevents executives from excessive risk-taking, but also provides top executives with incentives to focus on shareholders’ longterm value. China has been less affected by the global crisis due to its ‘closed’ capital account and insulated banking sector, primarily relying on deposits with no exposure to risky Western financial instruments (Schmidt, 75 76 Jessica Hong Yang and Nada K. Kakabadse 2009). As a result, the unique characteristics of the Chinese corporate governance system provide an interesting point for the study on how to make the boards work via the design of executive remuneration. There are a number of reasons. First, studies on executive remuneration have concentrated on a few developed countries such as the United States and the UK, due to the data availability (Rampling et al., 2011). Second, China has undergone a series of state-owned enterprise (SOE) reforms. Efficient managerial incentives and market-oriented corporate governance institutions effectively facilitate China’s sustainable economic growth. Finally, in China, the culture, including egalitarianism, heavily influences the remuneration system (Shen and Edwards, 2006). This distinguishes it from the pay and performance link, which most developed economies practice. In contrast to previous studies on the relationship between pay and performance based on quantitative study, this chapter provides new evidence that is relevant to this debate. It investigates whether and how Chinese styled remuneration provides incentives for the top executives in large SOEs based in Mainland China that are incorporated internationally and listed on the Hong Kong Stock Exchange (also referred to as red-chips) through examining board member and regulator perceptions in China. In particular, the chapter addresses the following questions: 1. What does executive remuneration look like in red-chips? 2. Why does executive remuneration look the way it does? This chapter makes a number of contributions to the recent executive remuneration research. First, in response to the policy and media debate on excessive board director remuneration in Chinese red-chips, we examine this perception. We also discuss the relationship between remuneration committees and the State-Owned Assets Supervision and Administration Commission of the State Council (SASAC). Second, unlike in the UK and United States, equity-based pay is rare in China. This is an interesting institutional difference between China and the United States or UK. We detail the pay elements and the incentive schemes that firms implement in China. Finally, we address the disclosure issue and pay attention to the performance criteria that firms use in linking executive remuneration more closely to company performance. The rest of the chapter is organised as follows: we provide a review of theoretical perspectives and empirical studies on executive remuneration. A discussion of the study sample and data collection follows. The data How Chinese Styled Executive Remuneration Works 77 allows us to address the unexplored remuneration issues in red-chips. Next we summarise the key findings in three themes. Finally, we offer some concluding remarks. Theories of executive remuneration The primary reason for the agency problem is due to the separation of ownership and management in the modern enterprise mechanism (Berle and Means, 1932). How to effectively align the manager’s interests with those of the shareholders has become a hot topic in executive remuneration. Theoretically, scholars divide the study of executive compensation into two competing views: the optimal contracting view and the managerial power view (Bebchuk and Fried, 2005; Weisbach, 2007; Choe et al., 2009; Bebchuk and Weisbach, 2010; Bebchuk et al., 2010; Sun et al., 2010). Optimal contracting anticipates that remuneration committees have sufficient incentives to determine executive compensation that optimises on behalf of shareholders (Mirrlees, 1976; Holmstrom, 1979). Structural variables such as board composition and characteristics are insignificant or irrelevant. In contrast, the managerial power perspective holds that optimal contracting helps remedy agency problems. This may actually contribute to the difficulties because board structure is inefficient due to unresolved agency issues. This leads to sub-optimal outcomes (Bebchuk and Fried, 2003). Executives may exert enormous influence over the board of directors to make such pay arrangements in favour of themselves instead of the shareholders. Bebchuk and Fried (2003) point out that managerial power and rent extraction seem to have great impact on executive remuneration design. Therefore, ‘outrage’ cost will occur easily. In order to minimise outrage cost, some executives have the incentive to obscure their rent extraction; however, excessive outrage may easily to trigger conflict between managers and shareholders. The managers may even lose shareholder support. Lee (2006) expresses considerable concern about the contractual terms of compensating top executives, particularly in the form of profit-related bonuses, share options and termination payments which often transpire with poor company performance. Johnson et al. (1997) provide evidence that outside perception influences and affects remuneration package design. Because of shareholder and public concern over high compensation packages, some managers hide and minimise outrage cost through camouflage. Bebchuk and Fried (2003) further emphasise that strong camouflage can result in a 78 Jessica Hong Yang and Nada K. Kakabadse firm adopting inefficient remuneration structures, which will directly impair the firm’s performance. Therefore, under this situation, transparency becomes more important to the company. Structure of executive remuneration Michael (1997) points out that a reasonable executive remuneration structure could benefit an entire company’s operation. This is because the executive managers are always the key players to lead the company. They have a large stake in a company’s success. Bebchuk and Fried (2005) further contend that appropriate remuneration can effectively motivate executives to generate value for the company and shareholders. It is important to guarantee that the remuneration package has aligned managers’ interest with shareholders’ interest. A reasonable executive remuneration structure may determine executive and employee contributions to the company. Conyon et al. (2000) state that every company has its own and unique remuneration package for executives, which each company’s remuneration committee usually determines. Executive remuneration design and structure is according to the company’s objectives and strategies and it changes from year to year (Mehran, 1995). More specifically, companies account for short-term and long-term objectives. In addition, external factors impact (e.g. financial crisis, currency crisis, market bubble, credit crisis) and play important roles in determining the executive remuneration structure. Bebchuk and Fried (2005) emphasise that when managers receive a high proportion of short-term bonus remuneration without tying long-term value on a manager’s wealth, they may tend to ignore the company’s long-term performance and only concern themselves with short-term profit. Therefore, a good remuneration package should allocate the short-term and long-term incentives properly. Bebchuk and Spamann (2010) claim that executive pay also must consider the longterm shareholder interests and sound risk management principles. The short-term incentive is indispensable. Otherwise, the executives do not have enough motivation to increase the company’s performance with short-term objectives (Beltratti and Stulz, 2009). Currently, for most executives, normal remuneration in the Chinese SOEs generally includes four parts: annual base salary, performance, long-term incentives and various social insurance benefits (Kato and Long, 2006a). John and John (1993) state that in order to attract and retain top-notch senior management, some companies will continue How Chinese Styled Executive Remuneration Works 79 to push executives’ total remuneration levels higher in order to remain competitive in the talent market. Key remuneration package elements to attract and retain excellent executives include long-term incentives and pensions. However, as Chinese executive pay levels rapidly climb, critics are starting to realise that some executives are overpaid and that the salary and performance are not well matched (Tung, 2010). How to build a reasonable executive remuneration structure and associate properly with the company’s value draws considerable attention from both the public and academia. Evolution of executive remuneration in China We can divide the research on Chinese-styled executive remuneration into two phases: the planned economy and the transitional economy. The Chinese planned economy bases the remuneration system on grade with significant characteristics of infrequent dismissals, egalitarian- and group-based pay and reward and welfare from cradle to grave (Goodall and Warner, 1997). The wage system that companies most commonly adopt is national wages scales (Wang, 1990). Employee income differentials in assorted job positions are at the minimal level (Nelson and Reeder, 1985). There are rarely pay increases, except for grade promotions for entire staff which the government unifies (Dowling and Welch, 2004). The old Chinese iron-rice-bowl approach which guaranteed job security also stressed that corporate management should provide social welfare programmes such as housing funds, education and medical insurance (Glover and Siu, 2000). This system does not provide any financial incentives for employees to seek promotions. When reformist leader Deng Xioping began to implement reforms towards a market economy in the mid-1980s, Chinese companies were given the autonomy to establish their own reward and compensation systems, whilst the nation still controlled the payroll’s total amount and size (Shen and Edwards, 2006). Since the 1990s, companies placed increasing importance on hiring a young, educated work force that could embrace work responsibilities and be motivated by levels of reward and pay (Child, 1994). Under the transitional economy, Chinese remuneration transferred from a grade- to a performance-related system (Shen and Edwards, 2006). This system is primarily based on post-plus-skills, referring to basic salary and efficiency-related bonuses. The basic wage mainly rests on age, job position, qualifications and salary category. Whilst seniority still has significant influence on pay, the egalitarian culture offsets the increases of reward and remuneration interests, 80 Jessica Hong Yang and Nada K. Kakabadse which consequently gives rise to the narrow range of wage and salary. Companies commonly distribute the bonus through group-based pay and managerial positions in spite of individual performance (Zhu and Dowling, 1994; Easterby-Smith et al., 1995; Huo and Von Glinow, 1995; Mitsuhashi et al., 2000). Nowadays, the remuneration system which Chinese companies most widely adopt is performance-related compensation systems (Reynolds, 1988; Hamill, 1989; Anderson, 1990; Dowling and Schuler, 1990; Logger et al., 1995; Dowling and Welch, 2004). The growing decentralisation in remuneration results in rewards and compensations that are increasingly subject to firms’ specific requirements rather than government and sector-specific criteria (Shen and Edwards, 2006). Therefore, most Chinese enterprises have increasingly paid attention to the performance-related pay system due to the growing awareness of fair and egalitarian remuneration packages. In the financial service sector, companies adopt the post-based pay approach which takes hierarchy into account (Reynolds, 1988; Hamill, 1989; Anderson, 1990; Dowling and Schuler, 1990; Logger et al., 1995; Dowling and Welch, 2004). This remuneration package contains a fixed position-based wage, performance-related bonuses and other relevant compensations. Compared with western firms, Chinese firms provide relatively less long-term rewards for staff, but more immediate cash rewards. The present study Considering the paucity of studies on the relationship between executive pay and firm performance in Chinese SOEs, we adopted an exploratory qualitative study to explore whether and how executive remuneration works in red-chips. This approach allowed us to explore complex issues that have human interaction at their core (Culpepper and Gilbert, 1999) by seeking views from board insiders. Our principal objective was to learn what impact, if any, that these respondents thought that executive remuneration might have on corporate governance and, consequently, firm performance. We purposefully targeted the top 20 red-chips to investigate the remuneration issue. Seven companies agreed to participate in this study. These companies are in strategic areas such as financial service, oil and mining sectors. We encountered practical difficulties in reaching potential participants who are few in number and often require higher levels of trust to initiate contact with them or to break the barrier to discuss sensitive topics (Faugier and Sargeant, 1997; Atkinson and Flint, 2001, 2004; Rhodes How Chinese Styled Executive Remuneration Works 81 et al., 2004). We used a ‘snowballing’ sampling method, a link-tracing technique that relies on a series of referrals within a circle of people who know each other or are loosely connected (Atkinson and Flint, 2001), to obtain a wider range of research contacts within a particular group’s culture in order to provide an account of meanings and activities from inside the unknown (Atkinson and Flint, 2004). As such, we based the selection of samples on insider knowledge and referral chains among subjects who possess common traits that are of research interest (Kaplan et al., 1987). The snowballing method also prevents problems of sample bias because of the non-random selection (Atkinson and Flint, 2001). Our sample consisted of 19 board members from seven boards and three government officials from SASAC. We began by contacting and interviewing government officials in SASAC, with whom we had direct or indirect personal or professional contacts. A chain referral technique improved our access as the officials referred us to the board members from some of the companies under their control such as those in the financial and energy sectors. At the end of each interview, we asked the participant to name other potential interview participants or to contact them on our behalf, which most of them did. This was especially important in our study when we asked respondents to comment on sensitive topics ranging from board colleague remuneration to their own and views on their remuneration arrangement. We conducted semistructured, open-ended interviews. The interviews varied from 1.5 to 3.5 hours, with the average interview lasting 2.5 hours. We conducted the interviews in Chinese. Most of the study participants were uneasy with the use of a tape recorder, so we captured the context through shorthand later transcribed the interviews. The study participants did not sign a formal confidentiality agreement, but we assured them of confidentiality and they were okay with this. We used a conversational analysis approach to interpret our data (Atkinson and Heritage, 1984). The interview collection and transcription process was on-going, with regular meetings between inquiring co-authors to discuss individual interviews with transcript in hand. We discussed whatever issues any of us noticed. Our analysis sessions were open-ended, with themes emerging as outcomes of our agreement during these sessions. Thus, our approach is interpretive data analysis where every inference is rooted in specific textual evidence of collected narratives whether they are transcripts or interview notes (Denzin, 1989). As Ewick and Silbey (1998: 29) observed, what ‘people tell about themselves and their lives, both constitutes and interprets those lives, as the stories describe the world as it is lived and understood by the 82 Jessica Hong Yang and Nada K. Kakabadse storyteller.’ Our approach was a bottom-up analysis in order to discover their meanings. This chapter focuses on the stories that board insiders and key stakeholders told us about their perceptions on the arrangement of top executives’ remuneration. The quotations only present views of our sample and offer ‘native’ insights for subsequent testing. Due to the commercial sensitivity of the information, we guaranteed the respondents’ anonymity. Results Following the analysis of the theoretical framework and earlier empirical studies, three dominant themes emerged from the narrative analysis: ‘perception on current remuneration strategy’, ‘process of setting executive remuneration’ and ‘disclosure of executive remuneration’. We provide illustrative examples for each theme, which we abstracted from the original participants’ narratives. This study’s findings reveal the board insiders’ perceptions on the design of top executives’ remuneration and its effects on reducing agency problems and linkage with firm performance. The perception on current remuneration strategy An issue surrounding executive remuneration is the directors’ perception on how the company sets the pay. When asked whether seniority and the culture of egalitarianism still influence the Chinese remuneration system, one director in our interviews believed that: An executive’s basic salary is based on age, job position, qualifications and salary category. For example, the chairman has the highest pay due to the position, which is followed by the CEO. Some retired executives have the qualification and age advantages so they also receive high remuneration. Overall, there is small income differentiation among the executives on the same level. As clearly stated above, management within the firms use seniority and the egalitarian culture to determine the basic pay. The bonus distribution is group-based regardless of individual performance. Often the firm awards the bonus to all executive directors on the same level depending on the firm’s performance. However, another director explains how his company has moved away from the old styled pay scheme towards a market-based scheme. Market-oriented American styled pay has generally replaced the culture of egalitarianism and seniority. How Chinese Styled Executive Remuneration Works 83 As top executives in SOEs discharge their role in government services, the public can hardly accept high-level salaries for them. When asked about public criticisms regarding the extremely high remuneration to executives in high profile red-chips, an SASAC officer commented: The gap between the average pay of the executives and employees has shrunk 13.6 times from 2003 to 12 times in 2011. In fact, China adopts a semi-market-oriented approach to set the executive pay in SOEs. The pay is significantly lower than that in a private company. However, as companies need to participate in the market competition, the pay must also reflect and recognise the market value of this post. But at the same time the management are not just the professional managers. They also have a government role. So, a semi-market-oriented approach is a good compromise. A number of directors said that the remuneration in red-chips is relatively lower than that in the same private sector industry. For example, two directors commented that: Yes, the executive pay in the strategic sectors, for example, financial services and oil and petrol sectors, has increased significantly in the past few years. According to the statistics by SASAC, from 2004 to 2007, the average annual salary of the executives of the centrally owned enterprises under SASAC supervision is 350,000 yuan (£35,000), 430,000 yuan (£43,000), 478,000 yuan (£47,800) and 550,000 yuan (£55,000) respectively. The annual increase rate is around 14 per cent. In 2009 and 2010, the average remuneration is 600,000 yuan (£60,000). It is not that high when comparing it with the pay for the executives in a similar industry in the private sector. Compared with the executive salary in the same industry in Chinese private sectors and developed countries, the pay in SOEs is still very low. If this is the case, it is worthwhile to investigate the recruitment and retention issues in red chips since the relatively low group-based pay restricts the company’s abilities to align the compensation with its strategy. One director claimed: We benefit from the pension and other benefits. This includes basic pension insurance, medical insurance, unemployment insurance and housing fund schemes and so on. The local government authorities give us a lot of support. The benefits will be invested in individual 84 Jessica Hong Yang and Nada K. Kakabadse accounts and could be gained after retirement. Although the bonus has been reduced due to the economic downturn worldwide, the pension and other benefits have increased accordingly and they become the main incentive except for base salary. One possible reason is that the government owns the majority of red-chip shares and the board does not have enough power to allocate shares. Directors, however, would have a better pension after retirement than those in private enterprises. Furthermore, in Chinese culture, loyalty plays an important part. It is the citizen’s duty to be loyal to the government, the company and family all the time. Once directors obtain a good job, they will be reluctant to change. Therefore, red-chips usually do not have to worry about retention of directors. The process of setting executive remuneration The directors from our study describe the information sources and processes that companies use to set directors’ pay. Two officers discussed the key stages in pay-setting. How to determine the pay for executives is a complex task and we need to consider all aspects of factors and balance the efficiency and fairness. The biggest problem encountered is in the formulation of the remuneration. From a practical point of view, the goal is to move towards a market-based remuneration system and to avoid a return to the era of the ‘iron rice bowl’. At the same time, we need to put a cap on the remuneration to avoid paying out too much. The basic annual salary is linked with the previous year’s average wage and paid monthly. Performance-based bonuses are based on the annual performance evaluation results in accordance with determined criteria. The total amount will be paid out to the SOEs. But the executives will initially be paid 60% and the rest 40% will be held until the end of the tenure. In fact, SASAC plays a more important role than the remuneration committee in setting the pay. Two directors stated that: Prior to the establishment of the SASAC, the remuneration was set by us, SOEs themselves. In September 2009, the SASAC issued the guidance to further standardise the remuneration of top executives in the largest SOEs. Currently, the salary structure of the executives is How Chinese Styled Executive Remuneration Works 85 composed of three parts: basic annual salary, the performance-based annual salary and medium-and long-term incentives. In actual operation, the basic annual salary and performance-based pay are relatively standardised. But I think that SASAC still lacks effective ideas and ways of setting medium-and long-term incentives. At present, our company has a remuneration committee, but they don’t know how to design a professional executive pay structure. Hence, the remuneration system’s efficiency is well dependent on SASAC’s efficacy. One director commented: I don’t think SASAC has sufficient information about the individual company. They also don’t have that much time to take part in the board meetings and to understand the company’s performance metrics. They only can provide very general guidance on the pay. This comment indicates that there is an unsound external supervision system when it comes to making salary recommendations. In China, SASAC is the agent and client of the state-owned properties. SASAC does not have the claim for firms’ residual profits and has no real responsibility for the state-owned properties. The unbalance between power of control and the infrastructure provides insufficient incentives for SASAC to evaluate and supervise CEOs seriously. Moreover, the severe information asymmetry prevents the government from other institution supervision (Zhao, 2011). Given the importance of linking rewards to performance, we sought to explore in our interviews with directors what standards and targets that their companies set for directors’ pay. A number of directors claimed that the company’s culture and characteristics, as well as their own performance, determine the pay levels. For example: The pay levels of executives in SOEs are determined by the size and industry of the enterprises, the pay of the national counterparts and the local economic and social development. We also consider the balance between personal and business interests, economic efficiency, enterprise development and social responsibility. This balance is also in line with the level of compensation culture in East Asia. The compensation design tends to be based on the consideration of fairness, incentives, economic development and corporate social responsibility. 86 Jessica Hong Yang and Nada K. Kakabadse Our company has established the economic value added (EVA) assessment indicators. I guess it will be used to set the pay … it will motivate SOEs to go bigger and achieve sustainable development and innovation. And it will facilitate better risk management. However, the directors in our interviews noted that the variable pay is still a very low proportion of the whole package. International experience shows that the key to a good pay system is to be built on the basis of the performance evaluation and the results of the firm performance must be linked with incentive pay. At the same time, the proportion of variable pay should be appropriately increased, which is both easy to linking pay and performance, but also can reduce the risk of the enterprise. In developed countries, a large proportion of the remuneration is equity based. But we don’t have equities of the company. We only have basic salary, social welfare, supplementary retirement benefits, termination benefits, enterprise annuity scheme and bonus plans. Our company doesn’t implement share incentives or share options. There are no executives holding or trading shares. This is common in Chinese listed firms, which means that most Chinese companies have no share options scheme in the remuneration system, therefore, there are few disclosures in reports. Conyon et al. (2000) indicate that share incentives are essential to retain and motivate employees for long-term development. Excessive short-term salaries and welfare benefits could cause executives to lap up the comfort, thus putting a damper on their incentive to remain innovative and competitive in today’s global business environment. Interestingly, in most of these companies’ annual reports, they claimed that they have applied performance-oriented incentive evaluation results to decide director appointments and dismissals, rewards and penalties, promotions and remunerations. However, the respondents could not articulate how they receive their incentive pay and whether the company links it to its performance. Another issue regarding executive remuneration is the perception that CEOs are able to set their own pay. One director noted: The CEO is very powerful and important in the company. The CEO typically has a say on his own remuneration and the remuneration for the group. It is not too difficult to change the criteria to get How Chinese Styled Executive Remuneration Works 87 the rewards. Who cares about the performance of the company? Nobody! This comment indicates that the CEO duality leads to serious insider control and corporate governance becomes a mere formality. On the surface, specialist consultants propose executive remuneration which the SASAC and shareholders approve. However, in reality, executives design their remuneration package themselves. Based on Zhao’s research (2011), executives always change the performance assessment index advantage in their favour, using their power on the board. They assess their work performance and create their own remuneration package. Zhao (2011) points out that under the influence of a high degree of uniformity between senior management and board of directors, the independent non-executive directors have lost equitable and logical judgement regarding executive remuneration. Disclosure of executives’ remuneration We are interested in the disclosure issue of executives’ remuneration as red-chips are publicly listed companies on the Hong Kong exchange. The China Securities Regulatory Commission (CSRC) has emphasised the requirement to establish a transparent, timely, accurate and full information disclosure system. When asked if it is possible to disclose an executive’s remuneration, the officer noted: In fact, for SASAC, the income of the leaders of SOEs is transparent. Red-chips have already disclosed the executive remuneration in the annual report. The problem is the requirements for disclosure have not yet been institutionalised. Not all SOEs choose to make the remuneration transparent to the public. People might question that they do not see the money in the end and how the money has been allocated. However, the disclosure of the executive pay is the trend and it is not difficult to operate. The UK and United States pay more attention to information disclosure, especially in annual reports. The various detailed information about executive remuneration provide important information for stakeholders, the public and the authority to make scientific judgements on the remuneration system (Cheng, 2009). However, in China, one can find only general payment information in annual reports, without personal information, schemes or responses from the remuneration committee 88 Jessica Hong Yang and Nada K. Kakabadse (Ye, 2012). Additionally, the lack of transparency and disclosure lead to a high cost for the public to gain detailed information and executive remuneration does not have extensive supervision and control (Ju, 2012). Thus, the absence of a detailed information disclosure system does not protect stakeholders’ rights properly. Discussion and conclusions Since the 1990s, China has reformed its SOEs and has listed them in domestic and foreign stock exchanges (Chen et al., 2010). This reform is an innovative attempt to diversify SOE ownership and increase SOE independence. However, it adds a series of problems in executive remuneration, in particular, the lack of detailed regulation and disclosure of executive remuneration, which increases financial risk (Ju, 2012). SOEs must engage in duties other than profit seeking, such as reducing the unemployment rate and maintaining social stability (Megginson and Netter, 2001). According to the findings, to maintain the stability of the polity, the Communist Party of China (CPC) would like to appoint government servants as CEOs. The political motivation of top executives refers to the stable position and the promotion of political rank (Cao et al., 2011; Liu et al., 2011). In the current circumstances, jobs in SOEs are more stable than in the private sector. Executives do not need to worry about performance targets. At the same time they have the right to be promoted as government civil servants. The findings also conclude that SOE executives gain more welfare benefits and other privileges. These usually include a housing allowance, supplemental medical insurance and a transportation allowance. These provide a secure and comforting guarantee for executives after retirement. In order to maintain consistency at the executive level and the safety of state-owned property, CEO duality is common in SOEs. CEOs are very powerful from both political and financial perspectives. This leads to high inside control. Our findings are consistent with Chen et al.’s (2010) study. They analysed the statistics for 502 Chinese listed SOEs from 2001 to 2006 and concluded that CEOs use their excessive board power to push executive compensation to a high level, which leads to the loss of state-owned properties. CEO duality is in a dominant position in smoothing business; however, it needs a sound legal system and mature financial markets, which are currently absent in China (Chen et al., 2010). As a special appointment system, executives in red-chips are government servants. On the one hand, SOE executives should have the same How Chinese Styled Executive Remuneration Works 89 wage scale with other officials in the same rank. On the other hand, in order to attract talent, SOE executive remuneration should be higher than or equal to the relevant industry. In fact, SOEs’ pay is lower that in relevant industries, which leads to talent migrating to better opportunities. The current state is that despite the relatively low pay, SOE executives might have unserviceable managerial abilities because of their excessive power. Since most SOEs are in monopolised industries, top executives could use this advantage to exchange inside information for grey income easily despite disobeying professional ethics. According to Liu et al.’s (2011) study, executives in large banks could gain more post relevant consumption and this consumption amount shows no direct connection with the firm’s operating performance. Our findings suggest that executive remuneration is increasing synchronously with the global benchmark of pay. Chen et al. (2010), however, argue that this rise is unreasonable, because it shows no link with the firm’s performance (Chen et al., 2010). Ye (2012) suggests that SOE executive remuneration system should suit its selection and appointment system. Since CEO appointments contain political elements, it is unreasonable to apply their payment with the market price. Firms should separate their remuneration packages into three kinds: ‘administrative price’ for government appointed CEOs, ‘semi-market price’ for those gaining jobs through competition and ‘market price’ for the professional managers without official capacities (Ye, 2012). The CSRC emphasised that listed companies should disclose timely, correct and transparent information to shareholders and other investors (Mallin, 2007). The transparency disclosure principles aim to offer shareholders full information in making investment decisions, which has influence on many areas of the corporation such as companies’ objectives, board information and financial results, especially the executives’ compensation policies (Madera and Sun, 2005). OECD Principles outlined the principles on executive compensation in 1999, and the CSRC also stated the requirement of providing executive remuneration measures within annual reports (Kato and Long, 2006b). Since 1998, Chinese publicly listed companies began to disclose top executive remuneration in annual reports, including the total size and amount of compensation to directors, supervisors and senior managers, and the aggregate cash remuneration such as basic wage, bonus and commission (Firth et al., 2005; Buck et al., 2008). Firms should submit disclosed information within annual reports to the stock exchange and accountancy firms should audit them (Liu, 2005). Despite the requirements, the findings suggest that until now, most Chinese listed companies did not 90 Jessica Hong Yang and Nada K. Kakabadse disclose precise executive compensation information or merely publish aggregate remuneration to executives or key staff members. Very few Chinese companies have a share options scheme in the remuneration package, which causes limited and inadequate disclosures in the annual report. The lack of transparent executive remuneration information disclosure has many influences on the company. A company merely discloses total salaries and executive bonuses, which may cause limited disclosures of the complicated relationship between executives’ remuneration and performance. Additionally, firms cannot guarantee the quality of performance from those executives and whether they have earned these fees. The unreported pay may lead to an undervaluation of incentives’ influence on performance. More importantly, the incomplete disclosure affects shareholders’ decision-making because they do not have access to full information. We suggest that it is important to improve SOE executive remuneration systems, especially in monopolised red-chips where it is important, to make the boards work. First, these companies should adopt an equity-based mechanism. For instance, in the UK and United States, since share price and corporate performance are important, stock and stock options are two popular components in executive remuneration (Cheng, 2009). Management has the priority to buy a certain number of stocks with a contractual price in the prescribed period. In this way, management could share the risks and profits together with shareholders. According to Cen’s (2011) study, appropriate shareholding ratios for executives, normally from 5% to 20%, can help improve operating performance and corporate value. Notably, the low-level shareholding ratio does not promote motivation, whilst a high-level ratio could reduce shareholders’ interests and control power. Second, it is important to establish a series of remuneration standards by considering companies’ relative profitability and absolute profitability to increase SOE’s asset utilisation efficiency and regulate the board director performance. Firms should separate the remuneration standards into several modules such as the customer growth module, surplus capability module and sustainable growth module (Chen, 2011). The government should make an appropriate balance by referencing global pay benchmarks and ensuring that the remuneration level is consistent with an individual’s performance. Additionally, despite that the government appoints directors, it is not appropriate to pay all executives at the same level. The executive remuneration system should be suitable for its selection and appointment system. Ye (2012) suggests three How Chinese Styled Executive Remuneration Works 91 packages: ‘administrative price’ for government appointed CEOs, ‘semimarket price’ for those who gain jobs through competition, and ‘market price’ for the professional managers without official capacities. Finally, the government must improve the Chinese legal and supervision system to keep pace with its economic growth. Executives in SOEs illustrate that the unsound regulation and supervision in SOEs conveniently provide ways for executives to seek grey income. To maintain long-term SOE development and keep state-owned properties safe, the government should set more restrictions on certain incentives, such as management buyouts (MBO) and executive shareholding. Remuneration committees and SASAC should work together to supervise and regulate directors’ pay. Overall, this chapter has added to the debate on executive remuneration in Chinese red-chips. We have highlighted the current remuneration structure, which is fixed pay and benefits predominate. We have shown that there is no correlation between pay and performance. It indicates that as one of the key control mechanisms, the remuneration policy does not contribute to board effectiveness. We have also used interview data from individuals in Chinese red-chips to show the diverse option on directors’ pay, current remuneration policy and its implementation. Undeniably, the current executive remuneration system in SOEs has certain advantages, such as protecting inside information from competitor plagiarism, which is sufficient encouragement for top executives. However, from the view of fairness and justice, the system requires more transparency to ensure that the stakeholders’ legitimate interests are protected. References Anderson, J. B. 1990. Compensating your overseas executives, part 2: Europe in 1992. Compensation and Benefits Review, 22, 25–36. Atkinson, J. M. and Heritage, J. 1984. Structures of Social Action: Studies in Conversation Analysis. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. Atkinson, R. and Flint, J. 2001. Accessing hidden and hard-to-reach populations: snowball research strategies. Social Research Update, 28, 93–108. Atkinson, R. and Flint, J. 2004. Snowball sampling. In: Lewis-beck, M.S., Bryman, A. and Liao, T.F. (eds) Encyclopedia of Social Science Research Methods. London, Sage. Bebchuk, L. A. and Fried, J. M. 2003. Executive compensation as an agency problem. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17, 71–92. Bebchuk, L. A. and Fried, J. M. 2005. Executive compensation at Fannie Mae: a case study of perverse incentives, nonperformance pay, and camouflage. Journal of Corporation Law, 30, 807–822. 92 Jessica Hong Yang and Nada K. Kakabadse Bebchuk, L. A. and Spamann, H. 2010. Regulating bankers’ pay. Georgetown Law Journal, 98, 247–287. Bebchuk, L. A. and Weisbach, M.S. 2010. The state of corporate governance research. Review of Financial Studies, 23, 939–961. Bebchuk, L.A., Cohen, A. and Spamann, H. 2010. The wages of failure: executive compensation at Bear Stearns and Lehman 2000–2008. Yale Journal on Regulation, 27, 257–282. Beltratti, A. and Stulz, R. M. 2009. Why Did Some Banks Perform Better during the Credit Crisis? A Cross-country Study of the Impact of Governance and Regulation. Cambridge, National Bureau of Economic Research. Berle, A. A. and Means, G. C. 1932. The Modern Corporation and Private Property. New York, Harcourt Brace. Buck, T., Liu, X. and Skovoroda, R. 2008. Top executive pay and firm performance in China. Journal of International Business Studies, 39, 833–850. Cao, J., Lemmon, M.L., Pan, X., Qian, M. and Tian, G. G. 2011. Political Promotion, CEO Incentives, and the Relationship between Pay and Performance. SSRN eLibrary. Cen, F. 2011. A study about the status of executive remuneration in commercial banks in China. Shanxi Financial and Economics Journal, 10, 35–36. Chen, J. J., Liu, X. and Li, W. 2010. The effect of insider control and global benchmarks on Chinese executive compensation. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 18, 107–123. Chen, Y. B. 2011. Listed banks ‘ decisions on willingness to pay incentives and executive compensation: an empirical analysis. Statistics and Decision Journal, 7, 142–144. Cheng, G. L. 2009. International comparisons of executive compensation system of commercial banks. Financial Theory and Practice Journal, 33, 240–270. Child, J. 1994. Management in China during the Age of Reform. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. Choe, C., Tian, G.Y. and Yin, X. 2009. Managerial Power, Stock-Based Compensation, and Firm Performance: Theory and Evidence. SSRN eLibrary. Conyon, M.J., Peck, S.I., Read, L.E and Sadler, G. V. 2000. The structure of executive compensation contracts: UK evidence. Long Range Planning, 33, 478–503. Culpepper, J. and Gilbert, T.T. 1999. Evidence and ethics. Lancet, 353, 829–831. Denzin, N.K. 1989. Interpretive Interactions. Newbury Park, CA, Sage. Dowling, P. J. and Schuler, R. S. 1990. International Dimensions of Human Resource Management. Boston, MA, PWS-Kent. Dowling, P. J. and Welch, D. 2004. International Human Resource Management: Managing People in a Multinational Context. London, Thomson Learning. Easterby-Smith, M., Malina, D. and Lu, Y. 1995. How culture sensitive is HRM? A comparative analysis of practice in Chinese and UK companies. The International Journal of Human Resource Management, 6, 31–59. Erkens, D.H., Hung, M. and Matos, P. P. 2012. Corporate governance in the 2007–2008 financial crisis: evidence from financial institutions worldwide. Journal of Corporate Finance, 18, 389–411. Ewick, P. and Silbey, S. S. 1998. The Common Place of Law: Stories from Everyday Life. Chicago, University of Chicago Press. Faugier, J. and Sargeant, M. 1997. Sampling hard to reach population. Journal of Advanced Nursing, 26, 790–797. How Chinese Styled Executive Remuneration Works 93 Firth, M., Fung, P.M. Y. and Rui, O. M. 2005. Corporate performance and CEO compensation in China. Journal of Corporate Finance, 12, 693–714. Glover, L. and Siu, N. 2000. The human resource barriers to managing quality in China. The International Journal of Human Resource Management, 11, 867–882. Goodall, K. and Warner, M. 1997. Human resources in sino-foreign joint ventures: selected case studies in Shanghai compared with Beijing. The International Journal of Human Resource Management, 8, 569–593. Hamill, J. 1989. Expatriate policies in British multinationals. Journal of General Management, 14, 18–33. Holmstrom, B. 1979. Moral hazard and observability. The Bell Journal of Economics, 10, 74–91. Huo, Y. P. and Von Glinow, M.A. 1995. On transplanting human resource practices to China: a culture-driven approach. International Journal of Manpower, 16, 3–15. John, T. A. and John, K. 1993. Top-management compensation and capital structure. The Journal of Finance, 48, 949–974. Johnson, M., Porter, F. and Shackell, M. B. 1997. Stakeholder Pressure and the Structure of Executive Compensation. SSRN eLibrary. Ju, J. W. 2012. How to design the executive remuneration in SOEs? http://finance. people.com.cn/GB/18008397.html, retrieved 18th October 2012. Kaplan, C.D., Korf, D. and Sterk, C. 1987. Temporal and social context of heroinusing populations: an illustration of the snowball sampling technique. Journal of Nervous Mental Disorders, 175, 566–574. Kato, T. and Long, C. 2006a. CEO turnover, firm performance, and enterprise reform in China: Evidence from micro data. Journal of Comparative Economics, 34, 796–817. Kato, T. and Long, C. 2006b. Executive compensation, firm performance, and corporate governance in China: evidence from firms listed in the Shanghai and Shenzhen Stock Exchanges. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 54, 945–983. Lee, T. A. 2006. Financial Reporting and Corporate Governance. Chichester, UK, John Wiley and Sons Ltd. Liu, Q. 2005. Corporate Governance in China: Current Practices, Economic Effects and Institutional Determinants. Hong Kong Institute of Economics and Business Strategy Working Paper. Liu, Q., Luo, W. and Xu, N. 2011. Political Motivation, Over-investment and Firm Performance. Peking University. Logger, E., Vinke, R. and Kluytmans, F. 1995. Compensation and appraisal in an international perspective. In: Harzing, A. and Ruysseveldt, J. (eds) International Human Resource Management. London, Sage. Madera, S.A. and Sun, L. 2005. International Listing Induced Improvements in Corporate Governance Practices: The Case of China Mobile (Hong Kong). Centre for Financial and Management Studies. Mallin, C.A. 2007. Corporate Governance. New York, Oxford University Press. Megginson, W. and Netter, J. 2001. From state to market: a survey of empirical studies on privatization. Journal of Economic Literature, 39, 321–389. Mehran, H. 1995. Executive compensation structure, ownership, and firm performance. Journal of Financial Economics, 38, 163. Michael, W. 1997. Corporate Governance: Responsibilities, Risks and Remuneration. Chichester, UK, John Wiley and Sons Ltd. 94 Jessica Hong Yang and Nada K. Kakabadse Mirrlees, J. 1976. The optimal structure of incentives and authority within an organization. The Bell Journal of Economics, 7, 105–131. Mitsuhashi, H., Park, H.J., Wright, P.M. and Chua, R. S. 2000. ‘Line and HR executives’ perceptions of HR effectiveness in firms in the People’s Republic of China. The International Journal of Human Resource Management, 11, 197–216. Murphy, K.J. 1985. Corporate performance and managerial remuneration: an empirical analysis. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 7, 11–42. Nelson, J. and Reeder, J. 1985. Labour relations in China. California Management Review, 27, 13–32. Rampling, P.N., Eddie, I. A. and Liu, J. 2011. Executive Remuneration in China: A Literature Review. SSRN eLibrary. Reynolds, C. 1988. Cost-effective compensation of expatriates. Topics in Total Compensation, 2, 319–326. Rhodes, W., Kling, R. and Johnston, P. 2004. A model-based approach for estimating prevalence of hard to reach populations. http://www.abtassoc.com/ reports/Final_Methodology_surveying_htr_populations.pdf. Schmidt, D. 2009. The financial crisis and its impact on China. China Analysis, 67, 1–4. Shen, J. and Edwards, V. 2006. International Human Resource Management in Chinese Multinationals. London, Routledge. Sun, S., Zhao, X. and Yang, H. 2010. Executive compensation in Asia: a critical review and outlook. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 27, 775. Tung, F. 2010. Pay for Banker Performance: Structuring Executive Compensation for Risk Regulation. SSRN eLibrary. Wang, Z. M. 1990. Human resource management in China, recent trends. In: PIEPER, R. (ed.) Human Resource Management: An International Comparison. Berlin, Germany, Walter de Gruyter. Weisbach, M.S. 2007. Optimal executive compensation versus managerial power: a review of Lucian Bebchuk and Jesse Fried’s pay without performance: the unfulfilled promise of executive compensation. Journal of Economic Literature, XLV, 419–428. Ye, X.N. 2012. Market review: how to deduct the whopping salary of executives in SOEs in China. http://finance.people.com.cn/GB/17537499.html, retrieved 23 June 2012. Zhao, C.X. 2011. Economic analysis of controlling executive compensation of state-owned enterprises. Journal of Guangxi University of Finance and Economics, 24, 109–112. Zhu, J.H. and Dowling, P.J. 1994. The impact of economic system upon HRM practices in China. Human Resource Planning, 17, 1–21. 4 The Secret to Boards in Reinventing Themselves Ouarda Dsouli, Nadeem Khan and Nada K. Kakabadse We almost invariably spend more time living with the consequences of our decisions than we do in making them. Pfeffer (1992: 19) After centuries of established corporate governance practice and a variety of national (Sarbanes-Oxley Act, 2002; UK Codes of Corporate Governance, 1992–2010; Viénot Reports, 1995–99, 2000) and international codes of good corporate governance practices (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, 1999, 2004) it seems that either the regulations are not working or that simply a few powerful elites, such as the Bilderberg group, define corporate faith and the parameters of corporate governance design and debate (Richardson et al., 2011). Thus, it appears that we are back to where we started as captured by Argenti’s (1976) six principal symptoms for corporate collapses: one-man rule; non-participative board; imbalanced management top team; lack of management depth; a weak financial function; and a combined chairperson/CEO role. Modern transnational corporation (TNC) power ranks effectively alongside national governments (Anderson and Cavanagh, 2000). Unregulated and unaccountable behaviour of players within these TNCs, as well as non-democratically elected leaders, continue to have an enormous impact on people’s lives worldwide. This is exemplified by unprecedented events such as the sub-prime mortgage crisis which imploded into the global financial crisis and the long-term recession. Efforts to restore corporate trust such as the Dodd–Frank Wall Street Reform and the Consumer Protection Act of 2010 in the United States, and revisions to the UK Code of Corporate Governance in 2010 are not new. Since the early 1970s stakeholders’ such as employees, suppliers, 95 96 Ouarda Dsouli et al. customers and local communities in the United States and UK started respectively questioning the large corporation’s influence on society (Tricker, 2012). What is often questionable these days is the government response to cope with the sovereign debt crisis in Europe, increasing unemployment rates across Western developed nations, among other concerns (Castells, 2012). Hence, the root cause lies beyond any one TNC and country’s capabilities to that of a massively complex network of TNCs (Vitali et al., 2011) and local governments with cross-holding shares, multiple directorships and excessive cross-leveraged funding, where the dynamics and ever-changing operational context is far beyond single control. In the face of globalisation, TNC boards that operate in multiple cultures, jurisdictions and currencies, are faced with various challenges and increasing responsibilities, but at the same time they are wielding enormous power (Tricker, 2012). This brings the board responsibilities and effectiveness to the forefront of the governance debate. Whilst the world economy is readjusting itself, new economic powers are emerging (Global Competiveness Report, 2012) and business executives still perceive globalisation as positive (IMD, 2012). Boards, on the other hand, are very resistant to becoming more global (Gillies and Dickinson, 1999; Staples, 2007). Boards hardily appoint non-nationals (Staples, 2007) and females (Zahidi, 2012), which suggests a lack of board diversity and integrity (Jensen, 2012). The issue of leadership misbehaviours persistently occupies the front pages of media outlets. The debate for the separation of board leaderships in the United States and the issue of compensation remain unresolved (Conyon et al., 2011; Pedersen & Partners, 2012; Tonello, 2012). In the current economic situation where there is increasing pressure for sustainable firms, boards are in need of leaders with a long-term vision and innovative skills. This could bring confidence back to the system and make the corporate sector of the economy more sustainable, widely respected, integrated with society and less interrupted. The rich and complex environment in which the corporation operates today and the challenges that boards face suggests that there is the need for a new framework. This framework should guide the power of the board towards reinventing itself in order to support the corporate firm’s ability to be competitively renewable for the longer term. The holistic framework will need to include board diversity, leadership, cultural dynamics and its capability to be sustainably innovative for the future. Therefore, this chapter examines each of these constituents and present a new conceptual and practically applicable framework in The Secret to Boards in Reinventing Themselves 97 support of making the board work effectively. We will test the proposed framework among the most sustainably recognised firms in the world to examine to what extent the boards of these corporations are and will be effective in reinventing themselves for the next 20–40 years. Board diversity Scholarly contributions to the composition of board diversity have explored visible factors (gender; age; ethnicity) and invisible characteristics (education; values; personality; skills) over the years (Milliken and Martins, 1996; Petersen, 2000; Watson et al., 1998). At a time when corporate openness is fast becoming a necessity (Rivas, 2012) rather than a competitive advantage (Porter, 1985), the endogenous institution of boards (Hermalin and Weisbach, 2003) remains reluctant to diversify (Harvey Nash, 2012). Gender balance Demographically, the most noticeable change in Western corporations has been the introduction of legislation in countries such as Norway (2004), Spain (2008) and France (2011), inducing quotas for female representation within boards (Ahern and Dittmar, 2012; Davies Report, 2011). However, Zahidi (2012) maintains that corporate gender equality remains a myth. This is not a global phenomenon and varies significantly from country to country as Table 4.1 indicates. The extant literature on positive effects of female representation support the motive for legislation (Carter et al., 2003; Erkut et al., 2008; Schwartz-Ziv, 2012; Shrader et al., 1997), whereby there may be better strategic input, leadership style and balanced decision making (Catalyst, 1995). However, we should recognise this as distinct from role modelling and stakeholder satisfaction motives, which infer a token gesture in social representation (Scherer, 1997). In Table 4.1, the Scandinavian boards lead followed by European and American boards, whilst South Africa reflects greater gender diverse than Germany and France. The rest of the world has yet to advance gender balance representation. Importantly, we reinforce that in a merit-based democracy culture should not dictate gender. The impact of gender representation within boards has been positive in America (Erhardt et al., 2003) whilst studies in Denmark suggest no correlation to firm performance (Rose, 2007). It may be that the resource employment pool (Erhardt et al., 2003) is different in Denmark or that the invisible required attributes of females, which include education and 7.7% 7.5% Belgium Austria Denmark Finland Sweden Norway 13.9% 24.5% 27.3% 40.1% Scandinavia Source: Catalyst (2012); GMI Ratings (2012a). 9.3% 11.2% Germany 8.7% 12.7% France Switzerland 14.0% Netherland Spain 27% UK Central Europe Canada US 10.3% 16.1% North America Table 4.1 Females on boards across continents Brazil Mexico 5.1% 6.8% South America Asia Japan Indonesia India China South Africa 15.8% Hong Kong Africa 9% 8.5% 5.3% 4.5% 0.9% Australia 8.4% Australia The Secret to Boards in Reinventing Themselves 99 appropriate experience, are already embedded within the Scandinavian education systems. Another factor in this case, may be the positive influence of female-friendly governance systems within Norway, Sweden and Denmark that offer higher order social benefits and employment regulation for family life planning. The ongoing legal issue in Europe of whether appointment based on gender is fair (BBC, 2012), argues for merit-based appointments that recognise skill sets and professional experience. The research suggests that whilst gender equality may be positive, there is a need for highly skilled and educated females before quotas are legislatively imposed. At the same time, the imposition (Reding, 2011) may over time foster more highly educated female role models and stakeholders (Catalyst, 1995) for the next generation. An earlier adopter of legislation in 2004, Norway is recognised in board circles for the phenomenon of ‘golden skirts’. This refers to a group of 70 female board members who are sitting on multiple boards to meet the quota requirements (Vinnicombe and Sealy, 2012). Beyond Norway, Kaczmarek et al. (2012) note that multiple directorships typically attract regulators’ attention in the UK as the Walker Report (2009) outlines. In this respect, the US Securities Exchange Commission requirement Regulation S-K, Item 407 (c) advocates increased transparency as part of ethical board recruitment processes (Schwartz-Ziv, 2012). In contrast to the mainstream literature which links board composition to firm performance (Ahern and Dittmar, 2012; Erhardt et al., 2003), the alternative perspective (Hermalin and Weisbach, 2003) posits that we should understand boards based on their actions and the situation that the firm faces. In this regard, Schwartz-Ziv’s unique lens (2012) to inside-the-black box of the boardroom (Daily et al., 2003; Leblanc, 2004) indicates that men and women have different management and supervisory qualities. Women are more communicative, active participants and prefer small networks, whereas men are more likely to take action individually and decisively. In this respect, maledominated boardrooms lack the necessary holistic qualities to promote high-performing board teams (Payne et al., 2009; Sonnenfeld, 2002). Age Another aspect of diversity is age. The average age of board members is over 60 (Table 4.2). This may reflect a need for life experience inadvance of a major responsible role or alternatively, it may suggest that following retirement, directorships offer better work–life balance and flexibility to members. The board re-election process offers short-term contracts (three mandates of three years each in the UK; eight years in 100 Ouarda Dsouli et al. Table 4.2 Average age of boards EU UK Spain France Italy Average age of board members 63 59 59 60 61 United States Canada 64 66 India 65 Source: Compiled by the authors from Spencer Stuart (2011b,c, 2012a,c). the United States; and four years in France) where in some cases, retirement age policies for directors are beyond 70 (72 in the United States; 70 in Spain). Thus, the old boys’ network (Edling et al., 2012) may be looking after each other and constraining diversity. In Table 4.2, the remarkably close range across the countries implies that this may be a global phenomenon. It is the advanced nations such as the UK and France that seem to have slightly lower average ages by a small margin. Some scholarly research suggests that age brings experiential benefits that translate into firm performance (Faleye, 2007). Other studies highlight beneficial advantages of external networks and multidirectorships in support of firm performance (Boyd, 1990; McDonald et al., 2008; Mizruchi, 1996). These factors become more prominent in crisis situations (Platt and Platt, 2012). The question arises that within the boardroom, should individual members be exploiting these networks in this way, rather than engaging transparent official channels for project management or skill enhancement for the firm? The end outcome seems to be that society suffers the longer-term consequences of inadequate knowledge or deficient structures (Enron, Newscorp, BP, BBC). Further, it seems odd that the older generation are making decisions without the input of the generation that will witness the longerterm impact of these decisions. Thus, the holistic lens questions this barrier where age should offer benefit of guidance and smooth transition to wider stakeholders. If a system of governance allows a young adult to form a company and operate it as an entrepreneur, then why is the boardroom also not open to these skill sets? Ethnicity Erhardt et al. (2003) find a positive correlation between ethnicity and firm performance in America. However, the majority of directors are white males (Harvard Business Review, 2011; Rhode and Packel, 2010). Similarly, Brammer et al.’s study (2007) of 463 UK-based firms found only 0.2% non-white board representation. Whilst scholars have given The Secret to Boards in Reinventing Themselves 101 attention to gender equality from a female perspective (Terjesen et al., 2009), limited studies have pursued ethnicity as the leading gender issue (Marimuthu, 2008; Roberson and Park, 2007; Westphal and Milton, 2000), making it more so part of the wider diversity dialogue (age, gender, ethnicity). Ethnic minorities have been under represented on boards for years; however, change started taking place in the 1990s (Farrell and Hersch, 2005). In the 21st century, ethnic composition is influenced by the growth of developing countries TNCs competing with developed countries TNCs; home and host country factors; and an increasingly informed and mobile global talent pool. Therefore, ethnic diversity and minority representation have different meanings and interpretations in different societal contexts. The research reaffirms the school tie network social phenomenon (Brammer et al., 2007) where the corporate elites accept minorities with the right background and connections into the boardroom. The critical lens appreciates that American history is more open to the ‘American Dream’ (Obama, Oprah, Powell) in contrast to the older nations such as the UK, Germany, France, India, China and Russia. Beyond the West, the global lens must appreciate that an increasing number of the emerging corporations are from BRIC nations. For example, Indian-based multinational automotive manufacturing company Tata operates in 80 countries. The environments of Brazil, Russia, India and China are less capitalistic and are both population- and resource-rich (Global Sherpa, 2012). More importantly emerges the cultural context (Hofstede et al., 2010) where conducting business in informal networked environments requires a different approach to conducting business in advanced systemised environments (Yoshikawa, 2012). The systemisation of developing societies has to some extent been restricted and controlled due to political instability (Pakistan, Egypt, Syria, North Korea) or deeper cultural differences (Saudi Arabia, Iran, America, Russia) whereas governance systems remain diverse across global markets, impacting the values and skills of the overall talent pool. Generally, it is the elite classes of developing nations that eventually emerge into the talent pool of western corporate society. The pattern of rising emerging market corporations (EMCs) indicates that ethnic or cultural backgrounds have little or no influence on board performance. More interestingly we observe a reverse phenomenon where Chinese and Indian companies (Huawei, Mittal) are extending beyond borders into the European talent pool (Kanungo, 2012). In contrast, Western society uses the term ethnicity in the minority context to represent the dispersed or displaced communities. In this 102 Ouarda Dsouli et al. regard, it seems odd that the new generation of ethnic minorities in countries such as the UK, United States, France or Germany are becoming majorities. For example, in 2011, over 50% of secondary school pupils in Birmingham, England, are of ethnic origin. As a result, the talent pool is forced to reconsider its glass ceiling of ethnic diversity. Mattis (2000) identifies that boards need to represent the labour force and customers in order to best utilise human capital (Gregoric et al., 2009). Research suggests that ethnic representation contributes to creativity, ethical behaviour (Macfarlane et al., 2010) and internationalisation (Wang and Cliff, 2009). More importantly, homogenous boards can be harmful (Wellalage et al., 2012). In an interconnected environment, the patterns suggest that cross-cultural backgrounds are fast becoming a necessity for corporate survival of boards (Wellalage et al., 2012). Sri Lanka has for many years had 40% ethnic representation on boards compared with S&P 500, which had an ethnic representation of 9% in 2010 and 11% in 2009 (Wallalage et al., 2012). Similar to female representation, the diversity of corporate boardrooms diversity inclusive structures are likely to ethnically broaden in the near future. Internationalisation Advances in technology and transportation globally have enhanced the interconnected environment in which we live. Internationalisation of trade is impacting the boardroom. Staples’ study (2007) reports that in 2005, 75% of TNCs had at least one non-national board member, indicating a considerable improvement over the previous 11 years (36.3% in 1993) (Gillies and Dickinson, 1999). However, only 10% of these corporations are governed by a majority of non-national members (Staples, 2007). More interestingly, in the post global financial crisis (Knyght et al., 2011), European boards averaged 23% non-national directors, which is an increase of 11% from 2008 (Heidrick and Struggles, 2009). In 2012, CAC 40 French firms have 27% foreigners. Whilst the 106 Spanish firms, including the IBEX 35 firms, have 11.4% foreigners, the UK FTSE 150 companies had 33% foreigners in 2011 (Spencer Stuart, 2011a, 2012 a,b). Within the European Union (EU) cross-border trade will be relatively more common compared with larger single nation trading blocs such as the United States and China. The EU talent pool (human capital) will also be more open to travelling abroad. At the same time, the Indian BSE 100 has 7.3% and the US S&P 200 has 53% foreign directors (Spencer Stuart, 2011b, 2012c). However, boards’ national diversification remains an issue as appointed members remain largely European or North American in mutually beneficial capacities (Spencer Stuart, 2012b). The Secret to Boards in Reinventing Themselves 103 The results of a larger cross-sectional study of 20,000 plus firms operating in 98 countries (Miletkov et al., 2012) concludes that younger firms with larger international shareholders and significant foreign operations are more likely to have foreigners on their board than their counterparts. In addition, companies operating in countries with relatively lower human capital are more likely to have foreigners on their boards (Miletkov et al., 2012). However, interestingly, the results do not support a relationship between foreign director and firm performance. This seems to suggest that the new generation of corporations are looking beyond geographic borders for financing and market opportunities, whilst at the same time, the global talent pool is open for recruitment. Where talent is restricted, a corporation can import it to add value to the firm. Interestingly, there is a negative correlation between financial performance and internationalisation of boards for firms operating in developed market equity, higher educated and legislatively strong institutions (Miletkov et al., 2012). Board structures and invisible relationships The internationalisation of boards’ members is not randomly distributed, as the choice to recruit independent foreign board member depends on the firm size, its shareholders structure and the potential costs and benefits associated to this diversification (Rivas, 2010). Most recently, a longitudinal investigation of individual director attributes and degree of internationalisation of firms (US, European) suggests that a broader invisible backgrounds of CEOs’ education, experience and values facilitates internationalisation of the firm (Rivas, 2012). However, at the same time, many chairpersons are from within the firm’s home country. This may be a natural phenomenon or it may more likely be a political choice to maintain corporate control with home country advantage (Rivas, 2012) whilst gaining access to overseas markets. Whilst board independency has received much attention (84% S&P 500, 82% French CAC 40 and 93% FTSE 150 UK) (Spencer Stuart, 2011a, 2012b,c), skills diversification remains critical to board diversity. The fact that board appointments among males and females is to some extent influenced by the conscious or unconscious biases of the eminent board member’s individual (CEO, chairperson or simply independent director) political and/or academic experience (The Diversity Summit, 2012) does not necessarily mean that there is a penury of skills, but the appointment process is rather supportive of the informal elite networks (Davies Report, 2011). This is still, to some extent, influenced by whom you know rather than what you know (Kakabadse, 2011). 104 Ouarda Dsouli et al. Besides, board recruitment is to some extent an exercise of box ticking the skills matrix, which consists of demographics (age, race, gender). As such, with the passage of time, knowledge and board expertise (operational knowledge such as industry expertise, specialised knowledge of areas such as marketing, international business, technology, finance) become core competencies (vision, strategic thinking, accountability) (Gifford, 2012). The deeper issue arises that progressive board structures (in terms of new appointments) become director interlocking relationships (Chu, 2012) where board size can also vary from a few members up to larger boards with 30 plus members. Known for its benefits, namely increasing openness, innovation and board effectiveness, board diversity is currently a category in the skills matrix (Spencer Stuart, 2012d) to which companies need to conform in order to meet regulation. Board diversity needs to be an end in itself, rather than a criterion for appointment. To achieve board diversity, the board requires a rich complementarity of personal and professional skills, backgrounds and inclusion of male and females equally based on their merits regardless of their demographics and nationalities. Developing diversity requires the adoption of both a top-down and bottom-up approach to lead diversity at all levels and at all times. Board leadership Concerns about the separation of the CEO and chairperson role have been ongoing for the last two decades (Tonello, 2012). The combination of the two roles entails the CEO putting into practice their expertise and acting with all autonomy and determination (Davis et al., 1997). However, this unitary structure could be detrimental for business transparency. CEO/chairperson actions might go unmonitored which may further pave the way for scandal and corruption as exemplified by bankruptcies such as Enron, Bank Credit and Commercial International (BCCI), Polly Peck, Coloroll and Maxwell Publishing. As a remedy to the conflicts of interests, the separation of the role of chairman and CEO emerged (Brickley et al., 1997) and is supported by corporate governance codes in the UK (Cadbury Committee, 1992), Netherlands (Dutch Corporate Governance Code, 2008), Finland (Companies Act, 2006), Australia (IFSA Guidance Note No. 2.00, 1999) and South Africa (King III, 2009). Other countries also favour role segregation. Yet, the separation of the two roles remains a subject of preference as Table 4.3 illustrates. Two-tier Unitary Unitarya Two- tiera Germany Spain Belgium Austria Unitary Denmark Two-tier Finland a a Other structures possible. Source: Compiled by the authors from Pierce (2010) and Mallin (2010). Unitarya Netherland Two-tier structure a France UK Board South America Africa Brazil Two-tier Unitary Australia Australia Unitary Unitary Dual Asia Indonesia Dual Japan Dual India Unitarya Mexico Two-Tier South Africa China America Unitary US Scandinavia Unitarya Sweden Central Europe Table 4.3 Boards structures across regions 106 Ouarda Dsouli et al. The practice of splitting the two top corporate positions is widespread among most developed countries. For instance, in the UK, a number of firms have introduced the separation of CEO and chairperson positions. Only 11 out of the FTSE 350 firms have combined the role of CEO/chairperson (Grant Thornton, 2011). In France, although legislation allows for the split of roles (Viénot, 1999), 62.5% of the French companies still opt for unitary leadership where the ‘président directeur-général’ (PDG) runs both the board and the company (Spencer Stuart, 2012b). In contrast, within the United States, strong single corporate leadership has prevailed over the longer term (Brickley et al., 1997; Coombes and Wong, 2004). Currently 43% of the S&P 500 firms have separated the two roles. This is considerably high compared to 25% a decade ago (Spencer Stuart, 2012c). This percentage increases to 51% among the largest 1743 US firms (Forbes, 2012a). Thus, it seems that beyond the 2008 global financial crisis, the United States may be changing its corporate structures endogenously via choice towards a duality. Further to the reduction of the conflicts of interests (Brickley et al., 1997), GMI Ratings’ data for 180 North American mega corporations (2012) suggests that the separation of the two roles leads to the reduction of costs and reduction of the risk associated to the ESG (environmental, social and governance). This facilitates improved accountability, greater investor protection and transparency (GMI Ratings, 2012b). The arguments for and against role separation vary with respect to the increase of checks and balances, board independence, long-term vision and accountability (Coombes and Wong, 2004; DGA, 2004; Kakabadse et al., 2006) and yet the literature findings remain inconclusive. Dalton et al.’s (1998) and Dalton and Dalton’s (2011) studies find no influence of duality on firm performance. However, boards continue to adopt the recommendations and revisions of the UK Cadbury Committee Report (1992, 2010). It currently extends to 60 countries. The influence of deeper regulatory or cultural influences may be at play at national levels in unitary or dual preferences. However, the Global Competitiveness Report 2012–2013 (World Economic Forum, 2012) also ranks countries with unitary board structure as very effective (South Africa, Australia, Sweden and Finland). Aligned to the role separation, duality approach, the independence of leadership has received much importance (Katz, 2012). Subject to legislative regulations (Corporate Governance Code, A2.1, 2012), all UK chairpersons are preferred to have an independent role, whilst within the US S&P 500, 23% of firms maintain a dual board structure with independent chairpersons (Spencer Stuart, 2012c). The reliance on The Secret to Boards in Reinventing Themselves 107 independent board directors (chairperson) may provide a different or external perspective and a wider lens of industry or it may lead to a lack of experience and expertise at the top of the board (Lorsch, 2009). In this regard, the issue of multiple directorships further supports a closed networking culture. One the one hand, the CEO plays a very important role as the mediator between the management and the board, whilst also managing the business on a day-to-day basis. On the other hand, the chairperson’s role is more of a moderator between shareholders, other board committees’ members and the CEO, hence their skilfulness in managing board-sensitive relationships, individual egos and mitigating interpersonal collision in a complex and subtle way is crucial for effective boardroom dynamics (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2001). What transpires is the complementary nature of these roles, which is vital for realising full potential board performance. In this regard, what becomes more important is the trust and integrity of the people in these roles, which extends to independence of role; knowledge of industry; synergy with other board members (NEDs) within the formative context of boardroom politics (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2004). Similarly, an in-depth study of state-owned enterprises (SOEs) and public limited companies (PLCs) in New Zealand recommends focusing on human relationships and behaviours beyond structural set-ups. The key findings identify the chairperson as a crucial role and more interestingly, poor information diversity and poor director behaviour as detrimental to board effectiveness (Smith, 2010). President of the Eurogroup of euro zone finance ministers, JeanClaude Juncker has described the critical issue of board leadership compensation/incentivisation as ‘a social scourge’ (Hay Group, 2008). CEO compensation has continued to rise within the recessionary time period (Fernandes et al., 2010). Notwithstanding that the majority of people have lost their jobs, the top executive compensation of the largest 100 firms in the United States and Europe enjoyed an average rise of 6.5% per year during the last five years (Pedersen & Partners, 2012). Similarly, the banking bonuses scandals have continued in the UK, France, Germany and the United States (Fernandes et al., 2010; Treanor, 2012) where many private shareholders have lost huge amounts due to poor performance of firms (RBS, Barclays, Northern Rock). It seems odd that top executive pay increases on average twice as fast in comparison with managers and employees within the firm in both the short and long term, which research suggests is likely to continue into the future (Pedersen & Partners, 2012). 108 Ouarda Dsouli et al. The US executive pay is higher than it is in Europe. This is mainly due to the structuring of stock options as benefits (Conyon and Murphy, 2000; Fernandes et al., 2009). The difference in cash plus bonus compensation is only around 5% where the average is €1,294,000 in Europe compared with €1,352,000 in America. However, the stock options granted in Europe are lower at 1 million, whereas, in the United States one-third of the US 100 largest firms top executives were granted more than €1 million (Pedersen & Partners, 2012). Increasingly wider market competitiveness and limited availability of talent have contributed to European corporations’ adoption of an American-style bonus incentivised structure. In the United States, the evaluation of compensation packages is heavily linked to firm performance, whilst in Europe it extends to include benchmarking against industry peer groups (The Economist, 2008). There are also differences within Europe itself. Scandinavian and Netherland executives are paid less compared with counterparts in France, Belgium and UK (Fernandes et al., 2010). Most recently there have been regulatory and interventionist efforts to keep board compensations at a reasonable level in austerity-directed environments. However, globally, the trend among prosperous Asian and Gulf countries is to offer higher packages. The Asian board salaries have already surpassed European executive compensation in 2010 and forecasters expect typical remunerations to surpass that in the United States by 2013 (Mercer, 2011). The conflict of interest is that if board members are individually financially motivated, then protectionist networks and lack of transparency will persist in restricting interests of wider stakeholders and longer-term renewal. This posits an urgent need for reforming compensation structures of boards beyond elitism, in favour of transparent, accountable sustainable renewal. Complementary to experience, education and learning may facilitate open-minded values and enhanced knowledge within the boardroom. Leadership qualities and skills go beyond those of management. Leadership drives the flow of vision within the firm whilst positioning the firm in context of externalities. The charisma, confidence, approachability and integration of board members as individuals collectively create the leadership team. A study of Fortune 500 CEOs’ educational backgrounds found that 163 CEOs do not hold advanced degrees. Almost an equal number, 165, hold MBAs (Forbes, 2012b). Regardless of the educational qualification of the CEO, both groups contribute equally to shareholder median total revenue (Forbes, 2012b). The Secret to Boards in Reinventing Themselves 109 This suggests that CEOs have equal opportunities or that there are social strata ties of networks that informally feed the leadership process (Nguyen, 2012). Irrespective of experience and educational background, the turnover among the Fortune 500 and S&P 500 board members increased to 12.3% in 2011. This is almost the same as the 2008–2009 recession level of 12.7% (Crist Kolder Associates, 2011). Forbes (2009) estimates that 40% of new CEOs depart within 18 months and 64% leave within 4 years of their appointments. The associated costs to the firm are in the millions for small corporations and tens of millions for large corporations. A gap in succession planning for the CEO role and sensible transition for the firm remains elusive (Katz, 2012). The planned succession of chairperson role has also come under the spotlight in UK firms (Spencer Stuart, 2011a). This is most recently exemplified by the resignation of British Broadcasting Corporation’s (BBC) director general George Entwistle in 2012. He was in the job for 54 days and took a year’s salary of £1,000,000 following his resignation. The question arises as to how corporations negotiate these individual contracts and why the stories only emerge in crisis, beyond legal reprise and contractual obligations. The networking twist emerges that the new director general is receiving guidance from Rupert Murdoch’s son-in-law (The Spectator, 13 November 2012). The underlying reason for CEOs’ replacement is a failure to fit within the organisation’s cultural context and the rejection of, rather than a lack of competencies and capabilities (Forbes, 2009). The relationships and dynamics between board leadership, board members and their connectedness with internal organisation and alignment with external markets become critically important. Board leadership is a personal and cohesive fit within the organisation that impacts board performance. In either single or dual boards, appointments should seek a good fit with other board members and the firm’s cultural context. Leaders should be long-term visionaries (20 years plus) with a balance of practical skills and open-minded qualities to enhance holistic performance. The dual board structure offers independence of mind, which should avoid compromise due to multi-directorship interests. Incentivisation of leaders may be better structured in advance and linked to longer-term targets of achieving sustainability and innovating rather than short-term financial targets. Furthermore, leaders’ succession plans should be implanted to allow smooth transition. 110 Ouarda Dsouli et al. Cultural dynamics Researchers, through archival and survey data, have mainly studied board performance through three sets of variables: input (board size and composition); process (board meetings and fiduciary tasks); and output (organisation’s financial performance, reputation, etc.). Regardless of the research approach, the findings remain inconclusive (Bhagat and Bolton, 2008; Dalton and Dalton, 2011; Dalton et al., 1998; DeRue et al., 2009). More pressing is that board effectiveness research is lacking in true behavioural studies (Clarke, 1998), in understanding board cultural dynamics and politics (Huse, 2001), along with individual corporate organisational contextual studies (Pye and Pettigrew, 2005). Furthermore, the majority of studies that have investigated board performance do so through a single theoretical model of corporate governance (agency theory, Fama and Jensen, 1983; resource dependency theory, Pfeffer, 1972; Pfeffer and Salancik, 1978; stewardship theory, Donaldson, 1990; stakeholder theory, Blair, 1995; Freeman, 1984). In international markets the corporation is subject to country-specific conceptions of corporate purpose (Hofstede et al., 2010). The expectation of how the corporation achieves its objectives follows along the line of ‘concessionist’ and ‘communitarian’ thinking. ‘Concessionist’ thinking environments emphasise maximisation of shareholder value as a primary board goal (Monks and Minow, 2004). The prominent developed nations that reflect this approach are Anglo-American capitalistic countries such as the United States, UK, Australia and Canada. Some developing countries moving in this direction include Brazil, India, Korea and Malaysia. Irrespective of rising global social awareness during the 1990s, exemplified in the emergence of corporate social responsibility (CSR) reporting, the Dow Jones Sustainability Index and the FTSE4Good Index, along with philanthropic practices (Porter and Kramer, 2011), the shared corporate purpose among the Anglo-American countries remains intact – ‘maximising shareholders’ value’ (Friedman, 1970). The ‘communitarian’ approach prioritises the interests of all stakeholders, of which shareholders are an important group among the wider group of employees, creditors, suppliers, environment and other constituents as the ultimate goal of the corporation (Freeman, 1984; Freeman et al., 2010; Monk and Minow, 2004). The contexts for this more inclusive approach include Continental Europe, Scandinavia, Japan and some developing nations such as South Africa. Consequently, the role of board of directors varies from one country to another (Pierce, 2011). The Secret to Boards in Reinventing Themselves 111 In addition to national cultural contexts, prevailing industry and sector conditions or politically driven governance regulatory forces influence the boardroom decisions at the macro level. At the micro level, the firm adopts a position within the marketplace engaging internal controllable mechanisms which include resources, skills, teamwork and unique capabilities. The combination of these cultural dynamics defines corporate organisational lifecycle stages, ownership patterns and the board dynamics (Luo, 2007; Minichilli et al., 2012; Pye and Pettigrew, 2005). Together these reflect the philosophy, values and morals that shape the company’s culture and more specifically, the culture and communication within and beyond the boardroom. This makes board connectedness the bedrock for corporate sustainability (Deal and Kennedy, 1982; Nadler, 2004). This very much depends on boards’ member capabilities, character, personality and their interpersonal dynamic synergies (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2001; Pierce, 2011). Whatever perspective one takes as a starting point for assessing board performance (macro; micro determinants), it is important to acknowledge that the board evolves over time and so it is the culture and characteristics of boardroom dynamics among its members that are continuously changing. In parallel to the academic classical board performance studies (Sonnenfeld, 2002) is the practice of board evaluation (Long, 2006). The rationale for this has emerged from the wider international debate concerning corporate governance, board performance and director professionalism (Ingley and Van Der Walt, 2002; Van Der Walt and Ingley, 2003). Over time, boards have come under increasing pressure to do more than just fulfil their fiduciary duties. More importantly, academics have concluded that existing explanations of board effectiveness, which include board structure and independence of directors have little or no explanatory or predictive capacities (Tricker, 2009). Statistics from 2007 revealed that 75% of the UK FTSE 350 boards were evaluated externally by committees at least every three years (UK Corporate Governance Code, 2010). Comparatively, this practice was less popular within North American (only 45%) and Japanese firms (30%) (Korn-Ferry, 2007). However, independent board evaluation has become a regulatory requirement in countries such as the UK (2010), Australia (2010), France (2008) and Belgium (2009). The current issues are whether self-evaluation or independent evaluations are actually facilitating transparency and whether boards fully understand the effectiveness of these evaluations? The current problem is that even independent evaluation is not truly independent. Dutra (2012) asks, ‘Who really gets to evaluate 112 Ouarda Dsouli et al. boards? Is it directors evaluating themselves and to what extent is this credible?’ The success of boards’ cultural dynamics may elevate when individual character and behaviour aligns between board members in connection with internal, industry, national and global influences from which they can extract value. In the current business climate, corporate global connectedness is at its highest level; however, many companies fail to align the internal and external cultural contexts within their board as the failure of Kodak exemplifies (Forbes, 2012c). Similarly, the synergies between owners, board members and their senior management require special attention as executives might manipulate and filter the information. One senior manager at Xerox explains, ‘I was never allowed to present to the board unless things were perfect … you could only go in with good news. Everything was prettied up’ (Charan and Useem, 2002). The Global Competitiveness Report (2012) ranks board efficacy and the results show that the leading country is South Africa, which ranks first out of 144 countries followed by New Zealand and Singapore. Australia ranks fourth out of 144 countries, whilst the Scandinavian countries rank higher than their European, North American, Asian and South American counterparts in decreasing order. Board committees have also emerged to monitor agent misbehaviour and protect the stakeholders, including the shareholders. For instance, remuneration and nomination committees have developed for the purpose of eradicating higher CEO compensation and for more transparency of the recruitment process, mainly after the corporate scandals (Higgs Report, 2003). Similarly, firms embraced audit and CSR or ethics committees to gain the minority shareholders’ and stakeholders’ credibility. Currently, boards committees are of a great importance to the overall board performance. Therefore, we suggest that board efficiency needs to determine board culture dynamics in balancing the synergies between board directors (independent and executives), CEO interrelationship and other board committees. Also, the decisional corporate body should know the firm inside out, namely, the boards need to have profound understanding of the corporate organisational context (understanding corporate), and its external environment knowledge (country culture and perception of corporate role ‘purpose’, and a deep understanding of industry and peers). Most importantly, boards’ directors need to act like owners in a sense where they have specific roles in driving the corporate strategy and risk management decisions (Wong, 2011). The Secret to Boards in Reinventing Themselves 113 Sustainable jugaad innovation In an increasingly populated world, globally expected to exceed 9 billion by 2050 (United Nations, 2009) the current major boom is in urbanised living. Whilst currently 50% of world population are in cities, statistics indicate that 7 out of 10 people will live in cities by 2050 (World Health Organization and United Nations Habitat, 2012). In meeting the demands of our rising megacities, we seem to be pushing the limits of our naturally available resources (energy, water and commodities) and we witness patterns of rising natural disasters, such as the Indian Ocean tsunami of 2004, the 2010 earthquake in Haiti and the 2011 tsunami in Japan. The combined impact of population rise, scarcity of resources and patterns of natural disasters are a cry for corporations to behave in a more ‘green’ and sustainable manner reflecting the ecological pressures on our planet. At the same time, the economic impact on markets and consumers of the global financial crisis of 2008 seems to be one of longterm recession. This leaves firms with contracted markets, consumers with limited spending and governments with reduced fiscal contributions. Hence, corporations are faced with a new consumer trend which has shifted from a demand for high quality over engineered goods to products /services that are more eco-friendly and reasonably priced for functionality (Radjou et al. 2012). The combination of a need for innovation and growth pressure for sustainability suggest that corporations should engage in jugaad innovation as a long-term vision. Whilst some successful corporations, such as Renault-Nissan, GE, Procter & Gamble, PepsiCo and Siemens are excellent examples of companies that have embraced jugaad innovation, the term is still nascent for the majority (Radjou et al., 2012). A Hindi word, jugaad means a creative idea or a quick alternative way of solving or fixing problems. India has practiced jugaad for many centuries. However, only recently has Western management literature popularised this concept. Larger corporations and developed nations are looking at this notion and are starting to introduce it into their environments and cultures. At the heart of this concept is the ability to innovate cost-effectively and sustainably under severe resource constraints (Radjou et al., 2012). We often associate the concept with innovations such as the nanocar at $2000, the Aakash Tablet PC at $50, the 1 cent /minute mobile phone call and the $25 water purifier. Whilst the simplest interpretation is ‘creative improvisation’, the deeper understanding appreciates that jugaad requires knowledge and wisdom and is really more of a mindset. Radjou et al. (2012) have 114 Ouarda Dsouli et al. proposed four principles for the application of jugaad within Western corporations. These are: 1. Thrift not waste – Tackle scarcity of all forms resources. Do More With Less 2. Inclusion, not exclusion – Enterpreneurial organisations need to put inclusiveness into practise by tightly connecting with, and harnessing the growing diversity that permeates their communites of costomers, employees and partners. Keep it Simple 3. Bottom-up Partipation,not top-down command and control – Collaboration. CEOs who tend to act as conductors must learn to facilitate collaborative improvisation just as jazz band players do. Follow your Heart 4. Flexible thinking and action, not linear planning – Flexibility in thinking and action jugaadpracticing firms are highly adaptable as they aren’t wedded to any single business model and pursue multiple options at any time. Think and Act Flexibly Source: Complied from Radjou et al. (2012). Global problems contextualised in India India is one of the BRIC nations. It is the seventh largest nation in the world by landmass (3.2 million sq. km) and has a population of 1.2 billion people (Asian History, 2012), giving it a population density/ landmass of 375. This makes the current global population (7 billion) to landmass (150 million sq. km) concern less of a problem (population density/landmass of 46.6). More interestingly, the difference is that India is one of the fastest growing economies with an average growth rate of 5.8% over the last two decades and it has the world’s second largest labour force with 487 million workers. Since 1985, 430 million people have come out of poverty. There are still fundamental problems. For example, 46% of children under three suffer malnutrition and India still has the largest concentration of people living on less than $1.25 a day. However, economic indicators show that India will overtake China as the most populous country in the world and PricewaterhouseCoopers (2011) has forecasted that it will overtake the United States in terms of gross domestic product (GDP) and purchase power parity (PPP) by 2045. The Secret to Boards in Reinventing Themselves 115 Economists expect the growth rate to remain at 8% over the next four decades. India is already the largest democracy in the world and by 2050 it will be the world’s fastest growing economy. If we consider the above facts and extend them to the global scenario, it reflects that jugaad may have huge potential on a larger scale. Importantly, jugaad is a bottom-up approach where even the CEO must embrace this mindset. From the concept of jugaad, the term ‘frugal engineering’ has emerged. Renault-Nissan CEO Carlos Ghohosn coined the term in 2006 after seeing Indian engineers in action. Over the last six years, Renault-Nissan has applied this term in the development of electric cars, and other companies have gradually acknowledged it more as a social phenomenon. Most recently, Prahalad’s (2005) analysis of the bottom of the pyramid questions why for the last 50 years the World Bank has not been able to solve the poverty problem. At the same time, new base of the pyramid (BoP) solutions are fast emerging. In view of the holistic global population and resources problem forecasted into the future and the potential solution in the form of sustainable jugaad innovation, we propose that corporate boards receive jugaad innovation training and practice this within their organisations. Sustainable jugaad board effectiveness requires open-minded top management to connect with base level players and connect sustainable innovation with capital for effective solutions. Critical to this is trustworthy open relationships, mutual respect and understanding, deeper interconnectedness and amazing results. In the resource-constrained environment Renault-Nissan’s CEO proposes that the way forward is to: 1. Create ‘good enough’ products that deliver high value for money; 2. Foster healthy rivalry among global R&D teams; 3. Tap partners in emerging markets who excel at innovating more with less; and 4. Send your top executives to emerging markets to cultivate the jugaad mindset. As well as engaging customers and developing innovation partnership (IBM, 2012), sustainable jugaad innovation requires empowering employees and mobilising knowledge collectively. Sustainable jugaad innovation needs to be top priority for boards to drive the corporation forward with a long-term evolving vision in support of the societies of 2050. Yet, collaborative partnerships beyond the firms and change of mind set within the firm must merge at board 116 Ouarda Dsouli et al. level. Then, the base of the pyramid will open up a whole new world of opportunities. Learning from the literature findings The literature suggests that board diversity presides in board demographics, namely, age, gender and ethnic origins. Regulation mainly drives the fact that currently boards focus on gender equality. Thus, in the future we might see regulations that will foster age equality and nationality balance as the majority of Western nations are ageing and businesses are increasingly global. Currently, there is lack of transparency in the appointment process. Whilst age equals higher experience, which has its benefits, it still seems odd that established boards are not open to the younger talent pool. This may be why people opt for the entrepreneurial route instead. Take, for example, the English business magnates Richard Branson and Alan Sugar. Whilst leadership compensation and separation of ownership still top the list of issues within leadership, new concerns are emerging, namely, succession as boards increasingly suffer from high CEO turnovers. In this respect, leadership education and connectedness becomes greatly important for leaders’ appointment. The literature, however, has paid little attention to cultural dynamics in a country and organisational context, along with the boards’ interpersonal skills. Similarly, board culture dynamics, and the emergent issues of sustainability require greater board attention and investment in sustainable jugaad innovation to thrive within the next 50 years. Hence, this chapter tackles the main deficiencies within the boards through proposing a framework for boards to reinvent themselves. Boards reinventing themselves framework Building on ‘the secret to boards in reinventing themselves’, we rely simply on their ability to balance the four elements of leadership, diversity, cultural dynamics and sustainable jugaad innovation (see Figure 4.1). These factors determine board relationships and dynamics. The pressures from within the company and from the firm’s macroeconomic environment necessitate management and boards to sustainably innovative to drive business for the next 50 years. Balancing the board effectiveness scoreboard In Table 4.4 we provide a weighting that translates into a 12-point evaluative scoreboard where diversity has a maximum possible 3 points; The Secret to Boards in Reinventing Themselves External Environment Shareholders 117 Society Firm Boards Sustainability Innovation 1. Diversity 2. Leadership 3. Culture dynamics 4. Jugaad Sustainable Innovation Sustainability Innovation CEO Management Figure 4.1 How to make boards work Source: Compiled by the authors. leadership has a maximum possible 5 points; cultural dynamics has a maximum possible 2 points; and jugaad effectiveness has a maximum possible 2 points. Emerging from the literature review, we have identified the criteria for awarding points as Table 4.4 illustrates. The higher the board scores, the more balanced the board. Testing the model To validate our framework we have used it to analyse a small selection of 16 firms from within the ‘Global 100: World leaders in sustainability’ list. This corporate sustainability list captures the data of firms with more than $2 billion market capitalisation and ranks them based on disclosed information using key performance indicators (KPIs). This annually produced list is available at http://www.global100.org/. We reduced the list of 100 companies by selecting corporations older than 50 years and then dividing the firms into six regions: Scandinavia, Europe, Africa, Central and South America, North America, and Asia (Figure 4.2). Where there was more than one country within the region we included the oldest corporation from each country in our sample. This left us with 16 firms against which to test our framework (Table 4.5). Our sample companies belong to the global 100 most sustainable corporations in the world. The criteria of this global 100 list consists of key performance indicators which assess firms’ environmental effects such as energy, carbon, water, waste productivity and firm’s capacity 118 Ouarda Dsouli et al. Table 4.4 Characteristics for making boards work Characteristic Evaluation criteria Measure Points 1 Board diversity Female gender Balance Internationalisation Above 30% Mix of nationalities Or (Foreign board members that are not American or European) Board members under the age of 40 1 Point 1/2 Point (1 Point) 1 Point Age diversification 2 Board leadership Leadership structure Unitary boards with – Board independence board independency between 50–70% Or (Dual boards with board independency between 25 and 50%) Leadership Average board qualification – member education 2 average board qualifications+1 leader education (CEO/Chairman) holding at least 3 qualifications Or (Average board member education 2 qualifications+1 leader, holding more than 3 qualifications and/ or board comprise nonqualified members) Leadership One/both leaders are connectedness connected to more than 200 individuals and sitting on no more than 3 boards currently Leadership succession Corporate with either Vice Chairman and/ or Deputy Chairman are suggested to allow a smoother transition Responsible CEO Link compensation to compensation sustainability innovation (targets achievement for reduction of CO2 emission, eco friendly strategies -production, and investment in R&D) 1 Point (1 Point) 1/2 Point (1 Point) 1 point 1 point (Continued) The Secret to Boards in Reinventing Themselves Table 4.4 119 Continued Characteristic Evaluation criteria Measure Points 3 Board cultural dynamics Employee representation Boards’ social responsibility and committees 1 Point ½ Point 1 Point 4 Sustainable jugaad innovation Innovation budgets 33% employees as board members Boards with minimum of three committees: audit, remuneration, compensation Or (Boards with 3 committees highlighted above and CSR committees) Investment of 5% of revenue in Research and Development and renewable energies Boards need to be more aware of their environment. They need to invest in renewable energies and cut their emissions (1 Point) Sustainability Total 1 Point 1 Point 12 Points Source: Complied by the authors. 1 Company that existed over 50 years 1 Country 1 Region Figure 4.2 Selection criteria Source: Compiled by the authors. to innovate. The metrics also consider employees’ safety, turnover, pension fund, in addition to factors of leadership diversity and links between board compensation and average employee pay – responsible compensation. This ties the firm to the notion of clean capitalism and its ability to be environment-friendly. The Global 100 also comprises the percentage of tax that the corporation pays. Apart from the 120 Ouarda Dsouli et al. Table 4.5 Sample for model testing Anglo-American Platinum South Africa Petroleo Brasileiro sa Brazil Komatsu Ltd Japan Accionasa Spain Seimens ag Germany Sainsbury’s UK Schneider Electric France Omv ag Austria Swisscom ag Switzerland Phillips Electronics Netherlands Suncor Energy Canada Stockland Trust Group Australia Storebrand asa Norway Johnson Controls Vestas Wind Systems Atlas Copco ab U.S. Denmark Sweden Source: Selected by authors from Global100.org. sustainable jugaad innovation criteria and the responsible compensation, which are controlled by the global 100 ranks, data have been collected from Board EX database. Hence, for companies that rank in the global 100 top quartile score 2 points, the ones that rank between 50 and 75 score 1.5 points, the ones that rank between 25 and 50 score 1 and the ones that rank in the bottom quartile score 0.5 point. Findings The application of the scoreboard to our sixteen boards suggests that boards have strengths and weaknesses within different regulatory environments and industries. Three companies overall are good in all model components. These are Anglo American, Vestas Wind Systems and Acciona. The rest of the companies are good in one aspect of our criteria or the other (see Table 4.6). Similarly, some regions are adopting balanced board practices as is the case for Scandinavian countries, followed by the European boards and then the Americans. The Scandinavian companies achieve almost half of the target points in each of the constituents whilst the European companies are slightly below that. North American companies are, on average, good in achieving balanced board leadership; however, they need to focus more on board diversity. Suncor Energy Inc. was the only company to score 0.5 point in the board leadership out of the American firms. The company had non-nationals within the board whilst the rest of the companies scored zero. This also applies to the Brazilian firm. In our study, the South African company tops the list and the Japanese firm scores lowest and is far behind. 2 ½ Austria Switzerland Netherlands Omv ag Swisscom ag Philips Electronics (koninklijke) 1 ½ Australia US Suncor Energy Inc. Stockland Trust Group Johnson Controls Inc. Sweden Norway Atlas Copco ab Storebrand asa Source: Compiled by the authors. Average Scandinavian Countries 1½ Denmark Vestas Wind Systems a/s 1.8 2½ 1½ 0.5 Average North American Countries 0 0 1.3 Canada Average European Countries 1 2 UK France Schneider Electric ½ 2 0 0 2½ Board diversity Sainsbury’s Spain Germany Japan Komatsu Ltd Siemens ag Brazil Petroleo Brasileiro sa Acciona sa South Africa Country of incorporation Anglo-American Platinum Ltd. Table 4.6 Results 2.2 1½ 2 3 2.3 2 2 3 1.8 1½ 2 1 2 2 1 3 1 2 3 Board leadership 1.2 1 1 1½ 0.7 ½ ½ 1 0.9 ½ 1 1½ 1 1 ½ 1 0 1/2 1 Culture dynamics 1.5 1 2 1½ 1.2 1 1 1½ 1.4 2 2 1 11/2 1/2 1½ 1½ 6.7 6 6½ 7½ 4.3 3½ 3½ 6 5.4 5 5½ 5½ 6½ 4½ 3½ 7½ 2 3 ½ 1 8 Total 1½ Jugaad innovation 122 Ouarda Dsouli et al. Discussion Board diversity The findings suggest that some firms are more highly diversified than others. For instance, Storebrand ASA, Anglo America Platinum Ltd. score 2.5 points each, whilst some others achieved zero points. These included Stockland Trust Group, Johnson Controls Inc, Petroleo Brasileiro and Komatsu. This suggests that whilst diversity is common practice within some firms, it is almost absent within other firms (Table 4.4). The board members average age in our 16 selected firms is equal to 59.53 years. This confirms the literature findings (Spencer Stuart, 2011b, c, 2012a, c) (Table 4.2). However, some companies seem to perceive the importance of injecting new blood into their boards. For example, five boards out of the 16 have board members below 40 years old. The youngest was 32 and this was an employee representative with no qualifications within Storebrand, Norway. The second youngest was a 37-year-old Emirati with three qualifications within OMV Ag-Austria. The third was a 38-year-old male with two qualifications within the board of Vestas Wind Systems, Denmark. The others two were 40-yearold females from Schneider Electronics (France) and Anglo-American Platinum (South Africa). Also 10 out of 16 youngest board members were comprised of females. This suggests that females are making their way into the masculine board world. In terms of internationalisation, only three companies have board directors who belong to non-European and American countries. There is one South Korean within the Schneider Electric (France) board. Two others were females, one Indian within the Phillips Electronics (Netherlands) board and an Emirati within OMV Ag (Austria). In terms of gender representation, only five out of 16 firms had female representation of 30% and above. Among these two were European: Sainsbury’s with 33.3% and Acciona with 44.4%. Two were Scandinavian: Storebrand with 44.4%, topping the list of female representation. This confirms the literature findings (GMI Ratings, 2012a). Next was Atlas Copco with 33.33%. The African company, Anglo-American Platinum, achieved 40% female representation. Men dominate the Japanese Komatsu board. They are representative of the typical old boys circle with board average age of over 70 (Edling et al., 2012). This also applies to the US Johnson Controls and the Brazilian Petroleo Brasileiro, which have female representation of 10% with the youngest board member age above 52 years. Vestas Wind System is the only Scandinavian firm that has 25% gender board representation. The The Secret to Boards in Reinventing Themselves 123 results confirm the GMI Ratings (2012a) and Catalyst (2012) findings (Table 4.1). Board leadership The firms also face issues with respect to the board leadership and board independence. Five out of 16 firms adopt the single structure. These are: Acciona, Schneider Electronics, Philip Electronics, OMV and Johnson Controls. Out of these five companies, three have board independence above 70% apart from OMV, which has board independence of 25%. Among the remaining 11 companies which have dual leadership, five companies rely more on independent directors. These are Storebrand, Sainsbury’s, Schneider Electronics, Vestas Wind Systems and Suncor Energy. This suggests that mostly boards rely heavily on independence of members, which implies a high possibility of the lack of inside knowledge of the business (Lorsch, 2009). This might be quite detrimental for the business, especially for the ones with single board structures. Whilst the majority of boards are well connected, multiple directorships are still an issue among all firms within this sample. Each firm had a minimum of one board member who sits on four or more current boards with a maximum of six board directorships. Among our sample, one female director was sitting on six boards. The director represents the Swedish Atlas Copco ab company, which brings to surface the issue of multiple directorships to the forefront (Vinnicombe and Sealy, 2012). On balance, regarding board leadership education and average qualifications, almost half of the firms in the sample scored 0, i.e. seven firms scored 0. Six out of these have an average board education below 2 qualifications. This suggested that the non-transparent board appointment process might, to some extent, influence boards (Kakabadse, 2011). In this respect, the board member recruitment process remains a concern. For example, Petrobras Petroleo (Brazil) has directors who have previously served as ministers before becoming directors of this corporation. Whilst we commend Petrobras for appointing the first-ever female CEO of an oil and gas company – Maria das Gracas Silva Foster – it is not a coincidence that she is a lifelong friend of the president of the republic of Brazil, Dilma Vana Roussef. Also out of the five companies with single board structure, only one company, US-based Johnson Controls, has no succession leadership (vice chairperson/ deputy chairperson) and 100% board independence. This implies a high transition risk in the event that the CEO steps down (Katz, 2012). The other company that is at risk within this category 124 Ouarda Dsouli et al. is Komatsu (Japan), as the board members have, overall, low levels of education, no succession plans and very low connectedness. Although, Stocklands (Australia) has a dual leadership structure, the company might be facing succession issues, as its current CEO is retiring next year and he is only the corporation’s third CEO in 60 years. Board cultural dynamics The results show that six out of the 16 firms have employee representatives on boards. Also the majority of the firms have a minimum of two boards, except for the Japanese firm Komatsu, which has neither committees nor employee representatives. Siemens AG is the only board with an employee representation of 50%, within which eight out of 10 representatives have no educational qualifications and two of these are females. This reflects the communitarian thinking embedded within the German system (Freeman, 1984; Freeman et al., 2010). On the other hand, the Anglo-American countries, such as the United States, UK, Canada, Australia, and the Spanish and South African companies have no employee representation which suggests the ‘concessionist’ shareholders thinking (Friedman, 1970). The result shows that even the most sustainable and innovative firms in the world hardly achieve the balanced boards’ structure which the framework proposes. Whilst a small number of companies succeed in reaching more than one aspect of the balanced boardroom, other firms still have a long way to go. This reinforces the literature findings and suggests a need for openness in boards to reinvent themselves. Limitations Although we conducted this study using a small sample, the results could be very useful in identifying potential trends or as a pilot for a larger-scale and more extensive macro comparison. Thus, currently the study results apply to the small scale sample rather than being more generally applicable (Dion, 1998; Lakatos, 1978). Other study constraints were those of time and availability of relevant data for analysis. The non-availability of percentage of investment in R&D and renewable energies restricted the sustainable jugaad innovation measure. Thus, the limitation translates to the reliance on the Global 100 measures for sustainable jugaad innovation and responsible CEO compensation. The application of our model for making boards work goes beyond an evaluation tool to more of a framework to guide board behaviour towards achieving balance in a wider context. We can tailor its range of The Secret to Boards in Reinventing Themselves 125 application to different environments, industries and change scenarios where the board seeks to develop transparent and trustworthy board practice. In our sample test, the model is from a Western perspective, where Eastern corporations may prefer to adopt greater emphasis on cultural dynamics items in their approach. This leaves the adoption of our framework open to context of application via use of the drivers: diversity, leadership, cultural dynamics and sustainable jugaad innovation as tailorable measures. This could also account for the Japanese firm Komatsu’s low score where internal and external values are different and more embedded within the culture. In this case, the board could endogenously achieve balance. We suggest that other studies may engage the model with different weightings appropriate to the firm’s environment or circumstance. Conclusion Anglo-American Platinum typifies the exemplar role model company for this study. We could link this to the charismatic, insightful and determined personality of the chairman of its parent company, Anglo American. However, the firm’s board members lack true internationalisation, as British and American members dominate. Furthermore, the firm shares multi-directorships with leading companies such as B.P., National Grid or Citigroup (British/American firms), which might be detrimental for the business’ future competitiveness. Acciona is the leading company within the European firms. This Spanish company is listed as one of the most innovative companies in the world within Booz & Company’s 2012 Global Innovation 1000 list (La Informacion, 2012). It is also a leading company in sustainability. Acciona has ranked number one in its sector on the Dow Jones Sustainability Index for the last six years (Acciona, 2012). This suggests that the company might be benefiting indirectly from the expertise of politicians, as Miriam Gonzales Durantez, wife of the current UK Deputy Prime Minister Nick Clegg, sits on the board. She also happens to be the daughter of a Spanish minister (Prince and Winnett, 2010). The Danish Vestas Wind System is the leading firm amongst the Scandinavian firms; however, the firm suffers from low gender balance (25% female representation). The patterns of findings through the application of our scoreboard offer insight into the boardroom practices from a new perspective. In comparative regional analysis, we find differences due to regulatory and cultural influences. For instance, Scandinavian firms scored 126 Ouarda Dsouli et al. overall high in all components with 6.7. However, it is interesting to note that whilst all Scandinavian firms have employee representation, none of them have CSR committees in place. This suggests that social responsibility may be embedded within the national regulation or social culture. The European firms collectively scored an average of 5.4. However, at component level, the average scores are low. This suggests that European firms may pay more attention to board diversity and leadership – the dominant features in our test case. This reflects that the cultures of these countries either are reluctant to change the ‘preserved culture’ or simply, they are resistant to the Americanisation of board practice. Whilst the American firms topped the list with an average of 2.3 in board leadership, they still have a long way to go in developing the diversity of their boards. Whilst history implies that Americans were the first movers in fostering equality and democracy principles, the diversity is nascent within the studied firms, apart from Suncor Energy which had non-nationals within its boards. All three firms have no female representation and no younger representation within their boards. Hence, it seems that regulatory pressure is forcing corporations to change behaviour rather than boards being pro-active. Our findings reflect a pattern of slow forced change of diversity rather than pro-active boards’ stakeholder representative desires. In the current business climate it seems that boards are unable to readjust their firms for growth. Therefore, we propose within this chapter that change needs to come from the CEO and board members. Boards should be regularly challenging their own perceptions and questioning from a moral as well as an economic perspective. One way to this is by reinventing themselves. Hence, this chapter focuses on boards’ most vulnerable aspects and proposes guidelines to tackle these deficiencies. In this respect, to be sustainable in reinventing themselves, boards needs to recognise that they are accountable and responsible for the firms that they lead. An important part of this is a shift of the mind set from one of hierarchical power and dominating competitive struggles towards open-minded collaborative understanding. Board members have to take a risk and open the doors to their boardrooms. Boards need to understand that it is not about being the best and leading by dominating, but it is more about delivering value to society, renewing effective solutions to everyday problems and building a self-sustaining world for tomorrow that will drive their firms for the future. The way forward is to extend this nascent initiative and daring to think differently about the future. The Secret to Boards in Reinventing Themselves 127 References Acciona (2012) Acciona named to the Dow Jones Sustainability World Index (DJSI World) for the fifth year in a row, http://www.acciona.com/news/acciona-named-to-the-dow-jones-sustainability-index [Accessed 20 November 2012]. Ahern, K.R. and Dittmar, A.K. (2011) The changing of the boards: the impact on firm valuation of mandated female board representation, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 127(1): 137–197, http://ssrn.com/abstract=1364470 or http://dx.doi. org/10.2139/ssrn.1364470 [accessed 4 November 2012]. Anderson, S. and Cavanagh, J. (2000) Top 200: the rise of global corporate power, http://globalpolicy.igc.org/socecon/tncs/top200.htm [accessed 18 February 2005]. Argenti, C. (1976) Corporate Collapse: Causes and Symptoms, McGraw-Hill, New York. Asian History (2012) Profile of India, http://asianhistory.about.com/od/india/ p/ indiaprof.htm [accessed 20 November 2012]. BBC (2012) European Union postpones women quota on boards plan, http:// www.bbc.co.uk/news/business-20039540 [accessed 19 October 2012]. Bhagat, S. and Bolton, B.(2008) Corporate governance and firm performance, Journal of Corporate Finance, 14(3): 257–273. Blair, M.M. (1995) Ownership and Control: Rethinking Corporate Governance for the Twenty-First Century, Brookings Institution Press, Washington. Boyd, B.K. (1990) Corporate linkages and organizational environment: a test of the resource dependence model, Strategic Management Journal, 11(6): 419–430. Brammer, S., Millington, A. and Pavelin, S. (2007) Gender and ethnic diversity among UK corporate boards, Corporate Governance: An International Review, 15: 393–403, doi: 10.1111/j.1467–8683.2007.00569.x. Brickley, J.A., Coles, J.L. and Jarrell, G. (1997) Leadership structure: separating the CEO and chairman of the board, Journal of Corporate Finance, 3: 189–220. Cadbury Committee (1992) Report of the Committee on Financial Aspects of Corporate Governance, HMSO, London. Carter, D.A., Simkins, B.J. and Simpson, W.G. (2003) Corporate governance, board diversity, and firm value, Financial Review, 38: 33–53, doi: 10.1111/1540– 6288.00034. Castells, M. (2012) Alternative economic cultures, London School of Economics, http://www.bbc.co.uk/iplayer/episode/b01n9yg1/Analysis_ Alternative_ Economic_Cultures/ [accessed 21 October 2012]. Catalyst (1995) Census of Women Board Directors of the Fortune 500, Catalyst, New York. Catalyst (2012) Women on boards – global board seats held by women, http:// www.catalyst.org/publication/433/ [accessed 5 October 2012]. Charan, R. and Useem, J. (2002) Why companies fail – CEOs offer every excuse but the right one: their own errors. Here are ten mistakes to avoid, Fortune, 145(11): 50–62. Chu, J.S.G. (2012) Who killed the inner circle? The end of the era of the corporate interlock network, http://ssrn.com/abstract=2061113 or http://dx.doi. org/10.2139/ssrn.2061113 [accessed 31 October 2012]. 128 Ouarda Dsouli et al. Clarke, T. (1998) The contribution of non-executive directors to the effectiveness of corporate governance, Career Development International, 3(3): 118–124. Conyon, M.J. and Murphy, K.J. (2000) The prince and the pauper? CEO pay in the United States and United Kingdom, Economic Journal, 110: F640–F671. Conyon, M.J., Ferreira, M.A., Matos, P. and Murphy, K.J. (2011) The Executive Compensation Controversy: A Transatlantic Analysis, Fondazione Rodolfo de Benedetti, Available from: http://digitalcommons.ilr.cornell.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1004&context=ics&sei-redir=1&referer=http%3A%2F%2Fsch olar.google.co.uk%2Fscholar%3Fq%3DThe%2BExecutive%2BCompensation %2BControversy%3A%2BA%2BTransatlantic%2BAnalysis%26hl%3Den%26 as_sdt%3D0%26as_vis%3D1%26oi%3Dscholart%26sa%3DX%26ei%3DOzqo UKKgAoXJ0AWy_IDACw%26ved%3D0CB4QgQMwAA#search=%22Executiv e%20Compensation%20Controversy%3A%20Transatlantic%20Analysis%22 [accessed 30th October 2012]. Coombes, P. and Wong, C.Y. (2004) Chairman and CEO: one job or two?, The McKinsey Quarterly: A New Era in Governance, 2: 43–47. Companies Act (2006), Cited in Pierce, C. (2010) Corporate Governance in the European Union – A County by Country Analysis of Corporate Governance Practices, Global Governance Services Ltd, Orpington, Kent, United Kingdom. Corporate Governance Code A2.1 (2012) U.K. Corporate Governance Code, September 2012, p. 12, Code A2.1 http://www.frc.org.uk/getattachment/ a7f0aa3a-57dd-4341-b3e8-ffa99899e154/UK-Corporate-Governance-CodeSeptember-2012.aspx Financial Reporting Council. Crist Kolder Associates (2011) The volatility report, http://www.cristkolder.com/ VolatilityReport2011.pdf [accessed 6 November 2012]. Daily, C.M., Dalton, D.R. and Cannella, A.A. (2003) Corporate governance: decades of dialogue and data, Academy of Management Review, 28(3): 371–382. Dalton, D.R. and Dalton, C.M. (2011) Integration of micro- and macro-studies in governance research: CEO duality, board composition, and financial performance, Journal of Management, 37: 404–411. Dalton, D.R., Daily, C.M., Ellstrand, A.E. and Johnson, J.L. (1998) Board composition, leadership structure, and financial performance: meta-analytic reviews and research agenda, Strategic Management Journal, 19: 269–290. Davies Report (2011), Women on boards, http://www.bis.gov.uk/assets/biscore/ business-law/docs/w/11–745-women-on-boards [accessed 12 October 2011]. Davis, J., Schoorman, F.D. and Donaldson, L. (1997) Towards a stewardship theory of management, Academy of Management Review, 22(1): 20–47. Davis, M. (2011) The effective Chair–CEO relationship: insights from the boardroom, Millstein Center for Corporate Governance & Performance, Yale School of Management, http://blogs.law.harvard.edu/corpgov/2011/03/17/ the-effective-chair-ceo-relationship-insights-from-the-boardroom/ [accessed 22 October 2012]. Deal, T. E., and Kennedy, A.A. (1982), Corporate Cultures, Addison-Wesley, Reading, United kingdom. DeRue, D.S., Ashford, S.J. and Cotton, N.C. (2009) Assuming the mantle: unpacking the process by which individuals internalize a leader identity, Exploring Positive Identities and Organizations: Building a Theoretical and Research Foundation, Routledge, New York, United States, pp. 217–236. The Secret to Boards in Reinventing Themselves 129 Dion, D. (1998), Evidence and inference in the comparative case study, Comparative Politics, 30 (2): 127–145. DGA (Davis Global Advisors) (2004) Leading Corporate Governance Indicators: 1996–2004, Davis Global Advisors, Inc., New York. Donaldson, L. (1990) The ethereal hand: organizational economics and management theory, Academy of Management Review, 15(3): 369–381. Dutch Corporate Governance Code (2008) Principals of good corporate governance and best practice provisions, www.ecgi.org/codes/documents/cg_code_ netherlands_dec2008_en.pdf [accessed 15 October 2012] Dutra, A. (2012) A more effective board of directors, Harvard Business Review, http://blogs.hbr.org/cs/2012/11/a_more_effective_board_of_dire.html [accessed 6 November 2012]. Edling, C., Hobdari, B., Randøy, T., Stafsudd, A. and Thomsen, S. (2012) Testing the ‘old boys’ network’: diversity and board interlocks in Scandinavia, The Small Worlds of Corporate Governance, MIT Press, pp. 183–220. Erhardt, N.L., Werbel, J.D. and Shrader, C.B. (2003) Board of director diversity and firm financial performance, Corporate Governance: An International Review, 11: 102–111, doi: 10.1111/1467–8683.00011. Erkut, S., Kramer, V.W. and Konrad, A.M. (2008) Critical mass: does the number of women on a corporate board make a difference? In: Vinnicombe, S., Singh, V., Burke, R., Bilimoria, D. and Huse, M. (eds) Women on Corporate Boards of Directors: International Research and Practice, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp. 350–366. Faleye, O. (2007) Classified boards, firm value, and managerial entrenchment, Journal of Financial Economics, 83: 501–529. Fama, E. and Jensen, M. (1983) Separation of ownership and control, Journal of Law and Economics, 26(3): 301–325. Farrell, K. and Hersch, P. (2005) Additions to corporate boards: the effect of gender, Journal of Corporate Finance, 11: 85–106, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j. jcorpfin.2003.12.001 [accessed 10 November 2012]. Fernandes, N., Ferreira, M.A., Matos, P. and Murphy, K.J. (2009) The Pay Divide: (Why) Are U.S. Top Executives Paid More? ECGI Finance Working Paper No. 255/2009 (Updated December 2010). Financial Times (2011) One woman, multiple boards: rise of the ‘super-connected’ director, http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/620ad5a0–7a20–11e0-bc74–00144feabdc0.html#axzz2BHLvLxFZ [accessed 22 October 2012]. Forbes (2009) Pick a CEO who truly fits the company, http://www.forbes. com/2009/04/09/ceo-succession-planning-leadership-governance-fit.html [accessed 8 November 2012]. Forbes (2012a) The need for balance: how powerful Chairman-CEOs put shareholder value at risk, http://www.forbes.com/sites/nathanielparishflannery/20 11/08/19/the-need-for-balance-how-powerful-chairmen-ceos-put-shareholder-value-at-risk/ [accessed 3 November 2012]. Forbes (2012b) CEO statistics, http://www.statisticbrain.com/ceo-statistics/ [accessed 3 November 2012]. Forbes (2012c) Barriers to change: the real reason behind the Kodak downfall, http://www.forbes.com/sites/johnkotter/2012/05/02/barriers-to-change-thereal-reason-behind-the-kodak-downfall/ [accessed 7 November 2012]. Freeman, R.E. (1984) Strategic Management: A Stakeholder Approach, Pitman, Marchfield. 130 Ouarda Dsouli et al. Freeman, R.E., Harrison, J.S., Wicks, A.C., Parmar, B.L. and de Colle, S. (2010) Stakeholder Theory: The State of the Art, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Friedman, M. (1970) The social responsibility of business is to increase its profits, New York Times Sunday Magazine, 13 September, 32–33 and 122–126. Ingley, C., and Van Der Walt, N. (2002) Board dynamics and the politics of appraisal, Corporate Governance: An International Review, 10 (3):163–174. Gifford, G. (2012) Throw away your old board recruitment matrix, http://www. ceffect.com/blog/better-boards/throw-away-your-old-board-recruitment-matrix/ [accessed 25 October 2012]. Gillies, J. and Dickinson, M. (1999) The governance of transnational firms: some preliminary hypotheses, Corporate Governance: An International Journal, 7: 237–247. Global 100.org (2012) 2012 global list, http://www.global100.org/annuallists/2012-global-100-list.html [accessed 8 October 2012]. Global Competitiveness Report 2012–2013 (2012) World Economic Forum, http://www3.weforum.org/docs/WEF_GlobalCompetitivenessReport_2012–1 3.pdf [accessed 4 October 2012]. Global Sherpa (2012) BRIC Countries – Background, latest news, Statistics, Latest News and Original Articles, http://www.globalsherpa.org/bric-countriesbrics[accessed 10 December 2012]. GMI Ratings (2012a) Women on boards survey, http://library.constantcontact. com/download/get/file/1102561686275–86/GMIRatings_WOB_032012.pdf [accessed 5 October 2012]. GMI Ratings (2012b) Combined CEO/Chairmen, http://www3.gmiratings.com/ home/2012/06/june-28–2012-combined-ceochairmen/ [accessed 27 October 2012]. Grant Thornton (2011) Corporate governance review: a changing climate – fresh challenges ahead, http://www.grant-thornton.co.uk/Documents/Corporate_ Governance_Review_2011.pdf [accessed 14 October 2012]. Gregoric, A., Oxelheim, L., Randøy, T. and Thomsen, S. (2009) Corporate Governance as a Source of Competitiveness for Nordic Firms, Nordic Innovation Centre. Harvard Business Review (2011) Vision statement: corporate now and then, http:// public.dhe.ibm.com/common/ssi/ecm/en/gbe03486usen/GBE03486USEN. PDF [accessed 21 October 2012]. Harvey Nash (2012) Inspire the influential business exchange, return on diversity: a study of diversity in the boardroom, http://www.harveynash.com/ inspire/documents/FinalReturnonDeiversity2012report.pdf [accessed 24 October 2012]. Hay Group (2008) Cited in The Economist (2008) Pay attention European politicians have declared war on ‘excessive’ executive pay – but companies are more prudent than they think, executive pay in Europe, Paris, http://www.economist.com/node/11543665 [accessed 30 October 2012]. Heidrick and Struggles (2009) Boards in Turbulent Times – Corporate Governance Report, ht t p://w w w.he id r ic k .com / P ubl ic at ion sRep or t s/ P ubl ic at ion sRep or t s/ CorpGovEurope2009.pdf [accessed 20 November 2012] Hermalin, B.E. and Weisbach, M.S. (2003) Board of directors as an endogenously determined institution: a survey of the economic literature, FRBNY Economic The Secret to Boards in Reinventing Themselves 131 Policy Review, 7–26, http://faculty.haas.berkeley.edu/hermalin/601herma.pdf [accessed date 12 November 2012] Higgs Report (2003) Review of the role and effectiveness of non-executive directors, http://www.ecgi.org/codes/code.php?code_id=121[accessed date 16 November 2012]. Hofstede, G. Hofstede, G.J. and Minkov, M. (2010) Cultures and Organizations: Software for the Mind, 3rd edition, McGraw Hill, New York. Huse, M. (2001) The Hidden Agenda: Exploring Boards of Directors, paper presented at the 16th Scandinavian Academy of Management, Uppsala, August. IBM (2012) Leading through connections, highlights of the global chief executive officer study, http://public.dhe.ibm.com/common/ssi/ecm/en/gbe03486usen/ GBE03486USEN.PDF [accessed 19 October 2012]. IFSA Guidance Note No.2.00 (1999) Governance: a Guide for Fund Managers and Corporations, www.ecgi.org/codes/documents/ifsa_july1999.pdf [accessed 15 October 2012]. IMD (2012) Globalization and economic reform under threat, http://www.imd.org/ research/publications/wcy/upload/GE_BE_gap.pdf [accessed 12 October 2012]. Kaczmarek, S., Kimino, S. and Pye, A. (2012) Interlocking directorships and firm performance in highly regulated sectors: the moderating impact of board diversity, Journal of Management and Governance, 1–26. Kakabadse, A. (2011) Leadership: what you know or who you know?, http://www. som.cranfield.ac.uk/som/dinamic-content/media/knowledgeinterchange/ topics/20111128/transcript-ak.pdf [accessed 22 October 2012]. Kakabadse, A. and Kakabadse, N. (2001), Geo-Politics of Governance: Impact of Contrasting Philosophies, Palgrave, London. Kakabadse, A., Kakabadse, N. and Barratt, R. (2006) Chairman and Chief Executive Officer (CEO): that sacred and secret relationship, https://dspace.lib. cranfield.ac.uk/bitstream/1826/1028/3/Chairman%2520and%2520chief%25 20executive%2520officer%2520CEO-2006.pdf [accessed 29 October 2012]. Kakabadse, N. and Kakabadse, A. (2004) Editorial, Corporate Governance. The International Journal of Business in Society, 4(4): 1–3. Kanungo, A.K. (2012) Internationalization of Indian Firms: Overseas Investment, A Key Strategy, Working Paper, http://www.freit.org/WorkingPapers/Papers/ ForeignInvestment/FREIT384.pdf [accessed 15 November 2012]. Katz, D.A. (2012) Advice for boards in CEO selection and succession planning, http://blogs.law.harvard.edu/corpgov/2012/06/11/advice-for-boards-in-ceoselection-and-succession-planning/#2b [accessed 6 November 2012]. King III (2009) King Code Of governance for South Africa, www.ecgi.org/codes/ documents/King3.pdf [16 October 2012]. Knyght, R., Kakabadse, N., Kouzmin, A. and Kakabadse, A. (2011) Chronic failure in globalized, oligopolistic markets: an urgent case for socialized capital, Society and Business Review, 6(1): 7–26. Korn-Ferry (2007) 34th Annual Board of Directors Study, https://docs.google. com/v iewer?a=v&q= cache:cR8l-E2oj9g J:w w w.kornferr y.com/Librar y/ ViewGallery.asp%3FCID%3D9962%26LanguageID%3D1%26RegionID%3 D262+&hl=en&gl=uk&pid=bl&srcid=ADGEESgzNhjl4HG9I7tKA0yZB6SE N_bsjK29t2FzRmstM0H6KJ9-XzqsBZjSzo8wIeWt6btUxzOwNPsZ_mgVQtSrt_ Nja4L35dGxib6qRAEOabOUu_GN48TUQ4Z7jjCELGb5WeVxdVn0&sig=AHI EtbSCyBcca1lOEbjbxD-vDUJyHpbgUA [accessed 11 October 2012]. 132 Ouarda Dsouli et al. Jensen, M. (2012) How integrity can save your company (and the world), http:// blogs.wsj.com/atwork/2012/10/12/how-integrity-can-save-your-companyand-the-world/ [accessed 15 October 2012]. La Informacion (2012) Telefónica, Iberdrola, Almirall, Acciona, Grifols y Zeltia, entre las firmas más innovadoras a nivel mundial, Telefónica, Iberdrola, Almirall, Acciona, Grifols y Zeltia, entre las firmas más innovadoras a nivel mundial [accessed 13 November 2012]. Lakatos, I. (1978), In Worrall, J. and Currie, G. (Eds), The Methodology of Scientific Research Programmes, Vol. 1, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Leblanc, R.W. (2004) What’s wrong with corporate governance: a note, Corporate Governance, 12(4): 436–441. Long, T. (2006) This year’s model: influences on board and director evaluation, Corporate Governance: An International Review, 14: 547–557, doi: 10.1111/j.1467– 8683.2006.00529. Lorsch, J.W. (2009) Leadership: the key to effective boards, In: Conger, J.A. (ed.) Boardroom Realities: Building Leaders Across your Board, Jossey Bass, San Francisco, 25–50. Luo, Y. (2007) Global Dimensions of Corporate Governance, Blackwell, Oxford. Macfarlane, F., Sinhuber, D. and Khan, T. (2010) Diversity briefing: the Canadian Institute of Chartered Accountants, http://www.ey.com/Publication/vw LUAssets/DirectorBriefingDiversity/$FILE/DirectorBriefingDiversity.pdf [accessed 20 October 2012]. Mallin, C.A. (2010) Corporate Governance, 3rd edition, Oxford University Press, Oxford. Marimuthu, M. (2008) Ethnic diversity on boards of directors and its implications on firm financial performance, The Journal of International Social Research, 1(4): 431–445. Mattis, M. C. (2004) Women entrepreneurs: out from under the glass ceiling, Women In Management Review, 19(3): 154–163. McDonald, M., Westphal, J. and Graebner, M. (2008) What do they know? The effects of outside director acquisition experience on firm acquisition performance, Strategic Management Journal, 29: 1155–1177. Mercer (2011) Global executive pay trends – Asian remuneration eroding West’s ability to attract scarce talent, http://uk.mercer.com/press-releases/1427125 [accessed 30 October 2012]. Milliken, F. J., and Martins, L. L. 1996. Searching for common threads: Understanding the multiple effects of diversity in organizational groups. Academy of Management Review, 21: 402–433. Miletkov, M., Poulsen, A.B. and Wintoki, M.B. (2012) Importing governance: a multinational study of the determinants and effects of having foreign independent directors, http://ssrn.com/abstract=2024655 or http://dx.doi. org/10.2139/ssrn.2024655 [accessed 15 October 2012]. Minichilli, A., Zattoni, A., Nielsen, S. and Huse, M. (2012) Board task performance: an exploration of micro- and macro-level determinants of board effectiveness, Journal of Organizational Behaviour, 33: 193–215, doi: 10.1002/ job.743. Mizruchi, M.S. (1996) What do interlocks do? An analysis, critique, and assessment of research on interlocking directorates, Annual Review of Sociology, 22: 271–298. The Secret to Boards in Reinventing Themselves 133 Monks, R. and Minow, N. (2004) Corporate Governance, 3rd edition, Blackwell, Cambridge. Nadler, D. (2004) What’s the board’s role in strategy development? Engaging the board in corporate strategy, Strategy and Leadership, 32(5): 25–33. Nguyen, B.D. (2012) Does the Rolodex matter? Corporate elite’s small world and the effectiveness of boards of directors, Management Science, 58: 236–252; published online before print, 22 December 2011. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) (1999) OECD Principles of Corporate Governance, OECD, Paris. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) (2004) OECD Principles of Corporate Governance, OECD, Paris. Payne, G.T., Benson, G.S. and Finegold, D.L. (2009) Corporate board attributes, team effectiveness and financial performance, Journal of Management Studies, 46(4): 704–731. Petersen, R. (2000) The Management of a Diverse Workforce in the Business Environment of Israel and Possible Applications for South Africa, Dissertation Abstracts International Section B: The Sciences and Engineering, 60: 4284. Pedersen & Partners (2012) Top executive compensation in top 100 companies averages 1.3 million Euros, http://www.pedersenandpartners.com/ articles/top-executive-compensation-top-100-companies-averages-13-million-euros?page=1 [accessed 18 October 2012]. Pfeffer, J. (1972) Size and composition of corporate boards of directors: the organisation and its environment, Administrative Science Quarterly, 17 (1): 218–228. Pfeffer, J. and Salancik, G.R. (1978) The External Control of Organisation: A Resource Dependency Perspective, Harper and Row, New York. Pierce, C. (2010) Corporate Governance in the European Union, Global Governance Services Ltd, Orpington, Kent, UK. Pierce, C. (2011) 21st century boardroom behaviors: the good, the bad and the ugly, http://www.board-evaluation.co.uk/index.php/news_stories/31 [accessed 25 October 2012]. Platt, H. and Platt, M. (2012) Corporate board attributes and bankruptcy, Journal of Business Research, 65(8): 1139–1143. Porter, M. E. (1985) Competitive Advantage, Free Press, New York. Porter, M.E. and Kramer, M.R. (2011) The big idea: creating shared value, Harvard Business Review, 89(1–2) (January/February). Prahalad, C. K. (2005) The Fortune at the Bottom of the Pyramid: A Mirage, Pearson Education, London. PricewaterhouseCoopers (2011) The world in 2050: the accelerating shift of global economic power: challenges and opportunities, http://www.pwc.com/en_GX/ gx/world-2050/pdf/world-in-2050-jan-2011.pdf [accessed 20 November 2012]. Prince, R. and Winnett, R. (2010) Nick Clegg’s wife lands lucrative job on board of Spanish building firm, Daily Telegraph, 9 June, http://www.telegraph.co.uk/ news/politics/nick-clegg/7812214/Nick-Cleggs-wife-lands-lucrative-job-onboard-of-Spanish-building-firm.html. Pye, A. and Pettigrew, A. (2005) Studying board context, process and dynamics: some challenges for the future, British Journal of Management, 16: S27–S38, doi: 10.1111/j.1467–8551.2005.00445.x. Radjou, N., Prabhu, J. and Ahuja, S. (2012) Jugaad Innovation: Think Frugal, Be Flexible, Generate Breakthrough Growth, Jossey Bass, San Francisco. 134 Ouarda Dsouli et al. Reding, V. (2011) Over-achieving and under-represented: the case for women on boards, Insead, http://knowledge.insead.edu/leadership-management/ over-achieving-and-under-represented-the-case-for-women-on-692 [accessed 8 October 2012]. Rhode, D. and Packel, A.K. (2010) Diversity on Corporate Boards: How Much Difference Does Difference Make?, Rock Center for Corporate Governance at Stanford University Working Paper No. 89, http://ssrn.com/abstract=1685615 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1685615 [accessed 12 November 2012]. Richardson, I., Kakabadse, A. and Kakabadse, N. (2011) Bilderberg People: Elite Power and Consensus in World Affairs, Routledge, London and New York. Rivas, J.L. (2012) Diversity and internationalization: the case of boards and TMT’s, International Business Review, 21(1): 1–12. Roberson, Q.M. and Park, H.J. (2007) Examining the link between diversity and firm performance: the effects of diversity reputation and leader racial diversity, Group & Organization Management, 32: 548–568. Rose, C. (2007) Does female board representation influence firm performance? The Danish Evidence, Corporate Governance: An International Review, 15: 404– 413, doi: 10.1111/j.1467–8683.2007.00570.x. Sarbanes-Oxley Act (2002) 15 U.S.C. § 78(j)10A(m)(3). Scherer, K. (1997) Women directors, Talent before gender, Corporate Board, 17: 1 – 5. Schwartz-Ziv, M. (2012) Does the gender of directors matter? http://ssrn.com/ abstract=1868033 [accessed 15 October 2012]. Shrader, C.B., Blackburn, V.B. and Iles, P. (1997) Women in management and firm financial performance: an exploratory study, Journal of Managerial Issues, 9: 355–373. Smith, J.L. (2010) Directors’ Insights from Inside the Boardroom: A New Zealand Perspective, Auckland University of Technology Master’s Thesis. Sonnenfeld, J.A. (2002) What makes great boards great, Harvard Business Review, 80(9): 106–114. Spencer Stuart (2011a) UK board index: current board trends and practices at major UK companies, http://content.spencerstuart.com/sswebsite/pdf/lib/ UK2011_FINAL.pdf [accessed 30 October 2012]. Spencer Stuart (2011b) 2011 India board index: current board trends and practices in the BSE-100, http://content.spencerstuart.com/sswebsite/pdf/lib/2011India-Board-Index_15Jun2012_FINAL.pdf [accessed 10 November 2012]. Spencer Stuart (2011c) Canadian board index: trends and practices of leading Canadian companies 2011, http://content.spencerstuart.com/sswebsite/pdf/ lib/CSSBI_2011.pdf [accessed 7 November 2012]. Spencer Stuart (2012a) España 2012: Índice Spencer Stuart de Consejos de Administración, 16a Edición, http://content.spencerstuart.com/sswebsite/ pdf/lib/Spain-Board-Index-2012_23Oct2012.pdf?__hstc=240410332.e97c736 ced88c2e0da05d0cc70fb3e9c.1353207222088.1353207222088.13532072220 88.1&__hssc=240410332.4.1353207222088 [accessed 1 November 2011]. Spencer Stuart (2012b) France Board Index 2012, 17th edition, http://content. spencerstuart.com/sswebsite/pdf/lib/France-Board-Index-2012_26Oct2012. pdf?__hstc=240410332.e97c736ced88c2e0da05d0cc70fb3e9c.13532072220 88.1353207222088.1353207222088.1&__hssc=240410332.2.1353207222088 [accessed 12 November 2012]. The Secret to Boards in Reinventing Themselves 135 Spencer Stuart (2012c) US board index, http://www.spencerstuart.com/research/ articles/1621/ [accessed 7 November 2012]. Spencer Stuart (2012d) Improving board effectiveness: Five principles for getting the most out of a board assessment, http://content.spencerstuart.com/sswebsite/pdf/lib/pov11_indArt_boards.pdf [10 November 2012] Staples, C.L. (2007) Board globalisation in the world’s largest TNCs 1993–2005, Corporate Governance: An International Review, 15: 311–321. Terjesen, S., Sealy, R. and Singh, V. (2009) Women directors on corporate boards: a review and research agenda, Corporate Governance: An International Review, 17(3): 320–337. The Diversity Summit (2012) The Diversity Summit, the value of inclusion. 6 December, the Dorchester, London. http://www.economistconferences.co.uk/ event/diversity-summit-2012/6497 attended by N. Khan. The Economist (2008) Pay attention European politicians have declared war on ‘excessive’ executive pay – but companies are more prudent than they think, executive pay in Europe, Paris, http://www.economist.com/node/11543665 [accessed 30 October 2012]. The Spectator (2012) Murdoch’s son in law advising the new BBC Chief, http:// blogs.spectator.co.uk/steerpike/2012/11/tim-davies-baleful-leadership-of-thebbc/ [13 November 2012] Tonello, M. (2012) Separation of Chair and CEO roles, Harvard Law School Forum on Corporate Governance and Financial Regulation, http://blogs.law. harvard.edu/corpgov/2011/09/01/separation-of-chair-and-ceo-roles/ [accessed 10 October 2010]. Treanor, J. (2012) Barclays just the tip of the iceberg as banking braced for more scandals. From rate fixing to bumper bonuses and PPI – reprehensible behaviour appears to be endemic throughout banking, http://www.guardian. co.uk/business/2012/jul/08/banking-scandals-barclays [accessed 20 November 2012]. Tricker, B. (2012) Corporate Governance: Principles, Policies and Practices, 2nd edition, Oxford University Press, Oxford. Tricker, B. (2009) Corporate Governance – Principles, Policies and Practices. Oxford University Press. U.K. Corporate Governance Code (2010) June (at s. A.3.1). United Nations (2009) World population to exceed 9 billion by 2050, http:// www.un.org/esa/population/publications/wpp2008/pressrelease.pdf [accessed 10 November 2012]. Van Der Walt, N., and Ingley, C. (2003) Board dynamics and the influence of professional background, gender and ethnic diversity of directors, Corporate Governance: An International Review, 11(3): 218–234. Viénot, M. (1995) The Board of Directors of Listed Companies in France (Viénot Report 1), Association Francaise des Enterprises Privees and the Mouvement des Enterprises de France, Paris, 10 July. Viénot, M. (1999) Recommendations of the Committee on Corporate Governance: Codes of Best Practice for the Corporate Governance of Listed Companies – Report Draft, Association Francaise des Entreprises Privees, Paris, July. Viénot, M. (2000) Recommendations of the Committee on Corporate Governance (Viénot Report 2), Association Francaise des Enterprises Privees and the Mouvement des Enterprises de France, Paris, January. 136 Ouarda Dsouli et al. Vinnicombe, S. and Sealy, R. (2012) The female FTSE board report 2012: milstone or millstone, http://www.som.cranfield.ac.uk/som/dinamic-content/ research/documents/2012femalftse.pdf [accessed 3 November 2012]. Vitali, S., Glattfelder, J.B. and Battiston, S. (2011) The network of global corporate control, PLos ONE, 6(10): e25995, http://www.plosone.org/article/ info%3Adoi%2F10.1371%2Fjournal.pone.0025995 [accessed 20 October 2012]. Walker Report (2009) A review of corporate governance in UK banks and other financial industry entities Final recommendation, http://webarchive.nationalarchives.gov.uk/+/http:/www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/d/walker_review_261109. pdf [20 November 2012]. Wang, Y. and Clift, B. (2009) Is there a “business case” for board diversity?, Pacific Accounting Review, 21: 88, http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/01140580911002044. Watson, W. E., Johnson, L., and Merritt, D. (1998) Team orientation, self-orientation, and diversity in task groups: their connection to team performance over time, Group & Organization Management, 23: 161–189. Wellalage, N.H., Locke, S. and Scrimgeour, F. (2012) The global financial crisis impact on ethnic diversity of Sri Lanka boards, Asian Journal of Finance & Accounting, 4(1): 52–68. Westphal, J.D. and Milton, L.P. (2000) How experience and network ties affect the influence of demographic minorities on corporate boards, Administrative Science Quarterly, 45(2): 366–398. Wong, S.C.Y. (2011) Elevating Board Performance: The Significance of Director Mindset, Operating Context, and Other Behavioral and Functional Considerations, Northwestern Law and Economics Research Paper No. 11–12, http://ssrn.com/abstract=1832234 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1832234. World Economic Forum (2012) Global Competitiveness Report 2012–2013, http:// www3.weforum.org/docs/WEF_GlobalCompetitivenessReport_2012–13.pdf World Health Organization and United Nations Habitat (2012) Hidden cities, unmasking and overcoming health inequities in urban settings, http://www. hiddencities.org/downloads/WHO_UN-HABITAT_Hidden_Cities_Web.pdf [accessed 10 November 2012]. Yoshikawa, T. (2012) Complementarities in Institutions, Director Capital and Director behaviours: A Contingency Model of Outside Directors Efficacy, presented at University of Cambridge CGIR 20th Anniversary Conference, July. Zahidi, S. (2012) Corporate gender gap, World Economic Forum, http://www. weforum.org/issues/corporate-gender-gap# [accessed 10 October 2012]. 5 Reinventing Board Effectiveness: From Best Practice to Best Fit Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau Does compliance with corporate governance codes lead to effective boards? Although governance codes and best practice recommendations have had a great deal of positive impact, we should not be blind for some of the downside effects as well. Codes of best practice have had a great deal of positive impact on boards, directors becoming more active and empowered, taking their jobs more seriously. Boards are not the cosy enclaves they used to be. Directors are getting tough(er) with CEOs today, asking critical questions and demanding answers from management. Moreover, boards face much greater pressure from the public, the government and the shareholders. Governance codes comprise reasonable recommendations, not in the least to cope with the painful memories of the numerous corporate failures and excesses. However, they also have serious flaws and unintended outcomes, which inevitably cause serious problems which can possibly diminish governance effectiveness. The time is right to face the limitations of these codes of best practice. Board effectiveness goes beyond ‘visible’ factors put forward by codes Emphasis has been too focused on externally observable governance elements. Most of the recommendations for change are coming from external groups, such as institutional shareholder groups, trade federations and regulators. Consequently they focus on those characteristics of boards that are visible to outsiders, typically the measurable input factors. They say little about what should actually happen inside 137 138 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau the boardroom, and as a result have too little substantive effect on governance. Focussing on what is visible may be the best way to put public pressure on boards to focus on ‘improvement’, but it misses the essential fact that these visible factors have rather limited impact on board effectiveness. The problem is that the existing scoring metrics and monitoring studies do not really come to grips with the very complex and dynamic reality. We should not forget that the real action takes place in the boardroom itself. It is time to regard boards for what they really are: complex social and political systems (Crainer and Dearlove, 2007). What is measurable (board input indicators and formal procedures) may matter far less than what is not readily measurable (competencies, governance attitude and behaviour). Indeed, understanding how boards work is not a simple task. Great boards do not work together by accident, magic or happenstance. If grasping how an individual will behave is difficult, the complexity involved in understanding how a group goes about overseeing the operations of organisations, often comprising hundreds or thousands of individuals, is daunting. It is important to move beyond simplistic indicators that can be put forward as mere window dressing or check-listing. We need to investigate the underlying character of the governance practice in all its dimensions. Fancy statements about the company’s corporate governance practices may look good in the annual report and make some shareholders feel good, but they don’t in and of themselves make boards more effective (Carter and Lorsch, 2004; Conger, 2009). Superficial checklists or window dressing about good governance are problematic (Sonnenfeld and Ward, in Conger, 2009). It is even stated that conventional wisdom about good governance can actually undermine governance effectiveness. Unfortunately, codes have unintentionally triggered a kind of ‘box ticking’ approach. In particular, this method is the reference for many external analyses. Although there are a myriad of indicators of good governance, governance ratings neglect key board process issues and leadership integrity. Our previous research already highlighted the shortcomings of the external governance ratings (Van den Berghe and Levrau, 2003), but also Richard Leblanc (in Conger, 2009) as well as Jeffrey Sonnenfeld (2002) are very critical of this methodology. They state that these governance scoring methodologies, such as the one used by ISS, appear to be incomplete at best, and deeply flawed at worst. Reinventing Board Effectiveness 139 Leblanc also points to the fact that externally measurable governance scores do not reflect the leadership, the chemistry, decisions, information, reporting, competencies and behaviour of boards and individual directors. The focus should be on process and the calibre of leadership to reach the goal of effective decision-making, not just on structural prescriptions. A similar observation can be made with regard to the public monitoring of corporate governance codes. Market-wide monitors are commonly found in the member states of the European Union and engage in two types of monitoring activities (see also Table 5.1): (i) Availability check: verification whether companies declare their adherence to the (national) code without assessing the quality of the available information; Table 5.1 Types of monitoring Market-wide monitoring parties Financial market authorities Monitoring activities Country (selected) examples Availability check Bulgaria (FSC); France (AMF); UK (FSA) Member states FMAs in Belgium, Estonia, France, Germany, Lithuania, the Netherlands, Portugal and Spain. Informative value Stock exchanges Availability check Informative value Trade bodies and professional organisations (= private parties) Availability check Informative value Financial press, analysts and academics Availability check Informative value Denmark (NASDAQ OMX Copenhagen); Ireland Stock exchanges in Denmark, Estonia, Finland, Lithuania and Luxembourg France (AFEP-MEDEF); Spain (Instituto de ConsejerosAdministradores); Sweden (The Corporate Board), Italy (Assonime) Belgium (GUBERNA/FBE) N/A Source: Compiled from the study of Risk Metrics Group (2009). 140 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau (ii) Informative value check: verification whether the information provided by the company enables market actors to make an informed judgement about the companies’ corporate governance practices. Our experience with monitoring the compliance with the Belgian Corporate Governance Code for listed companies1 clearly illustrates the relative value of such public monitoring. The code has been ‘dissected’ in its different variables, describing the numerous recommendations and guidelines. On a total of more than 300 variables, only some 47 variables are publicly measurable data while some 34 variables need an explicit declaration as to comply-or-explain.2 These statistics already show that the vast majority of the Code’s recommendations cannot be measured or evaluated from the outside. Moreover, analysing in more detail the variables that can be monitored from the outside, they clearly are limited to either input variables or formal procedure descriptions. Examples of the first category are the number of board members, the type of directors (executive, non-executive, either independent or not), the presence of board committees, the number of board and committee meetings, the separation of chair and CEO roles, etc. Examples of the disclosure of formal procedures are the obligation to publish a corporate governance charter, describing the governance structures and the roles of the board and of its respective committees, versus those of management and shareholders. Consequently, elements that are completely missing from such public monitoring are the requirements that the board should act as a collegial body, reaches decisions in the long-term interest of the company, the duty of directors to perform a professional job, to challenge the management in a constructive way, etc. Board effectiveness is no absolute given as codes might assume Remaining for a moment with the public assessment of the governance quality, another element that deserves further attention is the assumption that there is one set of best practices for all relevant companies. Most national codes start from international references,3 which they adapt or translate to their local situation. To this end, the ‘dominant governance logic’ in that country (Van den Berghe et al., 2002) becomes the prevailing national reference framework for all companies concerned (either listed or unlisted companies). However, governance practices do differ quite substantially from one country to another. Even within a given country the governance challenges companies are facing might be quite different according to the shareholding composition, the structuring Reinventing Board Effectiveness 141 of the governance tripod, etc. Nonetheless, national codes start from one set of ‘best practices’, while the EU legislation obliges listed companies to carefully explain any deviation from these best practices. Such approach leads to the perception that deviating from the best practice or the so-called ‘cookie-cutter’ solution is a second best solution (Kerstetter, 2009). It is possible to defend the opposite thesis, i.e. that deviating can be a best in class practice if it leads to a best fit for the company in question. This reasoning was also put forward by Sir David Walker in his final report4 (see Figure 5.1). Although everybody agrees nowadays that ‘one size does not fit all’, the analysis of board effectiveness suffers from insufficient fine-tuning of the governance approach to the real needs of the company. A number of assumptions of traditional governance appraisals should therefore be put into question. Based on a broad overview of the academic literature as well as on our large board and board evaluation practice, the proposal is to look for a tailored ‘congruence’ model. Indeed board effectiveness should be defined from a system approach. The numerous components of board effectiveness are highly interrelated, obliging a good fit with the internal organisation (culture, people, systems) as well as with the relevant external levels (dictating formal and informal norms and obligations). Therefore, an effective board will have an optimal fit between the various internal and external elements taking into consideration the roles required of the board (Nicholson and Kiel, 2004). Moreover, in order to reach board effectiveness, we should search for a dynamic and proactive approach where the board and governance model anticipate the future challenges the corporate strategy and ambition pose to the organisation. Directors should be vigilant for the triggers that indicate The FRC has confirmed that the intended and correct interpretation is not ‘comply or else’ and that clear and well-founded explanations which support actions to enhance the long-term value of the firm should be acceptable to shareholders … The suggestion of moving from ‘comply or explain’ to ‘apply or explain’ acknowledges that there may be instances where it is in the best interests of the shareholder for the philosophy underpinning a Combined Code principle to be met in a different way from that set out in the Code itself. Transition of this kind would be a welcome development… Figure 5.1 Extract from the Walker Report (2009) 142 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau the ‘next step’ in the governance development process and help tailoring and adapting the governance system to the firm’s future ambitions and goals. But foremost, attention should be given to a reality check on the effective translation of best practices into action. Indeed, formal compliance with best practices does not always translate into action while beliefs do not automatically translate into practice as intended. To this end we cannot rely on the public monitoring but should couple such external analysis with an in-depth internal analysis how to optimise the governance structure, processes and board dynamics. The challenge is to improve their effectiveness and contribution to the long-term success of the company. In reality, certain trade-offs will have to be made between different governance options. Making governance more effective supposes focusing much more on the true value drivers offered by corporate governance Codes for listed companies have traditionally been developed as a reaction to corporate scandals or failures. We should therefore not be astonished to observe that most of their attention goes to a more robust monitoring role for the board of directors. The huge attention for monitoring, control and risk oversight unfortunately often came at the detriment of sufficient attention for the leadership, strategy and performance side of governance. This trend was further exaggerated by the attention paid to a formal compliance with the governance recommendations given the public monitoring of (part of) the governance practice in listed companies. Many criticise this trend of overly engineering and formalising the governance approach. A Belgian-experienced director, who is also chairman of the Corporate Governance Commission, put it this way: The boardroom is full of road signs, but no one wonders whether directors are good car drivers! Governance has placed too much emphasis on structure and insufficient attention to board room behaviour; of course structures are much more easy to cure than behaviour. (Herman Daems, De Tijd, 23 November 2010) It is clear that in the last couple of years, pressure has mounted to pay more attention to board behaviour. There is a common understanding that an improvement in corporate governance will in essence require behavioural change. This ‘change of emphasis’ is also promoted by the Reinventing Board Effectiveness 143 Financial Reporting Council (2011). The UK governance supervisor clearly states: Boards need to think deeply about the way in which they carry out their role and the behaviours that they display, not just about the structures and processes that they put in place. Boards are encouraged to consider how the way in which decisions are taken might affect the quality of those decisions, and the factors to be taken into account when constructing the board and reviewing its performance. The danger of overly focusing on formalism and rules in the board, as we can observe for listed companies, clearly contrasts with the evolution in the segment of unlisted companies. Those ‘closed’ companies focus much more on the true value drivers behind corporate governance, offering strategic reflection, support for the development of the business, a critical reflection platform on succession issues, etc. Our research with unlisted growth companies clearly has proven that the incentives to commit to good governance practices are not at all compliance triggers but the true value added drivers (see priority list in Figure 5.2). In our opinion they are more successful in finding the ‘non-statutory routes’ to governance implementation, as suggested by Sir David Walker (2009), as their boards and major owners have more “ownership’ of good corporate governance. Listed companies have therefore a great deal to learn from their unlisted colleagues in finding a more balanced approach towards 1. Need for a ‘second opinion’ and critical sounding board 5. To guarantee leadership (succession) and continuity 2. To avoid the danger of naval-gazing and tunnel vision Why a board of directors? 4. Need for more professional monitoring of company, management and performance Figure 5.2 3. Further growth requires more in-house expertise Top 5 drivers for an active board of directors in unlisted companies Source: Workshop GUBERNA in collaboration with VOKA (2011). 144 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau corporate governance, with more attention for the substance over the form, with more attention for value creation over formal compliance and control. Illustrative in this respect is the research by the scholars from the London Business School, McKinsey and MWM consulting (Acharya et al., 2008). Their comparative research of board practices and board effectiveness revealed fundamental differences in the way boards of listed versus unlisted (private equity portfolio companies) operate. Whilst plc boards are typically more effective at governance compliance, risk oversight, management succession and control, PE portfolio company boards score significantly better on overall effectiveness, reflecting their greater added value on strategy and performance management. This added value is driven by PE boards’ aligned focus on value creation, their sharper clarity on strategic and performance priorities and the greater engagement and commitment of their board members. They therefore propose that listed company boards should improve their effectiveness by following an integrated programme of six initiatives: refocusing on strategy and performance dialogues, reducing their size to encourage more effective collaboration, increasing the time expectation of non-executive directors, transforming how boards are educated and informed about the business, significantly increasing informal interaction with executives and exploring ways to change the remuneration structure of nonexecutives. Scanning governance and board effectiveness is only possible on the base of a critical internal assessment The financial crisis has proven that (the public monitoring of) the compliance of listed companies with the governance codes has given a false feeling of comfort as to the quality of corporate governance. It is not because a corporation is nearly 100% compliant with the transparency on formal procedures and lives up to nearly all of the input requirements that the governance practice is effective. Developing a useful governance scan can rely upon the publicly available information as a first touchstone, but should merely be based on a critical internal assessment exercise. A board evaluation is the cornerstone to complement the public monitoring exercise, confronting the board practices and the individual perceptions with the formal documents like corporate governance charters and annual governance statements. Without such ‘internal’ governance assessment, it is impossible to make any evaluation of the intrinsic governance quality. Unfortunately, we analyse the Reinventing Board Effectiveness 145 hell out of everything, except of boards! Perhaps do we think that a board meeting is such a special, mystical and inviolate thing that we shouldn’t? An overall board evaluation exercise should make an inventory of all the relevant elements of board effectiveness, as will be described in Chapters 6 through 9. Overall facts and figures about the governance practices (as disclosed in the corporate governance charters and annual governance report) will need to be complemented by individual inquiries. Such individual interviews can illuminate differences in opinion within the board on the importance and satisfaction level for relevant governance aspects. However, such an in-depth exercise does not need to be repeated every year, on the contrary. As important as a full-fledged evaluation exercise may be, it is clear that regular updates and appraisals need to set priorities and focus on the most relevant issues, the topics that deserve special attention or/and are in need of further improvement, etc. Evaluating the same dimensions over and over again may at best yield merely incremental improvements and can cause the board to overlook areas it needs to review. These follow-up appraisals will have to prioritise and focus on the most relevant ‘gaps’ that need further reflection and improvement. The periodic judgement on board effectiveness should focus on progress made and on areas for further improvement. Every 3 to 4 years the effectiveness of the appraisal process itself might need some examination. Although board assessment pays quite a lot of attention to the socalled ‘soft factors’, like director behaviour and board dynamics, there is nothing soft on such board evaluation exercise. On the contrary, board assessment may be perceived as a rather hard process and consequently, is often confronted with much scepticism from within the board room. Directors may question the fact that they – as seasoned professionals – need to be evaluated. Still, a successful process of board evaluation and continuous improvement need to have commitment from inside the boardroom. Boards have to want to change. And many boards are working very hard to avoid it. (The Korn & ferry Institute, Briefings on Talent and Leadership, Q3 2011). The reluctance towards board assessments may also vary according to the type of company and even among countries. Our in-depth review of the governance practice of all listed companies in Belgium, for example, 146 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau revealed that the requirement for periodical board evaluations is one of the least respected governance recommendations.5 There is quite some resistance to the requirement of a periodic board assessment, let alone that boards have sympathy for externally supported board assessment exercises. In fact, those statistics do not provide any inside into the ‘profoundness’ of the board evaluation. The European study by Heidrick & Struggles (2011) states that board evaluation is more a matter of conformance rather than performance. They argue that 90% of current board evaluations probably fall short of what is needed. Similar, Sir David Walker (2009) has noted that not all boards have given the evaluation process the attention and seriousness it deserves. In this respect, he argues that it is timely to promote enhanced rigour and disclosure. For a long time, board assessment was indeed in its infancy. Step by step, more academic research, more board service practices and a greater emphasis of the governance regulators on board assessment help this governance discipline evolving into a more professional competency. There is a variety of approaches to board assessment:6 such a process can be facilitated by third parties, or the company may opt for a self-evaluation process under the guidance of the chairman acting as a facilitator, interviewer and participant. When it comes to (internally) evaluating the chairman, a lead director or an independent director can guide this self-evaluation. The secretary-general can play an important intermediary role, facilitating the evaluation process. The underlying questionnaire or interview protocol can be very elaborate or at the other extreme, boards can limit themselves to open questions or even a simple brain storm session during one or other board meeting. The success of pure internal board exercises will depend on the circumstances facing the board, the nature of the issues the board is required to address and particularly, the style and disposition of the chairman. Although each approach can bring interesting messages to the table, it increasingly becomes clear that an externally supported examination7 is the only guarantee for a more objective and thorough assessment exercise. Whereas previous governance codes introduced the need for a periodic board appraisal, evaluation or assessment, more recent updates of codes and recommendations clearly attach more importance to the quality and disclosure of the board evaluation process. The pressure is mounting for independent board evaluation. Governance regulators also increasingly point to the necessity to have from time to time (e.g. every two to three years) such an externally supported board assessment. In particular, an external reviewer is believed to be able to make Reinventing Board Effectiveness 147 a more substantial critical input. Most illustrative in this respect are the extensive recommendations in the Walker Report in the United Kingdom (2009). For example, in its section 4.39, it states that many comments on the draft report emphasised the importance of the independence alongside the capability of the evaluator. It is therefore suggested that the board service advisors should form a professional grouping with the purpose to articulate appropriate evaluation standards while also providing assurance that there are no conflicts of interest with the board service providers. In light of the independent assessment, it is more appropriate to work with non-conflicted board service firms, who do not deliver other important services to the company. Today, criticism remains as to the value added to such exercise. Why should a company perform a board appraisal? In most European countries it is now a firm recommendation in the governance codes for listed companies. For others, influential investors might impose such a critical evaluation. Instead of governance being a lagging indicator, board assessment can allow companies to get ahead of the curve and make governance a leading indicator of proactive and dynamic development of the company. We do believe that the company itself, its board, its management and even its shareholders and other stakeholders should be themselves convinced of the value add such examination might bring to governance effectiveness and even to the long-term success of the company. A well-organised evaluation process can bring the necessary level of awareness to the surface, improve the understanding of the individual director’s points of view and disclose board dynamics issues. It helps identifying areas that need greater attention by the board. Deeply held tensions may arise because of insufficient involvement of (some) directors, insufficient quality of director contributions (in relation to expectations for an effective board), incorrect delineation of boundaries of roles, clear differences of view, insufficient chemistry, problematic information procurement, etc. If suppressed tension is a concern and this concern remains unchallenged, this can cause irreparable harm. Board evaluation can clarify the individual and collective responsibility of the board of directors and the CEO in light of the changing role (demands) of the board and improve the working relationship between the board and the management. Indeed, boards can become a self-correcting system (e.g. if the board realises it is failing to perform a specific function effectively, it can take action to rectify the situation). Bringing discipline to the board can enhance its effectiveness. 148 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau Like with musicians or sportsmen, they all know that whenever they think about their technique they improve their performance. (Dunne, 1997) However, the critical question remains whether performance evaluations actually improve board performance. How the practice is implemented is critical to its effectiveness: GARBAGE IN – GARBAGE OUT is the adagium (Leblanc in Conger, 2009). Many boards do not perform their assessment in a rigorous enough manner. Social norms of respect and mechanical evaluation processes get in the way of candid and constructive feedback that could actually improve a board’s performance. Board evaluations are currently defective because they do not assess individual directors. And the greatest opposition comes from the individual directors themselves. Directors feel reluctant to criticise colleagues or make remarks that might undermine the chairman’s authority. Boards are also too reluctant to pull the trigger on a nonperforming director. Either they are afraid of their vested interests and/or are looking for the path of the least resistance. Moreover, most are reluctant to solicit the input of professional service advisors. The latter have most of the time other on-going professional relations with the companies whose boards they have to assess and consequently are commercially disinclined to engage in rigorous, indepth reviews. For those service firms, board evaluation may not be viewed as particularly remunerative or worth the risk, given more lucrative assignments being done for management. Consequently, what happens in many cases is the proliferation, photocopying and passing off of substandard, paper-based board and director evaluation questionnaires. But performed well, board evaluations can play a vital role in improving corporate governance. Our experience with board evaluation practice confirms that Conger (2009) is right when he stated that Directors told us that after they initiated board evaluations, their meetings went more smoothly, they made better decisions, they acquired greater influence, and they paid more attention to longterm corporate strategy. Formal evaluations can help ensure a healthy balance of power between the board and the CEO and improve the working relationship between the two. Given the emphasis on board behaviour and governance attitude, a thorough board evaluation exercise should include a written attitude Reinventing Board Effectiveness 149 From basic compliance evaluation >>>>>>> To ‘best in class’ evaluation Compliance & benchmarking exercise Figure 5.3 Assesment of the board as an effective decision-making body Structured board review at group level + Individual director assesment and profiling (Required) evolution in board evaluation survey, assessing the capabilities of the board to function as an effective decision-making body. According to Kakabadse and Kakabadse (2008) individual director assessment and profiling takes board development to a much greater depth than board assessment review check lists, but that does not mean that structured board assessment review should not be pursued. Board assessment and review focuses conversation at only the group level. Profiling draws out group and individual behaviour and implicitly displays the level of responsibility each individual feels to make changes (see Figure 5.3). However, a word of caution needs to be added: not all boards need profiling nor do all boards accept such an exercise nor are they prepared for deep individual and team scrutiny. Questions to test this include: are the board members capable of entering into penetrating examination of board dynamics? Are they able to face up to the reality? Do directors require development in resilience, robustness and confidence to openly discuss the outcome? Profiling is simply a more intense board review process and requires a greater level of courage to participate. Conclusion The leading role of governance codes to guide and judge governance practices has been copied all over the world, not only for listed but 150 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau more and more for unlisted companies, state-owned enterprises and social profit organisations as well. Governance codes are valuable as a first step, but we need to acknowledge that they are only a partial solution to foster governance and board effectiveness. To reach the goal of good governance, codes mainly focus on the necessary (measurable) input factors, while lacking sufficient attention for more process and qualitative drivers of good governance. To this end, attention should also be paid to board dynamics, professional governance behaviour and the professional development of directors. A second important flaw of the governance codes is the underlying assumption that the governance quality can be externally monitored by the market. This approach has not proven to be sufficiently effective. Although the pressure of public scrutiny might induce boards to improve their corporate governance, the public disclosure is not a valid solution to reach the final goal of effective boards, operating in the best interest of the company. Such public monitoring dares to (quickly) evolve towards a mere window dressing and ‘tick the box’ mentality, with a focus on full compliance with a standard set of ‘best practices’. Only if we combine active public monitoring with independent critical examination of board effectiveness and governance quality will we be able to make an important step forward in making codes more effective. Such approach should necessarily be much more tailored to the specific governance challenge each governance practice poses, taking into consideration the specific corporate context, the type of capital funding (listed, closed or any mixed formula in between) and the governance structures and players in place. Although this book is about board effectiveness, one should not ignore that in order to reach this goal we need to reflect thoroughly on the role of the shareholder. Most codes devoted relatively limited attention to this important pillar of good governance. As stated in the Walker Report (2009) ‘Responsibility of shareholders as owners has been inadequately acknowledged in the past’. In our board effectiveness approach we clearly try to remedy this omission by explicitly positioning the role of the board in the context of the shareholder model. At the same time we propose to integrate the vision of the shareholder in evaluating the role and value add of the board of directors (a so-called 360° assessment). Given our focus on improving the value added of boards, we however cannot pay sufficient attention to the interaction with shareholders, nor are we able Reinventing Board Effectiveness 151 to give to shareholder governance the place it deserves in corporate governance. In order to come up with a useful board assessment, such exercise should start off with a holistic and systemic approach, integrating all relevant context factors and comparing the formal procedures and governance principles with their execution in practice as will be highlighted in the next chapter. Notes 1. GUBERNA, the Belgian Directors and Governance Institute, together with the Federation of Belgian Companies has performed monitoring studies of the compliance with the Belgian Corporate Governance Code in 2006, 2008, 2010 and 2012. For more details on the outcome of these monitoring studies see www.guberna.be 2. The comply or explain principle is commonly found in Europe. 20 out of the 22 European governance codes are based on this approach. The principle offers companies flexibility to implement the Code by explicitly stating whether that recommendation is complied with or in case of non-compliance what the explanation is for such deviation. 3. Internationally, there is the OECD code that is accepted as a broad reference code. For the unlisted companies, ecoDa recently developed an international reference framework (see respectively http://www.oecd.org/corporate/ ca/corporategovernanceprinciples/31557724.pdf and http://www.ecoda. org/Publications.html). The first European code for listed companies, that became the reference for many other (European) countries, is the UK Code (from the Cadbury Code in the nineties to the Combined Code in the 21st Century). 4. Sir David Walker led an independent review of corporate governance in the UK banking industry. His report with final recommendations was published on 26 November 2009. 5. 75% of Belgian listed (index) companies declare in their annual report that they engage in a board evaluation exercise, describing briefly the main characteristics of the process (as required by the Belgian Corporate Governance Code). 6. See e.g. Kakabadse (2008); Nadler et al. (2006). 7. When using external support for board assessment, Kakabadse (2008) gives the following suggestions to choose the most relevant service provider: • choose the person not the institution; • choose the advisor that understands you and your organisation (sensitivity to the context); • concentrate on the intellectual firepower of the consultant, not the size, grandeur or boutique nature of the institution he or she works for; • don’t haggle over pay for the quality of advice needed. 152 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau References Acharya, V., Kehoe, C. and Reyner, M. ‘Private Equity vs PLC Boards in the UK: A Comparison of Practices and Effectiveness’, Finance Working Paper No. 233/2009 (August 1, 2008). Ahrendts, A. Beyond the Burberry Check (Los Angeles: The Korn/Ferry Institute, Briefings on Talent and Leadership, Q3 2011). Carter, C.B. and Lorsch, J.W. Back to the Drawing Board. Designing Corporate Boards for a Complex World (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 2004). Conger, J.A. Boardroom Realities. Building Leaders Across Your Board (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 2009). Crainer, S. and Dearlove, D. ‘Boardroom blitz: What happened to real debate among corporate directors?’, The Conference Board Review, November/December 2007. Daems, H. ‘Besturen is meer dan regels alleen’, De Tijd (23 November 2010). Dunne, P. Running Board Meetings: How to Get the Most from Them (London and Philadelphia: Kogan Page, 1997). Financial Reporting Council, Guidance on Board Effectiveness (London: Financial Reporting Council, 2011). Heidrick & Struggles, European Corporate Governance Report 2011. Challenging Board Performance (2011). Hendry, K. and Kiel, G.C. ‘The role of the board in firm strategy: integrating agency and organisational control perspectives’, Corporate Governance – An International Review, XII (2004) 500–519. Kakabadse, A. and Kakabadse, N. Leading the Board. The Six Disciplines of WorldClass Chairmen (New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2008). Kerstetter, T.K. Board Structure: One Size Does Not Fit All (The Board Blog, 24 November 2009). Leblanc, R. Getting the right directors on your board. In: Conger, J.A. Boardroom Realities. Building Leaders Across Your Board (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 2009), pp. 145–196. Nadler, D.A., Behan, B.A. and Nadler, M.B. Building Better Boards. A Blueprint for Effective Governance (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 2006). Nicholson, G.J. and Kiel, G.C. ‘A framework for diagnosing board effectiveness’, Corporate Governance – An International Review, XII (2004) 442–460. Sonnenfeld, J.A. ‘What makes great boards great’, Harvard Business Review, VIII (2002) 106–113. Sonnenfeld, J.A. and Ward, A. Conventional wisdom, conventional mythology, and the true character of board governance. In: Conger, J.A. Boardroom Realities. Building Leaders Across Your Board (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 2009), pp. 445–468. Van den Berghe, L. and Levrau, A. ‘Measuring the quality of corporate governance: in search for a tailor-made approach?’, Journal of General Management, XXVIII (2003) 71–86. Van den Berghe, L., Levrau, A., Carchon, S. and Van der Elst, C. Corporate Governance in a Globalising World: Convergence or Divergence? A European Perspective (Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers, 2002). Walker, D. A Review of Corporate Governance in UK Banks and Other Financial Industry Entities (London: The Walker Review Secretariat, 2009). 6 Fine-tuning Board Effectiveness Is Not Enough Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau The problem is that directors are essentially trying to make a refurbished 1955 Chevrolet keep up with the traffic on a twentyfirst century superhighway. (Carter and Lorsch, 2004, p. 29) Assessment of governance and board effectiveness is best served by a holistic system approach Defining governance and board effectiveness is not a straightforward exercise. In principle, boards are seen to be responsible for reaching the corporate goal and ambition. As an example, the Belgian corporate law states that it is the board’s duty (its reason for being) to do anything that is necessary in order to realise the corporate goal. Based on the fact that directors have been blamed (or even attacked) for not being able to prevent corporate collapses during the ‘Internet bubble’ or for the failures during the financial crisis, this seems to be the opinion of society as well. However, academic research has made it clear that it is not feasible to directly link board practice with corporate performance. In fact, boards do not operate in isolation but need to rely on management and the corporation in general to fulfil their ambitious role. Consequently, it is impossible to judge the value of a board on its own in isolation of the ‘system’ it operates in. Developing an understanding of governance and board effectiveness requires a holistic framework that includes all potential governance mechanisms as well as those relevant elements the governance model needs to be aligned with. In fact, board effectiveness is best served by a ‘system approach’ that views boards as dynamic and open social (and political) systems, where a change in one element will affect other elements in the system. 153 154 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau Such approach is inherently different from the one traditionally used in academic research. Historically most academic research is centred around specific sub-elements of the governance system and its effectiveness is judged on the basis of corporate results, such as the link between performance and the presence of independent directors, or the splitting of the roles of CEO and chairman (Daily et al., 2003). Research of Levrau (2007) clearly showed that in reality the link between board and corporate performance works in an indirect way. Moreover, the focus on input factors alone was by far insufficient to measure board effectiveness. The model developed by Levrau (2007), shown in Figure 6.1, which built further on previous work of Nicholson and Kiel (2004) and Forbes and Milliken (1999), demonstrates that we need to look at board effectiveness in different steps: from input over board process to board output, while taking into consideration the numerous interactions between all of the constituent elements within the broader framework of external boundaries (legislative and societal environment as well as the industrial environment) and contingencies (the relationship between the board and management, respectively shareholders). Boundaries Legislative and societal environment Industrial environment BOARD OF DIRECTORS AS A SYSTEM Input BOARD Composition Output INTERACTION & BEHAVIOUR BOARD TASK PERFORMANCE Cohesiveness Competence Structure Actual <> Conflict Debate Expected Feedback Figure 6.1 A congruence model for board effectiveness Board/management relationship Firm performance Size Processes Contingencies Board/shareholder relationship Fine-tuning Board Effectiveness Is Not Enough The Right FollowThrough The Right Remuneration 155 The Right Structures The Right People Board effectiveness The Right Issues The Right Process The Right Information The Right Culture Figure 6.2 Board effectiveness tool Paying more attention to the board process itself seemed to be the remedy, also in light of the failure of many companies fully compliant with the input and formal requirements of the governance codes. The challenge, however, is to capture these insights and translate the academic models into a practical instrument that support value adding board evaluation exercises. To this end we developed an own evaluation methodology for measuring board effectiveness, which is also inspired by a comparable approach promoted by the NACD. This tool is illustrated in Figure 6.2. The methodology is built on the assumption that the great challenge for any board was to find the right governance approach. Such governance approach should be in line with the (formal) requirements of the governance codes while at the same time enabling the development of the internal processes, culture and behaviour in order to allow the board to realise the value add it is supposed to deliver. Although this framework gains excellent feedback from the companies as a guide for developing a board evaluation exercise, it becomes clear that it is less adapted and suitable for judging the value added of the board (the final goal) and for understanding the interplay and trade-offs between the different elements that facilitate such value creation. In fact, the tool is still too much focusing on governance as an end in itself, rather than as 156 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau a means to an end. We have therefore developed a new holistic model that should remedy the flaws of the actual approach. Measuring board effectiveness should start with the question what effectiveness really means. We consider a board to be effective if it facilitates the creation of value added for the company, its management, its shareholders and all of its relevant stakeholders. The board’s value add capacity will be enhanced if we develop a better insight into what really drives board output. In our opinion, the two main drivers are effective decision-making and a board that optimally performs its role in line with the relevant context factors (see Figure 6.3). Each of these board output drivers in themselves is influenced by a whole set of determining factors, which operate and impact each other in a dynamic and interactive way. In the remainder of this chapter we will focus on the question what a congruent and best fit board role should look like, what elements may interfere in defining this role and to what extent the board’s role can be aligned with the relevant context factors. Figure 6.4 gives an overview of An effective board creates value added for the company 1. A congruent & best fit board role 2. Effective board decision-making 3. Board and director effectiveness (assumed vs real value added) are regularly assessed in an objective and critical way Figure 6.3 A systems framework for board effectiveness assessment Fine-tuning Board Effectiveness Is Not Enough Performance 1.1. External context – Laws & regulation – Code recommendations – Societal norms 157 1.4. Leadership DIRECT External monitoring & benchmarking 1.5. Strategy 1.2. Business context – Business life cycle – Business complexity & environment – Business performance & financial situation – Stakeholders Dual Role 1. A congruent & best fit board role 1.6. Advice Pro-active governance 1.3. Internal context Shareholder model Board model Management model CONTROL 1.7. Monitor Alignment Figure 6.4 Conformance A congruent and best fit board role the framework we developed to this end. Each of the constituent parts will be further analysed in greater detail in the following paragraphs. The second board output driver, effective board decision-making, will be studied in Chapter 8. Defining the ‘best fit’ governance structure A sophisticated understanding of the roles a board has to play and the interplay between those roles and the company’s environment is central to any assessment of board effectiveness. (Nicholson and Kiel, 2004) The model positions the board as an open system, interacting with the firm’s environment, both the external environment (1.1), the business environment (1.2) and the internal organisational environment (1.3). As Nicholson and Kiel (2004) pointed out, only boards that maintain a 158 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau balance with the internal and external environment will flourish. Besides the respect for the legal obligations (1.1.1), companies should align their board model and governance approach with the ‘best practice’ guidance, given by the relevant governance codes (1.1.2), while paying sufficient attention to the valid societal norms and expectations (1.1.3). However, the company must use the flexibility offered to translate the guidance into a fit with the corporate situation (1.2) including the stage in its life cycle, the challenges the company is facing, the strategy it envisions etc. (i.e. finding a pro-active congruence). In addition, the board model should perfectly be aligned with the other governance tripod bodies (referring to the shareholder structure and management model). It is indeed important that the positioning of the board of directors is in line with the respective roles of shareholders and management while paying special attention to their mutual interaction (1.3). These three steps, highlighted in Figure 6.4 are further analysed in the next paragraphs. External contingency factors Although legal principles set the minimum (theoretical) governance framework, for a long time most legislation and corporate bylaws stayed rather general in their description of the board’s structure and role. Consequently heterogeneous board and governance practices were developed, with some resembling ‘best practices’, while others are subject to (serious) critique and certainly show room for improvement. This has given lean way to the development of a large set of self-regulatory principles and recommendations. Both are intertwined, in the sense that in the EU, those self-regulatory principles have been embedded into law through the obligation for listed companies to designate a code of reference and respect the ‘comply or explain’ approach. But the legalisation of the self-regulatory guidance goes much further nowadays. In Europe, some specific parts of these codes have become mandatory (e.g. necessity to install an audit committee), while some member states go much further in ‘gold plating’ by integrating numerous other parts of their national code into corporate law (see e.g. the laws on gender quota for board composition, specific legislation on executive remuneration, the obligation to set up a remuneration committee, a legal definition of what constitutes an independent director, etc.). The evolution in legal reforms and self-regulatory requirements are all aimed at empowering the board and directors in performing their roles. Besides the legal principles and the code recommendations, societal norms also impact the board’s role. The empowerment of the board, as prescribed by the numerous recent governance codes, coincides Fine-tuning Board Effectiveness Is Not Enough 159 with the increase in societal expectations towards boards of directors and corporate leaders. Alongside this evolution, the societal interest in governance in general and boards of directors more specifically has substantially increased. Main Street has bypassed Wall Street in calling directors to account for the performance of their duties, leading to increased pressure on boards to perform effectively. Inquiries with board members (such as the one regularly done by McKinsey) revealed that the directors themselves want to live up to these societal expectations and express their interest in going beyond the traditional board scope by paying more attention to, for example, corporate strategy and business performance. Also academic researchers are impacted by this expansion of societal expectations towards boards. Historically, the governance literature concentrated on a single specific role of the board (the so-called mono-paradigm approach), hereby ignoring the need for an integrated approach as well as the numerous interactions between the different board roles (Nicholson and Kiel, 2004). More recently, the academic literature expanded its approach towards board effectiveness from a mono-paradigm to a multi-paradigm approach. These evolutions prove the dynamic approach needed to study board effectiveness. However, some academics have critique on the trend towards board empowerment and plead for a minimalist approach. Steen Thomsen (2008) states that boards become overloaded with responsibilities. They will either fail to live up to expectations or have dysfunctional effects on company behaviour and performance. Whereas they clearly have a role to play on the level of monitoring, management replacement, control and ratification of major decisions, they should abstain from playing a major role in strategy, risk management, shareholder and stakeholder relations. Like penicillin, boards may be essential for a limited range of very important tasks, but are no cure to all pains. This minimalist approach is mainly based on the limitations boards are facing, such as the information gap non-executive directors are confronted with and the limited resources available for board decision-making (available time, board support, difficulties with group decision-making). This seems to us a ‘defeatist’ point of view. We are, in contrast, convinced of the necessity to upgrade the board’s role and decision-making process because there is no valid alternative to a well-functioning and empowered board of directors. The corporate context factors The corporate context (including both external and internal business factors) also affects the conditions for board effectiveness. Important factors in this respect are the specific development cycle of the 160 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau company (development phase of the business and life cycle considerations: start-up, growth company, maturing business), the business performance (prospering, going concern or in trouble), the financial situation/structure (the need for capital), the competitive market position and evolution (new competitors, globalising markets), the business environment (technological turbulence, rapid technological change), etc. Comparing the governance in start-ups versus mature businesses or in companies in good financial shape versus those in crisis mode clearly reveals the need for adapting the board’s role and governance approach to those relevant corporate context factors. A small (unlisted) company, who is willing to develop a more active role for its board, will need to realise a serious upgrade in its corporate reporting, accountability and transparency in order to attract external directors who want to take up this responsibility (and liability). At the same time, due to the lack of sufficient in-house expertise, those directors might well expect to be confronted with numerous demands for advice and support also outside their regular role as directors. Strategy reflection might be much more important than any other board role. At the other end of the spectrum, a large (listed) company will have access to all relevant in-house or external expertise and be able to provide its directors with a – sometimes overwhelming – set of detailed information, strategy plans etc. Here the board might be much more leaning towards monitoring than to any other board duty. Consequently, a director who wants to serve in different types of corporate contexts should be well aware of the huge differences in governance approach. It is not that he or she has to behave as a ‘chameleon’, but there are ‘horses for courses’. Board effectiveness also presumes alignment with the complexity of the business. According to Carter and Lorsch (2004) complexity seems to be more important than corporate size to define the board’s role. The more diverse the portfolio of businesses, the more complex the role of the board becomes to oversee all of the relevant business contexts. The more international the business, the more complex the corporate structure becomes, leading to the need for an oversight of all of these corporate entities by the main board. Next to the governance role to be played by the main board, that board will need to install a tailored system of ‘internal governance’ at the level of the local/subsidiary boards as well as guaranteeing the interface with the main board. Internal or governance contingency factors In a system approach, it has to be made clear from the outset that numerous specific board elements will impact each other. A key driver Fine-tuning Board Effectiveness Is Not Enough 161 of board effectiveness is the optimal alignment of the board model with the shareholder, stakeholder and management model. In most cases, the shareholder model will substantially impact if not dictate the board model. In this respect it is essential to analyse the shareholding structure (degree of control; minority shareholders or not, etc.) and typology (families, joint venture between entrepreneurs, private equity, public capital market, institutional investors, public sector, etc.), as well as the development phase of the corporate shareholders (family life cycle, life cycle private equity, etc.). Moreover, boards need to have a very clear sense of what shareholders want to achieve. Numerous governance models consider directors as the stewards of shareholders, having a clear fiduciary duty towards shareholders. In a more stakeholder-oriented model, the board has a broader duty, focusing on the interest of the company and all its related parties. Although directors will normally define the management model, it is clear from governance practice that the management model and the type of leadership will in turn substantially impact the position and operation of the board. Moreover board effectiveness is substantially affected by the interface between management and the board and between the CEO and the chair of the board (the cutting edge management/board). Each company, each director or top manager may have a specific view on the role of the board and the best board model. Changes in top management constellation, board composition or board chair may substantially impact board practices. Conger (2009) developed a board typology, based on the position of management and its relationship with the board (see Figure 6.5). Board type 1 = monitors management in order for management to conduct the business in the best interest of the owners Board type 2 = partnering with management and case of joint decision-making Board type 3 = legitimating management to outside constituencies Board type 4 = controlling management on behalf of a dominant owner Board type 5 = is controlled by management, consequently limited to a pure regulatory body Figure 6.5 Board typologies in function of relationship with management 162 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau Ceremonial board = no formal decision-making Rubber stamping board = only role is agreement with finalised decisions Statutory board = discussions limited to formalistic role of the board (with limited role in strategy process) Pro-active board = much more active involvement of directors in strategy and decision-making, with board committees, independent directors etc. Participative board = with open debate culture, striving to reach consensus between management and the board, harmony and complementarily between board and management Figure 6.6 Board typologies in function of decision-making role Most boards struggle with drawing the right mix of board roles (Carter and Lorsch 2004). At one end of the spectrum boards are merely watch dogs that limit their role to observing events; they only act if they sense that something is amiss. Their only real option if the company falters is to replace the CEO. At the other extreme are the pilot boards that have much higher aspirations: its members believe that they should contribute to discussions and decisions about the company’s direction. The non-executives want to be very involved with management in making many key decisions and probing performance.1 The spectrum of board roles in relation to the impact of the board on corporate decision-making, might be summarised as follows in Figure 6.6. In practice, most boards are somewhere in-between. The challenge is therefore to be explicit on the distinct board duties: monitoring the company and management’s performance (minimal duty for every board, but question is what level of detail?), making major decisions (such as nomination/replacement of CEO, strategic decisions, major capital expenditures, M&A, capital structure & dividends; some are also involved in organisational structure changes) and offering advice and council to management (let management benefit from the directors’ experience and wisdom). Board task performance Judging board performance refers to the comparison between the expected role of the board (see points 1.4 through 1.7. in Figure 6.4) with its real value added. From a legal point of view, defining the Fine-tuning Board Effectiveness Is Not Enough 163 (expected) role of the board of directors is the right and duty of the shareholders or founders of an organisation. In fact, besides the legal responsibilities, the board’s decision-power is delegated to them by the shareholders. At the same time, shareholders are the ultimate judges of the performance of the board. They have the power to give discharge for a good performance or, if they judge that directors did not perform accordingly to their wish, they can dismiss the directors and nominate others. However, shareholders will seldom describe the expected role of the board in sufficient detail (in the bylaws) nor will the shareholders’ meeting be the public domain for a critical evaluation of board performance. When shareholders are outsiders (dispersed shareholding and no representation on the board) board effectiveness will be more an internal ‘self-regulatory’ issue, mostly under the pressure of a governance code. On the other hand of the spectrum, when shareholders are insiders (more concentrated shareholding and representation on the board) they again will not use the shareholders meeting to come up with a thorough board evaluation, but use -again- an internal approach to express their opinion on board performance. The analysis of the formal role of the board can be based on quite a number of reference documents, such as bylaws, statutes, corporate governance or board and committee charters, and internal regulations (e.g. delegation policies, management duties etc). However, to judge the real role of the board other information resources will be needed. A first indication of the board practice can be found in the Board Agenda and the Board Minutes. Of course, to be sure about the board output further inquiries with individual board members, the board secretary, the management and eventually with some important shareholders will be needed to complete the full picture. If governance should serve the company well, the board’s role should not only be judged in a retrospective way (did the board perform up to the set standards?) but in a prospective way as well (what are the expectations for the future evolution of the board, given the corporate strategy, ambitions and challenges?). Measuring board performance against the EXPECTED role of the board of directors Based on the (practical) guidelines of governance codes as well as on the academic input from the multi-paradigm theories, we can state that all boards should perform the following four roles (see Figure 6.4): ● ● Making sure the company has the right leadership (1.4) Deciding upon the strategic direction of the company and how this should be realised (1.5) 164 ● ● Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau Monitoring execution and results, including also the governance scan and board evaluation (1.7) Advisory/support function (resource-based view on the role of directors, 1.6). The many corporate failures have put the spotlights on the monitoring role of boards, pushing their stewardship role into the background. Most boards of directors tend to focus too much on control to the detriment of corporate development. Today the governance agenda might be unbalanced with too much attention for reporting and disclosure with the danger that the board concentrates far too much on monitoring and control (conformance), with less time available for direction and resource provision. (Nordberg, 2011) There is a plea to invest the available board time in a more balanced involvement in the various roles. But as discussed in the previous section, the relative importance of these major categories of board duties may substantially differ from one board to another depending on or influenced by the context. Given the need to develop a more holistic approach towards board effectiveness, each of these major roles raises quite a number of additional issues. Leadership The leadership role of the board is one of its most crucial tasks. It does not only consist of appointing the right leadership team and defining a workable delegation policy, but it also includes the duty to come to grips with a clear understanding of the nature and purpose of the organisation as a touch stone for judging strategic ambitions and corporate performance. From time to time, it is necessary that the board reflects somewhat deeper and decides on the corporate values, the ambition and the strategic goals of the corporation, to be proposed and approved by the shareholders’ meeting. This in itself is a tough job, because boards might be responsible to a very diverse set of shareholders, whose interests are not per definition aligned (e.g. widely varying investment horizons). Moreover, they have to take stakeholders’ interests into consideration. Apparently, board practices on balancing shareholder and stakeholder interests vary across different types of companies. According to research of London Business School and McKinsey (2008) listed companies Fine-tuning Board Effectiveness Is Not Enough 165 attach significantly more attention to stakeholder interests than their colleagues in private equity (PE) backed companies. This last board category is closely interwoven with its shareholders and has consequently a clear view on their interests. They focus nearly exclusively on corporate financial performance and cash flow. On the contrary publicly listed companies (plc) boards are faced with a wide variety of more distant shareholders and are open to public scrutiny to a much larger degree. Such boards invest much more time in developing a good dialogue and the right mix of attention for all sorts of shareholders and stakeholders’ interests. Family businesses operate somewhat in between. By definition they are much more sensible to the long-term survival of the firm and have a closer relationship to their important stakeholders than any other type of business. At the same time they operate – to some extent – as PE-backed companies with a much closer shareholder monitoring. Directors must exercise judgement and have a real challenge in deciding to whom they are really responsible and where there commitments ultimately lie. The financial crisis has given a boost to a higher sensitivity of boards towards fostering long-term value creation and corporate success within a framework of corporate social responsibilities. In this respect it is worthwhile to remember that boards have much more difficulties than a sports team: where a sports team has specificity and clarity, directors face ambiguity, diversity and multiple goals (Conger, 2009). Boards have to manage a complex set of goals, which may be strict trade-offs (cash for dividends or investments) or synergistic (invest in supply-chain to increase cost effectiveness and customer satisfaction). The multiplicity of goals makes one parameter of teamwork effectiveness challenging. Judging board effectiveness on the base of the evolution of the share price or even total shareholder return – as practiced in many academic publications – is therefore no longer a valid route. It is essential for directors to build a shared view of the corporate context, a holistic common understanding of the enterprise, its vision, goals, values and performance expectations (financial as well as non-financial ones). The chairman and the CEO play an important role in communicating and championing the organisation’s mission, values and strategy in order to reach a shared understanding about the nature and purpose of the organisation, the internal and external challenges and the direction to take in the future. An interesting test to check the alignment of the board and management can be to ask the board and top management about its raison d’être, the final goals of the company and its objectives to reach. Aligned focus on value creation and a sharp clarity 166 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau on strategic and performance priorities are seen to be key drivers of board effectiveness. A continuous effort of the board is to ensure that the company has the right ‘daily’ leadership. In fact, the board has only a part-time presence in the company and as such is not in the position to run the company. To this end the board has to appoint a competent management team that perfectly fits with the corporate strategy, ambitions, development cycle and governance model of the firm and as such aligning leadership with strategy. Although some shareholder models might place the responsibility for nominating the corporate leader with the shareholders, most governance recommendations consider it good practice that the board (eventually with the support of a nomination and remuneration committee) takes care of the nomination process and the contract negotiations for the top executives. Whatever the type of management structure chosen, there will be a key person, the CEO, who acts as the leader of the organisation. For a board it is essential to be aware to what extent the CEO commands the respect of the top team. Therefore the CEO will have to play a key role in the nomination process of ‘his or her’ management team. Depending upon the shareholder model and the shareholder impact, it will be entirely or partly the board’s role to define the delegation of power (and the empowerment philosophy), the authorisation levels as well as the organisation of accountability. The right level of delegation to management will depend upon numerous corporate and context factors. There is no right delegation or leadership style, what is important is to understand where shareholders and directors stand on this matter, not to neglect neither the impact of the management capabilities nor style preferences. From time to time, the board should reflect on the empowerment philosophy, its application in practice and its alignment with the management potential and the corporate strategy and ambitions (for some reflection questions, see Figure 6.6). Whatever the level of board engagement, delegation to management will always be substantial, because non-executive directors cannot (continuously) perform a (daily) management function. Therefore board effectiveness analysis should focus on the question if there are clear lines about which decisions necessitate board approval, which points need to be on the board’s agenda, etc. Although this might be explicated in a governance charter, the reality is much tougher than such charters might assume. Assuming that the dividing line between the board’s role and that of management is fixed is totally incorrect. The distinction between management and governance is not cut-and-dried. Fine-tuning Board Effectiveness Is Not Enough ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ 167 To what extent do directors want to be informed advisors to the CEO? What variables does the board want to monitor closely (financial info, competition info, risk exposures, management succession, employee morale, customer satisfaction)? How extensively does the board want to be involved in setting and evaluating strategy (only corporate level, after the strategy has been defined or part of that development)? What decisions and approvals are the board’s domain rather than that of management? How will we monitor the performance of the CEO and the company (aggregate outcomes, key drivers of performance, corporate level or business unit information, etc)? Figure 6.7 Reflection questions Corporate governance is about the exercise of power over corporate entities (Tricker, 2000): if management is about running the business, governance is about seeing that the business is run properly (Tricker, 1984). A continuous attention for a good understanding of each other’s role, coupled with sufficient flexibility (e.g. in case of unforeseen questions or in crisis situation) and empathy for the concrete execution of the delegation policy, are cornerstones of good governance (see e.g. Useem, 2006). Our research of Belgian governance practices clearly reveal that all listed companies nowadays have a corporate governance charter, describing the respective roles of the board and management. Nonetheless the execution in practice of those written procedures appears to be far from evident. The collaboration and interaction between those two main corporate bodies, board and management, is one of the most delicate elements for effective governance. In practice, the execution of written procedures is far from evident and remains a point of attention in all kind of companies. This is clearly a point where public monitoring is inadequate. Only a thorough in-depth evaluation of board effectiveness will be able to detect the points of attention that need further improvement. Special attention should be given to the relationship and interaction with the CEO. The board and the CEO must work together as partners; there really is no other way. Unfortunately, boards are rarely explicit about figuring out the best way to work effectively with the CEO, even not when a new CEO enters into office. Moreover, enhancing board power made the relationship with the CEO more problematic. 168 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau Increasingly, this is a complicated relationship and such tensions are not recognised by those pressing for governance reform, or by directors themselves (Carter and Lorsch, 2004). It is crucial to clarify the working relationship with the CEO and the senior management. The board has the ultimate legal authority but the reality is much more complex and the power relationship may well be the reverse. The directors are overwhelmingly dependent on the CEO for planning their meetings and providing them the information and knowledge they need. The board can only be as effective as the CEO wants it to be. Directors who understand that management has many levers of power will approach their task in a very different way from those who believe that they hold most of the power. In this sense, boards embody an interesting paradox: they are simultaneously among the most and the least hierarchical institutions in the business world. In order for boards to fulfil their leadership role, they should devote sufficient attention to talent management and succession planning (follow-up on the pipeline). Unfortunately, in practice this seems to be a point that does not receive the attention it should get. The interview data in our research of Belgian governance practices revealed that in most listed companies, succession planning of senior management is not a priority on the board’s agenda. Similar findings are reported for other countries. For example, only 1 out of 3 directors interviewed by McKinsey (McKinsey Quarterly, February 2008) reported that their boards have experience with talent management. In contrast, another McKinsey research (Acharya et al., 2008), revealed that listed boards perform a much broader role on people issues than their counterparts in the PE portfolio companies. They are involved in key management development process and are more active in defining remuneration policies. However, they are more advisory than directive and slower to act when changes are needed. Monitoring executive performance is a crucial element in the board’s leadership role. Such exercise is important for deciding upon the career development of the top team (and succession planning) as well as for deciding upon the variable remuneration (performance-based remuneration). CEO appraisal is a key to effective monitoring of the company’s performance and is a way for directors to build their understanding of how they all see the company and its leader (Carter and Lorsch, 2004). Our research of Belgian governance practices in listed companies shows that a yearly CEO evaluation exercise is a well-established event. A more complex question is the issue to what extent the board should also evaluate the performance of senior executives. In practice, the CEO will take Fine-tuning Board Effectiveness Is Not Enough 169 the lead in evaluating his top management team, while most boards will then decide in consultation with the CEO on the final appreciation of the top team. However, this interactive evaluation exercise poses a difficult balancing act between the leadership role of the board and the leadership role of the CEO. Being aware of that sensitive balance is crucial for effective governance practices. Given that the monitoring of executive performance will form the base for deciding upon variable executive remuneration, such an annual evaluation process includes several steps. Our own experience in remuneration committees coincides to a large extent with the proposals of Conger (2009) and Carter and Lorsch (2004) as set out in Figure 6.8. Step 1 Establishing evaluation targets (start of the year): finding the right objectives and measures; including both financial and non-financial targets; with attention for leadership skills, talent management (and succession planning), efforts at internal and external communications; an effective appraisal uses objectives that focus on behaviours and actions that the CEO can control directly. It should also adjust for changes in industry and economy; Step 2 Reviewing performance (on a regular basis, at least at mid year): checking whether on track; Step 3 Assessing results and determining rewards (end of the year): such an assessment can start with a self-assessment by the CEO. However, companies may not solely rely on CEO self-evaluations! Self-evaluation data should be balanced with other inside and outside information: remuneration committee/board assessment, whereby the board should distinguish between performance of the CEO and performance of the company and visit also how the CEO is perceived from within (by employees); this inside information should be complemented with information of performance vis-à-vis customers, investors including also comparison with peers; but also individual board members could give their personal view; some even propose written evaluations of the CEO’s performance by each director (combining open ended questions with scaling questions) because written feedback forces greater clarity and reflection. Anyway, it is good to foresee a set of performance levels, such as poor, acceptable & outstanding for each of the relevant key performance indicators (KPIs). Figure 6.8 Evaluation process of executive management 170 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau However, it is essential to implement this general framework with sufficient flexibility and tailor the ‘ideal’ process framework to the specific board context of each company. Moreover, directors should be aware that performance feedback is an emotional process that poses the danger of defensive attitudes (certainly when such evaluation deviates substantially from the self-evaluation), mishear what is intended (where the specific KPI’s sufficiently clear?), etc. The more KPIs can be made explicit and measurable, the less confusion performance assessment might pose. The more qualitative performance elements become, the more vigilant the board should be in order to prevent that tensions pop up at each performance feedback. The board’s role in deciding upon executive remuneration has not only been on the forefront of the recent governance literature, it is a top item in media attention as well. Based on societal and political critique, boards are blamed for failing in their duty to align the executive remuneration with the long-term performance of the company. Such critique is universal and points to a policy of ‘paying for non-performance’ and of overly generous bonus systems with the wrong incentives. In the slipstream of this critique, substantial new legislation has been developed. Shareholders are given more countervailing power, while the politicians increasingly interfere directly in defining the executive remuneration construction. Research (Baeten, 2012) has clearly proven that a governance model, where shareholders are on the board, performs a far tougher monitoring role on executive remuneration than models with dispersed and more distant shareholders. This research also highlights that remuneration committees might lead to more sophisticated remuneration models (with more complex short and long-term incentives) and more benchmarking, leading to an upward trend in pay levels (racketing effect). Therefore, an analysis of board effectiveness should devote sufficient attention to the board’s attitude and role towards the monitoring of executive remuneration in three areas (design, decisionmaking process and disclosure). Strategy The strategic role of the board of directors has historically been subject to much dispute, especially in the management literature. 2 Not surprisingly, there is no board duty that is executed with so many nuances around the globe as the interference of directors in the strategic process. Consequently any board evaluation should carefully check whether there is an explicit view on the role of the board of directors in the strategy cycle. There should be a clear view on the process of strategy Fine-tuning Board Effectiveness Is Not Enough 171 Shareholders Management BoD Aims/Objectives Ambition Feedback & adjustment Strategy cycle Monitoring implementation Strategic choices BoD & management Execution/ implementation BoD Management Figure 6.9 Conceptual model of the strategy cycle development and the respective role of the board and management. This reflection should be done in joint effort between the board and management. In fact, from a governance point of view, shareholders, management and the board should regularly interact to define, execute and evaluate the corporate strategy. We developed a conceptual model to describe the potential interaction and respective roles (Figure 6.9). The strategic role of the board is linked to the general scope of the board of directors (e.g. pilot versus watch dog) and the complementary role of executives and (eventually) shareholders. Instructive in this respect may be the observation whether the board receives strategy proposals and possible strategic scenarios or whether its role is limited to approving a finalised strategy proposal. Or on the other hand, the board should be aware to what extent shareholders want to (directly) interfere in important strategic choices and decisions. Delineating strategic responsibilities is an important duty and distinctive board models will lead to different strategy role models (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2008). Strategy is a dynamic process whereby the board can organise an annual retreat for thorough strategic reflection, but throughout the remainder of the year strategic issues and their execution will have to be further reflected upon. Directors have a role to play in the follow-up 172 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau of the strategy execution and should consequently be informed of how well (or not) the process of strategy is proceeding. The quality of the strategic decision-making process depends on quite a number of important aspects, as highlighted in the following Figure 6.10. Because of the increasing volatility, directors should go beyond the expected and be prepared for major adverse effects, anticipating change and asking for different scenarios. Taking sufficient time for ‘what if’ discussions, even debating alternative responses in a hypothetical context may be worthwhile. Versatility requires attentiveness to the context and its demands, anticipating when change is required. Some reflection questions on strategy are provided by Conger (2009) (see Figure 6.11). A real-life example of how a Dutch independent director challenges management on a big acquisition deal is provided in Figure 6.12. Moreover, ex-post evaluations and lessons learned are important to build a culture of continuous improvement in the board’s performance. It is not straightforward to recognise mistakes, but one can learn a lot from an ex-post evaluation of critical strategic decisions, such as M&A, large investments or divestments, etc. Recognising and acting on a failed course of action is critical for governance effectiveness. ● ● ● ● ● ● Taking all relevant goals into consideration; For each alternative the respective advantages and disadvantages, potential return, costs and risks have to be evaluated carefully; Intensive search for extra, new relevant information; Serious attention for the information and expert views of those that oppose the/some proposals; Final screening of advantages and disadvantages before making final choice; Coupling the choice with a detailed implementation (and crisis) plan. Figure 6.10 ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ Aspects of the strategic decision-making proces Does this proposal fit with the general strategy? What is the cost of not doing this? Are there alternatives? What are the unseen risks? Who would oppose this? Figure 6.11 Reflection questions on strategy Fine-tuning Board Effectiveness Is Not Enough 173 The size of the acquisition is really big and reflecting the potential deal again, I would appreciate if you could explain in more depth, at our next board meeting, some aspects of the deal such as: ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ Certainty to realise the ‘longer term synergy opportunities’ as described. Which managers (both from acquired company and our own division) will constitute the team that will run the new business and its integration? Will the quick exclusivity/high price be counterbalanced by a beneficial S&P Agreement (less reps and warranties?) Which person in the management board will be responsible for the acquisition and the subsequent integration? Will/could our responsible executive board member play a role in the BB project after his retirement? Combined procurement. Will the deal influence, in a material way, the corporate tax strategy? Figure 6.12 Reflection questions on M&As At the same time such more elaborate strategy process may reveal quite a lot about the management team. Are directors conscious of the spread of views amongst the management on the vision and strategy? Are they aware of tensions on the strategic course between the members of the top management team? Our governance research on listed companies in Belgium has revealed that in practice top management is not inclined to inform the board on differences in opinion within the top team, nor do they want to come to the board with a strategy proposal that does not receive the support of the whole team. Consequently it might be interesting for directors to become more attentive to the strategy process behind the scene, for example, which proposals do not get into the board room. An interesting test in this respect is to question management about the market challenges, the strains confronting the company and the route it should take. Ideally a strategic conclave might create a more open atmosphere than a regular board meeting and as such might reveal a deeper understanding of the strategic views of the different members of the management team. Although most boards want to be (more) involved in the strategy development (Carter and Lorsch, 2004), some academics are critical about this evolution. Thomsen (2008), for example, is convinced that the marginal value of a board of directors steeply declines when 174 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau it comes to their involvement in strategy (idem for risk management, shareholder and stakeholder relations). Thomsen states that – due to the lack of insight and information – (independent) directors are rather enablers than generators of strategy. Also research of the London Business School (Acharya et al., 2008) revealed that the role of listed companies’ boards is usually at best limited to challenging the strategy developed by management. Their directors are not involved early and often enough in the strategy process, not being presented with or exploring credible alternatives, or having sufficient information and insight to effectively engage in challenging the executive team. On the opposite end of the spectrum stands the private equity portfolio company boards who by far outperform the listed companies’ boards mainly because of their higher involvement in strategy and performance management. Those PE portfolio companies’ boards work very closely together to shape the strategy and define the priority agenda. Such boards are often the source of major strategic initiatives and ideas, stimulating management to look for ‘out of the box’ opportunities. Our research with unlisted companies and companies backed by private equity convinced us of the value add an effective board can bring to the strategy process. However such value add does not materialise itself so easily and necessitates that directors have an in-depth view on the company and the business, while at the same time devoting more attention to strategy than merely one annual open brain storm session. The model given in Figure 6.13 tries to demonstrate how such more elaborate strategy role might work out in practice. It includes not only the interaction between the board and management, but also refers to the specific role of the shareholders and a (eventually ad-hoc) strategy committee. Moreover, it starts from the assumption that strategy is a process that never ends, while at the same time being aware that not all meetings need to question the strategy over and over again. Board effectiveness is best served by a clear delineation and respect of each other’s role as well as a clear understanding of the priorities per meeting. Monitoring duties (and the alertness for red flags) Although there is much less controversy as to the monitoring role of the board, the execution in practice is not straightforward at all. Most, if not all governance codes have been developed in reaction to failing monitoring systems (like the Maxwell case in the 1990s, the Enron case at the beginning of the 21st century or more recently the financial crisis). Like Carter and Lorsch pointed out (2004, p. 141), ‘It seemed that Fine-tuning Board Effectiveness Is Not Enough Shareholders 175 Aims/objectives Ambition Management Main issues of company’s strategy Strategic choices/options Strategic committee Board of directors Debate strategic framework Challenge strategic proposals Agreement strategic direction Management Adjustment proposals Scenario/risk-analysis Strategic committee Board of directors Decision concrete/specific strategic proposal Management Strategy implementation Development of ‘ad hoc’ files Strategic committee Board of directors Follow-up strategy implementation Decision ‘ad hoc’ files Adjustment strategic plan Adjustment objectives/ambition Shareholders Discussion strategy and results Agreement adjustment objectives/ambition/plan Management Figure 6.13 New strategy cycle A board’s strategic role in practice the board was the last to know, and yet the industry ‘dogs’ had been barking for some time about the company’. Consequently, the attention for a deepening out of the monitoring role of the board of directors has been on the agenda everywhere in the world. In fact, the monitoring role of the board touches upon all of the company’s operations, activities and decisions. Monitoring is most of all associated with the financial control of the firm. In the larger companies this duty will be taken care of by a whole battery of people, 176 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau not in the least the audit committee, the external auditor and the internal audit. Audit committees have complex duties in overseeing the financial statements and the respect of the accounting principles. They should devote sufficient attention to delicate accounting issues, especially when judgement calls have to be made. Another important complementary monitoring duty relates to internal control and (enterprise) risk management. In this respect, the board should stimulate and oversee that the company develops a tailored management information system. Here the governance practice might be quite different according to the size of the company as well as the type of shareholders involved. In PE portfolio companies there has always been a great deal of investment of boards in understanding operational, business and financial risk. They seem to be more focused on risk management rather than risk avoidance. On the other hand the listed companies have been forced the last decade to develop much more sophisticated risk management processes, obliging the board to decide upon the risk appetite of the company. Risk management should indeed go beyond the traditional ‘insurable’ risks, including all types of risks, like financial and operational risks. But a domain that is often underdeveloped, while deserving greater attention, is the domain of strategic risks. Whereas the internal control and risk management can be delegated to the audit committee the discussion of the strategic risk should be at the core of the board’s deliberations. Unfortunately, our experience with board evaluation exercises points out that boards are still struggling to tackle this aspect in an appropriate way. Performance management is a monitoring role of the board that is conceived quite differently from one company to another. It should include the analysis of the financial as well as the non-financial performance, including relevant indicators of corporate social responsibility. The typical performance management in (larger) listed companies attaches quite some importance to delivering the performance the market expects and overseeing the quarterly/annual information to the financial markets. At the other extreme, boards of private equity portfolio companies play a much more prominent role in performance management and are actively involved in driving performance, monitoring progress intensively (Acharya et al., 2008). This part of the board’s role is perhaps the most striking difference between those two types of boards. Performance management includes identifying the critical performance initiatives and the key performance indicators to monitor as a board. Such exercise coincides to some extent with the evaluation of management performance. Fine-tuning Board Effectiveness Is Not Enough 177 With hindsight of the financial crisis, it is also very important that directors are vigilant guardians, attentive to any ‘red flag’ they may observe. A good board must be able to offer contestable advice and smell any smoke coming under the door. To this end, it is not only relevant to have independent directors, but such vigilance requires that some members of the board have relevant industry experience and can smell that smoke might be coming. Moreover it is essential that directors have a frank discussion within the board and with management. In order to be able to recognise problems before they are out of control, directors should speak out frankly to each other about their concerns. This is where strategy and monitoring again meet: directors should sufficiently challenge the strategic direction of the company, be alert to signals like missed plans and budgets, acquisitions that never work out, risk management failures, loss of market share to competitors, inadequate staff development, etc. (Carter and Lorsch, 2004). A dimension of the board’s monitoring role that has not received the attention that it deserves is the so-called internal governance (Van den Berghe, 2009). In this context, internal governance simply refers to the oversight of subsidiaries. In a globalised world, the single corporation becomes more the exception than the rule. Many companies nowadays control different subsidiaries via share holdings. For example, in its 2011 statements, Siemens reported more than 900 fully-owned and 400 majority-owned subsidiaries or joint ventures. General Electric, meanwhile, holds an ownership stake in 8,000 entities. In each of these cases, the subsidiaries are legally independent, with their own management teams and discrete businesses, yet they are very core and vital to the creation of value, also for group shareholders. The more complex corporations become, the more they are a conglomerate of diversified subsidiaries, branches and business units, the more elaborated internal governance should be. The example of Lernout and Hauspie shows how vulnerable shareholders and stakeholders may be when no robust internal governance mechanisms are installed by the corporate headquarters or when the corporate board has no proper nor full oversight of what is happening in the subsidiaries worldwide. Everyone knows good (corporate) governance must begin at the helm of an organisation, but for many multinationals it ends there, too. (Steger and Brellochs, 2006) Finally, boards of directors – especially of listed companies – face an increasing amount of transparency requirements, not in the least 178 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau triggered by the many corporate failures and crisis. The aim is to provide correct information to the market that goes far beyond financial statements. Being transparent on various dimensions of the company’s governance and activities should enable market parties to make an informed judgement. Part of the board’s monitoring duty is to oversee this external accountability and disclosure. Unfortunately, this task appears to be less straightforward in practice. In the previous paragraphs, we already pointed to the danger of the ‘box ticking’ approach, an approach many companies adhere to in there reporting on governance issues. Moreover, as shown by the many ‘monitoring’ studies, information on various elements of their governance is still lacking, leaving investors with an incomplete picture. In more extreme cases, a board of directors may be accused of providing misleading information. The Fortis debacle is still a painful memory in this respect.3 Advisory/support function Directors can also play an important role as advisors to management. This role reflects a resource-based view on the board of directors. Nonexecutive directors have indeed a wide experience and additional expertise they can bring to the table. Also their broad network can open doors in the interest of the company. The smaller the company the more this role comes to the forefront. However, it should be made clear from the outset that directors are there to oversee and control management, not primarily to be the advisors to management. Finding a right balance between the support role and the monitoring role is essential for effective governance. Some conclusions Defining governance and board effectiveness is not a straight forward exercise. In principle, boards are seen to be responsible for reaching the corporate goal and ambition. But it is impossible to judge the value of a board on its own in isolation of the ‘system’ it operates in. Board effectiveness is best served by a ‘system approach’, that views boards as dynamic and open social (and political) systems, where a change in one element will affect other elements in the system. Such approach is inherently different than the one traditionally used in academic research. Historically most academic research is centred around specific individual sub-elements of the governance system and its effectiveness judged on the base of corporate results. This approach does not yield consistent results because the governance practices are so complex that Fine-tuning Board Effectiveness Is Not Enough 179 they cannot be brought back to such unilateral and direct links. We need to look at board effectiveness in different steps: from input over board process to board output, while taking into consideration the numerous interactions between all of the constituent elements within the broader framework of external boundaries (legislative and societal environment as well as the industrial environment) and contingencies (the relationship between the board and management, respectively shareholders). Measuring board effectiveness should start with the question what effectiveness really means. We consider a board to be effective if it facilitates the creation of value added for the company, its management, its shareholders and all of its relevant stakeholders. The board’s value added capacity will be enhanced if we develop a better insight into what really drives board output. In our opinion the two main drivers: (1) a board that optimally performs its role in line with the relevant context factors and (2) that is able to reach the goal of effective decision-making in the long-term interest of the company and its relevant stakeholders. Each of those board output drivers is influenced by a whole set of factors, which impact each other in a dynamic and interactive way. In a system approach, it has to be made clear from the outset that governance components or board aspects cannot be analysed in isolation. Therefore we developed a holistic board assessment model that positions the board as an open system, interacting with the firm’s environment, the external contingency factors, the business environment and the internal organisational environment. Besides the respect for the legal obligations, companies should align their board model and governance approach with the ‘best practice’ guidance, given by the relevant governance codes, while paying sufficient attention to the valid societal norms and expectations. However, the company must use the flexibility offered to translate the guidance into a fit with the corporate situation including the stage in its life cycle, the challenges the company is facing, the strategy it envisions etc. Moreover, it is important that the positioning of the board of directors is in line with the respective roles of shareholders and management, while paying special attention to their mutual interaction and the dialogue with stakeholders. In fact, a key driver of board effectiveness is the optimal alignment of the board model with the shareholder, stakeholder and management model. Board assessment should bring along a view on the performance of the board, i.e. judging its value added and comparing the board’s contribution to the expected board role. A board has to perform a multitude of tasks, but the configuration of board roles may be quite different from 180 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau one context to another. In contrast to mainstream governance literature (focusing on agency theory), the configuration of board roles should be built on a multi-paradigm approach with the following four basic board tasks: making sure the company has the right leadership; deciding upon the strategic direction of the company and how this should be realised; monitoring execution and results, including the governance scan and board evaluation; advisory and support function. The leadership role of the board is one of its most crucial tasks. Of course, it consists of a multitude of subtasks. A crucial task is to appoint and take care of the succession of the leadership team, a team that is perfectly aligned with the strategic ambitions. The board will have to decide on a workable delegation policy and the empowerment philosophy that underlies such delegation. It is important for governance effectiveness that there is agreement on a clear division of roles, collaboration and interaction between the board and management, such division perfectly fit with the specific context at hand. Monitoring executive performance is of course a crucial element in the board’s leadership role. The leadership role also includes the duty to come to grips with a clear understanding of the nature and purpose of the organisation as a touch stone for judging strategic ambitions and corporate performance. Directors must exercise judgement and have a real challenge in deciding to whom they are really responsible and where there commitments ultimately lie. Apparently, board practices on balancing shareholder and stakeholder interests vary across different types of companies and nations. But the financial crisis has given a boost to a higher sensitivity of boards towards fostering long-term value creation and corporate success within a framework of corporate social responsibilities. However, the multiplicity of goals makes one parameter of teamwork effectiveness challenging. Judging board effectiveness on the basis of the evolution of the share price or even total shareholder return – as practiced in many academic publications – is therefore no longer a valid route. It is essential for directors to build a shared view of the corporate context, a holistic common understanding of the enterprise, its vision, goals, values and performance expectations (financial as well as non-financial ones). The strategic role of the board of directors has historically been subject to much dispute, especially in the management literature. Not surprisingly, there is no board duty that is executed with so many nuances around the globe as the interference of directors in the strategic process. Consequently any board evaluation should carefully check whether there is an explicit view on the respective roles of the board of directors, management and shareholders in the process of strategy development, Fine-tuning Board Effectiveness Is Not Enough 181 strategic choices, strategy implementation and evaluation. The trend towards more accountability of directors coincides with the tendency for the board to play a more prominent role in the strategy process with an annual strategic retreat and a vigilant follow-up throughout the remainder of the year of the evolution of the strategy execution. It might also be important that directors get a feel for the strategy process behind the board scene, for example which proposals do not get into the board room. Versatility requires attentiveness to the context and its demands, anticipating when change is required. Ex-post evaluations and lessons learned are important to build a culture of continuous improvement. Recognising and acting on a failed course of action is also critical for governance effectiveness. In contrast to the board’s role in strategy, there is much less controversy as to its monitoring role. However, the execution of the monitoring role is not straightforward at all, since many corporate scandals and business failures are due to a failing monitoring system. Monitoring is most of all associated with financial control, but in fact it touches upon all aspects of the company’s operations, activities, decisions and results, including also internal control and risk management, performance management, internal governance, external accountability and disclosure. In the larger companies, a whole battery of internal and external experts is involved to support the board in performing this important oversight function. The challenge for board effectiveness is not only to be complete in performing the monitoring role but at the same time to be aware of the need for a balanced collaboration and a clear role definition for the board, its committees and all experts involved in this monitoring process. Directors can also play an important role as advisors to management. The smaller the company the more this role comes to the forefront. However, finding a right balance between the support role and the monitoring role is essential for effective governance. Notes 1. This practice is for example commonly found among venture capital and private equity funds who invest in smaller or start-up businesses where management experience is lacking. The non-executive directors may be extra paid for the extra time invested. 2. See e.g. the discussions in various issues of Harvard Business Review, edited by Kenneth Andrews. 3. In 2010, Deminor launched a procedure against Fortis SA/NV for having violated its obligations as a listed company with respect to the information it has to communicate to the public. The purpose of this procedure, which is 182 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau launched before the Court of commerce of Brussels, is to claim damages for the investors who have hired Deminor. Deminor believed that, in particular since the announcement of the launch of the takeover of ABN Amro up until the dismantling of the group in the autumn 2008, Fortis’ communication was misleading on several material aspects, including on its subprime exposure, its dividend policy, its liquidity, its solvency and the consequences of the acquisition of ABN Amro. During this period of time, investors decided to buy and/or hold Fortis shares based on misleading information from Fortis (Deminor, 2010). References Acharya, V., Kehoe, C. and Reyner, M. ‘Private Equity vs PLC Boards in the U.K.: A Comparison of Practices and Effectiveness’, Finance Working Paper No. 233/2009 (1 August 2008). Baeten, X. Firm-level corporate governance characteristics and CEO remuneration: a cross-national European study, PhD thesis (Ghent: Ghent University, 2012). Carter, C.B. and Lorsch, J.W. Back to the Drawing Board. Designing Corporate Boards for a Complex World (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 2004). Conger, J.A. Boardroom Realities. Building Leaders Across Your Board (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 2009). Daily, C.M., Dalton, D.R. and Cannella, Jr. A.A. ‘Corporate governance: decades of dialogue and data’, Academy of Management Review, XXVIII (2003) 371–382. Deminor, ‘Misleading information – Deminor sues Fortis SA/NV’, Deminor News (31 August 2012). Forbes, D.P. and Milliken, F. ‘Cognition and corporate governance: understanding board of directors as strategic decision-making groups’, Academy of Management Review, XXIV (1999) 489–505. Kakabadse, A. and Kakabadse, N. Leading the Board. The Six Disciplines of WorldClass Chairmen (New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2008). Levrau, A. Corporate Governance and the Board of Directors: a Qualitative-Oriented Inquiry into the Determinants of Board Effectiveness, PhD thesis (Ghent: Ghent University, 2007). McKinsey Quarterly, Making the board more strategic: A McKinsey Global Survey (March 2008). Nicholson, G.J. and Kiel, G.C. ‘A framework for diagnosing board effectiveness’, Corporate Governance – An International Review, XII (2004) 442–460. Nordberg, D. Corporate Governance – Principles and Issues (London: SAGE Publications, 2011). Steger, U. and Brellochs J. ‘Herding your subsidiaries towards good governance’, Financial Times, 6 April 2006. Thomsen, S. ‘A minimum theory of boards’, International Journal of Corporate Governance, I (2008) 73–96. Tricker, B. ‘Corporate Governance’, Ashcroft Series on the History of Management Thought (Aldershot: Ashcroft Publishing, 2000). Tricker, B. Corporate Governance (Aldershot: Gower Publishing, 1984). Fine-tuning Board Effectiveness Is Not Enough 183 Useem, M. ‘How well-run boards make decisions’, Harvard Business Review, LXXXIV (2006) 130–138. Van den Berghe, L. ‘Internal governance: the neglected pillar of good governance’, International Journal of Business Governance and Ethics, IV (2009) 427–442. Part II The ‘Inside Out’ Perspective 7 An Effective Board Makes the Necessary Trade-Offs Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau Historically, the legal basis of corporate governance has been rather limited, leaving the companies free to organise their governance, direction and control as they saw fit. But corporate failures in the 1990s (such as Maxwell or BCCI in the UK) and in the beginning of the 21st century (such as Enron and Worldcom in the United States, or Parmalat and Ahold on the European continent) led to a real up-rise of governance codes (in Europe) as well as legislation (SOx in the US and European Directives) that drastically increased the requirements companies had to comply with. Although governance codes can never mimic the numerous challenges companies are confronted with, they have come a long way in describing in greater detail the conditions to reach good governance practices in general and board effectiveness more specifically. However, the recent financial crisis was an abrupt wake-up call that those recipes were not that effective after all. In answering the societal revolt, politicians (at both sides of the Atlantic) took over the reins and overwhelmed the companies with an avalanche of legal rules and obligations. This incremental building up of corporate governance laws and regulations, combined with strengthened self-regulatory recommendations, led to a construction that is not only very complex, but at the same time contains quite a number of paradoxes, that need further in-depth reflection and trade-offs. How can you promote the board as a collegial body if more and more discussions are delegated to specific board committees? How can you promote critical points of view by independent outsiders and constructive dissent, yet also reaching a consensus that is fully supported by the whole board? Can true independence be compatible with annual election or ad nutum dismissal of such directors? Can executives be both your peers as a director and at the same time the persons you 187 188 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau should monitor? And what about the dual role of a non-executive director as an advisor while also being the critical monitor of management? Diversity needs are growing in all directions, but what about a collegial chemistry? The board duties and the time commitment are increasing exponentially, but the remuneration of non-executive directors is not keeping pace. On the contrary, remuneration of directors is the central focus of huge societal and political attacks, completely ignoring the crucial distinction between executive and non-executive directors. Board decisions are taken behind closed doors not at least because of the sensitive issues that are being discussed. In addition discretion is a legal obligation of directors in many jurisdictions. Yet we live in a world of full disclosure and huge transparency needs, dictated by governance codes and regulations. The challenge of this chapter is to look deeper into each of these apparent paradoxes and reflect upon possible ways for boards to make the correct trade-offs. Trade-offs to ensure that the board behaves as a collegial body Boards embody an interesting paradox: they are simultaneously among the most and the least hierarchical institutions in the business world. As a collegial body – at least in theory – there is an almost complete absence of formal hierarchy within the board. Each director is individually and jointly responsible. Even the chairman is supposed to deal with the other directors as peers. At the same time, the board sits at the pinnacle of the corporate structure and as such is – theoretically at least – the boss of the CEO, mostly member (and thus peer) of that same board. However, reality is far more complex because director position (and power) may well depend on the degree of insight and information. The non-executive directors completely depend upon the CEO and the other executives to get the necessary information to perform their tasks. Put differently, non-executive directors suffer from an information gap vis-à-vis the executives while at the same time being responsible for controlling and monitoring those executives. This apparent paradox also puts forward some legal aspects. Although executive directors know far more from the inside and outside of the corporation, non-executive directors are assumed (in Europe) to have the same collegial responsibilities, accountabilities and even liabilities. Moreover, a comparable difference in information and insight may exist between the chairman and the other non-executive directors, between the members of a An Effective Board Makes the Necessary Trade-Offs 189 specific board committee and the non-members, between the directors representing the ‘controlling’ shareholders and the independent directors. Consequently, we need to devote much more attention to improving the information process and sources for the non-executives. Collective decision-making in its own right inhibits an important set of trade-offs. In fact, the board has been constituted as a collegial body, because it is assumed that key decisions necessitate a collective decision-making mechanism. As we will see in Chapter 8, collective decision-making may have quite substantial advantages over individual decision-making. However, these advantages will only be reached if the specific conditions of effective group dynamics are materialised. One of the main conditions is the need to reach consensus, based on in-depth discussions that leave ample room for constructive dissent. There must be a balance of perspectives on the board, building decisions on a wide and diverse set of opinions. In order to reach the goal of constructive dissent, boards are increasingly composed of independent ‘free-thinking’ individuals, yet at the same time they must function smoothly as a team. But can you reach a good cooperation between a group of ‘high calibre’ individuals (each with their own ego), with complex diversities of style, personality, background and being attached to their independence? With the emphasis on more independent directors, the opinions are assumed to be even more diverse than ever before (the opinion of independent directors are assumed not to depend on another person’s opinion or choice). Independent directors are attracted to intervene actively in the board’s deliberations with their own firm and non-biased opinion, critically judging the proposed decisions with respect to the (long-term) interest of the company. The difficulty is to get independent individuals with a tendency to be critical and even distrusted to work together. More attention for board chemistry and director behaviour is therefore of utmost importance. A good chemistry is vital. Good cooperation within the board team requires that directors take into account what everyone is saying, going beyond self-interest (faced with choices, a self-interested person chooses the one that benefits him personally the most) and selfishness (giving priority to one’s personal scoring). This goes hand in hand with professional behaviour aimed at building trust (while staying vigilant on verification) and reliability (you can be confident when they promise something or commit themselves). It also implies a social behaviour, fostering durable relations, not taking advantage of each other, while at the same time being strict on punishing noncooperative behaviour. It is evident that all these important dimensions 190 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau of a professional director have been grossly overlooked in the governance codes as well as in the recruitment and selection process. The board’s main role is to direct and control the company. This dual function in itself may give rise to quite a number of tensions. The board’s duty to ‘direct the company’ has of course to be seen in light of its ‘part-time’ presence in the company. In so far that the board’s first important duty is to make sure it installs the right permanent leadership by nominating a professional top management, evaluating its performance and deciding on its remuneration. Although the board will delegate an important part of the decision-power to the corporate leaders, he will remain responsible for quite a large set of duties. Such as deciding on the corporate goals and values, approving the corporate strategy and the concrete plans for its execution as well as setting key performance indicators. Besides this direction role, the board plays an important monitoring role, focusing on the conformance of the outcome and process with the approved goals, objectives and values. Directors watch over the execution of the strategy, analyse the outcome in comparison to the performance targets while also carefully controlling the (financial) results and the risks involved. These different roles require a very different orientation and behaviour of directors. The conformance role demands careful monitoring and scrutiny and is risk averse. Stimulating performance demands vision, in-depth understanding of the organisation and its environment, and a greater willingness to take risks. Not everybody is convinced that these two fundamental different roles can be reconciled. Cees Visser ,1 for example, argues that one should eliminate the advice role and limit the role of the supervisory board to supervision, monitoring and control only. Only such focus will guarantee more independent supervision and less inclination to have conflicts of interest in controlling one’s own strategic proposals and agreed upon strategy. This suggestion, aimed at the two-tier board structure (in the Netherlands), ignores however the claims put forward by the Dutch ‘Ondernemingskamer’ that the Dutch boards have not taken their strategic role sufficiently at heart. Although one might differ about the ‘depth’ of the involvement of the board in the strategy process, it is clear that the board has been installed as a college in order to decide on the most important choices for the company. Consequently, strategy is at the heart of the board’s duties. But directors should be aware that the combination of the monitoring function with the direction function will necessitate the necessary trade-offs in the respective roles of the executive and non-executive directors and of the board and management. Executive directors are assumed to play a prominent role An Effective Board Makes the Necessary Trade-Offs 191 in the strategy cycle, while being more at a distance when the controlling and monitoring function of the board is at stake. It is the other way around with non-executive directors, who play a predominant role in the audit, remuneration and nomination files, while they are less involved in each of the steps of the strategy process. In addition, the dual role of the board implies for non-executive directors the need to combine the necessary distance and good relationship with management (and executive directors). In this respect, Sir David Walker (2009) states that non-executive directors have to motivate executives, inspire them to act (as accelerator) while also challenging them. Challenging does not mean to overload them with fear, but make them well aware of the limits of the resources and the corporate risk appetite (the brake). A complementary element of specialisation can be found in the specialised board committees. According to Ward (1997) the 21st century board is characterised by committee federalism. The rise in the board committee power is already turning them into the tail that wags the boardroom dog at many companies. Tightened duties, with stronger technical oversight and checklists of procedures to prove compliance, have shifted power to committees. This is where the real action is migrating today. The long-term result will be a sort of governance federalism, with the overall board serving as a nexus that unites the power of committees. Combining the drive towards a truly collegial board with the increasing emphasis on board committees, each specialising in one of the main domains of direction and control (nomination, remuneration, audit and risk) is in itself again a kind of a paradox. Encouraging directors to focus and specialise, requires no less than a major paradigm shift in the way that a collegial board is conceived to work together. The symbiosis between the main board and its board committees is one of the largest challenges and trade-offs in the modern governance recommendations. On the one hand the installation of board committees makes sense: it allows making optimal use of the directors’ specialisation and their available time. Specialisation and focus can be the effective response to complexity, the need for in-depth discussions and for more pro-active attitude of directors (Carter and Lorsch, 2004). At the same time, this evolution might be dangerous from several perspectives. The more indepth specialisation of non-executive directors is not aimed at making them the functional specialists, because they do not have to duplicate the management responsibilities. Their duty remains on the steering 192 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau and monitoring level, not at the development or execution level. Too much interference with the operational business is counterproductive (from an efficiency point of view) and might lead to serious objections of management. Even more important is the fact that more involvement of (some) directors in specialised sub-domains of the board’s responsibilities might make them not only better informed than their colleagues, but also more implied in the specific decision-making. The more important the issues might be, the more threatened the nonmembers might feel. Our board assessment experience clearly showed that the least problematic is the role of the audit committee. More frustration pops up around the impact of (the members of) the remuneration and the nomination committee. But most critique is oriented towards strategic committees, because directors consider strategy as the life blood of a working board. According to Carter and Lorsch (2004), adding other board committees to the classical three (audit, nomination and remuneration), such as a strategy committee, often creates tensions with management because they delve too deep and get involved in managerial decisions. However, such a committee may be a viable solution for ad hoc projects (e.g. acquisition, important divestiture, crisis, risk situation). A specific side-effect of board committees includes the dual role nonexecutives themselves have to perform in discussing the board files. Being the chair or member of a board committee, a director will play a ‘subordinate’ role towards the full board, ‘presenting’ the committee’s advice while the other non-executive directors are assumed to take the role of critical evaluators and discussants of those proposals (and the other way around for other committees). It is interesting to observe that such reporting and discussions might take another format and create other types of board dynamics than the traditional interaction with the presentations made by management (Meurisse, 2011). Since greater focus is key to governance excellence in complex businesses, we will have to find a way around and solve the implicit and explicit trade-offs that come with board committees. We may never forget that it is the main board that finally has all decision rights as well as responsibilities and accountabilities for effectively governing the company. This does not mean that boards need to redo the work performed in committee meetings. More attention needs to be paid to a swift and clear interaction between both levels. The committee chairs should diligently and carefully inform all directors about the committee proposals and give notice of the diverging opinions – if any – within the committee. All directors should feel responsible and interested to take fully part An Effective Board Makes the Necessary Trade-Offs 193 in the approval of the committee proposals. Companies will also need to invest more in a periodic assessment of the effectiveness of board committees: do they achieve their role and their purpose, is their composition adequate, do they cooperate positively with the board, etc.? The trade-offs in composing the board of directors If there is one governance item that has engendered worldwide attention, it certainly is the composition of the board of directors. Today companies, especially the listed ones, are confronted with so many additional requirements and even mandatory rules for board composition that it becomes a hell of a job to make all the necessary trade-offs. On the one hand, a company should strive for an ‘optimal’ board size, because this is a precondition for having effective board discussions and reap the benefits of collective decision-making. On the other hand, corporate boards are faced with a complex set of obligations related to diversity, including business expertise and board experience, to specialised board committees and independence, which could easily lead to a large parliament, rather than a smooth collegial team. Moreover, each of these requirements in their own right leads to quite a number of trade-offs that a board needs to make when deciding on its optimal composition. In the 1990s, the need for independent directors was put forward as one of the main governance recipes to give the boards more teeth in their ‘supervisory’ function. Non-executive directors who are separate from and genuinely independent of management, provide a vital counterbalance to the executives, as well as valuable advice, guidance and monitoring. (Colvin, The Australian, 13 July 2011) In companies with dispersed shareholding it became clear that management did not have sufficient countervailing power with boards that were merely handpicked by the corporate leaders themselves. Everyone remembers the provocative statement on (US) directors who were compared with ornaments on the corporate Christmas tree (see Lorsch and Maciver, 1989). So boards needed to become much more independent of management, with a majority of independent directors forming the backbone of the empowered board. Apparently, the same recipe was sought for companies with controlling shareholders. In this case, the ‘disease’ was different and consequently the emphasis was on the need 194 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau to have sufficient independence and countervailing power towards the powerful position of the main shareholder(s) instead of the CEO (with the main shareholders being insiders, present or represented on the board). Most of the countries with controlling shareholders went a long way in obliging (by means of law) or at least promoting (by means of a governance code) more independence in the board. Not that they went so far in mandating a majority of independent board members, but at least they need to install a majority of independent directors in the most important board committees (audit, nomination and remuneration committee). At the same time it is clear that the role and functioning of independent directors has been under attack, not in the least in the slipstream of the financial crisis. Having more independent directors is not a synonym per se for better governance, because board independence comes at a cost (Carter and Lorsch, 2004). Directors who have no other relationship with the company may probably know not so much about its business and will have a lot to learn (for which they will be very reliant on management). The more boards are becoming independent, the more directors are very part-time (with demanding careers, serving on more boards). Extending the number of days non-executive directors need to be available for their board mandate still leaves them with only a fraction of the full-time commitment of executives. The solution is not to abolish independence, because it remains instrumental in avoiding conflicts of interest and is a necessary prerequisite for unbiased board oversight. But the pendulum went too far, with too much attention being paid to independence at the detriment of other design elements. Boards need to understand the downside of independence and find ways to combine the advantages with better managing the potential disadvantages. So they need to achieve a better balance between understanding the business and independence while making sure a minimum number of non-executive directors have deeper knowledge of the company and its industry. According to statistics of Governance Metrics International, the general trend in Europe the last couple of years seems to be that the relevant importance of independent directors has regressed (from 49% to 38% in Germany, from 68% to 58% in Sweden and from 65% to 51% in France over the period August 2005 to December 2010). This trend seems to prove that companies attach more and more importance to other competencies and business expertise than to ‘textbook’ definitions of independence. Independence is indeed only one essential component of the diversity and competence needed to stimulate good governance. While board An Effective Board Makes the Necessary Trade-Offs 195 independence is important (and independent directors form a crucial input factor to this end), we may not focus on one element of good governance and ignore the complexity of how boards (should) work. The challenge is finding the right balance between (cognitive) diversity and independence. Business knowledge and sector expertise should never be substituted by a purely independence focus. Moreover, team context principles may limit the ideal of absolute independence. Positive regard and avoiding open conflict, an essential element of effective teams, may be seen as a threat to independence. An aligned team may lack sufficient independent thinkers and succumb to groupthink. It is a fine line, and the board’s ability to lead as a team is about creating appropriate checks and balances and sufficient interdependence, not about independence in the absolute. The concept of independent directors raises an important challenge in governance models with controlling shareholders. In such companies, independent directors are mandated to perform a countervailing power towards the insider shareholders. However, these shareholders control the shareholders’ meeting (and often also the board) and as such have all the powers to nominate, appoint and dismiss independent directors. Moreover, in many countries independent directors can be dismissed at will (or ‘ad nutum’), even without any formal explanation or reimbursement whatsoever. If the shareholders decide that a board member no longer lives up to ‘their’ expectations, they have the right to send him (or her) away without further notice or explanation. These points of reflection have been largely ignored in academic research, probably because most research focuses on the Anglo-American models with dispersed shareholding. In contrast herewith, independent directors that operate in a model with controlling shareholders often express their concern about the apparent or potential impediment of their independence. More recently, also the EU and some shareholder activists have expressed their concern about this independence ‘paradox’. A special example of this increasing interest can be found in the UK where the Financial Reporting Council is considering changes to the UK Code to increase the independent status of directors in listed companies with controlling shareholders (2011). We therefore need to pay more attention to ways of promoting solutions for this independence paradox in governance models with controlling shareholders. The solution promoted by the Financial Reporting Council (2011) is double: on the one hand, the board should be composed of a majority of independent directors, even in companies with controlling shareholders; on top of that, the independent directors 196 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau must have a casting vote in the nomination committee when the nomination of independent directors is at stake. This solution will probably be met with great scepticism by the majority shareholders, who consider their controlling position as one of the most essential conditions for their willingness to go and stay on the stock exchange. Another proposal that might inspire a route towards a (better) solution can be found in the nomination procedure as developed by the Belgian State for Belgacom. When launching the IPO, the by-laws and the prospectus explicitly foresaw two types of directors, the ones nominated by the state (by royal decree) and the independent directors nominated by the general assembly, in a vote where the state had to abstain from voting. So in fact, the independent directors are nominated by the minority shareholders (holding less than 50% of the shares). Another additional route could be to adapt the regulation of dismissal at will, for example by obliging a clear explanation in the shareholders meeting when independent directors are dismissed before the end of their mandate, or even to foresee a special majority (e.g. a total support of two-thirds of all shareholders or a double majority of the controlling as well as of the minority shareholders) and/or to foresee a compensation in case of a pre-term ending (e.g. a severance pay equal to (part of) the director remuneration for the remainder of the mandate period). The last couple of years the attention of politicians and the media has shifted to the gender balance on the board of directors. Although a better gender balance can be rationally defended on the base of the advantages offered by more cognitive diversity, attention is mostly focused on (demographic) fairness and (economic) justice arguments. There is probably no country in the world where the demographic texture is well represented on the board of directors. For ages, boards have merely been composed by relatively older, white, male directors. It is only during the last two decades that women have increasingly taken up board mandates. Yet, even today, most boards still do not have that many female directors. This ‘unbalance’ has triggered public attention, with regular lists of companies having the best and worst gender balance and with numerous proposals before parliament to introduce mandatory gender quota for listed companies, for state-owned enterprises, etc. Some countries, like Norway, have shown the way, in the sense that they were the first to introduce female quota regulations for listed companies, stimulating the other Scandinavian countries to go the same way, yet with a more self-regulatory approach. Boards in these countries are today among the most gender diverse, inspiring more and more European countries to follow their example. Although it is the right of An Effective Board Makes the Necessary Trade-Offs 197 politicians to introduce gender quota legislation, this poses again an important additional challenge for board composition. Companies and their nomination committees will need to adapt their view on director vacancies. Gender diversity should not lead to ‘token’ directors, but focus on the competencies and experiences needed. Diversity does not come so easily and investments will be necessary to enlarge the relevant pool of good board candidates.2 We do agree with Carter and Lorsch (2004) that the so-called shortage of candidates is more likely reflecting nominating committees’ failure to look beyond the obvious than it is because of a genuine lack of talent. Is the shortage of board talent among women not the logical outcome of the view that the only good directors are CEOs and ex-CEOs? With such reference group, the candidate pool is indeed very small. A diversity element that has gained less attention in governance codes, yet it is one of the main elements of a one-tier board structure, is the optimal mixture of executive and non-executive directors. More precisely, the choice of which members of the executive team also sit on the board raises numerous important challenges that need further reflection. Too much focus on independent directors can have the perverse, unintended effect that the vital role of insiders to effective board functioning is overlooked. Insiders bring a depth of perspective on the company (Sonnenfeld and Ward in Conger, 2009). There appears to be a consensus that it is important to have the CEO as a board member for the in-depth knowledge of the firm and its context. In contrast, for other executives to join the board as a director, opinions may differ. A first observation is certainly that the more executives on the board, the larger the board will become, triggering the level of effective discussions. But there are other, more important disadvantages that deserve our attention. It is essential for executives on the board to feel ‘equal’ to everyone else in the board, in light of its collegial character. Given the more hierarchical structure of most management bodies, this collegial approach is especially tricky for other executives than the CEO, because their boss is also member of that same college. This may make it hard to take a position different from that of the CEO, while they cannot act as a subordinate, since they are a member in a collegial board. The danger is real that the other executive directors stick to the opinion or preference view of the CEO. Moreover, the presence of executive directors on the board can pose problems if difficult issues about management have to be discussed at board level. However, without executives, the board misses the deep knowledge of the firm and the business environment, such executives might bring into the deliberations. 198 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau All these trade-offs might lead to the conclusion that it is best to have the CEO on the board, while the other top executives might be invited to present their dossiers to the board. This is what frequently happens in practice. Our research of governance practices in listed companies in Belgium revealed interesting observations in this respect. Inviting other members of the management team to the board meetings brings the executive team closer to the board and gives the non-executive directors a better view on the potential pipeline for succession planning. Besides, it is also perceived to be an effective way to avoid the danger that the board’s information is limited to what the CEO wants the nonexecutive directors to hear (making it more likely that the CEO can mislead the board). Moreover, it is a good practice that all executives are invited to the strategic conclave, so the non-executives can take full advantage of their expertise and business knowledge in order to make the important strategic decisions. The trade-offs in the relation between executives and non-executives Besides reflecting on the role of executives on the board, the relation between the non-executive directors and the executives, whether nominated as board members or not, deserves special attention. The board must have an open and trusting relationship with top management in order to be able to reach a productive critical working relationship. The non-executive directors need to find the right balance between oversight and direction, between monitoring management and being their advisors, between challenging the executives while at the same time being supportive of their proposals. In an effective board everybody tries to recognise that each party has a valid position and a job to do. This is delicate because powerful egos are involved, significant careers are at stake and there may even be a clash of styles and personalities. For non-executive directors, an empowered board implies that they need to invest time and energy in learning more about the company, its business environment, its challenges and its risks. Who would be better positioned to guide them in this learning process than the executives themselves? Therefore, there is a growing trend to couple the formal contacts in the margin of the board meetings with more informal contacts. Traditionally, non-executive directors have contacts with the management team at a limited number of formal meetings. Most of the time, this will be during real-time board discussions, in front of the CEO and the management group, which directors are supposed to monitor. An Effective Board Makes the Necessary Trade-Offs 199 How empowered the board might be, it is never the aim that nonexecutive directors trample on the toes of management. The challenge is to find the right balance and interface with management. This balance is hard to achieve. The more the board gets empowered, the higher the expectations towards directors, the more difficult this balance may become. We should clearly ask to what extent companies in general and top management more specifically are prepared to accept the consequences of a more involved board of directors. A point that mostly poses problems is how far the board should get involved in the operational matters. Their monitoring role should not be translated into micro-management. The aim should be to respect the NIFO principle, that is, Nose In Fingers Out. In board discussions, it is important to make the distinction between micro-management and appropriate questioning, which is not always a bright line. What really defines micro-management is not whether a director is digging into details. It is really a question of which details and for what purpose. Drilling down details may be beneficial if it helps revealing a higher level issue, detecting structural elements, getting at the root of a problem or questioning the effectiveness of a process. Asking questions of an operational nature is not in itself micro-management as long as the question leads to insights about strategic performance, major investment decisions, key personnel, choosing objectives or risk assessment. However, micro-management may derail board discussions, taking the focus off more serious issues. Micro-managing may typically happen in the area of a director’s expertise and may be driven by the personal need to demonstrate superior knowledge on the subject (Charan, 2009). In strategic discussions, non-executive directors can be a rich source of information and advice, but the entrepreneurship should finally come from the management team. The board should ensure (and check) that management delivers the performance expected form them and encourage and support management to take the firm forward. Once the nonexecutives become too much involved in an advisory role, they might enter into a conflicting zone between advice, support and oversight. This danger is especially present in smaller and medium-sized companies who suffer often from a lack of internal specialists and specific support functions. There can be confusion about when directors are offering advice and when they are making a decision that management must accept. The need to both control management and be their support and partner can be a source of role conflict and tension for both directors and management. Effective boards are well aware of these potential tensions 200 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau and invest to find the right balance that best suits the company and the people involved. The trade-offs to make sure non-executive directors can perform their role in a professional way Legally, boards are responsible for the company even if they delegate the largest part to management. Even then, the scope of their responsibility is hard to reconcile with the limits of time and knowledge that (independent) directors must live with. There is a growing gap between what directors (can) do and what is expected of them. A key reality for every board is that there is more to do than there is time to do it. Most boards are still bound too tightly to historical practices and traditions to handle their expanding responsibilities with ease (Carter and Lorsch, 2004). The sheer complexity of today’s businesses and the practical limits on directors’ time mean that boards simply can’t achieve everything that is expected of them, even if they do devote more time to their board duties. Boards that clearly understand their roles will use their limited resources better because their efforts will be much more focused. Boards are becoming more differentiated in their composition and activities. Directors must focus clearly on their major tasks, rather than trying to do everything. Doing the right things is the challenge, while at the same time managing the tension of upgrading the ‘time available’ and the ‘knowledge required’. Additional solutions can be found in the way the board is organised with a clear and differentiated definition of a specific board’s role (and less dogma-driven design), where work is allocated among directors (specialisation via the different board committees) and the correct board behaviour is promoted (all the rules in the world won’t govern behaviour behind closed doors, only more peer pressure through board assessments and education can help). The old style board structure, with part-time ‘amateur’ directors, is ill-suited for the heavy demands placed on today’s boards. If directors want to live up to the huge expectations of their board mandate, they will need to further professionalise. By professionalisation we explicitly mean that the director is willing to invest time and effort in getting acquainted with the needs of a specific board mandate and this in three different directions: from a governance perspective (board effectiveness), with sufficient knowledge of all of the different functional domains (director effectiveness) as well as of the company and its business environment (business effectiveness). However the term An Effective Board Makes the Necessary Trade-Offs 201 ‘professional’ director might also be used to refer to the director, who builds a profession with different non-executive board seats. Gilson and Kraakman (1991) proposed to introduce the professional director, which they defined as being full-time committed to board service for a portfolio of companies, with up to six mandates in their portfolio and nominated by the institutional shareholders. They would be the ultimate pipeline between those who own and those who manage. This approach is often used by private equity players who can rely on a number of external or outside directors, experienced former CEOs or experts specialised in the sectors the private equity company invests in. The question is to what extent such directors can still be considered independent directors in the strict sense of the word, if they need to represent one of the shareholders. Where we do agree with this proposal is that the status of a professional director could increase his independence in so far that, with so many seats he can offer his expertise to all, but is dependent on none. Given the unwillingness (of US companies) to open up their boards, their proposal resulted in no action. Whatever the route chosen to arrive at a professional directorship, non-executive directors will remain ‘non-executive’, leaving them with a ‘part-time’ status at (each) company they govern. They will need to cope with complex dossiers, take on their shoulders heavy responsibilities and combine this with other functions or mandates. However, even as ‘outsiders’ they will need to stay up to date with the specific dossiers on the board’s agenda. Here directors must be able to increasingly rely upon better methods to make the relevant information available, accessible (in-between meetings) and memorable. But the corporate world should also walk its talk and take the consequences of such huge investment of their non-executive directors at heart. It is the corporation and its management that will finally need to facilitate their non-executive directors becoming more professional. This comes down to quite a different position than today. If non-executive directors need to fulfil their governance role as assumed by law, by the governance codes and by societal norms, than there is no other way than to better support these ‘part-time’ directors. This starts with induction and professional development offered by the company, combined with a professional information process and completed with a correct remuneration. As more is demanded of directors in terms of time commitment, responsibility and exposure to public scrutiny and potential liability, the question of a significant increase in their remuneration is on the table. We agree with Carter and Lorsch (2004) that compensation of directors is rarely discussed 202 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau in the board room. It is only in the margin of a board assessment that some companies may ask for a ‘bench marking’ study to find out what others are paying. It is difficult to find a convincing logic for the actual practices, certainly if compared to the remuneration paid to executives or to consultants. 3 The whole subject is more mystery than science. GUBERNA, as an association of directors, has been asked for guidance over and over again. Therefore we recently developed an analysis of corporate practices with listed as well as unlisted companies, of small, medium or larger size. Although market practices might be quite different from one country to another, this study revealed some interesting observations that might be valid also from an international perspective. Whereas payment for services is seen as a straightforward practice, quite a lot of small to medium-sized companies were – at least in the past – rather reluctant to pay for their non-executive directors (most of them being shareholder anyhow, so they were indirectly remunerated). Once independent directors enter the board room, it is clear that for them a ‘decent’ reward for their board role has to be foreseen. Longitudinal research on the payment of directors in non-listed companies (GUBERNA, 2012) clearly proved the significant increase in the companies effectively remunerating their (independent) nonexecutive directors. At the same time, the amount paid has increased over the last couple of years. However, the remuneration policy for nonexecutive directors does not seem to have been developed with great reflection, leading to a very complex web of numerous pay practices. Although many codes propose a fixed remuneration for non-executive directors, many pay schedules include a kind of variable remuneration linked to the ‘performance’ of the director. The director’s performance is measured with respect to their effective time investment, with indicators such as their additional functions in board committees, in chairing the board or the committees and in effectively attending the meetings of the board and the committees. Some companies combine all of these time indicators on top of a fixed remuneration for their general board mandate, while others only use some of these elements (e.g. attendance record in the main board and/or membership fee per committee). More critical is the question of variable remuneration based on ‘corporate’ performance criteria. This issue deserves special attention, with quite divergent views on the feasibility of such remuneration policy. In light of the need for sufficient independence and countervailing power towards management (who often receives important performance-related pay packages), it is assumed that it is An Effective Board Makes the Necessary Trade-Offs 203 preferable not to (overly) expose non-executive directors to the same type of performance-related pay. Anyhow, the failures in the financial sector have shown the downside of too much exposure to variable remuneration. Consequently in many continental European countries, such variable remuneration is not an accepted practice for nonexecutive directors or is even prohibited by law (as is the case for listed companies in Belgium unless explicitly allowed by the shareholders). In other countries shareholding of directors is considered important (UK, United States) if not necessary (see e.g. France). In those countries shares and/or share options might be part of the remuneration package of a non-executive director. In companies backed by private equity such performance-related remuneration might be the rule, rather than the exception. The same holds for younger companies or start-ups who may not have the necessary cash flow available to pay their directors the necessary (fixed) remuneration and who need to rely on stock options to compensate them in a sufficient way. Apparently there are some advantages and disadvantages attached to both remuneration approaches. The study of Acharya et al. (2008) provides an interesting view in this respect. They make a plea for exploring new ways to change the remuneration structure of non-executive directors and make them more performance-related. This suggestion is based on the observation that boards of PE portfolio companies outperform their colleagues at listed companies, because such boards are far more focused on clear performance objectives, given that their remuneration is aligned with those performance objectives. However, the authors of the report acknowledge that such type of variable remuneration may trigger the independence of directors’ oversight role and carry the danger of a focus on short-term results. But they consider the advantage of such variable remuneration so important, that a search for corrective factors to neutralise potential downsides be the goal to accomplish. In this respect they, for example, propose to give non-executive directors performance shares tied to a rolling three-year performance period (which brings those suggestions in line with the recent European executive remuneration proposals). Taking the need for sufficient checks and balances into consideration, it is the shareholder that will finally have to approve the board remuneration policy and structure. However, it will be the remuneration committee that will need to support the board in seeing to it that such remuneration policy is developed, determining the form and amounts of director remuneration, with appropriate benchmarking against peer companies. 204 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau The trade-offs in light of the increased attention for transparency Since boards make important decisions that influence the future of the company (such as developing its strategy, deciding on its competitive positioning and approach, setting priorities in asset allocation, nominating management at the top of the company) such decisions have a confidential character by their very nature. Consequently directors are assumed to respect the confidentiality of all board information (the duty of discretion). Confidentiality is considered essential for the protection of the corporation as well as to guarantee board effectiveness with open discussions, where every director can be critical and frank. Our own experience with board evaluation reveals that a lack of confidentiality can also be detrimental for the trust between the board and management, in particularly for the openness in the information flow. It is a firm belief that individual directors have to abstain from any public information on the board decisions and underlying discussions, unless specifically requested to play such a role (e.g. the chairman may have a more specific communication role). Certainly in listed companies board information may be sensitive and any abuse of fair disclosure and incorrect information may trigger liability claims towards the company and its directors. This makes the decisions behind closed board room doors a kind of a black box4 for the outside world, something contradictory in an era of disclosure and transparency. Carter and Lorsch (2004) ask special attention for this paradox. And they are not the only ones. Especially in the slipstream of the global financial crisis, more and more voices are heard questioning this total discretion. The cry for more external accountability and justification (justification for the decisions made) is growing exponentially. Because of their duty of discretion, directors have to comply rarely with more open justification. It is seldom that the outside world gets a glimpse on how the members of the board contribute as individuals or work together. Most of the time such deliberations as a group escape to the world outside. It is therefore almost impossible for anyone ‘outside the circle’ to get an accurate reading on whether pressing issues are receiving the appropriate scrutiny with pertinent information at hand, and whether decisions are made with due consideration and thorough discussion, in sum whether the board is performing to its potential. That the work of boards takes place ‘behind closed doors’ is the major reason experts are sceptical about many of the current proposals for board reform. An Effective Board Makes the Necessary Trade-Offs 205 And a lack of transparency is usually a fertile ground for myths about boards of directors. Although the norm has long prevailed that board room discussions stay in the board room, an emerging norm of transparency will encourage directors and executives to reveal more about their decisionmaking behind closed doors (Conger, 2009). However, the challenge goes beyond external disclosure and accountability. Our experience in board evaluations and director education has shown that many boards are unaware of the impressions they are giving to other members of the company. Most board evaluations that focus on the board’s image only do so in the context of its members’ images. Board assessment should however attach more importance to improving the internal and external communication on the board’s role, position and decisions taken. The board should find the right balance between installing sufficient trust in the discretion of directors so to stimulate open and frank discussions. But at the same time directors cannot neglect (any longer) that the modern era of disclosure and transparency necessitates that the board finds the right tone in explaining the decisions taken and feels accountable to justify and defend the choices made, the resources invested, etc. This even holds for so-called closed companies: even if they do not rely on external or public funding, they will increasingly need to face the modern demand on more openness. In this context, Paul Strebel (2011) goes a step further by bringing in the position of the critical stakeholders. He argues that boards need an outreach program, an explicit program of reaching out beyond the board room, comprising the following elements: identify which stakeholders are critical for value creation, adapt the composition of the board to enable reaching out to the value critical stakeholders, develop communication channels with them, tune into what they are saying and draw on them to promote the creation of long-term value. However, we should remain vigilant that transparency might encompass an unintended danger. Due to the increasing emphasis on accountability and transparency, board decisions could be impacted by the need for rational explanations and justification. This might induce an attitude of more risk-averse directors and less room for intuition in developing entrepreneurial ventures. Some conclusions The incremental building up of corporate governance laws and regulations, combined with strengthened self-regulatory recommendations, 206 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau led to a construction that is not only very complex, but at the same time contains quite a number of paradoxes, which need further in-depth reflection and trade-offs. The challenge for boards is to look deeper into each of these apparent paradoxes and reflect upon possible ways to make the correct trade-offs. The trade-off to ensure that the board behaves as a collegial body In theory, the board is a college of peers with almost complete absence of formal hierarchy. In practice, this assumption is hard to reach because board organisation necessitates a more formal leadership (chairman) while board composition leads to quite different types of directors: executives, non-executives, independent or not, committee member or not. Not only do these different types of directors have quite different degrees of access to information but also their eventual role as shareholder may put them on a different footing when it comes to decision power. An effective board tries to cure these apparent paradoxes by paying more attention to the role of the chairman in fostering a collegial decision-making. All non-executive directors need to receive the necessary information and induction allowing them a ‘collegial’ involvement in board decision-making. In this respect, the symbiosis between the board and its committees remains one of the largest challenges. In insider models, with shareholders on the board, one must be more vigilant to guarantee that the board (and all directors) foster(s) the corporate interest while the shareholders meeting and dialogue may focus on the interest of shareholders. The trade-off to ensure that the board reaches a consensus The assumption of a collegial body is built on the belief that at the helm of a company, important decisions need to be taken in a consensus style, after ample discussion, open to constructive dissent. Open discussions and constructive dissent of independent free-thinking individuals are hard to combine with smooth consensus decisions that are supported by all directors (also those uttering critique). It certainly necessitates a chairman that is making nice music out of a bunch of creative musicians. But it also supposes a group of directors with the right chemistry and professional board behaviour, elements that have been grossly overlooked in board recruitment and director assessment. An Effective Board Makes the Necessary Trade-Offs 207 The trade-off between direction and control The dual role of the board (to direct and to control) may in itself give rise to a number of tensions. Those roles require a different orientation and behaviour of directors, with monitoring necessitating careful scrutiny and risk aversion, while direction is more oriented towards entrepreneurship and strategic risk-taking. This dual role also implies that the non-executive directors combine the necessary distance with good relationship with management. Moreover one must remain vigilant that the direction role fits with the part-time character of the board and that sufficient delegation is given to the full-time managers and executive directors. The non-executive directors need to find the right balance between oversight and direction, between monitoring management and being their advisors, between challenging the executives while at the same time being supportive of their proposals. The trade-off in composing the board of directors It is increasingly hard to comply with all code and legal requirements for the composition of the board of directors. On the one hand, the board should not be too large in light of effective discussions and board dynamics. On the other hand, an increasing arsenal of diversity and independence criteria complicate the completion of the optimal board configuration. In a one-tier board a first topic for reflection is on the mixture between executive and non-executive directors, which executives (besides the CEO) should be on the board? Although executives can bring a deep knowledge of the company to the board, those executives are working in a hierarchical management structure which conflicts with the peer structure of the board. Independence is considered a precondition for decision-making in the interest of the corporation. However the focus on independence often came at the detriment of sufficient knowledge of the business, while independent directors can complicate reaching consensus in a cohesive board team. Moreover, the respect of strict criteria to define independence is no guarantee at all that those directors will have an independent attitude. Their personality may be less robust than expected or their ability to go against possible abuse of powerful positions may be hampered because finally their nomination may depend on those powerful insiders (shareholder or executive directors). 208 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau Increasingly, the emphasis is on board diversity, with an overwhelming focus lately on gender diversity. Although diversity may deliver better board dynamics, it also offers quite some challenges, such as a more complex recruitment process and a tougher route towards consensus and team building. The solution is to find the right balance between all these different recommendations while at the same time coping with the potential side-effects of those requirements. This again reconfirms the necessity to launch a professional recruitment of directors with sufficient attention for their potential value added as well as for the conditions of effective board dynamics. The trade-off to reach a professional board There is a growing gap between what directors (can) do and what is expected of them. Boards simply cannot achieve everything that is expected of them, even if they do devote more time to their board duties. Doing the right things is the first answer to this challenge. Boards should use their limited resources better, allocate work among colleagues through the use of board committees and focus on their major tasks, rather than trying to be involved in operational issues. A second solution lies in upgrading the ‘time available’ and the ‘professionalism’. Moreover, corporations and their management should facilitate a professional board through a better support of part-time directors. The board duties and the time commitment are increasing exponentially, but the remuneration of non-executive directors is not keeping pace. On the contrary, remuneration of directors is the central focus of huge societal and political attacks, completely ignoring the crucial distinction between executive and non-executive directors. It is time boards and their remuneration committees construct a modern remuneration policy that is in line with the specific challenges a non-executive director is confronted nowadays. The trade-off to reach transparency We live in a time of open communication with social networks and Internet connections and citizens that increasingly demand accountability from everybody. Although the codes on corporate governance and corporate law considerably increased the demands for disclosure (especially in listed companies, this evolution is in sharp contrast with An Effective Board Makes the Necessary Trade-Offs 209 the traditional assumptions of discretion and confidentiality that underscore the decision-making in boards of directors). In light of these tensions the board should act in concert on the best way forward in complying with legal and code recommendations and in answering the huge demands society is placing on their shoulders. Boards should develop a more pro-active outreach plan that not only encompasses public disclosure and justification but also internal communication. Even for corporate insiders, the board is often considered as a black box. Directors should be aware that a lack of transparency is usually a fertile ground for myths about board of directors. Notes 1. Briefing note issued by Ernst & Young in 2007. 2. Different initiatives are taken to create a larger pool such as the supply of education for (potential) female directors and the launch of mentoring projects as it is the case in Belgium and other European countries. 3. These may be two interesting reference groups; the Higgs report in the UK, for example, made the suggestion to compare the level of the remuneration of a non-executive director with the daily remuneration rate of the company’s senior professional advisers. 4. Steen Thomsen (2008) however does not agree with this ‘black box metaphor’. According to him this statement is ill-founded, because companies make increasingly more disclosure about boards. He even goes one step further by proclaiming that today, we know much more about board decisionmaking than about many other kinds of company behaviour. References Acharya, V., Kehoe, C. and Reyner, M. ‘Private Equity vs PLC Boards in the U.K.: A Comparison of Practices and Effectiveness’, Finance Working Paper No. 233/2009, (August 1, 2008). Carter, C.B. and Lorsch, J.W. Back to the Drawing Board: Designing Corporate Boards for a Complex World (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 2004). Charan, R. ‘When directors sweat the small stuff: micromanagement in the boardroom’, The Conference Board Review, XLVII (2009) 46–48. Colvin, J. ‘Dilemma for directors as complexity increases’, The Australian, 13 July 2011. Conger, J.A. Boardroom Realities. Building Leaders Across Your Board (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 2009). Financial Reporting Council, Guidance on Board Effectiveness (London: Financial Reporting Council, 2011). Gilson, R.J. and Kraakman, R. ‘Reinventing the Outside Director: An Agenda for Institutional Investors’, Stanford Law Review, XLIII (1991) 863–906. GUBERNA, Vergoeding voor externe bestuurders van een KMO: Basisrapport en richtlijnen (Brussels: GUBERNA, 2012). 210 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau Lorsch, J.W. and Maciver, E. Pawns or Potentates: The Reality of America’s Corporate Boards (Boston: Harvard Business Review Press, 1989). Lorsch, J.W. Leadership: The Key to Effective Boards. In: Conger, J.A. Boardroom Realities. Building Leaders Across Your Board (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 2009). Meurisse, P. A Board of Directors in Action During a Board Meeting: recovering and describing the phenomenon (Northamptonshire: Veritas Business Services Limited, 2011). Sonnenfeld, J.A. and Ward, A. Conventional Wisdom, Conventional Mythology, and the True Character of Board Governance. In: Conger, J.A. Boardroom Realities. Building Leaders Across Your Board (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 2009). Strebel, P. ‘In Touch Boards: Reaching Out to the Value Critical Stakeholders’, 10th European Corporate Governance Conference (06/12/2010), Brussels Corporate Governance, XI (2011) 603–610. Thomsen, S. ‘A Minimum Theory of Boards’, International Journal of Corporate Governance, I (2008) 73–96. Walker, D. A Review of Corporate Governance in UK Banks and Other Financial Industry Entities (London: The Walker Review Secretariat, 2009). Ward, R. 21st Century Corporate Board (New York: Wiley, 1997). 8 Promoting Effective Board Decision-Making, the Essence of Good Governance Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau Boards are at the helm of the company, making important decisions. According to Meurisse (2011) the board of directors is the most powerful group, having the power not only to internally guide and influence all other organisational actors, but also to externally commit and legally bind the organisation as a whole and in its interaction with other societal actors. This power has been delegated to him by his superior, the shareholder. The board itself, as superior, further delegates to top management, his subordinates. The principal work of boards revolves around complex decision-making (Leblanc, 2009). Useem and Neng (2009) refer to this fundamental board duty as those moments when governing boards face a discrete and realistic opportunity to commit company resources to one course or another on behalf of the enterprise’s objectives, a choice of means to accomplish ends which are not personal. Decisions are made by people, and in the case of a board, by a group of peers1 acting together as a college. A board can only become effective if it is organised as a collective decision-making body. Although this might sound straightforward, numerous companies, large (subsidiary companies) and small ones (unlisted companies), do not organise active board meetings. Consequently, they are losing the value add of a corporate body, dedicated to objective decision-making in the interest of the company. But also a more active board, merely operating as an advisory body, will not reap the benefits of group decision-making. In such cases, there is no need to take diverging opinions into consideration; the leader’s opinion will (probably) prevail. Again, the company dares to lose the most valuable thing of a group, that is collective wisdom. It is only with active board members that the essence of collective decision-making will be realised. 211 212 ● ● ● ● ● ● ● Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau Good governance must be embedded in a company’s values. It provides mechanisms to ensure leadership, integrity and transparency in the decision-making process. The board should be small enough for efficient decision-making. It should be large enough for its members to contribute experience and knowledge from different fields and for changes to the board’s composition to be managed without undue disruption (board composition). No individual or group of directors should dominate the board’s decision-making. No one individual should have unfettered powers of decision-making (group dynamics). The agenda should list the topics to be discussed and specify whether they are for information, for deliberation or for decision-making purposes (board organisation). Evaluating the actual contribution of each director’s work, the director’s presence at board and committee meetings and his constructive involvement in discussions and decision-making (board assessment). The board should set up specialised committees to analyse specific issues and advise the board on those issues. The decision-making remains within the collegial responsibility of the board. Clear procedures should exist for proposals from the executive management for decisions to be taken by the board and for the decisionmaking by the executive management (board organisation). Figure 8.1 The guidance on good decision-making, given by the Belgian Corporate Governance Code Increasingly, the governance codes pay attention to effective board decision-making. For example, the Belgian Corporate Governance Code for listed companies sets out different points of attention, as listed in Figure 8.1. Although these proposals already point to the importance of group dynamics and collective decision-making, and refer at least to some of the underlying conditions (such as board composition and board organisation), transparency obligations or public monitoring will be sufficient to reach that goal. It is only with a board assessment that such sensitive matters as group dynamics and board behaviour can be thoroughly analysed. This chapter analyses the route towards effective board decision-making. Quality decisions will depend upon numerous factors, such as the composition of the board, the manner in which the board is led and directors interact among themselves and with management. We will structure the discussion on how to reach effective board decision-making around six key components (see Figure 8.2): board leadership, board dynamics, Promoting Effective Board Decision-Making, the Essence of Good Governance 213 2.1. Board leadership 2.6. Board composition 2.2. Board dynamics 2. Effective Board Decision-Making 2.3. Professional behaviour 2.5. Board information 2.4. Board organization Figure 8.2 Effective board decision-making thanks to group dynamics (2.2) professional behaviour, board organisation, board information and board composition. Each of these components includes a set of drivers that will be explained in the next paragraphs, with the exception of board leadership that deserves a special chapter (Chapter 9). The board as a collective decision-making mechanism The legal assumption, underpinning the installation and operation of a board of directors, is that, at the top of the company, one needs a collegial body, striving to reach decisions in a consensus style. This legal assumption is built on the belief that in order to decide on the most important corporate affairs, one needs a well-balanced reflection while at the same time installing a ‘checks and balance’ culture within the organisation. This is in sharp contrast to the centralised power delegated to a CEO. In fact, decision-making through a ‘college’ is much more complex and challenging than individual decision-making. However, it also apparently offers some benefits in comparison to individual decision-making. Individual leaders might be more efficient decision-makers 214 ● ● ● ● Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau The many are smarter than the few or as the French say ‘du choc des idéesjaillit la lumière’; Collective wisdom shapes business, economies, societies and nations; Group decisions will over time be intellectually superior to the isolated individual, no matter how smart or well-informed he may be: due to the law of large numbers, neutralising errors, etc.; Diversity contributes not just by adding different perspectives to the group, but also by making it easier for every director to say what they really think. Figure 8.3 Benefits of group decision-making from a timing perspective, but the downside might well be that their decisions are more subjective, pay less attention to the numerous (sometimes conflicting) interests of a corporation and are less well-balanced in light of a complex business environment, full of volatility and uncertainties. Illustrative of the benefits of group decision-making are the values attached to the ‘wisdom of crowds’ (Surowiecki, 2004) as explained in Figure 8.3. The worldwide assumption is that corporate decision-making at the helm of the (larger) company should be based on collective reflection and group decisions. Effective collective decision-making is very crucial for realising the value add boards are created for. Yet, at the same time it is a very challenging element that has not received the attention it deserves in light of the complexities involved in reaching that goal. It sounds like an ideal situation: gather a diverse group of accomplished, energetic, dedicated leaders from all walks of the public and private sectors; give them stewardship of an important enterprise; and let them prioritize the relevant issues and make good decisions for present and future shareholder value. A dream story, but it doesn’t always work like magic. (Walton, 2009) In reality, boards can only look for ‘satisfying’ decision-making. In general, running a company requires making decisions that may turn out poorly, taking entrepreneurial risk and acting on the basis of imperfect information (Paredes, 2004). Real life is not about making optimal decisions with perfect information and using fully rational thinking, but about making sufficiently Promoting Effective Board Decision-Making, the Essence of Good Governance 215 acceptable decisions, often using subjective judgement, given the constrained resources (including time and financial cost) available to individuals as well as organisations. (Simon, 1983) Board decision-making suffers from what is called ‘bounded rationality’. Indeed, board decision-making is not a completely rational process (problem definition, generating solutions, choosing the solution, execution and follow-up) but bounded by numerous complexities as well as decision-making infirmities and biases. Different types of pressure can inhibit the quality of board decisions. Directors may suffer from insufficient information, certainly in light of the growing volatility and uncertainty for corporate affairs. The board information can be abstract, complex at best and may be partly or completely lacking at worst. There may be insufficient time to thoroughly reflect on all relevant aspects and risks. But being a non-executive director may also mean a lack of sufficient resources and support to study all of the relevant aspects. Moreover, some of the major corporate decisions might resemble a big bet: once done, they are hard to undo (such as M&A). Consequently, the more important decisions are, the more attention should be paid to the decision-making process. Andrew Campbell (ICSA 2011) gives some suggestions (see Figure 8.4). Board effectiveness should work on each of these challenges. Nevertheless, it will be impossible to eliminate risk completely: the more volatile the business environment, the more difficult it becomes to judge beforehand the consequences and risks attached to major corporate decisions. It may therefore be appropriate to pay more attention to the underlying uncertainties, the assumptions, possible scenarios, while at the same time looking for sufficient flexibility and adaptability ● ● ● ● ● Describe the process the proposal has gone through: who was involved? The one who champions the proposal should present it directly to the board Consider options; Get independent views; Put additional safeguards in place, such as to prevent conflicts of interest; Do not let the champion participate in the decision-making. Figure 8.4 Suggestions for board decision-making 216 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau (escape ways) in case evolutions oblige such corrective steps, more specifically the analysis of the strategy role of the board. The primary setting where decision-making takes place is the board meeting. The board room is supposed to be ‘the arena’ where directors (and top management) come together and interact as a group. Meurisse (2011) describes a board meeting as a context-sensitive board process, a joint activity in context, that board members jointly constitute, whilst they are shaping the board meeting, paying attention to what they do together (tasks) as well as how (process/behaviour). In studying boards, he has identified a standard flow of activities in the decision-making process (a summary is provided in Figure 8.5). This sequence in board decision-making appears to be straightforward but at the same time it shows the vulnerability when specific steps are missing or are not well carried out. We agree with Meurisse that context and group characteristics as well as group behaviour mutually interfere and dynamically shape the board meeting and hence effective decision-making. Therefore, we try to ravel out some of the steps of the decision-making process and as such to shed a light on the inner workings of the board. ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● Opening of the agenda point by the meeting chair. Reporting by the owner of the agenda point. The meeting chair explicitly invites reactions. Board members react upon the reporting: such intervention might take the form of demanding more information (question), challenging, tacit expressions of not being assured (yet) and explicit formulation of (not) being assured. The owner provides complementary reporting of the agenda point, gives answers to the questions raised and tries to give additional assurance either directly after each intervention, or after the discussion round. If these are not sufficiently assuring the directors continue their discussion. The chair may interfere in this discussion for reasons of time management or to bring the discussion back on track. When the chair considers the time right, he summarises the discussions and comes to the tacit or the explicit (consensus) decision or conclusion. If no explicit remarks on the proposed conclusion/decision, the meeting chair closes that point of the agenda and opens up a next one. Figure 8.5 Standard flow of activities in the decision-making process Promoting Effective Board Decision-Making, the Essence of Good Governance 217 Influence of group members on each other is inescapable Group members influence each other, certainly in a relatively small group. In fact, small groups have an identity of their own and this is overwhelmingly clear when comparing the workings of different corporate boards (also over time). Board members can become so identified with the group that the possibility of dissent seems practically unthinkable. Such groups can exacerbate our tendency to prefer the illusion of certainty over the reality of doubt. Where internal cohesion and loyalty prevail, one strives for unanimity at the detriment of valuable counter opinions and critical evaluation of alternatives. It is crystal clear that board effectiveness necessitates that we try to overcome the danger of emphasising consensus over dissent and more generally the danger of group think and herding. The concept of ‘group think’ was invented by Irving Janis (1983) to describe specific patterns of conformism and collective misjudgement of risks. It refers to social pressure to conform, and consequently not opening people’s mind but closing them. Herding is following one’s peers, influential people (obedience to authority or expertise) or those speaking first. In general, the danger is sticking with the crowd, not challenging, in order not to stand out but to conform. Those with opposing views often convince themselves that the majority view is correct. Herding danger may especially be relevant in boards with a strong majority coalition or strong personalities. The danger of group think might increase with autocratic leaders or when the group gets more closed and more isolated. As we have seen with the financial crisis (see Figure 8.6), group think and herding may lead to collective misjudgement of risks (neglecting potential risks, adverse effects etc). The more isolated a group becomes, the more they can get a feeling of invulnerability. Exposure to external transparency The pressure for conformity on boards can be strong, generating corresponding difficulty for an individual board member who wishes to challenge group thinking. Such challenge on substantive policy issues can be seen as disruptive, non-collegial and even as disloyal. Yet, without it, there can be an illusion of unanimity in a board, with silence assumed to be acquiescence. The potential tensions here are likely to be greater the larger the board size, so that an individual who wishes to question or challenge is at greater risk of feeling and, indeed, of being isolated. Figure 8.6 Extract from the Walker report regarding pressure for conformity 218 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau and accountability is therefore an important lever for more empathy and critical reflection. Diversity and independence as remedies for effective group decision-making To overcome the danger of group think and herding it might be opportune to look for remedies that bring diversity of opinion and independent position taking (Surowiecki, 2004). Most governance codes and recommendations attach quite a lot of importance to installing the necessary degree of diversity and independence when composing the board of directors. The underlying rationale is that diversity of opinion is the single best guarantee to reap the benefits from face-to-face board discussions, questioning evidence, revealing uncertainties, etc. A minority viewpoint leads to debate, more nuanced decisions and more rigorous decision-making. Diversity of opinion is driven by sociological, conceptual and especially cognitive diversity, adding different perspectives, better and more novel conceptualisation of problems and various possible solutions, picking the good ones, while killing the losers. Diversity is all the more important in small groups, hence the importance of bringing in new members, new ideas and opinions. Secondly, independent director opinions are not determined by those of others but are (relatively) free from the influence of others. Independent directors are best placed to express an individual judgement, an own opinion, that may well deviate from the mean stream of thinking (independence procures diversity of opinion). However, independence must not be confused with rationality (an independent view can be irrational), nor with impartiality (independent views can be biased). However, such input recommendations by themselves are no guarantee for constructive dissent. Different types of research have proven that more is needed in order to overcome group think and herding. A recent study of Hudson on gender diversity in the board room, for example, revealed that there are no significant differences in board behaviour of female versus male directors. This is contrary to the significant differences at lower levels of hierarchy. They explain this phenomenon by the ‘coalition of the dominant’, whereby personality is adapted (a kind of cloning) to be able to ‘belong’ to the dominant group (male). A solution might be to require a minimum number of female directors (allies who go against the tide), as is foreseen in the numerous quota regulations that were introduced recently (with quota between 30% and 40% of gender diversity). A comparable outcome was observed in studying the Promoting Effective Board Decision-Making, the Essence of Good Governance 219 effect of independence on group decision-making. Our recent review of the board practices at listed companies in Belgium revealed that outside a more pronounced role in the different board committees, independent directors are not perceived to perform a different role than their nonindependent colleagues. This does not mean that they do not operate as professional directors, but that their interventions in board room discussions are not perceived as being different from those of their colleague directors. In contrast to the gender diversity issue, this is not a matter of an insufficient number of independent directors. These observations convince us more than ever that the judgement of independence should not be based on a detailed check list of a priori independence criteria.2 In fact, a thorough board assessment should include an in-depth analysis of individual director board behaviour. It is only when independence and diversity lead to more constructive dissent that the conditions for effective collective decision-making will be guaranteed. As Surowiecki (2004) states, it is not so much about sociological diversity but much more about cognitive diversity. Promoting constructive dissent as a remedy for effective group decision-making Directors cannot be uncritical lovers but have to be loving critics of the institution which they are paid to serve. (Crainer and Dearlove, 2007) A candid dialogue and constructive dissent are essential to guarantee effective group decision-making. By asking critical questions and by challenging assumptions, directors may force executives to explain and justify their tentative decisions, prior to execution. Effective boards encourage candid dialogue, inquiry and challenging arguments by directors. Open dialogue supposes that there is sufficient time for discussion before decisions are taken and that directors are proactive, inquisitive and highly responsible people in search of the best solution for the company. It is about asking questions, providing an alternative view, being a sceptical voice when all are in agreement. Well-positioned logic and constructive criticism strengthen relationships and commitment rather than damage them. The challenge is to question but not hurting nor inquisitor, to explore but not putting down anyone and to constructively interrogate the argument. Such approach ensures successful adoption of the proposal, reduces risk and safeguards the reputation of the organisation and also increases the commitment 220 ● ● ● ● ● ● Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau Directors should never doubt that their contribution is not sought or valued. Boardroom conversations have to be well-managed, so that different points of view are heard, contemplated, debated and synthesised. The chair should foster active discussions, getting each director into the discussion, solicit individual expressions of opinions especially on touchy issues. Once emotions are drawn to the surface, the chair should use his personal strength to work through these sentiments with considerable resilience and discipline. Conversations should incorporate specialised knowledge but not allow specialists or experts to dominate the decisions. Individual interest should never hamper an open discussion or guide the decision making. Consensus is not important at the start of the process, but only at the end. To reach consensus it is important to check with all directors before reaching a major decision while not pushing too quickly deciding on important strategic choices. Be aware of executives who are defensive and not open with the board! But vice versa be aware that directors may also shoot the messenger if management reports bad news. Also pay attention to the fact that directors also need to listen to each other and to management. The chances are that directors talk a lot but listen less. Figure 8.7 A recipe for constructive dissent of the board and management to a project. A recipe for constructive dissent in provided in Figure 8.7. Expressing different opinions is important to prevent the pluralistic ignorance syndrome (Westphal and Bednar, 2005), that is, directors may not dare to express their personal opinion because they think that the others do not share the same opinion or that a different opinion will not be accepted. In any case, we should be aware of the potential impact of the one who makes a proposal, or formulates the first choice. The proposal or the first reaction may trigger the others to follow (nonconflicting followers). If there is no room for constructive dissent we risk ending up with the Abeline paradox, that is, taking a collective decision that nobody really wants because everyone went along with the proposal, thinking that the others would like it. In fact, directors may seriously underestimate that other directors share their concern based on the illusion of unanimity. Or as Surowiecki (2004) puts it: ‘a camel is a horse made by consensus’. Diversity has numerous advantages for a well-balanced decision-making, but only if opinions are made explicit. Promoting Effective Board Decision-Making, the Essence of Good Governance 221 The real value add of collective decision-making stands or falls with the acceptance or not of diversity of opinions. Group norms can however discourage dissent and add pressure to reach consensus quickly. Directors shut up in order not to violate the board’s norms or offend peers, not wanting to rock the boat. Even though they notice problems at the horizon, they stop asking questions or expressing doubts, even when not convinced. ‘Going along’ is a relatively low-cost strategy (Paredes, 2004). The last couple of years we observed societal critique that directors did not dare to challenge management sufficiently or ask hard questions about board proposals. Especially Sir David Walker puts this sharp in his analysis of the banking industry (see Figure 8.8). According to Conger (2009), numerous failures were caused by directors that became complacent and too confident in their top management. Generally, people are biased to avoid the cognitive dissonance that dissenting gives rise to. Board leaders and other directors face great difficulty in dealing with dissonant information. Individuals tend to interpret new evidence, at least initially, as being consistent with their strongly held prior beliefs. Consequently, they are slow to accept new information inconsistent with these beliefs (cognitive dissonance). It takes courage to go against the tide and stick to ones beliefs, even if they are a minority of one. It is at this point that true ‘independent’ board behaviour becomes observable. In order to convince others of the necessary nuances or opposition, directors will have to find allies who can enhance the influence of challenging opinions. In the end, it really comes down to ‘negotiation skills’, understanding board dynamics, knowing who are (the other) influential directors and what their thoughts on the issues at hand are. The essential ‘challenge’ step in the sequence (of decision-making) appears to have been missed in many board situations and needs to be unequivocally clearly recognised and embedded for the future. The most critical need is for an environment in which effective challenge of the executive is expected and achieved in the boardroom before decisions are taken on major risk and strategic issues … serious shortcomings in the financial sector were above all the failure of individuals or of non-executive directors as a group to challenge the executive on substantive issues as distinct from a conventional relatively box-ticking focus on process. Figure 8.8 Extract from the Walker Report regarding the lack of challenge 222 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau Sir David Walker (2009) has given us another wake=up call, by putting the spotlights on the intolerance of the CEO towards challenging in the board room. He argues that: Even a strong and established CEO may have a degree of concern, if not resentment, that challenge from the non-executive directors is unproductively time-consuming, adding little or no value, … the greater the entrenchment of the CEO, perhaps partly on the basis of excellent past performance and longevity in the role, the greater is likely to be the risk of CEO hubris or arrogance and, in consequence, the greater the importance (and, quite likely, difficulty) of nonexecutive director challenge. It is worth exploring whether a process is in place to ensure that all angles are canvassed. Is there a workable model that provides directors the opportunity to ask penetrating questions that may make management uncomfortable, yet avoids or at least minimises the feeling of being personally attacked? Opposition may be organised in case of very important decisions, for example, by formally allocating the responsibility for opposite or alternative views, by creating a (special) committee, betting the business decision or appointing a designated critic. However, a critical director may feel marginalised after a number of interventions, both by management and his fellow board members as having never anything positive to say. In order to keep the collegial and team spirit in the board it is important to rotate the responsibility for opposition, so that the danger of being stigmatised as the negative one is not falling on one or some directors. In any case, a professional director should not agree with a rubber stamping role, with management reporting a decision as a ‘fait accompli’ without the opportunity to explore alternative courses of action or with a chairman who is monopolising the decision-making process. Everyone benefits from a beast in the boardroom (Kellaway, Financial Times, 9 October 2011) In today’s governance environment special attention is also required for the impact of board committee proposals. Directors, who are not member of the committee in question, should remain vigilant and be aware that committee proposals may seem much more consensus than the underlying discussions within the committee. A committee may have a stylised effect showing a tendency to speak with one voice after Promoting Effective Board Decision-Making, the Essence of Good Governance 223 the committee meeting. The same attention should be paid to strategic proposals coming from management. To some extent the challenge of a non-nuanced view also exists for board decisions vis-à-vis external parties. Dutch research states it as follows: The desire to speak with one voice, the inclination to paint a rosy picture by some members, the suppression of scepticism by others, etc. can be explained by the wish of board members to come across as well informed. (Visser and Swank, 2006) In our opinion it is more the collegial decision-making that necessitates directors speaking with one voice towards the external world. Nuances or differences in opinion should in principle be kept internally unless the opposing director explicitly wants to see this mentioned in the minutes and the annual report to the shareholders (e.g. in case the director wants to limit his or her liability). Preventing unconstructive dissent as a remedy for effective group decision-making However, a culture to support or even stimulate directors to speak up and express their doubts or differences of opinion should be managed with great care. Board assessment should pay special attention to the danger of individual director interventions that might undermine the effectiveness of the board’s deliberations. Some directors might play a follower role or shut up in order not to ‘look stupid’. Others might expose a ’look good’ attitude and use the meeting to score points with other directors to prove that they are very wise, or have read their board papers. Discussion monopolists might undermine the decision-making process. Some directors take up time describing how wonderful they have done in their company, failing to tackle the real critical issues at hand in this board. Powerful individuals can unwittingly divert the conversation down a number of unproductive avenues. Board interaction should allow functional cognitive conflict or constructive dissent. However, the border line with dysfunctional or affective conflicts is a sensitive one. Essential is the question if differences of opinion are considered as positive functional conflicts or rather as dysfunctional affective conflicts. Differences of opinion can be interpreted as personal critique, meant to be confrontational or merely as political gaming. Sometimes there is a very fine line with functional conflicts. Managers sometimes complain about the way critique and questions of 224 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau directors are put forward. Some even call this growing critical attitude of boards the ‘boardroom blitz(krieg)’ (Crainer and Dearlove, 2007). They complain that management prepares lengthy documents to be sent out 10 days before the board, allowing the directors to read and think them through. But directors sometimes only read their material on their way to the meeting, extracting at random some tricky questions, entering the boardroom ready to fire. In this respect, Kakabadse and Kakabadse (2008) pleads to pay more attention to the substantial difference between a dialogue and a debate. Debate has a rather negative connotation as it induces win or lose (beating down) and the taking of sides for or against, so that the most powerful presence in the board room carries the case, irrespective of whether that is the best argument. In contrast, in a dialogue everybody Step 1: break down the argument into workable components: the chairman coaches the management to emphasise the relevance (to the organisation, its strategy and policies), alignment (with strategy and other initiatives, projects), commitment of management, quality of supporting evidence and justification of the case; Step 2: position the argument, with a clear display of point and counterpoint; hidden behind are often powerful emotions; how an argument is introduced and the signals from the chair can make a huge difference! Step 3: manage expectations: no board likes surprises; the chairman’s guidance of the challenges facing management assists the board to realistically assess the merits of the case put before them; setting stretching expectations is motivational, but requiring impossible hurdles to be met deteriorates the performance of management; as the chairman positions the board to be receptive to the argument from management, he also briefs management concerning board expectations and mind-set; Step 4: have a full and frank discussion: the form of the discussion depends on the psychological contract between the chairman & the CEO! The aim is to have all board members fully involved in the discussion; Step 5: rework the argument to get final approval; a half-hearted yes is more damaging than rethinking the proposal; on the management side, all too often propositions never reach the board for fear of rejection, not because the case is weak but because the board is not ready; effective boards facilitate the reworking through a no shame culture, no pet themes, clear criteria for reworking as well as realistic time frames. Figure 8.9 Steps for effective and constructive decision-making Source: Kakabadse and Kakabadse (2008). Promoting Effective Board Decision-Making, the Essence of Good Governance 225 is engaged, no one wins. More specific, dialogue encourages in-depth, uninhibited mutual exploration and inquiry to find the argument which is best, given the circumstances and context. Effective and constructive dialogue encompasses five steps, set out in Figure 8.9. Although it is clear that an effective board should stimulate dialogue over debate, this requires fundamental skills of the board members. According to Herman Van den Broeck and colleagues (2006), the quality of board decision-making depends upon the cognitive capacities of the directors and the process of interaction (allowing functional cognitive conflict and constructive dissent). You can be the smartest person, but if you don’t speak out frankly, it’s worthless. You’ve got to be effective in communicating, in a way that people will listen to and not just turn off. (Finkelstein and Mooney, 2003) Moreover, it does not prevent that conflicts still arise because the interests at stake may be quite different. According to Nordberg (2011) tensions on the board can come from the interactions between the different actors involved: executives (seeking to have their proposals and policies adapted), non-executives (checking the executives) and the chairman (arbiter of disputes). Besides, directors might exhibit a tendency towards unconstructive dissent. Such attitudes and potential conflicts need to ● ● ● ● ● Assess what kind of conflict is driving the problem: task conflict, relationship conflict, process conflict or some combination of the three. Remember that trust is gold dust in these situations. With trust a board can have strong task conflict without it turning personal. But in the absence of trust, task conflict has a tendency to mutate into personal dislike. Where you don’t have strong trust among the board, use a qualified consensus decision rule (i.e. everyone agrees they can ‘live’ with the decision). Avoid a majority-rule decision-making process where possible. Such rule can usually be an excuse for the majority to quickly silence a dissenter. Moreover engaging with minority opinions has typically been associated with high-quality group decision-making. If you are in doubt about the level of trust and conflict in the board, then discuss it with the board members or go for an externally supported board assessment exercise. Figure 8.10 Recipe for managing conflict in the boardroom 226 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau be managed. Certainly when it comes to personal conflicts, this often turns toxic. Rules to successfully manage conflict may include the following steps (Peterson, 2007) (see Figure 8.10). Also important in preventing dysfunctional conflict in the boardroom is the style of questioning. Directors should preferably pose their questions in a non-threatening, non-personal and well-organised way. A practical suggestion is to transfer the opposing or alternative views to management beforehand, so that they can take the time to thoroughly consider the alternatives. Another route is to organise the decision-making in several steps by asking management to develop an adapted version, taking into consideration the different opinions. A second round of discussion can then follow, before finally deciding on important matters. The introduction of an open-ended point at each board meeting may offer the opportunity for expressing more general concerns, doubts and raising specific questions and consequently may help in fostering an atmosphere or culture of open dialogue (Campbell and Stuart, 2009). From diversity of opinion towards consensus decisions However good the debate, finally a decision must be made. Directors have a shared destiny as they are part of a collegial body. There are only board decisions, and there are no individual decisions. Directors must align behind common goals and live the collective results. It is clear that the final goal within the board of directors is to reach a consensus, supported by all board members. Moreover, once a decision is reached, the CEO should have the full support of the board in implementing it. However, consensus-building might be quite challenging. Evidence of research on groups point out that also in boards, coordination problems may arise.3 Coordination becomes increasingly difficult the more diverse and outspoken director opinions are. The challenge is to reach a good cooperation between a group of ‘high caliber’ individuals, each with their own ego, their own independence status, their specific point of view, style, personality and back ground. In addition, we know – from the work of Surowiecki (2004) – that there will be problems with decision-making in a small group if there is no method of aggregating the opinions of its members. However, this recipe does not work that well in a collegial body. Instead of a simple majority rule or a super majority for certain types of decisions,4 a collegial body should strive for unanimity, certainly for very fundamental decisions. Reaching a consensus may offer extra stress because the normal coordination methods may Promoting Effective Board Decision-Making, the Essence of Good Governance 227 be considered insufficient. Anyhow, for a collegial body there should be some alternative rules, in case of persistent differences in opinion. Of course, decision-making may be facilitated by autocratic leadership, but such leadership endangers group think, again eliminating the mere advantages of a collegial decision-making body. In practice, the personality and style of the chairman as well as that of the CEO can exert a considerable impact on the final decision-making. The CEO may be particularly convincing and able to persuade (which is an important source of CEO control). Since non-executive directors are not equipped to exercise better judgment than the CEO (because of his informational advantage), the rational choice of non-executives may be to go along with the insiders who have the best insight. A board should always be vigilant towards charismatic and confident leaders, certainly once they tend to become overly self-confident and subject to hubris. But also autocratic chairmen may fail to welcome dissent or to seek out alternative courses or disconfirming opinions, installing a culture of consent, pushing decisions and avoiding trouble and conflict. Furthermore, directors should also be aware of the dangerous ‘salami technique’. This technique, sometimes used by management, consists of cutting large strategic decisions into smaller pieces to allow the board to address them sequentially. This requires vigilant directors: after making a decision, they should not only ensure that these partial decisions are well implemented but foremost it should be clear from the outset that many secondary subsequent decisions, which stem from the primary decision, are dealt with from the very beginning. A special point of attention is which ‘non-board members’ are invited to the board, for example to make presentations. Even if such persons do not have decision-making power they might well influence the outcome of the discussion and the final decision in different ways, for example by their presentation, their intervention in the discussion, their non-verbal utterances (like nodding their head) or the place they receive at the board room table (Meurisse, 2011). Finally, directors should avoid the practice of frequently postponing decisions because differences in opinion remain (evasive attitude, side-stepping the problem). It is at this point that the chairman should step forward and expose his force of synthesis and consensus building. After encouraging debate and comment, the chairman should focus on the main conclusions and propose a decision with conviction and persuasion (what he says and how he says it are fundamental for final decision-making). 228 ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau Is the chairman’s leadership style effective? Do the chairman and CEO have a good working relationship? Do they understand their respective role? Does the CEO encourage contributions from the board? Is the relationship between management and the directors a constructive one? Are there agreed procedures for contact between management and directors outside board meetings? Can individual directors raise issues for discussion without difficulty, in other words is dissent OK? Do directors express their views to each other and to management in ways that are constructive? Having reached decisions, are directors cohesive in supporting the board’s decision? Is bad news communicated quickly and openly by management to the board? Figure 8.11 Reflection question on board dynamics From the various points tackled in the previous paragraphs, it becomes clear that checking the quality of board dynamics is a difficult exercise and should be tailored to the specific challenges the company and its board is confronted with. As inspiration we include in Figure 8.11 a tentative list of questions for assessing board dynamics (with a scoring scale from 1 to 5 as suggested by Carter and Lorsch, 2004). Professional (director) behaviour (2.3) Room for improvement Board dynamics can only be developed effectively if the constituent parties of the board, that is, the directors, behave in a professional way. In contrast to the attention paid to the board of directors, its structure, composition and organisation, the governance codes have not sufficiently emphasised the professional behaviour of directors. This again is a much more qualitative aspect of board effectiveness that is difficult to judge from the outside. We have already pointed that the debacle of numerous financial institutions that apparently had good governance records, based on the public monitoring of their disclosed board statistics, was a wake-up call. The inconsistent governance ratings alarmed experts as well as politicians to turn their attention increasingly to the Promoting Effective Board Decision-Making, the Essence of Good Governance 229 promotion of professional director behaviour. In addition, we observe a huge increase in expectations towards directors. Being a director these days can seem like competing in the Olympic high jump – you might put in a world-beating performance, but the bar just keeps getting higher … There is an expectation gap between how the public and the law see the role and responsibility of nonexecutive directors as against what could reasonably and realistically be expected of the directors, given the complexities of managing a modern corporation”. (Colvin, The Australian, 13 July 2011) As can be detected from the recent European Green Papers on corporate governance, the European Commission tries to stimulate member states to pay more attention to the time availability and the commitment of (non-executive) directors. Regulators increasingly interfere to limit the number of mandates per director, certainly in listed companies. These conditions will become more and more important, given the complex and more demanding job. Directors should think carefully before joining a board and check to what extent their existing engagements allow an additional board mandate. On the other hand, bringing the need of sufficient involvement of directors to the front should also push companies to act more rigorous in their selection process and choice of new board members. But the business world itself does not sit still too. There is a tendency to stimulate directors to commit to a personal code or charter of professional behaviour. Various companies have already articulated their expectations towards the directors in a ‘code of conduct’ while other private initiatives start to flourish. GUBERNA, the Belgian Director and Governance Institute, for example developed a ‘Guidance for the professional director’ in close collaboration with its member network. The aim is to create awareness among individual directors of a professional attitude and to provide them with a practical tool that supports such behaviour. One important lesson learned from the past incidents is that effective governance is predominantly determined by the governance attitude and behaviour of individuals. Therefore a judgement of the governance quality should primarily pay attention to those more immaterial and behavioural aspects. Such examination necessitates a comparison of the actual governance practices with the external norms and guidelines as well as with the internal board norms and board culture. Moreover, a closer look at the engagement, commitment, involvement and attitude, 230 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau so examining the ‘performance’ of the individual directors becomes crucial to complete the board assessment. Unfortunately, in most cases such ‘individual’ evaluations might pose serious resistance even more than towards a collective board assessment. While most boards no doubt expect annual evaluations of the senior management, most do not hold their own performance to the same level of scrutiny. (Sonnenfeld and Ward, 2009) If a board is asking senior management to re-examine the way they manage the company, it had better re-examined itself as well (Campbell and Stuart, 2009). Behaviour in line with external and internal norms External as well as internal factors may influence board behaviour.5 Although directors meet in private, their decisions are often scrutinised and criticised in the public arena, so they risk damaging their reputation, and risk legal repercussions. This has undoubtedly an impact on individual behaviour. However, the most important impact will come from the role and leadership style of the chairman as well as from the norms that evolve in any group. ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● Active involvement of directors is stimulated. Directors ask tough questions without management becoming defensive. Dissent among directors is encouraged, and pressures for conformity to the majority opinion are acknowledged and guarded against. Knowing that everyone in the room is ultimately honest and has the best interest of the organisation at heart. Directors aren’t intent on scoring points, by putting other directors or management down. Instead they respect each other’s opinion and expertise and engage in discussions with the goal of reaching understanding and consensus. Directors understand when to listen and when to stimulate discussion. Any discussion between directors and managers is two-way. Executives can disagree with directors if they believe the latter are misinformed or wrong, and directors really listen to management’s ideas. Directors respect the agenda, are mindful of the schedule and understand the importance of staying focused on the important issues. While discussion is encouraged, they recognise the limits imposed by time. Figure 8.12 The minimum requisite behaviours Promoting Effective Board Decision-Making, the Essence of Good Governance 231 Norms are a set of informal rules derived from shared beliefs which regulate directors’ behaviour (Nadler et al., 2006). These unwritten standards –some would describe them as the board’s culture – determine the behaviours that board members see as appropriate or otherwise as ambiguous, uncertain or sometimes threatening. Much of the effectiveness of the board is determined by the process of the board, how the directors work together, rather than by the actions of the individual director on its own. New directors learn about them by simply observing experienced board members, such as who sits where, how to behave if meetings fall behind schedule, which director’s opinion deserve respect, etc. An overview of the minimum requisite behaviours is provided in Figure 8.12. It’s the chairman’s role to make sure these norms are respected, and to encourage an atmosphere in which different views are seen as constructive and encouraged. Scanning board effectiveness should therefore attach importance to checking if the board behaviour in general and the individual directors’ behaviour more specifically fits with the relevant best practices and norms. But as already highlighted before, critically evaluating individual director performance and attitude is perhaps the most controversial topic because it can undermine board collegiality and may lead to conflict. Rigorous evaluations might drive away good directors (who feel they have already proven themselves sufficiently). Moreover, it is not an easy task to evaluate peers. Directors spend relatively little time together while what occurs in the board room may not be the best gauge of a director’s contribution. It is not only what goes on in the meeting that counts, also sidebar conversations, at dinners, during telephone conversations in-between meetings can really matter! In order to lower the barriers to such individual assessments, a board reflection could start with the review of how the ‘team’ is functioning, if the mix is right, if everyone contributes (which does not mean that everyone should be leading). Some relevant questions are provided in Figure 8.13. Also informing about the ability of the board and committee chairs to have an open dialogue and crucial conversations about why things are working or not working that well is a valuable step forward. The aim is to review how a director can best contribute to the effective functioning of the board. It is also suggested to get some input from management on how it interacts with the board. Individual appraisals could benefit from a self-evaluation form, to be used only in private with the board chair, but this is not enough. The individual bias in self-appraisals needs to be balanced by the perception 232 ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau Does it occur because of the persistent actions of one or a few directors? Is personal feedback needed or should we replace one or two directors? Does the problem lie with the board’s chair or CEO? Do the difficulties stem from the board’s use of time? Is there an overloaded agenda? Do we need more meeting time or more delegation to committees? Or is the quality of knowledge and information a problem? Figure 8.13 Reflection questions on altering board behaviour Source: Carter and Lorsch (2004). ● ● ● Personal one-on-one interviews of the board chair with each individual director, questioning whether they have specific suggestions or constructive advice for any of their fellow directors. However such interviews might inhibit candour, lack supporting objective data and invite assertions of subjectivity or bias. A third-party survey can form a more neutral and less biased framework. External parties can also provide individual feedback to directors (eventually together with the chairman). In-between, different scenarios of a hybrid approach exist. Combining the involvement of a third-party survey with formal individual discussions, reporting back by the chair or by the governance or nomination committee (who can coordinate the board assessment). Figure 8.14 Methods for individual director assessment of others. In practice there may be different approaches or methods as described by Leblanc (2009) (see Figure 8.14). A full-fledged director assessment should be based on a rigorous process and a tailored approach (not a copy-paste questionnaire), with sufficient nuances. A director interview protocol should be tailor-made, taking into consideration the relevant criteria of the specific director profile (personality, functioning as a director, role in board committees, leadership capacities, etc.). In fact, different directors contribute in different ways. As a collegial body, each director will have to deliver its part of the puzzle of expertise, competency and experience. In board committees as well as in board discussions these individual specialities will pop up. A ‘standard’ evaluation may not capture such performance nuances (e.g. director x may not say a lot during meetings but can be instrumental in building bridges outside of meetings). Promoting Effective Board Decision-Making, the Essence of Good Governance 233 According to research of Carter and Lorsch (2004), CEOs are very critical about the value add of their independent directors. They doubt their knowledge of the business and the organisation, their time investment (insufficiently prepared) and the quality of their interventions (cannot recall what happened at previous meetings). However, nowadays under the pressure of governance codes and societal claims, shareholders, management as well as directors themselves are much more exigent on board performance. A good attendance record or perfunctory (routine) questions is no longer sufficient. Appraisals are an effective means to make those new performance expectations clear. Involved directors can bring an added value thanks to their understanding of the company’s critical and strategic issues, being well informed about the important issues facing the company, understanding the industry they compete in, being well aware about what is driving the performance of the company and the main risks the company is taking. Involvement and quality of the preparation will materialise itself in the level of contribution to boardroom discussions and in fulfilling the accountabilities of the board. But these new demands should trickle down into the recruitment process, where much more information will be gathered than just a mere CV. More and more is the attitude of the director what ultimately determines the governance potential a person holds. Not in the recruitment of directors, or in the individual board assessment is this shift of mind towards the ‘soft skills’ of directors already prevailing. These individual director attitudes are becoming more important than (executive) experience. More attention for such attitude elements is therefore essential to improve board effectiveness. An example of relevant attitude elements is given in Figure 8.15. ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● the way a director brings the message, tone of voice; a director can be right without being effective; independent when to put your foot down; separating the less and more important issues; willingness to take constructive stands; constructiveness in addressing and managing conflict in meetings; discretion and confidentiality with board information; willingness to encourage contributions of other directors; effectiveness in communicating; ability to ensure that the board makes decisions. Figure 8.15 Attitude elements 234 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau An in-depth individual director assessment will need to compare the selection profile, the director’s role and his or her performance to come up with suggestions for further individual improvement as well as for the optimisation of the board’s composition. Afterwards mandatory (individual) feedback should be provided to each assessed individual. However, such individual assessments will only bring lasting effect if coupled with a good follow-up and by eventual corrective actions. Are the results acted upon? Are they integrated into a development programme for directors? Are the results linked to continued tenure? The outcome of an individual assessment can indeed serve as an important tool to decide on re-nomination or not (Leblanc, 2009). Director assessment is all the more important when it comes to the chairman, who really performs a pivotal role in creating the right governance spirit, culture and board effectiveness. To this end it might be important to have an externally facilitated board assessment, or at least appoint an independent or lead director to lead the evaluation of the chairman. Given the pivotal role the chairman is playing, this book devotes different chapters to that theme (see Chapters 5, 6, 7 and 9). Gaining expertise in the art of decision-making In modern boards, directors have to become good decision-makers in their own right. According to Goffee and Jones (2006) individual directors should behave as ‘authentic chameleons’. This means that they are able to correctly read the context and choose the one(s) they are able to operate. Moreover, they know how to strike a careful balance between showing emotions and withholding them, getting close and keeping sufficient distance, conforming yet being different, while at the same time being true to oneself and walking the talk. Professional behaviour is more than having interesting contributions to make. Directors should give careful thought to how they are involved in board discussions, contributing to a constructive dissent, keeping the focus on the corporate interest and not on their own personal interest and pet projects, not wasting valuable time in ‘fishing expeditions’ for personal interest issues (not central to the board’s work). They should pay attention to the relevance of their interventions: do they relate to the topics under discussion, do they focus on the most relevant aspects in the interest of the corporation (See section Organising effective board meeting and Using meeting time effectively and efficiently). Promoting Effective Board Decision-Making, the Essence of Good Governance Engaged but nonexecutive 235 Challenging but supportive Independent but involved Figure 8.16 Effective non-executive director behaviour Directors should treat their colleagues as well as the executives with respect and encourage early disclosure of problems (never shoot the messenger). In addition, individual directors should also be aware of their own limits. In studying the work of non-executive directors in the UK, Roberts and colleagues (2005) come up with three couplets of effective behaviours in this respect as summarised in Figure 8.16. Directors should examine their own decision processes – explicit or not. Directors should not prevent but rather promote critical board evaluations in order to reach the goal of continuous improvement also in their personal behaviour. It is learnt from board experience that it is interesting to have from time to time (e.g. at the occasion of a board assessment) an appraisal of the decision-making quality. A good exercise in this respect is a systematic evaluation of very important past decisions (e.g. ex-post evaluation of (underlying assumptions of) an important investment or a post-mortem M&A failure analysis) may help in improving board decision-making. In many cases, a board will find that a decision was sound when it was made but that the business environment changed unexpectedly. Some decisions however will be exposed as flawed from the start (Campbell, 2009). Director typologies Some academics have managed to study individual director behaviour and identified different director types. Most influential in the field is the typology developed by Leblanc and Gillies (2005). They made a 236 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau distinction between functional and dysfunctional directors as shown in Table 8.1. From a different perspective, Dunne (1997) classifies directors in quite a detailed set of director types as listed in Figure 8.17. Table 8.1 Individual director types Functional directors Dysfunctional directors Conductor-chairs Caretaker-chairs Change agents Controllers Consensus-builders Conformists Counsellors Cheerleaders Challengers Critics ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● The silent seether: very clever, very shrewd who sadly lack either confidence or arrogance to get themselves heard, The seether: neither as quiet or as bright; over-promoted insecure type, The key influencer : powerful, e.g. family member, heir, key shareholder (representative), Mr or Mrs Wonderful: ideal board member: strong views but will listen to others, questions rather than states, motivated by what is best for the board/company, never a slave to political correctness or to the convenient, expedient but flawed compromise, shares responsibility, The quiet floater: diplomat, has never done much wrong, letting other do all the fighting and emerging as the winner, The dangerous ones: with nothing more to offer than their silken tongues (wonderful capacity to sound good but aren’t), The really useful old hand: sage guys, seen many swings, survived numerous crises and had the joy of as many triumphs, The really useless or dead hand: little to offer, fearful of anything that involves too much change or disturbance, decision avoidance, The great debater: just likes to talk, winning attention, The young pretender or heir apparent: has not yet reached the formal position, needs a mentor and a constructive critic to keep him balanced, The pulse: has an innate sense of what people think inside and outside, help the board spot the logical decision and to calibrate the baron’s (managing directors) and the seethers (directors), and Rosey: cheering up the rest, finding a positive interpretation, overpromoted super salesman unsuited to a board role. Figure 8.17 Director types Promoting Effective Board Decision-Making, the Essence of Good Governance 237 These few examples of classification categories are withheld to show that directors are human beings which expose specific behaviour in a board context. Depending on the personality and background a director will tend towards a more functional or dysfunctional role. However, this role is not set in stone. In certain situations a director might behave differently than what is perceived to be his normal fashion (Leblanc and Gillies, 2005). This underlines the complexity of the way individual behaviour impact board dynamics and group decision-making. The challenge is to find an optimal mix of behavioural characteristics of directors in the specific composition of the board in order to promote effective board processes. A useful tool in this respect, which combines expertise with behavioural aspects, is the ‘Diversity Optima Disk’ developed by Martin Hilb and Nils Jent.6 Organising effective board meetings (2.4) Our board satisfies all of the requirements of Cadbury, Greenbury and Hampel, but our board meetings are a complete waste of time. (Carter and Lorsch, 2004) Sooner or later we will have to redesign how the board works from a clean sheet of paper. There are a number of tools we can use for this task: using technology such as teleconferencing, greater use of outside counsel, a core of staff for dedicated board support, streamlining board meetings etc. (Ward, 1997). Using meeting time effectively and efficiently According to Carter and Lorsch (2004) time is the overarching constraint on the role any board can adopt. Increasingly, directors have to commit much more time to their board mandate due to more stringent governance recommendations and societal pressure. Thomsen (2008) is pointing to the time constraints of non-executive directors as one of the main reasons for his opposition against the increasing empowerment of the board of directors. However, by investing more time (and money) and by more efficient use of board meetings, one should get the value add a board has been established for. To get more value from board meetings, every board should critically assess its board organisation. It might be wise to screen the number of board and committee meetings: monthly meetings may slip into a routine with too much focus on detail, but quarterly meetings may be inadequate for the task at hand. Screening the available meeting time includes also an analysis of the duration per meeting. Most directors 238 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau complain that there is too little time scheduled for tackling all agenda points. Adding meetings may be harder to do (certainly for international boards) than adding some extra hours per meeting. As proposed in most governance codes, board committees help to enhance board effectiveness. Different specialised board committees offer the advantage of combining expertise with efficient use of time and division of responsibilities. However, such evolution has to be developed with great care. One must not forget that it is the board as a whole that finally needs to take the decision, based on sufficient insight in the underlying dossier and in the discussion and advice of the different committees. Clear agenda setting helps to have focused discussions and decisionmaking. Effective agenda planning supposes an achievable agenda that focuses on the right topics. A board evaluation exercise should assess whether sufficient time is devoted to the real important issues: do the discussions and decisions relate to the most relevant and prominent challenges the corporation is faced with? One can do so by comparing the time spent for each of the important agenda points with their relative weight or importance. According to Carter and Lorsch (2004) directors frequently spend too little time discussing important strategic issues, the agenda being too much dominated by reviewing the past (what recently happened) and routine items. Therefore, codes often recommend to reserve a substantial part of every board meeting to the major issues affecting the company’s future and to foresee an annual strategic retreat of at least one full day. Effective use of time is more than a question of what topics are on the agenda. A critical board assessment will judge whether there is a good balance between presentations and discussions. The challenge is to have sufficient time to reach meaningful decisions by in-depth analysis and discussion, while not degressing into areas outside the board’s realm. Finding the right balance is difficult and will be quite different from one board model to another. At one end of the spectrum, board time is predominantly used for presentations by management. Paredes’ research (2004) stated that many directors complained that they had relatively little say over what was brought before them and that management presentations consume most of the time allotted to an agenda item, affording directors little opportunity to ask questions and discuss the matter during the formal meeting. This is in line with the research of Carter and Lorsch (2004), observing that directors complain that there is too much time in presentations and insufficient time for meaningful discussion especially on strategic matters. At the other extreme, we observe boards that discuss over and over again, while twisting Promoting Effective Board Decision-Making, the Essence of Good Governance 239 the management presentations in very strict time constraints. Such approach can frustrate well-prepared managers, as phrased by Carter and Lorsch (2004): Senior executives who have been asked to discuss their business are kept waiting outside the boardroom, and are then told they have twenty rather than the originally scheduled forty minutes to talk about an issue that is vital to them… This prevents thoughtful discussion and good decision making on critical issues, and tends to undercut the motivation of the managers affected. It’s also insulting to them. Our own research on governance practices at Belgian listed companies has revealed the following points of attention, and they are listed in Figure 8.18. Although respecting the foreseen timing (start/end time) is a sign of a well-organised board, we should be aware of the danger that finishing meetings timely does not lead to important discussions being truncated because the last items are treated in a hurry. So timing should be aligned with the agenda and overloaded agendas may be dangerous impediments to effective decision-making. A solution that has proven its value in practice is to foresee A- and B-items, with the A-items referring to the most important agenda points that have the priority. The B-items are of less importance and might be placed at the end of the agenda, so that any time pressure leads to quickly going over the less prominent agenda points. Moreover, a good board agenda should clearly point out whether agenda points are for information, discussion or approval. Engagement outside the regular board meetings The empowerment of the board implies a much larger involvement of directors, also in-between meetings. Outside the regular board meetings, directors often meet for board committee meetings. Moreover, ● ● ● ● By moments, too much time spent on presentations by management Too much details are being discussed in board room deliberations Time pressure: dossiers are not sufficiently being tackled in-depth or discussions are being cut to soon Files presented to the board are sometimes too ‘operational’ Figure 8.18 Flaws in board meetings 240 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau directors and managers have ample opportunities to discuss board issues in-between meetings. In this context, Carter and Lorsch (2004) even go a step further and propose to move the involvement of directors outside the board room. In larger (listed) companies hardly any time is spent in conversations with down-the-line managers, visiting plants or key customers, talking to industry experts etc. Given the increasing role of directors of ‘empowered’ boards and taking into consideration the increasing volatility of the business environment non-executive directors need to be much more involved. According to research of Acharya et al. (2008) formal board meetings should become the structured backbone, but not the main body of board interactions. Non-executive directors should make more time available for these informal discussions and meetings with executives as well as for information sessions tailored to the specific needs of the individual director and of the business in a given point in time. Their research showed that the difference in board effectiveness between listed companies and PE-backed unlisted companies is partly based on the difference in involvement of directors. In contrast to practices in listed companies, directors in PE portfolio companies engage with the business in a much more active way, and have numerous informal contacts with management and businesses (phone calls, field visits, ad hoc meetings with executives, interim information etc). This makes them more involved and engaged directors, leading to more effective boards. Whereas previous emphasis was especially on the independence of the board, the new challenge is to have professional directors who really know the business, the challenges the company is faced with, the risks it runs, etc. However, this evolution will again necessitate finding the right balance or Nose In Fingers Out (the so-called NIFO method). A clear procedure how to organise the higher involvement of non-executive directors might be more than helpful. Indeed most CEOs want to know when such conversations with their team members, employees or subsidiaries are taking place. Non-executives may not undermine the CEO’s position and relationship with subordinates. It is therefore necessary to reflect on specific rules for non-executive directors contacting down-the-line managers (e.g. informing the CEO and the chairman/ secretary-general) and vice versa. Director information (2.5) A lack of knowledge is a lack of power. (Monks and Minow, 2001) Promoting Effective Board Decision-Making, the Essence of Good Governance 241 Board material For a board of directors to operate effectively, information is very essential. The board and the committees can only be as good as the info they have at their disposal. The most basic information a director receives is of course the board material, that is, the dossiers with information on each of the (important) agenda points of the board meeting. The time has gone that companies could permit themselves to distribute a limited dossier at the board meeting itself. In essence, board information should be timely, consistent and relevant. Our research of governance practices in listed companies in Belgium has revealed that over the last decade the flow of information and the timing of delivery of board material has considerably improved. That does not mean that there is no room for improvement, even the contrary. In his critique on the empowerment of boards, Thomsen (2008) builds his doubts on board effectiveness among other things (a.o.) on the fact that directors suffer from insufficient information, in so far that their formal (legal) authority does not imply real authority. Especially in the smaller, unlisted and less ‘mature’ companies, providing an active board with sufficient board material may be a huge challenge. Research of Reheul and Jorissen (2010) showed that an important trigger in the development of management information is the installation of an active board with external directors. At other companies, such as the listed or more outspoken in state-owned ones, the problem might be the reverse, i.e. too much information. Paredes’ research (2004) showed that directors complained they do not have the valuable information or in the alternative are overloaded with information. Carter and Lorsch (2004) stated that directors are concerned about the flow of information they receive. Too much information poses serious problems for non-executive directors. With their part-time status, they probably will not have the time to go through all of the nitty gritty details. Weighty dossiers can hide (or bury) essential information. Also our own experience with board evaluations in different types of companies confirms that the expectations towards board material are very diverse. In particular, the individual information needs of directors differ substantially. A gap may exist between what information the non-executive directors want to receive and what management deliver (both in quantity and quality). The challenge is to deal with these diverging expectations and to get clear and concise information that offers sufficient details but only include those elements that add value for good decision-making. A solution that has proven its value in practice is to foresee a thorough executive 242 ● ● ● Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau Trust, but verify management : organise regularly (very) short board sessions without management (but be vigilant to remain polite, trustful and focus on effectiveness); Try to get assurance; Search for extra info. Figure 8.19 Tips for a director regarding board information summary that highlights the most sensitive parts of the important agenda points, giving a clear recommendation as to the proposed decision and the risks involved, eventually amended with a legal and/or financial expert opinion. Still a director can never be guaranteed to have all the relevant info and therefore it is suggested to endorse the behaviour set out in Figure 8.19. Minutes of board meetings can be important reference documents for board decision-making and may guide management in their execution of board decisions and non-executive directors in their follow-up of execution. To this end, special attention should be paid to the quality of the minutes. A common dilemma is whether to record just the decision, or also a summary of the discussion or even the individual interventions (eventually on a name basis). Inquiries with secretary generals reveal that mentioning individual interventions is mostly limited to those dissent voices that explicitly want to be referred to in the minutes. Detailed minutes might be especially relevant to prove the specific diverging opinions, or more generally, the workings and deliberations of the board and the disagreements if any. However especially in the United States warnings are given that elaborate minutes can be a ground of litigation. Finding the right balance of detail is a real challenge (Dunne, 1997). On the one hand the more sterile the minutes the less for a lawyer to have a go at; on the other hand the easier a negligence suit might be. Increasingly, courts and regulators raised questions about the amount and scope of attention that was spent on a matter when the minutes did not adequately support the recollection of the directors as to what transpired (Lipton, 2008). This is not only a practice in the United States but increasingly also in Continental Europe with the Dutch Enterprise Chamber as the leading example. Taking appropriate minutes is an art and the secretary-general (and general counsel) should work with the directors to ensure that the written record properly reflects the discussion and decisions taken by the board. The language Promoting Effective Board Decision-Making, the Essence of Good Governance 243 of board minutes is an art form in itself (sometimes people interpret what has been said as something different). Therefore it is advisable to draft minutes promptly and circulate them to directors for their consideration shortly after the meeting.7 For effective follow-up, preferable minutes are completed with an overview of decisions taken as well as with a detailed list of implementation tasks (to-do list). On top of the periodic pillar of board material, non-executive directors increasingly receive quite a substantial amount of additional (interim) information, such as a monthly business update, investor reports, update on important board files and even daily press clippings about the company and its business environment. Thinking more strategically about board information Even if directors are overwhelmed with the volume of information, they are often underwhelmed by the content. Board material might focus too much on past financial performance and on financial forecasts and too little on competitive performance, customer reactions, swot etc. This was critically put forward by the study of Deloitte (2004), expressively titled ‘In the Dark: What Boards Don’t Know about the Health of their Businesses’. The results of polling nearly 250 board members of different countries were sobering. While the overwhelming majority of board members and senior executives said they need incisive information on their companies’ key nonfinancial drivers of success, they often find such data lacking; when nonfinancial information is available, it is of mediocre or poor value. (Deloitte, 2004) We need to think more strategically about board information. It is essential that directors understand the business model, the functioning of the organisation as well as its strategic challenges, risks and opportunities. At the occasion of a board assessment, directors along with management can carefully define the information the board needs. Developing a list of what is the key information a non-executive director should receive will inevitably differ from one company to another, depending on its portfolio of activities, its business and corporate environment, its development/maturity cycle, etc. For them it is essential to know how the business model really works and what the key drivers of success are. Non-executive directors need a robust understanding of how money is made and at what risk. Therefore, looking at the key questions a director might ask can be a good guidance for composing the 244 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau list of key documentation a director should receive. The following two lists of questions, provided by Carter and Lorsch (2004) and Kakabadse and Kakabadse (2008), can be helpful in this respect (see Figures 8.20 and 8.21). With hindsight of the corporate failures, it might be good to pay special attention to so-called red flags or early warning signs which may provide insight of what is really going wrong in companies. Making board information more memorable and accessible Companies should also make efforts to make information more memorable and accessible. In board reviews, top management complains sometimes about the problems their non-executive directors as part- 1. Where is shareholder value being created and destroyed? Do we know which businesses earn in excess of the cost of capital? 2. What are the long term trends in our business? 3. What are the major risks the company is exposed to (and are these risks well managed)? 4. Are there any financial reporting issues, aggressive accounting? 5. What major projects are under way (capital & change projects) and is implementation on schedule? 6. What is the level of employee morale, retention rate? 7. Is our market share in key markets holding? What are customer satisfaction trends? 8. What is happening to our major brands and our corporate image? 9. How does our strategy differ from that of our competitors? 10. How is our stock viewed by analysts? Are we buy, hold or sell? Figure 8.20 ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ Ten key questions on the company’s business What is the competitive advantage of the firm? Do customers recognise the value this firm provides? Is it the reality that most customers can barely tell the difference between one company’s services and the next except for those at the very top of the value chain? Is price the only real differentiator from the customer’s point of view? What do shareholders expect in terms of return on their investment? Is greater value to be gained from keeping the enterprise together or separating out the assets for sale? Figure 8.21 Some business reflection questions Promoting Effective Board Decision-Making, the Essence of Good Governance 245 timers are faced with. The amount of information they need to master is growing rapidly. Markets are changing at an ever-increasing rate. The task of remembering – let alone keeping up with change – is huge for part-time directors who have to turn their minds to other matters when board meetings are over, and who are often faced with gaps of two months between meetings. To make information more memorable, directors need frameworks to help them capture and hold on to the crucial elements in the flood of information that comes their way. They need to use tools to synthesise and prioritise information. Models such as the balanced scorecard (to evaluate performance), the five forces model of Porter (to analyse competition), the Dupont equation (to analyse the financial outcome) and risk mapping (to define risk appetite) are useful to help directors cope with complexity and to ensure that they focus on the things that really matter. In using new technology, companies can help their directors in making information also more accessible. It could not only facilitate the timeliness of information, but also the possibility to easily retrieve prior information, make comparisons between different files, etc. However, numerous companies do not dare to take the step towards electronic information files for fear of data protection, etc. With all modern techniques available nowadays, this should no longer be an excuse. Necessity of a diversity of information sources In order to fulfil their monitoring role and to come to well-thought-out discussions, non-executive directors have increasingly been asked to combine the information received from management with information gathered by the board itself. The main aim is to overcome the subjectivity of the information that goes to the top of the organisation (see theories of Herbert Simon). In fact, there might be serious bottlenecks and filters the info has to get through, certainly in larger organisations, which implies the danger that the information may be outdated and distorted before it gets to the board. Certainly for important and sometimes controversial dossiers, directors should be able to gather information within the company, coupled with second opinions via site visits, hearings with different types of stakeholders and education/tutorial events (Dunne, 1997). Directors should also have access to outside counsel and support where needed. This is also foreseen in most Codes. Directors can’t offer perspective in a void. They need the support of knowledge and perspective from qualified advisors. (Elson, Hubbard and Zarb, 2012) 246 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau Practice shows that especially board committees rely very frequently on outside counsel. In audit committees there is the support of external auditors and fiscal and due diligence specialist. For benchmarking executive remuneration, remuneration committees often rely on outside counsel. Nomination committees turn to head hunters in search of top management and board vacancies. Governance committees sometimes consult external specialist for developing governance procedures, board charters or for organising a board assessment. Of course boards should guard against overly relying on outside advisors, certainly when the company has substantial in-house support facilities. Kerstetter (2009) reflects on the question when to use or not to use outside board advisors (see recommendations in Figure 8.22). An adjacent question that is increasingly posed is to what extent non-executive directors should be able to rely on a specific support function. In this respect, the Institute of Chartered Secretaries and Administrators (ICSA) and ecoDa (The European Confederation of Directors’ Associations) developed a ‘Board Support Survey’ (2010). Although initially focusing on the board secretary, they observed that in order to reach the goal of board effectiveness and given the huge increase in board responsibilities, non-executive directors are in need of much more ‘support’ than ever before. In the study of Acharya et al. (2008), it is stated that the PE non-executive directors (who represent the PE company on the board of their portfolio companies) can indeed play a much more efficient and active role because they will have junior staff who can analyse data and provide additional support and leverage while delivering a more granular view on topics of board attention. Interestingly, many activist investors joining public company boards will similarly insist on having a budget to cover additional staff support. If we really want to make the empowered board work and realise the value add an effective board can bring to the company, we also should pay attention to the support of independent directors. ● ● ● ● Start with selecting and trusting the right management. Be aware that you can’t hire outside advisors for every decision, the board doesn’t feel comfortable with. You are on the board – at least partially – because of your good judgement. There are no standard rules or guidance when outside board support is necessary. Figure 8.22 Recommendations for the use of outside board advisors Promoting Effective Board Decision-Making, the Essence of Good Governance 247 Director induction and education For effectiveness reasons, companies should install an education process for new directors (induction) as well as invest in the regular refreshment of the knowledge of non-executive directors. But also executive directors will need to undertake specialised board training because they need to effectively make the transition from operational manager (with a focus on one aspect of a firm’s activities) to company director (where they must exercise oversight over the firm as a whole). Induction is essential for all new directors, to provide them the necessary introduction into the company, its board and the duties of directors. The more directors are distant from the business in question (and this is often the case for independent directors), the higher the need for an in-depth induction process. Independent directors bring their unique lens to a problem, but they need to be aware of the limits of that lens, so that for them special education programmes may be very relevant. According to research of Acharya et al. (2008), only one-third of the directors of listed companies they surveyed describe the induction as of high quality. This contrasts substantially with the deep business understanding of non-executive directors in PE portfolio companies (see also the governance manual for NEDs of 3i). According to Kakabadse and Kakabadse (2008), the introduction for a new chairman is even more important, mainly to get information on the board culture and board dynamics, on the critical relationships, the shadow board (those that really pull the strings), those that have negative feelings of being passed over. Besides an induction programme, there is need for continuous director education. This is not only recommended by the Codes but is also emphasised by Sir David Walker (2009) (see Figure 8.23). To ensure that non-executive directors have the knowledge and understanding of the business to enable them to contribute effectively, a board should provide thematic business awareness sessions on a regular basis and each non-executive director should be provided with a substantive personalised approach to induction, training and development to be reviewed annually with the chairman. Appropriate provision should be made similarly for executive board members in business areas other than those for which they have direct responsibility. Figure 8.23 Extract from the Walker Report regarding director education 248 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau Once in office, directors need to stay relevant, individually and collectively (Conger, 2009). Skills have to be kept fresh to be of value. It might also be opportune to schedule field trips to bring directors closer to the company. However, each director may have quite separate and more personalised development requirements. Therefore it is suggested to ask the directors for their ideas on continuing education and to set the tone for active learning. According to Conger (2009) it is important to support active learning, such as by way of corporate-funded directors’ education (in-company). In-board room programs are particularly powerful experiences because the team can learn together. Active learning must be a team phenomenon, because the consequent knowledge gained from active learning must be useful to the full group. However, also board education outside the board room can help directors stay relevant. By learning what other directors are doing, a director can compare and contrast the skills and practices of his or her own board with others, and also calibrate his or her skills in a broader population of directors. Mixing with different directors of different backgrounds, from different sectors and organisations of a considerably different structure and complexity, forces the individual to re-examine his or her assumptions (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2008) Corporate management techniques have benefited from several generations of business school research and training. But the scholarship and study of corporate boards is still a largely ignored field. In many boardrooms there remains little more than shared wisdom and rules of thumb for decisions. (Ward, 1997) For years there has been little or no formal education for most directors. In contrast with general management education that most top managers went through when taking over the leadership of a company, directors were assumed to be wise men (most were effectively men) who didn’t need any additional training at all. Even on the contrary, it seemed ‘humiliating’ to dare challenge the mere need for additional education with such impressive track record as executive. Every year, companies invest huge amounts of time and money on executive development and education. Yet very little is spent on formally developing the board. Instead, board directors are somehow expected to step over the threshold of the boardroom fully formed or to magically transform themselves. We disagree there is a choice in the matter. That was the past; development is now a must! (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2008). Promoting Effective Board Decision-Making, the Essence of Good Governance 249 The last couple of years, this trend seems to be changing, with national as well as international director education (slowly) becoming a discipline in its own right. But the changing trend still leaves much room for improvement before companies will be convinced of the value add of such additional education programmes. On the other hand, the trend towards ‘director certification’ appears to evolve at a more rapid pace, as proven by the many alumni of national directors’ institutes such as the IOD in the UK and GUBERNA in Belgium. A board composition that induces the right governance attitude and creates value add The context and personalities influence board functioning and board contribution. (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2008) A top priority in governance codes Structuring the board with the right people is indeed a crucial building block for board effectiveness. Worldwide, governance codes have paid considerable attention to the right board composition. However, the codes’ recommendations mainly focus on the essential input criteria, mostly ignoring the necessary behaviour and group dynamics. A first element of board composition codes focus upon is the ‘optimal’ number of directors. Although Egon Zehnder’s research states that size is the factor that is the least relevant for board effectiveness, the assumption gains support that the number of board members matters from a group dynamics point of view. There is no ‘holy’ number, rather it is more an optimal range below or above which collective decisionmaking becomes less feasible. The study of Heidrick & Struggles (2011) provides some insights on the size of European boards and point out that boards are becoming bigger to accommodate the requirements for diversity, to populate the increasing number of committees and to increase the competency set. On the other hand, there is the proposal to limit the board size. Such proposition is not only retained in most governance codes, but is equally supported by academic research. Carter and Lorsch (2004) state that smaller boards are more effective than larger ones, because larger boards pose more problems for optimal group dynamics, directors are less involved and committed and consequently less powerful. In such boards it is increasingly difficult to communicate and discuss together and there is less contact among directors outside the regular meetings. However, there has to be a minimum number of directors 250 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau in order to have a well-functioning collective decision-making process. There should be sufficient directors so that there is sufficient expertise on the board and ideally not too much overlap among board committees. Some companies find the solution in opting for a relatively small board that is supported by additional external specialists; without them being director they complement the board’s (committees) expertise. Another important input factor identified in the governance codes is that (unitary) boards need a majority of non-executive directors in order to guarantee the objectivity required in the monitoring process. A board has to oversee management and too much executives on the board might lead to insufficient ‘checks and balances’. In the same line of thinking it is also recommended that the functions of chairman of the board and CEO, or leader of the executive management, should be split. Probably most attention in recent governance recommendations has been paid to the minimum degree of independence, not only in the board as a whole, but especially in the main board committees. In board committees, such as the audit and remuneration committee there is a plea for a majority of independent directors, again in light of a thorough control and the prevention of conflicts of interest.8 As soon as board members face a conflict of interest, independent directors should step in to guarantee that only the corporate interest prevails. In that perspective, independence is indeed an important element of board effectiveness. However, the attention for independent decision-making is no guarantee whatsoever. It might give a false sense of effectiveness if a company perfectly ticks of the box of the minimum number of independent directors, selected on the base of a strict definition of what constitutes independence. Judging board independence is more than a minimum number of independent directors. Independence in character should prevail over independence in structure: most important is the intellectual independence, and the courage to speak up as well as the board’s tolerance for candour. We fully agree with Carter and Lorsch (2004) that independence is primarily a psychological condition. In fact, independent directors can expose a lack of independent attitude, whereas non-independent directors (e.g. (representatives of) shareholders) can adopt a more independent position, than the Codes assume. Independence must become a state of mind that permeates the boardroom. To this end, it is important to have at least a minimum number of (three) independent directors, achieving a strong sense of identity as a group, eventually meeting alone from time to time. Such group that regularly refers to the corporate interest as the only relevant reference point will affect the entire board step by step in behaving Promoting Effective Board Decision-Making, the Essence of Good Governance 251 independently. If any conflict of interest arises, there should be automatically a strict procedure respected, informing the board, limiting or even fully eliminating the involvement to the concerned director in the discussion and certainly in the decision-making. Another side-effect of overly emphasising the minimum number of independent directors is that this might lead to insufficient attention for ‘insiders’ with knowledge of the company and its business environment. A board composition element that recently gained lots of attention, especially in the media and in the political world,9 is the need for more diversity, especially gender diversity. As already highlighted before, diversity is an important determinant of effective group decision-making. In this respect, gender is one of the different demographic and business characteristics that constitute a condition for effective group dynamics. Not everybody agrees with the pressure put on the business world to integrate more female directors in their board. However, gender diversity has gained so much importance in public life, that whatever the corporation’s opinion might be, publicly listed companies and state-owned enterprises will increasingly have to live up to this societal pressure and pay more attention to the gender balance in their board of directors. Probably all other boards will be faced with a comparable pressure, albeit of a less mandatory nature. All of these ‘input’ requirements need to be guaranteed by installing a professional nomination process for the recruitment of directors. Corporations have been blamed, all over the world, for their adherence to a very amateur selection of new directors, fishing in the same ‘old boys’ network’ over and over again. Moreover, boards often were fixed on brand name or marquee directors, while it has become clear that the quality of their contributions, the knowledge directors bring and their passionate interest in the business is much more important. It is clear that for effective group dynamics one should search new directors beyond the famous ‘old boys’ network’. The diversity search does not come so easily and investments will be necessary to enlarge the relevant pool of good board candidates. However, we do agree with Carter and Lorsch (2004) that the so-called shortage of candidates is more likely reflecting nominating committees’ failure to look beyond the obvious than it is because of a genuine lack of talent. Is the shortage of board talent among women not the logical outcome of the view that the only good directors are CEOs and ex-CEOs (knowing that 99% of the CEOs of S&P 500 companies in 2002 were male according to Carter and Lorsch (2004)). Codes have tried to incentivise nomination committees to open the Pandora box and go for a more formal selection 252 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau process. According to Timmerman and Van Durme (2009), a professional selection process should include the following three steps. Firstly, it should start by developing a selection profile. Next, the nomination committee has to guarantee rigor in deciding on re-nomination and eventually opening up a vacancy for a new candidate. Finally, specific attention should be paid to the complementary role of the nomination committee, board and shareholders. Our research on governance practices in listed companies in Belgium has revealed some progress in the professionalism of the selection of independent directors. In particular, we witness more attention for a well-defined profile and an increasing role of the nomination committee. Nevertheless, the influence of the ‘own’ network for recruiting the candidates is still prevalent and may not be underestimated. The United States has been leading the movement for more regulatory intervention in the nomination of directors. The Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) formally adopted a new governance disclosure regulation (active as from the 28 February 2010), which among others, obliges listed companies to disclose the specific qualifications of their directors and of the candidates put forward for nomination on the board. Such disclosure will require boards to give careful thought to the skill sets directors bring along because they will have to disclose the attributes or skills that qualified a person to serve as a director. Moreover for each director all previous and actual board mandates at listed companies (and registered investment companies) during the past five years will have to be disclosed as well. Also the European Union follows that track. In its green papers on corporate governance in the financial sector and more generally in listed companies the route towards more mandatory rules for board nominations has been investigated. For the financial sector this already resulted in more stringent rules (CRDIV), which will have to be monitored by the financial sector authorities (see e.g. the consultation document of the EBA and the position paper of ecoDa). However, we need to think more strategically about board composition and recruitment Although most codes relate their recommendations on board composition to the need for effective board decision-making, none take these recommendations far enough. In practice, we frequently observe the temptation to get the most qualified or high-profile directors, focusing to a large extent on their specific expertise and past accomplishments. Such recruitment efforts, without due regard to the board as a group Promoting Effective Board Decision-Making, the Essence of Good Governance 253 decision-making body, may be missing a key consideration: lack of chemistry. Good decision-making depends upon effective interaction, with each director making his or her contribution that affects the whole (group dynamics). People with the right governance attitude and with the relevant business competencies are key for creating the right board chemistry that facilitates collegial decisions in the long-term interest of the company. It is therefore important that the nomination committee tries to consider if a board candidate has the personal and interpersonal qualities that will contribute to the boardroom process, culture and chemistry, taking into consideration the existing board members. This implies that, with each new vacancy, the behavioural qualities of incumbent directors must be assessed (and remedied as appropriate) as well. There is much room for improvement when it comes to defining the ideal director profile for a board vacancy and certainly for a chairman’s vacancy. The concept of strategic board recruitment is still fairly new (Ward, 1997). While board structure is important, the calibre and abilities of the directors is an even more critical determinant of a board’s effectiveness. Good people – who are suited to the job at hand – will perform well even if the structure is less than ideal, but the opposite is certainly not true. Even with a perfect structure, modest talent or expertise that is not suited to the needs of the company will limit a board’s effectiveness. The mix of characters on the board will clearly have a big influence on its effectiveness. Directors should be there because they are able to add something. As stated before, building a board of great character is both a matter of the individuals who compose the board and the group process norms the board holds. Although each individual director can make a vital contribution and can make a difference to the character of the board, ultimately it is the collective functioning of the board as a unit that provides effective corporate governance. As such, building a board is not a matter of building a model of the ‘ideal’ director and selecting eight or ten of these ideal individuals, but instead means finding a balance of skill sets, experience, leadership and connections across the board as a whole in order to form an ideal combination. Indeed 11 top football players do not make a winning football team. That’s why we need to think differently about the type of people who make good directors and about how they are encouraged to live up to their potential, once on the board and that underlines the plea to focus on the character, skills, leadership and experience of the individual, and the collective needs of the board (Sonnenfeld and Ward, 2009). 254 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau It is important to realise that the board is a social system that may be substantially influenced by the nomination of new director(s). There can be a period of ‘relative instability’, while relationships and board practices adapt to the new element(s) in the group, bringing in different knowledge, skills, abilities and behaviour. The board will evolve over time to a new equilibrium. These board dynamics should be reminded again, also because board composition and the board’s role mutually influence each other. The defined role influences the composition needed and the composition influences the practical execution of this role. The challenge for the board is to understand the roles required and then match the intellectual capital of the board to those roles (Nicholson and Kiel, 2004). Our own experience with board evaluation exercises confirms the importance of this critical fit. In particular, it is striking to observe that there is to some extent a correlation between the topics tackled by the directors and the expertise present in the board. HR issues as well as aspects of risk management, for example, are being less discussed in contrast to financial and legal dimensions of a proposal partly because these competencies are commonly under-represented. Such observations point to the need to clearly develop the board’s profile with respect to all relevant competencies. The aim should be to try filling the vacancies –as much as possible – with the missing competencies and experiences. Defining the board (vacancy) profile Before drafting any board vacancy profile, one needs to update the general board profile so that the vacancy fits with the relevant context factors of the company (see also Chapter 6). Whatever the recommendations of governance codes, defining a board profile is no universal given, nor a permanent one size fits all recipe. In order to install an effective board, one needs to align the board profile with the specific role the board has to play in that company, taking into account the future needs of the company. One must think strategically about the required skill mix and the value add demanded from that board (Hudson, 2009). Diversity needs should be defined in relation to the expertise and experience that fits the specific needs of the company, in light of its strategic ambition and challenges. Consequently there is no ‘one size fits all’ solution to define the value a board should bring to the company. No board is the same and even over time the functioning of a board may drastically change, with new shareholders stepping in, new management in the leadership role or new directors on board. Therefore, only a system approach that translates the context factors into the intended board profile can create a strategically relevant profile for a board vacancy. Promoting Effective Board Decision-Making, the Essence of Good Governance 255 When defining a profile for a board vacancy it is important that a new director will complement the existing board. To this end a skills matrix gap analysis should be developed, detecting in the set of necessary competencies, skills and experiences which ones are missing (Leblanc, 2009). Such gap analysis supposes that the existing board composition is critically assessed in light of the necessary board profile. The nomination committee, with the support of management, will have to identify the competencies, skills and experience needed in light of the board’s role, the corporate strategic objectives and other relevant context factors. A critical board assessment should help in identifying the current skills as well as the missing ones. An interesting example in this respect is the case of Belgacom. A few years ago, the board of directors has profoundly reflected on its composition and has set out the competences required in relation to the specific nature of the company and its defined strategy (see Tables 8.2 and 8.3). Next, the competences mentioned were summarised and set out in a grid (see Table 8.4). The Table 8.2 Competencies in function of the nature of the company Nature of the company Competence needed NV quoted on the stock exchange Corporate governance Telecom Understanding of telecom and ICT Autonomous public sector company Relation state – company Political world in Belgium Statutory personal Table 8.3 Competencies in function of the company’s strategy Strategy of Belgacom Competence needed Maintaining profitable market share Marketing in the consumer market Pricing strategy Customer service and call centres Achieving operational excellence HR – competence management HR – social relations IT-systems Telecom networks Investing in profitable growth New technology (VoIP, broadband, e-services) Media/TV External growth West European telcos (Netherlands, France, Germany) Emerging markets (Northern Africa – Middle East) Mergers and acquisitions 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 Available competences – ** – Consumer Pricing Ext. Markets Service Experience Customer retention *** – ICT VoIP Broadband e-services Social relations Statutory employees – New technology Media *** 9 *** 8 Strategy 7 Finance 6 *** 5 Corp Gov 4 ** 3 *** 2 Public sector company 1 Business author Desired competences Director Table 8.4 Competencies grid Promoting Effective Board Decision-Making, the Essence of Good Governance 257 individual directors’ profiles were evaluated by indicating the degree the competences were available or rather lacking. The outcome of this assessment enabled the board to detect possible overlaps and gaps. The aim of this exercise was to develop a more long-term perspective on director recruitment and to include the missing skills in the vacancies for the mandates that come to an end in the following years. In the meantime new appointments have been reoriented to complement the missing competences. In this respect, the grid does no longer reflect the current board composition. In general, the vacancy profile should allow to optimally complement the existing board members. On the one hand complementarity is linked to the need for diversity (visible and invisible factors) as a precondition for effective group decision-making. On the other hand complementarity is essential in light of the growing specialisation within the board committees. Notwithstanding the fact that a board is a collegial body, there is more and more specialisation taking place within boards and board committees (see also Chapter 7 on governance paradoxes). When defining the necessary board and individual director profiles, one should therefore carefully investigate the degree of diversity and specialisation wanted, in order to define the necessary complementarities between board members. Diversity is often defined in demographic and social terms (age, gender, nationality, etc.). How important such socio-demographic diversity might be, the most relevant diversity stems from the need to install a board with the right mixture of individual competences and experience, that is, the skills, abilities and resources resulting from the director’s leadership, past and current experience as well as his knowledge, expertise and functional capabilities acquired through learning, training and experiences. Elements that count in this respect are given in Figure 8.24. As already highlighted before, skills are a necessary but not a sufficient condition. Engagement and deployment of those skills is as important. We fully agree with Finkelstein and Mooney (2003) when they state that communication style of potential directors as well as personal attitude and integrity should be taken into consideration. Core competencies on personality are very fundamental for building the right board chemistry and for promoting effective group dynamics. The relevant personality core competencies contain individual characteristics as well as specific group-oriented and interpersonal skills. A concrete example is provided by Richard Leblanc (2009) and cited in Figure 8.25. 258 ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau Understanding the business, its environment and business model: someone with relevant experience to smell any smoke coming under the door and able to offer contestable advice; this requires some members (of the board) with experience relevant to the industry, specific skills in relation to customer or geographic segments. Intelligence to assess the strategic issues, business plans, etc. (experience with developing corporate strategy; executive experience). Leadership questions and monitoring management. Monitoring results (understanding the financial and non-financial results) and control (operational experience, view on internal control and risk management; legal matters). Experience in running a business such as CEOs or former CEOS. However be aware that (ex)CEOs can make lousy directors because they can’t adjust to an environment where theirs is not necessarily the most important opinion and where they must listen more than they talk. Some directors should have special empathy with the concerns of the wider population. Experienced directors (expertise in other relevant board of directors). Governance expertise. Figure 8.24 Elements of a board (vacancy) profile The question of re-nomination In principle directors are nominated for a limited number of years. The term of a board mandate may vary from 1 (exceptional), to 3 or 4 (the new norm) till 6 years or more. Most countries allow that a re-nomination can take place. In light of the more critical assessment of board composition, the question of re-nomination and – more generally – of keeping directors on board deserves special attention. In a much more critical environment, we need to raise the performance bar for board members. Boards should learn a lesson from team sports, where mediocre players are dropped and even those who are successful are sometimes moved on to rebalance the skill mix of the team. (Carter and Lorsch, 2004) We should therefore start to define performance standards for directors and organise performance reviews at the moment of re-nomination.10 To reach the goal of board effectiveness, one should dare to ask directors to resign or not to stand for re-election, if their contribution is under standard or does not fit any longer with the new board profile. Promoting Effective Board Decision-Making, the Essence of Good Governance 259 Individual oriented: ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● Vision Open minded Courage, forthrightness Inquisitive nature Change-oriented Integrity (ethical standards, truthful and honest) Independent attitude (valid for all directors; however special attention to independent directors, cfr. infra) => objectivity Authority Interest (in the company and its business) Commitment (to contribute), responsibility, time Judging Helicopter view while also analytic Deciding Sense of urgency Inspiring Challenging Context judging; Directors should realise that there are ‘horses for courses’. Indeed, different boards are effective in different ways. Making use of that versatility requires being grounded in the challenges of the organisation on whose board the director sits. The worst notion to hold is of a success somewhere else, which makes success over here impossible to achieve. Group oriented: ● ● ● ● ● ● Interpersonal relationships, teamwork abilities Trust and integrity are critical to chairmen and to boards. Trust is the essence of relationships at the level of top management and between management and the rest of the organisation, with shareholders and other stakeholders Coaching Likable, fitting in the group, absence of conflicts Understanding others and the dynamics of groups Decision-making skills and style. Figure 8.25 Individual and group-oriented selection criteria Through codes and legislation, tenure limits are identified as an important aspect of governance. The assumption is that if directors stay too long, independent directors can get too cosy with senior management. Tenure limits are also used as an indirect way of getting directors – who are not contributing – off boards. Whereas a retirement age is important, there are several caveats about tenure limits. The point is that director contribution improves with time. So a high-performing board is not helped 260 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau by limitations to director tenure. A high-performing board requires anything between a 7- and 12-year period of tenure together (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2008). Directors can be forced to retire while they are still making a major contribution. Moreover, trust and confidence are built up over extended periods of time. It takes new independent directors a long time to learn about their company. Installing a tenure limit may also be an excuse for not conducting meaningful performance evaluations. There is a case for not having term limits, but the price is a serious performance appraisal. In any case, boards need to be refreshed on a regular basis: growing old together will become less and less effective. Some conclusions The principal work of boards revolves around complex decisionmaking. A board can only be effective if it is organised as a collective decision-making body, composed of a group of peers, acting as a college. Although this might sound straightforward, numerous companies, large (subsidiary companies) and small ones (unlisted companies) alike do not organise active board meetings. Consequently, they are losing the value added of a corporate body, dedicated to objective decisionmaking in the interest of the company. But also a more active board, merely operating as an advisory body, will not reap the benefits of group decision-making. In such cases, there is no need to take diverging opinions into consideration; the leader’s opinion will (probably) prevail. Again, the company dares to lose the most valuable thing of a group, that is, collective wisdom. It is only with active board members that the essence of collective decision-making will be realised. Increasingly, the governance codes emphasise the need for effective board decisionmaking. However, they do not develop a clear guidance on how to reach that goal. Based on intensive research and practical board experience, this chapter develops a first attempt for such a reference framework. The discussion on how to reach effective board decision-making is structured around six key components: board dynamics, professional behaviour, board organisation, board information and board composition and last but not least board leadership. Board dynamics The legal assumption is that the board of directors is a collegial decisionmaking body that strives to reach consensus. This assumption is built on the belief that in order to decide on the most important corporate affairs, one needs a well-balanced reflection with sufficient ‘checks and Promoting Effective Board Decision-Making, the Essence of Good Governance 261 balances’. This is in sharp contrast with the centralised power delegated to a CEO but apparently offers quite some benefits in comparison to individual decision-making. Yet, at the same time it is a very challenging element that has not received the attention it deserves. In fact, decisionmaking through a ‘college’ is much more complex and challenging than individual decision-making. Board decision-making not only suffers from ‘bounded rationality’ (and the more volatile the business environment, the more difficult it becomes to judge beforehand the consequences and risks attached to major corporate decisions) but at the same time board dynamics pose numerous challenges. Context and group characteristics as well as group behaviour mutually interfere and dynamically shape the board meeting and hence effective decision-making. Therefore, we need to unravel the steps in the board decision-making process and as such shed a light on the inner workings of the board. Influence of board members on each other is inescapable and this is all the more clear in smaller groups of peers. Board effectiveness necessitates that we overcome group think and herding, with the danger of misjudgement of risk, the prevalence of loyalty and unanimity over valuable counter-opinions and critique, social pressure to conform, emphasising group consensus over dissent, not opening one’s mind but closing them. The danger of group think might increase with autocratic leaders or when the group gets more closed and more isolated. To overcome the danger of group think and herding, it is opportune to look for remedies that bring diversity of opinion and independent position taking. The underlying rationale (also in the many governance codes) is that (cognitive) diversity and independent opinion are the single best guarantee to reap the benefits of group decision-making while at the same time overcoming the danger of herding and group think. Moreover, it is important to effectively promote candid board dialogue and constructive dissent as a route towards effective board decisionmaking while at the same time preventing unconstructive dissent and dysfunctional or affective conflicts. Open dialogue supposes that there is sufficient time for discussion before decisions are taken and that directors are proactive, inquisitive and highly responsible people in search of the best solution for the company. Well-positioned logic and constructive criticism strengthen relationships and commitment rather than damage them. The challenge is to question but not hurting nor inquisitor, to explore but not putting down anyone and to constructively interrogate the argument. Such approach ensures successful adoption of the proposal, reduces risk and safeguards the reputation of the organisation and also increases the commitment of the board and management to a project. 262 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau However good the debate might be, finally a decision must be made. Directors have a shared destiny: as they are part of a collegial body, they must align and live the collective results. Consensus building might be all the more difficult the more diverse and independent the board is and the more constructive dissent is searched for. The pivotal role played by the chairman is key in this respect (cf. infra). Finally, expost assessment of individual director behaviour and group dynamics is essential to make sure that the theoretical benefits of collegial decisionmaking are effectively realised in practice. Professional behaviour A critical condition for board dynamics being effective is that the directors behave in a professional way. Although the codes pointed to numerous aspects of board composition, insufficient attention has been paid to the numerous aspects of professional behaviour of director, a crucial element that is also shied away from the limelight of public governance monitoring. However, we can observe an increasing interest especially from governance experts and directors themselves for developing guidance for the professional director.11 Coupled with the (scarce) relevant governance literature it is possible to detect a number of professional director behaviour aspects that should be integrated in any board assessment: time availability and commitment, active and focused involvement based on appropriate insight and knowledge, constructive dissent with respect for each opinion, honest and ethical behaviour, discretion, loyalty and focus on independent decisionmaking in the sole interest of the company. In modern boards, directors have to become good decision-makers in their own right. However, such factors are of a qualitative nature and consequently measuring individual director behaviour is a complex exercise. It is therefore important that each board explicitly agrees upon the norms (shared beliefs) and (informal) rules (or the board’s culture) that should guide the individual director in performing a professional board mandate. In practice evaluating individual director behaviour and performance is probably the most controversial topic today. More efforts are necessary to further promote a professional assessment of directors. But there is more, these behavioural norms should trickle down into the recruitment process, where much more information must gathered than just a mere CV. More and more is the attitude of the director what ultimately determines the governance potential a person holds. Given that the board should act as a college of complementary peers, the real challenge is to find an optimal mix of behavioural characteristics of Promoting Effective Board Decision-Making, the Essence of Good Governance 263 directors. Not in the recruitment of directors, or in the individual board assessment is this shift towards the ‘soft skills’ of directors prevailing. Organising effective board meetings To get more value out of the board meetings, every board should critically assess its board organisation. It might be wise to screen the number and format of the board and committee meetings. Effective agenda planning supposes an achievable agenda with sufficient time devoted to the real important issues. Effective use of time means that there is a good balance between presentations and discussions while leaving sufficient time for clear decision-making. The growing expectations towards boards of directors imply that the engagement of directors goes beyond the regular board and committee meetings. Those formal meetings represent the structured backbone of a director mandate, while informal discussions, information sessions and business visits complement the embedment of a non-executive director in the evolution of the company. Besides a professional and independent behaviour, the new challenge is to have professional directors who really know the business and the challenges it faces. Director information For a board to operate effectively, information is very essential. Besides the material that supports the preparation of the board agenda, the minutes of the board meetings are crucial feedback on board discussions and decision-making, while also serving as reference for the follow-up of the execution of the board decisions. On top of this periodic pillar of board material, non-executive directors increasingly receive additional interim information. In important and sometimes controversial dossiers, it might be opportune that non-executive directors get additional information from other sources than the executives or have access to external support and information. A gap may exist between what non-executive directors want to receive and what management is able and willing to deliver (both in quantity and in quality). Board information should be timely, consistent and relevant. In some companies (e.g. smaller ones) directors may suffer from insufficient information, while in others (e.g. the larger ones) information overload may pose problems. Even if directors are overwhelmed with the volume of information, they may be underwhelmed by the content. Board material might focus too much on past financial performance and on financial forecasts and too little on competitive performance, customer reactions and SWOT. We need to think 264 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau more strategically about board information. It is essential that directors understand the business model, the functioning of the organisation as well as its strategic challenges, risks and opportunities. Companies should make efforts to make board information more memorable and accessible. Directors as part-time outsiders need summaries and frameworks to help them capture and hold on to the crucial elements in the flood of information that comes their way. Companies should not be reluctant to use technology, giving their non-executive directors access to timely and easily accessible information. Last but not least, empowered boards need sufficient attention for director induction and education, tailored to the needs of the specific board and the individual directors. On the occasion of a board assessment, directors along with management can carefully define the information format and the education the board needs. Board composition Worldwide, governance codes have paid considerable attention to the right board composition. However, the codes’ recommendations mainly focus on specific composition elements, mostly ignoring the necessary aspects in relation to director behaviour and group dynamics. Points of attention include the optimal number of directors, a majority of non-executive directors (in case of unitary boards), a minimum contingent of independent directors, specific diversity elements (with great attention for gender diversity) and a professional nomination process. As already pointed out we need to think more strategically about the board composition and the recruitment of non-executive directors. Effective board dynamics necessitate that the board acts as a team, with complementary competencies but also with sufficient chemistry and behavioural fit. Moreover the board’s role and board composition mutually influence each other. Developing the profile for a board vacancy needs to be done in a professional way, with reference to the required skill mix and the value add demanded (a new board member should complement the existing board). Skills are a necessary but not a sufficient condition. Engagement and deployment of those skills is as important. In case of re-nomination a performance review is essential as well as a reflection on tenure limits. Notes 1. From a legal perspective, being a peer means that everybody has the same set of rights and obligations as a board member, also during board meetings (Meurisse, 2011). Promoting Effective Board Decision-Making, the Essence of Good Governance 265 2. This kind of checklist is foreseen by the EU recommendations and even mandated into law in certain European countries, like in Belgium and Spain. 3. In society numerous types of coordination mechanisms exist, such as topdown authority and coercion (e.g. assembly line), more bottom-up liberal or independent methods (e.g. queues in a supermarket, flock of birds) or cultural norms and conventions (such as laws, e.g. driving on the right side of the road). 4. This kind of decision-making rules are commonly found in a general assembly of shareholders. 5. For a detailed questionnaire on board behaviour, see Kakabadse and Kakabadse (2008), pp. 107–108. 6. Prof. Dr. Martin Hilb leads the Centre for Corporate Governance at the University of St. Gallen. The Diversity Optima Disk combines three dimensions of board diversity related to the individual directors: know-how, roles and comparable competencies. For more information, we would like to refer to the website: http://www.ifpm.unisg.ch 7. Delaware courts condemned a company for consistently sending out draft minutes too late – months after the meeting. 8. The danger of conflicts of interest is most prevalent in setting executive remuneration, transactions between the company and a major shareholder, transactions with a company directed by one of the board members, etc. 9. In Europe, this topic is high on the agenda of the Commissioner for Justice and Home Affairs, Viviane Reding. Her proposal on gender diversity was leaked to the press in September 2012. In this proposal, she opted for a directive introducing a binding objective of at least 40% of the non-executive board members being female (of the other gender) by 2020. The directive excludes SMEs. State-owned enterprises should achieve the 40% objective already by 1 January 2018. Member states have a broad discretion which sanctions to choose. However, more than half of the EU member states heavily protested against this proposal. 10. If no external assessment is done a minimum effort should be to have a selfassessment, checked by the chair and the other directors. 11. See for example the toolkit developed by GUBERNA. References Acharya, V., Kehoe, C. and Reyner, M. ‘Private equity vs PLC boards in the U.K.: a comparison of practices and effectiveness’, Finance Working Paper No. 233/2009 (1 August 2008). Campbell, A. and Stuart, S. ‘Using the crisis to create better boards’, McKinsey Quarterly (October 2009). Carter, C.B. and Lorsch, J.W. Back to the Drawing Board. Designing Corporate Boards for a Complex World (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 2004). Colvin, J. ‘Dilemma for directors as complexity increases’, The Australian (13 July 2011). Conger, J.A. Boardroom Realities. Building Leaders Across Your Board (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 2009). 266 Lutgart Van den Berghe and Abigail Levrau Crainer, S. and Dearlove, D. ‘Boardroom blitz: What happened to real debate among corporate directors?’, The Conference Board Review, November/December 2007. Deloitte, In the dark. What boards and executives don’t know about the health of their businesses – A survey by Deloitte in Cooperation with the Economist Intelligence Unit (Deloitte, 2004). Dunne, P. Running Board Meetings: How to Get the Most from Them (London and Philadelphia: Kogan Page, 1997). Elson, C.M., Hubbard, G. and Zarb, F., Bridging board gaps. Report of the Study Group on Corporate Boards. Columbia Business School, Columbia University and the Weiner Center for Corporate Governance, University of Delaware, 2011. Finkelstein, S. and Mooney, A.C. ‘Not the usual suspects: how to use board process to make boards better’, Academy of Management Executive, XVII (2003) 101–111. Goffee, R. and Jones, G. Why Should Anyone Be Led by YOU? What It Takes to Be an Authentic Leader (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 2006). Heidrick & Struggles, European Corporate Governance Report 2011. Challenging Board Performance (2011). Janis, I. Groupthink: Psychological Studies of Policy Decisions and Fiascoes (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1983). Kakabadse, A. and Kakabadse, N. Leading the Board. The Six Disciplines of WorldClass Chairmen (New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2008). Kellaway, L. ‘Everyone benefits from a beast in the boardroom’, Financial Times (9 October 2011). Kerstetter, T.K. Board Structure: One Size Does Not Fit All (The Board Blog, 24 November 2009). Leblanc, R. Getting the right directors on your board. In: Conger, J.A. Boardroom Realities. Building Leaders Across Your Board (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 2009), pp. 145–196. Leblanc, R. and Gillies, J. Inside the Board Room. How Boards Really Work and the Coming Revolution in Corporate Governance (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 2005). Lipton, M. ‘Some thoughts for boards of directors in 2008’, AEI Legal Center – Briefly, XI (2008). Meurisse, P. A Board of Directors in Action During a Board Meeting: Recovering and Describing the Phenomenon (Northamptonshire: Veritas Business Services Limited, 2011). Monks, R.A.G. and Minow, N. Corporate Governance, 2nd edition (Oxford: Blackwell, 2001). Nadler, D.A., Behan, B.A. and Nadler, M.B. Building Better Boards. A Blueprint for Effective Governance (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 2006). Nicholson, G.C. and Kiel, G.C. ‘A framework for diagnosing board effectiveness’, Corporate Governance – An International Review, XII (2004) 442–460. Nordberg, D. Corporate Governance – Principles and Issues (London: SAGE Publications, 2011). Paredes, T. ‘Too Much Pay, Too Much Deference: Is CEO Overconfidence the Product of Corporate Governance?’, Washington University School of Law, Working Paper No. 04-08-02. (5 September 2004). Promoting Effective Board Decision-Making, the Essence of Good Governance 267 Peterson, R. In: Crainer, S. and Dearlove, D. ‘Boardroom blitz: What happened to real debate among corporate directors?’, The Conference Board Review, November/December 2007. Reheul, A-M. and Jorissen, A. ‘Do boards with different compositions face different organizational information contexts?’, Review of Business and Economics, LV (2010) 55–75. Roberts J.T., McNulty, and Stiles P. ‘Beyond agency conceptions of the work of the non-executive directors: creating accountability in the boardroom’, British Journal of Management, XVI (2005), Special Issue S5–S6. Simon, H.A. (1983) Reasons in Human Affairs. Stanford, CA: Standford University Press. Sonnenfeld, J.A. and Ward, A. Conventional wisdom, conventional mythology, and the true character of board governance. In: Conger, J.A. Boardroom Realities. Building Leaders Across Your Board (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 2009), pp. 445–468. Surowiecki, J. The Wisdom of Crowds (New York: Random House, 2004). Thomsen, S. ‘A minimum theory of boards’, International Journal of Corporate Governance, I (2008) 73–96. Timmerman, M. and Van Durme, Y. Directors: Working on the Relevant Mix. Hudson Presentation March 2009. Useem, M. and Neng, L. Globalizing the company board: lessons from China’s Lenovo. In: Conger, J.A. Boardroom Realities. Building Leaders Across Your Board (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 2009). Van den Broeck, H., Devos, G. and Bouckenooghe, D. ‘Besluitvorming binnen Boards: een Preliminaire Literatuurstudie’, Studierapport Vlerick Leuven Gent Management School, (2006). Visser, B. and Swank, O. ‘How to organise the decision-making process’, Tinbergen Magazine, XIV (Fall 2006) 7–10. Walker, D. A Review of Corporate Governance in UK Banks and Other Financial Industry Entities (London: The Walker review secretariat, 2009). Walton, E. How your board can leverage team practices for better performance. In: Conger, J.A. Boardroom Realities. Building Leaders Across Your Board (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 2009). Ward, R. 21st Century Corporate Board (New York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 1997). Westphal, J. and Bednar, M. ‘Pluralistic ignorance in corporate boards and firms’ strategic persistence in response to low firm performance’, Administrative Science Quarterly, L (2005) 262–298. 9 The Appropriate Board Chair: A Reality Check Abigail Levrau and Lutgart Van den Berghe Already two decades ago, Parker (1990: 42) concluded in his influential work on the chairmen of UK companies that the role of the board chair ‘has become increasingly demanding as the corporate environment has become increasingly complex and internationally competitive’. This statement sets the tone for what occurred in the years that followed. Many corporate scandals and especially the global financial crisis have triggered society at large to be more attentive and critical towards the performance of boards. In addition, corporate governance codes are strengthened in order to empower the board of directors in carrying out their duties and to protect long-term shareholder wealth. The public scrutiny as well as the corporate governance reforms put exponentially more pressure on boards and their chairmen. The board chair versus the CEO: the principles As highlighted in the previous chapters, it is striking to observe that most of the requirements for board leadership stress structural governance elements, or what Finkelstein and Mooney (2003) once called the ‘usual suspects’ of board effectiveness. Among these ‘usual suspects’ is the demand to split the CEO and board chair roles in order to curb power at the top of the organisation and to ensure an objective independent judgement of the board on corporate affairs. This simple requirement, however, underestimates the sensitivity of introducing this kind of check and balance in practice. In the vast majority of continental European countries as well as in the UK there appears to be a trend toward non-executive chairs as the standard board leadership model for large listed companies (Heidrick & Struggles, 2011). In contrast, in some countries, such as the United States and France, there is still much 268 The Appropriate Board Chair: A Reality Check 269 In a number of countries with single tier board systems, the objectivity of the board and its independence from management may be strengthened by the separation of the role of chief executive and chairman, or, if these roles are combined, by designating a lead non-executive director to convene or chair sessions of the outside directors. Separation of the two posts may be regarded as good practice, as it can help to achieve an appropriate balance of power, increase accountability and improve the board’s capacity for decision-making independent of management. The designation of a lead director is also regarded as a good practice alternative in some jurisdictions. Such mechanisms can also help to ensure high quality governance of the enterprise and the effective functioning of the board. Figure 9.1 Extract from the OECD guidelines on board leadership controversy on this matter and most companies remain attached to unitary power (Dalton, 2012; AMF, 2010). The OECD Guidelines of Corporate Governance (2004) have recognised this controversy and have introduced the ‘lead director’ as a good practice in cases of joint leadership structures (see Figure 9.1). The dichotomy in views also reflects the underlying theories in governance research. Proponents of organisation theory and/or stewardship theory argue that if the CEO also serves as the chairman, this duality provides unified strong leadership, builds trust and stimulates the motivation to perform (see e.g. Muth and Donaldson, 1998; Finkelstein and D’Avanti, 1994). Agency theory, on the contrary, provides the rationale for separation of roles. Splitting the roles of CEO and chairman dilutes the concentration of power of the CEO, avoids CEO entrenchment and reduces the potential for management to dominate the board (Jensen and Meckling, 1976). The public attention for board leadership structures has triggered academics to study this topic more in-depth. However, empirical research has not yielded strong results to support the push towards CEO duality, neither with respect to improving board effectiveness nor firm performance (Daily and Dalton, 1997; Daily et al., 2003, Westphal, 2002). This feeds the criticism and not surprisingly the question arises if the debate on CEO duality has the right focus or to quote Daily and Dalton (1997), ‘much ado about nothing?’ However, this dichotomy is a valid perspective for pointing to the unique leadership challenges a chairperson of a board is faced with due to the specific characteristics of boards. In essence, the board of directors can be considered as a multi-member governing body, standing at 270 Abigail Levrau and Lutgart Van den Berghe the apex of the organisation (Bainbridge, 2002). The legal assumption, underpinning the installation and operation of a board of directors is that at the helm of the company, one needs a collegial body, striving to reach decisions in a consensus style. Put differently, in order to decide on the most important corporate affairs, only a group of people can deliver a well-balanced reflection while also installing a ‘checks and balance’ culture within the organisation. This constitution reflects the belief and trust in collective wisdom, once expressed by a classical author as ‘Nemo solis satus sapit’ (no person can be wise enough on his own) (Cadbury, 2002). This is in sharp contrast with the centralised power delegated to a CEO, and has implications for the chairperson. Being a leader of a board is much more complex and challenging than individual leadership of a company. In fact, while the board of directors is the highest decision-making body in the organisation, the board chairperson is not at the top of any decision hierarchy as is the CEO (Gabrielsson et al., 2007). The differences between board chairperson and CEO leadership is summarised in Table 9.1. Table 9.1 Comparison of board chairperson and CEO leadership Board chairperson CEO Accountable to shareholders and a broader set of stakeholders together with the other board members Accountable to the board of directors The highest level of decision-making in the firm together with the other board members Responsible for implementing decisions made by the board Leads a team of peers (formally and socially) Placed at the top of a hierarchy (formally and socially) Leads board meetings that generally take place with infrequent intervals and time constraints Leads subordinates on a continuous basis generally with frequent contact with subordinates Does not have instruction authority over the other board members Has instruction authority over subordinates Generally a part-time leader of the board Generally a full-time leader Generally non-executive, facing limited and incomplete information and highly dependent on management Has insight information on the daily operations of the organisation and has access to all layers in the organisation Source: Gabrielsson et. al. (2007) and Conger (2009). The Appropriate Board Chair: A Reality Check 271 Splitting the roles in practice Similar to the Anglo-American countries, Belgium is characterised by a unitary board model where executives and non-executives are sitting together in one governing body. Following the international pressure against CEO duality, the separation of roles of CEO and chairman is also recommended by the Belgian Corporate Governance Code. The Code reflects the assumption that the primary role of the chairman is to run the board and that of the CEO is to manage the company, encompassing fundamentally different tasks and activities. Our research with Belgian listed companies1 reveals that only six of those companies still pursue role duality (7%). All other companies opted for a split of responsibilities. Further analysis indicates that 40% of the board chairs are defined as independent chairmen, while 46% can be considered as non-executive chairmen (see Table 9.2). The distinction in nomenclature in Table 9.1 is based on compliance or non-compliance with the independence criteria set forward by Belgian Company Law. Table 9.3 shows a more detailed overview. Table 9.2 Board structure in Belgian listed companies Executive chair BEL 20 (N = 18) Non-executive chair Independent chair 5% 55% 40% BEL Mid (N = 31) 16% 52% 32% BEL Small (N = 34) 18% 35% 47% Total (N = 83) 14% 46% 40% Table 9.3 Chairman nomenclature Board chairperson Definition Executive chairman Chairman and CEO roles are held jointly (CEO duality) (or chairman is part of management) Non-executive chairman Chairman and CEO roles are separated Chairman has close ties with shareholder or Chairman is former CEO Independent chairman Chairman and CEO roles are separated Chairman complies with independence criteria of art. 524 of Company Law = criteria of Belgian Corporate Governance Code for listed companies 272 Abigail Levrau and Lutgart Van den Berghe Although most Belgian listed companies comply with the Corporate Governance Code, the division of roles at the head of the organisation puts an additional challenge for the non-executive and independent chairmen. The apparent simplicity that sharing the burden of responsibility (between the chairperson and the CEO) offers appears to be somewhat illusory and sometimes difficult to implement in practice. One of the most often cited comments that popped up during the interviews with respect to board chair leadership relates to the importance of a well-functioning chairman–CEO in tandem. It was noted that the relationship is successful in cases where the CEO and chairman have complementary profiles and show mutual respect for their respective roles. Nonetheless, the working relationship appears to be a delicate exercise, depending on different factors such as the personality and background of the individuals involved. Ambiguity in the division of responsibilities can easily lead to tensions that radiate negative vibrations to the board–management relationships. Notwithstanding the awareness of the importance and the dangers of the chairman/CEO relationship, only a few companies have formally described the role and responsibilities of the chairperson and the CEO in their board’s terms of reference. These findings are fully in line with previous qualitative exploratory studies on the relationship between the chairman and the CEO. In particular, the often cited research by John Roberts (Roberts and Stiles, 1999; Roberts, 2002) also pointed to the need for a co-operative relationship between the chairperson and the CEO. He found that this is the result of a process of dialogue and negotiation of power, a clear recognition of the differences in roles, and avoidance of competition. Besides, he concluded that the chairman–CEO relationship also has a decisive influence on the quality of the wider set of relationships between executives and non-executives. A similar conclusion was made in a more recent study by Kakabadse et al. They found that clarification and negotiation between the chairman and the CEO is required with respect to different elements of the two roles in order to avoid tension (Chapter 11). In addition it was stated that the chairman–CEO relationship has a major effect on boardroom dynamics. But the board chair faces much more challenges There is a growing awareness among academics as well as among practitioners that the inner workings of a board (Pettigrew, 1992; Hermalin and Weisbach, 2000), the board’s ability to work together as a team as The Appropriate Board Chair: A Reality Check 273 well as the leadership role and skills of the chairman are very critical dimensions of effective board performance (Cadbury, 2002; Leblanc, 2005; Levrau and Van den Berghe, 2009). Moreover, practice shows that the influence of the chairperson, irrespective of whether the position is hold jointly or separately, may extend beyond the boardroom. Apart from chairing the board meeting, the chairperson is expected to fulfil various roles towards internal and external stakeholders. Referring to this augmented role, it is argued that an effective chairperson has the potential to contribute to the long-term success of an organisation (O’ Higgins, 2009). There appears to be a growing awareness of the pivotal role of the chairman for effective board governance and the sustainability of companies. Although the role of the chair is not defined by law, most corporate governance codes attach great importance to this matter and spell out the responsibilities of the chairperson. They offer a good point of reference in delineating the role of the chairperson. In particular, they include distinct activities for the chairman inside and outside the boardroom as summarised in Figure 9.2. Nonetheless, as stated by Cadbury (2002) ‘the primary task of chairmen is to chair their boards. This is what they have been appointed to do’. It is the job of the chairman to get the best out of his directors and to ensure that the board provides the leadership to the company. In this INSIDE THE BOARDROOM OUTSIDE THE BOARDROOM Oversee the avtivity of the board Chair and prepare board meetings Chair shareholder meetings Oversee the board strategy The role of the chairperson Oversee compliance with legal and CG requirements Board development and evaluation performance Liaise with CEO and management Liaise with shareholders and stakeholders Figure 9.2 The role of the chairman Source: Adapted from O’Higgins (2009). 274 Abigail Levrau and Lutgart Van den Berghe context, a chairperson is commonly compared with a conductor of an orchestra, filled with world-class musicians. The challenge is to deploy the talents of the musicians, let them play together in harmony, from the same song sheet in order to create beautiful music. The major difference is that the ‘score’ for a board chair is a lot more dynamic and complex (Beatty, 2012). Put differently, in order to make ‘great music’, the chairperson must be aware of and deal with the particularities surrounding board leadership. The chairperson has no statutory position. All directors have legally equal responsibilities and as such the chairperson is no more equal than any other board member. His authority is simply derived from that of its board. The chairperson of a board of directors is in fact the ‘primus inter pares’ (the first among equals). He is chosen among and by the directors to lead the board. Lorsch (2009) defines boardroom leadership as ‘the emergence of directors who are willing and capable to influence their fellow directors to take needed actions’. In this respect, a board leader must have the standing among its fellows as well as the will and ability to shape decision-making. Even without the lack of former legal power, McNulty et al. (2011) argue that chairmen can tapp into four sources of power when fulfilling their leadership role: (i) Structural power is the power inherent in the formal organisational structure and hierarchy. (ii) Ownership power is the power deriving from either owning a significant shareholding in the firm, or power gained from forging longterm relationships with significant owners or founders. (iii) Expert power is the power that emanates from demonstrating an ability to handle the firm’s key tasks and contribute to organisational performance. (iv) Prestige power is the power related to personal prestige or status. Possessing these power sources can be an indicator for the potential power that a chairperson brings to its responsibilities. Boards of directors are there to take governance decisions. Decisions are made by people, and in the case of a board, by people acting together as a college. The chairperson has to lead the board in this task of complex decision-making which is based on collective reflection and group decisions. In addition, board decision-making depends upon effective interaction and dynamics among its members. It is the job of the chairman to assure that board members work together and leverage the practices of a good team. According to Pettigrew and McNulty (1998), the The Appropriate Board Chair: A Reality Check 275 will and skill of individual board members, and the interpersonal and group processes through which their energies are combined, determine to a larger extent the effectiveness of a board rather than its composition and structure. At the same time, literature points out that boards, like any other group, are vulnerable to negative group dynamics which may hamper their working (Bainbridge, 2002; Surowiecki, 2004). Moreover, a chairperson faces the need to resolve apparent paradoxes inherent in board decision-making. From literature, we learn that collective decision-making is successful if some remedies are in place to cope with the danger of negative group dynamics. In particular, diversity of opinions is perceived to be the best guarantee to reap the benefits from face-to-face board discussions, questioning evidence, revealing uncertainties etc. (Schweiger et al., 1986, Surowiecki, 2004). However, capturing the value of diversity is quite a complex process. In fact, it is the role of the chairman to stimulate open candid discussion, to support directors to speak up and express their opinions but at the same time he should be able to manage conflicting or dissenting views. The more diverse opinions are uttered, the more pressure is put on maintaining coherence among the group and on the possibility to reach a consensus in the decisions. However good the debate, finally a decision has to be made. The difficulty of facilitating a good cooperation between a group of ‘high caliber’ individuals, leveraging expertise, preserving high standards of openness while fostering effective ‘collegial’ decisionmaking underlines the importance of the leadership skills of the chairperson in the conduct of board meetings. In this respect, it is noted that the chairperson influences the performance of the board in the way he manages the group’s tasks, structures discussions, handles internal conflicts and displays more subtle leadership behaviours (Hackman and Morris, 1975; Cadbury, 2002; Leblanc, 2005, Levrau, 2007). Undoubtfully, the interest in the role of the board chairperson and his impact on decision-making is increasing. Still, our knowledge on the work of today’s chairman is limited and largerly (mis)understood, despite the bulk of empirical research on board leadership structure (see Daily and Dalton, 1997 for an overview). Moreover, mainstream board research focuses on the antecedents and outcome of the decisions without taking into account the quality of the decision-making process. Only the last decade, some scholars were able to overcome the access difficulties that is the main source of constraints in studying ‘managerial elites’ (Pettigrew and McNulty, 1998). Several of these valuable studies focus on board chairmanship and enhance our insights on (i) the disciplines that a world-class chairman has to master (Kakabadse 276 Abigail Levrau and Lutgart Van den Berghe and Kakabadse, 2008); (ii) the functional director’s typology to serve as a chair (Leblanc and Gillies, 2005); (iii) the general characteristics of effective chairs and their perceived impact (Harrison and Murray, 2012); (iv) a typology of chair power and influence (McNulty et al., 2011), as well as on (vi) different models of chairman–board relationships (Roberts, 2002) and (vii) the roles of the chairperson vis-à-vis the CEO (Roberts and Stiles, 1999; Stewart, 1991). The decision-making style of the chairman: in theory An important duty is attributed to the chairman with respect to effective board decision-making. Sir David Walker has again emphasised this responsibility when drafting the final recommendations after reviewing the corporate governance in UK banks and other financial industry entities (see Figure 9.3). The Belgian Corporate Governance Code for listed companies, for example, includes the basic principles, as set forward by Sir David Walker. In addition, it highlights the need for a constructive board climate, stimulated by the chairman: The chairman should take the necessary measures to develop a climate of trust within the board, contributing to open discussion, constructive dissent and support for the board’s decisions. (Belgian Corporate Governance Code, 2009) Clearly, the chairman has to lead the discussion and assure that the board engages in collegial decision-making, focusing on the long-term interest of the company. The chairman, as the leader of the board, has The chairman is responsible for leadership of the board, ensuring its effectiveness in all aspects of its role and setting its agenda so that fully adequate time is available for substantive discussion on strategic issues. The chairman should facilitate, encourage and expect the informed and critical contribution of the directors in particular in discussion and decision-taking on matters of risk and strategy and should promote effective communication between executive and non-executive directors. The chairman is responsible for ensuring that the directors receive all information that is relevant to discharge of their obligations in accurate, timely and clear form (recommendation 9) Figure 9.3 Extract from the Walker report regarding board leadership The Appropriate Board Chair: A Reality Check 277 to draw to the surface what board members really feel about the operations of the board, the collaboration with management, the way issues are dealt with, etc. Hereby, he has to take into account the unique challenges of the board on the one hand and balance the interest of shareholders and stakeholders on the other. As elaborated in the previous paragraphs, the main paradox in group decision-making is that groups, such as boards of directors, generally have the potential to produce more adequate decisions than individuals but at the same struggle with engagement of their members in reaching effective decisions. This gave the impetus to Jay Hall and his colleagues to develop a conceptual framework to study decision-making behaviour in order to facilitate theory building on decision-making. Their Decision-making Grid reflects the relationship between two basic dimensions that are considered to be critical in group decision-making: (i) the concern for decision adequacy experienced by the individual decision-maker and (ii) the concern for commitment of others to the decision which individuals experience when working on a joint decision-making task (Hall et al., 1964). Each dimension forms the axis of the grid and has been scaled from 1 to 9 in order to reflect the degree of a particular concern which individuals possess. In particular, the value 1 denotes minimal ‘concern for’ while the value 9 denotes maximal ‘concern for’. Based on the relationship between the two dimensions, five decision-making styles are derived: Self-sufficient decision-making: this decision-making style is characterised by a maximum concern for decision adequacy and minimal concern for commitment (9/1 position on the grid). The assumption is that a group does not have the capacity for good decision-making. The 9/1 decision-maker does not get involved with others and is most confident in his personal assessment of the problem concerned. He prefers to push the others in the direction of his own solution, which seems ‘best’ to him. This decision-making style can also be labelled as ‘authoritarian’ leadership. The success rate of this kind of leadership depends on the amount of power the person possesses over the group. Good neighbour decision-making: This decision-making style is characterised by a minimal concern for decision adequacy and a maximum concern for commitment (1/9 position on the grid). The assumption of mutuality and trust, fair play and peaceful co-existence forms the rationale for this style. The 1/9 decision-maker attaches great importance to maintaining harmony and understanding among the group members. He has a kind of aversion to disagreement and tries to avoid conflict. He shifts his personal opinion to correspond with the rest of 278 Abigail Levrau and Lutgart Van den Berghe the group, or he does not tackle touchy areas in favour of the well-being of the group. Default decision-making: This decision-making style is characterised by a minimal concern for decision adequacy and minimal concern for commitment (1/1 position on the grid). This style reflects a passive, non-participating role of the decision-maker. This behaviour occurs in situations where the decision-maker shows no interest in the topic under discussion. In other cases the decision-maker may feel threatened by the others in the group, triggering the role of ‘silent member’. Eye-to-eye decision-making: This decision-making style is characterised by a maximum concern for decision adequacy and maximum concern for commitment (9/9 position on the grid). This style is based on the assumption that better decisions can be reached if all available resources in the group are utilised. This is only possible if all groups members are involved and make a contribution to the task at hand. Typically, power by the 9/9 decision-maker is shared among the group members in order not to stifle creativity and expression of different views. Traditional decision-making: This decision-making style reflects the central 5/5 position on the grid. The underlying assumption is that both concerns (adequacy and commitment) are necessary but mutually exclusive. Put differently, the 5/5 decision-maker is convinced that if he emphasises one concern more, the less emphasis can be put on the other. In this respect he is willing to share some of his individual power, confer with the group members and modify his own position to reach a decision that is supported by the majority of the group. Put differently, this style is characterised by the attempt to reach a compromise. The decision-making style of the chairman: in practice Although this framework is well developed from a conceptual point of view, it has to our knowledge never been used to empirically study the work of the board chair. This offers a unique opportunity to further enhance our insights and complement existing studies in the field. We included this framework in our qualitative survey on board practices of Belgian listed companies.2 The Decisions-making Grid was used to capture the perceptions of the listed companies on the decision-making style of their chairman (Figure 9.4). A general observation is that there exists a considerable diversity among the perceived decision-making styles of the chairmen of the BEL 20 and Bel MID companies (the number of observations are indicated by xxx in Figure 9.4). A considerable amount of chairmen in our sample tends towards the eye-to-eye decision-making style (quadrant A), The Appropriate Board Chair: A Reality Check High 9 Concern for Commitment 8 7 279 (1/9) Good Neighbour Decision Making (9/9) Eye-to-eye Decision Making The important thing is for members to support the group position. The task should not be allowed to destroy the group because without cooperation there would be no group to work on problems. Involvement of all group members in the dicision results in both maximum support and a higher quality decision through an increase in resources. 6 (5/5) Traditional Decision Making 5 People must realise they have to give a little and take a little to get a job done. Push for the best decision but make sure there is enough agreement to get a decision and to insure implementation. 4 3 2 Low 1 1 Low (1/1) Default Decision Making Disagreement and emotional thinking go hand in hand with group situations. It is better to rely on precedent or experts outside the group, and not feed the conflict. Just go along and ‘mark time’ until the group sees the light. 2 3 (9/1) Self-Sufficient Decision Making Group-centred action is a bid for mediocrity. The quality of decisions comes first, and the demands of the group detour decisive though to irrelevant issues. 4 5 6 7 Concern for Decision Adequacy 8 9 High Figure 9.4 Decision-making styles of chairpersons of BEL 20 and BEL MID companies meaning that they attach great importance to decision adequacy as well as to the involvement of the board members. The study participants explained that their chairman is offering the other directors the opportunity to intervene in the discussion and share their opinions and views. They emphasised that there is room for deliberations but that the chairperson also ensures that decisions are made and that they are clear for all board members. In second order, there are a number of chairmen who are perceived to expose a more ‘authoritarian’ or self-sufficient decision-making style (quadrant B). Although these types of chairmen also attach great importance to the concern for adequacy of the decision, they care less about the involvement of other board members. The comments added by the study participants explained that the chairman has a ‘natural authority’ with a strong view on the outcome of the decisions and strictly keeps reins in decision-making. There is some room for input of other board members but in the end it’s the opinion of the chairman that prevails. Thirdly, in some cases the perceptions of the study participants revealed a good neighbour decision-making style (quadrant D) of the chairman. In these cases, the chairman attaches great importance to involving the board members but pays less attention to decision adequacy. Study 280 Abigail Levrau and Lutgart Van den Berghe participants noted that looking for compromises is not feasible at all times. The chairman shows a striking diplomacy and lets the board members speak. Discussions are allowed but he is concerned to make sure all points are cleared up and to resolve potential conflicts in order to safeguard the harmony in the group. In an equal number of cases the chairman is perceived to look for compromises. This coincides with the traditional decision-making style in the centre of the grid (5/5 position). The study participants explained that the chairman has his own opinion but waits to express his point of view. He opts to give other board members first the opportunity to enter into the discussion and share their comments. Afterwards he will add his opinion and the debate will continue until the board has reached a compromise. Finally, there appears to be a few cases of chairmen who are perceived to tend towards the default decision-making style or expose a decisionmaking style that is situated in between the models. And the other aspects of decision-making The decision-making grid also facilitates to get insights into the decision-making process within the board and the way this process is led by the chairperson in particular. Two attributes of the chairperson leadership emerged from the data. The chairman as time manager: An often cited comment by the study participants is that the chairman manages the board meeting time, in order to make efficient use of the available time. The challenge for him is to keep an eye on the clock but in such a way that board members do not feel the meeting is rushed or too rigid. In this respect, he presses for discipline among his fellow directors during board meetings. His concern is to have a balanced attention for presentations made by management and room for discussion on the agenda points at hand. He strives to come to a conclusion within the scheduled and limited time frame without important discussions being truncated. Our board meetings commonly last 3 to 4 hours. A specific moment in time the chairperson says: ok, good we’ve heard various opinions now it’s time to make a decision; so at the end of the discussion he will try to summarize the essence of the debate and ask the board members: do we agree on this point? The board has limited time so the chairman introduces the topic, gives management the opportunity to present and then the The Appropriate Board Chair: A Reality Check 281 chairman takes back the topic and states: look, we need to take a decision. After some debate the chairman puts forward a proposal for decision. If nobody contests, the decision is made. That is the common procedure. The chairman as decision-facilitator and consummate listener: Study participants commonly point to the fact that the chairperson facilitates decision-making. For this purpose he uses different techniques, irrespective of the individual decision-making style. Apparently, chairmen have precontacts with other board members. During these brief exchanges ‘behind the scene’ sensitive topics are being ‘demined’ before they are openly tackled during the board meeting. The pre-meeting conversations help to understand the differences in point of views as well as the concerns of the directors that apparently are hard to express in a full board. It’s the chairman’s role to actively manage these sensitivities in a subtle way and ensure that the different perspectives that were uttered beforehand are taking into account in the final decisions. Of particular interest are the contacts between the chairman and the CEO (in cases where these roles are split) before and in between board meetings. Although the frequency and format of these contacts differ among the BEL 20 and BEL MID companies, they are perceived by the study participants to be influential on board decision-making. One frequently cited element was the interaction between the chairman and the CEO in setting the board agenda and as such on the topics that will be tackled during the board meetings. Another tactic used by various chairmen during board meetings is ‘polling’ of directors, although this does not seem relevant nor necessary for every agenda item or discussion issue. In relevant cases the chairman calls on directors to express their personal opinion or concern on the topic. The rationale for doing so differs. Sometimes the director involved has a particular expertise that can add value to the discussion. Some directors are also less vocal than others or feel less comfortable raising comments on a topic that is not directly their field of expertise. By this ‘polling’ technique the chairman safeguards that most, if not all directors have an input in the discussion and the decision-making. However, our findings reveal that not all chairmen are in favour of this tactic. In contrast they simply assume that if directors want to add something to the discussion they will do so. Their role is to make sure that there is room and occasion to contribute. In addition, study participants pointed out that the chairperson is aware of his responsibility to lead the board to a decision. Taking into account that in practice board decisions are commonly taken by 282 Abigail Levrau and Lutgart Van den Berghe consensus, this requires specific skills of the chairperson. In order to reach a decision that is supported by the board, the chairman must strike a delicate balance to make sure he receives and consolidates different perspectives, while also integrating them with his own point of view. It is perceived to be an ‘art’ to frame the input of directors within their respective backgrounds, to anticipate, spot and manage (potential) tensions, to stimulate interaction between executives and non-executives, to keep the discussion task-oriented etc. Moreover, the chairman has ’to feel’ whether a consensus is likely be obtained or not. Consensus should not come at the cost of meaningful decisions and sometimes it feels more appropriate to postpone decisions in order to revisit issues at a next board meeting. Some chairmen try to undermine wide diverging opinions by having individual and informal side-talks before or in between meetings. In some cases, when no consensus can be reached, the chairman decides to put the topic to a vote or has a casting vote in the final decision. When the chairman has heard all points of view, he will collect them and summarizes the main points. Out of this he will suggest a decision… in a company like ours, he is well aware of the fact that the board must come to a conclusion and needs to take a decision, but he is not dominant in this approach. The chairman of the board strives for a neutral position to ensure that all the interventions are taken into account and that exchanges are sufficiently open. He has a facilitator role, he brings opinions to the surface and makes room for divergent opinions … He perfectly knows how to make sure the various board members express themselves in order to reach a decision … how to lead complex decision-making, without manipulating things. The difficulty of being a chairman is that he has an own opinion, as part of the board of directors, that he should be able to express this opinion without acting as a ‘guerrilla leader’ towards other directors … therefore this chairman attaches attention to give others the opportunity to intervene, to hear different opinions as well as to add his own arguments… next, all will be balanced and of course the interest of the company is taking into account when finally taking a decision. These findings confirm the results of other empirical studies on chairmen and touch upon various issues. Firstly, chairpersons vary in their ways and approaches in fulfilling their job. A common feature is that The Appropriate Board Chair: A Reality Check 283 in carrying out their board leadership role they are involved in two key sets of relationships: (i) interaction with the board as a whole as well as with individual directors and (ii) interaction with the CEO. The chairman, as the board leader, forms the nexus of these relationships. Relationships also encompass an emotional dynamic. Various conscious and unconscious forces can be identified which make board chairs reluctant to share power or can hamper building high-quality relationships between the chairman and other actors. The importance of establishing and maintaining these relationships is recognised by other scholars (Harrisson and Murray, 2012; O’Higgins, 2009; Roberts and Stiles, 1999). It also complies with the conviction to approach a board as a social and political system, with boundaries, interdependence among the members and defined roles (Crainer and Dearlove, 2007; Cascio, 2004). Secondly, we found many different pictures of individual decisionmaking styles exposed by the chairmen. Hall et al. (1964) state that each decision-making style is designed to deal with three by-products of decision-making: (1) time-loss resulting from endless discussion points not strictly related to the decision; (2) lack of assurance that a decision once reached will be implemented; and (3) inability of the group to profit by its experience in future work sessions. In this respect, the eye-to-eye decision-making style is put forward to be the most effective one, especially for a collegial body. Although in our sample various chairmen adhere to this preferred model, the findings suggest that application in practice requires specific techniques of the board leader. This is also recognised by Katharina Pick (2009) when studying first-hand the behaviour of board chairs of US companies. She identified four roles of the chairperson in leading boardroom discussions: (i) managing the ‘status dilemma’ of leading a group of equals; (ii) managing the ‘tension’ in the interaction between the board and senior management, (iii) sustaining the cohesion in the board while encouraging debate, and (iv) managing the ambiguous nature of the board’s role. This role set addresses the unique challenges the board chair faces while each role includes a range of tactics that are used by the chairperson. In their impressive study on chairmen in 12 countries throughout the world, Kakabadse and Kakabadse (2008) identified six common disciplines of board leadership. One of the disciplines refers to the skill of ‘influencing outcome’ in order to realise a particular goal. They found that skilful influencing is a subtle art which requires appropriateness of style. Various techniques were identified which allow a chairman to focus board energy towards a decision, which takes into account the perspectives of each director, despite the unique nature of each circumstance. 284 Abigail Levrau and Lutgart Van den Berghe Finally, the findings suggest that leading board decision-making also requires personal (behavioural) competencies to work effectively in practice. Not formally embedded in law, the position of the chairman of the board appears to be a very personal and subjective one. This is in line with the study of Harrison and Murray (2012). Their qualitative part revealed three categories of perceived characteristics of effective and less effective board leadership: (i) the chair’s motivation for taking on the role (ii) features of the chair’s personality and (iii) typical ways that chairs behave in the role. They conclude that chair leadership effectiveness is influenced by the personal qualities the leader brings to the position. They support this conclusion by referring to the notion of ‘emotional intelligence’. Board leaders with emotional intelligence tend to have a higher degree of self- and social awareness and are able to better manage themselves and others in relationships than those without. Gabrielsson et al. (2007) rely on the team production approach to understand board leadership. The rationale is that each chairperson faces the challenge to create and maintain a constructive team production culture in the board room because this culture contributes to value creation. To this end a chairman has to possess various attributes that are decisive towards a team production culture. These include among others creativity, criticality, preparedness and commitment. The future for the board chair Taking into account the fact that the decision-making style is highly correlated with the chairman’s personality, it is relevant to provide instruments supporting the development of leadership skills of those who are appointed as the chairman of the board. The latter is of utmost important in case the individual has no previous experience with chairmanship. Moreover, a change in chairperson implies a change in decision-making style, which can have a major impact on the effectiveness of a board. Development opportunities such as leadership training, mentoring or peer-learning circles can help chairmen to transcend the challenges inherent in personality and board collegiality in order to evolve towards the most effective decision-making style. Kakabadse and Kakabadse (2008) correctly perceive this as one the largest domains for improvement, that is, the specific development of directors to take over the position of chairman of the board. Traditionally, new chairmen have had to make the transition by developing themselves. Nor have The Appropriate Board Chair: A Reality Check 285 business schools and other external training suppliers developed effective programs for new chairmen. If boards are to become more effective – and more Enrons are to be avoided – there is an urgent need to find ways of supporting the development of chairmen. He therefore proposes to run a series of master classes, getting people who are considered outstanding chairmen to run the master class with those who have the ambition and insight to become chairmen and give people insights on what it means to be chairman, what kinds of issues to face, what kind of problems to face and how to deal with people. Sir David Walker also follows on this track when he states that ‘an appropriately intensive induction and continuing business awareness programme should be provided for the chairman to ensure that he or she is kept well informed and abreast of significant new developments in the business’. Taking these suggestions to heart, GUBERNA, the Belgian Director Institute, has successfully launched a ‘chairmen’s forum’, where mature and new chairmen meet in a confidential setting to discuss the numerous challenges a modern board chair is faced with. Furthermore, we also advocate for a regular assessment of the chairman. As pointed out in the literature, feedback can be a powerful tool in enhancing individual and group performance. Dunne (1997) noted ‘[l]ike with musicians or sportsmen, they all know that whenever they think about their technique they improve their performance’. A worthwhile example in this respect is the self-assessment exercise by a Belgian chairwoman. She was appointed two years ago as board chair. It was a new role as she had no previous experience with chairmanship. Her personal lessons learned are reported in Figure 9.5, described as 10 tips and tricks for a non-executive chairman. In addition, we have introduced the concept of strategic board recruitment. More in particular, we have argued that the people who are responsible for recruiting directors, should think differently about the type of people who make good board members and about the ways they are encouraged to live up to their potential, once on the board. A similar plea can be made towards the selection criteria and process of the chairman. Given the unique challenges and complexity of board chair leadership, the process of choosing the right person for the job is a delicate exercise and deserves more attention. Our research into board practices of Belgian listed companies reveals that boards pay some attention to the specific selection criteria for the chairman, but these criteria vary substantially among the companies involved. Furthermore, these criteria are not commonly made explicit into a profile. Figure 9.6 provides some examples. 286 Abigail Levrau and Lutgart Van den Berghe The non-executive chairman as leader of the board room meeting: know, speak and make change 1. Know the company’s by-laws/articles of association: read the formal obligations and learn about the expectations of the various governing bodies. 2. Know your people: make a list of the directors and other actors (management, auditor, experts etc.) who attend the board meetings. Learn about their responsibilities, personalities, their professional affinities/interests. 3. Be aware of your responsibilities: know for what kind of files your board has to make a decision and who will implement the decision. 4. Indicate priorities in the board agenda: make a distinction between strategic and monitoring or more technical points on the agenda, make sure to prepare thoroughly the files that you consider as priority. 5. Formulate: have frequently (min. 1 hour) contact with the CEO/ management to systematically discuss the board issues, projects, communication, actuality. Express your expectations but keep the roles district and show respect for the responsibilities of the CEO. 6. Demand: ‘stand on your stripes’, claim the required support and develop your own prerogatives: determine the agenda, prepare and lead the board meeting, follow-up on execution of board decisions and to do’s. 7. Decide: determine the number of board meetings and organise only additional meetings if necessary or of additional value. Consider informal appointments as ‘preparatory’ and formalise decisions in board meeting. 8. Be accountable: explain what you do and why in a transparent way, take accountability for your initiatives, frame them within the working of the board and (implementation of) the decisions that are taken. 9. Change: have the courage to make changes to ‘old habits’ by means of introducing new standards/rules/norms. Observe the resistance to each change but concentrate on the ones who show a constructive attitude. 10. Trust: consider each experience as a learning process for improvement and as an opportunity to increase performance while keeping your objectives in mind. Share your experience with others and listen to their feedback. Figure 9.5 Ten tips and tricks for a non-executive chairman Finally, taking into account the many challenges of being an effective board chair as well as the increasing expectations towards boards and their chairs in particular, questions about the required time investment will rise. It is obvious that the practice of ceremonial board chairman has come to an end. On the other end of the spectrum is the chairman who acts as an executive. It is a thin line to find the appropriate degree The Appropriate Board Chair: A Reality Check • • • • • • • 287 Strong character/personality Authority/status, track record, experience Broad network Organisational talent Charisma All-round expertise Knowledge of the business Figure 9.6 Selection criteria for the chairman The chairman of a major bank should be expected to commit a substantial proportion of his or her time, probably around two-thirds, to the business of the entity, with clear understanding from the outset that, in the event of need, the bank chairmanship role would have priority over any other business time commitment (so better not having an executive function). Depending on the balance and nature of their business, the required time commitment should be proportionately less for the chairman of a less complex or smaller bank, insurance or fund management entity. The higher time commitment should be recognized in the fee level. Figure 9.7 Extract from the Walker Report regarding time investment by the board chair of involvement that fits the needs of the board and the organisation. Nevertheless, there appears to be a consensus that sufficient availability of the chairperson should be expected in order to fulfil its role in an effective way. In general one can state that the more complex the sector and the company, the more time will need to be invested in the board chair function. Illustrative in this respect is the far-reaching recommendation for the financial sector as included in the Walker Report in the UK (Figure 9.7). Some conclusions Company boards and their decision-making process have largely been shielded from both business community and academic circles. Consequently, many researchers and code developers (who are outside the company) have remained at a considerable distance from actual board practise and rely on board characteristics which can be easily retrieved and assessed from an external point of view. In particular, 288 Abigail Levrau and Lutgart Van den Berghe board leadership is commonly looked at from a rather narrow approach, deducing the attention to the appropriateness of a choice between separating or combining the roles of CEO and chairman. The emerging norm of increased transparency will undoubtfully include and affect the role of the board chair. By pulling back the curtain, at least to some extent, we have tried to shed some light on the behaviour and heterogeneity of board chairmanship. Not formally embedded in law, the position of the chairman of the board appears to be a very personal and subjective one. Taking into account the distinctive features of a board of directors, the chairman, besides being a team leader needs to be a relational leader. The relationship with the CEO as well as the interactions with other board members in and outside the board room are perceived as critical. This highlights the importance of role clarity of the board chairman. In this respect, the plea by Leblanc (2012) for a formal position decryption for key governance actors such as chairman and CEO is justifiable. These job descriptions should delineate responsibilities and accountabilities related to each role, as well as competencies and other attributes required. Besides, optimal decision-making implies the use of specific techniques and appeals to personal competencies of the chairperson involved. Moreover, the position of the chairman is not neutral. The way he takes position in board room deliberations influences intendedly or unintendedly the outcome of the decision-making. Although in practice, various decision-making styles exist, the eye-to-eye decision-making model is perceived to be the most effective one, both in theory and in practice. In order to reach the path towards optimal decision-making, one of the most crucial elements of board effectiveness, it is advisable to put more effort into the professional selection and development of board chairmen, a clear engagement as to their commitment and time investment, a periodical assessment of the ‘room for improvement’ as well as to foresee sufficient support for this crucial board function. Notes 1. Our research of ‘listed companies’ refers to those listed companies that are part of the BEL 20, BEL Mid and BEL Small indices. They represent the largest part of the market capitalisation. 2. The findings that are reported with respect to the Decision-making Grid stem from interviews with company secretaries of BEL 20 and BEL Mid companies. The Appropriate Board Chair: A Reality Check 289 References AMF, Rapport 2010 de L’AMF sur le gouvernement d’entreprise et la rémunération des dirigeants (Paris: Autorité des Marchés Financiers, 2010). Bainbridge, S.M. ‘Why a board? Group decision-making in corporate governance’, Vanderbilt Law Review, LV (2002) 1–55. Beatty, D.R. ‘The role of the chair orchestrating the board’, Rotman Magazine, Spring (2012) 48–53. Cadbury, A. Corporate Governance Chairmanship. A Personal View (New York: Oxford University Press, 2002). Cascio, W.F. ‘Board governance: a social systems perspective’, Academy of Management Executive, XVIII (2004) 97–100. Commission Corporate Governance, Belgian Corporate Governance Code (Brussels, 2009) Conger, J.A. Boardroom Realities. Building Leaders Across Your Board (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 2009). Crainer, S. and Dearlove, D. ‘Boardroom blitz: what happened to real debate among corporate directors?’, The Conference Board Review, November/December 2007. Daily, C.M. and Dalton, D.R. ‘CEO and board roles held jointly or separately: much ado about nothing?’, Academy of Management Executive, XI (1997) 11–20. Daily, C.M., Dalton, D.R. and Cannella, Jr. A.A. ‘Corporate governance: decades of dialogue and data’, Academy of Management Review, XXVIII (2003) 371–382. Dalton, D.R. ‘Counterpoints to separating the roles of CEO and board chair’, The Corporate Board, (2012) 16–20. Dunne, P. Running Board Meetings: How to Get the Most from Them (London and Philadelphia: Kogan Page, 1997). Finkelstein, S. and D’Avanti, R.A. ‘CEO duality as a double-edged sword: how boards of directors balance entrenchment avoidance and unity of command’, Academy of Management Journal, XXXVII (1994) 1079–1108. Finkelstein, S. and Mooney, A.C. ‘Not the usual suspects: how to use board process to make boards better’, Academy of Management Executive, XVII (2003)101–111. Gabrielsson, J., Huse, M. and Minichilli, A. ‘Understanding the leadership role of the board chairperson through a team production approach’, International Journal of Leadership Studies, III (2007) 21–39. Hackman, J.R. and Morris, C. Group task group interaction process and group performance effectiveness. A review and proposed integration. In: L. Berkowitz, Advances in Experimental Social Psychology (New York: Academic Press, 1975), pp. 45–99. Hall, J., O’Leary, V. and Williams, M. ‘The decision-making grid: a model of decision-making styles’, California Management Review, VII (1964) 43–54. Harrison, Y. and Murray, V. ‘Perspectives on the leadership of chairs of nonprofit organization boards of directors. a grounded theory mixed-method study’, Nonprofit Management & Leadership, XXII (2012) 411–437. Heidrick & Struggles, European Corporate Governance Report 2011. Challenging Board Performance (2011). Hermalin, B.E. and Weisbach, M.S. ‘Boards of directors as an endogenously determined institution: a survey of the economic literature’, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 8161 (2000).. 290 Abigail Levrau and Lutgart Van den Berghe Jensen, M.C. and Meckling, W.H. ‘Theory of the firm: managerial behaviour, agency costs and ownership structure’, Journal of Financial Economics, III (1976) 305–360. Kakabadse, A. and Kakabadse, N. Leading the Board. The Six Disciplines of WorldClass Chairmen (New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2008). Leblanc, R. ‘Assessing board leadership’, Corporate Governance – An International Review, XIII (2005) 654–666. Leblanc, R. ‘General commentary on European Union corporate governance proposals’, International Journal of Disclosure and Governance, IX (2012) 1–35. Leblanc, R. and Gillies, J. Inside the Board Room. How Boards Really Work and the Coming Revolution in Corporate Governance (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 2005). Levrau, A. and Van den Berghe, L. Identifying key determinants of effective boards of directors. In: Kakabadse, A. and Kakabadse, N. Global Boards. One Desire, Many Realities (New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2009), pp. 9–44. Levrau, A. Corporate Governance and the Board of Directors: a Qualitative-Oriented Inquiry into the Determinants of Board Effectiveness, PhD thesis (Ghent: Ghent University, 2007). Lorsch, J.W. Leadership: The Key to effective boards. In: Conger, J.A. Boardroom Realities. Building Leaders Across Your Board (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 2009), pp.25–68. McNulty, T., Pettigrew, A., Jobome, G. and Morris, C. ‘The role, power and influence of company chairs’, Journal of Management & Governance, XV (2011) 91–121. Muth, M.M. and Donaldson, L. ‘Stewardship theory and board structure: a contingency approach’, Corporate Governance – An International Review, VI (1998) 5–27. O’ Higgins, E. The chairman of the board of directors: role and contribution. In: Kakabadse, A. and Kakabadse, N. Global Boards. One Desire, Many Realities (New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2009), pp. 217–235. Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development, OECD Principles of Corporate Governance (Paris: OECD Publications Service, 2004). Parker, H. ‘The company chairman’, Long Range Planning, XXIII (1990) 35–43. Pettigrew, A. ‘On studying managerial elites’, Strategic Management Journal, XIII (1992) 163–182. Pettigrew, A. and McNulty, T. ‘Sources and uses of power in the boardroom’, European Journal of Work and Organizational Psychology, VII (1998) 197–214. Pick, K. First among equals: leading your fellow directors as a board chair. In: Conger, J.A. Boardroom Realities. Building Leaders Across Your Board (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 2009), pp. 85–120. Roberts, J. ‘Building the complementary board. The work of the plc chairman’, Long Range Planning, XXXV (2002) 493–520. Roberts, J. and Stiles, P. ‘The relationship between chairmen and chief executives: competitive or complementary roles?’, Long Range Planning, XXXII (1999) 36–48. Schweiger, D.M., Sandberg, W.R. and Ragan, J.W. ‘Group Approaches for improving strategic decision making: a comparative analysis of dialectical inquiry The Appropriate Board Chair: A Reality Check 291 devil’s advocacy and consensus’, Academy of Management Journal, XXIX (1986) 51–71. Stewart, R. ‘Chairman and chief executive: an explanation of their relationship’, Journal of Management Studies, XXVIII (1991) 511–527. Surowiecki, J. The Wisdom of Crowds (New York: Random House, 2004). Walker, D. A Review of Corporate Governance in UK Banks and Other Financial Industry Entities (London: The Walker Review Secretariat, 2009). Westphal, J.D. ‘Second thoughts on board independence: why do so many demand board independence when it does so little good?’, Corporate Board, XXIII (2002) 6–10. 10 The Leadership Attributes of the Chairman of the Board: An International Study Andrew Kakabadse, Nada K. Kakabadse, Chris Pierce and Frank Horwitz Introduction Board composition and its impact on board performance has been an area of significant corporate governance research activity (Dulewicz et al., 1995; Leblanc and Gillies, 2005; Charan, 2005; Nadler et al., 2006; Ehikioya, 2009). Boardroom dynamics has also been identified as both positively and adversely effecting boardroom performance and, in turn, organisational performance (Abor and Biekpe, 2007). In particular, the issue of CEO duality (i.e. the CEO performing chairman of the board functions) has been a focus of research due to CEO duality increasing agency problems and leading to poor firm performance (Maharaj, 2009). This position has found support among some academics, who propose splitting the position of CEO and chairman as a way to control the scale of the agency problem (Jensen, 1993; Coombes and Wong, 2004). Despite the fact that no clear indication has emerged concerning the impact of role separation or duality on firm performance (Moyer et al., 1996; Schmid and Zimmermann, 2008; Saibaba and Ansari, 2012; Wong, 2010), most studies emphasise the dominance of the CEO role. Drawing upon role theory, leadership theory and agency theory, Roberts and Stiles (1999) have argued that there is no clear line separating the roles and responsibilities of chairman and CEO and that their strategic relations are particularly prone to role overlap, contingent on context. Roberts (2002) agreed and found that the role of chairman positively contributes to CEO performance, but only when the two roles are scrutinised from the view of identifying role complementarities. Kakabadse et al. (2006) found that nature of the chairman–CEO relationship impacted on board effectiveness. The chairman’s contribution was identified as first creating a platform for participation, and second, 292 The Leadership Attributes of the Chairman of the Board 293 respecting the division of roles between the chairman and CEO, both of which deeply influence boardroom dynamics. Their study highlighted the criticality of the chairman–CEO relationship by calling attention to ‘personal chemistry’’ and the need for a ‘sharing of philosophy’’. However, the study equally emphasised that it is up to the chairman to initiate high-quality interaction with his/her CEO, and that this interaction acts as the spur to work through boardroom tensions. Confident in the quality of the chairman–CEO relationship, ‘an outstanding chairman is able to comfortably raise submerging concerns to the realm of evident and workable dynamics’’ (Kakabadse et al., 2006: 147). Unlike the Nadler et al.’s perspective (2006) that the leader of the board should be seen as a facilitator and first among equals, Kakabadse and Kakabadse (2008) emphasise the importance of the chairman initiating the debate on clearly delineating roles and responsibilities between themselves, the CEO and the senior independent directors. Building on role delineation, the other leadership skills of the chairman are to gain the trust and respect of board members, to be an independent thinker, to challenge the CEO when necessary, to build a constructive working relationship with the CEO, to foster a broad environment of open communication to conduct effective meetings, to have good listening skills and to be knowledgeable about the company, its business and industry. Too cosy a relationship between CEO and chairman can adversely affect both boardroom and top team performance (Ong and Wan, 2008; Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2008). Sir Adrian Cadbury (2002) was one of the first to recognise the contingent context that chairmen work within: The role of a chairman is a personal one. It will vary with the individual chairman, with the boards for which they are responsible, with their chief executives, if they do not hold both posts, and with their companies. It will also vary through time. There is no straightforward job description to which chairmen can work. Chairmen have to decide for themselves just what they are able to do for their boards and for their board colleagues which no one else can and just what it is that their boards expect of them. (p. 101) Early research into board leadership focused upon individual board competences that the board as a whole should possess (Dulewicz et al., 1995). However, more recent research has begun to emphasise specified director attributes being associated with different board roles. An investigation into the competencies critical for success as a chairman 294 Andrew Kakabadse et al. or CEO (Dulewicz and Higgs, 2002, 2003) has provided evidence that emotional intelligence attributes (self-awareness, emotional resilience, motivation, interpersonal sensitivity, influence, intuitiveness and conscientiousness) are perceived as ‘vital’’ or ‘highly relevant’’ to the two leadership positions, chairman and CEO, by a majority of directors. Leblanc and Gillies (2005) were among the first to propose that: [t]here is no more significant factor in determining effective board governance than the leadership qualities of the chair. The chair of the board is not like other directors. The chair is primus inter pares – he or she is first among equals. Chairs have the same responsibilities and the same legal obligations as all directors, but, in addition, they have the responsibility of running the board – of managing its operations. Not all directors can be effective chairs, but every effective board has one. Board leadership is a critical and determinative predictor of board process and overall board effectiveness. Functional boards have strong chairs; dysfunctional boards have weak ones. The focus upon the leadership role of the chairman is now being reflected by policy makers in the revisions that are being made to corporate governance codes around the world. The influence of the King Reports of Corporate Governance in South Africa (King, 1994, 2002, 2006, 2009) has been and continue to be profound. The reports cover, amongst others, risk management, auditing, compliance, integrated sustainability reporting board configuration, the independence of the chairman and other board directors, and other issues such as ethics, integrity and disclosure. In particular, King (2009) recommendations focus on clarifying the duties and responsibilities of the role of chairman in relation to the role and contribution of other board directors and effective boardroom performance. Core functions for a high-performing chairman are identified that include: ● ● ● ● setting the ethical tone for the board and the company; overall leadership to the board; identifying and participating in selecting board members and overseeing a formal succession plan for the board, CEO and certain senior management appointments such as the chief financial officer; formulating the yearly work plan for the board against agreed objectives and playing an active part in setting the agenda for the board meetings; The Leadership Attributes of the Chairman of the Board ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● 295 presiding over board meetings and ensuring that time in meetings is used productively; managing conflicts of interest; acting as the link between the board and management and particularly between the board and the CEO; being collegial with board members and management while at the same time maintaining an arm’s length relationship; ensuring that directors play a full and constructive role in the affairs of the company and taking a lead role in the process for removing non-performing or unsuitable directors from the board; ensuring that complete, timely, relevant, accurate, honest and accessible information is placed before the board to enable the board to reach an informed decision; monitoring how the board works together and how individual directors perform and interact at meetings; mentoring to develop skill and enhance directors’ confidence and encourage them to speak up and make an active contribution at meetings; ensuring that all directors are appropriately made aware of their responsibilities through a tailored induction programme and ensuring that a formal programme of continuing professional education is adopted at board level; ensuring good relations are maintained with the company’s major shareholders and its strategic stakeholders and presiding over shareholders meetings; building and maintaining stakeholders trust and confidence in the company; upholding rigorous standards of preparation for meetings; ensuring that the decisions by the board are executed. The King III Report also recommended that the chairman’s role and functions should be formalised and recognised that this formalisation will be influenced by matters such as the life cycle or circumstances of the company, the complexity of the company’s operations, the qualities of the CEO and the management and the skills and experiences of each board member. Over the last decade, the directorships held by black people of listed South African companies have slowly but progressively increased (Commission of Employment Equity, 2008). However, a comparable increase of female directors has not taken place in South Africa. Yet, the research identifies that despite the fact that there is an 296 Andrew Kakabadse et al. emerging tendency to appoint black people to non-executive director (NED) roles, there remains a paucity of appointments of black candidates to the role of chairman. The UK Code of Corporate Governance (2010) published by the Financial Reporting Council states that ‘the chairman is responsible for leadership of the board and ensuring its effectiveness on all aspects of its role’. The Code specifies a chairman’s responsibilities for: setting the board’s agenda and ensuring that adequate time is available for discussion of all agenda items, in particular strategic issues; promoting a culture of openness and debate by facilitating the effective contribution of non-executive directors and ensuring constructive relations between executive and non-executive directors; for ensuring that the directors receive accurate, timely and clear information; and ensuring effective communication with shareholders (Principle A.3). Overall, it is the more recent literature that emphasises the need for a sound relationship between the chairman and CEO and for a board to not do so would give rise to a negative culture and dynamics on the board. In effect, the corporate governance codes are integrating the research findings that emphasise the functionality of roles, with boardroom dynamics being the essence of chairman leadership (Kakabadse et al., 2008a). Building a capability at board level that combines insights and skills with a productive style of directors’ interaction, irrespective of the diversity and magnitude of challenges that the organisation may face, is considered to be the nature of high-performance stewardship (Heracleous, 1999; Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2001, 2007; Roberts, 2002; Kakabadse et al., 2008a). Research questions The analysis and evaluation of the leadership attributes of chairmen is of considerable importance, since the chairmen are responsible for leadership of the board and ensuring board effectiveness. This chapter poses the following propositions concerning a chairman’s effectiveness in leading the board which builds upon the earlier research work of the authors as outlined in Kakabadse et al. (2008a). Proposition 1: The roles of the Chairman, the Deputy Chairman and the CEO are clearly delineated Kakabadse et al. (2008a) have particularly emphasised the importance of the chairman initiating the debate on clearly delineating roles and responsibilities between themselves and the CEO. The research The Leadership Attributes of the Chairman of the Board 297 described in this chapter identifies the scale of clarity concerning the delineation of roles between the chairman and CEO. Proposition 2: Chairmen have additional responsibilities above managing Board performance The research by Kakabadse et al. (2008a) emphasised the importance of the chairman initiating the debate on clearly articulating their roles and responsibilities. More recent changes in corporate Governance Codes such as the South African Code King III (2009) and the Walker Report in the UK (2009) have recommended that the chairman’s role and functions should be formalised. This research focuses upon clarifying the chairman’s additional responsibilities above managing board performance. Proposition 3: The self-evaluation concerning chairman effectiveness is aligned with other board members’ perceptions This research sets out to identify whether the self-evaluation concerning chairman effectiveness is aligned with other board members’ perceptions. Proposition 4: Chairmen encourage open communication among board members Kakabadse et al. (2008a) identified the importance of the chairman in fostering a broad environment of open communication to conduct effective meetings and to have good listening skills. This research sets out to identify how the chairmen’s contribution to this process is perceived by the other board members. Research method development Initial development of survey instrument The survey instrument was initially developed in 2007 for UK organisations in both the private and public sectors to analyse board activity and was described in Kakabadse and Kakabadse (2007). Demographic information was collected to include information about the respondent’s role, type of organisation and turnover. The questionnaire was divided into a number of sections. The first set of questions focused on demographic information about the respondent (e.g. age, gender, role, etc.) and the operation of the board (e.g. the number of directors on the board, the frequency and length of meetings, etc.). The second part 298 Andrew Kakabadse et al. of the questionnaire invited participants to give their opinions of the chairman using a Likert rating scale (1=Not at all true to 9=Very true) in a number of key areas that included strategic decisions, governance, risk, style, qualities and performance. In further sections, participants also were given the opportunity to rate the performance (using the 1 to 9 scale) of the CEO and the board. United Kingdom survey results (2007) The survey instrument described above was subsequently sent to all board members from the UK FTSE 350 who were invited to participate as part of an international, non-attributable survey examining the role, contribution and performance of chairmen and other key members of the Board. A tailored questionnaire was sent out to 2,678 individuals (discarding duplicates where individuals were members of more than one board). In total 286 questionnaires were returned, representing a response rate of approximately 11%. Considering the levels of responsibility held by the respondents and the time pressures that they face, this was deemed to be an excellent response. The UK sample had the following demographic profile: ● ● ● Boards tend to be male-dominated, with 1 in 10 respondents (9.1%) being female. This figure corresponds with similar other research (Pye, 2011). The majority of respondents (71.4%) were well-qualified and held either undergraduate, postgraduate or master’s degrees. The age profile differed according to the area of responsibility. Around two-thirds of the Chairmen and Senior Independent Directors were aged 60 or over. The youngest, however, were more likely to be in the role of Finance Director or Chief Financial Officer. International surveys (2008) A number of international studies were undertaken with large listed private sector organisations in the United States, UK, Australia, Turkey, Ireland, Germany, Russia, Belgium, China and France. The studies involved semi-structured interviews with over 350 Non-Executive Directors, CEOs, Chairs and Executive Directors in the United States, UK, Australia, Turkey, Ireland, Germany, Russia, Belgium, China and France. These interviews provided the researchers with a greater understanding of boards and existing inter-relationships. Following the outcomes of these interviews, a survey instrument was developed to The Leadership Attributes of the Chairman of the Board 299 determine how well boards were perceived to be performing, especially with respect to the chairman, the CEO and the board itself. In comparing differences between the chairman and views of others, T-tests were used to statistically compare mean scores. To assess the relationship of demographic variables to perceived performance of the chairman, an ANOVA technique was used. In addition, a triangulation approach using the UK survey results of 2007 was used. The demographic findings were consistent across the countries in that the majority of respondents were male and were well-qualified. The age of the chair was consistent across countries apart from Russia where chairmen tend to be younger. The background of individuals can have a significant influence on their opinion with respect to business issues. When taking demographic variables such as age, gender and education level into account, there were found to be no significant differences of view between age groups and education level when analysing the performance of the directors and chairman, the directors of the board and the CEO/MD. Looking at variables such as position on the board, size of the board, number of board meetings per annum and the typical length of these meetings, there were found to be no significant differences of view. Views were found to differ in relation to the performance of the chairman, directors of the board and the CEO/MD in that chairmen were more positive about themselves and the directors than those in other positions. South African survey (2010) Board members from a sample of South African companies, who were either members of the Institute of Directors (IoD) based in Johannesburg or from a University of Cape Town (UCT) Graduate School of Business (GSB) library database, were invited to participate in an international, non-attributable survey on the role and contribution of chairmen and directors of the board (Kakabadse et al., 2010). A questionnaire was sent out to the South African board members and staff within the IoD and UCT GSB helped collate the responses. Respondents were asked to complete the questionnaire with respect to one board that they were a member of. The questionnaire was divided into a number of sections. The first set of questions focused on demographic information about the respondent and the operation of the board. The second part of the questionnaire invited participants to give their opinions of the board directors and the chairman using a rating scale (1=Not at all true to 9=Very true) in the key areas that were identified in the initial UK study in 2007 outlined above namely: strategic decisions, governance, risk, 300 Andrew Kakabadse et al. style, qualities and performance. In further sections, participants also rated the performance (using a 1 to 9 scale) of the board, the CEO/MD and the deputy chairman (where applicable). A triangulation approach using the UK survey results of 2007 and the international survey of 2008 was used. In total 100 questionnaires were completed. Considering the nature of respondents and the lack of board data available within South Africa, this is deemed to be a good response, but care needs to be taken regarding making generalisations about the broad population of company directors as a whole, as views of non-executive directors were under-represented. Table 10.1 shows a breakdown of respondents to the survey – a sizeable proportion held the position of CEO/MD or executive director (80%). The sample of non-executive directors is small (3%) and it is therefore not possible to analyse the views of these directors. The South African sample had the following demographic profile: ● ● Gender Boards in South Africa are male-dominated and 1 in 7 (15%) of the respondents were female. This is broadly consistent with the findings of the 2007/8 Annual Report of the Commission for Employment Equity (CEE), which found that 15.2% of top and senior level managers were white females and a further 9.7% were black females. Our comparative research shows that gender representation on the boards of Australian, UK and Russian firms is not much different from that found in South Africa. Education The majority of respondents (82%) were well-qualified and held either an undergraduate or a master’s degree. Table 10.1 South African response segmentation Current position held Chairman CEO MD Chief Financial Officer/Finance Director Executive Director Company Secretary Non-Executive Directors Other Total Number of responses 9 20 15 14 31 5 3 3 100 The Leadership Attributes of the Chairman of the Board Table 10.2 Age Under 40 40–49 50–59 60 or over Total ● ● 301 Age and board position of respondents in South Africa Chairman 0.0 25.0 50.0 25.0 100.0 CEO/MD 21.2 30.8 36.5 11.5 100.0 Executive Directors 18.5 40.8 37.0 3.7 100.0 Other board members 28.7 19.0 33.3 19.0 100.0 Race Top and senior executive positions held by black people amount to 32.4% (Commission on Employment Equity, 2008). Age The average age of respondents differed slightly according to responsibility. Table 10.2 shows the age split of board members. Chairmen tend to be slightly older and executive directors younger overall. Two out of three respondents (67%) worked on a board that had between 6 and 11 members and 21% had between 12 and 14 members. On average the respondents’ companies had around five board meetings a year and these meetings typically lasted for up to half a day (66%), or a day (33%), but rarely longer. Analysis of research UK survey results (2007) Proposition 1: The roles of the Chairman, the Deputy Chairman and the CEO are clearly delineated The UK survey responses identified that the roles of the chairman, the deputy chairman and the CEO were clearly delineated and understood by the respondents. In particular the chairman’s role in the following activities was highly rated by board respondents: utilising the skills and experience of board members, evaluating the performance of the CEO, evaluating the performance of the board, determining the spread of skills and experience required on the board, evaluating the performance of the board members, clarifying the skills and experience required for each board member, encouraging feedback on each board members performance and evaluating the performance of the deputy chairman / senior independent director. 302 Andrew Kakabadse et al. Proposition 2: Chairmen have additional responsibilities above managing board performance The UK survey responses identified that the chairman’s responsibility for managing board performance was of critical importance. However, other activities were identified as being important attributes of a chairman that included utilising the skills and experience of board members; evaluating the performance of the CEO, the deputy chairman, the senior independent director, the board and board members; determining the spread of skills and experience required on the board; clarifying the skills and experience required for each board member; and encouraging feedback on each board member’s performance. The chairmen were rated highly by all the UK board respondents with respect to their contribution to effective board functioning, integrity and trustworthiness and a concern for shareholders and for stakeholders. Proposition 3: The self-evaluation concerning Chairman effectiveness is aligned with other board members’ perceptions The chairmen of UK companies were rated highly by all the UK board respondents with respect to their ability to clearly delineate the role of the board from that of management. When analysing the performance of the chairman and the CEO, there were no significant differences (p>.05) between responses concerning the gender and education level of the chairman and the CEO; however, age emerged as a significant demographic variable. Older chairmen (60+) were rated as more effective than younger chairmen with respect to their ability to clearly delineate the role of the board from that of management. Chairmen of UK companies rated themselves significantly higher (p<.05) with respect to their contribution to strategic decisions, governance thinking and application, risk, personal style, personal qualities and performance. Other board members gave a lower rating for their chairman in all of these areas. Chairmen rated themselves significantly higher (p<.05) with respect to: encouraging feedback on the chairman’s performance; clarifying the skills and experience required of each board member; and evaluating the performance of the board as a whole. Executive directors, rather than the non-executive directors, were the least positive in their opinion of their chairman. Proposition 4: Chairmen encourage open communication among board members Although the chairmen rated themselves significantly higher (p<.05) with respect to encouraging feedback on the chairman’s performance, The Leadership Attributes of the Chairman of the Board 303 the executive directors gave the chairmen a significantly lower rating. In particular they focused their criticism of chairmen on the following activities and attributes: ● ● ● ● ● Encouraging open debate Raising and handling tensions and sensitive issues Promoting teamwork Encouraging challenge Acting as a role model for others. International surveys (2008) Proposition 1: The roles of the Chairman, the Deputy Chairman and the CEO are clearly delineated The chairman and the CEO As in the initial UK study discussed above, the international survey responses identified that the roles of the chairman, the deputy chairman and the CEO were clearly delineated. In particular the role of the chairman in the following activities was highly rated by board respondents: ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● Utilises the skills and experience of board members (Australia had the highest ranking at 7.15 on a scale of 1 to 9; Kakabadse et al., 2008b) Evaluates the performance of the CEO (Russia had the highest ranking at 7.42 on a scale of 1 to 9; Kakabadse et al., 2009) Evaluates the performance of the board (Russia had the highest ranking at 7.31 on a scale of 1 to 9; Kakabadse et al., 2009) Determines the spread of skills and experience required on the board (the United Kingdom had the highest ranking at 7.02 on a scale of 1 to 9) Evaluates the performance of the board members (Russia had the highest ranking at 7.20 on a scale of 1 to 9) Clarifies the skills and experience required for each board member (the United Kingdom had the highest ranking at 6.39 on a scale of 1 to 9) Encourages feedback on each board members performance(the United Kingdom had the highest ranking at 6.64 on a scale of 1 to 9) Evaluates the performance of the deputy chairman / senior independent director (Russia had the highest ranking at 6.50 on a scale of 1 to 9) 304 Andrew Kakabadse et al. The chairman and the deputy chairmen role. The international survey respondents were clear that the deputy chairman understood his or her role. On a score of 1 to 9, the UK rated the deputy chairman as having clearly identified tasks and responsibilities at 6.43, in Australia it was 5.52, in Russia it was 6.65 and in South Africa it was 5.70. On a score of 1 to 9, the UK rated the deputy chairman’s understanding of his or her role as 6.76, in Australia it was 6.20, in Russia 6.86 and in South Africa it was 5.70. The survey also considered deputy chairman’s attributes in the following areas: having the confidence of the directors and the board, acting as the link between directors and the chairman, leading the search process for a new chairman, being the person directors can approach when difficulties can arise, being the person shareholders can approach when difficulties can arise and holding separate board meetings with board members. Proposition 2: Chairmen have additional responsibilities above managing board performance The survey responses identified that the chairman’s responsibility for managing board performance was of critical importance. Proposition 3: The self-evaluation concerning chairman effectiveness is aligned with other board members’ perceptions The Australian, South African and Russian survey results relating to chairmen provided significant evidence that chairmen tend to rate their performance in their role higher than other board members do. In South Africa, in particular, other board members tended to have a lower opinion of the chair’s effectiveness compared to the UK, Australian or Russian survey responses. Proposition 4: Chairmen encourage open communication among board members The international survey responses identified that board members felt able to challenge the chairman where necessary. On a score of 1 to 9, the UK rated this ability to challenge the chairman at 6.98, in Australia it was 7.06, in Russia it was 6.80 and in South Africa it was 6.34. In general, the respondents were very content with their board’s performance and effectiveness. On a score of 1 to 9, the UK rated board performance effectiveness at 7.55, in Australia it was 7.54, in Russia it was 7.22 and in South Africa it was 7.00. The Leadership Attributes of the Chairman of the Board 305 South African survey (2010) Proposition 1: The roles of the Chairman, the Deputy Chairman and the CEO are clearly delineated The chairman and the CEO The South African survey responses identified that the roles of the chairman, the deputy chairman and the CEO were in general clearly delineated and well understood. In addition, the relationship between the chairman and the CEO was found to be strong at a personal level. In their responses, both the chairman and the CEO believed that they are of a like mind; have an open relationship; and have a high degree of respect for each other. While other members of the board (the executive and non-executive directors) generally concurred with the shared views of the CEO or the chairman, they did not rate this relationship as highly. Other aspects of the relationship between the chairman and the CEO again showed that chairmen scored themselves significantly higher (p < .05), especially in terms of: working well with the CEO to realise the goals of the organisation; clearly delineating their role from that of the CEO; being professional in the search for a CEO replacement; and effectively evaluating the performance of the CEO. Several significant differences between the opinions of CEOs and chairmen were identified. The interview responses provided significant evidence that CEOs believed that they as CEOs determined the vision; however, the chairmen’s responses indicated that chairmen believe that CEOs merely drive the vision once the board has determined the vision. Also, the chairmen’s responses indicated that the board determines the organisational strategy and both the chairmen and the CEOs believe that the CEOs subsequently drive the strategy. This difference in the delineation of role concerning vision determination and the board’s ultimate responsibility of determining strategy, unsurprisingly, suggests that CEOs feel disempowered by the chairman and this may lead to feelings of being undermined by the chairman. These findings support previous research (Kakabadse et al., 2008a) that highlighted the importance of delineating boundaries and boundary roles in respect to responsibility for governance, the CEO mandate, the contribution of board members, role duality combining executive (insider) position with the role of independent chairman, clarity between the chairman and CEO as to who sets the vision and responsibility for building the right mix of skills of the board and assessing the level and quality of director contribution. Our previous studies highlight the contribution of the chairmen in effectively addressing these issues. This 306 Andrew Kakabadse et al. survey raises concerns about the capability of South African chairmen to address these critical issues which affect board performance. The chairman and the deputy chairman. Deputy chairmen are less prominent in the South African business landscape with organisations not always having this role represented on the board. Our findings show that their potential contribution is nonetheless important. The South African survey responses identified that the roles of the chairman and the deputy chairman were clearly delineated. Although there were only 10 responses to the section on the deputy chairman (where the role existed), their role is seen to be potentially an important one in that they have the confidence of directors, work well with the board directors and act as the ‘link’ between the directors and the chairman. Proposition 2: Chairmen have additional responsibilities above managing board performance The South African survey responses identified that the chairman’s responsibility for managing board performance was of critical importance. Additional attributes and activities of the chairman were also considered to be of importance by the respondents and these included: utilising well the skills/experience of directors (average score = 6.19) and effectively evaluating the performance of the CEO/MD (6.14). Proposition 3: The self-evaluation concerning chairman effectiveness is aligned with other board members’ perceptions The responses from the survey indicated that South African chairmen consistently rated themselves higher in terms of performance than other board members rated the chairman (Figure 10.1) particularly with reference to encouraging feedback on their performance, clarifying the skills/experience required of each director, effectively evaluating the performance of the CEO/MD and the performance of the board as a whole. The responses also provided evidence that chairmen of South African companies consistently scored themselves higher than the other board members in terms of taking a long-term view, being inclusive, encouraging challenge, promoting teamwork, being easy to talk to and being robust in their arguments. It is not clear why these differing views exist between the chairmen and other board members – possibly the chair is out of touch with what is happening with respect to the directors, or perhaps they may want to put a positive spin on their own performance. The Leadership Attributes of the Chairman of the Board 307 Performance The Chair ... Effectively evaluates the performance of the Deputy Chairman Effectively evaluates the performance of the CEO/MD Encourages feedback on his/her performance Evaluates the performance of the board as a whole Determines the spread of skills/experience required on the board Utilises well the skills/experience of directors Clarifies the skills/experience required of each director Effectively evaluates the performance of directors Displays little concern for shareholders 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 [1 = Not at all true, 9 = Very true] n = 100 Figure 10.1 Chair Other Board roles South African chairman performance Proposition 4: Chairmen encourage open communication among board members The survey responses identified that board members believed that chairmen of South African companies encouraged open communication among board members. In particular, directors felt that they were able to: discuss sensitive issues with the chairman, encourage the chairman to intervene when necessary and challenge the chairman when necessary. Discussion and conclusions The results from the various surveys show that generally speaking boards within South Africa, the UK and the international samples are perceived by board members as performing fairly effectively, and the views expressed concerning board performance and effectiveness do not differ greatly amongst board members. The only exception to this finding involves the chairman’s performance. The findings support previous research (Kakabadse et al., 2008a), which highlighted the importance of delineating boundaries and boundary roles in respect responsibility for governance, the CEO mandate, discretionary choice on relative contributions of board members, role duality combining executive (insider) position with the role of an independent chairman, clarity between the chairman and CEO as to who sets the vision and responsibility for 308 Andrew Kakabadse et al. building the right mix of skills of the board and assessing the level and quality of director contribution. The research also highlights the tenuous question of perceived power or ‘social distance’ between chairmen and CEOs and the substantively stronger association of board members with the latter. In spite of the little attention on better understanding the role of the chairman in comparison to the often heroic leader status of the CEO, the chairman is pivotal in influencing outcomes and the long-term direction of the firm (Kakabadse et al., 2008a). These findings have implications for: ● ● ● ● The future role and responsibilities of the chairman, the board and the CEO. The articulation of the chairman’s contribution and performance which emerges as requiring specific attention. Understanding the decision-making process at board level. Board member development. References Abor, J. and Biekpe, N. (2007). ‘Corporate governance, ownership and performance of SMEs in Ghana’. Corporate Governance, 9 (3): 288–300. Cadbury, A. (2002) Corporate Governance and Chairmanship, Oxford University Press, Oxford. Charan, R. (2005) Boards that Deliver, Jossey Bass, San Francisco, CA. Commission for Employment Equity (2008) Annual Report statistics quoted in Khuzwayo, W. ‘Skills shortage not to blame for slow transformation’. Business Report, 21 September 2008, pp. 1–2. Coombes, P. and Wong, S. (2004) Chairman and CEO – One Job or Two? The McKinsey Quarterly, No. 2. Dulewicz, V., Macmillan, K. and Herbert, P. (1995) ‘Appraising and developing boards and their effectiveness’, Journal of General Management, 20(3): 1–19.. Dulewicz, V. and Higgs, M.J. (2002) ‘Emotional intelligence and the development of managers and leaders’, in M. Pearn (Ed.) Handbook of Individual Development in Organisations, John Wiley, Chichester. Dulewicz, V. and Higgs, M. (2003) ‘Leadership at the top: the need for emotional intelligence’, Journal of Organizational Analysis, 11(3): 193–210. Ehikioya, B.I. (2009). ‘Corporate governance structure and firm performance in developing countries’. Corporate Governance, 9 (3): 231–243. Financial Reporting Council (2010) UK Corporate Governance Code, FRC, London. Heracleous, L.T (2001), ‘What is the impact of corporate governance on organizational performance?’ Corporate Governance: An International Review, 9(3): 165–173. Jensen, M., (1993) ‘Presidential address: the modern industrial revolution, exit and the failure of internal control systems’, Journal of Finance, 48: 831–880. The Leadership Attributes of the Chairman of the Board 309 Kakabadse, A. and Kakabadse, N. (2001) Geo-Politics of Governance: Impact of Contrasting Philosophies, Palgrave, London. Kakabadse, A., Kakabadse, N., and Barratt, R. (2006) ‘Chairman and chief executive officer (CEO): that sacred and secret relationship’, Journal of Management Development, 25(2): 134–149. Kakabadse, N. and Kakabadse, A. (2007). ‘Chairman of the board: demographics effects on role pursuit’, The Journal of Management Development, 26(2): 169. Kakabadse, A. and Kakabadse, N. (2008). Leading the Board: The Six Disciplines of World-class Chairmen. Palgrave MacMillan, London, pp. 1–2, 18–20, 96–98, 138–140, 189–191. Kakabadse, A. Kakabadse, N. and Myers, A. (2008a). Chairman of the Board: A Study of Role, Contribution and Performance of UK Board Directors, Cranfield School of Management and Manchester Square Partners. Kakabadse, A. Kakabadse, N. Pumphrey, D. and Myers, A. (2008b). Chairman of the Board: A Study of Role, Contribution and Performance of Australian Board Directors, Cranfield School of Management and Heidrich and Struggles. Kakabadse, A. Kakabadse, N. and Myers, A. (2009). Chairman of the Board Research: A Survey of Russian Organisations, Cranfield School of Management, UK and Russian Management Association, Moscow. Kakabadse, N.K., Kakabadse, A.P., Myers, A., and Horwitz, F.M. (2010). ‘The Leader Deficit of the Chair of the Board’. Paper presented to the Corporate Governance track of the British Academy of Management (BAM), October, pp. 1–9. King, M. (1994) The King Report on Corporate Governance: The Code of Corporate Practices and Conduct, Institute of Directors in South Africa, Parkland, South Africa. King, M. (2002) King II Report on Corporate Governance for South Africa, Institute of Directors in South Africa, Parkland, South Africa. King, M. (2006). The Corporate Citizen – Governance for all Entities. Penguin Books, Johannesburg, pp. 17–18, 39–45. King, M. (2009) King III Report: Code of Corporate Governance for South Africa, The Institute of Directors in Southern Africa (IoDSA), Institute of Directors in South Africa, Parkland, South Africa, 1 September. Leblanc, R. and Gillies, J. (2005) Inside the Boardroom, Wiley, London. Maharaj, R. (2009). ‘View from the top – what directors say about the board process’, Corporate Governance, 9(3): 326–337. Moyer, R., Rao, R. and Baliga, B. (1996) CEO duality and firm performance: what’s the fuss? Strategic Management Journal 17(1): 41–53. Nadler, D. A., Behan, B. A., and Nadler, M. B. (Eds.) (2006), Building Better Boards. Jossey Bass, San Francisco, CA. Ong, C.H. and Wan, D (2008). ‘Three conceptual models of board role performance’. Corporate Governance, 8(3): 317–329. Pye, A. (2011) Leading FTSE Companies: a Synopsis of the Continuing Study of Corporate Directors, ESRC, London Roberts, J. (2002), ‘Building the complementary board: The work of the plc chairman’, Long Range Planning, 35(5): 493–520. Roberts, J., and Stiles, P. (1999) The relationship between chairmen and chief executives: Competitive or complementary roles?’ Long Range Planning, 32(1): 36–48. 310 Andrew Kakabadse et al. Saibaba, M. and Ansari, V. (2012) A study of CEO duality, audit committees and corporate governance in companies listed in BSE 200 Index (12 May 2012). The IUP Journal of Corporate Governance, X(3): 44–51. Schmid, M. and Zimmermann, H. (2008), ‘Leadership structure and corporate governance in Switzerland’, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 20(1): 109– 120. Walker, D. (2009) A Review of Corporate Governance in UK Banks and Other Financial Industry Entities: Final Recommendations, FRC, London. Wong, S. (2010) Who’s Really in Charge? Why Non-Executive Chairmen Keep Running into Trouble. Conference Board Review, pp. 56–59, Fall 2010. 11 CEO/Chairman Role Duality Desire: Resistance to Separation Irrespective of Effect Nada K. Kakabadse, Andrew Kakabadse and Reeves Knyght Introduction Pre-19th-century notions of the governance of the enterprise were based on trust, namely that the stewards of the firm could be trusted to make best use of the assets of the organisation on behalf of the owners (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2008). At that time, governance processes were informal by nature but that soon changed. The birth of the joint stock corporation was accompanied by the registering of companies and the establishing of rules for corporate conduct, overseen by a body known as the Board. The reason for such stringency was the emergent misalignment between the interests of shareholders and that of the management (Shleifer and Vishay, 1997). In effect, the ‘manager’ agenda was viewed as differing from that of the shareholders (i.e. owners). In order to minimise such differences a number of actions have been taken tying managers’ actions tightly to shareholders’ goals through incentive-based mechanisms such as direct managerial share ownership (Jensen and Meckling, 1976) and the use of a variety of managerial remuneration schemes (Murphy, 1998). These levers have been central to Anglo-American (English) corporate governance practice (Roe, 2003: 1). Thus, the emergent purpose of corporate governance mechanisms has been to bring about greater alignment between owner (i.e. shareholders) and agent (i.e. managers). In essence, corporate governance has converged toward the delivery of sound corporate performance within the confines of the ‘accepted’ rules and norms of corporate behaviour. In doing so, governance practice itself has pursued to two main principles: corporate performance and/or corporate conformance (Cadbury, 1992). Yet, irrespective of whether boards have adopted a more performance or conformance 311 312 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. perspective to their governance practice, the measurement of the effectiveness of the board has, for a considerable time, focused on the capture of ‘hard’ measures (Roe, 2003). The ‘hard side’ of corporate governance has revolved around considerations of finance, legalities and economics. In contrast, corporate governance was historically conceptualised as a system of relationships between the shareholders, the management team represented by the chief executive officer (CEO), and the board of directors, all for the purpose of sharing the responsibility for realising the success of the corporation on behalf of its shareholders (Levrau and Van den Berghe, 2009). The shock waves from governance debacles such as Enron, WorldCom, Tyco and the sub-prime mortgage crisis global financial crisis highlight that the ‘hard side’ of corporate governance was never sufficient focus for board performance measurement. Inevitably, ‘soft side’ considerations of culture, board dynamics and interpersonal politics would sooner or later have to be taken into account in determining sensitive governance practice. A critical aspect underlaying this web of governance interrelationships has been the appointment and monitoring of the performance of the CEO. It has long been recognised that the board has had the primary task of selecting the CEO and the singular responsibility of holding the CEO accountable for the accurate reporting of the corporation’s financial health and of its overall performance (McNulty and Pettigrew, 1999). An additional but important responsibility of the board is that of holding the senior executive team accountable for the execution of strategy (Higgs, 2003). In order to do so, board members have been and are expected to ask penetrating questions that go beyond the information presented by management (Keasey et al., 2005). In order to better ensure the exercise of these two accountabilities, research shows that the chairman of the board is central to nurturing a culture of sound debate between board members and between the board and the executive team (Kakabadse et al., 2010). Engaging management in meaningful dialogue on strategic planning, direction and execution, confronting an unresponsive CEO and intervening if it is identified that change is required at the individual, team and organisational level are necessary elements of the board’s oversight role. Kakabadse and Kakabadse (2007: 62) argue that ‘a good chairman is the best safeguard against executive dictatorship’. It is no surprise therefore that the literature points to the fact that the oversight function of the board has grown in importance (Levrau and Van den Berghe, 2009). As US corporations have begun to dominate world markets, CEOs have accumulated power. As corporations have CEO/Chairman Role Duality Desire 313 become larger and more powerful, the position of CEO has grown both in status and public recognition. Thus although the board of directors is invested with the stewardship responsibility for the company a number of commentators point to the fact practical reality is that the CEO is very much in charge of both corporation and the board (Useem and Zelleke, 2006; Lorsch and MacIver, 1989; Useem, 1996). As Useem and Zelleke (2006: 2) aptly state, the problem is that ‘until recently, management’s power in large American companies reflected less a deliberate delegation of authority by a sovereign body than a de facto reality in which management had become dominant, effectively controlling the agenda of the board to which it was only nominally subordinate’. In the US culture, the CEO’s embrace of celebrity status is viewed as a valuable and intangible asset of the firm. As a result US CEOs enjoy broad discretion and can assert greater control over the firm, which in turn reinforces both the efficacy of the CEO as well as supposedly the firm’s performance (Hayward et al., 2004). American corporate governance has evolved within the formative context of the pioneering spirit and the values of hero leaders, which has now become deeply imbedded in the psyche of American entrepreneurialism (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2001). However, a number of writers emphasises that the concentration of management power is compromising the board’s abilities to monitor and discipline management (Mallette and Fowler, 1992; Finkelstein and Hambrick, 1996). In fact, CEO duality is identified as an impediment to the board’s monitoring of top executives (Fama and Jensen, 1983; Mallette and Fowler, 1992; Jensen, 1993; O’Sullivan, 2000; Aguilera, 2005; Dalton et al., 2007; Tuggle et al., 2010). This is due to vesting the power of the CEO and the chairman of the board in one person which is viewed as eroding the board’s ability to exercise effective control (Finkelstein and D’Aveni, 1994; Millstein, 1992). ‘The over-centralisation of power in the CEO is evident in the gap between the CEO’s salary and that of other executives’ (Aguilera 2005: 45). Research highlights that CEOs almost always set the agenda and control the information given to the board (Jensen, 1993). Moreover, CEO role duality signals that ‘the board is not an effective device for decision control unless it limits the decision discretion of individual top managers’ (Fama and Jensen, 1983), as the CEO can steer the boards’ attention away from the monitoring of issues towards topics that suit their own interests through setting detailed and rigid agendas (Tuggle et al., 2010) and through low voluntary disclosure of information to the board (Cadbury, 1992; Cheng and Courtney, 2006; Adams and Ferreira, 2007; Dalton et al., 314 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. 2007). Aguilera (2005: 45) poignantly concludes that in the US corporate governance system, the CEO, ‘who usually also exercises the role of chairman of the board’, enjoys the immense power and that ‘the split of these two roles is generally perceived as a transitional arrangement or a sign of weakness’ whilst the ‘over-centralisation of power in the CEO is evident in the gap between the CEO’s salary and that of other executives’. Over-centralisation of power can lead to CEO overconfidence and further US studies (Hayward and Hambrick, 1997; Malmendier and Tate, 2005) suggest that overconfident top managers are more likely to destroy value. However, a string of corporate scandals and the resounding and damaging impact of the global financial crisis (GFC) brought matters to a head concerning the quality and effectiveness of the governance of US corporations in particular, and large-sized firms in general. As a result, various laws are under consideration in Congress. If passed these will introduce new measures constraining executive pay (i.e. no more than 100 times the firms average wage unless 60% of shareholders approve), inhibiting ‘golden parachutes’ for public firms, pushing for the separation of the roles of chairman and CEO, annual election for all board members and the establishment of a risk committee for every board (The Economist, 2009). The Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) is also expected to introduce new rules allowing large shareholders to nominate candidates for board election. Further a ‘new rule introduced by the New York Stock Exchange will end discretionary voting by brokers who hold shares on behalf of clients as these votes have tended to be cast consistently in favour of the incumbents’ (The Economist, 2009: 70). Within this whirlwind of change initiatives, three issues have attracted media attention: (i) the separation of the functions of the CEO and chairman of the board, (ii) the independence of the board and (iii) the extent of CEO pay (Felton, 2004; Keay, 2006; The Economist, 2009). Bearing in mind the increasing pressure for the governance reform of the US corporation, and also considering the three focal points of media concern, this chapter explores the attitudes and opinions of a sample of CEOs/chairmen of US corporations towards these three issues. This is preceded by a literature analysis examining the case for the separation of roles of the CEO and chairman, the nature of board independence and the reasons for and likely future trends concerning CEO pay. The chapter concludes by highlighting the unwillingness to change by the present role incumbents leading major US corporations. CEO/Chairman Role Duality Desire 315 Separation of chairman and CEO Roles In the United States ‘one of the most contentious issues in public debate about the role of boards of directors’ is the long-standing controversy of combining the tasks and responsibilities of the CEO and the chairman of the board (Finkelstein and Hambrick, 1996: 213). This has been pursued despite calls for their separation by a notable opinion former, Conference Board, through various reports such as the Bacon Report on Corporate Boards and Corporate Governance (1992) and the Report of the Conference Board Commission on Public Trust and Private Enterprise (2003). Firms also face shareholder pressure to reconfigure their governance structures as concern has grown that the combining of the CEO and chairman roles reduces both the risk and monitoring abilities of the board. Providing the firm with a clear focus and unity of command at the top is no compensation for two governance deficiencies. In effect, Fama and Jensen (1983: 3044) purport that role duality can increase the likelihood that the CEO will ‘take actions that deviate from the interests of residual claimants’. Scholars (Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Finkelstein and D’Aveni, 1994; Rhoades et al., 2001) arguing from an agency theory perspective suggest that CEO duality increases agency problems and leads to poor firm performance because role duality promotes CEO entrenchment by reducing board independence. Yet, irrespective of the pressure for change, the percentage of US firms with combined functions has remained at approximately 80% over the last two decades (Kakabadse et al., 2010). Of those firms who boast a separation of functions, some are and have been in a position of transitioning to a new CEO. Thus for certain corporations, the separation of these two prime functions has only been temporary, namely for the duration of the succession process (Brickley et al., 1997; Dahya and Travlos, 2000). Studies also indicate that the phenomenon of role duality in the US corporation has given licence to the CEO/chairman (sometimes also president) to freely stamp their personality on the corporation and to pursue their personal goals in the arena of corporate decision making (Keay, 2006). With that as a long-standing practice, the management and leadership literature in the United States has progressively focused on praising the ‘hero’ CEO/chairman, eulogising their wielding of power to reallocate resources, holding in awe their exercising of their personal influence to motivate others to achieve the CEO/chairman’s goals and emphasising their building of a vision of the corporation’s future that is inspirational and shared with enthusiastic followers (Mintzberg, 2006). Implicit in this literature is the suggestion that remaining within 316 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. boundaries is for ‘losers’; winners bend or break with protocols, as rules and procedures constrain. Hence the message that seeps through is that what is needed is more ‘heroic’ leadership, or ‘transformational change driven leadership’ in order to turn companies around, and that the inspiration to do must emanate ‘from the top’. In fact, notable pundits have emphasised that the heroic leadership perspective dominates much of American management thinking where ‘the great one who rides in on the white horse to save the day, [changes] everything at will, even if he or she only arrived yesterday, with barely any knowledge of the organisation, its history or its culture’ (Mintzberg, 2006: 1). Analysis of US corporate scandals strongly suggests that corporate practices have suffered from CEO dominance, weak boards, information misalignment and deeply flawed executive compensation schemes (Felton, 2004; Keasey et al., 2005; Keay, 2006). Various studies also reveal that an emergent view amongst US investors is that they look forward to the separation of chairman and CEO roles, the enhancing of board accountability and executive compensation reforms (Felton, 2004; Keasey et al., 2005; Keay, 2006). The established US practice of the CEO and chairman (sometimes also the President of the company) as one person is in stark contrast to the traditions of the UK and other Anglo-American countries such as Australia and South Africa, where the separation of chairman and CEO is now the norm. Drawing on non US experience, a number of scholars have called for the systematic evaluation of the CEO, the establishing of independent nominating committees and the appointment of lead independent directors (LIDs: Alderfer, 1986; Hambrick and Jackson, 2000). Lorsch and Graff (1996), for example, have argued that leadership duality results in the incumbent CEO/chairman dominating meetings and controlling the agenda and flow of information. In support, Fama and Jensen (1983: 314) argue that granting the CEO dual-role responsibilities ‘signals the absence of separation of decision management and decision control’. This leads to self-interested and inefficient behaviour (Finkelstein and D’Aveni, 1994: Jensen and Meckling, 1976), ultimately reducing shareholder value as well as the value of the other employees of the firm. Additionally Fama and Jensen (1983) purport that agency costs in large organisations can be reduced by separating decision management from decision control, and that the board of directors is only an effective device for decision control if it limits the decision discretion of top managers. In support of this perspective, Jensen (1993: 36) states that the function of the chairman is to run board meetings and oversee the process of hiring, firing, evaluating and compensating the CEO. CEO/Chairman Role Duality Desire 317 Clearly the CEO cannot perform this function apart from his or her personal interest. Without the direction of an independent leader, it is much more difficult for the board to perform its critical function. Therefore, for the board to be effective, it is important to separate the CEO and chairman positions. As highlighted both from the academic and more popular literature, there is a growing sentiment that the CEO should not simultaneously hold the office of the chairman of the board (Dalton et al., 1998). Some go further and argue that a serious conflict of interest arises in having the CEO sitting as a voting board member let alone function as the chairman of the board (Rechner and Dalton, 1999; Taylor, 2000). International study advocates that effective governance is only likely under non-dual arrangements (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2008). This view is strengthened by Norburn et al.’s (2000) study where it was emphasised that separating the chairman and CEO roles strengthens the monitoring and scrutiny functions of the board, thus ensuring for greater CEO accountability. However, a vociferous counter case has been put forward. Boyd (1995), for example, found the dual leadership structure to be appropriate for firms that operate in uncertain environments, characterised by low resource abundance and high complexity. Ugeux (2004) has argued that role duality suits many US companies due to cultural fit reasons, and to alter that would induce unwelcome and unmanageable disruption. Similarly, Faleye (2007) pursued the cultural argument emphasising that coercing firms to separate out the CEO and chairman functions would be counterproductive. Similarly Donaldson and Davis (1991) consider that the stewardship aspect of the CEO’s role is best facilitated through governance structures that provide this top executive position with high levels of autonomy and managerial discretion. Brickley et al. (1997) also suggested that a leadership structure with combined roles is efficient and in general consistent with meeting shareholders’ interests, particularly for large US companies. On this basis, legislative reform forcing the separation of chairman and CEO roles would be misguided. Becht (1997: 11) aptly summarised the debate in favour of a governance structure of role duality as being ‘about the mechanisms that can ensure that powerful managers run companies in the interests of their owners’. Overall, the cost/benefit of role separation vs. role duality has induced mixed empirical evidence. From the perspective of the external director, some scholars (Wei Shen, 2005: 84; Useem 1984) indicate that ‘among 318 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. large US corporations there are strong disincentives, rather than incentives, for non-executive directors to challenge executives or to adopt corporate governance reforms that will limit managerial autonomy. These disincentives come from the social pressure to maintain managerial autonomy and authority for the elite of corporate leaders’. Further Westphal and Khanna’s (2003: 387) study found that non-executive directors experience social sanctions from their peer directors (of Forbes 500 companies) if they are perceived to threaten their elite position by advocating the separation of CEO and chairman positions or that of independent nominating committees. Some contend that firms with separated functions outperform firms with combined functions, whilst others find the opposite (Donaldson and Davis, 1991; Pi and Timme, 1993). Still others conclude that there is no statistically significant difference in performance between firms with role separation against those with combined roles (Baliga et al., 1996; Brickley et al., 1997). Further, Faleye (2007) drew attention to the fact that with ever greater organisational complexity and with an organisational performance dependency on CEO reputation, the likelihood is that role duality will continue and even become more popular. The combination of functions is also more likely to be favoured when insider ownership is dominant and the board is small in terms of membership size. But from whichever perspective, the literature confirms that the strong hero leader is deeply embedded in the US culture and strongly influences thinking on governance, board and organisational configuration and performance (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2008). Independence of the board Despite the arguments highlighting the pervasive effect of role duality, one underlying principle has not changed in US corporate governance thinking and practice, namely that the purpose and function of the board is to protect the principals (i.e. shareholders), particularly against agent indiscretion (Dooley, 1992). The question therefore remains as to why sentiments as, ‘boards can arguably retain power pursuant to a Madisonian conception of corporate governance that allows contracting parties to agree in advance via the corporate charter to allow the board to entrench itself’ (Kahan and Rock, 2003: 473), continue to be held dear. Why indeed when the American classic school of economic thought is perched on the Hamiltonian idea (Ben-Atar and Oberg, 1998; Martin, 1999) of maximising the authority of the shareholders’ representatives particularly over the approval to sell the company (Kihlstrom and Wachter, 2002) CEO/Chairman Role Duality Desire 319 and that has failed to produce the desired results: that of a sustainable corporation (Easterbrook and Fischel, 1981). The Madisonians model of governance views shareholders as capable of making intelligent decisions on acquisition offers but who in turn have chosen to accord decision-making powers to the board of directors because of their superior ability to determine and implement a value-maximising sales strategy (Coates, 2001). In this sense, the Madisonian model of corporate governance calls for appreciate checks and balances that are currently lacking in the combined role of CEO and chairman as one person. The history of corporate governance in the United States is better appreciated when viewed from the thinking underlying the securities exchange laws introduced in the 1920s, captured by the Berle and Means (1967) corporate model of the separation of ownership from management and dependence on the principle of external control through the ‘free market’. Through these laws, US corporations are subject to rules and regulation with regard to proper business and management conduct, as well as to the perennial threat of takeover when found to be underperforming. United States determined corporate governance centres on the struggle between the stringent enforcement of legislative requirement and codes of conduct protocols, and a management focus on financial performance as much induced by incentive-based compensation schemes. With numerous corporate scandals undermining the trust in management to pursue the best interests of shareholders through financial incentivisation, the trend today is for the greater monitoring of enforcement duties through the independent directors of the board (Blair, 2003; Veasey, 2003). Bearing in mind the notion of independence, it is common practice for US boards to be composed of none or a limited number, of ‘insider’, executive directors (i.e. ‘those directors also serving as the firm’s officers’; Johnson et al., 1996: 417). The majority of the members of the board are ’outside’ appointments, whether they are formally independent and/or are ‘gray’ (those with some current or previous association with the firm; Donaldson, 2000). Yet, despite the predominance of external directors, observers have noted a decline in board oversight, board intervention and a diminution of recognised voices of independent authority (Donaldson, 2000). As a result, the rationale of agency theory, namely that outside directors are able to more rigorously monitor management than inside members, is under serious scrutiny (Denis, 2001). Not that the US notion of having boards with the majority being independent directors is unique. Such configuration is wide spread across many countries, notably those supposedly well governed, such 320 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. as Switzerland, Germany and France (Ugeux, 2004). However, board composition is also vulnerable to endogeneity due to an interlocking membership of boards and the development of personal relationships between independent directors with each other and with management, both of which blur the lines of independence (Denis, 2001). Thus, when accounting for cultural considerations and the corporate scandals of the last decade and despite the influence of the United States across the globe, the overall rubric of role duality remains under attack. The volatility resulting from a ‘one person rule’ in terms of scandal, temptation and an idiosyncratic approach to strategy determination and execution has now become a clarion call for ‘truly’ instituting board independence. A cacophony of voices are urging to keep the two roles apart (Mintzberg, 2006). CEO pay As highlighted one historically, distinctly held assumption in the United States is that linking director performance to remuneration better ensures for effective governance (Berle and Means, 1967). Dana (2006) reported that policies that closely tie short- and long-term executive remuneration to shareholder return are indicative of strong and effective governance as remuneration aligns the interests of both of the parties of agent and principle. Furthermore, linking performance to pay is congruent with the recent demands for governance reform (Norburn et al., 2000). Norburn et al. (2000) have argued that high base executive remuneration with low performance-linked bonuses is counterproductive, as that can be used by the CEO to guarantee loyalty, or worse still, passivity from the directors, therefore hampering the monitoring role of the board. Overall, boards of directors have been criticised by the media/press and scholars for overpaying CEOs; that CEO pay is out of step with organisational performance reality and that boards are dominated by their CEO (Kaplan, 2008). For example, the average CEO pay according to the S&P 500 stood at $14.2 million in 2007 which some consider as too much in relation to the mediocre performance of firms (Walsh, 2008). In keeping with this line of argument, Jensen et al. (2004) purport that disproportionate increases in CEO pay are nothing new and have been taking place since the 1970s. In similar vein, Bebchuk and Fried (2005) show that substantial increases in CEO pay accelerated after 1995, but with no parallel increase in organisational performance. Yermack’s (2005) study of the severance agreements of 179 instances of CEO turnover in Fortune 500 companies reported a CEO/Chairman Role Duality Desire 321 mean separation payment of $5.4 million. (compared to average pay of $8.1 million). Also research shows that US executive pay for the top managerial positions has been considerably higher than that of their counterparts abroad (Bogle, 2008). In 2005, the CEOs of the 1,000 largest public firms (ranked by sales) in the United States took home $9.025 billion, approximately equivalent to Bolivia’s GDP ($9.71 billion) and on average 7% of the firm’s total sales (Walsh, 2008). The fact that from 2003 to 2005, CEO salaries and bonuses increased by 35% in the UK and only 14% in the United States (White and Patrick, 2007),illustrates that US pay started from a higher base and that the desire for extensive CEO remuneration is spreading across the Anglo-American economies. Bogle (2008: 25) concluded that ‘CEO compensation is seriously out of line, and too often has provided excessive and unreliable lottery-type rewards based on evanescent stock prices rather than durable intrinsic corporate value.’ However, despite public disgust, executive pay has continued to rise, reaching a peak within the last decade (The Guardian, 2010). The FTSE 100 companies’ top executives pay rose by more than 160% between 2000 and 2010. Britain’s bosses pay rose by 55% between 2009 and 2010 and only registered a 1.5% drop among the FTSE 100 Top Chief Executive Officers during the recession peak between June 2008 and 2009 (The Guardian, 2010). To date, pay for the directors of the UK’s top FTSE 100 businesses rose 50% over the past year (2011) (BBC News, 2011), whilst in the United States, the ‘CEOs’ 2010 median pay jumped 27% in 2009, one of the largest increases in recent history’ (US Today, 2011: 1). The US manifestation of Anglo-American corporate governance has afforded CEOs of large corporations’ inordinate power and wealth. The study Relatively few have explored the relationship between boardroom dynamics and emergent corporate behaviour (Forbes and Milliken, 1999; McNulty and Pettigrew, 1999; Oliver, 2000; Ibrahim et al., 2003). As Kahl (1957: 10) poignantly noted, ‘those who sit amongst the mighty do not invite sociologist to watch them take the decisions about how to control the behaviour of others’. Zald (1969: 98) noted that boards of directors are hard to study as they, ‘often conduct their business in secret, their members are busy people; the processes themselves are sometimes most effectively described by novelist’s’. Others (Pahl and Winkler, 1974; Norburn, 1989) also report practical difficulties in becoming close to the top management of large organisations. In effect, 322 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. access difficulties have and continue to remain a source of constraint in examining boardroom dynamics effects on corporate performance and governance thinking and practice. This is especially the case at a time of business scandal and fallen business heroes, where the aim of this study is to better understand how the combined functions of the CEO and chairman of the board impacts on the independence of board, the governance of the corporation and the nature of CEO remuneration. Our aim in this study was to explore the views held by dual-role occupants of role duality and its impact on board independence, the governance of the corporation and the nature of CEO remuneration. In doing so, we attempted to understand how dual-role occupants perceive their role within the board and to appreciate their sentiments for or against role duality within US listed companies. Due to the latent difficulties in reaching ‘difficult-to access’ populations such as elites who by nature are few in number and where high levels of trust are required to initiate contact (Rhodes et al., 2004), we chose a qualitative approach through purposeful sampling, relying on substantial trust as the mechanism to secure interviews. We conducted confidential and guided interviews of 60 minutes in length with 12 US CEOs during a two-year period (Bryman and Stephens, 1996; Conger, 1998). The themes pursued in interview were a capture of the critical concerns facing US CEOs with special reference to their experience of holding and balancing the dual roles of CEO and chairman of the board (Zald, 1969; Zahra and Pearce, 1989; Leighton and Thain, 1997). A list of organisations with combined chairman and CEO roles was compiled through a database of organisations with whom the authors of this chapter were already familiar. From the 30 organisations approached, 12 US-based CEO/chairmen agreed to participate in this exploratory study. Although it took 24 months to collect data, considerable time spent gaining agreement for interview with the participants. The greatest challenge was that of matching diary dates and balancing of workloads in order to squeeze into busy schedules. On reflection we consider that the data was collected reasonably fast. While there are no specifically defined rules for sample size in qualitative research (Baum, 2000; Patton, 2001), this study followed the well-established argument that qualitative investigation relies on small sample sizes with the aim of scrutinising the topic of inquiry in depth and detail (Miles and Huberman, 1994; Patton, 2001). The 12 top executive that participated in our study were drawn from the services ‘supersector’ (North American Industry Classification System, NAICS) of which six of the participants worked in the finance and insurance CEO/Chairman Role Duality Desire 323 sectors and six within professional and business services. Eleven of the participants who agreed to be interviewed were male and one female. Eight of the participants were experienced CEO-chairman who had for the last 5 to 15 years held dual roles in two or more companies. Four of our participants were first time CEO-chairman but with considerable executive line experience. In order to avoid the danger of prescriptive interview with a list of questions ‘written in stone’ (Thomas, 1993: 40), we, the authors, pursued guided discussion. Guided conversation facilitates understanding of the complex phenomena under scrutiny, in this case, the mindset of the particular participants towards role duality, without limiting the field of inquiry (Fontana and Frey, 1994). Hence, we drew on ‘grand tour questions’ (Spradley, 1979), offering the respondents the opportunity to answer in their way with content and experience relevant to them, not the inquirer. The participants were asked a series of open-ended questions such as ‘How do you work with your board? What have been some of your challenges with your board?’; in this way ensuring for commonality across interviews whilst encouraging the participants to expand on points they viewed as important. The interviews lasted on average 60 minutes and were conducted face-to-face. Most of the interviews were hand recorded with only a few tape-recorded, as that was the desire of the participants. Most of the study participants expressed discomfort at being taped verbatim. However, we were prepared for note taking as earlier experience surfaced that US participants expressed discomfort at being recorded, from the perspective of possible liability at some future date. We are certain that if our participants had not known us from previous engagements they would not have granted us an interview. Even they indicated that our pervious interaction was the reason access was allowed based on their trust of us. All interviews were then transcribed in order to capture the meanings in detail and so facilitate easier data manipulation. The analysis of empirical material followed a cyclical process in which ‘data-text translation, coding, and conceptualising occurred at the same time, albeit at different rates of progresses’ (Lindlof, 1995: 215). The preliminary reading of each script was followed by a data reduction step analysis, whereby the data was coded into manageable categories (Marshall and Rossman, 1989). We used a cross-case process of analysis, which grouped together responses from different interviewees (Patton, 2001). Through successive cycles of coding four categories emerged, the nature of board director talent, the criticality of leadership at the level of CEO and the importance of trust (rather than independence) at 324 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. the CEO level and CEO remuneration. Interestingly, discussion began with an examination of the CEO/chairman role duality but in all cases migrated to the four above mentioned findings. Study findings Talent The study participants considered that high-performing managers appointed to the role of CEO should hold requisite expertise and experience of particularly industries, or geographic area, and preferably should already have been a CEO. While some have argued that board directors should possess due diligence abilities, have board experience and display personal qualities such as strong personal values and relationship skills to ensure for effective governance (Taylor, 2000), the study participants more emphasised the importance of displaying a granular understanding of the leadership challenges facing the CEO. In this sense, the study participants most favoured external director on the board is the CEO of another company on the basis that only such a person can deeply understand the challenges facing the CEO/chairman. Any interference (perceived or otherwise) or curtailment of the CEO’s leadership reach was viewed as preventing the CEO from doing his or her job in a fast changing and ‘over competitive market’. In support of this argument, Nadler (2004) has emphasised the importance of top managers holding the right mindset. Nadler (2004) argues that corporate governance reforms unduly emphasise paying attention to several narrow aspects of board composition driven by Sarbanes-Oxley prescription in order to have director independence, and all that hides the real issue, which is ‘performance competence’. By the time you reach a board position you have all the skills and competencies you will ever need. More importantly, you need the right mindset for a particular board. It’s a quality of mind that that you need in the boardroom and that, I think, is the toughest quality to find … Yes, that is the reason I am looking for a current or former CEO to join my board. Someone who knows what it means to be a leader. (Participant 3) You want on your board a director who is a current or a former CEO. … Why is a sitting CEO the most sought after board candidate? CEO/Chairman Role Duality Desire 325 – Because he understands what it means to be a CEO and because you can assess the performance of his company by the stock price, companies’ reputation and the attitudes of its customers and employees. … The market will tell you all that you need to know about him. (Participant 10) OK, the selection process must be made on the basis of the nominee’s competencies and character and particularly on his moral and spiritual capacity. In this place, personal integrity is the single most important factor for selecting a CEO. How a CEO perceives and manages his privileged leadership position reveals much about his character. Evaluating the CEO’s character is most difficult. You must go by his reputation and trust your network. (Participant, 7) Further discourse revealed the importance of highlighting the skill areas that are lacking on the board and how these might be met by new members. Equally the study participants raised the question of how a diverse group of directors could enhance the company’s performance and the challenges of leveraging diversity to positive effect. Yet overall, emphasis was given to appointing a director who was a former or current CEO. The individual’s and company’s reputation was considered as counting for a great deal. Further, the character and values of the individual was given emphasis but so was the opinion held by the relevant networks of the individual, particularly if members of the network held close friendship ties with the CEO in question. Drawing on such opinions better guaranteed insight into the candidate’s character. Criticality of leadership All participants acknowledged that the pace of change in the corporate world has accelerated dramatically, with the forecast that this pace will increase. Equally acknowledged was that the firms’ well-being will increasingly depend on strong leadership particularly with the shift to emerging new and alternative technologies. You need all the power you can marshal in order to deliver results. Remember, no one is irreplaceable. If the results are not being delivered, or even if they are, the pressure to continuously improve performance is enormous. (Participant 11) 326 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. The buck stops with you. You are the CEO and you need everything it takes to get results. Play differently and you will not be sitting in this chair! (Participant 5) This is the United States of America, and if you want to be successful here, you must first understand fundamentals, our laws and market forces. Yes, you may say that we are a litigious bunch, but we are also very entrepreneurial. … To run a successful board you need to observe two principles, have a single leadership role of CEO/Chairman and have the confidence of the board of external directors. The rest is up to your abilities. You are the rain maker. (Participant 2) Whether the company is facing a financial squeeze, or an adverse economy, or experiencing rapid growth or being dragged screaming and kicking through change, you need a strong leader. The combined CEO and Chairman role provides that structure and if you have a talented person in that role, then both management and shareholders are on a winning side. The CEO/Chairman will move himself and their firm ahead of the pack, and the marketplace will reward these firms. There is no better way to achieve sustainable competitive advantage than having a strong CEO/Chairman. (Participant 9) The study participants narrated a sense of pride about the importance of their dual leadership role. In contrast to the positive comments of the study participants, Lorsch and Graff (1996) positioned dual leadership structures as resulting in the incumbent CEO/chairman inducing negative effects such as dominating meetings and controlling the agenda and the flow of information. In support, Hayward and Hambrick (1997: 106) noted the ‘exaggerated sense of pride or self confidence’ is common feature of CEOs. The irony is that on points of detail the study participants concurred, but from a positive perspective. Dominating ‘the agenda’ and controlling information flows was recognised by the study incumbents as necessary levers for achieving positive results. The participants expressed the view that the board and the CEO need to have a clear understanding of the markets, a clear view of the competitive advantage of the firm and clear understanding of the leadership that differentiates the firm from its competitors. CEO/Chairman Role Duality Desire 327 To do well, take charge of the board and the executive team. Meetings are where this is done. (Participant 7) The phenomenon that certain commentators have highlighted of CEO arrogance and the unwillingness of the CEO/chairman to obtain the approval of the board for certain strategic actions, or to follow established procedures (Lorsch and Graff, 1996), were dismissed by most of the study participants. The interviewees considered this to be an incorrect perception held by others who do not understand the nature of the CEO leadership role, or in the small minority of cases as the exceptional and idiosyncratic behaviour of just certain CEOs. The separation of the CEO from the chairman role was strongly resisted on the basis that that added new risk to strategic thinking and action. The greatest fear expressed by the study participants was of the possible changes that could be made in Congress, or in the Department of Justice and other enforcement agencies. To separate out the CEO from the Chairman role is unwelcome. Control of the firm is critical. I know so much depends on the values and nature of the person in charge, but that still is the case if you have a CEO and Chairman as separate positions. (Participant 12) In fact, the participants perceived role duality as an enabling feature: Yes, obviously it helps me in terms of the management of the … (name of organisation) and obviously it helps me in board meetings and how certain decisions are made because I have full control of things I think that that helps. (Participant 11) None of our participants perceived conflicts of interest through occupying dual roles. The majority of participants were explicit that they would not have joined the company had the CEO and chairman roles been separate. There is no conflict. No not really, I have to show some social etiquette and board room etiquette and business etiquette in terms of how I bring things to board. Having a separate Chairman would 328 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. prevent me from doing that. You’ve got to do things in the right way and you need that freedom to do it. (Participant 3) Further the participants clearly emphasised the sort of board/corporation they would wish to join. I wouldn’t ever choose to be a director of a company where the CEO is not the Chairman. I just think those are the types of companies that I would not want to be a part of. I think that I want to run company that I feel am interested in, where I like the business and where I think I can add value. Most importantly, I have to feel I add value. I don’t think I can add value to a company where my role is constrained. (Participant 7) Other studies have equally captured this point of view concerning the competitive culture of the United States and the incessant drive for market leadership (Krishnan and Visvanathan, 2008). However, these studies also highlight that in doing so less regard is given to risk management and reliable forms of financial reporting (Krishnan and Visvanathan, 2008: 36–47). Trust rather than Independence Although scholars have argued that independence is critical for ensuring effective governance (Shleifer and Vishny, 1997; Archambeault, 2000; Charu, 2005; Dalton and Dalton, 2005) on the basis that outside directors be rigorous in monitoring the CEO and the management (Denis, 2001), the study participants expressed a strong preference for trust rather than independence. The expressed reason for this view was the need to work with board directors who understand the nature of the challenges the CEO/chairman faces in achieving the objectives set, rather than having board members who are actively engaged in strategy formulation, which implicitly was considered as interference. My board operates on the basis of complete confidentiality. I am the CEO-Chairman-President of this company and if, I have a problem with my board, I can just deal with it. This is a tough market. There is no room for nice stuff. We need to be focused on results. … I have people that I can trust. Trust is very important in the board. There is always a danger of giving away competitive advantage or disclosing CEO/Chairman Role Duality Desire 329 premature or misleading information that can adversely effect investors’ decisions. All our deliberations are conducted behind closed doors in complete confidentiality. (Participant 1) If the board is to work with you and act as your primary advisor, then you need people who know you well and understand you and your business. That may be through business, the golf-course or personal ties. They also need to be trusted and have the lustre of a well-known name. (Participant 4) All my directors have my trust. I also give them all that they need to exercise their independence; nearly all of our decisions are ratified through unanimous vote and reported via the lead independent director. (Participant 6) I would rather have on my board another CEO who knows what it takes to run a company rather than a retailer or a lawyer or banker. These talents we already have and we can also get them from outside. (Participant 12) Probing further into why another CEO is so important to have as an external director on the board, Participant 9 explained, ‘if you know what it means to lead the company, you do not interfere by asking stupid question. The CEO as board director on my board will know that what I am proposing is the best way for the firm’. The point of trust over ‘seeming interference’ was emphasised. Put it this way, if there was a decision that had a bit of controversy then I don’t want, to get 6 votes for and 4 votes neigh and the motion passes. I don’t think I want that. I want total support from my board. (Participant 1) The respondents again emphasised that boards perform a better monitoring role if their directors hold or have held top managerial positions and understand, ‘what it means to run the company’ (Participant 2). Interestingly, certain of the study participants such as participant 4 330 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. viewed the function of monitoring as synonymous with that of advice. This finding is in line with other studies that report that, ‘American CEOs serving on those boards because the dominant model here is a supportive board. The function of a board member in the U.S. is basically to counsel and support the CEO’ (Jensen in Walkling, 2008: 139). As noted by Monks and Minow (2008: 379) ‘in America a board does pretty much what the CEO wants it to do’, which in turn leads to situation where, ‘even senior directors can get shut out of a debate when “airtime” is constricted in tightly choreographed board meetings’ (Finkelstein and Mooney, 2003: 111). Research has highlighted that best-in-class boards are much more than a roster of prominent names and that effective boards are wellbalanced bodies that harness the diverse experiences, skills and intellects of their directors to pursue the strategic objectives of the company they serve (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2008). In contrast, the participants of this study placed greater emphasis on CEO expertise and trust in order to realise outstanding company performance. Few would dispute the Pearce and Zahra (1991: 135) comment that powerful boards are the ‘brain and soul of the organization, as well as the guardians of shareholder interests’, and, ‘powerful boards’ are considered necessary for ‘organizational effectiveness’ (Pearce and Zahra, 1991: 136) as board directors strengthen the links between the organisation and its environment by providing useful business contacts (Pettigrew, 1992; Meyer, 2000). However, the point of contradiction is that the study participants described such boards as, ‘being more progressive and more encouraging and supportive of CEO efforts’ (Pearce and Zahra, 1991: 136), as long as the trust between the CEO and the board directors resulted in a supportive relationship and not one of being challenged. Supporting the study participants viewpoint, Salanicik and Pfeffer (1977) posit that power reflects the capacity of the directors and the CEO/chairman to bring about the outcomes they desire through formal and informal means. CEO remuneration The cost of not recruiting the best CEO available for the company was considered as outweighing paying any market price for the highperforming CEO. The punitive costs of hiring the wrong person was presented as inducing greater risk than overpaying the ‘effective CEO’. The overwhelming view to emerge from this study was that success in the marketplace and having satisfied investors and shareholders justified CEO remuneration levels. The consistent comment from the study CEO/Chairman Role Duality Desire 331 participants was that boards need to have a clear understanding of the range of leadership talent in the marketplace and be prepared to pay market price for the best talent they can attract. It is sort of taken for granted. They all knew my background, my knowledge of the business and my ability. That is the reason I got the job … Yes I come with a certain price tag, but that is my market value. Think, what is the cost of not recruiting the best CEO available for your company? (Participant 4) Of course American CEOs make much more money than the average American worker. And yes, the growth and magnitude of CEO pay is newsworthy and subject to Congressional inquiry, but so is the work the CEO does. These are tough times and you need a lot of talent and stamina to manage risks, seize opportunities and satisfy shareholders. (Participant 12) Pay in the US is market-based. For example, if you have a poor performing firm and you can find someone to make it perform well for only $20 million per year, and lead that firm to generate a return on assets of 20–25% in this labor market, well that is a bargain. (Participant 7) In my view, CEOs are properly and appropriately paid in most US top firms. If you do not want a risk that that the firm will slip into default or bankruptcy, then you have to be prepared to pay market price for a talented CEO. (Participant 10) The sentiments expressed in interview are supported in the academic literature. Kaplan (2008: 17) has argued that ‘increasingly difficult and less pleasant CEOs may not be overpaid but in fact, may be underpaid’. Whilst, Kaplan (2008) questioned the wisdom of calling for the increased regulation of CEO pay through the US government’s ‘Say on Pay’ bill, Monk (in Walkling, 2008: 145), on the other hand, has suggested that corporations in their striving for profit ‘at any price’ waste considerable resources in terms of unnecessary transactional costs. This latter perspective was firmly rejected by this group of study participants. 332 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. There is absolutely no need for more regulation. There are very formal structures in place, the formal remuneration committee, audit committee, a formal agenda, and the agenda is read with a sense of formality and board members have their say. (Participant 1) The participants did not acknowledge the contradiction that may arise as a result of role duality. Participant 1, for example, expressed the need for full support from the board but did not feel any need for regulating CEO’s remuneration. Similarly, participant 7 expressed that ‘you have in a remuneration structure to try and ensure that you’ve got fairness, that’s fairness to the individual and fairness to the firm which show concern for the individual in the first place and the organisation second. This is typical of the American individualistic culture’. This view is in line with Asma’s (1996) conclusion that American corporations place greater emphasis on individual based reward systems rather than group rewards. Bebchuk and Fried’s (2005: 13) review of reports of compensation committees in large companies reveals that a large majority use ‘peer groups to determine pay and set compensation at or above the 50th percentile of the peer group’. They conclude that ‘such ratcheting is consistent with a picture of boards that do not seek to get the best deal for their shareholders, but are happy to go along with whatever can be justified as consistent with prevailing practices’ (Bebchuk and Fried, 2005:13). Conclusion The Anglo-American governance debate has given considerable attention to the ‘responsibility and accountability of corporate managers’ (Becht, 1997: 10). The reason for this is the long-standing argument that investors have a keen interest to focus on financial accountability, particularly on the actions of one person, that of the CEO who is legally recognised as being accountable for the affairs of the company. Both the literature and these study participants views confirm that US governance concerns ultimately home in on the conduct of the CEO. Such a perspective results from holding dear broader considerations such as investor safeguards and enhancing the wealth creation processes on behalf of the nation. It is also considered that both social and political structures are highly influential in terms of corporate governance thinking and application. In this sense, the supreme office of President is replicated in the US corporate structure, but without the CEO/Chairman Role Duality Desire 333 Congressional checks and balances in place. Since 1787 the President according to the US Constitution can use his or her executive powers to issues executive orders (i.e. rules and regulation that do not require Congressional approval), to veto proposed bills, but can only return to Congress a veto message offering suggested changes to proposed legislations and make nominations to the judicial branch of government but which require Senate confirmation. The dual CEO/chairman (often president) however chooses his or her executives, chooses the board and chooses the external auditor. The dual role of CEO/chairman allows for greater powers than Madison had envisaged. Despite this, the notion of leadership is deep in the American culture. National cultural values arguably infiltrate corporate structure, governance practice and corporate ways of working (Light, 2001: 191–203). It does seem that the phenomenon of the one man/woman in charge is deeply etched into the American psyche. Similar cultural influence is found in other governance regimes where the formative context of the nation then become the accepted norms, laws and governance practice of the firm (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2001). The question is raised as to whether the original Madisonian logic of ‘power is widely distributed [and] “ambition” is “made to check ambition” so there is less need to rely on “enlightened statesmen” and “higher motives”’ (Rabkin, 1987: 199) is now undermined. Certainly, the study participants desired supportive boards in order to ‘cheer them’ in their endeavours rather than question their activities let alone control their actions. Participant 4 so aptly captured this sentiment, ‘I need a board that is one hundred per cent behind me and can cheer me in my endeavours’. The danger is of having board composed of ‘business cheerleaders’. Not surprisingly, many voices have come to question the efficacy of reliance on the one person. The relationship between the top management and the board of directors, as well as between the board and shareholders in US firm, has historically been precarious (Kanter, 2002). Critics complain that all too often US boards operate with inaccurate/ deficient and late information provided to them by management, and despite such insights nothing is done to improve the situation (Kanter 2002). Moreover, US boards operate on the promise of power (not its delivery), which is evident in the leadership structure as well as the relationship between the board, management and shareholders (Pound, 1995). In fact, the emphasis placed by the study participants reported in this chapter on the necessity for continuing with the CEO/chairman duality and the expectation of having a ‘non interfering’ board, is testament to that. 334 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. We conclude that there is need for structural change in order to effectively reshape corporate governance practice in the United States. This is particularly so as separate studies emphasise that the role of chairman is increasingly important and requires significantly higher commitment than that and of other board directors (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2008). To just make the CEO/chairman relationship ‘work’ is a task of itself and then of course there are the relationships with the other directors, the organisation as well as attending to critical external relations (Kakabadse et al., 2010). Yet, whatever the evidence and logic for role separation, this study highlights the embedded nature of role duality in the US corporate mind. The antipathy to the splitting out of the roles of CEO and chairman runs deep: Whatever happens, let the CEO run the company and by all means censure that person if they do not do that well. But at least give them a chance to do that! In order to do that, in today’s market, the CEO and Chairman positions need to be combined. The managers and the board need a strong binding relationship. (Participant 9) Our study reveals that many CEO’s ‘taken for granted’ assumptions expressed as a rational view of the legitimacy of their role needs to be further explored and tested. Although scholars such as Proimos (2005) argue that in order to ensure the effectiveness of corporate governance principles, these principles must become requirements that are prudently monitored by law, we conclude from our exploratory study that the United States is country with a rule-based corporate governance system where rules are in abundance, yet these rules have not cured the ‘boom and bust’ culture of crisis prone American corporations (Perrow, 1984; Pauchant and Mitroff, 1992; La Porte, 1996). On 2 November 2011, several dozen students walked out of an introductory microeconomics course at Harvard University taught by Professor N. Gregory Mankiw, a former economic adviser to President George W. Bush and current advisor to Republican Presidential candidate in the 2012 presidential elections, Mitt Romney. The student walk-out was an expression of discontent over the bias inherent in the introductory economics course, stating that ‘we are walking out today to join a Boston-wide march protesting the corporatization of higher education as part of the global Occupy movement. Since the biased nature of Economics 10 contributes to and symbolises the increasing CEO/Chairman Role Duality Desire 335 economic inequality in America, we are walking out of your class today both to protest your inadequate discussion of basic economic theory and to lend our support to a movement that is changing American discourse on economic injustice’ (Concerned Students of Economics 10, 2011: 1). It will probably not take long for further questioning of deeply embedded American values, such as the ‘hero leader’ and ‘winner takes it all’ to take place. Once that happens the leadership of and the structural platform of the American corporation will come under penetrating and forceful scrutiny. References Adams, R.B. and Ferreira, D. (2007) ‘A theory of friendly boards’, Journal of Finance, 62(1): 217–250. Aguilera, R.V. (2005) ‘Corporate governance and director accountability: an institutional comparative perspective’, British Journal of Management, 16(1): 1–15. Alderfer, C.P. (1986) ‘The invisible director on corporate boards’, Harvard Business Review, 64(1): 38–52. Archambeault, D.S. (2000) The relation between corporate governance strength and fraudulent financial reporting, Unpublished Ph.D. thesis, University of Alabama, Alabama. Arlen, J. and Talley, E. (2003) ‘Unregulable defenses and the perils of shareholder choice’, University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 152: 577–581. Asma, A. (1996). Going Glocal: Cultural Dimensions in Malaysian Management, Malaysian Institute of Management (MIM), Kuala Lumpur, Malaysia. Bainbridge, S.M. (2002) ‘Dead Hand and No Hand Pills: Precommitment Strategies in Corporate Law’, Law and Economics Research Paper No. 02-02, UCLA School of Law. Baliga, B.R. Moyer, C.R. and Rao, R.P. (1996) ‘CEO duality and firm performance: What’s the fuss?’, Strategic Management Journal, 17: 41–53. Baum, F. (2000) The New Public Health, Oxford University Press, Oxford. BBC News (2011) ‘Directors’ pay rose 50% in past year, says IDS report’, 28 October, http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/business-15487866 (Accessed: 25 January 2012). Bebchuk, L.A. and Fried, J.M. (2005). ‘Pay without performance: overview of the issues’, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 17(4), 8–23. Becht, M. (1997) Strong Blockholders, Beak Owners and the Need for European Mandatory Disclosure, European Commission, Brussels. Ben-Atar, D. and Oberg, B.B. (1998) ‘Introduction: the paradoxical legacy of the federalists’ in Ben-Atar, D. and Oberg, B.B. (eds.) Federalists Reconsidered, University of Virginia Press, Charlottesville, VA, pp. 7–9. Berle, A. and Means, G. (1967) The Modern Corporation and Private Property, Harcourt Brace World, San Diego. Blair, M.M. (2003) ‘Reforming Corporate Governance: What History Can teach US’, Working Paper No. 4855663, University of Washington Law Center, 28 August. 336 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. Bogle, J.C. (2008) ‘Reflections on CEO compensation’, Academy of Management Perspective, 22(2): 21–25. Boyd, B. K. (1995) ‘CEO duality and firm performance: a contingency model’, Strategic Management Journal, 16(4): 301–312. Brickley, J.A., Coles, J.L. and Terry, R.L. (1994) ‘Independent NEDs and the adoption of poison pills’, Journal of Financial Economics, 35: 371–390. Brickley, J.A., Coles, J.L. and Jarrell, G. (1997) Leadership structure: separating the CEO and chairman of the board, Journal of Corporate Finance, 3: 189–220. Bryman, A. and Stephens, M. (1996) ‘The importance of context: qualitative research and the study of leadership’, Leadership Quarterly, 7(3): 353–371. Cadbury, A. (1992) Report of the Committee on the Financial Aspects of Corporate Governance, Cadbury and Financial Reporting Council, Gee & Company, London. Carver, J., (1990) Boards that Make a Difference, Jossey-Bass, San Francisco, CA. Charu, G. R. (2005) ‘Determinants of board size and composition: a theory of corporate boards’, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 40(2): 283– 306. Chen, C-W., Lin, J.B. and Yi, B. (2008) ‘CEO duality and firm performance: an endogenous issue’, Corporate Ownership and Control, 6(1): 58–65. Cheng, E.C.M. and Courtenay S.M. (2006) ‘Board composition, regulatory regime and voluntary disclosure’, The International Journal of Accounting, 41(3): 262–289. Coates, J.C. IV (2001) ‘Explaining variation in takeover defenses: blame the lawyers’, California Law Review, 89: 1329–1333. Concerned Students of Economics 10 (2011) ‘Open letter to Greg Mankiw’, Harvard Political Review, http://hpronline.org/harvard/an-open-letter-to-gregmankiw/ (Accessed: 20 January 2012). Conger, J. (1998) ‘Qualitative research as the corner-stone methodology for understanding leadership’, Leadership Quarterly, 9(1): 107–122. Dahya, J. and Travlos, N.G. (2000) ‘Does the one man show pay? Theory and evidence on the dual CEO revisited’, European Financial Management, 6(1): 85–98. Dalton, D. and Dalton, C. (2005) ‘Boards of directors: utilizing empirical evidence in developing practical prescriptions’, British Journal of Management, 16(s1): S91–S97. Dalton, D., Daily, C., Ellstrand, A. and Johnson, J. (1998) ‘Meta-analytic reviews of board composition, leadership structure and financial performance’, Strategic Management Journal, 19(3): 269–290. Dalton, D.R., Hitt, M.A., Certo, S.T. and Dalton, C.M. (2007) ‘The fundamental agency problem and its mitigation: independence, equity, and the market for corporate control’ in Brief, A. and Walsh, J. (eds.), Academy of Management Annals (Volume 3), Routledge, London, , pp. 1–64. Dana, R. H. (2006) ‘Executive compensation and corporate governance’, Internal Auditing, 21(2): 36–38. Denis, D. (2001) ‘Twenty-five years of corporate governance research … and counting’, Review of Financial Economics, 10(3): 191–213. Donaldson, L. (2000) ‘Organizational portfolio theory: performance-driven organizational change’, Contemporary Economic Policy, 18(4): 386–396. CEO/Chairman Role Duality Desire 337 Donaldson, L. and Davis, J. (1991) ‘Stewardship theory or agency theory: CEO governance and shareholder returns’, Australian Journal of Management, 16: 49–64. Dooley, M.P. (1992) ‘Two models of corporate governance’, Business Lawyer, 47: 461–465. Easterbrook, F.H. and Fischel, D.R. (1981) ‘The proper role of a target’s management in responding to a tender offer’, Harvard Law Review, 94: 1161–1164. Faleye, O. (2007) ‘Does one hat fit all? The case of corporate leadership structure’, Journal of Management & Governance, 11: 239–259. Fama, E.F. and Jensen, M.C. (1983) ‘Separation of ownership and control’, Journal of Law and Economics, 26(2): 301–325. Felton, R.F. (2004) ‘What Directors and Investors Want from Governance Reform: A Survey of Directors and Institutional Investors Shows that Board Governance Has A Long Way to Go’, The McKinsey Quarterly, Vol. 2. Finkelstein, S. and Mooney, A.C. (2003). ‘Not the usual suspects: how to use board process to make boards better’, Academy of Management Executive, 17(2): 101–113. Finkelstein, S. and D’Aveni, R. A., (1994) ‘CEO duality as a double-edged sword: How boards of directors balance entrenchment avoidance and unity of command’, Academy of Management Journal, 37(5): 1079–1108. Finkelstein, S. and Hambrick, D.C. (1996). Strategic Leadership: Top Executives and Their Effects on Organizations, West Publishing Company, Minneapolis/ St. Paul, MN. Fontana, A. and Frey, J.S. (1994) ‘Interviewing: the art of science’, in Denzin, N.K. and Lincoln, Y.S. (Eds), Handbook of Qualitative Research, Sage, Thousand Oaks, CA, pp. 361–76. Forbes, D.P. and Milliken, F.J. (1999) ‘Cognition and corporate governance: understanding boards of directors as strategic decision-making groups’, Academy of Management Review, 24: 489–504. Hambrick, D.C. and Jackson, E.M. (2000) ‘Outside directors with a stake: the linchpin in improving governance’. California Management Review, 42: 108– 127. Hayward, M., and Hambrick, D. (1997) ‘Explaining the premiums paid for large acquisitions: evidence of CEO hubris’, Administrative Science Quarterly, 42: 103–127. Hayward, M.L.A., Rindova, V. and Pollock, T. (2004) ‘Believing one’s own press: the causes and consequences of CEO celebrity’, Strategic Management Journal, 25: 637–653. Higginbottom, G.M.A. (2004) ‘Sampling issues in qualitative research’, Nurse Researcher, 12(1): 7–20. Higgs, D. (2003). Review of the role and effectiveness of non-executive directors, http://www.berr.gov.uk/files/file23012.pdf (accessed 20 June 2010). Ibrahim, N.A., Howard, D.P. and Angelidis, J.P. (2003) ‘Board members in the service industry: An empirical examination of the relationship between corporate social responsibility orientation and directorial type’, Journal of Business Ethics, 47: 393–401. Jensen, M.C. (1993) ‘The modern industrial revolution, exit, and the failure of internal control systems’. The Journal of Finance 48: 831–880. 338 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. Jensen, M.C. and Meckling, W.H., (1976) ‘Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency and ownership structure’, Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4): 305–360. Jensen, M.C., Murphy, K.J. and Wruck, E.G. (2004)’Remuneration: where we’ve been, how we got here, what are the problems, and how to fix them’, Working Paper, Harvard Business School, NOM Working paper 04-28. Jensen, M.C. and Meckling, W. (1976) ‘Theory of the firm: managerial behaviour, agency costs and ownership structure’, Journal of Financial Economics, 3: 305–360. Jensen, M.C. (1993) ‘Presidential address: the modern industrial revolution, exit, and the failure of internal control systems’, Journal of Finance, 48: 831–880. Johnson, J. L., Daily, C. M. and Ellstrand, A. E. (1996) ‘Boards of directors: a review and research agenda’, Journal of Management, 22(3): 409–438. Kahan, M. and Rock, E.B. (2003) ‘Precommitment and managerial incentives: corporate constitutionalism: antitakeover charter provisions as precommitment’, The University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 152: 473–490. Kahl, J. (1957) The American Class Structure, Reinhart, New York. Kakabadse, A. and Kakabadse, N. (2001) The Geopolitics of Governance, Palgrave Macmillan, Basingstoke. Kakabadse, A. and Kakabadse, N. (2007) ‘The return of the chairman’, Business Strategy Review, 8(4): 60–65. Kakabadse, A. and Kakabadse, N. (2008) Leading the Board: The Six Disciplines of World-Class Chairman, Palgrave, London. Kakabadse, A., Kakabadse, N. and Knyght, R. (2010) ‘The chemistry factor in the chairman/CEO relationship’, European Management Journal, 28(4): 285–296. Kanter, R.M. (2002) ‘Strategy as improvisational theater’, MIT Sloan Management Review, 43(2): 76–81. Kaplan, S. (2008)’ Are U.S. CEOs overpaid?’, Academy of Management Perspectives, 22(2): 5–20. Keasey, K., Short, H. and Wright, M. (eds.) (2005) Corporate Governance: Accountability, Enterprise and International Comparisons, Wiley, Chichester. Keay, A.R., (2006) ‘Enlightened shareholder value, the reform of the duties of company directors and the corporate objective’, Lloyd’s Maritime and Commercial Law Quarterly, 335–361. Kihlstrom, R. E. and Wachter, M.L. (2002) ‘Corporate policy and the coherence of Delaware Takeover Law’, University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 152: 723–726. Krishnan, G. and Visvanathan, G. (2008) ‘Was Arthur Anderson different? Further evidence on earnings management by clients of Arthur Anderson’, International Journal of Disclosure and Governance, 5(1): 36–47. La Porte, T.R. (1996) ‘High reliability organizations: unlikely, demanding and at risk’, Journal of Contingencies and Crisis Management, 4: 60–71. Leighton, D.S.R. and Thain, D.H. (1997) Making Boards Work: What Directors Must Do To Make Canadian Board Effective, McGraw-Hill Ryerson, Whitby, Canada. Levrau, A. and Van den Berghe, L. (2009) ‘Identifying key determinants of effective board directors’ in Kakabadse, A. and Kakabadse, N. (eds), Global Boards, Palgrave Macmillan, Basingstoke, pp. 9–44. CEO/Chairman Role Duality Desire 339 Light, A. N. (2001) ‘The mother of all path dependencies toward a cross-cultural theory of corporate governance systems’, Delaware Journal of Corporate Law, 26: 149–209. Lindlof, T.R. (1995) Qualitative Communication Research Methods, Sage, Thousand Oaks. CA. Lipton, L. (1979) ‘Takeover bids in the boardroom’, Business Lawyer, 35: 101–108. Lorsch, J. and Graff, S. (1996) ‘Corporate governance’, in Warner, M. (ed.), International Encyclopaedia of Business and Management (Vol. 1), Routledge, New York, pp. 772–782. Lorsch, J.W. and E. MacIver (1989) Pawns or Potentates: The Reality of America’s Corporate Boards. Harvard Business School Press, Boston, MA. Mallette, P. and Fowler, K.L. (1992) ‘Effects of board composition and stock ownership on the adoption of “poison pills”’, Academy of Management Journal 35: 1010–1035. Malmendier, U. and Tate, G. (2005) ‘Does overconfidence affect corporate investment? CEO overconfidence measures revisited’, European Financial Management, 11: 649–659. Marshall, C. and Rossman, G.B. (1989) Designing Qualitative Research, Sage, Thousand Oaks, CA. Martin, J.P. (1999) ‘When repression is democratic and constitutional: the federalist theory of Representation and the Sedition Act of 1798’, University of Chicago Law Review, 66(1): 117–182. McNulty, T. and Pettigrew, A. (1999) ‘Strategists on the board’, Organisational Studies, 20(1): 47–74. Meyer, H. (2000) ‘Boards take on the heavy lifting’, The Journal of Business Strategy, 21(4): 18–23. Meyers, M. (1967) The Jacksonian Persuasion: Politics and Belief, Stanford University Press, Stanford, CA. Miles, M.B. and Huberman, A.M. (1994) Data Analysis, Sage, Thousand Oaks, CA. Millstein, I. (1992) The Limits of Corporate Power: Existing Constraints on the Exercise of Corporate Discretion, Macmillan, New York. Mintzberg, H. (2006) ‘The Leadership Debate with Henry Mintzberg: Communityship is the Answer’, Financial Times, 23 October, http://www. ft.com/ (Accessed: 20 October 2009). Monks, R.A.G. and Minow, N. (2008) Corporate Governance, 4th edition, Wiley, Chichester. Murphy, K. (1998) ‘Executive compensation’, in Ashenfelter and Card (eds.), A Handbook of Labour Economics, North-Holland, Amsterdam. Nadler, D.A. (2004) ‘Building better boards’, Harvard Business Review, 82(5): 102–111. Norburn, D. (1989) ‘GoGo’s YoYo’s and Dodo’s’ company directors and industry performance’, Strategic Management Journal, 7(1): 101–117. Norburn, D., Boyd, B., Fox, M. and Muth, M. (2000) ‘International corporate governance reform’, European Business Journal, 12(3), 116–133. Oliver, R.W. (2000) ‘The board’s role: driver’s seat or rubber stamp?’, The Journal of Business Strategy, 21: 7–9. O’Sullivan, N. (2000) ‘The impact of board composition and ownership on audit quality: evidence from large UK companies’, British Accounting Review 32(4): 397–414. 340 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. Pahl, R.E. and Winkler, J.T. (1974) ‘The economic elite: theory and practice’, in Stanworth, P.J. and Giddens, A. (eds.), Elites and Power in British Society, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 102–122. Patton, M.Q. (2001) Qualitative Research and Evaluation Methods, 3rd edition, Sage, Newbury Park, CA. Pauchant, T.C. and Mitroff, I.I. (1992) Transforming the Crisis-Prone Organization: Preventing Individual, Organizational, and Environmental Tragedies, JosseyBass Publishers, San Francisco, CA. Pearce, J.A. and Zahra, S.A. (1991) ‘The relative power of CEO’s and board of directors: association with corporate performance’, Strategic Management Journal, 12: 135–153. Perrow, C. (1984) Normal Accidents, Basic Books, New York. Pettigrew, A. (1992) ‘On studying managerial elites’, Strategic Management Journal, 13: 163–182. Pi, L. and Timme, S.G. (1993) ‘Corporate control and bank efficiency’, Journal of Banking and Finance, 17: 515–530. Pound, J. (1995) ‘The promise of a governed corporation’, Harvard Business Review, 73(2), 89–99. Proimos, A. (2005) ‘Strengthening corporate governance regulations’, Journal of Investment Compliance, 6(4): 75–84. Rabkin, J. (2005) Law Without Nations? Why Constitutional Government Requires Sovereign States, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ. Rechner, P. and Dalton, D. (1999) ‘CEO duality and organizational performance: a longitudinal analysis’, Strategic Management Journal, 12(2): 155–160. Rhoades, D.L., Rechner, P.L. and Sundaramurthy, C., (2001) ‘A meta-analysis of board leadership structure and financial performance: are two heads better than one?’, Corporate Governance: An International Review, 9(4): 311–319. Rhoades, D.L. and Packel, A.K. (2010) Diversity on Corporate Boards: How Much Difference Does Difference Make? Rock Center for Corporate Governance, Stanford University. Rhodes, R. E., Courneya, K. S. and Jones, L. W. (2004) ‘Personality and social cognitive influences on exercise behaviour: adding the activity trait to the theory of planned behaviour’, Psychology of Sport and Exercise, 5: 243–54. Roe, M. J. (2003) Political Determinants of Corporate Governance, Oxford University Press, Oxford. Roll, R. (1986). ‘The hubris hypothesis of corporate takeovers’, Journal of Business, 59: 197–216. Salanicik, G.R. and Pfeffer, J. (1977) ‘Who gets power and how they hold on to it: Strategic contingency model of power’, Organisational Dynamics, 5(1): 3–21. Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. (1997) ‘A survey of corporate governance’, The Journal of Finance, 52(2): 737–783. Spradley, J. (1979) The Ethnographic Interview, Holt, Rinehart & Winston, New York. Taylor, D. (2000) ‘Facts, myths and monsters: understanding the principles of good governance’, The International Journal of Public Sector Management, 13(2/3): 108–125. The Economist (2009) ‘A chill in the boardroom’, 10 December, pp. 69–70. The Guardian (2010) FTSE 100 Bosses Criticised as Boardroom Pay Leaps by 55%, 29 October 2010, Available from: http://www.guardian.co.uk/business/2010/ oct/29/ftse-boardroom-pay-soars (Accessed: 25 January 2012). CEO/Chairman Role Duality Desire 341 Thomas, J. (1993) Doing Critical Ethnography, Sage, Newbury Park, CA. Tuggle, C.S., Sirmon, D.G., Reutzel, C.R. and Bierman, L. (2010) ‘Commanding board of director attention: investigating how organizational performance and CEO duality affect board members’ attention to monitoring’, Strategic Management Journal, 31(9): 946–968. Ugeux, G. (2004) ‘Towards global convergence in corporate governance: an assessment of the current situation’, International Journal of Disclosure and Governance, 1(4): 339–355. US Today (2011) ‘CEO pay soars while workers’ pay stalls’, 4 April, http://www.usatoday.com/money/companies/management/story/CEO-pay-2010/45634384/ (Accessed: 25 January 2012). Useem, M. (1984) The Inner Circle, Oxford University, New York. Useem. M. (1996) Investor Capitalism, Basic Books, New York. Useem, M. and Zelleke, Z. (2006) ‘Oversight and delegation in corporate governance: deciding what the board should decide’, Corporate Governance: An International Review, 14(1): 2–22. Veasey, E.N. (2003) ‘Musings on the dynamics of corporate governance issues, director liability concerns, corporate control transactions, ethics, and federalism’, University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 152: 1007–1008. Walkling, R. (2008) ‘U.S. corporate governance: accomplishments and failings a discussion with Michael Jensen and Robert Monks’, Journal of Applied Finance, 18(1): 133–158. Walsh, J.P. (2008) ‘CEO compensation and the responsibilities of the business scholar to society’, Academy of Management Perspectives, 22(2): 26–33. Wei Shen (2005) ‘Improve board effectiveness’, British Journal of Management, 16, S81–S898. Westphal J.D. and Khanna, P. (2003) ‘Keeping directors in line: social distancing as a control mechanism in the corporate elite’, Administrative Science Quarterly, 361–398. White, E., and Patrick, A. (2007) ‘Shareholders push for vote on executive pay’, Wall Street Journal, 26 February. Yermack, D. (2005). ‘Golden Handshakes: Separation Pay for Retired and Dismissed CEOs’, Working Paper, New York University. Zahra, S.A. and Pearce, J.A. (1989) ‘Boards and directors and corporate financial performance: a review and integrative model’, Journal of Management, 15(2): 291–334. Zald, M.N. (1969) ‘The power and functions of boards of directors: a theoretical synthesis’, American Journal of Sociology, 75(1): 97–111. 12 High-Performing Chairmen: The Older the Better Nada K. Kakabadse, Reeves Knyght and Andrew Kakabadse Introduction The field of leadership, both in terms of academic and practitioner contribution, has attracted substantial attention since the beginning of the 20th century. The debate has fluctuated between understanding what capabilities of leadership can transform the status quo versus the recognition that situations restrain leaders’ discretion and despite the qualities and skills of any one person only transactional outcomes are feasible (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 1999). Further, the study of leadership has not just focused on the upper echelons of the organisation but has also examined the leadership challenges of ensuring operational activities are undertaken in a manner that leverages that extra edge in order to better realise competitive advantage. Yet despite the popularity of the topic, leadership at board level (the ultimate upper echelon strata) has not been a major focus of study. This is surprising as the literature points to the antecedents and consequences of great and poor leadership according to organisational level/ position, degree of differentiation in function, geographic location and environmental and cultural and societal complexities (Zaccaro, 1998). In effect it is acknowledged that the performance demands on leaders vary considerably according to context, thus requiring the person to draw on a contrast of leadership capabilities. Yet, to have so omitted the pinnacle of accountability in the organisation draws into question the value of other studies. Having limited insight on how boards work suggests only transactional understanding of how the rest of the organisation functions. However, interest in board leadership is growing. Due to the multitude of scandals that have arisen over the last two decades and the 342 High-Performing Chairmen: The Older the Better 343 inordinate attention given to governance regulations and protocols, one particular role has recently come under scrutiny and that is the role of the chairman. Historically, the chairman has been the pivotal position of influence and authority (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2008). It was the chairman who was the guardian of financial contracts drafted for the purpose of trade. As early as 1250 AC, the Bazacle Milling Company (Société des Moulins du Bazacle, Toulouse, France) was underwritten by a group of local seigneurs (feudal tenants) who shared profits according to the number of shares they possessed. The guardian of such agreement was the chairman (NYSE Euronext, 2008). By 1654, the role of chairman meant the occupier of the chair of authority. Whether artisan or gentry, it was the person with ultimate signature rights concerning contractual documents. By 1730, the role of chairman has expanded to being the focal member of a corporate body chosen to preside over the meetings determining the performance and future of the enterprise. Historically, the chairman of the board was independent of management and additional to the contractual responsibilities of the firm. The chairman was the senior member of the board responsible for the hiring and firing of management. Yet, with the separation of the ownership and control of the company in the 1920s and 1930s in the United States, management became the driving force of the corporation and through their ever greater control of the corporation the CEO progressively assumed the role of chairman. In effect the board became less of a monitoring body and more of an advisory group to management (Berle and Means, 1932). Even now in the United States, it is the prevailing practice for the CEO and chairman of the board to be the same person. This has allowed US management to ‘handpick’ board members who essentially act as advisors rather than the scrutinisers of the corporation (Blair, 1995; Kristie, 2010). In other English speaking countries, and to a certain extent in Continental Europe, the roles of CEO and chairman were and continue to be separated and the board more monitors than mentors the management. The emergent dominance of the CEO, particularly in the United States, did not go unnoticed. The CEO was challenged. Ever greater managerial power ignited shareholder activism in the 1950s and the independent director movement of the 1970s. A further counter to the managerial domination of the corporation was championed by the Securities Exchange Commission (SEC) in stipulating that public companies establish audit committees composed of independent directors (Blair, 1995; Kristie, 2010). Yet, despite these developments, the question remains as to whether boards make a substantial contribution to firm performance, especially 344 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. as the CEO continues to capture the headlines (Nonaka and Takeuchi, 2011). The one individual popularly attributed with glorifying the CEO and consolidating executive influence over both the board and management was Lee Iacocca. Lido Anthony ‘Lee’ Iacocca accepted the job of President and Chief Operating Officer (COO) of the Chrysler Corporation in late 1978. He championed performance above all else by requesting a dollar-a-year salary, with the remainder of his remuneration in stock options and bonuses. By 1980 Iacocca earned $868,000 placing him 100th on the Forbes’ annual Best Paid CEOs list (Forbes, 2002). By 1986, his total compensation stood at $25.5 million as he exercised his stock options (Forbes, 2002: 1). However, with the rise of hostile takeover activity in the 1980s, the Delaware courts demanded board independence. By the early 1990s the issue of the independence of the board became a mainstream concern. The accounting scandals that lead to the enactment of the SarbanesOxley Act spawned further SEC requirements namely that the audit, compensation and nomination committees be instituted and these be composed entirely of independent directors. So, over time, and despite the dominance of the ‘hero CEO’, independent directors became the majority members of the board. Ironically, the notion of independence has not extended to the role of chairman, where still some 76% of US corporations have the CEO, chairman and president as one and the same person. With the financial services meltdown of 2008/2009, the role of the chairman has come to prominence. The rise of the influence of the chairman does not extend to a usurpation of the executive function, but rather a re-affirmation that in addition to the traditional requirement of the board to ‘govern’ (monitor the corporation through applying regulatory rigour), the board should also contribute to realising the company’s competitive advantage (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2008). Studies have shown that the involvement of the board in shaping strategy has been increasing. Overall, the greater and more focused the level of board involvement in the strategic decision process the better the strategic and operational outcomes (Nadler et al., 2006). Board contribution and purpose has been captured as shifting from that of control (agency perspective) to that of the board as a social phenomenon (social exchange perspective; Nicholson and Kiel, 2004; Kaplan and Norton, 2006). In effect, the board is tasked with drawing heavily on its intellectual capital in order to enhance the performance of the firm. Thus, in order to ensure the board’s effective functioning, the chairman is required to develop a clear and shared perspective with the other board High-Performing Chairmen: The Older the Better 345 directors of what the board is aiming to accomplish (Lorsch, 2005). In leading the board and coming to a clear understanding of the role of the board, effective chairmen, now more than ever, hold prolonged and sensitive discussions with board members (both executive and non-executive directors) concerning the value proposition underlying the firm and the role of the board in enhancing that value. In so doing, research shows that it is the chairman’s responsibility to clearly delineate the role and contribution of the board vis-a-vis the management (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2008). Thus, with the re-emergence of the chairman, evidence indicates that boards define their role anywhere from that of ‘watchdog’ to ‘helmsman’ (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2010). The traditional three board roles of monitoring, advising (including strategy) and accessing resources (Pfeffer and Selznick, 1978; Zahra and Pearce, 1989; Nicholson and Kiel, 2004) have expanded to include entrepreneurial leadership, shaping strategy, ensuring for capable human and financial resources to achieve objectives, promoting talent, reviewing management performance, determining the company’s values and standards and being satisfied over the integrity of financial information and the robustness of financial controls and risk management (IoD, 2007). With such a spread of tasks and responsibilities, one emergent but critical discipline required of chairmen is to clearly define the role and spread of tasks of the chair against those of the CEO in relation to the challenges facing the organisation (Kakabadse et al., 2010). Bearing in mind the cacophony of demands for better governance and the need for greater diligence from the board, this chapter explores an under-examined area of governance and leadership, namely the role, contribution and quality of performance required of the chairman. In order to be consistent with the literature, we have made the decision to retain the generic term chairman when referring to the occupant of the role irrespective of gender. This chapter first explores the literature scrutinising the chairman’s role and contribution. What follows is a detailed qualitative, exploratory analysis examining the characteristics of highperforming chairmen. The study results highlight that understanding board, organisational and environmental context is critical to appreciating the challenges facing the chairman. It is shown that each role of chairman is unique, and each chairman needs to find their own configuration through the myriad of concerns they face. Despite the fact that idiosyncrasy of approach to problem-solving predominates, one demographic in particular stands out and that is age. Analysis indicates that the older the chairman the more likely the individual will effectively find pathways through the contrasting perspectives of strategy, vision, direction 346 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. and purpose of the board and the organisation, and through the tensions that arise from discussions concerning the role and contribution of the board and its directors in the strategy determining process. The implications of these findings and recommendations for the performance improvement of the role of chairman concludes this chapter. Role of chairman In the UK’s self-regulatory model of governance, the power accorded to the chairman is that of ‘strong persuader’, whilst also being the first amongst equals. The UK Combined Code of Corporate Governance supporting principle holds that the chairman ‘should also facilitate the effective contribution of non-executive directors in particular and ensure constructive relations between executive and non-executive directors’ (FRC, 2008: A2). In being the one ultimately accountable for the health of the corporation, the role of the chairman has become increasingly demanding requiring ever greater teamwork for effectively dealing with the governance and issues of future direction of the corporation. Yet, as noted by Cadbury (2002), the chairman’s role in leading board discussion is routinely taken for granted, although it is this aspect that is recognised as most challenging and exceedingly important (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2008). The study emphasises that it is the chairmen’s ability to nurture dialogue and to deal with all issues on the agenda that unlocks the value that each director is capable of contributing (Lorsch, 2005). Failure to do so deprives the board from not only providing advantage to the functioning of the organisation, but also from instituting effective governance (Kakabadse et al., 2010). It is the chairman’s skill to hold sensitive discussion with board members in order to encourage directors to express their views and reach consensus. Only when a culture of open conversation and meaningful discussion is attained can the board determine its contribution to the company, particularly in terms of realising firm competitive advantage. It is no surprise therefore that certain scholars argue that the chairman’s role is considered as the most critical in the managerial hierarchy, particularly in terms of controlling the boardroom agenda, the nomination of non-executives and the appointment and dismissal of the CEO (Garratt, 1999; Roberts, 2002). Parker (1990: 36) describes the role of the chairman as ‘making tomorrow’s company out of today’s’, where through actively leading the board, the company can realise a sustainable, longterm strategic direction. Moreover, Parker (1990:42) emphasises that ‘the High-Performing Chairmen: The Older the Better 347 chairman should first ensure that the company’s culture is robust and adaptive, second enhance the motivation and morale of the people who work for the company and third that the chairman be capable of leading the company to effectively pursue acquisitions and equally defend it against other acquirers’. For Parker (1990) the chairman is the ultimate discretionary role, whereby each successful chairman is such by his or her appropriate reading of circumstances and acting accordingly. Kakabadse et al. (2006) concur and emphasis that ‘an outstanding chairman is able to comfortably raise submergent concerns to the realm of evident and workable dynamics’. Others agree and argue that in an increasingly politicised context where the firm’s purpose changes to reflect the shifting interests of the company, or its members, or various stakeholder coalitions, the primary role of the chairman is that of chief negotiator where (Haspeslagh et al., 2001: 89), ‘purpose and policies that drive corporate performance requires the subtle trading of the quid pro quads with the partisans in the enterprise…’ A brief summary of the literature capturing the role, purpose, contribution and skills of the chairman is provided (Table 12.1). The overview of the literature emphasises that chairmen need to exhibit a broad range of skills and capabilities necessary for effective performance. Although this reflects a requirement to perform in a broad range of contexts, the emergent theme is that the chairman should be accomplished in behavioural complexity and social intelligence, which mediate the translation of cognition into action in complex environments. According to Pratt (1998, 2000) board level work requires that directors are engaged in sense making, sense breaking (drawing on alternative senses) and sense giving, or direction setting, on behalf of the organisation as well as for a multiplicity of stakeholders. In so doing, directors generally and the chairman in particular have to be equally cognisant of the financial and moral consequences of their deliberations. However, many social exchange models obscure the importance of the leadership contribution of knitting together information acquisition, sense making, sense-breaking, sense giving, systematic social networking, boundary spanning, long-term strategic decision making and short-term operational follow through (Fleishman et al., 1991). The drawing together of such a broad range of facets emphasises the idiosyncratic nature of the chairman’s role. So much is dependent on interpretation of context and the ‘make up’ of each single role occupant. Such a rich and unpredictable combination shapes the nature of trust and the relationships that are formed and emotions that are displayed in the boardroom (House, 1998). House’s (1998) reflections on 348 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. Table 12.1 Chairman’s attributes for effective performance Author Study Performance characteristics Parker (1990) Interviews with 15 chairmen • Make tomorrow’s company out of today’s • Outward/forward looking. Stewart (1991) Periodic interviews over two years with 20 GMs and 29 chairmen in the National Health Service (NHS), UK • Interdependent, complimentary – partnership with CEO • Balancing activities amongst key figures. Cadbury (1995) Experiential practice • Leadership of the board • External face of the company (e.g. investors). Garratt (1999) Case studies • Boss of the board • Designee and chair of the process of the board’s meetings/activities • Inducts new board members • Develops competencies of board members • Develops the board. Kakabadse et al. (2001) 35 in depth, semistructured interviews and three focus group of 20 (i.e. 95 encounters) NEDs/ chairmen, CEOs – FTSE 100, UK • Maturity • Relational skills • High political and social competence • Meetings skills • Coaching capabilities • Managing boardroom dynamics. Roberts (2002) 35 interviews with chairmen, CEOs and NEDs, UK • No ambition for executive power • Complimentary to CEO (i.e. supporting role of executive) in: - Skills - Experience - Knowledge - Temperament - Business focus - Values • Chairing meetings (e.g. focusing, stimulating discussion, openness, trust) • Replacing CEO. Kakabadse and Kakabadse (2008) Over 500 interviews – international study • Six disciplines of chairman º Delineating boundaries º Sense making º Interrogating the argument º Influencing outcomes º Living the values of the company º Developing the board. (Continued) High-Performing Chairmen: The Older the Better Table 12.1 349 Continued Kakabadse et al. (2008) Questionnaires, 286 of FTSE 350, UK • Delineating roles of chair/CEO; board from management • Contribution to strategic decisionmaking • Encouraging of feedback • Leading the board • Board and executive succession • Qualities of leadership, wisdom, sensitivity, resilience. his 15 months as chairman of three companies highlights that trust plays an important part in the determination of board directors feelings towards the chairman. From the chairman’s perspective, his or her feelings towards other board members varied over time. The House (1998) study emphasises that trust cannot be taken for granted in terms of board relationships, but that trust is one of the most critical binding forces that determine board effectiveness. The literature emphasises that the role and the responsibilities of the chairman varies from one company to another, depending on the external environmental and internal contextual influence and on the subsequent boundary negotiation between chairman and CEO, and board and management (Roberts, 2002; Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2007). Certainly, one point clearly made is that only when boundaries are delineated can one of the key principles of the Combined Code of corporate governance in the UK be practised, that of, ‘no one individual should have unfettered powers of decision making’, (FRC, 2007: A2). The study Preliminary exploratory interviews with chairmen from both private and public sector organisations and of both genders identified one particular theme affecting the performance of the chairman, namely those over 60 years were consistently considered as more effective across a range of chairman performance dimensions. With this insight, 20 further semi-structured interviews were held with chairmen, CEOs and NEDs from both private and public sector organisations. The interview data was transcribed and through thematic analysis, distinct items were identified and clustered together to form a structured survey instrument. The instrument was then utilised to survey FTSE 100–250 350 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. companies investigating the role, contribution and performance of the chairman of the board. A total 286 responses were received, in effect an 11% response rate. Thirty-eight per cent of these respondents were aged 60 or over; 87% male; 71% had either an under graduate or post-graduate qualification; 90% were British; 54% sat on between two to four boards. The role profile of the respondents was 26% non-executive directors (NEDs), 28% chairmen, 9% senior independent directors (SIDs), 22% executive directors who sat on boards and 11% CEOs. The others comprised of company secretary, legal counsel and other board members. The respondents were asked to rate the chair in terms of performance effectiveness, particularly concerning their capability to lead the board. Study findings Overall, the findings are consistent with an earlier study reported by Kakabadse et al. (2008), namely that the chairman is critical to providing the necessary leadership for the effective functioning of the board and to ensuring that the organisation has a sustainable future. In order to do so, displaying integrity and being trustworthy were identified as key qualities that the chairman needs to display. Those in the 45–59 age group were identified as being less positive than those in the 60+ age group (Figure 12.1). Those aged 60 or over were scored significantly higher on the following aspects; the chairman ● ● ● ● ● ● ● ● effectively evaluates the performance of the CEO, effectively evaluates the performance of the senior independent director (SID), effectively evaluates the performance of other board members, encourages feedback on his or her performance, clarifies the skills and experience of each board member, calls upon the SID to intervene, supports the intervention of the SID, and discusses sensitive issues with the SID. Those chairmen in the age group 60+ (male and female) were consistently scored higher (significant at p<.001) on each of the questionnaire items when compared with the under 60 age group. Our findings suggest that older chairmen are considered to be more effective, not by the issuing of commands or by imposing their will on the board, but by being able to surface and deal with negative High-Performing Chairmen: The Older the Better 351 sentiments and promote a robust and meaningful dialogue. In the words of one director, Our Chairman has a talent for consensus and dialogue with this group of people of which most of them are his equals as some are chairmen of other boards. He knows how to deal with complex and conflict issues in a most humane way. I think that his humanity as well as his clarity is his most disarming quality for when he opens the meeting our guards go down and we talk freely. Thinking about it, it is perhaps our easiness to talk that makes us an effective board. (The Chairman referred to here was over 60). (P3-NED) Scholars have shown that ‘dialogue is clearly suited to providing opportunity to generate alternative perspectives over any issue or to challenge the vocabularies of dominant ideologies’ (Heidlebaugh, 2008:47). In small groups this is particularly effective as ‘participants with different power and knowledge, [are] dealing with complex and conflictive issues’ (Innes and Booher, 2003: 55). It has been recognised that dialogue allows for the expression of emotion which entices collaboration (Barnes et al., 2007). If ‘deliberation has to be based solely in reason, which is usually defined as neutral and dispassionate, and conducted solely through rational argument it will exclude many people’ (Barnes et al., 2007: 38). A complaint of certain of the NEDs in this study was that they were not ‘given’ the opportunity to contribute. This was particularly prominent amongst female directors who felt that if they showed enthusiasm and asked too many questions, they felt themselves labelled as ‘clueless’, ‘high maintenance’ or plain ‘difficult’. In the word of one female study participant (P9-NED), In the boardroom, signals easily get crossed due to different reasons, but once a label is on, it can be all but impossible to remove it. The emergent findings of thus study are not unusual as separate studies have shown that inhibited dialogue in the boardroom is the norm (Kakabadse et al., 2006). Thus, if dialogue, deliberation and feeling free to contribute are necessary elements of effective boardroom functioning, but with the reality being that an unwelcome boardroom context is one of the key reasons for tension between actors, how then can such contrasts be bridged? It was Aristotle (1941) who noted that practical wisdom (phronesis) is embedded in the older statesman and in so being 352 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. Under 60 60 or over Effectively evaluates the performance of the CEO 6.58 7.48 Effectively evaluates the performance of the Senior Independent Director 6.01 6.81 Effectively evaluates the performance of the board members 6.29 7.01 6.19 Encourages feedback on his/her performance Clarifies the skills/experience required of each board member 7.36 6.11 6.85 Calls upon the Senior Independent to intervene where necessary 6.5 7.18 Respects the intervention of the Senior Independent Director 6.85 7.61 Discuss sensitive issues with the Senior Independent Director 6.39 7.38 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Average scores Not at all true Figure 12.1 Very true Performance: the chairman the individual, who exhibits an essentially moral form of knowledge, is guided by the habits of virtue that come through experience. Aristotle (1941: 1033) noted that over time the individual acquires an ability to identify certain kinds of worthy action, and in so doing is able to develop contextually appropriate approaches that satisfactorily address the challenges leaders face. Since the time of Aristotle (1941), one question has repeatedly been raised and that is whether people matured by life are better able to work their way through conflicting tensions than they were able to do when younger (Schalk, 2004). Boardroom leadership requires not only sense making, or the interpretation of current circumstances taking in consideration past, present and possible future trends and influences, (Weick, 1995), but also sensebreaking, namely the act of discarding alternative narratives or routines from the past (Pratt, 1998, 2000). Shaping consensus in the boardroom requires the chairman to capture the more disabling overt and underlying sentiments of board members and redirect them to focus on positive outcomes through providing values, priorities and clarity about the issues at hand. ‘Clarity on values clarifies what is important in High-Performing Chairmen: The Older the Better 353 elapsed experience, which finally gives some sense of what that elapsed experience means’ (Weick, 1995: 28). Hence, leadership in the boardroom has a moral dimension and as such requires the capacity to discern through conflicting data but in so doing demands fairness in the treatment of those involved. It is the chairman’s in-depth appreciation of the particular challenges facing the key members of the board and his or her display of understanding of their context that enables the surfacing of sentiments, which, in turn, allows for meaningful dialogue. It’s the Chairman’s instinct to see and feel what I was going through in my role as CEO that made the difference to handling a particularly heavy issue. The guy seemed to feel for me and also the other board members. When he spoke to us he appreciated our perspective and could see the limitations of what we could or could not do. The fact that we were coming from different angles and were all over the place didn’t fluster him. That more than anything was the reason he was then able to bring us together. (The Chairman discussed here was over 60) (P11-CEO) My role is particularly problematic. I’m the SID (Senior Independent Director). If I act too early I cause a problem. If I wait for others to approach me and then say or do something, its too late. But the Chairman of that Board felt that it was how he handled me and recognised my predicaments. That, and his very personal style allowed for a necessary but uncomfortable conversation that had been put off for ages, to take place. That had the cathartic effect the board had needed for a long time. (The Chairman discussed here was over 60) (P14-SID) According to Aristotle (1941) practical wisdom provides the framework for accessing how individuals understand the issues at hand and how then to communicate with them in order to apply consequentially derived principles within their context. Thus only when the chairman’s experiential knowledge becomes embedded in the individual’s character is action effectively applied. Phronesis, as a moral form of knowledge, is learnt and re-learnt from one particular boardroom to the next. Such learning is the nurturing that Aristotle (1941) referred to and the study reported in this chapter identifies that as occurring from 60+ years of age. Research in neuroscience has found that with age, older people develop the skill of bilateralisation, namely the use of both sides of the brains instead of just one (Strauch, 2010). Moreover, research in 354 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. neuroscience reveals that the amount of myelin, the fatty (80% lipid, 20% protein) substance that insulates nerve fibres, continues to increase well into middle age, peaking at the age of 50 and in some cases in the sixties. It is this substance which boosts the brain cells’ processing capacity (Strauch, 2010). In fact, increases in myelin have been found to boost the brain’s ability to process experiences and information by up to 3,000%, which suggests that older people are much better at controlling and balancing their emotions as the elderly brain is less dopamine-dependent, thus enabling people to be less impulsive, more controlled and less prone to reactions of a dramatic emotional nature (Jeste, 2010). Hence, older people are identified as able to get to the point of an argument faster than a younger person, are able to appreciate the rational, emotional and political nuances in situations more insightfully and thus better able to work through emotionally demanding concerns, context by context (Jeste, 2010). Research shows that the greater the increase in myelin, the greater the individuals’ use of the frontal lobes of the brain which control emotion, risk-taking and decision-making as well as the temporal lobes which are responsible for responsiveness to language, music and mood (Jeste, 2010). Equally, the neuroscience study clearly indicates that with the age, ‘fluid intelligence’ (i.e. ‘native mental ability’ – the information system processing), or the ability to speedily think and reason logically tends to decline and thus impacts on attention and memory capacity. The individual becomes slower at mental calculation or recall of facts. ‘Crystallized intelligence’ however, or the ability to use skills, knowledge, reasoning and experience all of which are the product of educational and cultural experience, improves with age (Cattell, 1987; Blair, 2006; Jaeggi et al., 2008). In effect, neuroscience strongly suggests that older people display greater capacity for reasoning about, and working through social dilemmas and conflicts (Grossmann et al., 2010). In fact, the Grossmann et al. (2010) study shows that relative to young and middle-aged people, older people make greater use of higher-order reasoning schemes, adopting multiple perspectives and recognise the limits of rational knowledge, all of which more easily allow for compromise. Thus social reasoning improves with age, despite the decline in fluid intelligence (Grossmann et al., 2010). For example, a study of 118 pilots aged 40 to 69 showed that the older participants outperformed their younger colleagues when avoiding traffic collisions whilst not performing as well in terms of mathematical calculation (Strauch, 2010). New research suggests that assigning older individuals to key social roles involving legal decisions, counselling and High-Performing Chairmen: The Older the Better 355 intergroup negotiations produces more sustainable results (Grossmann et al., 2010). The Chairman’s role is one of consolidator and for that reason he is able to create cohesive board that can come to consensus on issues under consideration. Otherwise you have bunch of oversized egos or one super large ego running the board. (Participant 4, NED) Highly effective chairmen are able to develop board norms where issues are logically considered and morally moderated. (Participant 15, Chairman, aged over 60) I need a Chairman with whom I can sit down to share thoughts, ideas, fears and aspirations, and at the same time have him/her interrogate my assumption. Such chairmen are few and far between, but the one I have now, especially because of his age makes me feel comfortable and yet scrutinises me intensively. (Participant 18, CEO was referring to his Chairman who was aged over 60) The results reported in this study parallel those reported from neuroscience, namely that effective chairmen are so because of the particular strengths they have developed as a result of ageing. Older chairmen deal better with matters where doubt infects the debate and where deliberation is required, such as the handling of sensitive but critical relationships, where individual ego can distort the reaching of rational decisions with which all could identify and support. Conclusion The study results emphasise phronesis, namely practical wisdom as an attribute of the outstanding chairman. What is only just beginning to be understood is the impact of phronesis as the mean that enables the achievement of board goals and responsibilities, as well as minimising the potential threats that could jeopardise the achieving of those goals. The study results highlight that effective chairmen need to be able to know how to recognise and avoid (or at least minimise) threats and whether the orientation of each individual board members presents a threat or opportunity to board functioning. Knowing how to determine 356 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. appropriate action, when and how to improve relationships with the others on the board and with stakeholders, as well as knowing when to take a long-term or short-term view and generally how to deal with major challenges and dilemmas, differentiates the outstanding chairman from the rest. What is highlighted in this study are the chairman’s skill to work through tensions, yet still focus on the salient points in the debate and as a result align expectations (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2008). The chairman’s most potent tool is ‘practical wisdom’ through dialogue. Although our study confirms the Kakabadse et al. (2008) findings, further research is required. One particular theme for exploration is whether older chairmen act more independently and hold more of an independent mind-set than do their younger counterparts. The results of this study suggest that older chairmen may well be able to muster the necessary emotional resilience to act independently, but this assertion requires further scrutiny. Such examination is necessary as studies at lower levels of the organisation suggest that older employees display higher levels of obligation, namely they feel obliged to work extra hours, to work well with others, to provide good service and to deliver good work in terms of quality and quantity. However, the older employee is shown to feel that their employer is more obliged to provide them with a sound working environment with bonuses based on performance, all emphasising a ‘stronger’ psychological contract between employer and employee than is the case with the younger counterpart (Huiskamp and Schalk, 2002; Schalk, 2004; van der Heijden et al., 2008). Such results suggest a dependency need for approval. Further study will be useful in informing retirement policy design as well as exploring whether older people are less productive. Certainly recent trends emphasise the importance of such research as the Creditsafe group, the business intelligence forum, reports 10,000 directors over 65 have been appointed to newly incorporated enterprises (in the UK) in the six months prior to April 2011 (Clarke, 2011). These silverpreneurs, i.e. over 65’s, are not only starting their own businesses but that the UK already has 360,000 or so directors at pensionable age who still work (Clarke, 2006). Further, the reported average age of the top 20 billionaires in the world is 67.4 years (Clarke, 2011). The need to examine the leadership and managerial characteristics of this population is overwhelming. The ‘silverpreneurs of Creditsafe’ are simply not going to go away. High-Performing Chairmen: The Older the Better 357 References Aristotle (1941) The Basic Works of Aristotle, Random House, New York. Barnes, M., Newman, J. and Sullivan, H. (2007), Power, Participation and Political Renewal. Case Studies in Public Participation, The Policy Press, Bristol. Berle, A. A. and Means, G.C. (1932/1968), The Modern Corporation and Private Property, 12th Edition, Transaction Publishers, New Brunswick. Blair, C. (2006) ‘How similar are fluid cognition and general intelligence? A developmental neuroscience perspective on fluid cognition as an aspect of human cognitive ability’, Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 29: 109–160. Blair, M.M. (1995), Ownership and Control: Rethinking Corporate Governance for the Twenty-First Century, Brookings Institution, Washington, D.C. Cadbury, A. (2002) Corporate Governance and Chairmanship: A Personal View, Oxford University Press, Oxford. Cadbury, A. (1995) The Company Chairman, Directors Book, Hamel Hempstead. Cattell, R. (1987). Intelligence: It’s Structure, Growth, and Action. Elsevier Science, Amsterdam. Clarke, T. (2011) ‘Older shoulders can take the weight of late retirement’. Citigate Dewe Rogerson, Toby Clarke citigate.co.uk, April 2006 Clark, G. L., Caerlewy-Smith, E. and Marshall, J. C. 2006. ‘Pension fund trustee competence: decision making in problems relevant to investment practice’, Journal of Pension Economics and Finance, 5(01): 91–110. Fleishman, E.A., Mumford, M.D., Zaccaro, S.J., Levin, K.Y., Korotkin, A.L. and Hein, M.B. (1991). Taxonomic efforts in the description of leader behavior: A synthesis and functional interpretation. Leadership Quarterly, 2, 245–287. Forbes (2002), ‘The Dollar-A-Year Man’, 5 August, http://www.forbes.com/2002/ 05/08/0508iacocca.html (accessed: 20 August 2010). FRC (Financial Reporting Council) (2008), The Combined Code on Corporate Governance, Financial Reporting Council, London, June. Garratt, B. (1999), ‘Developing effective directors and building dynamic boards’, Long Range Planning, 32(1), 28–35. Grossmann, I., Na, J., Varnum, M.E.W., Park, D.C., Kitayama, S. and Nisbett, R.E. (2010), ‘Reasoning about social conflicts improves into old age’, PNAS, 107(16), 7246–7250. Haspeslagh, P., Noda, T., Boulos, F. (2001), ‘Managing for value: it’s not just about the numbers’, Harvard Business Review, 79(7), 65–73. Heidlebaugh, N. J., (2008), ‘Invention and public dialogue: lessons from rhetorical theories’, Communication Theory, 18(1), 27–50. Huiskamp, R. and Schalk, R. (2002), ‘Psychologische contracten in arbeidsrelaties: de stand van zaken in Nederland’, Gedrag en Organisatie, 15, 370–385. House, M. (1998), ‘Researching the dynamics of board-stakeholder relations’, Long Range Planning, 31(2), 218–226. Innes, J. and Booher, D. (2003), ‘The Impact of Collaborative Planning on Governance Capacity’, Institute of Urban and Regional Development’, IURD Working Paper Series, Paper WP-2003–03, http://repositories.cdlib.org/iurd/ wps/WP-2003–03, (access: 20 April 2006). IoD (2007), Corporate Governance Guidance and Principles for Unlisted Companies in the UK, Institute of Directors (IoD), London. 358 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. Jaeggi, S. M., Buschkuehl, M., Jonides, J. and Perrig, W. J. (2008), ‘Improving fluid intelligence with training on working memory’, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 105(19), 6829–6833. Jeste, D. (2010), ‘Why the wise man takes up juggling in old age’, International Congress of the Royal College of Psychiatrists, Edinburgh, 21–24 June, http:// www.rcpsych.ac.uk/press/pressreleases2010/wisdominoldage.aspx (accessed: 20 September 2010). Kakabadse, A. and Kakabadse, N., (1999), Essence of Leadership, International Thomson, London. Kakabadse, N. and Kakabadse, A., (2007), ‘Chairman of the board: demographics effects on role pursuit’, Journal of Management Development, 26(2). 169–192. Kakabadse, A. and Kakabadse, N. (2008) Leading the Board: The Six Disciplines of World-Class Chairman, Palgrave, London. Kakabadse, A. and Kakabadse, N. and Knyght, R. (2010) ‘The “chemistry factor” in the Chairman/CEO Relationship’, European Management Journal, Special Issue: New Leadership Themes. Guest Editors: McCalman, J. and Paton, R.A., 28(4), 285–296. Kakabadse, A. Kakabadse, N. and Myers, A. (2008), Chairman of the Board: A Study of Role, Contribution and Performance of UK Board Directors, Cranfield School of Management and Manchester Square Partners. Kakabadse, A., Kakabadse, N. and Barratt, R. (2006), ‘Chairman and chief executive officer (CEO): that sacred and secret relationship’, Journal of Management Development, 25(2), 134–150. Kakabadse, A., Ward, K., Kakabadse, N. and Bowman, C. (2001), ‘Role and contribution of non-executive directors’, Corporate Governance: The International Journal of Effective Board Performance, 1(1), 4–7. Kaplan, R.S. and Norton, D.P. (2006), Alignment: How to Apply the Balanced Scorecard to Corporate Strategy, Harvard Business School Press, Boston. Kristie, J. (2010), ‘The Great Divide: to separate the chairman and CEO roles, or not? To make such a separation mandatory, or not? A panel of experts tackles the thorny theoretical issues and practical concerns involved in splitting the two top leadership positions of the corporation’, Directors and Boards, Winter. http://findarticles.com/p/articles/mi_go2446/is_2_34/ai_n53035103/ pg_2/?tag=content;col1 Lorsch, J.W. (2005), ‘The chairman’s job description: time for a change in your governance leadership? In the post-SOX era, there is a new interest in separating the top jobs. Here is what’s required of the nonexecutive chair’, Directors and Boards, 22 September, http://goliath.ecnext.com/coms2/gi_0199–4959183/ The-chairman-s-job-description.html (accessed: 20.08.2010). Nadler, D. A., Behan, B. A. and Nadler, M. B. (Eds) (2006) Building Better Boards, Jossey- Bass, San Francisco, CA. Nicholson, G. J. and Kiel, G. C. (2004) ‘Breakthrough board performance: How to harness your board’s intellectual capital’, Corporate Governance: International Journal of Business in Society 4(1): 5–23. Nonaka, I and Takeuichi, H (2011), ‘The wise worker’, Harvard Business Review, 89(5), 58–67. NYSE Euronext (2008), ‘History of Paris stock exchanges’, http://www.euronext. com/editorial/wide/editorial-1989-EN.html (accessed: 20 August 2010). High-Performing Chairmen: The Older the Better 359 Parker, H. (1990), ‘The company chairman: his role and responsibilities’, Long Range Planning, 23(4), 35–43. Pfeffer, J. and Salancik, G.R. (1978), The External Control of Organizations: A Resource Dependence Perspective, Harper & Row, New York. Pratt, M. G. (1998) ‘To be or not to be: central questions in organizational identification’ in D. Whetten and P. Godfrey (eds.), Identity in Organizations: Developing Theory Through Conversations, Sage, Thousand Oaks, CA, pp. 171– 207. Pratt, M. G. (2000) ‘The good, the bad, and the ambivalent: managing identification among amway distributors’, Administrative Science Quarterly, 45, 456–493. Roberts, J., (2002), ‘Building the complementary board. The work of the plc chairman’, Long Range Planning, 35(5), 493–520. Schalk, R. (2004), ‘Changes in the employment relation across time’, in Coyle-Shapiro, J.A-M., Shore, L.M., Taylor, M.S. and Tetrick, L.E. (Eds), The Employment Relationship: Examining Psychological and Contextual Perspectives, Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp. 284–311. Stewart, R. (1991), ‘Chairman and chief executive: an exploration of their relationship’, Journal of Management Study, 28(5), 511–527. Strauch, B. (2010), The Secret Life of the Grown-up Brain: The Surprising Talents of the Middle-Aged Mind, Viking, London. van der Heijden, B.I.J.M., Schalk, R. and Marc J.P.M. van Veldhoven (2008), ‘Ageing and careers: European research on long-term career development and early retirement’, Career Development International, 13(2), 85–94. Weick, K.E. (1995) Sensemaking in Organizations, Sage, Thousand Oaks, CA. Zaccaro, S.J. (1998). The contingency model and executive leadership. In Yammarino, F.J. and Dansereau, F. (Eds), Leadership: The Multiplelevel Approach, : JAI Press, Greenwich, CT. Zahra, S.A. and Pearce, J.A., II. (1989), ‘Boards of directors and corporate financial performance: a review and integrative model’, Journal of Management, 15(2), 291–334. 13 Aligning the Board: The Chairman’s Secret Nada K. Kakabadse, Reeves Knyght and Andrew Kakabadse Introduction Whilst government response to corporate scandal and market failure has been to spawn ever greater regulation and/or comply or explain protocol, it has also been long recognised that a formulaic approach to governance codes limits the contribution and value the board can offer the business (Steiner, 1972). Even the proponents of role duality, namely the combining of the CEO and chairman roles, argue that adopting an over-structured, rules-driven perspective to the governance of the enterprise limits the board’s stewardship of the firm (Charan, 1998). Equally, the champions of role separation (Leblanc and Gillies, 2005; Lorsch and Zelleke, 2005; Hossack, 2006) acknowledge that keeping the CEO and chairman as two distinct entities is a necessary but not a sufficient condition for board effectiveness. Both the role duality and role separation schools concur that the contribution of the board to the continued future of the organisation is principally dependent on the behaviour, experience and skills of its members. Moreover a growing number of scholars have identified that the leadership provided by the chairman is fundamental to encouraging ever higher levels of board performance (Leblanc and Gillies, 2005; Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2007). Leblanc (2004), for example, argues that research needs to focus on the ‘black box’ of how boards actually work in order to understand the behaviour and contribution of the chairman and the value provided by the individual directors. In the same vein, McNulty et al. (2003) argue that a better understanding of boardroom dynamics as well as sensitivity towards the quality of relationship between executive and non-executive directors (NEDs) will enable boards to enhance their performance. In support, Sonnenfeld (2004) concludes that the 360 Aligning the Board: The Chairman’s Secret 361 missing element to board research is the ‘human side’, a perspective echoed by a number of commentators (Brass and Burkhardt, 1993; Dalton and Dalton, 2005; Dalton et al., 2003; Hermalin and Weisbach, 2003). The point being made is that greater understanding of the internal working processes of the board is needed in order for the board to add value to the organisation it monitors. Thus, attention to the behavioural side of the board work is the pertinent concern when examining the vexed question of alignment, first between board members and second between the board and the rest of the organisation. This is especially the case over the issue of reaching a shared view concerning the purpose, vision, mission and strategy of the enterprise (Watson, 2008). Despite the continued calls for in-depth behavioural, soft analysis the evidence to date indicates a bias towards a structural/systems scrutiny of corporate governance and board performance, with only a minority of studies examining the relationship aspects of board functioning (Gabrielsson and Huse, 2004). Bearing in mind the concern to penetrate the ‘black box’ of boardroom relationships (Gabrielsson and Huse, 2004) and the recognition that chairmen wield particular influence, this chapter explores how boardroom tensions can be minimised and/or resolved through realising alignment between the board and the management. Particular attention will focus on the chairman’s capability to find pathways through boardroom differences especially through surfacing and working through the deeply held sentiments board members hold concerning their inter-relationships with each other and with the board. Preceding such examination is a review of the chairman’s role and the necessary capabilities to effectively exercise this position. In this analysis, attention is given to examining the purpose of the board and the need to realise alignment between the board and between internal and external stakeholders. This is followed by an in-depth examination of the qualitative data captured in this study. The chapter concludes that the chairman’s leadership in encouraging the sharing of director experiences is a critical factor in shaping positively inclined boardroom behaviour, which in turn is fundamental to the board adding value to the organisation. Chairman; role, contribution and capability There is growing evidence that the chairman is critical to the monitoring of individual and collective managerial performance (Cadbury, 2002; Hossack, 2006). Particularly from the agency theory perspective, 362 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. the reason monitoring is given such emphasis is the concern over realising alignment of interests between owners and managers (Jaskiewicz and Klein, 2007). Alignment, or the capacity to demonstrate a positive relationship between organisational purpose/strategic objectives and the achieving of financial targets, has long been considered a critical leadership challenge facing boards (Barnard, 1938). It has also been recognised that the greater the level of alignment between the staff and management on how the resources of the firm are to be leveraged, the greater the level of job satisfaction for those concerned (Dennison, 1992; Kotter and Heskett, 1992), the fewer the number of conflicting goals to pursue (Perrow, 1961), and as a result the greater the competiveness of the firm (Semler, 1997). The concept of alignment draws heavily from both agency theory and stewardship theory (Sundaramurthy and Lewis, 2003). Agency theory steers governance in favour of control through instituting vigilant, externally dominated boards, drawing on their discipline and detachment in order to achieve distinct structural alignment and thereby incentivise management (Jensen and Murphy, 1990). In this sense, agency theory searches for that one solution to reduce conflicts of interest and, in turn, tie managers wealth to realising shareholder wealth (Jensen and Murphy, 1990). Agency theory holds that incentivising the CEO in particular enhances alignment through decreasing the need for monitoring and encouraging the use of social capital ties. On this basis, the CEO is more likely to be willing to take measured risk through seeking the advice, support and the loyalty of the board (Sundaramurthy and Lewis, 2003). Stock option based rewards have been and continue to be considered a deep sharing of interests between management and shareholders, thus reducing agency costs (Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Jensen and Murphy, 1990) and contributing to the increased performance of the firm. All these characteristics combined means that shareholder wealth is enhanced (Jensen and Murphy, 1990; Rosenberg, 2004). In contrast, adopting the rent extraction perspective indicates that stock options may increase the conflict between management and shareholders (Hernandez, 2008). In fact, it is postulated that firms that grant stock options exhibit a lower stock return than firms that do not extensively adopt such remuneration measures (Melle-Hernandez, 2005). Moreover, irrespective of stock option adoption larger firms, in general, are recognised to be more complex to manage and to monitor, especially as they exhibit greater potential for agency conflict (Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Williamson, 1967). Yet despite the more formulaic Aligning the Board: The Chairman’s Secret 363 approach of agency theory, studies suggest that the leadership skill of the chairman to ensure for comprehensive monitoring remains the critical factor in ensuring for effective governance (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2008). Stewardship theory, on the other hand, steers governance in the direction of collaboration favouring the governance of collective decision making in order to achieve goal alignment (Sundaramurthy and Lewis, 2003). In effect, stewardship theory combines a values-based philosophy with economic rationalist notions of wealth creation in order that success can be achieved even in the most challenging of circumstances. Through so integrating two contrasting strands of thinking, stewardship theory draws on leadership process theory which holds that influencing the key managers in the organisation to realise strategic alignment is only likely to occur when account is taken of the reality of their context and their motivation to be more cohesive (Mohrman et al., 1995). If the uniqueness of context and the idiosyncrasy of top manager interaction are not taken into account then influence attempts are likely to be less than successful. Study also emphasises that central to influencing board members to become better aligned is the chairman (Lorsch and Zelleke, 2005). Thus from both the stewardship or agency perspective, the contribution of the chairman to nurturing a cohesive board is pivotal. Still, there is reason for further study and that is based on the recognition that there is still too little understanding of how chairmen influence director behaviour and motivation in order to determine effective boardroom performance (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2008). Towards this end, the need for the chairman to direct and lead the board and be held accountable for the performance of the board has been increasingly noted in the literature (Cadbury, 2002; Lorsch and Zelleke, 2005). One line of inquiry already pursued is that capable chairmen lead by example, empowering and involving fellow directors in decisionmaking processes (Bloch, 2005). Others agree and add that the chairman influences through being a role model, acting as the guardian of the values of the firm and upholding the highest standards of probity and integrity (Higgs, 2003; Hossack, 2006). Through qualitative analysis, Roberts et al. (2005) concluded that board effectiveness depends on the behavioural dynamics between the executive and non-executive directors, and the quality of those interactions considerably depends on the mediation skills of the chairman. Research (Roberts, 2002; Hall and Rolfe, 2005) further shows that board effectiveness is positively related to the quality of interpersonal relationships between board members, 364 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. where trust and openness are essential to generating commitment between the directors. The leadership of the chairman is prerequisite to nurturing these behavioural qualities (Roberts and Stiles, 1999). Further studies (Pettigrew and McNulty, 1995; Leblanc, 2004; Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2008; Levrau and van Den Berghe; 2007) confirm the chairman’s influence in shaping the dynamics of the board. Particular commentators (Westphal, 1999; Hackman and Wageman, 2005) focus on the chairman’s ability to ensure receipt of relevant information to board directors, thus enhancing autonomy of decision making, reinforcing board independence and reducing NED reliance on the executives in order to be informed. Other researchers more concentrate on the leadership contribution of the chairman in acting as a counter weight to the influence of the CEO and the executive directors in order to guarantee board independence (Alexander et al., 1993; Hambrick and Fukotomi, 1991; Mace, 1971; Pfeffer, 1981). It is postulated that through sound leadership the chairman increases the effectiveness of the monitoring function of the board, thus better ensuring that managers run the firm according to shareholders’ interests (Hillman and Dalziel, 2003). An Egon Zender International survey of 66 CEOs and chairmen across 12 European countries identified that almost two-thirds of the expected skills of the chairman are on the ‘soft side’, with leading and motivating people being at the top of the list, even above business judgment, risk analysis and sector knowledge (Hollanders, 2004). Similarly the Kakabadse and Kakabadse (2008) study reveals that effective board performance depends on the chairman’s ability to exercise the necessary leadership in order for the board to positively influence firm performance. In so doing, the chairman nurtures a ‘psychological understanding’ amongst board members in order for the board to be able to freely consider how to add value to the organisation (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2008). Thus, study emphasises that it falls upon the chairman to continually assess the boards capacity to both monitor and steward, and consider how to act between competing tensions posed through environmental turbulence in an increasingly globalised world (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2008). The study In keeping with previous studies examining the role and contribution of the chairman and whilst paying particular attention to the need for deliberative practice (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2007), an interpretative inquiry approach was adopted in order to avoid the ‘pretensions’ of Aligning the Board: The Chairman’s Secret 365 objectivity (Taylor, 2001). Throughout the inquiry attention was paid to language, communication patterns, director interaction and context in order to better appreciate how board members construct their social world resulting from the nature of their reasoning for the actions they undertake (Ryfe, 2006: 73). Open-ended interviews with 23 board directors from the UK, the United States, Australia, China and Russia were pursued. The sample included chairmen, CEOs and NEDs. The purpose for adopting an open-ended interview approach was to allow for freedom of expression of life-stories, and self narratives (Shamir and Eilam, 2005) in order to draw out ‘hidden patterns and hitherto unexplored meanings’ (Kearney, 2002: 12). Saturation of themes (Glaser and Strauss, 1967) was reached by 21 interviews, broadly in line with Alexandersson’s (1994) and Sias et al. (2004) findings. All interviews were tape-recorded and transcribed thus collating detailed narratives from each respondent. Many ways exist to analyse participants’ narratives capturing their experiences (Taylor and Bogdan, 1984), ranging from examination of the narrative as a whole (Lieblich et al., 1998), to identifying self-contained story formats (Boje, 1991), to determining patterns of themes that recur in discourse (Reissman, 1993; Pentland, 1999). The third approach of thematic analysis pattern recognition was adopted, since the focus of the study was to appreciate the meanings attached to expressions of deeply held beliefs and emotions concerning board director contribution towards achieving alignment across disparate agendas within the boardroom. Hence, the themes were derived from recurring expressions of participants experiences and feelings (Taylor and Bogdan, 1989), ‘bringing together components or fragments of ideas or experiences, which often are meaningless when viewed alone’ (Leininger, 1985: 60). Emergent themes and frameworks were amended in the light of subsequent transcriptions in order to ensure for coherence of ideas which ‘rests with the analyst who has rigorously studied how different ideas or components fit together in a meaningful way when linked together’ (Leininger, 1985: 60). Study results and discussion Four themes emerged from thematic examination of how the chairman ‘shaped’ boardroom dialogue (or the lack of it), which in turn effected the level of alignment between board directors. The four themes portray the particular dynamics underpinning the inhibited board, the actionoriented board, the self-congratulating board and the learning board. 366 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. Inhibited board: lack of effective dialogue Aristotle, in 450 BC, argued that if communication is to change individual behaviour, it must be grounded in the desires and interests of the receiver. Modern-day scholars agree highlighting that if a person is to be motivated to change, the communication they receive needs to ‘touch’ their interests and values (Larkin and Larkin, 1994). No, NEDs are not used effectively. I don’t think we are clear what we are here to do. I think that the Chairman needs to clarify our roles and enable us to contribute. I don’t know whether we are getting the right information or not, but it goes beyond information. We are not encouraged to ask questions. The moment one of us ask questions the invisible shields goes up and you feel it. (Participant 3, NED). The level of collective experience and knowledge NEDs share is taken for granted. They are almost all household names, but I think that they are not given space to contribute and that is due to the Chairman’s style (Participant 4, MD) Few would argue that it is chairman’s responsibility to focus boardroom discussion to relevant matters and to appropriately direct the decisionmaking process. In order to effectively do so, managing time and allowing for debate on complex issues and encouraging challenge have been recognised by a number of review bodies (Cadbury, 2002; Higgs, 2003), practitioners (Bloch, 2005) and academics (Leblanc and Gillies, 2005) as critical. Leblanc and Gillies (2005) conclude that the chairman is pivotal to identifying the goals and objectives of the board through the setting of the agenda. Roberts and Stiles (1999) agree and hold that the chairman facilitates the active contribution of executive and non-executive directors. If conversation does not easily flow, boards are deprived of individual directors experience and wisdom. Within the theme of the inhibited board, a number of the study respondents narrated that their skills and experience were considerably underutilised due to the inhibiting board culture nurtured by the chairman. Uninvited conversation was reported as unwelcome: But when you go to the actual Board meeting and watch things you get an almost monotone presentation and sometimes it may have just too many numbers in it. So you get lost in the detail. The non execs feel inhibited and don’t quite know how to respond or what questions to ask … Nobody dares to challenge. (Participant 10, NED) Aligning the Board: The Chairman’s Secret 367 Avoiding social costs from not expressing opinion (Miller and Nelson, 2002) often leads to a ‘spiral of silence’ (Noelle-Neumann, 1993: 1). Certain researchers highlight that board members who hold private concerns about the organisation and its practices tend to assume from the lack of expressed concern by others that they are in the minority, thus making them less likely to state their concerns (Westphal and Bednar, 2005). This collective psychology is what some have labelled as a ‘pluralistic ignorance’ (Westphal and Bednar, 2005). Self-congratulating board: sharing positive experience Sharing positive experience and emotions has long been recognised as ‘motivating’, particularly in the pursuit of ‘achievement, recognition, pursuing challenging work and taking responsibility which all contribute to personal, team and organisational advancement’ (Herzberg et al., 1959: 63). Yet, over focusing on positive experience can lead to self-deception, an ‘emotional switching off’ especially when challenged with perspectives that do not fit the individual’s glowing picture of the world (Sousa, 2004: 65). Certainly drawing on emotions to shape thinking and identify ways forward is an influential power lever, much dependent on the intentions of the individual ‘swaying the crowd’ (Bovens, 1999). X’s strength is how he uses dialogue, his words are not empty nor condescending, he uses dialogue not to veil intentions, but to disclose deeply held realties. He uses dialogue not to antagonise but to establish relations and create new realities. I think that these are mandatory skills for an effective Chairman. Even after… when motivations were low, he managed to preserve a trusting and positive ear in the boardroom. He keeps reminding us of the good things that we had done and how we did them (Participant 14, NED). Participant 14 outlines the upside to drawing on positive experiences, unlike the narrative offered by participant 3. We have a very enthusiastic and hardworking Chairman that genuinely appreciates the sharing of our success stories, which is all well. But when we needed to discuss some potentially sensitive issues, willingness to listen to peoples less positive feelings abated. For example, in Russia, we were not only entering a new market but we were targeting their national champions, their strategic assets, their financial services, which could inflame nationalistic sentiments, and yet 368 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. we were not discussing these issues. I have 20 years of Russian experience and no one asked me for my opinion, because I had some negative feelings about it all. Any negativities were not welcome and that was due to the Chairman’s inability to handle anything less than positive, but necessary to raise sentiments. (Participant 3, NED). The incapacity to surface relevant but unwelcome sentiments can lead to groupthink or related decision making bias. We never talked about what we knew was going to happen. The Chairman could not bring himself to face up to the CEO and that one other director. We were all encouraged to put on a good face and say positive things. Soon the skill became, ‘stop your real emotions spilling out’. And you know what, the inevitable happened in the way we all knew it would. It was a hell of an encounter. Although painful, I felt a sense of relief. Pretending being positive drained me. (Participant 2, NED). Interestingly, most of the study participants who admitted to pretence also stated that the longer that continued, the clearer their insights concerning future effects, especially those of bankruptcy, take over or collapse. Yet, despite these insights, many narrated a lack of action, a conspiracy of silence, of becoming paralysed and unable to enter into dialogue. Action-oriented board: sharing of negative expertises Raising the uncomfortable issue has been recognised as a critical skill of dialogue (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2011). Cross-cultural dialogue in particular is potentially loaded with unwelcome tension, leading to miscommunication and misunderstanding, requiring empathy as the antidote (Goleman, 1998). Being attuned to the subtleties of body language needs to be complemented by hearing ‘the message’ beneath the words being spoken and it is these aspects that are promoted as core to skilful negotiation (Goleman, 1998:101). You can say that it is X’s experience, his nurturing style, his use of words, his general demeanour, his determination, his actions. The bottom line is that he instils trust in the others on this multicultural board which potentially can be minefield. I think that is what makes him a very effective Chairman. It is that trust that plays a vital role in having effective dialogue in the boardroom which allows Aligning the Board: The Chairman’s Secret 369 for discussion of negative feelings and gives permission for sensitive issues to emerge. That more than anything helps us engage in the difficult conversations. (Participant 7, NED) As I got older, I become more aware and sensitive to peoples emotional ways, so I try to connect with all board members on a human level and build trust irrelevant from which corner of the world they come from. They all have their own issues, but I allow them to openly express themselves and share their frustration in a constructive way and that way you build trust. … I think that sharing negative emotions builds trust faster than the sharing of positive experiences. Common human problems bind people together. (Participant 23, Chairman). Study suggests that people better recall negative events than positive ones (Minar et al., 2005; Brison, 1999; Dasborough, 2006) due to the fact that negative emotions tend to be more immediate and pressing (Frijda, 1986) and people are hardwired to respond to them (Taylor, 1991). To surface and positively draw upon negative emotions can lead to a ‘galvanisation of emotion and energy’, which can then be harvested for action. However the question that commentators have raised is, through being enthused by the catharsis of emotional release, can sense of judgement be lost leaving the individuals concerned unable to discriminate between data and objectives (Griffiths, 2004: 247)? Getting all this off our chest was great. We swung in to action only to discover we should have stopped and thought a bit more. (Participant 22, Chairman) Catharsis was narrated by the study participants as critical to fostering constructive boardroom dialogue, but an additional step was identified as required, that of being able to stand back, rationalise, allow for the negative emotions to subside and only then enter into the decision taking/making processes. Learning board: sharing of positive and negative experiences Dialogue, as an open-ended conversation in which participants strive to understand their experiences, language and ways of thinking and through so doing build safe spaces for the expression of dissention and difference for the creation of shared meaning, has been identified as 370 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. critical for high level board performance (Kakabadse and Kakabadse, 2008). In the first evening of our away days, the Chairman reflected on his long experience with the board. Then he asked the longest serving board director to reflect on his experience. Then the second longest serving and so on until all members had told their story. I was last, as I had been on the board for only two months. Each story was reflective, some were quite funny and few were a deep reappraisal of the bitter experience with the former CEO. The upshot of telling stories was to connect longer serving board members with new ones, and to discover the deeply held sentiments that some members harboured. The result was that by telling stories, we all gained a perspective about each other and as a consequence showed understanding which reduced a lot of barriers between us. X …. has an easy style of communicating and sharing that prompted us all to open up. The evening paved the way for a next day of deep discussion. I am a seasoned board member and have been on many boards, but have never had such a profound, experience as here. I think that the success of this board is very much due to X’s….(the Chairman’s) sensitive style. (Participant 10, NED) Drawing on significant experiences allows for sense of continuity, which the study participants narrated as important for positive board room contribution, ‘there is no continuity without an appreciation of the past. People will experience continuity when they can recognize the past in their present actions and intentions for the future’ (Bouwen and Overlaet, 2001: 34). To do so requires the sharing of personal experiences, where both negative and positive emotions are the driving force behind social action (Barblet, 1998). This was particularly emphasised by one study participant: We went through the very traumatic experience of CEO replacement. There were some ugly scenes between the CEO and Chairman. I think that Chairman handled it well. He delved deep in to our experience and brought out our resentments. After that we went from strength to strength. Trust is fundamental for building open discussion in the boardroom, but that very much depends on the Chairman’s skill, benevolence and integrity. Fairness, discretion, integrity and openness are a precondition for effective boardroom communication. (Participant 9, NED). Scholars have argued that emotions reflect value judgments in that emotions guide the individual to appraise and appropriately respond Aligning the Board: The Chairman’s Secret 371 to social situations (Kemper, 1978; Averill, 1980; Fineman, 1993). In so doing, the study participants emphasised that for learning on the board to take place (which in turn leads to considered action) attending to both positive and negative emotions is required. Discussion All of the study participants narrated that the sharing of experience in the boardroom is critical to opening up conversation in order to reach meaningful decisions. Inducing an open sharing of experience was dependent on the chairman’s skill to surface the sentiments each board member held about the board, its directors and the chairman. The data reveals two intertwined but over-arching dimensions that are instrumental in the surfacing of sentiments, namely, the sharing of positive experiences and the sharing of negative experiences. Juxtaposing these two dimensions, the study surfaced four board identities which can as much discourage learning and conversation as encourage learning and positive dialogue (see Figure 13.1): 1. Inhibited board: Low sharing of negative experience and low sharing of positive experience. 2. Self-congratulating board: Low sharing of negative experience and high sharing of positive experience. Action Oriented Board Learning Board Inhibited Board Self-Congratulating Board Low Sharing Negative Experience High Boardroom Behaviour Low High Sharing Positive Experience Figure 13.1 Boardroom behaviour 372 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. 3. Action-oriented board: High sharing of negative experience and low sharing of positive experience. 4. Learning board: High sharing of negative experience and high sharing of positive experience. The study results support previous findings that emotional information is as much a legitimate source of knowledge about reality as information provided through systems and structures (Sousa, 2004). Constructs related to social sharing through the surfacing of positive emotions have been identified as inducing moral building, enhancing of communication, offering of support, displaying a positive attitude, providing encouragement and showing enthusiasm, which together foster a shared memory of a rewarding experience (Jehn and Shah, 1997). Constructs related to the raising of negative emotions have been identified as unwelcome painful experiences, but if well handled foster caring, empathy, support, compassion and constancy (Kahn and Isen, 1993). Most of the study participants expressed themselves as more comfortable to be around other directors who projected a ‘happy disposition’, but equally admitted that boards that share only positive emotions can engender ‘political’ behaviour where directors focus on ends rather than means. In effect, attention concentrates on what can be achieved without exploration of the pitfalls to be faced and the need for capability development to realise the stated aims of the board and the organisation. In contrast, the study participants narrated that the sharing of negative experiences engenders a cathartic release, which acts as a precursor to action but then needs considered deliberation to better guarantee a quality outcome. Such sensitive but penetrating discussion requires that board members trust each other. A number of the study participants narrated that trust is only realised by board directors behaving authentically. Authentication is conceptualised as being unpretentious, through being unmasked of thought, feelings and beliefs (Khan, 1992). To be viewed as authentic, the study participants considered it important for board directors to feel genuine about their emotional welfare and the board environment which they inhabit. Being authentic is recognised as ‘owning one’s personal experiences, be they thoughts, emotions, needs, preferences, or beliefs, processes captured by the injunction to know oneself’ (Harter, 2002: 82). I have a very deep philosophy about human participation and I encourage people to be true to themselves in whatever they do, because I think that’s where they find the space and energy that Aligning the Board: The Chairman’s Secret 373 allows them to fulfil their greatest potential and to exercise their gifts that are unique to each person. I think that every board member has special gifts that are often not exercised because people are encouraged by social norms and inauthentic behaviour. (Participant 11, Chairman) Participant 11 draws attention to the challenge of being authentic primarily because of the feeling of being unable to express negative emotions, which has its toll on the individual. As noted by one participant ‘having a permanent grin on your face comes with a price’ (Participant 8, NED). One study participant went further and linked the suppression of negative emotions to ‘burn out’, with the only way of coping being to ultimately exit the board. You can suppress your feelings only for so long and then comes the time that you must do something about it. You must assess the situation and air things in the boardroom or if you think that the climate is not right for such discussion you must leave. There is no point in making yourself ill. In retrospect, after many sleepless nights and unsuccessful attempts to bring issues on the table, I resigned. It was the sensible thing to do. (Participant 2, CEO) Conclusion The study participants emphasised the social benefits of raising and deliberating the social experiences of the board such as the emotions evoked through undergoing critical events, the changing of board members or facing a setback. Through making these experiences the object of dialogue, encounters became legitimised which then allowed the board members to trust their own co-construction of events. The study emphasises the need for quality dialogue on the board where ‘truth’ is not seen to hold in any particular point of view, but more the dialogue between points of view. Within this process, the study participants emphasised the need for trust in order to permit deep-seated sentiments to emerge. One of the essential elements to building trust is the perception that each actor would raise sensitive concerns in a constructive way, given the space to do so (Butler, 1991; Mayer et al., 1995). Other factors that lead individuals to trust each other include behavioural constancy, fairness in the treatment of others, behavioural integrity, accurate capture of events, openness and naturally expressing concern for people and situations 374 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. (Butler, 1999; Whitener et al, 1998). ‘The best device for creating trust is to establish and support trustworthiness’ (Hardin, 1996: 29). Additionally dependability and emotional security provide for a unique form of trust which in turn allows for expressions of care and concern (Granovetter, 1985; Rempel et al., 1985). The study highlights that trust between critical actors can be achieved by facilitating communication dynamics that balance the forensic penetration of inquiry against the comfort of camaraderie amongst colleagues necessary for meaningful dialogue. Through so balancing, the actors involved can better grasp the underpinnings of the broader themes they face, one can listen, ask direct questions, present one’s ideas, argue, debate, and so forth. The defining characteristic of dialogic communication is that all of these speech acts are done in ways that hold one’s own position but allow others the space to hold theirs, and are profoundly open to hearing others’ positions without needing to oppose or assimilate them. When communicating dialogically, participants often have important agendas and purposes, but make them inseparable from their relationship in the moment with others who have equally strong but perhaps conflicting agendas and purposes. (Pearce and Pearce, 2004: 45) Creating space for communication through dialogue is an evolving delicate craft rather than a fixed technique which the study participants considered as only certain experienced chairmen have mastered. The making of space requires discipline and time, and demands a willingness to reflect on individual and group communication habits and power relationships. Equally important is the determination to experience different ways of relating to each other within a formal context such as the boardroom. The study participants profoundly recognised that dialogue promotes sharing of experiences, doubts, deep-seated emotions as well as pleasurable encounters between board members which in turn builds the trust to surface troubling sentiments. All this is done by opening up conversation about alternative ways of speaking and knowing which encourages imagination and through so doing averts a crisis mentality and provides important information for decision making. The social sharing of emotions serves an opportunity for reappraisal leading to new interpretations of events. In doing so, a further human need is identified that of satisfying the need for affiliation, status and Aligning the Board: The Chairman’s Secret 375 recognition (Fineman, 1993). This study has identified that where the surfacing of emotions becomes a board norm, the directors engage less in political behaviour. Boards need quality conversation. There is always room for a challenge, some disagreement and critical interjection. But if the boardroom ends up being a battle ground then it does nobody any good. The sharing of sentiments can be catalytic for a board. However, there is a fine balance to strike between being on somebody’s side, exchanging emotional support and being that critical friend. The end result is trust, rapport and not being driven by likes and dislikes. (Participant 17, Chairman) An effective board member needs to know how and when to challenge. Criticism, even when constructive, can be difficult for executive members to take. However when that balance is reached, those negative politics between us disappear and the positive politics of addressing each proposal on its merits and arguing on behalf of the position one has adopted, takes over. (Participant 19, Chairman) The study results emphasise that the social sharing of emotions helps form strong personal ties, which run much deeper than just interpersonal affects, namely the idiosyncrasy of likes and dislikes (Granovetter, 1973; Casciaro and Lobo, 2005). The study reported in this chapter highlights that if the board is to prepare itself to face stretching challenges, it is critical to find ways to surface those sentiments that have inhibited board members from not facing up to the issues that have lingered from the past. Whilst cognisant of the sensitivity of relationships, directors can make these sentiments the object of dialogue and in so doing legitimise the exploration of negativities through each individual’s co-construction of events. The findings indicate that the greatest challenge to dialogue is to surface inhibiting tensions. From such a perspective, it would be easy to conclude that it is solely the chairman’s responsibility to nurture an interactive board culture. The study findings however emphasise that each individual board member needs to separately and additionally consider how to find ways to raise positive and negative sentiments in order to help the board develop the skill and courage to speak openly and in a way that others find supportive. Yet despite this proviso, the study results highlight that unless the chairman creates a climate for surfacing past resentments for the benefit of the board, little progress will realistically be made in confronting continuous and damaging tensions. Perhaps 376 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. the most worrying concern is the blatant conspiracy of silence that can plague a board and the need to work through the spread of emotions that bedevil open discussion. This well-kept secret is only prised open by an act of courage, more often than not, initiated by the chairman. References Alexander, J.A., Fennell, M.L. and Halpern, M.T. (1993) Leadership instability in hospitals: the influence of board-CEO relations and organizational growth and decline, Administrative Science Quarterly, 38: 74–99. Alexandersson, M. (1994) Method och medvetande (Methods and Consciousness). Goteborg, Sweden: Acta Universitatis Gothobourgensis. Averill, J.R. (1980) A constructivist view of emotion. In R. Plutchik and H. Kellerman (Eds.), Emotion: Theory, Research and Experience, vol. 1, pp. 305–339. New York: Academic Press. Barblet, J.M. (2002) Moral indignation, class, inequality and justice: an exploration and revision of Ranulf. Theoretical Criminology, 6(3): 279–297. Barnard, C. (1938) The Functions of the Executive. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Bloch, S. (2005) What Makes a Great Board Chair. London: Whitehead Mann Group Report. Boje, D.M. (1991) The storytelling origination: towards a narrative view of strategic discourse. Administrative Science Quarterly, 36(1): 106–126. Bouwen, J. and Overlaet, B. (2001) Managing continuing in a period of takeover. Journal of Management Inquiry, 10(1): 27–38. Bovens, L. (1999) The two faces of Akratics Anonymous. Analysis, 59(4): 230–236. Brass, D.J. and Burkhardt, M.E. (1993) Potential power and power use: an investigation of structure and behaviour. Academy of Management Journal, 36: 441–470. Brison, S.J. Trauma narratives and the remaking of the self. In M. Bal, J. Crewe and L. Spitzer (Eds.), Acts of Memory: Cultural Recall in the Present, pp. 39–54. Hanover and London: University Press of New England. Butler, J.K., Jr. (1991) Toward understanding and measuring conditions of trust: evolution of a conditions of trust inventory. Journal of Management, 17: 643–663. Butler, J.K. (1999) Gender Trouble: Feminism and the Subversion of Identity. New York: Routledge. Cadbury, A. (2002) Corporate Governance and Chairmanship: A Personal View. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Casciaro, T. and Lobo, M.S. (2005) Competent jerks, lovable fools, and the formation of social networks. Harvard Business Review, 82(6): 93–100. Charan, R. (1998) Boards at Work, San Francisco, CA: Jossey Bass. Dalton, C. and Dalton, D.R. (2005) Boards of directors: utilizing empirical evidence in developing practical prescriptions. British Journal of Management, 16: S91–S97. Dalton, D.R., Daily, C., Certo, T. and Roengpitya, R. (2003) Meta-analyses of financial performance and equity: Fusion or confusion? Academy of Management Journal, 46: 13–26. Aligning the Board: The Chairman’s Secret 377 Dasborough, M.T. (2006) Cognitive asymmetry in employee emotional reactions to leadership behaviors. Leadership Quarterly, 17: 163–178. Dennison, D. (1992) Corporate Culture and Organizational Effectiveness, New York: Wiley. Fineman, S. (1993) Emotional arenas revisited. In S. Fineman (Ed.), Emotion in Organizations, Thousands Oaks, CA: Sage. Frijda, N.H. (1986) The Emotions, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Gabrielsson, J. and Huse, M. (2004) Context, behaviour & evolution. International Studies of Management & Organisation, 34(2): 11–36. Glaser, B. and Strauss, A.L. (1967) The Discovery of Grounded Theory: Strategies for Qualitative Research, Chicago: Aldine. Goleman, D. (1998) What makes a leader?, Harvard Business Review, 92–102. Granovetter, M. (1973) The strength of weak ties. American Journal of Sociology, 78(6):1360–1380. Granovetter, M. (1985) Economic action and social structure: the problem of embeddedness. American Journal of Sociology, 91: 481–510. Griffiths, P.E. (2004) Is emotion a natural kind? in R.C. Solomon (Ed.), Thinking about Feeling: Contemporary Philosophers on Emotions, pp. 233–249. New York: Oxford University Press. Hackman, J.R. and Wageman, R. (2005) A theory or team coaching. Academy of Management Review, 30: 269–287. Hall, J. and Rolfe, A. (2005) The Role of the FTSE 100 Chairman. London, UK: SpencerStuart. Hambrick, D.C. and Fukutomi, G.D.S. (1991) The seasons of a CEO’s tenure. Academy of Management Review, 16: 719–742. Hardin, R. (1996) Trustworthiness. Ethics, 107: 26–42. Harter, S. (2002) Authenticity. In C.R. Snyder and S.J. Lopez (Eds.), Handbook of Positive Psychology, pp. 382–394. New York: Oxford University Press. Hermalin, B. and Weisbach, M. (1988) The determinants of board composition. RAND Journal of Economics, 19(4): 589–606. Hernandez, M. (2008) Promoting stewardship behavior in organizations: a leadership model. Journal of Business Ethics, 80(1): 121–128. Herzberg, F., Mausner, B. and Synderman, B. (1959) The Motivation to Work, New York: Wiley. Higgs, D., (2003) Review of the Role and Effectiveness of Non-Executive Directors, London: The Stationery Office. Hillman, A.J. and Dalziel, T. (2003) Boards of directors and firm performance: integrating agency and resource dependence perspectives. Academy of Management Review, 28: 383–396. Hollanders, N. (2004) Does your chairman need to be Superman? Nature Biotechnology, 22: 131–132. Hossack, R. (2006) Together at the top: the critical relationship between the chairman and the CEO, Ivey Business Journal, Jan/Feb: 1–4. Jaskiewicz, P. and Klein, S. (2007) The impact of goal alignment on board composition and board size in family businesses. Journal of Business Research, 60: 1080–1089. Jehn, K.A. and Shah, P.P. (1997) Interpersonal relationships and task performance: an examination of mediating processes in friendship and acquaintance groups. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 72: 775–790. 378 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. Jensen, M. C. and Meckling, W. (1976) Theory of the firm: managerial behaviour, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4): 305–360. Jensen, M., and Murphy, K. (1990) Performance pay and top-management incentives. Journal of Political Economy, 98: 225–264. Kahn, B. E., and Isen, A. M. (1993) The influence of positive affect on variety seeking among safe, enjoyable products. Journal of Consumer Research, 20: 257–270. Kahn, W. A. (1992) To be fully there: psychological presence at work. Human Relations, 45(4): 321–349. Kakabadse, A. and Kakabadse, N. (2007) The return of the chairman. Business Strategy Review, 18(4): 52–65. Kakabadse, A. and Kakabadse, N. (2008) Leading the Board: The Six Disciplines of World-Class Chairman, London: Palgrave. Kakabadse, A. and Kakabadse, N. (2011) Minister of state: transactional politician or transformational leader? British Politics, 6(3): 345–378. Kearney, R. (2002) On Stories. London: Routledge. Kemper, T.D. (1978) A Social Interactional Theory of Emotions. New York: Wiley. Kotter, J. and Heskett, J. (1992) Corporate Culture and Performance. New York: Free Press. Larkin, T.J., and Larkin, S. (1994) Communicating Change – How to Win Employee Support for New Business Directions. New York: McGraw-Hill. Leblanc, R. (2004) What’s wrong with corporate governance: a note. Corporate Governance, 12(4): 436–441. Leblanc, R. and Gillies, J.M. (2005) Inside the Boardroom: How Boards Really Work and the Coming Revolution in Corporate Governance. New York: Wiley. Leininger, M.M. (1985) Ethnography and ethnonursing: models and modes of qualitative data analysis. In M.M. Leininger (Ed.), Qualitative Research Methods in Nursing, pp. 33–72. Orlando, FL: Grune & Stratton. Levrau, A. and van den Berghe, L. (2007) Identifying Key Determinants of Effective Boards of Directors, Vlerick Leuven Gent Working Paper Series 2007/11. Lieblich, A., Tuval-Mashiach, R. and Zibler, T. (1998) Narrative Research, Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. Lorsch, J.W. and Zelleke, A. (2005) Should the CEO be the chairman. MIT Sloan Management Review, 46(2): 70–74. Mace, M. (1971) Directors: Myth and Reality. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press. Mayer, R.C. Davis, J.H. and Schoorman, F.D. (1995) An integrative model of organizational trust. Academy of Management Review, 20(3): 709–734. McNulty, T., Roberts, J. and Stiles, P. (2003) Creating Accountability Within the Board: The Work of the Non-Executive Director. London: HM DTI and Treasury. Melle-Hernandez, M. (2005) Cómo valora el Mercado de valores español la adopción de planes de opciones sobre acciones para directivos y consejeros? Investigaciones Económicas, 29(1): 73–115. Miller, D. T. and Nelson, L.D. (2002) Seeing approach motivation in the avoidance behavior of others: implications for an understanding of pluralistic ignorance, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 83: 1066–1075. Aligning the Board: The Chairman’s Secret 379 Minar N., Burkhart, R., Langton, C. and Askenazi, M. (1996) A Toolkit for Building Multi-agent Simulations. Santa Fe Institute. Mohrman, S., Cohen, S. and Mohrman, M.A. (1995) Teams and Technology. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press. Noelle-Neumann, E. (1993) The Spiral of Silence: Public Opinion – Our Social Skin. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Pearce, B.W. and Pearce, K.A. (2004) Taking a communication perspective on dialogue. In R. Anderson, L.A. Baxter and K.N. Cissna (Eds.), Dialogue. Theorizing Difference in Communication Studies, pp. 39–56. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications. Pentland, B.T. (1999) Building process theory with narrative: from description to explanation. Academy of Management Review, 24(6): 711–724. Perrow, C. (1961) The analysis of goals in complex organisations, American Sociological Review, 854–66. Pettigrew, A. and McNulty, T. (1995) Power and influence in and around the boardroom, Human Relation, 48(8): 845–873. Pfeffer, J. (1981) Power in Organizations, Marshfield, MA: Pitman Publications. Reissman, C.K. (1993) Narrative Analysis, Newbury Park: Sage. Rempel, J.K., Holmes, J.G. and Zanna, M.P. (1985) ‘Trust in close relationships’, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 49: 95–112. Roberts, J. and Stiles, P. (1999) The relationship between chairmen and chief executives: competitive or complementary roles? Long Range Planning, 32: 36–48. Roberts, J., McNulty, T. and Stiles, P. (2005) Beyond agency conceptions of the work of the non-executive director: creating accountability in the boardroom, British Journal of Management, 16 (supplement 1): 5–26. Rosenberg, M. (2004) Essays on Stock Option Compensation and the Role of Incentives and Risk, Swedish School of Economics and Business Administration. Ryfe, D.M. (2006) Narrative and deliberation in small group forums, Journal of Applied Communication Research, 34(1): 72–93. Semler, S. W. (1997) Systematic agreement: a theory of organizational alignment. Human Resource Development Quarterly, 8: 23–40. Shamir, B. and Eilam, G. (2005) What’s your story? – a life-stories approach to authentic. leadership development, The Leadership Quarterly, 16: 395–417. Sias, P.M., Heath, R.G, Perry, T., Silva, D. and Fix, B. (2004) Narratives of workplace friendship deterioration’, Journal of Social and Personal Relationships, 21(3): 321–340. Sonnenfeld, J. (2004) Good governance and the misleading myths of bad metrics, Academy of Management Executive, 18, 108–113. Sousa, R.D. (2004) Emotions what I know, what I’d like to think I know, and what I’d like to think. In R.C. Solomon (Ed.), Thinking about Feeling: Contemporary Philosophers on Emotions, pp. 61–75. New York: Oxford University Press. Steiner, I.D. (1972) Group Process and Productivity. New York: Academic Press. Sundaramurthy, C. and Lewis, M. (2003) Control and collaboration: paradoxes of governance. Academy of Management Review, 28: 397–415. Taylor, J.R. (2001) The rational organization reconsidered: an exploration of some of the organizational implications of self-organizing. Communication Theory, 11: 137–177. 380 Nada K. Kakabadse et al. Taylor, S.J. and Bogdan, R. (1984) Introduction to Qualitative Research Methods: The Search for Meanings. New York: Wiley. Watson, M. (2008) Euphoria, Risk and Corporate Scandal: Enron and the Commercial Corruption of Expertise within Financialised Captialism, Working Paper. University of Warwick. Centre for the Study of Globalisation and Regionalisation, Coventry. Westphal, J.D. (1999) Collaboration in the boardroom: behavioral and performance consequences of CEO-board social ties, Academy of Management Journal, 42(1): 7–25. Westphal, J.D. and Bednar, M.K. (2005) Pluralistic ignorance in corporate boards and firms’ strategic persistence in response to low firm performance. Administrative Science Quarterly, 50(2): 262–298. Whitener, E.M., Brodt, S.E., Korsgaard, M.A. and Werner, J.M. (1998) Managers as initiators of trust: an exchange relationship framework for understanding managerial trustworthy behavior. Academy of Management Review, 23(3): 513−530. Williamson, O.E. (1967) Hierarchical control and optimum firm size. Journal of Political Economy, 75(2): 123–138. Index Abeline paradox, 220 absenteeism, 58, 65 academic institutions, 25–6 Acciona, 120, 125 accountability, 106, 205, 217–18, 312 advisory role, 178, 190–1 age, 122 of board members, 99–100 of chairman, 342–56 agency problem, 11, 16, 316, 362–3 agency theory, 47, 48, 77, 361–2, 363 alignment, 360–76 Anglo-American corporate governance model, 28, 44, 48–9, 53, 63–4, 110, 195, 311, 321, 332 Anglo-American Platinum, 120, 125 Anglo-American relations, 16 annual reports, 87–8 Apple, 20, 23, 26, 52 appraisals, of directors, 230–4 Arab Spring, 18, 22 arms exports, 17 Asia, executive pay in, 108 audit committees, 176, 192 austerity programmes, 30 Australia, 112 banking sector, 14, 17–18 Bank of New York, 14 Bank of Scotland, 14 Barclays, 26 Belgian Corporate Governance Code, 212, 272 Bilderberg group, 95 Bill of Rights, 44 black box, 204 Black Tuesday, 13 Blackwater, 17 board committees, 112, 191–3, 222–3, 246, 257 board dialogue, 3, 224–5, 366–76 board dynamics, 228–9, 260–2, 264, 292, 363–4, 366–76 board effectiveness assessment tool, 4, 116–21, 153–82 board information, 241–6 board meetings, 216 agenda setting for, 238 effective, 237–40, 263 engagement outside of, 239–40 flaws in, 239 minutes of, 242–3 time management for, 237–9, 280–1 board members age of, 99–100, 122 assessment of, 230–4, 262–3 communication among, 297, 302–3, 304, 307, 366–76 compensation of, 201–3 demographics of, 298, 300–1 distance between Chairman and, 6 diversity of, 97–102, 122–3 education process for, 247–9 ethnicity of, 100–2 gender of, 97–9, 122–3, 196–7, 251 induction of, 247–9 professionalism of, 228–37, 262–3 relationships between, 254, 363–4 re-nomination of, 258–60 roles and responsibilities of, 5 turnover, 109 typologies of, 235–7 boards of directors advisory/support role of, 178, 190–1 alignment of, 360–76 CEO and, 167–9, 188, 198, 312–13, 328–30 challenges facing, 3 as collegial bodies, 188–93, 206, 226–7, 260–1 composition of, 193–8, 207–8, 249–60, 264, 292 corporate performance and, 153 cultural dynamics, 4, 110–12, 119, 124 381 382 Index boards of directors – continued decision-making role of, 162, 163, 189, 211–65 diversity, 27–30, 97–114, 116, 118, 122–3, 196–7, 208, 218–19, 251, 257 effectiveness of, 111–12, 116–21, 137–51, 153–82, 312, 363–4 empowerment of, 159 evaluation of, 111–12, 144–9, 153–82 independence of, 106–7, 190, 193–6, 207, 218–19, 250–1, 318–20, 328–30 information for, 241–6, 263–4 inside-out perspective on, 2 internationalisation of, 102–3 leadership, 5, 104–9, 118, 123–4, 268–9, 342–3 leadership role of, 164–70, 180 management and, 161, 166–7, 198–200, 313 monitoring role of, 174–8, 180, 181, 190–1, 207, 250, 312, 313, 362 optimal size of, 249–50 outside advisors for, 245–6 outside-in perspective on, 2 oversight function of, 312–13 performance of, 4, 163–4 recruitment, 103–4, 123, 252–8, 285 redesigning, 11–33 reinvention of, 4, 95–126 roles of, 11, 163–78, 190–1, 200–3 selection process for, 251–2 strategic role of, 170–4, 180–1, 190–1, 344 structure of, 22–7, 103–14, 197, 200–1, 207, 271–2 supervisory function, 193 task performance, 162–78 tensions and tradeoffs in, 4–5 trade-offs by, 187–209 Board Support Survey, 246 board vacancy profile, 254–8 bonuses, 53, 108 bounded rationality, 215 Branson, Richard, 116 Brazil, 101 BRIC countries, 101, 114 British Broadcasting Corporation (BBC), 25, 109 British East India Company, 12–13, 16, 29, 30 business context, 159–60 Cadbury Code, 26 capital, 26, 28 capitalism, 17, 27–8 Central Intelligence Agency (CIA), 3, 68 CEO, see chief executive officer (CEO) chairman of the board, 268–88 age of, 6, 342–56 assessment of, 234, 285 attributes of effective, 348–9 board alignment and, 360–76 CEO and, 5, 104, 106, 268–72, 288, 292–3, 296 ceremonial, 286–7 challenges facing, 272–6 corporate performance and, 343–4 as decision facilitator, 281–4 decision-making and, 227–8, 274–84, 288 decision-making style of, 276–80 demographics of, 298 development of, 284–5 dual CEO role for, 311–35 effectiveness of, 297, 302, 306 future of, 284–7 high-performing, 342–56 independence of, 106–7 influence of, 363–4 interaction between board members and, 6 isolation of, 6 leadership attributes of, 292–308 nomenclature, 271 role of, 5, 272–6, 292–7, 301, 303–6, 342–9, 360–76 selection criteria for, 287 surveys on, 297–308 time investment by, 287 as time manager, 280–1 tips and tricks for non-executive, 286 Cheney, Dick, 17 Index Chevron, 17 chief executive officer (CEO) background of, 103–4, 108–9 board and, 167–9, 188, 198, 328–30 Chairman and, 5, 104, 106, 268–72, 288, 292–3, 296 in Chinese state-owned enterprises, 3–4, 75–91 dissenting opinions and, 222 dual chairman role for, 311–35 influence on decision-making, 227 leadership of, 325–8 monitoring of, 312 pay levels for, 45–69, 75, 107, 320–1, 330–2, 344 power of, 312–13, 344 role of, 5, 107, 292–3, 296–7, 301, 303–4, 305–6 talent of, 324–5 turnover, 109 China, 15, 23, 101 Confucius, 29 corporate governance in, 75–91 executive remuneration in, 3–4, 75–91 China Gas Company, 14 China Mobile, 29 China Security Regulatory Commission (CSRC), 87, 89 Cigna Insurance, 14 Citibank, 14 cities, 26–7 Code of Corporate Governance, 95, 296 cognitive diversity, 218 collective decision-making, 189, 211–16 chairman’s role in, 274–84 consensus and, 226–8 dissent and, 219–26 effective, 218–19 group think and, 217–18 independence of, 218–19 collective wisdom, 270 collectivist cultures, 29 collegial bodies, 188–93, 206, 226–7, 253, 260–1 colonialism, 16 commodities, 28 383 Communications Assistance for Law Enforcement Act, 23 communications technology, 28 communism, 17 Communist Party of China (CPC), 30, 88 communitarian thinking, 110 compensation packages, 108 see also executive remuneration competencies, 255–7 competition, 17 concessionist thinking, 110, 124 confidentiality, 204 conflict management, 225–6 conflicts of interest, 106, 108 conformity, 217 Confucius, 29 Congo, 18 consensus, 4–5, 206, 217, 221, 226–8, 352–3 constructive criticism, 219–23 consumer goods, 26 Consumer Protection Act, 95 continuing education, for directors, 247–9 corporate collapse, symptoms of, 95 corporate context, 159–60 corporate culture, 22–7 corporate Gini index (CGI), 3, 55–7, 62–8 corporate governance, 311–12 Anglo-American model of, 28, 44, 48–9, 53, 63–4, 110, 195, 311, 321, 332 ‘best fit’ structure for, 157–62 China, 75–91 codes, 4, 137–44, 212, 249–52, 294, 296 corporate context factors affecting, 159–60 executive remuneration and, 52–5, 75 external contingency factors affecting, 158–9 externally monitored, 138–40 history of, 319 holistic framework for, 153–82 internal assessment of, 144–9 384 Index corporate governance – continued internal contingency factors affecting, 160–2 Latin model of, 63 Madisonian model of, 318–19 national frameworks for, 140–1 practices, 95 regulations, 95, 187, 314 U.S., 318–35 value drivers, 142–3 corporate performance board practice and, 153 chairman and, 343–4 corporate Gini index and, 62–8 executive pay and, 51–69, 320–1 income inequality and, 57–69 remuneration based on, 202–3 corporate scandals, 25, 26, 52, 104, 112, 314, 316, 342–3 corporate social responsibility (CSR), 16, 110, 126, 165 corporations characteristics of, 13 cyclical change, 14–16 dominance of, 28 emerging market, 101 expectations for, 110 externalities affecting, 14–15 future role of, 31–3 geo-politics and, 16–19 headquarters of, 29 interests of, 24 overview of, 12–13 power of, 18, 95 purpose of, 19–21 remuneration in, 3 role of, 3 theories of, 24–5 wealth controlled by, 22 corruption, 17 critical stakeholders, 205 cronyism, 17 crystallized intelligence, 354 CSR, see corporate social responsibility (CSR) cultural dynamics, 4, 110–12, 119, 124 culture, corporate, 22–7 cyclical change, 14–16 decision-making board meetings and, 216 chairman and, 227–8 chairman’s role in, 227–8, 274–84 collective, 189, 211–16, 217–28 collegial, 188–93, 206, 226–7, 253, 260–1 consensus and, 226–8 default, 278 effective, 211–65 expertise, 234–5 eye-to-eye, 278 facilitation of, by chairman, 281–4 influence of group members on, 217–18, 261 information for, 241–6 non-board members and, 227 older individuals and, 353–5 postponement of, 227 process, 216 professional behaviour and, 228–37 role, of board, 162, 163 self-sufficient, 277–8 steps for constructive, 224 suggestions for, 215 traditional, 278 de-humanisation, 31 democracy, 15 Deng, Xioping, 79 Denmark, 97, 99 developing countries, capital inflows, 15–16 development cycle, 28 dialogue, 3, 224–5, 366–76 digital music industry, 23 director information, 240–9, 263–4 director typologies, 235–7 disclosure, 205, 208–9 dissent, 219–26, 261–2 diversity, 4, 27–30, 97–114, 116, 118, 122–3, 196–7, 208, 218–19, 251, 257 Dodd-Frank Act, 17, 95 Dow Jones Sustainability Index, 20, 110 dual board structure, 106–7, 109, 124, 292–3, 311–35 Dupont, 14, 24 Index Durantez, Miriam Gonzales, 125 Dutch Enterprise Chamber, 242 DynCorp, 17 earnings per share (EPS), 64 East Asia, 28 East India Company, 12–13, 16, 29, 30 eco-corporations, 20–1 ecoDa, 246 economics-based theories, of executive pay, 48, 50 economic value added (EVA), 51–2 Edison, Thomas, 26 education, 25–6, 31, 108, 123, 247–9 effective engagement, 6 Egypt, 18, 26 elites, 22, 103–14 emerging market corporations (EMCs), 101 Emirates Airlines, 30 emotional intelligence, 294 employee performance measures, 58, 65 employee stock options (ESOs), 52 employment, 19, 31 Enron, 25 Entwistle, George, 109 environmental degradation, 19, 27 environmental disasters, 18–19 Environmental Performance Index (EPI), 19 ethnicity, 100–2 Europe, 126 executive pay in, 108 sovereign debt crisis, 15, 96 European Central Bank (ECB), 15 European Data Retention Directive, 23 Eurozone, 18 executive directors, 45, 82, 190–1, 197, 198–200, 207, 240 executive performance monitoring, 168–9 remuneration and, 51–69, 170 executive remuneration, 3, 19, 26, 320–1, 344 board leadership and, 96 board’s role in setting, 170 for CEO, 320–1, 330–2, 344 385 in China, 3–4, 75–91 corporate Gini index (CGI) of, 55–7 corporate performance and, 51–69, 170 disclosure of, 87–8 evolution of, 60 governance and, 52–5, 75 income inequality and, 44–5 mainstream perspective on, 52–5 perceptions of, 82–4 performance and, 170, 320–1 process of setting, 84–7 regulatory action on, 54–5 rise in, 44–7, 75, 107 standards for, 90–1 structure of, 78–9 theories of, 47–51, 77–8 trends in, 108 in U.S., 45–7, 108 expert power, 274 external contingency factors, 158–9 external norms, 230–4 Facebook, 14 female board members, 97–9, 122–3, 251 financial regulations, 17 financial sector, 17–18 food industry, 22–3 Ford, Henry, 26 foreign direct investment, 30 France, 15 frugal engineering, 115 FTSE4Good index, 20, 110 future trends, 30–1 Gazprom, 29–30 gender balance, 97–9, 122–3, 196–7, 251 General Electric, 14, 24 geo-politics, 16–19, 29 Germany, 24 Ghohosn, Carlos, 115 Gini index, 55–7 Global Competitiveness Report, 112 global financial crisis (GFC), 13–15, 17, 75–6, 95, 113, 194, 204, 314, 344 global governance, 21–2 386 Index globalisation, 18, 28, 44, 96 good governance, 194–5 Google, 23 governance corporate. see corporate governance country, 24 effective, 229–30 executive remuneration and, 52–5, 75 global, 21–2 good, 194–5 inside-out perspective on, 2 internal, 177 outside-in perspective on, 2 publications on, 1 governance codes, 4, 137–44, 212, 249–52, 294, 296 Great Eastern Life Assurance, 14 Greece, 15, 18, 26 green agenda, 18 group decision-making, see collective decision-making group dynamics, 213 group norms, 221 group think, 217–18, 261 GUBERNA, 151n1, 202, 229, 285 Halliburton, 17 Harrods, 14 headquarters, 29 herding, 218, 261 Honduras, 17 Hong Kong and Eu Yan Sang, 14 hostile takeovers, 344 human rights abuses, 17 Iacocca, Lee, 344 IBM, 14, 24 income inequality, 44–5 corporate performance and, 57–69 measurement of corporate, 55–7 income scale, 56 independence, 106–7, 190, 193–6, 207, 218–19, 250–1, 318–20, 328–30 India, 15, 101, 114–16 indigenous populations, 29 Indonesia, 15 induction process, 247–9 information, board, 241–6, 263–4 innovation, 4, 23, 26, 31 capital and, 28 jugaad, 113–16, 119–20, 124–5 patterns, 24 sustainable, 4, 113–16, 119–20, 124–5 value creation through, 25 insiders, 251 Institute of Charted Secretaries and Administrators (ICSA), 246 intellectual property, 23 Interactive Corp, 52 internal contigency factors, 160–2 internal governance, 177 internal norms, 230–4 internationalisation, 102–3, 122 International Labour Organisation (ILO), 19, 55 International Monetary Fund (IMF), 21 Iraq, 18 Ireland, 15, 26 Italy, 15 Japan, 15, 46 Johansson, Leif, 46 Johnson Controls, 123 JP Morgan, 14 jugaad innovation, 113–16, 119–20, 124–5 Juncker, Jean-Cleade, 107 key performance indicators, 176 Kodak, 24 Komatsu, 124 Kongo Gumi, 12 Latin corporate governance model, 63 leadership, 4, 5, 104–9, 118, 123–4, 164–70, 180, 268–9, 271, 292– 308, 325–8, 342–3 Lehman Brothers, 14 Leveson Inquiry, 23 Libya, 18, 26 life expectancy, 27 limited liability, 30 Limited Liability Act, 13 Lloyds TSB, 14 Index lobbying, 17 Lockheed Martin, 17 London riots, 22 Magna Carta, 44 Malaysia, 15, 23 Malian Empire, 22 management model, 161 Mansa Masu I, 22 media, 23 mentoring, 4 mercantilism, 12 Merck, 14 Mercury, 52 Microsoft, 14 migration, 31 mobile communications, 23 monitoring, 4, 174–8, 180, 181, 190–1, 207, 250, 312, 313, 362 multiple directorships, 123, 125 Murdoch, Rupert, 109 myelin, 354 national debt, 15, 16 National Foreign Trade Council (NFTC), 17 natural resources, 19 neo-liberalism, 15 Nestle, 14 networks, 17, 26, 27, 32–3, 101, 103–14 Newscorp, 25, 26 News of the World scandal, 23 New Zealand, 112 NIFO (Nose In Fingers Out) method, 240 Nigeria, 17 Nokia, 23 nomination committee, 196, 251–2, 253 non-executive directors, 87, 140, 144, 159, 162, 166, 188–94, 197–203, 206–9, 215, 221, 222, 227, 229, 235, 240–5, 250, 263–4, 360, 366 norms, 230–4 Northern Rock, 14 Norway, 99 Occupy Wall Street (OWS), 44 old boys networks, 251 387 oligopoly, 17 one-tier board structure, 197, 207 organisation theory, 269 outside board advisors, 245–6 oversight function, 312–13 ownership power, 274 Oxford University Press, 14 Pepsi, 17 performance competence, 324–5 performance management, 176, 190–1 performance targets, 190 Petro China, 16 phronesis, 6, 351–3, 355–6 population growth, 28, 30, 113 population principle, 56 poverty, 19 power perspective approach, to executive pay, 47, 48, 49, 77 practical wisdom, 351–2, 353, 355–6 prestige power, 274 private security, 17 professional directors, 240 professionalism, 208, 228–37, 262–3 profit maximisation, 26 public private partnerships (PPPs), 30 public sector expenditures, 30 Qatar, 18 quantitative easing, 15 questioning style, 226 recruitment process, 103–4, 123, 252–8, 285 red flags, 174–8 regulations, 111 on board nomination, 252 corporate governance, 95, 187, 314 on executive pay, 54–5 relational networks, 26, 27, 32–3, 103–14 remuneration, see executive remuneration Renault-Nissan, 115 re-nomination, 258–60 resource scarcity, 19, 27 Rice, Condoleezza, 17 ring-fencing, 17 388 Index risk management, 176 role separation, 6, 104, 106, 268–9, 271–2, 292–3, 311–35 Rolls Royce, 14 Royal Mail, 14 Russia, 23, 29–30, 101 SABIC, 29 salami technique, 227 Samsung, 23 Sarbanes Oxley Act, 26, 344 Scandinavia, 99, 112, 126, 196 school social networks, 101 Schweppes, 14 sea levels, 30 Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), 252, 314, 344 self-regulatory principles, 158, 163 sense-breaking, 352 SEOs,see state-owned enterprises (SEOs) shareholder model, 161 shareholder return, 165 shareholders, 195–6 Shell, 17 Siemens AG, 124 Simon Property Group, 19 Singapore, 112 Smith, Adam, 13, 29 social inequality, 3 social networks, 101 social reasoning, 354 social reform, 28 social unrest, 22 socio-comparative theories, of executive pay, 49, 50–1 socio-political perspective, on executive pay, 48 soft skills, 233 South Africa, 5–6, 16, 24, 112, 295–6, 299–301 sovereign debt crisis, 15, 96 Spain, 15, 26 specialisation, 191–3, 257 stakeholders critical, 205 interests of, 164–5, 180 start-ups, 160, 203 state-owned enterprises (SEOs), 29–30 executive remuneration in, 3–4, 75–91 stewardship theory, 269, 363 stock options, 52, 108, 344, 362 Stora Kopparberg, 13 strategy, 170–4, 180–1, 190–1, 344 structural power, 274 student plagiarism, 25 sub-prime mortgage crisis, 25, 95 succession leadership, 123–4 succession planning, 168 Sugar, Alan, 116 Suncor Energy, 24, 120, 126 supervisory function, 193 surveillance, 23 sustainability, 18, 20, 24 sustainability index, 20 sustainable innovation, 4, 113–16, 119–20, 124–5 Svanberg, Carl-Henric, 46 Sweden, 46, 99 Swiss Federal Institute (SFI), 22 Syria, 18, 21 Takamatsu Corporation, 12 talent, 324–5 talent management, 168 task performance, 162–78 Tata, 101 taxation, 20, 31 technological change, 14 technology, 23 communications, 28 future trends, 30–1 industries, 23 Thailand, 15 time management, 237–9, 280–1 tournament theory, 48, 49–50 trade-offs, 4–5, 187–209 in board composition, 193–8, 207–8 between direction and control, 207 to ensure collegial atmosphere, 188–93, 206 to ensure non-executive role performance, 200–3 to reach consensus, 206 to reach professional board, 208 in relation between executives and non-executives, 198–200 Index for transparency, 204–5, 208–9 transfer principle, 55 transnational corporations, see corporations transparency, 20, 25, 54, 106, 177–8, 204–5, 208–9, 217–18, 288 trust, 26, 27, 328–30 turnover, 58, 65, 109 Unilever, 14 unitary leadership, 106, 250, 268–9, 271 United Kingdom, 15, 23 austerity programmes, 30 banking sector, 17–18 executive pay in, 45 London riots, 22 United States, 23, 126 chairman/CEO/president in, 6 corporate governance in, 318–35 executive pay in, 45–7, 108, 320–1 national debt, 16 quantitative easing policy, 15 389 universities, 25–6 vacancy profile, 254–8 value, 4 value creation, 25 Vestas Wind Systems, 120 Volcker Rule, 17 wages, 19, 60, 61–2 Walker Report, 247, 287 Walmart, 19, 25, 28 water scarcity, 19 wealth distribution, corporate, 57–69 wealthiest persons, 22 Wealth of Nations (Smith), 13 wisdom, 6 women, on boards of directors, 97–9, 122–3, 196–7, 251 World Bank, 21 World Economic Forum (WEF), 56 World Health Organisation (WHO), 21 World War I, 16 World War II, 16