“The debt isn't the reason we can't have nice things. Our broken thinking is.” In her book, The Deficit Myth, Professor Stephanie Kelton advocates for an unorthodox approach to solving the biggest economic problems of our day. Her prescription is simple: print more money and spend it. This idea, known as Modern Monetary Theory (MMT), argues that a government that controls its own currency can print money to fund its expenditures with no repercussions. 1 This thinking has inspired politicians such as Bernie Sanders, Elizabeth Warren, and Alexandria Ocasio-Cortez to release ambitious spending plans for infrastructure, pollution reduction, health care, education, and crisis response, promising to improve all these areas without raising taxes.2,3,4 Is this a fairy tale come true? Despite the rosy predictions, this “modern” theory is nothing but a repeat of old fantasies that threaten to upend decades of monetary discipline that generations of central bankers have built and which should not be hastily embraced by governments. It’s the Inflation The MMT approach of massively increasing money printing would result in dangerous degrees of inflation. Funding government expenditures using unlimited quantities of newly created money leads to a super-charged version of the expansion of the monetary base, which will create hyperinflation, significantly destabilizing the economy. Traditionally, when central banks try to increase the money supply, they have to inject money into banks and hope that the banks will then lend the money out to the market.5 Under that system, the money supply will not increase unless additional lending takes place. But if such money were placed in the hands of the government for spending, it would go to the market directly, increasing the money supply with no delay. Even if such money eventually went back to banks, to slow its circulation in the economy the central bank would have to increase interest rates 6 . The central banks then must continually print more money to cover the interest payments, leading to a potential spiral effect of escalating inflation. The history of monetary policy is littered with disastrous attempts to fund governments through money printing. After World War I, the Weimar Republic was saddled by massive war debt and reparation payments. Facing the possibility of sanction for failing to pay, its central bank resorted to printing money to buy foreign currencies to satisfy payment obligations. 7 Within six months, the general price level rose by 1700%. 8 Hyperinflation led to the rapid depreciation of the German Mark to such an extent that the exchange rate between the Mark and the US dollar reached an alarming ratio of four trillion Marks to one dollar.9 Since then, this horrific scenario has repeated itself in Zimbabwe, Argentina, and most recently Venezuela.10 Proponents of MMT reject these well-known precedents and argue that using money printing as a source of government revenue does not inevitably lead to inflation. They highlight Japan and the United States as compelling examples.11 In Japan, despite loose monetary policy with persistently low-interest rates falling below one percent for 1 years, 12 the country experienced consistently low inflation rates since 1990, with figures mostly below two percent and occasionally even entering negative territory.13 Furthermore, the money supply in Japan has continuously increased, nearly tripling by 2021.14 The United States witnessed a similar phenomenon from 2008 to 2019, with the money supply more than doubling, 15 while the Consumer Price Index (CPI) remained relatively stable at around two percent. 16 These prominent examples challenge conventional understandings of inflation and strengthen the claim that public expenditure funded by money creation does not necessarily result in significant inflation. Inflation is a multifaceted outcome influenced by various factors. Low inflation that occurs despite a constant expansionary monetary policy regime can be attributed to technological progress, an aging population, and low inflation expectations. 17 Technological advancements have boosted worker productivity, lowered average costs, and subsequently reduced overall price levels.18 Additionally, in Japan’s case, its labor market is characterized by firm-specific skills developed through long-term employment practices. 19 The increasing proportion of unemployed older workers, competing in entry-level positions without firm-specific skills, exerts downward pressure on wages, leading to long-term deflationary effects.20 Inflation expectations also play a paramount role in the recent success of taming inflation. A central bank that can act independently from the government’s fiscal authorities strongly influences inflation expectations.21 Notably, greater central bank independence correlates with lower expected inflation rates.22 The United States, for example, has maintained low inflation due in part to public trust in the Federal Reserve. During the 1970s, the Federal Reserve’s policies exemplified its commitment to maintaining price stability. This period, referred to as the great inflation, was marked by a decline in aggregate supply triggered by the oil crisis.23 Despite the risk of a recession, the Federal Reserve made the deliberate decision to raise interest rates as much as 20% to counter the escalating inflationary pressures. 24 , 25 More recently, Chairman Jerome Powell pledged that Federal Reserve would keep raising interest rates to tame the current supply shock-induced inflation even if that meant sparking a recession.26,27 This strategic approach showcased the central bank’s unwavering focus on curbing inflation and safeguarding the overall stability of the economy. As a result, professional forecasters and financial analysts anticipate that price inflation will align with the Federal Reserve’s target in the medium term.28 This sentiment fosters reduced public sensitivity to economic fluctuations, as confidence in the Fed’s commitment to the two percent inflation target reduces the likelihood of abrupt price level swings.29 However, the reliance on the central bank for government spending severely undermines central bank independence. In this framework, fiscal authorities gain the power to control the decisions of the central bank, blurring the boundaries between monetary and fiscal policies. As a result, government spending becomes synonymous with expansionary monetary policy, leading to an increase in the money supply. 2 However, this approach diminishes the central bank’s ability to effectively adjust interest rates, which historically served as a tool for addressing inflationary pressures. Consequently, public trust in the central bank erodes, and the economy becomes more sensitive to economic fluctuations, jeopardizing price stability.30 The loss of trust in the central bank undermines its capacity to implement effective measures to control inflation, creating a challenging environment for economic stability. Hurt Growth Potential Even setting aside the inflation issue, printing money to fund the government can still destabilize the economy and stymie growth. Continuous expansionary monetary policy necessitates a zero-interest rate environment, which, in turn, encourages borrowing and speculative behavior. With cheap credit amply supplied, individuals will invest in various assets as a means of increasing their wealth, leading to an asset price bubble.31,32 This was seen, for example, from 2008 to the days before the pandemic, as Bitcoin’s price jumped from a fraction of a penny to $19,345. 33 Additionally, when the government injects money into the economy, particularly through the central bank, it can also contribute to the formation of asset price bubbles. As the injected funds circulate through expenditure and income flows, a portion finds its way into the financial circuit through saving activities.34 This surplus liquidity, in turn, drives up asset prices due to increased demand. Simultaneously, “zombie firms” thrive due to the prevailing low borrowing costs in the economy, trapping productive workers in unproductive firms. Such firms are characterized by a lack of profitability over consecutive years, rendering them unable to meet their debt obligations.35 But when the interest rate is low, zombie firms can survive by borrowing. Specifically, the number of zombie firms correlates negatively with the nominal interest rate.36 This relationship was further evidenced during the Covid-19 pandemic in Japan when a zero-interest pandemic loan program was introduced in 2020 to provide financial aid to businesses. 37 This low-interest rate program resulted in a significant increase of 20,000 zombie firms from 2019 to 2020.38 The presence of zombie firms presents a significant menace to overall economic performance due to their inherent inefficiency, leading to ineffective resource allocation. These companies typically exhibit lower levels of productivity and have the potential to impede the growth of more efficient firms by locking up resources, leading to what is commonly known as “congestion effects.”39 By competing for resources, zombie firms drive down prices of other products in the market while simultaneously inflating wages and funding costs. In addition, adopting zero interest rates as a consequence of continuous expansionary monetary policy will inevitably result in a significant depreciation of the domestic currency. The principle of covered interest parity dictates that for people to hold a currency with a low interest rate, the exchange rate would have to appreciate to compensate for the absence of interest income associated with holding the domestic 3 currency. 40 However, the persistent disparity between domestic and foreign interest rates in the above scenario would trigger a steady outflow of capital and result in currency depreciation.41 Such depreciation means people would have less reason to hold the domestic currency, leading to further depreciation. The foreign exchange rate thus collapses, rendering international trade unsustainable due to the extreme devaluation of the currency. This severe depreciation adversely affects people’s living standards and exacerbates the economic challenges faced by the country. The above scenario spells doom, especially for developing countries. Developing countries are more likely to rely on imports for critical resources such as food and medicine42,43. A devalued currency means fewer imports, but to stop the devaluation, such countries also face unpleasant choices. Under the concept of the impossible trinity, also known as the trilemma, a country cannot achieve the following objectives simultaneously but only two: “autonomous monetary policy,” “free capital movement,” and a “stable foreign exchange rate.44.” With the interest rate staying at zero and an urgent need to stabilize the currency, developing countries would have to close their capital market to stop money from flowing out. This is problematic because the free movement of capital facilitates efficient investment allocation, leading to increased investment levels, improved living standards, and overall economic development. 45 Without it, investors would be hesitant to invest in a country, causing that country to further lose growth potential. A compelling example of the importance of attracting foreign investment and a stable exchange rate for developing countries is observed in China's post-liberalization policy. 46 From 1979 to 1994, annual capital inflows experienced a significant rise, increasing from less than 1 percent of total fixed investment to 18 percent.47 These foreign capital inflows have led to the establishment of factories, job creation, integration into global markets, and technology transfers. Furthermore, China's strategic decision to maintain a stable (while undervalued) exchange rate between 2002 and 2008 resulted in impressive export growth, averaging 27.3% and contributing significantly to its GDP expansion.48 Approximately 30% of China's economic growth during that period can be directly attributed to the outstanding performance of its export sector.49 Inflation due to money printing would have hindered this progress. Conclusion While Keynes advocated for government intervention in a world filled with uncertainties, his argument was often misconstrued in order to justify big government. Our predicament today is brought by this very hubris: unrestrained spending, even in normal times, leads to mounting debt, and when true needs for government intervention arise, there is no money for them. The last thing that should be done now is to look for some other defunct theory in the air. Instead of solely relying on increased tax revenue and direct government intervention in the market, an alternative approach can be pursued by employing policies that redirect existing market funds toward specific 4 industries. Such tried-and-true market-based solutions have worked well in the pursuit of environmental sustainability, for example, as carbon taxes have proven to be the most cost-effective way of removing CO2 emissions.50 Moreover, governments can keep incentivizing private sector participation in renewable energy ventures by removing market barriers and creating a business-friendly environment, without further burdening their budgets. This approach harnesses market forces and encourages private-sector engagement, allowing for efficient resource allocation and greater economic growth. Notes N. Gregory Mankiw. "A Skeptic’s Guide to Modern Monetary Theory." 12 December 2019, pp. 2 3. Ocasio-Cortez, Markey Reintroduce Green New Deal Resolution. 20 April 2021. https://ocasiocortez.house.gov/media/press-releases/ocasio-cortez-markey-reintroduce-green-new-deal-resolution-0 3 See Bernie Sander’s version of the green new deal, https://berniesanders.com/issues/green-new-deal/ 4 Warren version. https://elizabethwarren.com/plans/climatechange#:~:text=Elizabeth%20will%20require%20the%20Pentagon,microgrids%20and%20advanced% 20energy%20storage. 5 N. Gregory Mankiw. Macroeconomics, 10th edition, New York: Worth Publishers. 2019 6 N. Gregory Mankiw. "A Skeptic’s Guide to Modern Monetary Theory." 12 December 2019, pp. 2 3. 7 Evans, Richard J. The Coming of the Third Reich. New York City: Penguin Press. 2003 8 Ibid. 9 Coffin. Western Civilizations: Their History & Their Culture. W. W. Norton & Company; 14th edition. January 1, 2002 10 These three countries, historically exhibiting bad fiscal judgments, currently top the global inflation chart, https://www.imf.org/external/datamapper/PCPIEPCH@WEO/VEN?zoom=VEN&highlight=VEN 11 Only recently, both countries are beginning to experience inflation, mild compared to other examples we mentioned. And more importantly, economists agree that the current inflation is caused by supply shocks, not monetary policies. 12 The World Bank. Deposit interest rate (%) - Japan. <https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/FR.INR.DPST?locations=JP>. 13 International Monetary Fund. Inflation rate, average consumer prices, Annual percent change. <https://www.imf.org/external/datamapper/PCPIPCH@WEO/JPN?zoom=JPN&highlight=JPN>. 14 CEIC. Japan Money Supply M2. <https://www.ceicdata.com/en/indicator/japan/money-supplym2#:~:text=What%20was%20Japan's%20Money%20Supply,table%20below%20for%20more%20data >. 15 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (US), M2 [M2SL], retrieved from FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis; https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/M2SL, June 25, 2023. 16 The World Bank. Inflation, consumer prices (annual %) - United States. <https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/FP.CPI.TOTL.ZG?end=2022&locations=US&start=2009>. 17 Juan M. Sánchez , Hee Sung Kim. Why Is Inflation So Low?. 02 February 2018. <https://www.stlouisfed.org/publications/regional-economist/first-quarter-2018/why-inflation-so-low>. 18 Ibid. 19 Higuchi, Naoto, and Kiyoto Tanno. “What’s Driving Brazil-Japan Migration? The Making and Remaking of the Brazilian Niche in Japan.” International Journal of Japanese Sociology, vol. 12, no. 1, Nov. 2003, pp. 33 47. DOI.org (Crossref), https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-6781.2003.00041.x. 20 Shigeru Fujita & Ippei Fujiwara, 2021. Aging and the Real Interest Rate in Japan: A Labor Market Channel. Working Papers 21-23, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia. 21 Lee, James, et al. What Are Inflation Expectations? Why Do They Matter? 22 Jácome, Luis, and Samuel Pienknagura. Central Bank Independence and Inflation in Latin America—Through the Lens of History. IMF Working Papers, vol. 2022, no. 186, Sept. 2022, p. 1. DOI.org (Crossref), https://doi.org/10.5089/9798400219030.001. 1 2 5 Meltzer, Allan H., “Origins of the Great Inflation,” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 87, no. 2, part 2 (March/April 2005), pp. 145 75. 24 History of Federal Funds Rate, https://www.thebalancemoney.com/fed-funds-rate-history-highslows3306135#:~:text=The%20Fed%20increased%20the%20benchmark,stop%2Dgo%E2%80%9D%20mon etary%20policy. 25 See also the history of the Great Inflation, told by the Federal Reserve, https://www.federalreservehistory.org/essays/great-inflation 26 NPR Report, https://www.npr.org/2022/08/26/1119604922/federal-reserve-jerome-powell-inflationinterest-rates-recession 27 See also PBS’s documentary The Age of Easy Money. 28 Belz, Sage, and David Wessel. Explaining the Inflation Puzzle. p. 2. 29 The 2% target rate was first practiced by the central banks in New Zealand and now is followed by most advanced economies. 30 In the three countries with the highest inflation we mentioned, none has independent monetary authority. 31 Palley, Thomas I. Modern Money Theory (MMT): The Emperor Still Has No Clothes. p. 17. 32 See also the asset price bubble in Japan in the 80s, which was accompanied by monetary growth. Shiratsuka, Shigenori. n.d. The Asset Price Bubble in Japan in the 1980s: Lessons for Financial and Macroeconomic Stability. no. 21. 33 “A history of Bitcoin price,” https://www.investopedia.com/articles/forex/121815/bitcoins-pricehistory.asp 34 Palley, Thomas I. What’s Wrong with Modern Money Theory (MMT): A Critical Primer. p. 14. 35 Banerjee, Ryan, and Boris Hofmann. The Rise of Zombie Firms: Causes and Consequences. 2018. 36 Ibid. 37 JIJI. “Japan sees 'zombie' firms rise 30% after zero-interest pandemic loan program.” 03 May 2023. <https://www.japantimes.co.jp/news/2023/05/03/business/pandemic-zombie-companies/>. 38 “Zombie Firms Rise Again in Japan with Aid of Pandemic Loans.” 09 August 2022. <https://www.nippon.com/en/japan-data/h01399/>. 39 Banerjee, Ryan, and Boris Hofmann. The Rise of Zombie Firms: Causes and Consequences. 2018 40 Palley, Thomas I. Modern Money Theory (MMT): The Emperor Still Has No Clothes. p. 16. 41 Schmidt, Johannes. The Open (Economy) Flank of Modern Monetary Theory (MMT). p. 8. 42 Sri Lanka has just experienced such a crisis. And countries in Africa are also suffering as Russia’s invasion of Ukraine has propelled food price to rise. 43 Zanna, Luis-Felipe. Fighting Against Currency Depreciation, Macroeconomic Instability and Sudden Stops. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System International Finance Discussion Papers. 2005 44 Mankiw, N. Gregory. Macroeconomics, 10th edition, New York: Worth Publishers. 2019 45 Guitián, Manuel. The Challenge of Managing Global Capital Flows. 46 While China does not exactly have an open capital market, it does give special privileges to FDI that other developing countries may not be able to copy. See this analysis https://www.minneapolisfed.org/article/2016/chinas-foreigninvestment#:~:text=From%201990%20to%201994%2C%20total,82%20percent%20from%20other%2 0nations. 47 Zuliu Hu, Mohsin S. Khan. Why Is China Growing So Fast? April 1997, International Monetary Fund ed.: 5. 48 Yang Yao. "The Chinese Growth Miracle." Handbook of Economic Growth. Ed. Philippe Aghion, Steven N. Durlauf. Vol. II. 2014. 943-1031. <https://doi.org/10.1016/B978-0-444-53540-5.00007-0.>. 49 Ibid. 50 OECD Report on Effective Carbon Prices, 2013, https://read.oecdilibrary.org/environment/effective-carbon-prices_9789264196964-en 23 6