Journal of Business Administration and Management Sciences Research Vol. 2(12), pp. 319-329, December, 2013 Available online athttp://www.apexjournal.org ISSN 2315-8727© 2013 Apex Journal International Full Length Research Paper How far and wide? A cointegration analysis of trade openess and economic growth in Nigeria (1980-2011) OGUNRINOLA, Ifeoluwa Israel Department of Economics and Development Studies, Covenant University, Ota, Nigeria. Email: proxydave@yahoo.com Accepted 15 November, 2013 The study examines the relationship between trade openness and economic growth in Nigeria but focuses on how wide in terms of volume the nation should be towards foreign trade. The study employs the ADF test for unit root to investigate the presence or otherwise of unit root in the model. The variables were found integrated of order 1. The OLS estimation technique was also employed to establish linear relationship between variables in the regression model while a co-integration analysis was carried out to determine if there exists a long run relationship between variables of interest in the study. The study confirmed statistical significance of most variables in the model while a long run cointegration relationship was found of the variables involved. The period under study is from 1980-2011. The study concludes by agreeing that for the Nigerian economy to experience long run growth, it should focus on a fairly restricted policy oriented, open/receptive economy for international trade. Keywords: Trade openness, economic growth, nigeria, cointegration. INTRODUCTION In the world economy since 1950 there has been a massive liberalization of world trade, first under the auspices of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), established in 1947 and now under the auspices of the World Trade Organization (WTO) which replaced the GATT in 1993. According to Thirwall (2000), tariff levels in highly developed nations have skimmed down dramatically, and now average approximately 4 percent. Tariff levels in developing nations of the world have also been reduced, although they still remain relatively high, averaging 20 percent in the low-and middle-income countries. Non-tariff barriers to trade, such as quotas, licenses and technical specifications, are also being gradually dismantled, but rather more slowly than tariffs. Regional Trade Agreements (RTAs) have also become very fashionable in the form of Free Trade Areas and Customs Unions. The WTO lists 76 that have been established or modified since 1948. The major ones are the European Union (EU); the North American Free Trade Area (NAFTA); Mercosur covering Argentina, Brazil, Paraguay, Uruguay and Chile; APEC, covering countries in the Asia and Pacific region; ASEAN covering South-East Asian countries, and SACU, covering countries in southern Africa. The liberalization of trade has led to a massive expansion in the growth of world trade relative to world output. While world output (or GDP) has expanded fivefold, the volume of world trade has grown 16 times at an average compound rate of just over 7 percent per annum. In some individual countries, notably in South-East Asia, the growth of exports has exceeded ten percent per annum. Exports have tended to grow fastest in countries with more liberal trade regimes, and these countries have experienced the fastest growth of GDP (Thirwall, 2000). Foreign trade can be defined as commercial transactions (in goods and/or services) across international frontiers or boundaries. Foreign trade plays a vital role in estimating economic and social attributes of countries around the world. The workings of an economy in terms of growth rate and per-capita income have been based on the domestic production and consumption activities and in conjunction with foreign transactions of goods and services. Further, the role of foreign trade in economic development is considerable and the relationship between openness and economic growth has long been a subject of much interest and controversy in international trade literature. The classical and neo-classical economists attached so much importance to foreign trade 320 J. Bus. Admin. Manage. Sci. Res. in a nation’s development that they regarded it as an engine of growth. Over the past several decades, the economies of the world have become greatly connected through international trade and globalization. Foreign trade has been identified as the oldest and most important part of a country’s external economic relationships. It plays a vital and central role in the development of a modern global economy. Its impact on the growth and development of countries has increased considerably over the years and has significantly contributed to the advancement of the world economy. The impact of foreign trade on a country’s economy is not only limited to the quantitative gains, but also structural change in the economy and facilitating of international capital inflows. Trade enhances the efficient production of goods and services through allocation of resources to countries that have comparative advantage in their production. Foreign trade has been identified as an instrument and driver of economic growth (Frankel and Romer, 1999). It has been stated theoretically and proven empirically that economic openness contributes to the level of the economy (Ersoy and Deniz, 2011; Sakyi, 2011; Chaudhry et al. 2010). This is because in a competitive environment, prices get lower and the products become diversified through which consumer surplus emerges. Gains from specialization and efficiency are also further advantages of economic openness. Hence, it is quite reasonable that economies generally desire to be economically open. Of the various objectives of foreign trade, the promotion of economic growth and stability holds more weight. Various researchers have, in their various research works, delved into studying the numerous advantages and gains obtainable from trade between economies. As a result, there has therefore been an increasing interest in the study of foreign trade and its benefits particularly to developing countries. However, (recent) empirical investigations have not been able to show how healthy or otherwise, vastly (or scarcely) opened boarders are to economic growth. Actual gains from trade rather than gains accrued to vastly or scarcely open boarders are most often, the major points of discourse in most research. To this end, this research work concerns itself with examining how porous the Nigerian economy should be towards foreign trade. How exactly wide and receptive should the economy accommodate foreign trade in the quest for sustained long run economic growth? This study focuses extensively on the trade pattern of Nigeria over the years with more attention on the various trade policies or programs that had been adopted over the years. Relevant trade theories ranging from classical theories to contemporary trade theories shall be highlighted. The Real Gross Domestic Product (Real GDP) shall be used as the indicator for the economic growth of Nigeria. The study time frame shall be restricted to fall between 1980 and 2011. The relevant questions in this research are: What has been the pattern of international trade in Nigeria? Has trade openness in Nigeria stimulated economic growth? To what extent should the economy be open to foreign trade in the quest for sustainable long run growth and development? Therefore, the main objectives of this paper are to: (1) examine the pattern of international trade in Nigeria. (2) determine if indeed, trade openness stimulates economic growth in Nigeria and, (3) determine the extent to which the economy should be open to foreign trade in the quest for sustainable long run growth and development. Cointegration analysis is adopted for this study to test for the long run relationship between trade openness and economic growth in Nigeria. Individual variable relationship between the various trade openness indicators and economic growth variable (Real GDP) will be established and actual functional relationships will be determined using the OLS estimation method. The Augmented Dickey-Fuller unit root test for stationarity will also be conducted for the variables of interest. Secondary data would be used in this study. The relevant data to be used would be sourced from the Central Bank of Nigeria’s statistical reports, annual reports and statement of accounts for the years under review. REVIEW OF RELATED LITERATURE AND THEORIES Openness refers to the degree of dependence of an economy on international trade and financial flows. Trade openness on the other hand measures the international competitiveness of a country in the global marked. Thus, we may talk of trade openness and financial openness. Trade openness is often measured by the ratio of import to GDP or alternatively, the ratio of trade to GDP. It is now generally accepted that increase openness with respect to both trade and capital flows will be beneficial to a country. Increased openness facilitates greater integration into global markets. Integration and globalization are beneficial to developing countries although there are also some potential risks (Iyoha and Oriakhi, 2002). Trade openness is interpreted to include import and export taxes, as well as explicit non tariff distortions of trade or in varying degrees of broadness to cover such matters as exchange-rate policies, domestic taxes and subsides, competition and other regulatory policies, education policies, the nature of the legal system, the form of government, and the general nature of institution and culture (Baldwin, 2002). One of the policy measures of the Structural Adjustment Programme (SAP) adopted by Nigeria in 1986 is Trade Openness. This means the dismantling of trade and exchange control domestically. Trade liberalization has been found to perform the role of engine of growth, especially via high real productivity export (Obadan, 1993). He argued that with export, a nation can take advantage of division of labour and procure desired Ogunrinola goods and services from abroad, at considerable savings in terms of inputs of productive resources, thereby helping to increase the efficiency of the export industry. Export growth sets up a circle of growth, so that once a country is on the growth path, it maintains this momentum, of competitive position in world trade and performs continually better relative to other countries. The doctrine that trade enhances welfare and growth has a long and distinguished ancestry dating back to Adam Smith (1723-90). In his famous book, and inquiry into nature and causes of the wealth of nations (1776), Smith stressed the importance of trade as a vent for surplus production and as a means of widening the market thereby improving the division of labor and the level of productivity. He asserts that “between whatever places foreign trade is carried on, all of them derive two distinct benefits from it. It carries the surplus part of the produce of their land and labour for which there is no demand among them, and brings back in return something else for which there is a demand. It gives value to their superfluities, by exchanging them for something else, which may satisfy part of their wants and increase their satisfaction. By means of it, the narrowness of the labour market does not hinder the division of labour in any particular branch of art or manufacture from being carried to the highest perfection. By opening a more extensive market for whatever part of the produce of their labour may exceed the home consumption, it encourages them to improve its productive powers and to augment its annual produce to the utmost, and thereby to increase the real revenue of wealth and society” (Thirwall, 2000). We may summarize the absolute advantage trade theory of Adam Smith, thus, countries should specialize in and export those commodities in which they had an absolute advantage and should import those commodities in which the trading partner had an absolute advantage. That is to say, each country should export those commodities it produced more efficiently because the absolute labour required per unit was less than that of the prospective trading partners (Appleyard and Field, 1998). In the 19th century, the Smithian trade theory generated a lot of arguments. This made David Ricardo (1772-1823) to develop the theory of comparative advantage and showed rigorously in his principles of political economy and taxation (1817) that on the assumptions of perfect competition and the full employment of resources, countries can reap welfare gains by specializing in the production of those goods with the lowest opportunity over domestic demand, provided that the international rate of exchange between commodities lies between the domestic opportunity cost ratios. These are essentially static gains that arise from the reallocation of resources from one sector to another as increased specialization, based on comparative advantage, takes place. These are the trade creation gains that arise within customs to trade are removed between members, but the 321 gains are once-for-all. Once the tariff barriers have been removed and no further reallocation takes place, the static gains are exhausted. The static gains from trade stem from the basic fact that countries are differently endowed with resources and because of this the opportunity cost of producing products varies from country to country. The law of comparative advantage states that countries will benefit if they specialize in the production of those goods for which the opportunity cost is low and exchange those goods for other goods, the opportunity cost of which is higher. That is to say, the static gains from trade are measured by the resource gains to be obtained by exporting to obtain imports more cheaply in terms of resources given up, compared to producing the goods oneself. In other words, the static gains from trade are measured by the excess cost of import substitution, by what is saved for not producing the imported good domestically. The resource gains can then be used in a variety of ways including increased domestic consumption of both goods (Thirwall, 2000). Baldwin (2003) has demonstrated persuasively that countries with few trade restrictions achieve more rapid economic growth than countries with more restrictive policies. As poverty will be reduced more quickly through faster growth, poor countries could use the trade liberalization as a policy tool. Trade liberalization reduces relative price distortions and allows those activities with a comparative advantage to expand and consequently foster economic growth. Poor countries tend to engage in labour-intensive activities due to an overabundance of available labour. Thus the removal of trade barriers in these countries promotes intensive economic activity and provides employment and income to many impoverished people. On the other hand, the pursuit of trade-restrictive policies by labour endowed poor countries distorts relative prices in favor of capital-intensive activities. The removal of trade barriers could lead to a decline in the value of assets of protected industries and therefore to the loss of jobs in those industries. This implies that trade liberalization has distributional effects as industries adjust to liberalized trade policies. Economist Ann Harrison‘s 1991 paper makes a synthesis of previous empirical studies between openness and the rate of GDP growth, comparing the results from cross-section and panel estimations while controlling for country effects. Harrison concluded that on the whole, correlations across openness measures seem to be positively associated with GDP growth - the more open the economy, the higher the growth rate, or the more protected the local economy, the slower the growth in income. On the other hand, trade restrictions or barriers are associated with reduced growth rates and social welfare, and countries with higher degrees of protectionism, on average, tend to grow at a much slower pace than countries with fewer trade restrictions. This is because tariffs reflect additional direct costs that 322 J. Bus. Admin. Manage. Sci. Res. producers have to absorb, which could reduce output and growth. Frankel and Roma (1999) and Irwin and Tervio (2002) in their separate and independent studies also suggested that countries that are more open to trade tends to experience higher growth rates and per-capital income than closed economy. Klanow and Rodriguez – Clare (1997) used general equilibrium model to establish that the greater number of intermediate input combination results in productivity gain and higher output, despite using the same capital labour input which exhibit the economics increasing international trade return to scale. Nigeria is basically an open economy with international transactions constituting a significant proportion of her aggregate output. To a large extent, Nigeria’s economic development depends on the prospects of her export trade with other nations. Trade provides both foreign exchange earnings and market stimulus for accelerated economic growth. Openness to trade may generate significant gains that enhance economic transformation. This means that, there will be diffusion of knowledge and innovation amongst other open economies of the world. Trade openness has been hailed for its beneficial effects on productivity, the adoption and use of better technology and investment promotion – which are channels for stimulating economic growth. Over the years, Nigeria has identified deeper trade integration as a means to foster economic growth and to alleviate poverty. Theoretical Review Trade theories: Trade as engine of growth The origins of trade can be traced to the absolute and comparative advantage as well as Hecksher Ohlin theories (Jayme, 2001). The theory of absolute advantage was formulated by Adam Smith in his famous book title “Inquiry into the nature and the wealth of Nations” 1776. The theory emanated due to the demise of mercantilism. Smith argued that with free trade each nation could specialize in the production of those commodities in which it could produce more efficiently than other nations and import those commodities it could not produce efficiently. According to him, the international specialization of factors in production would result in increase in the world output. Thus this specialization makes goods available to all nations. Comparative advantage theory This theory was propounded David Ricardo. The theory assumed the existence of two countries, two commodities and one factors of production. To him a country export the commodity whose comparative advantage lower and import commodity whose comparative cost is higher. The theory also assumed that the level of technology is fixed for both nations and that trade is balanced and rolls out the flow of money between nations. However, the theory is based on the labour theory of values which states that the price of the values of a commodity is equal to the labour time going into the production process. Labour is used in a fixed proportion in the production of all commodities. But the assumptions underlying is quite unrealistic because labour can be subdivided into skilled, semiskilled and unskilled labour and there are other factors of production. Despite the limitations, comparative cost advantage cannot be discarded because its application is relevant in explaining the concept of opportunity cost in the modern theory of trade. Hecksher-Ohlin trade theory The theory focuses on the differences in relative factor endowments and factor prices between nations on the assumption of equal technology and tastes. The Model was based on two main propositions; namely; a country will specialize in the production and export of commodity whose production requires intensive use of abundant resources. Secondly, countries differ in factor endowment. Some countries are capital intensive while some are labour intensive. He identified the different in pre-trade product prices between nations as the immediate basis of trade, the prices depends on production possibility curve (supply side) as well as the taste and preference (demand side). But the production possibility curve depends on factor endowment and technology. To him, a nation should produce and export a product for which abundant resources is used be it capital or labour. The model suggests that developing countries are labour abundant and therefore they should concentrate in the production of primary product such as agricultural product and they should import capital intensive product i.e. manufactured goods from the developed countries. The model also assumes two countries, two commodities and two factors and that two factors inputs labour and capital are homogenous. The production function is assumed to exhibit constant return to scale. However, the theory is not free from criticism and this because factors inputs are not identical in quality and cannot be measured in homogenous units. Also factor endowment differs in quality and variety. Relative factor prices reflect differences in relative factor endowmentsupply therefore outweigh demand in the determination of factor prices. Despite this criticism, trade increases the total world output. All countries gain from trade and it also enables countries to secure capital and consumption of goods from the rest of the world. Theories of economic growth Economic growth is best defined as a long term Ogunrinola expansion of productive potential of the economy. Trend growth is the smooth path of long run national output i.e. it requires a long run series of macroeconomic data which could be twenty years or more. The trend of growth could be expanded by raising capital investment spending as a share of national income as well as the size of capital inputs and labour supply, labour force and the technological advancement. There are different schools of thought that have discussed the causes of growth and development and they are discussed as follows: Neo-Classical growth theory This was first propounded by Robert Solow over 40 years ago. The model believes that a sustained increase in capital investments increased the growth rate only temporarily, because the ratio of capital to labour goes up. The marginal product of additional units is assumed to decline and thus an economy eventually moves back to a long term growth-path with the real GDP growing at the same rate as the growth of the workforce plus factor to reflect improving productivity. Neo-classical economists who subscribe to the Solow model believes that to raise an economy long term trend rate of growth requires an increase in labour supply and also a higher level of productivity of labor and capital. Differences in the rate of technological change between countries are said to explain much of the variation in growth rates. The neo-classical model treats productivity improvements as an exogenous variable which means that productivity improvements are assumed to be independent of the amount of capital investment. Endogenous growth theory To them, they believe that improvements in productivity can be attributed directly to a faster pace of innovation and external investment in human capital. They stress the need for government and private sector institutions to encourage innovation and provide incentives for individual and business to be inventive. There is also central role of the accumulation of knowledge as a determinant of growth i.e. knowledge industries such as telecommunication, electronics, software or biotechnology are becoming increasingly important in developed countries. The proponent of endogenous growth theory believes that there are positive externalities to be exploited from the development of a high value added knowledge economy which is able to developed and maintain a competitive advantage in fact growth within the global economy. They are of the opinion that the rate of technological progress should not be taken as a constant in a growth model- government policies can permanently raise a country growth rate if they lead to 323 move intense competition in markets and help to stimulate product and process innovation. That they are increasing returns to scale from new capital investment and also private sector investment is a key source of technical progress and that investment in human capital is an essential ingredient of long term growth. Harrod – Domar growth model Harrod-Domar opined that economic growth is achieved when more investment leads to more growth. They theory is based on linear production function with output given by capital stock (K) tines a constant. Investment according to the theory generates income and also augments the productive capacity of the economy by increasing the capital stock. In as much as there is net investment, real income and output continue to expend. And, for full employment equilibrium level of income and output to be maintained, both real income and output should expand at the same rate with the productive capacity of the capital stock. The theory maintained that for the economy to maintain a full employment, in the long run, net investment must increase continuously as well as growth in the real income at a rate sufficient enough to maintain full capacity use of a growing stock of capital. This implies that a net addition to the capital stock in the form of new investment will go a long way to increase the flow of national income. From the theory, the national savings ratio is assumed to be a fixed proportions of national output and that total investment is determined by the level of total savings i.e. S = SY which must be equal to net investment, I. The net investment which is I = ∆K = K∆Y because K has a direct relationship to total national income. And, therefore SY = K∆Y which simply means ∆Y/Y is growth rate of GDP that is determined by the net national savings ratio, s and the national capital output, K in the absence of government, the growth rate of national income will be positively related to the saving ratio i.e. the more an economy is able to save and invest out of a given GDP, the greater the growth of GDP and which will be inversely related to capital output ratio. The basis of the theory is that for an economy to grow, it should be able to save and invest a certain proportion of their GDP. The basis for foreign trade rests on the fact that nations of the world do differ in their resource endowment, preferences, technology, scale of production and capacity for growth and development. Countries engage in trade with one another because of these major differences and foreign trade has opened up avenues for nations to exchange and consume goods and services which they do not produce. Differences in natural endowment present a case where countries can only consume what they have the capacity to produce, but trade enables them to consume what other countries produce. 324 J. Bus. Admin. Manage. Sci. Res. Therefore countries engage in trade in order to enjoy variety of goods and services and improve their people’s standard of living. Some stylized facts Nigeria is Sub-Saharan Africa’s second largest economy, with nominal 2006 GDP of $235bn (at PPP) behind South Africa’s $600bn. It has also been one of Africa’s fastest growing economies, outpacing South Africa, Kenya, Ghana and most of its neighbors with a CAGR of 7% over the past 10 years. However, its growth has been more erratic due to the high reliance on natural resources (see further UNDP, Human Development Report 2007). Despite the fast pace of growth and the strong resource endowment, Nigeria has so far not increased its GDP per capita beyond that of its smaller and resource-poor neighbors. It’s GDP per capita is below that of Cameroon, Ivory Coast, Kenya, and it is only 12% that of South Africa. Poverty and the rural nature of the Nigerian economy put pressure on financial services institution to innovate and to reach out to poor customers. Nigeria’s economy is heavily reliant on the oil and gas sector. It makes up more than 40% of the GDP (Natural Resources and Industry), and accounts for virtually 100% of exports and 80% of budgetary revenues for the government. Nigeria is the world’s 12th largest producer of oil, mainly supplying the US. Next to natural resources the most important sector is agriculture, accounting for approximately 35% of GDP. A large portion of this is subsistence farming with declining productivity. This composition of GDP is quite unlike that of its neighbors, due to the importance of natural resources in the country. The natural resources sector is one of the drivers of sophistication in the financial services industry. While rising oil and gas prices have had a strong positive effect on GDP, exports and government revenues over time, it has however, not been Nigeria’s only driver of growth. For instance, in 2007 political unrest in the Delta region affected oil production, but strong growth in the non-oil sector meant that overall GDP still grew by 5.8%. The non-oil sector has grown at a 7% CAGR over the past 10 years. This growth is expected to remain robust, due to good performances in certain sectors of the economy, particularly in communications, wholesale and retail trade, and construction; the financial sector will play a key part in facilitating further growth in the economy. Hence, as a result of the large volume of oil export in Nigeria, it is clear that foreign trade is essential in ensuring foreign earnings which should enrich the nation’s foreign exchange/national reserves with a view to exploring such surpluses into growth related activities for the country. RESEARCH RESULT This METHODOLOGY aspect basically concerns AND itself EMPIRICAL with the methodology of the research as well as presenting the result of econometric estimation and gives explanation of various findings. The importance of this section lies in its quantitative and empirical content within which the purpose of this study would be justified. Also of importance, the overall findings and validation of hypothesis tested. Model specification Following the production function theory which show how the level of a country’s productivity depends on foreign direct investments (FDI), trade openness (OPN), exchange rates (EXRT) and government expenditure (GEXP), we specify our model showing how the interplay of these chosen variables actually affect the economic growth of Nigeria. The mathematical model will be based on the methodology adopted by Jude and Pop-Silaghi (2008) for the countries Romania and Karbasi; Mohammed and Ghofrani (2005) for 42 developing countries. However for this study, we make some slight adjustments to the adopted methodology to suit the scope within which this study covers. The model used for this study has been so chosen because of its relevance to the Nigerian environment and availability of data. The dependent variable chosen for this study as proxy for economic growth is the real gross domestic product, written as RGDP. The explanatory variables are: Exchange rate, Foreign Direct Investment, Government Expenditure and Trade Openness. Mathematically, the functional relationship between variables of interest is shown: RGDP = f(OPN, EXRT, FDI, GEXP) …………………..(i) Writing the above equation explicitly in an econometric sense, we have: RGDP = β 0 + β1OPN + β 2 EXRT + β3 FDI + β 4 GEXP + ε ….(ii) (+/-) (+/-) (+) (+) (+/-) With a view to linearizing equation (ii), we apply the Logarithmic function thus: LGRGDP = β 0 + β1LGOPN + β 2 LGEXRT + β3 LGFDI + β 4 LGGEXP + ε ………………………………………………………..…(iii) Where β 0 , β1 , β 2 , β3 and β 4 are regression ε is the standard error term, which is a parameters and random variable and has well defined probabilistic properties. Also, OPN = Degree of openness, determined by the sum of total imports and exports, divided by total output i.e. M +X GDP Ogunrinola 325 Table 1. The augmented dickey-fuller test for stationarity. Variables LGEXRT LGFDI LGGDP LGGEXP LGOPN ADF test statistic ST At level At 1 difference -2.271587 -3.241196 -0.149602 -10.90008 0.900422 -3.854137 -0.082212 -3.720971 -1.326643 -5.301568 Critical values (5%) ST At level AT 1 difference -2.960411 -2.963972 -2.967767 -2.967767 -2.960411 -2.963972 -2.960411 -2.963972 -2.963972 -2.963972 Order of integration I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) Source: Author’s computation EXRT = Real exchange rate in Nigeria FDI = Foreign Direct Investments from abroad to the country GEXP = Government Expenditure in the country. of central bank of Nigeria, Economic and financial Review and Central bank of Nigeria Statistical bulletin. DISCUSSION The signs on the variables are based on the apriori Unit root test result expectations from theory, which is the direction of the relationship between the respective independent Literature has established that most time series variables variables and the explained or dependent variable. are not stationary. Therefore, using non-stationary The Real GDP variable is included to capture the variables in the model might lead to spurious regression growth and activity of the economy. How well an which cannot be used for precise prediction (Gujarati, economy is performing, how rich an economy is, as well 2003). Hence, our first step is to examine the characas how the condition of general well-being in an economy teristics of the time series data used for estimation of the is are all captured in the RGDP variable. model to determine whether the variables have unit roots, The degree of openness, OPN, measured as the ratio that is, whether they are stationary or otherwise. The of the sum of total export and total imports to the GDP. Augmented Dickey-Fuller test is used for this purpose. A According to Alege and Osabuohien (2013), African variable is considered stationary if the absolute ADF teconomies can be regarded as largely open in view of statistic value is higher than any of the absolute OPN at an average of about 104.85% over the period of Mackinnon values. The test is conducted with intercept study and 82.26 per cent in 2007 only. Open economies term. are preferred by market seeking and efficiency seeking From the unit root test as summarized in Table 1, it investors since there are fewer trade restrictions, broader shows that all variables in the model (LGEXRT, LGFDI, market access, numerous advantages from international LGGDP, LGEXP and LGOPN) are all non-stationary at division of labor and wider economic linkages. level i.e. they all contain a unit root. However, The Real Exchange Rate variable, EXRT, measured by differencing each variable once makes all non stationary the amount of the national currency required in exchange variables stationary at 5% level of significance. This now for one unit of another foreign currency, notably the US$ implies that the variables no longer contain a unit root or, is another variable which measures the growth rate of an we say they are integrated of order one i.e. they are I(1). economy. When this number increases, depreciation of This therefore, makes the variables suitable for the OLS local currency occurs while when it is lower, appreciation regression analysis which follows. of local currency also occurs. The Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) from abroad to the The OLS estimation country is included in the model since the contribution of foreign investments to an economy may affect long run From the regression result, in Table 2, the estimated growth. model can be re-written thus: Finally, Government Expenditure (GEXP) is set to capture the effects of government consumption expenditure or public spending on international trade on DLGRGDP = 17.52990 - 0.223382DLGOPN − 0.138123DLGEX economic growth in the country since- some evidences DLGRGDP = 17.52990 0.223382D LGOPN − 0.138123DLGEXRT − 0.027512DLGFDI + 0.230351DLGGEXP suggest a positive relationship between government spending and economic growth. As earlier mentioned, annual time-series data on the The implication of the OLS estimation variables under study covering a nineteen-year period 1980-2011 are used for estimation of functions. Data The R squared which measures the goodness of fit of the were collected from various editions of the various issues estimated parameters stands at 91.8998%, implying a 326 J. Bus. Admin. Manage. Sci. Res. Table 2. OLS analysis result. Dependent Variable: DLGGDP Method: Least Squares Date: 07/28/13 Time: 13:02 Sample (adjusted): 1982 2011 Included observations: 30 after adjustments Variable DLGOPN DLGEXRT DLGFDI DLGGEXP C R-squared Adjusted R-squared S.E. of regression Sum squared resid Log likelihood Durbin-Watson stat Coefficient -0.223382 -0.138123 -0.027512 0.230351 17.52990 0.918998 0.906038 0.064314 0.103406 42.48615 1.345918 Std. Error 0.079919 0.036675 0.029505 0.034258 0.769473 t-Statistic -2.795107 -3.766129 -0.932448 6.724046 22.78171 Mean dependent var S.D. dependent var Akaike info criterion Schwarz criterion F-statistic Prob(F-statistic) Prob. 0.0098 0.0009 0.3600 0.0000 0.0000 22.01654 0.209810 -2.499077 -2.265544 70.90883 0.000000 Source: Author’s computation from EViews 5.0 Software package. good fit. However, the adjusted R squared which takes care of the degree of freedom and the number of regressors in the model stands at 90.6038%. This also implies a good fit. The Durbin-Watson statistic which measures the level of serial correlation among variables in the model reads 1.345918. This point out the presence of a positive serial correlations between variables in the model. The joint significance of variables in the model measured by the F statistic is 70.90883 with p value of 0.000000. This implies that all variables in the model are jointly significant in explaining variations in the Real GDP. Individual significance as measured by the t-statistic for LGOPN, LGEXRT and LGGEXP are -2.795107, 3.766129 and 6.754046 respectively. This means that LGOPN, LGEXRT and LGGEXP are individually statistically significant in explaining variations in the dependent variable, LGGDP. However, LGFDI is not individually statistically significant in explaining variations in LGGDP because of its low t-statistic value (-0.932448). The log-linear form of the model compels an explanation of the behavior of individual variables in form of elasticity. Hence, all explanatory variables in the model (with the exception of the constant term) are inelastically related to the dependent variable. More explicitly, an increase in each of the independent variables by 1 per cent yields a less than 1 percent increase in the dependent variable. According to apriori, the constant term is expected to show either positive or negative sign. From the result, we observe a positive sign. The trade openness variable is expected to carry either a positive or a negative sign. From the result, we observe a negative sign, though statistically significant. This imply that trade openness, though important in stimulating economic growth, can deter the rate of growth through external shocks on the domestic economy from the international market, weakness of domestic industry as a result of overreliance on imports, large disparities in foreign exchange rates, and much more. It is from these and many more reasons that the openness variable caries a negative sign. The exchange rate and fdi variables also carry a negative sign which negates expectation from apriori. These may be caused by various reasons such as: i. Use of domestic resources (both human resources, sometimes capital and natural resources) while repariating profits from such investments abroad (i.e. home country of the foreign investors). This leads to the continuous use of Nigeria’s resources of all sorts in the generation of output whose profits are not accounted for in the country’s GDP. ii. Exchange rate disparities which leads to deficits in the balance of payments iii. Increase in the cost of imports to the country. iv. Deficit financing of trade transactions by the government v. Poor trading policies and terms of trade, e.t.c. Government expenditure shows statistical significance and a positive relationship to economic growth as indicated by the positive sign. This suggests the importance of government spending in foreign trade and the possible effects it has on economic growth. this also imply that as government makes more effort in financing international trade arrangements, as well as providing other fiscal and monetary services such as subsidy arrangements to Ogunrinola 327 Table 3. Co-integration test result. Date: 07/27/13 Time: 22:09 Sample (adjusted): 1983 2011 Included observations: 29 after adjustments Trend assumption: Linear deterministic trend Series: LGGDP LGOPN LGEXRT LGFDI LGGEXP Lags interval (in first differences): 1 to 1 Unrestricted Cointegration Rank Test (Trace) Hypothesized Trace 0.05 No. of CE(s) Eigenvalue Statistic Critical Value None * 0.803271 102.0035 69.81889 At most 1 * 0.632638 54.85155 47.85613 At most 2 0.403887 25.81076 29.79707 At most 3 0.304443 10.80835 15.49471 At most 4 0.009614 0.280142 3.841466 Trace test indicates 2 cointegrating eqn(s) at the 0.05 level * denotes rejection of the hypothesis at the 0.05 level **MacKinnon-Haug-Michelis (1999) p-values Unrestricted Cointegration Rank Test (Maximum Eigenvalue) Hypothesized Max-Eigen 0.05 No. of CE(s) Eigenvalue Statistic Critical Value None * 0.803271 47.15199 33.87687 At most 1 * 0.632638 29.04079 27.58434 At most 2 0.403887 15.00241 21.13162 At most 3 0.304443 10.52821 14.26460 At most 4 0.009614 0.280142 3.841466 Prob.** 0.0000 0.0096 0.1345 0.2236 0.5966 Prob.** 0.0008 0.0323 0.2887 0.1795 0.5966 Max-eigenvalue test indicates 2 cointegrating eqn(s) at the 0.05 level * denotes rejection of the hypothesis at the 0.05 level **MacKinnon-Haug-Michelis (1999) p-values Source: Author’s Computation from EViews 5.0 Software Package. domestic trading partners, the economy stands a better chance of experiencing admirable growth progressions in time. Cointegration analysis Co-integration analysis is carried out to determine the existence of long-run relationship that exists between the dependent variable and its regressors. When one or all of the variables is/are non-stationary at level, it means they have stochastic trend. Essentially, co-integration is used to check if the independent variables can predict the dependent variable now (short-run) or in the future (longrun). The long run relationships among the variables are examined using the Johasen (1991) cointegration framework. The cointegration result is presented in Table 3. From the co-integration result presented in Table 3, the indication of two co-integrating equations from the trace test statistic was observed. To this end, we reject the null hypothesis that there is no co-integration between variables in the model. In conclusion, we validate the existence of a long run relationship between LGRGDP, LGEXTR, LGFDI, LGOPN and LGGEXP in the model. Conclusion How wide, really, does an economy need to open up to foreign transactions with other nations of the world to attain sustainable long run growth and development? The result of this study has indicated that trade openness, exchange rate, foreign direct investment and government expenditure can serve as a stimulant of growth in Nigeria given that the country is “open enough” for international trade arrangements with other countries. Also, going by apriori, other variables save the exchange rate and foreign direct investment conform to expectation which implies that the chosen variables indeed show conformity with relevant theories in confirming the importance of each variable as well as the combination of all on the economic growth of Nigeria. The influence of the degree of openness of trade on economic growth is a circle of causation. First, external trade increases the quantity and quality of foreign direct investment. This leads to the upgrading of all other sectors of the economy, which in turn raises the national productivity level. Foreign direct investment by itself increases the productivity level of other sectors which increases national output and causes an upgrade in living 328 J. Bus. Admin. Manage. Sci. Res. standards. A poor external trade system will produce aneconomy that will prevent investment from producing positive trickle down effects in a recipient (open) economy. We find that although, trade openness shows statistical significance, it is however negatively related to growth; a behavior which has been predicted by apriori. In conclusion, it has been learnt from the study that for an economy to grow, it must strengthen its relative capacity to trade by improving its domestic industry for exports in order to avoid over reliance on imports, render its economy less vulnerable to trade shocks by implementing new workable international trade policies while making necessary adjustments to existing ones and also create an enabling environment for trade. For the case of Nigeria however, how permeable her economy is to foreign international trade should be curtailed for the following reasons, among others: i. Due to its relatively weak economic and financial structure, overly profound volumes of international dependence in Nigeria may further weaken the economy as a result of direct shock effects on the economy. Exchange rate volatility may cause further disequilibrum on the balance of payments, turn the government to harmful deficit financing policies and may also render the domestic currency valueless over time. ii. The Nigerian economy is characterized by a largely uncatered informal sector. Such sector which is very large is needed to drive the economy through domestic production to cater for domestic needs. However, a widely open boarder for imports of all domestic substitute goods kills domestic initiatives, causes unhealthy competition with domestic production and results in over reliance on imported goods rather than focusing on domestic strengths. iii. Negligence of other sectors in the economy other than the oil sector as a result of a very porous international barrier on oil exports. iv. Various unhealthy international trade transactions which may be detrimental to the general well-being of economies and its citizenry may result from a largely porous foreign trade barrier in an economy. For these reasons, and many more yet unmentioned, the degree of openness to trade in Nigeria must be wide enough, yet with sufficient restrictive foreign trade policies in order to help foster sustainable long run growth and development in the country. REFERENCES Alege, P.O., Osabuohien, E.S. (2013). “G-Localization a Development Model: Economic Implications for Africa”, Int. J. Applied Econ. Econom. 21(1): 41-72 Appleyard, R.D., Field, A.J., Cobb, S.L. (2006), International Economics, (5th Ed.), McGraw Hill, New York. Atoyebi.O., Kehinde, .O., Adekunjo, Felix .O., Edun Olufemi, Kadiri Kayode I. (2012). “Foreign Trade And Economic Growth In Nigeria An Empirical Analysis” IOSR J. Humanities Social Sci. (JHSS) ISSN: 22790837, ISBN: 2279-0845. Volume 2, Issue 1 (Sep-Oct. 2012), PP 73-80 www.iosrjournals.org Baldwin R.E (2002). “Openness and growth: what’s the empirical relationship.” NBER. WP 9578, March. Central Bank of Nigeria, (2008) “Statistical Bulletin.” Abuja Frankel, J.A., Romer, D. (1999). “Does trade cause growth”? Am. Econ. Rev., 89 (3): 379 – 399. Irwin, D.A., Tervio, M. (2000). Does trade raise income? Evidence from the twentieth century, J. Int. Econ., 58(1): 1-18. Johansen, S. (1991). “Estimation and Hypothesis Testing of Co-Integration Vectors in Gaussian Vector Autoregressive Models” Econometrica. 59: 1551-1580. Jude, C., Pop-Silaghi, M.I. (2008), “Some determinants of economic growth in Romania: foreign trade and foreign direct investment”, The Annals of the University of Oradea, Economic Sciences, Vol.17 Karbasi, A., Mohamadi, E., Ghofrani, S. (2005), Impact of foreign direct investment and trade on economic growth, Paper presented at the 12th Economic Research Forum Conference, 19th-21st December, Cairo, Egypt. Obadan, M.I. (1983). “Prospects for diversification in Nigerians export trade in annual conference of Nigeria Economic Society”, Heinemann press, Ibadan page 3353 unpublished mass: press. Ohlin, B. (1933) Interregional and International Trade, Cambridge, Harvard University Press. Rodriguez, F., Rodrik, D. (2000), Trade policy and economic growth: A skeptic's guide to the crossnational evidence, processed, May. World Bank (2004). World Development Indicators. Washington, DC: The World Bank. World Bank (2005). ‘Indicators of Governance and Institutional Quality’ http://www1.worldbank.org/publicsector/indicators.htm. Accessed 14 September 2005. Ogunrinola 329 APPENDIX Data set table YEAR 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 EXRT 0.546781 0.617708 0.673461 0.72441 0.766527 0.893774 1.754523 4.016037 4.536967 7.364735 8.038285 9.909492 17.29843 22.0654 35.48194 65.09269 86.89102 86.53464 80.42102 92.3381 101.6973 111.2313 120.5782 129.2224 132.888 131.2743 128.6517 125.8081 116.383 148.9 150.3 153.86 GDP 3233459068 3406878861 3379066399 3534949883 3479589248 3337557583 3303604303 3280269197 2871881520 2823128094 2820500756 2815121711 2825973080 2814919609 2908866342 3080833198 3276286557 3406249572 3532675436 3781225303 3936327817 4052872049 4083427038 4186354768 4408746006 4597552925 4856157720 5091775108 5274667877 5103701327 5490032606 5420517562 Source: CBN Statistical Bulletin (2010), World Bank (2004, 2012) FDI -7.39E+08 5.42E+08 4.31E+08 3.64E+08 1.89E+08 4.86E+08 1.93E+08 6.11E+08 3.79E+08 1.88E+09 5.88E+08 7.12E+08 8.97E+08 1.35E+09 1.96E+09 1.08E+09 1.59E+09 1.54E+09 1.05E+09 1.01E+09 1.14E+09 1.19E+09 1.87E+09 2.01E+09 1.87E+09 4.98E+09 4.85E+09 6.04E+09 8.20E+09 8.56E+09 6.05E+09 8.03E+09 OPN 48.6 49.1 38.7 31.1 27.8 28.5 37.6 53.3 45.1 57.9 72.2 68.6 82.7 97.8 82.5 86.5 75.6 82.7 71.6 78 86 75.3 64.4 83.1 75 77.6 70.6 67 74 64.7 65.1 77.4 GEXP 45152999360 52806799808 55053099584 59381700096 62400800256 69707599552 75547999616 1.04596E+11 1.43652E+11 2.07851E+11 2.22528E+11 3.08819E+11 6.09301E+11 9.9706E+11 1.22483E+12 1.93614E+12 2.23937E+12 2.72797E+12 2.95713E+12 3.34714E+12 3.64997E+12 4.76749E+12 7.17711E+12 8.54482E+12 1.01684E+13 1.24527E+13 1.58773E+13 1.77262E+13 2.17168E+13 2.37687E+13 3.25392E+13 3.6247E+13