Uploaded by urooj hoque

EC2016 Intermediate Macroeconomics 2 rayan

advertisement
EC2016 Intermediate Macroeconomics 2
Part A:
1.
According to the Ricardian Equivalence, the general level of consumer spending in an economy is not much
influenced by government spending or taxing policies. According to the hypothesis, when governments borrow
more money to pay for expenditures, consumers anticipate more taxes in the future and change their spending
habits accordingly. As a result, any rise in disposable income brought about by more government spending will
be countered by a decrease in private spending as people increase their savings in order to cover upcoming tax
liabilities. First, people might not have complete knowledge of upcoming tax laws or their own potential sources
of income, making it challenging for them to anticipate the future with accuracy and modify their behaviour
accordingly. Furthermore, when making decisions about their current consumption, some people might not even
think about their future tax obligations. Moreover, a variety of factors outside anticipated future tax costs affect
consumers' saving habits. Savings in the home, for instance, may be influenced by preventive factors like job
instability or health concerns. It’s still not apparent whether it holds true in reality. Beyond only consumer
behaviour, a number of other variables, such as the nature and timing of governmental spending and taxing
policies, affect the success of fiscal policy.
2.
As foreign investors seek greater returns on their investments, an increase in r* might lead to in capital inflows
into the SOE. The value of the SOE currency could rise as a result. In turn, this can help consumers by lowering
the cost of imports and easing inflationary pressures. Capital inflows can encourage domestic investment and
growth. Investors seeking a greater return may be drawn to the SOE as global interest rates climb. The SOE's
financial markets may benefit from this cash infusion, which could also aid in funding investment initiatives. By
granting access to outside finance sources, this can support economic expansion and development. The boost
may entice capital inflows from investors abroad looking for greater returns, spurring economic expansion and
productivity. Second, higher interest rates may result in a stronger currency, which would be advantageous to the
SOE by lowering import costs, enhancing terms of trade, and lessening inflationary pressures. Furthermore, a
greater r* may draw foreign capital, allowing the SOE to borrow money at a reduced rate and promoting
sustainable development. An increase in global interest rates may be advantageous if the SOE is suffering
inflationary pressures or is at risk of capital flight. Inflationary pressures can be lessened and domestic demand
can be restrained by higher interest rates. Additionally, it can encourage investors to hold domestic assets,
reducing capital outflows and stabilising financial markets.
3.
Macroeconomics places more emphasis on the overall health of the economy than it does on specific measures
used by governments to censor the media. However, if a government were to support such a claim, it might do
so on the grounds of preserving stability and averting unfavourable economic effects. A critical publication may
be closed, the government may claim, in order to protect investor confidence and economic stability. They would
contend that unfavourable press coverage can damage investor confidence, which would therefore discourage
investment and economic activity and ultimately hurt the economy. The goal of the government is to uphold a
favourable reputation, draw in investment, and foster economic progress. They can contend that safeguarding
national interests and averting destabilising forces falls under their competence. Despite the fact that investor
confidence is not completely based on favourable media coverage, the argument for closing down a critical
newspaper based on macroeconomic theory can be refuted by the reality that macroeconomic stability is indeed
a crucial factor. Investors take into account a wide range of variables, including institutional strength, political
stability, the rule of law, and economic fundamentals. Suppression of dissenting voices could lead people to
question the government's adherence to democratic values and openness, which would eventually erode public
confidence. A rich marketplace of ideas is fostered by a diverse media environment that allows for the expression
of many viewpoints. This diversity may result in novel ideas, better policies, and sounder economic judgement.
Limiting critical voices reduces the variety of thoughts and viewpoints available, potentially inhibiting innovation
and obstructing growth.
5.
The Solow growth model was important because it offered a framework for comprehending long-term economic
growth. It was created in the 1950s. The diminishing returns to capital accumulation anticipated that countries
with lower income levels would have quicker rates of growth. In the 1980s and 1990s, academics noticed that
some nations were maintaining rapid rates of economic growth despite having comparable levels of physical
capital as other nations. This led them to develop the endogenous growth model. As a result, theories were
created that highlighted the contribution of innovation, human capital, and technology to economic progress.
The two models are primarily distinguished by how they handle technological advancement. In contrast to
endogenous growth models, which place emphasis on the function of policies like research and development
subsidies or educational programmes in supporting technological progress, the Solow model posits that
technological progress is exogenous and cannot be controlled by policy.
a.
A macroeconomic model called the Real Business Cycle Model (RBC) holds that changes in total factor
productivity (TFP) are what cause changes in output, employment, and other economic indicators. A brief but
sustained increase in TFP would result in an upward change in the production function curve in this closed
economy. when a result, when businesses generate more goods and services with their current resources,
current output would rise. As businesses look to create more output, there would be an increase in demand for
labour with a rise in TFP. The labour demand curve would be shifted upward as a result of this. As more
employees are hired to fulfil the rising demand for labour, current employment levels will increase. Investment is
a function of projected future earnings, thus it is likely to rise as a result of the TFP shock's greater predicted
future productivity. The investment demand curve is shifted upward as a result. Consequently, existing
investment levels will rise. The meeting point of the labour supply and demand curves determines real wages.
Real wages will rise together with the upward change in the labour demand curve brought on by increased TFP
as employees become more productive and consequently earn higher wages. Prices would go down because of
lower production unit costs brought on by increased productivity levels brought on by the TFP shock. The price
level or aggregate supply curve will shift lower, which suggests that prices are falling even as output rises. Finally,
due to increased anticipated future returns on capital investments following the TFP shock, present real interest
rates will decline. An upward change in the production function implies an increase in the capital's marginal
product, which lowers the cost of capital and lowers real interest rates. Overall, these adjustments show that an
economy can benefit from changes like enhanced TFP, which boost employment rates, GDP growth rates, and
inflation rates while lowering real interest rates, following the occurrence of a brief but lasting shock. As a result,
the Real Business Cycle Model demonstrates how numerous areas of the economy can be significantly impacted
by a transient but sustained spike in TFP. How this shock impacts current employment, output, investment, real
wages, prices, and real interest rates is shown graphically in the analysis. Increased output and employment
result from an upward shift in the production function, and as prices decline because of more supply, inflation is
also reduced. Higher predicted future returns on capital investments also translate into lower capital
expenditures, which in turn results in lower real interest rates. Overall, these adjustments imply that favourable
economic outcomes are still attainable even in the face of transient shocks like an increase in TFP.
b.
We still see variations in total factor productivity (TFP) in closed economies. TFP assesses how effectively inputs
are used to produce output and reflects advancements in technology. It is determined as the output to input
ratio, with labour, capital, and intermediate inputs being the inputs. The two elements of TFP growth are
technological change and efficiency change. Efficiency change captures the results of businesses' attempts to use
resources more effectively, whereas technical change represents advancements in technology. There are several
methods for calculating TFP growth. The Solow residual approach, which estimates a production function that
connects output to inputs and then uses the residuals as a measure of TFP growth, is one popular technique.
Growth accounting is a different approach that breaks down output growth into contributions from labour,
capital, and TFP. Finally, there are econometric techniques that calculate TFP directly from input and output data.
Overall, keeping an eye on TFP fluctuations is crucial for comprehending long-term economic growth and finding
areas where resource allocation and technical advancement can be improved.
c.
Changes in TFP (Total Factor Productivity), which affect the economy's growth rate over time, are thought to be
persistent in closed economies. The economy is growing more effective at generating goods and services with
the same number of inputs while TFP is increasing. Higher output and earnings for businesses result from this,
which motivates them to invest and increase their production capacity. As businesses grow, they increase staff
and invest in new gear and equipment, which boosts the economy's capital stock. Additional productivity
improvements and economic expansion follow from this. These advantages would soon disappear as enterprises
returned to their prior level of productivity, though, if TFP were not permanent. Changes in TFP can also result in
breakthroughs and technological advancements that have a long-term effect on the economy's productive
capacity. These can include brand-new techniques for producing goods as well as cutting-edge technologies that
allow for the emergence of completely new industries.
d.
In response to a brief rise in total factor productivity, the average productivity of labour and employment is
predicted to behave differently by the Real Business Cycles Model and the Coordination Failure Model. Current
TFP shocks and current average labour and employment productivity have a positive correlation in the RBC
model but a negative correlation in the Coordination Failure model. These predictions match actual data, and we
discover that both models have advantages and disadvantages of their own. Although the RBC model does a
decent job of explaining short-term changes in output and employment, it is unable to consider long-term trends
like productivity increase. The Coordination Failure model, on the other hand, helps to explain persistent
unemployment but has trouble explaining quick economic recovery following recessions. Overall, when
examining economic occurrences, it is crucial to consider both models. Even though they might make various
predictions, they all provide insightful information about the intricate dynamics of the economy.
Download