MACROECONOMIC CONSEQUENCES OF PEACE: AMERICAN RADICAL ECONOMISTS AND THE PROBLEM OF MILITARY KEYNESIANISM, 19381975 Downloaded by Mr Tim Barker At 07:40 30 April 2019 (PT) Tim Barker ABSTRACT This chapter is a contribution to the intellectual history of the anxiety that full employment in the modern United States depended somehow on military spending. This discourse (conveniently abbreviated as “military Keynesianism”) is vaguely familiar, but its contours and transit still await a full study. The chapter shows the origins of the idea in the left-Keynesian milieu centered around Harvard’s Alvin Hansen in the late 1930s, with a particular focus on the diverse group that cowrote the 1938 stagnationist manifesto An Economic Program for American Democracy. After a discussion of how these young economists participated in the World War II mobilization, the chapter considers how questions of stagnation and military stimulus were marginalized during the years of the high Cold War, only to be revived by younger radicals. At the same time, it demonstrates the existence of a community of discourse that directly links the Old Left of the 1930s and 1940s with the New Left of the 1960s and 1970s, and cuts across the division between left-wing social critique and liberal statecraft. Keywords: Keynesian economics; military Keynesianism; secular stagnation; military-industrial complex; Paul Sweezy; permanent arms economy Including a Symposium on 50 Years of the Union for Radical Political Economics Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology, Volume 37A, 1129 Copyright r 2019 by Emerald Publishing Limited All rights of reproduction in any form reserved ISSN: 0743-4154/doi:10.1108/S0743-41542019000037A004 11 Downloaded by Mr Tim Barker At 07:40 30 April 2019 (PT) 12 TIM BARKER “Some weeks ago,” wrote Herbert Gintis in 1970, “a bright young Marxist economist, lecturing at Harvard University, was asked by a member of his audience the probable effects of a drastic cut in ‘defense’ spending on the American economy. Perennial question!” The bright young Marxist gave the “perennial Marxist answer,” denying that “the American economy could, either in the short run or the long, adjust to an economic atmosphere of peace.” Gintis, then a recent PhD employed at Harvard as a lecturer, initially doubted the speaker’s claim, but upon reflection agreed that “the success of Keynesian economics itself in the United States has been predicated upon the growth of the war machine since the Second World War” (Gintis, 1970, p. 245). Gintis was right that the question and the answer were old. But they were not quite perennial. As his own reference to the situation “since the Second World War” suggests, the argument had its origins in the late 1930s and 1940s, the conjuncture that brought together the Keynesian revolution with unprecedented levels of spending on hot and cold wars. Back in 1947, another untenured Harvard economist, Paul Sweezy, had asked a capacity crowd in Littauer Auditorium, “What chance is there, looking at our depressions, that the American capital economy can passively recover its post-depression equilibrium without the outside shot in the arm of war?” (Schumpeter Sees, 1947). This chapter is a contribution to the intellectual history of the anxiety that full employment depended somehow on military spending. This discourse (conveniently shorthanded as “military Keynesianism”) is vaguely familiar, but its contours and transit still await a full study.1 Here, I show the origins of the idea in Sweezy’s left-Keynesian milieu, with a particular focus on the diverse group that cowrote the 1938 stagnationist manifesto An Economic Program for American Democracy. I discuss how questions of stagnation and military stimulus were marginalized during the years of the high Cold War, only to be revived by younger radicals like Gintis. At the same time, I demonstrate the existence of a community of discourse that directly links the Old Left of the 1930s and 1940s with the New Left of the 1960s and 1970s, and cuts across the division between left-wing social critique and liberal statecraft. FROM STAGNATION TO WAR For military Keynesianism to be understood as a solution, economists first had to diagnose capitalism with a chronic savings glut and suggest permanent public investment as the cure.2 In the United States, this line of thinking was developed by Alvin H. Hansen and his circle, largely at Harvard University, in the late 1930s.3 Hansen’s 1938 AEA presidential lecture, “Economic Progress and Declining Population Growth,” is the best remembered articulation of the secular stagnation thesis. But just as politically influential was a short book published by Hansen’s followers the same year, entitled An Economic Program for American Democracy. The book was presented as the product of collective discussion and composition by “seven Harvard and Tufts economists,” including names both familiar and obscure: Richard V. Gilbert, Lorie Tarshis, Paul M. Sweezy, Maxine Y. Sweezy, John D. Wilson, Arthur W. Stuart, and Downloaded by Mr Tim Barker At 07:40 30 April 2019 (PT) Macroeconomic Consequences of Peace 13 George H. Hildebrand, Jr. Emile Despres, Alan R. Sweezy (Paul’s elder brother), Walter S. Salant, and perhaps others participated but withheld their names because they were working for the government at the time.4 According to Herbert Stein, the Economic Program pamphlet was “Keynesian in analysis, stagnationist in diagnosis, and all-out in prescription, going beyond deficit spending to drastic measures of income redistribution for the purpose of stimulating consumption” (Stein, 1969, p. 165). A surprise best seller, by early 1939 the book “began to assume a relationship with the New Deal that was later pre-empted by Keynes’ General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money itself” (May, 1981, pp. 149150). Franklin Roosevelt himself, who had recently embraced deficit stimulus for the first time, recommended the book to his son (Stein, 1969, p. 487 n.70). This primal version of American Keynesianism struck one business economist as “not greatly distant from neoMarxian thinking” and pushed corporate organizations like the Committee for Economic Development to developing their own, more constrained, approaches to fiscal policy (Collins, 1981, p. 97). The fearful businessmen were perhaps not far off the mark. Paul Sweezy would later recall that “it was hard to draw the line in those days between the left New Dealers and the beginnings of the Marxist movement” (Phelps, 1999, p. 38). Classes on socialist and Marxian economics were regularly offered by Harvard instructors including Joseph Schumpeter. Paul Sweezy (1942b) presented in English for the first time many of the debates about underconsumption, imperialism, and crisis tendencies that had long exercised European Marxists, while also demonstrating through reproduction schema how Marx and Keynes might begin to be reconciled. Drawing on Keynes, a Marxist could conclude that: socialists should […] take the lead in organizing mass support behind a policy of large-scale government spending, since at the present time this is the only policy which can save democratic institutions and thus keep the way clear for eventually winning the masses to a socialist position. (P. Sweezy, 1938) From Marx, and his inheritors such as Rosa Luxemburg, a Keynesian could learn the role of income distribution in determining output, as well as the importance of secular, evolutionary patterns of accumulation, stagnation, and crisis. The latter perspective was somewhat at odds with the General Theory’s assumption of “a given state of technique, resources and costs,” though it could draw on stray suggestions that “the richer the community, the wider will tend to be the gap between its actual and its potential production” (Keynes, 1936, pp. 21, 28). James Tobin (a Harvard undergraduate and precocious Keynesian in 1938) remembered that while the Economic Program authors included both “Marxists” and “just Keynesians,” the resulting text saw “Marxism […] crowded out, and the result was liberal Keynesianism rather than socialism” (Tobin, 1988, p. 37). But the book’s conclusion bore a distinct left-wing impress. If the depression was not ended by “conscious social endeavor,” the authors warned, businessmen might replace democracy with dictatorship. Then, “like the sorcerer who could no longer control the forces of the netherworld which he 14 TIM BARKER had called up by his spell, business would be overwhelmed by its own creature.” If this sentence clearly recalls the sorcery metaphors of the Communist Manifesto, what follows anticipates the postwar discourse of military Keynesianism: Such a dictatorship would revive economic activity but it would be activity devoted increasingly to producing weapons of death and destruction which sooner or later plunge the country into a holocaust of slaughter and bloodshed. (Gilbert et al., 1938, pp. 9091) The image of Nazi Germany clearly stood behind such rhetoric. In fall 1940, Paul Sweezy worried that: Downloaded by Mr Tim Barker At 07:40 30 April 2019 (PT) Our armament program has just begun; as it expands there will be an end to economic stagnation just as there was in Germany. Our own ruling class will, if it can, seize the opportunity to impose upon us a regime indistinguishable in principle from that which has been imposed upon the German people. (P. Sweezy, 1940) Paul’s wife, Maxine Y. Sweezy, another avowedly Marxist Economic Program contributor, wrote a dissertation on the Nazi economy (Woolston, 1941).5 The German experience also informed the work of Michał Kalecki, the Polish-born socialist whose work on business cycles anticipated Keynes and profoundly inspired figures such as Paul Sweezy and Joan Robinson (Toporowski, 2016). In a celebrated essay, Kalecki suggested that “armaments are the backbone of the policy of fascist full employment.” Even in peacetime capitalist democracies, he warned, business resistance to nonmilitary public investment would still seriously constrain the possibility of full employment (Kalecki, 1943, p. 327). Even those less radical than Paul Sweezy feared that a rearmament-driven recovery could mean American fascism. In 1939, prominent New Deal agricultural advisor Mordecai Ezekiel warned that the absence of peacetime planning would inevitably bring war planning: If once we engage in war, there will be no hesitancy to plan […] democracy shall have little place in such planning […] If the war lasts long enough, we may expect to see here too concentration camps, federal penitentiaries, and near the front lines, firing squads, to welcome all those who as “labor agitators” “subversive journalists,” or “enemy sympathizers,” dare expose the propaganda of our own wartime Fascism. (Ezekiel, 1939, p. 5) But as Germany declared war on the United States and the Soviet Union, the economists of the New Deal and the Popular Front came to see wartime planning not as the road to fascism but as the only alternative to it. No one had sought war as a Keynesian measure, but the implications were hard to mistake. Keynes himself told BBC listeners that “The grand experiment has begun. If it works, if expenditure on armaments really does cure unemployment, I predict that we shall never go back all the way to the old state of affairs” (Keynes, 1939, p. 1143). The next year, writing for an American audience, he worried that it seemed “politically impossible for a capitalistic democracy to organize expenditure on the scale necessary to make the grand experiments which would prove my case, except in war conditions,” but mused that “good might come out of evil.” While British rearmament would require austerity, in the United States: Macroeconomic Consequences of Peace 15 Downloaded by Mr Tim Barker At 07:40 30 April 2019 (PT) war preparation, so far from requiring a sacrifice, will be the stimulus, which neither the victory nor the defeat of the New Deal could give you, to greater individual consumption and a higher standard of life. (Keynes, 1940, p. 158) The war brought the first generation of American Keynesians close to power. Members of the Harvard-Tufts group served in the Office of Price Administration, the Office of Strategic Services (OSS), the War Production Board, the Federal Reserve, the State and Treasury Departments, and the Federal Reserve, among other wartime organizations. Perhaps, the most consequential was Richard V. Gilbert, the lead (and oldest) author of the Economic Program, later referred to as “the outstanding, unsung hero of American wartime economic policy” (Salant, 1980, p. 1062). On the strength of the 1938 Economic Program book, Gilbert had been hired away from Harvard by Commerce Secretary Harry Hopkins (Stein, 1969, p. 168). He brought with him Walter Salant, another member of the Harvard-Tufts group, who would later suggest that one of their 1939 reports represented “the first statement in an official document of what is now called the ‘new economics’” (Salant, 1970). Work quickly turned toward mobilization: by September 1940, Gilbert was predicting that rearmament “would undoubtedly be the most important influence in the business situation and a powerful source of expansion” (Mitra-Kahn, 2011, p. 255). Gilbert’s participation in the wartime mobilization permanently transformed national income accounting. As chief economist of the Office of Price Administration, he helped replace Simon Kuznets’s original national income methodology with a distinctively martial Keynesian framework. For Kuznets, defense spending was an intermediate good which provided society with security, rather than a contribution to the pool of final goods and services. Such spending should be counted as a deduction from national income, not a contribution (Higgs, 1992; Mitra-Kahn, 2011, pp. 237247). Gilbert and his bureaucratic allies “struggled to get the US to invest in war capacity” because “the administration worried that such investment would be bad for the economy on the basis of Simon Kuznets’s definition of the economy” (Mitra-Kahn, 2011, p. 273). Drawing on the latest work by Keynes, Gilbert sought to recast gross national product so that it would include the “military requirement plus the normal civilian requirement” (Mitra-Kahn, 2011, p. 259). Ultimately successful, this redefinition allowed government military spending to enter directly into gross national product figures, providing the statistical foundation for countless postwar debates about the relation between defense spending and economic performance. Under the sign of anti-fascist military imperatives, leftist and liberal economists continued to work closely together. Gilbert collaborated on early national income figures with Victor Perlo, an economist close to the Communist Party (Gilbert & Perlo, 1942). Sometimes, Marxist and liberal convictions mingled in the same mind, as in the case of Economic Program contributor Alan Sweezy. Remembered today, if at all, as Paul’s “less radical” brother, the elder Sweezy had been something of a cause celebre when, in 1937, his teaching contract at Harvard was not renewed a decision some saw as motivated by Sweezy’s 16 TIM BARKER Downloaded by Mr Tim Barker At 07:40 30 April 2019 (PT) support for the newly formed Congress of Industrial Organizations (Mason & Lamont, 1982, pp. 426429). During the war, Sweezy taught at Williams, worked for the Federal Reserve Board, and published both in professional journals and in the radical press. In the Marxist theoretical journal Science and Society, he praised New Dealer Mordecai Ezekiel as well as Lenin (A. Sweezy, 1942a). He pondered whether “Soviets of workers, soldiers and peasants will spring up to fill the void and will proceed immediately to the abolition of capitalist society” while analyzing “The Government’s Responsibility for Full Employment” in the American Economic Review (A. Sweezy, 1942b, 1943a). In the course of a New Masses review of a book by American Communist leader Earl Browder, Sweezy declared: As an economist, I am convinced not only that the capitalist economy can be made to work but also that the only way it can be done is through the further development of progressive policies of the New Deal type. (A. Sweezy, 1944, p. 13) Sweezy’s contributions to the debate on secular stagnation also reflected his mix of Marxist and Keynesian inclinations. Sweezy argued that while modern economists had “much to learn from Marx,” it was also the case that: some of Marx’s most important insights, ideas he was struggling to express with the inadequate analytical apparatus then available, become thoroughly clear for the first time in terms of the modern [Keynesian] analysis. (A. Sweezy, 1942, p. 136) For Sweezy, unlike Hansen, the true problem of stagnation was not to be found in objective factors like population, closed frontiers, or technological enervation. Rather, the crisis of oversavings was really the crisis of a particular social order, in which investment opportunities had to be profitable to be attractive. In a society directed toward human need, on the other hand, there could never be a shortfall of socially beneficial uses for the growing product of an advanced industrial economy (A. Sweezy, 1940, 1943, 1947). The war effort, while it lasted, had created a capitalist society where high levels of investment were guaranteed by the state, in the name of anti-fascist combat a situation in which both radicals and liberals could see the economic effects of mobilization in a positive light.6 This consensus would not survive the war’s end, leaving a splintered political reality for the Harvard-Tufts group and their students to interpret in the decades to come. POSTWAR AMBIGUITIES Events after 1945 eroded the conditions that had made the Economic Program collaboration possible, leaving them on opposite sides of the question of military-fiscal economics. The splits within the labor-left-liberal world, embodied in Henry Wallace’s 1948 third party challenge to Harry Truman and the expulsion of leftists from the CIO in 19491950, ran directly through the group. The Sweezy brothers were involved with the Wallace campaign, though Alan had misgivings and would move toward the center after the 1948 election (PMS, Downloaded by Mr Tim Barker At 07:40 30 April 2019 (PT) Macroeconomic Consequences of Peace 17 A. Sweezy to B. Laub, November 5, 1948, copy in Box 1, file: AZ, 19471948; PMS, A. Sweezy to P. Sweezy, November 29, 1958, Box 1, file: AZ, 1963 or earlier). Arthur W. Stuart, forced out of the Treasury Department in 1953 because of his connections with Harry Dexter White, worked as a rug salesman before landing a job at one of the unions that had been kicked out of the CIO in 1950 (Williams, 1993, pp. 80103). Even the less radical Economic Program contributors had to be careful. Lorie Tarshis wrote the first Keynesian textbook, only to see it buried by a coordinated right-wing campaign (Colander & Landreth, 1996, pp. 6670). Emile Despres was blocked from a job on George Kennan’s State Department Policy Planning Staff because of vague security concerns, perhaps related to his support of Carl Marzani, an alleged Communist spy who had worked with Despres and Paul Sweezy in the OSS (Hixson, 1989, pp. 156157; Dutkin, 1947, p. 1). Despite these anti-communist attacks, Keynesian economics saw something of a victory in politics with the passage of the 1946 Employment Act, which committed the government to maximizing employment and purchasing power and created the Council of Economic Advisors. But the version of the Employment Act that passed was less forceful than the originally proposed Full Employment Act a sign that the businessmen gathered in the Committee for Economic Development had succeeded in steering a course between preKeynesian fiscal reticence and the left-wing excesses of the stagnationists (Collins, 1981, pp. 99109). Besides the end of the Popular Front and the rise of commercial Keynesianism, the postwar years posed another challenge to the followers of Alvin Hansen. The end of the war was followed by a sustained boom rather than the depression many had feared. But the stagnation question was far from settled. Early in the war, coauthor of Economic Program George Hildebrand had imagined the possibility of a temporary postwar boom, stimulated by deferred consumption and investment (Hildebrand, 1942). Hansen himself had departed from many economists in not forecasting a postwar depression, on the basis that demand backlogs could be enough to generate “a vigorous private investment boom” (Hansen, 1943). After all, the core stagnationist claim was not that stagnation was inevitable but that it could only be avoided by robust fiscal policy. As it turned out, “military spending rather than public investment fueled expansion and the new frontier that opened was in the defense-related industries of electronics and automation” (Mehrling, 1997, p. 137). This development allowed stagnationists to continue to press their claim, and to worry about what would happen if peace were ever to break out. As Hansen put it in 1947, before the Korean War and the formation of NATO: That we should be enjoying a period of postwar prosperity is not surprising to anyone. A world situation so threatening as to require very large and growing military expenditures, sufficient to offset the eventual decline in private capital outlays, might, indeed, give us an almost indefinite period of high employment. But this is a solution which would point to and probably eventuate in a world calamity. Apart from such a consideration there are few, if any, who doubt that a severe depression is, sooner or later, in store. (Hansen, 1947, p. 61) 18 TIM BARKER Seven years later, Hansen judged the contribution of military stimulus even more significant: Downloaded by Mr Tim Barker At 07:40 30 April 2019 (PT) In the kind of world now in prospect, the problem of stagnation assumes a quite different aspect from that of 1949. Indeed even in 1949, with a federal budget of about $40 billion, half of which was for national security, the situation was obviously not at all like the peacetime conditions prevailing in the ’thirties before the Second World War. It is amazing how many economists have been able to close their eyes and blandly announce that events since 1940 have disproved the stagnation thesis! (Hansen, 1954, p. 409) Hansen’s concerns found a place in postwar liberal cultural criticism. Richard Hofstadter appears to have coined the term “military Keynesianism,” and David Riesman helped to popularize the phrase (Hofstadter, 1950, p. 35; Riesman 1958, p. 139). But the problem found its most assiduous students farther left. The idea that “the economy is dependent on military orders” echoes constantly through the correspondence of Paul Sweezy and Paul A. Baran in the 1950s and early 1960s (Age of Monopoly Capital, 2017, p. 359). They saw this thesis as what separated their collaborative efforts from both liberals and orthodox Marxists. “What argument will convince the liberal,” wondered Sweezy to Baran in 1953: who is determined not to be convinced, that public works cannot be turned on and off at will to take the place of war spending? Either you see that this is a question of the class-structure of society and the location of political power, or you don’t. (Age of Monopoly Capital, 2017, p. 107) Conversely, Sweezy had complained the previous year that “the most comprehensive contradiction of capitalism its continued existence depends entirely on its preparing for total destruction, including self-destruction escapes the most orthodox of Marxists” (Age of Monopoly Capital, 2017, p. 94). The quarrel with liberals could be quite personal. “I wonder if our colleagues like Tarshis and Despres, who at least once knew something learned from Keynes and the 30’s, will be able to swallow this,” Sweezy wrote about two of his Economic Program coauthors (PAB, P. Sweezy to Baran, February 1, 1962, file: #23). He told Baran, who had aborted a manuscript collaboration with Tarshis, “You are absolutely right to refuse to sign anything with the Keynesian philistines” (PAB, P.M. Sweezy to P.A. Baran, September 21, 1952, file: #4). But this invective shared space with a persistent sense of left-Keynesian identity. Regarding his own work, Baran wrote, “Even where it smacks with Keynesian notions, it is o.k. because I think that it is fully in keeping with Marx” (PAB, Baran to P. Sweezy, May 15, 1952, file: #3). Postwar correspondence between George H. Hildebrand and Paul Sweezy both contributors to the 1938 Economic Program for American Democracy illustrates the postwar breakdown of the left-Keynesian consensus as well as continued dialogue on military-fiscal politics. Hildebrand completed his master’s degree at Harvard, where he joined the group that wrote An Economic Program for American Democracy. While serving as a principal economist for the National War Labor Board, Hildebrand published an early paper applying Keynesian national income analysis to the problem of “Depressionless Downloaded by Mr Tim Barker At 07:40 30 April 2019 (PT) Macroeconomic Consequences of Peace 19 Transition to a Post-war Economy.” Echoing the tones of the Economic Program, this paper described the world war as “in large part a struggle over systems of government and of social organization which is motivated by the conflict between the promise of the machine process and the patent facts of poverty, insecurity, and inequality of economic opportunity as the customary lot of the common citizen” and advocated “heavy injections of public expenditure, but for peace rather than for war” as a solution to the reconversion puzzle (Hildebrand, 1942, pp. 215, 223). In the AER the next year, Hildebrand cited Hansen and Alan Sweezy on the likelihood that future levels of private investment demand “would continue to be too low to permit the economy to operate at the high levels proved possible by the war” (Hildebrand, 1943, p. 600). After the war, Hildebrand would become a successful labor economist and arbitrator, and eventually Deputy Undersecretary of Labor for International Affairs under Richard Nixon (Bernstein, 1970). His political evolution is illuminated in his replies to an invitation from Paul Sweezy to write something for his new journal Monthly Review in 1949. Hildebrand, who was at the time teaching a class on socialist thought at UCLA, took the occasion to alert Sweezy that he now found “Soviet political morality” to be “the equal of Nazi Germany’s” (PMS, G. Hildebrand to P.M. Sweezy, October 13, 1949, P.M. Sweezy Papers, Box 1, file: AZ, 1963 or earlier). In a subsequent letter, Hildebrand conceded that in the 1930s he “was aware of a certain seamy side to the USSR,” but “it seemed to me that there was a real promise that a decent democratic society could emerge there,” an orientation strengthened by his impression that the Nazis “had emerged in a capitalist environment” and that “our economic system was operating very badly.” Events since 1939, he wrote, had led him to change his mind about socialism, a fact which he thought made it unlikely that he would write for Monthly Review (PMS, G. Hildebrand to P.M. Sweezy, March 19, 1950. P.M. Box 1, file: AZ, 1963 or earlier). But Hildebrand remained intrigued by the effect of military spending on growth and stability. At the 1954 meeting of the AEA, Hildebrand gave a paper, “Defense Expenditures and the Problem of Deflation,” on a panel called “The Automaticity of Full Employment under the Assumption of Diminished Defense Expenditures.” In 1957, he prepared an official report at the request of Congressman Wilbur D. Mills on the influence of military spending on the domestic economy. He and his coauthor declared themselves “certain that the tasks of fiscal and monetary management with a greatly reduced level of security spending would be harder, rather than easier, than they are now” and that military spending “does much to explain the brevity and shallowness of the three postwar contractions and the absence of a major depression since 1941” (Hildebrand & Breckner, 1957, pp. 539540). Aware of their shared interest in fiscal-military dynamics, Hildebrand sent Sweezy an advance copy of his congressional report. He drew Sweezy’s attention to the fact that “we made good use of the Model, Rowland [sic], & Stone study, which we cite with sincere approval.” The study in question was The ScientificIndustrial Revolution, a pamphlet published without a byline by the investment bank Model, Roland, and Stone, and actually written by Paul Sweezy. Clearly, Downloaded by Mr Tim Barker At 07:40 30 April 2019 (PT) 20 TIM BARKER Hildebrand was aware of the authorship and promised Sweezy he would do his best to get the study reviewed in the AER, which it deserved as a study “unique in its perception of a vital new development” (Hildebrand to P.M. Sweezy, October 7, 1957. Box 1, file: AZ, 1963 or earlier). One member of the Harvard-Tufts Economic Program group was now citing another coauthor’s work in testimony before Congress about the fiscal effects of the Cold War even though one was a fully paid-up member of the establishment and the other was blacklisted.7 It is not surprising, then, that Baran and Sweezy still saw fleeting opportunities for a new popular front this time built around anti-militarism. Baran noted that Republican Secretary of Defense (and erstwhile General Motors executive) Charles E. Wilson was “on the record with a few pretty good speeches (one against too much armament, another warning of the creation of a permanent munitions industry with a vested interest in armament)” (PAB, P.A. Baran to P.M. Sweezy, November 21, 1952, file: #5). Baran also helped to edit a special issue of the Nation on “Economic Hazards of Arms Reduction,” which included contributions from Sweezy and Tarshis (PAB, P.M. Sweezy to P.A. Baran, January 2, 1959, file #18). Bringing it all back home, he even wrote, “[I] wonder whether it wouldn’t be very timely to produce a little pamphlet a la Harvard-Tufts economists’ advancing a genuine program for ‘Peace and Prosperity’” (PAB, P.A. Baran to P.M. Sweezy, March 4, 1959, file: #18). REBIRTH OF RADICAL POLITICAL ECONOMICS In 1966, two years after Baran died, Baran and Sweezy’s Monopoly Capital was published. The result of more than a decade of work by these veteran radicals would prove to be one of the key influences on the revival of radical political economy associated with the 1960s. Among its other gifts to the New Left, Monopoly Capital offered a timely revival of left-Hansenian stagnation theory as well as what would become the most-cited account of military Keynesianism. To familiar arguments about armament-driven prosperity, Baran and Sweezy added new empirical research (including an appendix which attempted to measure the magnitude of the surplus generated by underconsumption). They also employed a broad, acerbic cultural criticism which reflected their discovery of Thorstein Veblen as an intellectual ancestor, not least because of his SpanishAmerican War-era analysis of “the social function of militarism” (Baran and Sweezy (207208). Even liberal critics conceded that Baran and Sweezy were “economically literate radicals” offering a “sophisticated form” of the old claim that capitalism requires war (Tobin, 1974, p. 41). For younger readers, it provided “the introduction to radical economic analysis for an entire generation of university students and an important influence on the New Left” (Lebowitz, 2004). The publication of Monopoly Capital in 1966 was well timed to appeal to the cohort of that would succeed Baran (born 1909) and Sweezy (born 1910). It argued that even a fully employed America was pathological, but unlike some contemporary writings by Baran’s former Frankfurt School associates, the book Macroeconomic Consequences of Peace 21 also argued that the seeming stability of postwar capitalism was still threatened by economic contradictions. After suggesting that “the government could spend enough to keep the system from sinking into the mire of stagnation” on “arms, more arms, and ever more arms,” Baran and Sweezy insisted that even here “obstacles and contradictions are in operation” (Baran & Sweezy, 1966, p. 213). The knife’s edge on which the New Economics sat at the onset of the escalation of the Vietnam War was suggestively recalled by macroeconomic pioneer Lawrence Klein: Downloaded by Mr Tim Barker At 07:40 30 April 2019 (PT) I remember vividly a particular social party in Washington at which the thought of inflationary pressure in 1965 was not considered serious and recall the extent to which various government economists had conflicting information on the defense build-up. (Klein, 1982, p. 615) A major complaint of the revived radical political economy was that mainstream economics didn’t talk about the war. In a paper he gave at the contentious 1969 AEA meeting, on a panel chaired by Paul Sweezy and featuring the Union for Radical Political Economy’s Arthur McEwan as a respondent. Monthly Review coeditor Harry Magdoff remarked that “Peace reigns supreme in the realm of neoclassical economics” (Magdoff, 1970, p. 237). The editorial note to an early issue of the Review of Radical Political Economy charged that: By reading the principal economics journals, one would never know that the United States is fighting a war (and has been fighting it for many years) which has had an enormous impact on the economy. (Wachtel, 1970) In his 1970 report to the mainstream, Martin Bronfenbrenner explained the new radicalism in part as a reaction to the “failure to achieve full employment in America without large military budgets for hot and cold wars” (Bronfenbrenner, 1970, p. 748). The economics of militarism thus emerged as part of the expanded object domain that radicals proposed to study as part of political economy. But like other disciplinary insurgents of the Vietnam era, radical economists were also interested in the moral responsibility of intellectuals, in particular the government Keynesians. Richard B. Du Boff and Edward S. Herman leveled such a charge in RRPE: “To our knowledge, not one resigned or otherwise withdrew his services from the government on moral or political grounds.” The title of their piece, which labeled the New Economics “handmaiden of inspired truth,” alluded directly to the complicity of German scientists with Nazism (DuBoff & Herman, 1972, p. 63). At the 1971 AEA meeting, John Kenneth Galbraith arranged for Joan Robinson, a protégé of Keynes and an increasingly radical critic of American foreign policy and “bastard Keynesianism,” to give the Richard T. Ely address. In New Orleans that year, she accused American Keynesians of abetting the warfare state, thereby turning “Keynes’ pleasant day-dream […] into a nightmare of terror” (Robinson, 1972, p. 7). The scene was described by AEA secretary-treasurer Rendig Fels as “an overflow audience with enthusiasm rarely seen at academic gatherings” (King, 2002, p. 124). The shift from World War II when Marxists and liberals together worked to mobilize the economy against Nazism was clear. Like the original authors Downloaded by Mr Tim Barker At 07:40 30 April 2019 (PT) 22 TIM BARKER of the Economic Program, the new radicals saw the fascist threat at home. At the first national URPE conference, held in Philadelphia in December 1968, Daniel R. Fusfeld gave a paper on “Fascist Democracy in the United States” (Fusfeld, 1968; republished with alterations as Fusfeld, 1972). Fusfeld, born in 1922, exemplified the connections between the concerns of the Depression and World War II generation and the concerns of the emerging New Left. He remembered that reading erstwhile Trotskyist James Burnham made him see “the possibility of American fascism dominated by big business in a reaction against the New Deal and militant labor” (Fusfeld, 1997, p. 4). He worked as a junior economist at the War Production Board before being drafted into the army, an experience which he later wrote left him “an angry and hostile person, obsessed with the killing I had participated in and the things I had seen” (Fusfeld, 1997, p. 10). At the University of Michigan, he was an ally of the radical students who would found URPE, and wrote a successful heterodox textbook. The fourth issue of RRPE (August 1970) was devoted to connections between war and the economy. Most of the papers and several appendices were contributed by an Ad-Hoc Committee of Students and Faculty on the Economy and the War of the Department of Economics, Harvard University. The next issue included a significant piece by Michael Reich and David Finkelhor that sought to distinguish radical critiques of militarism from liberal views of the militaryindustrial complex (Reich & Finkelhor,1970; cf. Reich, 1972). The arms economy, they wrote, was not a triumph of special interests or a corruption of political virtue but “the only workable solution to the dangerous and profound crisis created by the Depression of the 1930’s.” Reich and Finkelhor referred to recent research in input-output or interindustry analysis to suggest that the actual importance of defense spending was greater than a simple focus on prime military contractors or defense spending as a share of GDP would suggest. “The military sector is not an enclave,” they warned. “Its tentacles are implanted deep in the heart of the capitalist economy, and it is entirely fused with it.” This way of seeing the warfare economy an octopus, not a leech was key to New Left conceptions of military Keynesianism. It stood in direct contrast to the idea of a military-industrial complex popularized in 1961 by outgoing Republican president Dwight Eisenhower. Like Eisenhower, well-known critic Seymour Melman saw “Pentagon capitalism” as a parasitic special interest within American capitalism, rather than a functional response to a secular capitalist trend toward excess capacity (Melman, 1970). Before the escalation in Vietnam made such dialogue impossible, Melman spent an hour discussing military spending policy with President Lyndon B. Johnson at the White House, suggesting the potentially broad appeal of his arguments (Johnson, 1963). Even Nikita Khruschev, in a January 1960 speech, came around to the idea that capitalism did not require war, arguing that while “some people in the West assert that disarmament threatens grave consequences for the economy of the capitalist countries,” such claims are “completely unsubstantiated.” Referring to his conversations with “the most reasonable” American businessmen, he suggested that Downloaded by Mr Tim Barker At 07:40 30 April 2019 (PT) Macroeconomic Consequences of Peace 23 a cut in defense spending could easily be translated by a capitalist economy into lower taxes and increased consumption, social spending, and foreign trade (Khruschev, 1960 p. 9). It was against this growing consensus that New Leftists stressed the importance of military spending to the entire economy, rather than specific regions and industries. James Cypher, the figure associated with URPE who wrote most frequently about military Keynesianism, took aim at Seymour Melman with ideas drawn from stagnationist theory: Melman, he charged, “seems oblivious to the fact that American Capitalism was unable to generate adequate aggregate demand” between 1928 and the coming of war (Cypher, 1972, p. 112). If radical political economists were eager to differentiate themselves from liberals, liberals returned the favor. Liberal Keynesians could easily see that things had gone awry with American foreign policy and domestic political economy, and even concede that these things might be connected. They clearly preferred the special interest, military-industrial interpretation over a more structural account. “Of course, particular groups benefit from war,” wrote Paul Samuelson in the New York Times. “The plowshare industry stands to gain from peace, just as the sword industry gains from war” (Samuelson, 1973). Tobin suggested that “Eisenhower’s ‘military-industrial complex’” a special interest group with untoward lobbying power could explain a better explanation of excessive military spending “than Marxist-Keynesian grounds” (Tobin, 1974, p. 44). These liberal responses to the revival of radical political economy were influenced by the opportunism of the Republican Party, which in 1968 had retaken the White House for the first time since Eisenhower. Richard Nixon’s declaration that “I am now a Keynesian in economics” is well known (“Nixon Reportedly,” 1971). But around the same time, he also espoused a version of military Keynesianism that departed markedly from Eisenhower’s worries about military-industrial interests. Obsessed with the relation of the business cycle to his reelection, Nixon repeatedly invoked the end of the war in Vietnam as an alibi for the existence of unemployment (Nixon, 1971). Nixon’s remarks were seized upon by liberals seeking to fend off the New Left charge that the welfare and warfare states were somehow connected. Charles L. Schultze (who would become a lead economic advisor to Jimmy Carter) lamented that as “the recent presidential campaign demonstrated, both the Republican and Communist parties agree that large military spending is needed in the United States to maintain full employment” (Schultze, 1973, p. 522). Tobin struck an identical note, describing what he called the “MarxistNixon position”: The Marxists and New Leftists have an unlikely ally in President Nixon, who has repeatedly said that the U.S. has in the past not achieved full employment in peacetime […] Proponents of the Marxist-Nixon position can point to the political barriers to expansion of civilian spending in the first Kennedy-Johnson administration, and note that otherwise firm taboos on deficit spending could be broken for the Berlin build-up in 1961 and the Vietnam escalation later. (Tobin, 1974, p. 42) Downloaded by Mr Tim Barker At 07:40 30 April 2019 (PT) 24 TIM BARKER Tobin found this view “a dangerous error of economic theory and history, a Marxist criticism of American society which is surprising to hear from a President” (Tobin, 1971). Likewise, Schultze maintained that “the level and the rate of growth of national income and employment are in no fundamental way dependent on the maintenance of heavy military spending” (Schultze, 1973, p. 523). The ongoing economic troubles kept the question in circulation. Before the recession of 19741975, and even before the oil shock of late 1973, the New York Times ran a series of editorials titled “Capitalism, For Better or Worse,” several of which linked the question of secular stagnation with military spending. Paul Samuelson, while dismissing the idea that “capitalism must break down in depression if it does not find imperialistic ventures that spend money and destroy surplus goods,” admitted that the questions “deserve hard-headed and unflinching investigation.” Indicating the recent ubiquity of the debate, as well as its complex intellectual provenance, Samuelson described the set of thinkers interested in the problem as including “Luxemburg and Lenin (and Hobson and Alvin Hansen),” “Marx and Engels, Luxemburg and Lenin, Sweezy and Baran, Jack Gurley and Sam Bowles, [and] your freshman brother at Yale” (Samuelson, 1973). Kenneth Arrow’s less glib entry in the series, modestly titled “Somehow, It Has Overcome,” acknowledged that the problem of excess capacity was “by far the most serious criticism of and threat to the capitalist economic system.” He described Baran and Sweezy as: sophisticated radical economists [who] quickly recognized that the Keynesian solution would work but argued that in a capitalist system the government could spend enough to insure full employment only on socially wasteful and even destructive ends, such as war and preparation for war. Arrow offered an empirical rebuttal: Japan, without a military budget, had outstripped American capitalism in growth, employment, and efficiency (Arrow, 1973). Sweezy, struck by the frequent references to his work, asked for space in the New York Times to respond and was refused. Leonard Silk, an economics correspondent who would reintroduce the concept of secular stagnation to 1970s New York Times readers, eventually published a volume which included Sweezy’s response along with the original pieces by Arrow and Samuelson (Silk, 1974). By the time of the global recession of 19741975, there were hints that military Keynesianism was receding into history. One was that by the early 1970s, professional historians were starting to take interest in martial Keynesianism as an academic topic. The same AEA meeting where Joan Robinson accused the New Economics of enabling atrocities also saw a panel on “The Keynesian Revolution and Its Pioneers.” Alan Sweezy gave a memoir of Keynesianism within the New Deal, incidentally publicly claiming coauthorship of An Economic Program for American Democracy for the first time (A. Sweezy, 1972). Byrd L. Jones, a former student of Emile Despres, spoke on the Keynesian role in mobilization for the world war, striking a disillusioned note in conclusion: Downloaded by Mr Tim Barker At 07:40 30 April 2019 (PT) Macroeconomic Consequences of Peace 25 “The economists’ defeat in the dispute over reconversion has foreshadowed the long years of the Cold War when military expenditures would take precedence over social welfare programs” (Jones, 1972). The declassification of NSC-68 the long-acknowledged but officially secret policy planning document for America’s Cold War gave further impetus to retrospective, academic students, who would outline the role played by growth-oriented New Dealers like Leon Keyserling and the integration of Japan and West Germany into a complex, interdependent “international military Keynesianism” (Block, 1977; Borden 1984). The war in Vietnam ended and, for most of the next decade, defense spending fell. By 1971, military spending had been surpassed by nondefense transfer payments in the federal budget (OMB, 2018, table 6.1). Keynesianism in general famously fell on hard times. According to URPE’s James Cypher, who saw military spending as the principal means of economic planning in the postwar United States, Nixon’s New Economic Policy raised the possibility of “a new era of capitalist planning in the U.S.,” which would turn away from military spending and its problematic tendency to “add to the current inflation” (Cypher, 1974, p. 15). Alan Wolfe, associated with neo-Marxist journal Kapitalistate, saw military Keynesianism circa 1950 as an effective stratagem but suggested that after Vietnam, “the overall results of military spending are now recognized to be inflation, negative balances of payments, structural unemployment, and unproductive uses of capital” (Wolfe, 1981, p. 208). With the close of the 1970s, a long-running conversation with its origins in the late New Deal and World War II and which had been elaborated by successive generations of liberals and radicals now had the sense of an ending. Increasingly, military Keynesianism was seen as a period in American history, rather than a permanent condition. The discourse would not disappear entirely, any more than would the Pentagon or the federal budget deficit. Indeed, it saw a notable revival during the Reagan years, when critics were quick to charge that the new military buildup gave the lie to neoliberal rhetoric about small government and free markets. But concerns about secular stagnation, once so common across political divisions, were expressed less frequently, especially after the record-breaking peacetime boom of the 1990s. Still, the recent revival of mainstream discussion of secular stagnation, along with the fundamental uncertainty of international politics, means that there may still be more of a future for military Keynesianism than one would like to think. NOTES 1. Some of the more comprehensive extant studies are Cypher (2015), Turgeon (1996), and Howard & King (1992). 2. On secular stagnation broadly, see Shaikh (1978) and Backhouse and Boianovsky (2016). 3. I focus here on the American case, at the expense of crucial European precedents in Marxism and Continental business cycle theory. For thorough consideration of a depression-era British contribution to the discourse of military Keynesianism, see King (2004). 26 TIM BARKER 4. Alan Sweezy identified himself, Salant, and Despres as the unnamed authors (A. Sweezy, 1972, p. 122); Lorie Tarshis included those three plus Robert Bangs (Colander & Landreth, 1996, p. 64); Salant included himself, Alan Sweezy, Despres, and Martin Krost, but not Bangs, though he noted, “I can’t recall whether there was one other” (WSS, W. Salant to H. Stein, April 5, 1967, p. 3, Box 6, Herbert Stein folder). 5. This work is notable for introducing the concept of “privatization” into Englishlanguage social science (Perelman, 2006). 6. In focusing on the popular front relationship between New Deal liberals and Communist fellow travelers, this chapter neglects the Trotskyist and anarcho-pacifist currents which generated early critiques of the “permanent arms economy” while the war was still ongoing (van der Linden, 2018). 7. The study was published as Scientific-industrial Revolution (1957). For Sweezy’s authorship, see Age of Monopoly Capital (2017), p. 503. Downloaded by Mr Tim Barker At 07:40 30 April 2019 (PT) ACKNOWLEDGMENTS I am grateful to Tiago Mata and two anonymous reviewers for their comments and guidance, as well as to the archivists at Houghton Library, Harvard, and the Harry S. Truman Presidential Library and Museum. REFERENCES Arrow, K. (1973). Somehow, it has overcome. New York Times, March 26. Retrieved from https:// www.nytimes.com/1973/03/26/archives/somehow-it-has-overcome-capitalism-for-better-orworse.html Backhouse, R., & Boianovsky, M. (2016). Secular stagnation: The history of a macroeconomic heresy. The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 23(6), 946970. Baran, P., & Sweezy, P. (1966). Monopoly capital. New York, NY: Monthly Review Press. Bernstein, H. (1970). Nixon aide sees $15 billion deficit. Washington Post, October 19, p. C9. Block, F. (1977). The origins of international economic disorder: A study of United States International Monetary Policy from World War II to the present. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Borden, W. S. (1984). The Pacific alliance: United States foreign economic policy and Japanese trade recovery, 19471955. Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin Press. Bronfenbrenner, M. (1970). Radical economics in America: A 1970 survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 8(3), September, 747766. Colander, D., & Landreth, H. (1996). The coming of Keynesianism to America: Interviews with the founders of Keynesian economic. Brookfield, VT: Elgar. Collins, R. M. (1981). The business response to Keynes, 19291964. New York, NY: Columbia University Press. Cypher, J. (1972). The liberals discover militarism. Review of Radical Political Economics, 4(1), January, 109116. Cypher, J. (1974). Capitalist planning and military expenditures. Review of Radical Political Economics, 6(3), (Fall), 119. Cypher, J. (2015). The origins and evolution of military Keynesianism in the United States. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 38(3), 449476. DuBoff, R., & Herman, E. (1972). The new economics: Handmaiden of inspired truth. Review of Radical Political Economics, 4(4), August, 5484. Dutkin, H. L. (1947). Marzani loyal beyond doubt, says witness. Washington Post, 20 May, pp. 12. Ezekiel, M. (1939). Jobs for all through industrial expansion. New York, NY: Knopf. Fusfeld, D. (1968). Fascist democracy in the United States. Conference Papers of the Union for Radical Economics (pp. 335). Ann Arbor, MI: URPE. Fusfeld, D. (1972). The rise of the corporate state in America. Journal of Economic Literature, 6(1), March, 122. Downloaded by Mr Tim Barker At 07:40 30 April 2019 (PT) Macroeconomic Consequences of Peace 27 Fusfeld, D. (1997). An intellectual journey. In N. Aslanbegui & Y. B. Choi (Eds.), Borderlands of economics: Essays in honour of Daniel R. Fusfeld (pp. 222). London: Routledge. Gilbert, R., & Perlo, V. (1942). The investment-factor method of forecasting business activity. Econometrica, 10(3/4), JulyOctober, 311316. Gilbert, R. V., Hildebrand, G. H., Stuart, A. W., Sweezy, M. Y., Sweezy, P. M., Tarshis, L., & Wilson, J. D. (1938). An economic program for American democracy. New York, NY: Vanguard Press. Gintis, H. (1970). American Keynesianism and the war machine. In D. Mermelstein (Ed.), Economics: Mainstream readings and radical critiques (pp. 245248). New York, NY: Random House. Hansen, A. H. (1943). The postwar economy. In S. E. Harris (Ed.), Postwar economic problems (pp. 926). New York, NY: McGraw-Hill. Hansen, A. H. (1947). Needed a cycle policy. ILR Review, 1(1), October, 6065. Hansen, A. H. (1954). Growth or stagnation in the American economy. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 36(4), November, 409414. Higgs, R. (1992). Wartime prosperity? A reassessment of the U.S. economy in the 1940s. Journal of Economic History, 4160. Hildebrand, G. (1942, December). Depressionless transition to a post-war economy. The Southwestern Social Science Quarterly, 23(3), 215225. Hildebrand, G. (1943, September). Monopolization and the decline of investment opportunity. American Economic Review, 33(3), 591601. Hildebrand, G. (1954, May). Defense expenditures and the problem of deflation. American Economic Review, 44(2), 410422. Hildebrand, G., & Breckner, N. (1957, November 5). The impacts of national security expenditure upon the stability and growth of the American economy: Federal expenditure policy for economic growth and stability. Papers submitted by Panelists Appearing before the Subcommittee on Fiscal Policy. Retrieved from https://fraser.stlouisfed.org/content/?item_ id¼1593&filepath¼/files/docs/historical/jec/19571105jec_fedexpenditure_hildebrand.pdf Hixson, W. L. (1989). George F. Kennan: Cold War iconoclast. New York, NY: Columbia University Press. Hofstadter, R. (1950). American power: The domestic sources. American Perspective, IV(Winter 1950), 3236. Howard, M., & King, J. (1992). A history of Marxian economics (Vol. II, pp. 19291990), London: Macmillan. Johnson, L. (1963). The President’s First News Conference (December 7). Retrieved from http:// www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid¼26176 Jones, B. L. (1972, March). The role of Keynesians in wartime policy and postwar planning, 19401946. American Economic Review, 62(1/2), 125133. Kalecki, M. (1943). Political aspects of full employment. Political Quarterly, 14, 322331. Keynes, J. M. (1936). The general theory of employment, interest, money. London: Macmillan. Keynes, J. M. (1939, June 1). Will re-armament cure unemployment? The Listener, 11421143. Keynes, J. M. (1940, July 29). The United States and the Keynes plan. New Republic, 103(5), 156159. Khruschev, N. (1960). Disarmament is the path toward strengthening peace and ensuring friendship among peoples: N. S. Khrushchev’s Report at U.S.S.R. Supreme Soviet session. Current Digest of the Russian Press, 12(2), February 10, 323. King, J. E. (2002). A history of post-Keynesian economics since 1936. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. King, J. E. (2004). Frederick Allen and the crisis of capitalism. History of Economic Ideas, 12(2), 728. Klein, L. R. (1982). Two decades of U.S. economic policy and present prospects. In K. Marwah (Ed.), Selected papers of Lawrence R Klein: Theoretical reflections and econometric applications (pp. 614625). Singapore: World Scientific Publishing, 1997. Lebowitz, M. A. (2004). Paul M. Sweezy. Monthly Review. Retrieved from https://monthlyreview.org/ 2004/10/01/paul-m-sweezy/ Magdoff, H. (1970, May). Militarism and imperialism. American Economic Review, 60(2), Papers and Proceedings of the Eighty-second Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association, 237242. Downloaded by Mr Tim Barker At 07:40 30 April 2019 (PT) 28 TIM BARKER Mason, E. S., & Lamont, T. S. (1982, August). The Harvard department of economics from the beginning to World War II. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 97(3), 383433. May, D. L. (1981). From new deal to new economics: The American liberal response to the recession of 1937. New York, NY: Garland Publishing. Mehrling, P. (1997). The money interest and the public interest: American monetary thought, 19201970. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Melman, S. (1970). Pentagon capitalism: The political economy of war. New York, NY: McGraw Hill. Mitra-Kahn, B. H. (2011). Redefining the economy: How the ‘economy’ was invented in 1620—And has been redefined ever since, PhD dissertation in Economics, City, University of London. Nixon, R. (1971). Annual message to the congress: The economic report of the President, February 1). Retrieved from http://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid¼3232 Nixon Reportedly Says He Is Now a Keynesian. (1971). New York Times, January 17, p. 19. Office of Management and Budget [OMB]. (2018). Historical tables. Retrieved from https://www. whitehouse.gov/omb/historical-tables/ Perelman, M. (2006, September 11). The Nazi heritage of privatization. Retrieved from https:// michaelperelman.wordpress.com/2006/09/11/the-nazi-heritage-of-privatization/ Phelps, C. (1999, May). An interview with Paul M. Sweezy. Monthly Review, 51(1). Reich, M. (1972, March). Does the U.S. economy require military spending? American Economic Review, 62(1/2), 296303. Reich, M., & Finkelhor, D. (1970, Fall). Capitalism and the military-industrial complex: The obstacles to conversion. Review of Radical Political Economics, 2(4), 125. Riesman, D. (1958). Abundance for what? Bulletin of the Atomic Scientists, 14(4), 135–139. Robinson, J. (1972, March). The second crisis of economic theory. American Economic Review, 62(1/2), 110. Salant, W. (1970, March 30). Oral history interview with Dr Walter S. Salant. Washington, DC: Harry S. Truman Presidential Library and Museum. Retrieved from https://www.trumanlibrary.org/oralhist/salantws.htm Salant, W. (1980, September). The collected writings of John Maynard Keynes: Activities 1940-43 and 1944-46: A review article. Journal of Economic Literature, 18(3), 1062. Samuelson, P. A. (1973). Capitalism, for better or worse. New York Times, March 4. Retrieved from http://www.nytimes.com/1973/03/14/archives/taking-stock-of-war.html Schultze, C. L. (1973, April). The economic content of national security policy. Foreign Affairs, 51 (3), 522540. Schumpeter Sees Peaceful Socialist Spread as Sweezy Remains Skeptical. (1947, March 28). Harvard Crimson [no author]. Retrieved from https://www.thecrimson.com/article/1947/3/28/schumpeter-sees-peaceful-socialist-spread-as/ Shaikh, A. (1978). An introduction to the history of crisis theories. In U.S. capitalism in crisis. New York, NY: Union for Radical Political Economics. Silk, L. (Ed.) (1974). Capitalism: The moving target. New York, NY: Quadrangle. Stein, H. (1969). The fiscal revolution in America. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Sweezy, A. R. (1940, November). Population growth and investment opportunity. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 55(1), 6479. Sweezy, A. R. (1942a). Reviewed work: Strategy for democracy by J. Donald Kingsley, David W. Petegorsky. Science & Society, 6(4), (Fall, 1942). Sweezy, A. R. (1943). Secular stagnation? In S. E. Harris (Ed.), Postwar Economic Problems (pp. 6782). New York, NY: McGraw- Hill. Sweezy, A. R. (1944). Making our economy work. New Masses (September 5) 1314. Sweezy, A. R. (1947). Declining investment opportunity. In S. E. Harris (Ed.), The new economics: Keynes’s influence on theory and public policy (pp. 424435). New York, NY: Augustus Kelley, 1947. Sweezy, A. R. (1972). The Keynesians and government policy, 10331939. American Economic Review (May), pp. 116124. Sweezy, P. M. (1938). Strategy for socialism. The Nation (June 25), p. 732. Sweezy, P. M. (1940). Letters to the editor, The Nation (October 12), p. 347. Downloaded by Mr Tim Barker At 07:40 30 April 2019 (PT) Macroeconomic Consequences of Peace 29 Sweezy, P. M. (1942). The theory of capitalist development. New York: Oxford University Press. The Age of Monopoly Capital: Selected Correspondence of Paul M. Sweezy and Paul A. Baran, 19491964. (2017). N. Baran and J.B. Foster (Eds.). New York, NY: Monthly Review Press. Sweezy, P. M. (1957). The Scientific-Industrial Revolution. New York, NY: Model, Roland, & Stone. Tobin, J. (1971). Reasons for recession. New York Times, May 16, E12. Tobin, J. (1974). The new economics one decade older. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Tobin, J. (1988). A revolution remembered. Challenge, 31(4), 3541. Toporowski, J. (2016). Multilateralism and military Keynesianism: Completing the analysis. Journal of Post-Keynesian Economics, 39(4), 437443. Turgeon, L. (1996). Bastard Keynesianism: The evolution of economic thinking and policymaking since World War II. Westport, CT: Greenwood Press. Van der Linden, M. (2018). Edward L. Sard (191399), theorist of the permanent war economy. Critique Journal of Socialist Theory, 46(1), 117130. Wachtel, H. (1970). Note. Review of Radical Political Economics, 2(3), i. Williams, S. R. (1993). Red-listed: Haunted by the Washington witch hunt. Reading, MA: AddisonWesley. Wolfe, A. (1981). America’s impasse: The rise and fall of the politics of growth. New York, NY: Pantheon Books, 1981. Woolston, M. B. Y. S. (1941). The structure of the Nazi economy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. ARCHIVAL SOURCES AB ¼ Paul A. Baran, correspondence with Paul M. Sweezy (19491964). Stanford Digital Repository. Available at http://purl.stanford.edu/km151hd0812, Paul Alexander Baran Papers (SC1234). Dept. of Special Collections and University Archives, Stanford University Libraries, Stanford, CA. PMS ¼ Paul Marlor Sweezy Papers, 19002004 (MS Am 3024). Houghton Library, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA. WSS ¼ Walter S. Salant Papers, 19211995. Harry S. Truman Library and Museum, Independence, MO.