Reappraising Japan’s Proposal for an Asian Monetary Fund in 1997 Fabio Masini Abstract At the Annual Meeting of the World Bank and the IMF in Hong Kong on September 21st, 1997, soon after the collapse of the Thai baht in July and the subsequent outburst of the East-Asian currency crisis, the Japanese Finance Minister Hiroshi Mitsuzuka officially proposed the creation of a $100 billion Asian Monetary Fund. Surprisingly, the proposal excluded any involvement from the USA and the IMF, causing their violent negative reaction and veto. Until then, Japan had always involved the USA in Asian regional integration. Although such initiative would radically change the course of regional financial integration in East-Asia and the global balance of power in the forthcoming decades, it received attention only by very specialized authors, who concentrated on single, fragmented explanations of an issue that was multifaceted and complex. The aim of this paper is to reappraise this affair and provide a comprehensive picture of the relevant issues at stake, reconstructing the intertwined relationships between – and highlighting the relative role of – economic theories, financial dynamics, and political/strategic considerations. JEL codes B22, B29, E42, F02, F20, F33, F42, F50, H12 Keywords East-Asian crisis, Asian Monetary Fund, IMF, Japan Introduction At the Annual Meeting of the World Bank and the IMF in Hong Kong on Sunday September 21st, 19971, soon after the collapse of the Thai baht in July and the subsequent outburst of the East-Asian currency crisis, the Japanese Finance Minister Hiroshi Mitsuzuka proposed the creation of a $100 billion Asian Monetary Fund (AMF), financed half by Japan and half by Taiwan, Singapore, Hong Kong, and China. The proposal followed a less detailed and unofficial suggestion circulated on September 10th. Surprisingly, the proposal excluded any involvement from the USA (who discovered about it only on September 14th) and the IMF, causing violent negative reactions, which resulted in a de facto political veto. As Amyx (2002, 1-2) noted: “this move drew a great deal of attention and signaled an important departure in both substance and style from Japan’s prior regional institution-building initiatives that included the United States”. Until then, Japan had always involved the USA in Asian regional integration (Lee 2006, 1 A few weeks earlier, Hong Kong had formally returned under the sovereignty of China, after over one century and a half of British dominance. The meeting was therefore held in the territory of China: a symbolic but significant step. Ironically, on that same day and during the storm, an implausible session had been organized at the IMF and WB Annual Meeting titled South Asia: The Next Miracle? On that Sunday afternoon, at 15:00 was also scheduled the Per Jacobson lecture by Joseph Yam (JP Chief Executive, Hong Kong Monetary Authority) on Asian Monetary Cooperation. In that speech, although acknowledging the extraordinary effort from multilateral institutions such the IMF and BIS to provide financial assistance, he observed: “some in this region have felt that such support and guidance, particularly from the multilateral institutions, have been less forthcoming than they would have liked, comparing for example the support given to Thailand with Mexico. They also feel that the special circumstances and interests of economies in the region have not been adequately taken into account. Nor do their voices count for enough”. 1 340), and in the first weeks of the crisis Japan had supported the IMF in its scheme for short-term (conditional) financial assistance to the region (ibidem). Why did Japan’s officials openly challenge the role of the IMF and the USA in tackling a currency crisis in Asia? Eisuke Sakakibara (2001), Vice-Minister of Finance for International Affairs in Japan during the crisis and major protagonist in the AMF proposal, suggested this should be explained as a reaction to the aggressive behavior of the Clinton administration against Japan in the previous years, instrumental to reducing its export capacity via an undervalued dollar against the yen. A plausible explanation, given Japan efforts during the previous years to emerge as a dominant regional power in East Asia. An explanation, though, that seems to neglect the role of other major triggering factors, such as the financial crisis that had been hitting Japan already before the East-Asian currency crisis (that cannot be just a matter of uncorrelated coincidence). Japan’s dominance, in short, was being challenged already before the currency crisis (and the AMF proposal) emerged, not because of its failed attempt and/or the crisis itself. Another intriguing question, given the subsequent evolution of the balance of power and regional integration in South-East Asia, is if the behavior of China in this affair can be neglected. What is mostly surprising in this event is that, although it radically changed the course of regional integration in South-East Asia and the global balance of power in the forthcoming decades, it received attention only by very specialized authors, who concentrated on single, fragmented explanations of an issue that was, by its nature, multifaceted and complex. Scholars in international relations stressed the role played by the evolving USA-Japan relations (Narine 2003). The journalist Paul Blustein (2003) focused on the role of the above-mentioned Sakakibara as an ideological opponent to the neoliberal wave imposed by Washington in the Nineties. Scholars in financial issues underlined the role that the failure of the banking system (in Japan) and its sudden depreciation since 1995 played both in triggering the crisis and in the making of the Japanese proposal (Ito 1999). Economists stressed the role of supply and demand mismatch (overinvestment) and subsequent trade divergences (Sohn 2004) due to currency misalignments (basically the peg of the South-Asian currencies to the US dollar) during the previous years (Tobin 1998); Roubini (2009, 84) underlined “rollover/liquidity risks […], lack of risk sharing and rigid external debt payment structures”; and Stiglitz (2001) explained the crisis as the outcome of the USA strategic behavior to force conditional changes, through the IMF, that would make such countries more vulnerable and exposed to US capital penetration in their economies; hence the need for a regional safety net. That both the IMF and USA felt as a threat (Stiglitz 2002, 112ff) Each of these narratives, although providing convincing rationales for both the emergence of the crisis and the Japanese suggestion concerning an AMF, neglect the role of other features and lack a general framework, that should include geopolitical and strategic considerations, trade wars, the role of each major actor in regional financial assistance (IMF included), different approaches to capitalism and the role of public authorities in the economy, previous crises such as Mexico, the role of the parallel process towards monetary integration in Europe. The aim of this paper is to reappraise this affair and provide a comprehensive picture of the relevant issues at stake, reconstructing the intertwined relationships between – and 2 highlighting the relative role of – economic theories, financial dynamics, and political/strategic considerations. We shall follow a chronological order, first enquiring into the evolving international economic role of both Japan and the USA during the late 1980s and 1990s, with special reference to the East-Asian region and the different models and concepts of the role of economic policy and public intervention in the economy, including some reference to the evolving Japan-specific banking crisis that preceded the East-Asian currency crisis (first section). We will then detail the evolving events that led to the proposal and its dismissal (second section), before we observe the follow-up of financial integration in the area (third section). 1. The building up of systemic problems Attempts at regional cooperation and integration in South-East Asia had a long history, even without direct involvement of the USA and the IMF. In 1947 a United Nations commission called ECAFE (Economic Commission for Asia and the Far East) was established, along with one for Europe (UNECE) and one for Latin America (ECLAC, better known as CEPAL, from the Spanish and Portuguese acronym). In 1950, a forum for discussion among central bankers (called SEANZA, from the participating countries: South-East Asia, New Zealand, and Australia) was created, aiming at providing training on financial supervision and transnational, regional cooperation. Research was also the focus of the following initiative, taken in 1966 with the creation of SEACEN (an acronym for Southeast Asian Central Banks), based in Kuala Lumpur. In the meanwhile, an initiative had been taken in 1960 in Bangkok to strengthen SouthEast Asian cooperation (Ibrahim 1961, 1), which would lead in 1963 to the first Conference on East-Asian Cooperation that tried “to implement two schemes simultaneously, namely, (a) ECAFE trade liberalization and expansion scheme, and (b) ECAFE monetary co-operation scheme, which comprises (i) the Asian Reserve Bank and (ii) the Asian Clearing Union” (Lee 1973, 1). While trade liberalization proceeded with the establishment in 1967, in Bangkok again, of the ASEAN (the Association of SouthEast Asian Nations), that meant to implement regional integration along similar lines to the ones adopted in Europe, mainly targeted to the creation of a common market, the second scheme (a clearing union) was systematically neglected. Just before the collapse of the Bretton Woods system in 1971, Robert Triffin and Pierre Uri strongly advocated “a gradual shaping-up of an Asian or ECAFE Reserve System” (Triffin 1969, 243), which should be pooling 10% of the reserve assets of each participating country in the form of gold, foreign currencies and SDRs to provide financial assistance in case of balance of payments disequilibria, leaving the US and the IMF out. While before the end of the dollar-exchange standard such proposals were tolerated (if not openly supported) by both the US and IMF, that were de jure leading the international monetary system, after 1971 the USA had to counter every attack to their hegemony in the monetary and financial field2 which was, in turn, key to their political hegemony worldwide. During the floating of the 1970s (precisely: in 1977): “the ASEAN 2 This is precisely what systematically happened in the following decades, such as in 1975, when the OPEC countries discussed whether to be paid in SDRs instead of dollars and the US managed to impose the use of dollars, in exchange for the US engagement in ensuring security in the area. 3 countries had agreed to create a network of short-term bilateral swap agreements under which each ASEAN country could obtain U.S. dollars in exchange for its own national currency. A swap could last for no more than three months but could be renewed for three more months. As the amounts involved were small, however, the swaps were rarely activated and were not used at all during the Asian crisis” (Kenen and Meade 2008, 154; see also Rhee, Sumulong and Vallée 2013). After the tightening of monetary policy by Volcker in the early 1980s, the Plaza Accord in 1985 led to a devaluation of the dollar against most other countries (DM, GBP, Yen) of about 50%. The growth of East-Asian currencies, pegged to a devaluating dollar, was partially accompanied by Japan (Goldar and Ishigami 1999), as “the appreciation of the yen after 1985 pushed many Japanese firms to establish lower cost production bases within the region” (Thomsen 1999, 12). At least until the Louvre Accord reversed the currencies dynamic in 1987, when agreement was reached on halting the dollar depreciation. In 1989 the APEC (Asia Pacific Economic Cooperation) was established to ease trade and investment among the 18 member countries, and in February 1991 the EMEAP (Executives’ Meeting of East Asia Pacific Central Banks) was created under Japan’s initiative, to regain momentum for regional monetary integration. Things started becoming more tensed in those early Nineties. The increasing relevance of the US in the East-Asian economic growth during the 1990s is key to understanding its continued explosive development. The USA had been providing fresh funds for direct investments in South Korea, Malaysia, Singapore, Taiwan, Thailand, Hong Kong, Indonesia, and the Philippines. US’s FDIs in the area rose from $29.9bn to $95.5bn (more than three times) in five years between 1990 and 1995 (JETRO, Japan External Trade Organization on OECD data, 1997; see table below). In the same period, Japan’s FDIs declined from $48.1bn to $22.7bn, less than half. While the US took the leadership in East-Asian FDIs, the relative economic and political importance of the two countries in the region changed accordingly. According to Kindleberger (1969), FDIs provide an optimal allocation of resources, relocating them to places where there is some competitive advantage compared to domestic investment. In the case of East-Asia, the key feature was the low labor cost. Nevertheless, it is difficult not to underline the strategic importance of FDIs. Multinational corporations usually make FDIs according also to strategic considerations 4 and alliances, not necessarily driven only by cost-reducing and profit-maximizing considerations. Furthermore, without a favorable institutional and political setting, FDIs become risky; and a comprehensive cost-benefit analysis might assess that costs prevail over benefits. While European integration was being shaken by speculative attacks – with the emergence of Germany as the rule-setter of monetary integration – Kwan (1993) was strongly advocating the establishment of an Asia-Pacific “yen bloc”3. He provided evidence of the increasing interdependence among Asia-Pacific countries, suggesting the need for a hegemonic role of the (then) most important currency, the Japanese yen. During the 1990s, nevertheless, the Asian currencies still pegged the US dollar, which had been rapidly appreciating against the yen since 1995, mostly to stabilize the domestic value of their dollar-denominated debt. The narrative of the yen bloc was therefore spreading in Japan (and elsewhere in the region) when its external hegemonic role in the area was being challenged by its internal financial flaws and by an aggressive USA exchange rate setting. It is doubtful whether Japan promptly understood and anticipated such radical change, although according to Murphy (2011) Japan not only understood this, but eased such process of hegemonic dominance of the USA in the area. In any case, Japanese exports increased; and East-Asian exports to Japan, their most relevant market, dramatically decreased. Intra-Asian balance of payments disequilibria started becoming worrisome, pressing for a devaluation of all East-Asian currencies against the yen, which was nevertheless resisted due to the dollar peg. The result was that “by early 1997, the Asian Tiger economies were confronted with a choice: (1) do nothing, and watch their exports become much less competitive as the US dollar appreciated but be better able to pay their US dollar–denominated debts or (2) break the peg to the US dollar, devalue their currencies, and resume their export growth” (Rimkus 2016). This also implies that, in this latter event, their economies, while recovering competitiveness, would see their US dollar–denominated obligations become more costly. As (Rimkus 2016) argues: “the currency markets astutely sensed the dilemma and, despite official pegs to the dollar, began selling the domestic Asian currencies”. In this inherently unstable framework, where the dollar and the yen floated in the market and Asian currencies rigidly followed the dollar, a major crisis in the Japanese banking system burst out, soon before the currency crisis. The November 1997 banking crisis that saw the collapse of a few major financial institutions in Japan (suggesting that it might have been triggered by the currency crisis) had therefore its roots in what took shape before the currency crisis of July, not as a consequence of it. What had happened in the Japanese banking system? Kanaya and Woo (2000, 5) suggest that relaxation of interest rate controls and capital market deregulation may explain the skyrocketing performance of the stock exchange and the asset bubble during the 1980s. Private agents, especially in the banking sector, were largely convinced – encouraged by the attitude of both the Treasury and the Bank of Japan (Nakaso 2001, 17) – that, in case of financial stress, small businesses would be saved by greater ones, and that the latter 3 The reference to – and insistence on – the “yen bloc” was probably unfortunate, as it closely reminded China of the proposals for a “yen bloc” to manage areas under Japan’s domination (included a major part of China) just before and during WWII (Hunsberger 1938). 5 were too big to fail. The dramatic drop of both the Nikkei and real estate prices at the beginning of the 1990s dramatically impacted on the balance sheets of many financial institutions, later reflected in a significant downgrading by rating agencies. To protect their margins, banks – especially weakly capitalized ones (Woo 1999) – further relaxed credit conditions and extended the maturity of their lending, thus increasing systemic risk. Instead of acknowledging the changing environment, banking institutions bet on stock and real estate prices to rise again (Kanaya and Woo 2000, 22). An evolution that well resembles the endogenous dynamics of crises highlighted by Minsky (1982). Source: Macrotrends, Nikkei, https://www.macrotrends.net/2593/nikkei-225-index-historical-chart-data As would be later the case with the US financial crisis originated in the sub-prime mortgage sector in 2007-08, since 1992 Japanese mortgage companies were already in deep trouble. A few of them were dissolved as early as in the Summer of 1995. At the end of 1994 two credit cooperative were suspended. It was just the beginning of a landslide. Public money was used to protect depositors, but regulators failed to change the supervisory legislative framework. According to Nakaso (2001, 18) the Bank of Japan was the first to realize (since 1993) that the problem deriving from a halt in the real estate bubble might become a landslide for financial institutions, especially for those linked to increasing non-performing loans, but was confronted with the risk that any move in strengthening a safety net might signal systemic risks to the market, triggering a major financial crisis. This might help explaining the reason why Japan and USA had been trying to cooperate in those years. This was rather manifest in the Mexican crisis, in which the USA found it difficult to provide bailout funds. The FMI would need additional funds too, as had been suggested by IMF Managing Director Michel Camdessus, who in early 19944 tried to issue some tenth billion SDRs, clashing with the violent resistance from the US and Germany, which ultimately brought to the decision to avoid new general allocations5. 4 Camdessus’s proposal came prior to the outburst of the Mexican crisis in December 1994, but after Mexican government entering a new political (risky) path, with the assassination of the Presidential candidate Calosio in Tijuana in March 1994, and the sharp rise in interest rates as risk premium on Treasury bonds. As is largely known, the whole turmoil came to a sudden halt only one month later, when the US agreed a $50bn rescue package jointly managed by the IMF, the G7, and the BIS. 5 As the German Horst Siebert made explicit in a workshop on the future of SDRs in 1996, the need for an increase in reserves did not per sé justify the allocation of SDRs (Mussa, Boughton and Isard 1996, 101ff). The point was mainly political, not merely technical: SDRs would decrease the need to recur to the IMF conditionality in case of financial distress. If one reads carefully Camdessus’s (2016) reconstruction of those events, it seems that the struggle was between using the IMF as an instrument of control of the global 6 The spillover effects of the Mexican crisis on the whole global economy, east-Asia included, triggered a proposal from the Governor of the Federal Reserve Bank of Australia, Bernie Fraser, to build a sort of Asian BIS to provide funds in case of financial distress in the area. His talk was given in September 1995 in Adelaide. In 1996 the BIS in Basel accepted a few new members, among which: China, India, South Korea, Singapore, and Hong Kong. Japan’s fragility was still unresolved: in November 1996 the Nippon Credit Bank had to be bailed out by the Ministry of Treasury, firstly trying to rely on a consortium of private institutions. Then with the direct involvement of the Central Bank, that decided to use the New Financial Stabilization Fund, an instrument that had been set up only six months earlier (Nakaso 2001, 7-8). In the following months Japan raised taxes to avoid a fiscal deficit, but the decision was a boomerang, as it sank market expectations; as noted by Edward Lincoln (1998, 23), Senior fellow at The Brookings Institution: “the moves in 1997 were too much too soon. The tax increases had negative real impact on the economy as well as a negative psychological impact. Having created a pessimistic public psychology, the government then faced a difficult task of reversing those attitudes”. In April 1997 the Nissan Life Insurance, one of Japan’s largest insurance corporations, was suspended. The yen started losing ground against the dollar on exchange markets and in early May 1997 Japan suggested it might raise interest rates to defend the currency; although this never took place, international investors started to perceive that they had better quit the South-Eastern currencies. This was the already seriously deteriorated financial framework in which the currency crisis erupted. On 14 and 15 May 1997, the Thai Baht came under attack. Thai’s Prime Minister announced on June 30th that he would not devalue the THB. Instead of assuring investors, this triggered further speculation and on July 2nd, after wasting over $30bn to defend the currency and running out of reserves, capital flights forced a huge devaluation6 of the Baht; on July 24th the Central Bank of Thailand announced its floating. In brief, although the public only perceived the problem in Autumn, when major changes took place in the Japanese banking supervisory and regulatory system7, it had already emerged manifestly in Spring. And we may argue that – contrary to what is usually told – the crisis in the area did not start in Thailand in July, but much earlier in the Japanese banking sector. Thailand, with its opaque behavior, played the role of the triggering factor. 2. The Unfolding of the Crisis and the AMF Proposal Most commentators at that time underlined that the macroeconomic fundamentals in the countries of the area appeared to be robust. At least, this was the case with Malaysia (Bin Mohamad 1999), as the IMF Managing Director Michel Camdessus had recalled, pointing with satisfaction to the policy stance implemented in the previous decade there. economy (the US position), or as a venue for economic cooperation, as was theoretically enshrined in its mission and as its Managing Director was struggling to pursue. 6 In five months, the Baht/Dollar rate would collapse from 23 to 56. 7 At the end of 1997 the Fiscal Structure Reform Law was enacted and early in 1998 the fiscal and financial authorities were separated, creating the Financial Supervisory Agency. In 1998, officials of both the finance ministry and the Bank of Japan were arrested in bribery scandals, and both the finance minister and the governor resigned. 7 Even Korea, although suffering from high short-term foreign debts in 1997, seemed not to be in a situation as serious as Mexico had been, as beset by temporary illiquidity rather than fundamental insolvency; hence the need to address temporary balance of payments adjustment, rather than “imposing major structural and institutional reforms” (Feldstein, 1998). Despite these optimistic views, as we noted in the previous section, South-Asian economies showed several fragilities, even in the very heart of the regional financial and banking sector: Japan. Japan’s financial infrastructure was exposed to many challenges, that were exacerbated by tensions with the regional partners and their inherently increasing systemic risk. Thailand’s export-led growth model had resulted in an average 9% annual GDP growth rate between 1985 and 1996, with very similar performance in the other countries of the area, but the debt to GDP ratio for the whole ASEAN tigers had increased on average from 100% to 167% between 1993 and 1996. Sovereign debt risk was perceived to be sharply increasing and the interconnections of sovereign bonds with a banking sector in Japan (that owned much of them) at risk of collapsing played a major source of contagion, at least as concerns market expectations. After the sharp devaluation of the THB on July 2nd, the following day the Philippine Central Bank attempted to defend the peso raising the overnight interest rate from 15% to 32%. Without any success. The domino effect had started for the whole South-Asian area. It would become a landslide by the end of the year, affecting Indonesia, Korea and all the economies of the region. In 1998 China (together with Russia and Brazil) would also be involved. The impact of the crisis, in terms of GDP per capita, can be appreciated in the following graph. The Thai bailout, managed under the responsibility of the IMF and in which the “United States [was] conspicuous by its absence” (as the Washington Post observed on August 12) was $17.2bn. Japan contributed for $4bn, the same sum directly provided by the IMF. 8 Despite very critical remarks8 the conditionality attached to the rescue plan was the usual one: currency devaluation, privatization of strategic assets, trade openness, etc. From the point of view of markets, during that August the situation was far from stabilized, and the Thai currency depreciated further. Hamada (1999, 33) underlines that: “during the Tokyo Meeting of Ministers in August 1997, in an effort to rescue the crisis situation, many Asian countries were interested in the idea of a permanent international facility that can provide financial support to troubled countries”. The time seemed to be ripe for the Ministry of Finance of Japan to consider betting on a regional solution: the AMF. Lipscy (2003, 95) argues that the timing of the proposal suggests a correlation to dynamics internal to the Japanese Ministry of Finance. On July 15th, 1997, there had been a change in the top management of the Ministry: “Sakakibara and Kuroda had been respectively promoted to Vice Minister of International Affairs and Director of the International Bureau” (Lipscy 2003, 94-95). Both were very much committed to the idea of an AMF since the earlier years (Blustein 2003, 165); their rising role in the Ministry was certainly crucial for the emergence of the proposal. According to Murphy, though, this move had nothing to do with internal struggles. It was a diplomacy decision, given the strict relationships that Sakakibara had established in the earlier years with Larry Summers, the powerful9 Deputy Secretary of the US Treasury since 1995. The two had met in Harvard, where Summers was teaching and Sakakibara was a visiting scholar. And they were both sitting in the so-called G7D, where the Finance Ministers’ deputies in fact negotiate agreements on the global economy within the G7 before they are signed by the Ministers and by the Heads of Government themselves (Blustein 20013, 34). The relationship between the two had seen moments of tension in the months before, during, and after the Mexican crisis; but eventually Japan agreed to help the US face the concerted bailout together with the IMF and BIS. The Japanese government might therefore have thought that their personal relations were robust enough to bring constructive solutions to the South-East Asian crisis. They nevertheless had differing views on the crisis itself and on the way out. Sakakibara, in a speech given at the World Bank in Washington in April 2000, denied that the Asian crisis had been triggered by macroeconomic weakness. Unlike the previous example of Mexico, the countries hit did not show short-term debt exciding “foreign reserves by a substantial margin” (Sakakibara 2000, 2)10. Explanations had to be sought elsewhere; mainly in a “crisis of capitalism” due to changes in the available technology (Sakakibara 1998, 27), combined with unfettered capital movement liberalization, and a strategic behavior of the USA against the risk of a rising hegemony of Japan in the area (Sakakibara 2001). Policy responses needed to be designed accordingly. 8 Such as Ikegami (1999, 891-2), arguing that: “The International Monetary Fund (IMF) entered the scene by imposing aggressive economic restructuring programs to overhaul the economic structures, financial institutions, and political processes in Korea, Indonesia, and Thailand”. 9 Larry Summers, among whose uncles he had two Nobel laureates, such as Paul Samuelson and Kenneth Arrow, had entered the MIT at sixteen, and became full professor at the age of 28, before joining the US Treasury. 10 In a previous paper, presented at the Foreign Correspondents Club, Tokyo, on January 22nd, 1999, Sakalibara (who was still Japan’s Vice Minister of Finance) had nevertheless recognized that, although sovereign debt was not particularly high, private debt in those countries had skyrocketed in the previous years (Sakakibara 1999). 9 A closer look at these two protagonists of the affair, Sakakibara and Kuroda, may be inspiring. Their career within the Ministry of Finance went in parallel, at least until Sakakibara (who was three years and a half older than Kuroda and preceded him as Director of the International Bureau) resigned in 1999 to lead the Keio University's Global Security Research Center11. Different in character, the two were in close intellectual syntony, both inspired by Keynesian-like analysis and policies. Sakakibara, studied economics at the University of Tokyo, before receiving a PhD from the University of Michigan. He repeatedly argued against “market fundamentalism” (1999), rooted in the alleged virtues of Walrasian general equilibrium models; in fact, he was targeting the emerging dominance of dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models, that suggested public authorities should refrain from intervening in the economy. His book Beyond Capitalism: the Japanese Model of Market Economics, published in 1993 by University Press of America, had provided a few guidelines for a “third way” (Sakakibara 1993). In a paper written in September 2000 as the transcript of his intervention before the World Bank at the 12th Annual Conference on Development Economics held in Washington in April 2000, Sakakibara (2000, 3) argued: “For economists, particularly those educated under the neoclassical paradigm, it comes natural to assume the rationality of market participants. […] In the global economy where interdependence has become very strong and where uncertainty driven by revolutionary technological innovations is large, the assumption of one stable equilibrium is unwarranted. We are under multiple equilibria situation and once we leave the neighborhood of one equilibrium, we are likely to be thrown into a very unstable area. Too much flexibility in exchange rates, in this kind of situation, is not necessarily a blessing. Under the euphonic expectation for the future of the economy, free floating exchange rates may have accelerated, not moderated, the boom resulting in a more serious bursting of the bubble.” A few pages further, he would sympathize with Soros’s The Crisis of Global Capitalism12 “where he argued that global markets are inherently instable. Expounding on two basic concepts which he calls ‘reflexivity’ and ‘fallibility’ he leads us to the conclusion that ‘market fundamentalism is today a greater threat to open society than any totalitarian ideology’.” (ibid., 5). In 1995 he had actively promoted the establishment of the Four Markets Committee, with representatives from Japan, Singapore, Australia, and Hong Kong, aiming at strengthening multilateral financial supervision and intervention, which would become in 1996 a Six Market Committee, extended to China and the USA. Sakakibara often underlined how regional safety nets may be crucial to tackle countryspecific or region-specific crises, as an early response or complementary instrument to the IMF. Haruhiko Kuroda graduated in Law, studied economics at Rice University (Houston, Texas) and would later become Vice Minister of Finance for International Affairs (19992003). From 2003 Kuroda served as Special Advisor to the Cabinet of Prime Minister Koizumi, while teaching economics and finance as a Professor at the Hitotsubashi 11 In February 2000 Sakakibara would be officially nominated by Japan for the post of Managing Director of the IMF. In the following weeks, the IMF Executive Board unanimously decided to hire for that post Horst Köhler (until March 2004, when he would be elected President of the Federal Republic of Germany). 12 The reference is to Soros (1988). 10 University Graduate School of Economics. He then became President of the Asian Development Bank (2005-2013) and from 2013 to 2023 Governor of the Bank of Japan. On November 18th and 19th, 1999, as Vice Minister, he would publish in the Yomiuri Shinbun, the most important Japanese newspaper (and the most read in the world, with over seven million copies sold each day) an article in Japanese titled The Third Way: International Financial System, in which he emphasized, like Sakakibara, the limits of both Marxist approaches to the North-South relations and of the neoliberal, market radical views and policies, suggesting that a different approach to the relationship between markets and public intervention should and could be pursued. He would be among the most prominent supporters of the so-called Abenomics (from Shinzo Abe, the Japanese Prime Minister from 2012 to 2020, committed to easing monetary and fiscal policies to contrast the negative effects of Japanese secular stagnation). As Jeremy Clift later observed, after the failed attempt to adopt an AMF, Kuroda kept a lower profile than Sakakibara, starting to underline the compatibility between a regional and global solutions to local crises: “Kuroda has gone out of his way to emphasize the primacy of the IMF. ‘The IMF remains the only global financial institution governing the international monetary system, and East Asia's regional financial architecture must complement its role’, he wrote with University of Tokyo economist Masahiro Kawai in the Financial Times in 2004. "Strengthening the region's financial architecture will also strengthen the IMF's global role because regional financial stability contributes to the stability of global finance." But Asian leaders are edging toward acting on their own, announcing plans to boost the CMI's ability to lend without recipient countries needing to have an IMF program in place and building up the world's largest foreign exchange reserves as a bulwark against currency speculation and possible future instability related to the large imbalances in the global financial system” (Clift 2006). The protagonists of the AMF affair were therefore both extremely critical against the rise of neoliberalism (from an intellectual perspective), DSGE models (from a theoretical one), and US imperialism along what Williamson had described as the Washington Consensus. According to Lipscy (2003, 94), it was Kuroda who drafted the proposal, together with Toyoo Gyohten13 and Hajime Shinohara, from the Institute for International Monetary Affairs in Tokyo. As he observes, the Institute was: 13 As we can read from his profile at The Chinese University of Hong Kong “Mr. Toyoo Gyohten is President of the Institute for International Monetary Affairs. Having graduated from the University of Tokyo, Mr. Gyohten joined the Ministry of Finance (MOF) in 1955. Before he was appointed Vice Minister of Finance for International Affairs in 1986, he occupied various senior positions including Director-General of International Finance Bureau at the Ministry of Finance and also served for the IMF and the Asian Development Bank on lease. After his retirement in 1989 he was a visiting professor at Harvard University, Princeton University and the University of St. Gallen. In 1992 he became Chairman of the Bank of Tokyo, Ltd. (currently the Bank of Tokyo-Mitsubishi UFJ, Ltd.). Since 1995, he has been President of the IIMA and has concurrently served as Senior Advisor to the Bank of Tokyo-Mitsubishi UFJ, Ltd since 2006. Mr. Gyohten also chaired Working Party III of the OECD (1988-90) and the Institute of International Finance (1994-97). He was appointed as a special advisor to Prime Minister Obuchi in 1998, advisor to the Cabinet Secretariat (special envoy to Prime Minister), and more recently was a Special Advisor to the Minister of Finance”. https://www.igef.cuhk.edu.hk/programmes/executive-leadership-programme-in-global-finance/5thprogramme/detailed-program/mr-toyoo-gyohten/ 11 “affiliated with Tokyo-Mitsubishi Bank, which has traditionally close ties with the International Bureau of MOF, and the President is usually a retired Vice Minister for International Affairs (as is Toyoo Gyohten). Shinohara and Gyohten had toyed with the idea for an ‘Asian Monetary Organization’ in the fall of 1996 after the US/IMF bailout of Mexico, based on the premise that the US would not act as vigorously in the event of a similar crisis in Asia14. The initial size of the fund was envisioned to be around $20 billion. By February to March 1997, the IIMA had come up with a blueprint for the AMO and intended to promote the proposal at the May 1997 ADB meeting at Fukuoka as the ‘Gyohten Initiative’. However, the proposal was temporarily shelved because of unrelated events undermining Japan’s position in Asia” (Lipscy 2003, 94) Sakakibara, Kuroda, and the Institute for International Monetary Affairs must have thought that the time was ripe for the official emergence of their idea in the international arena. Under their pressure, on September 10th, 1997, the Ministry of Finance submitted an unofficial (without any specific quantitative suggestion as concerned the number of resources to be mobilized) proposal for an AMF to the Asian counterparts (South Korea, Hong Kong, Indonesia, Malaysia, and Singapore). Four days later, on September 14th, Larry Summers15 phoned Sakakibara complaining16 for not being informed, although the two had discussed about an AMF a few days earlier in Paris17. The official response from the USA came on September 17th, signed by Rubin and Greenspan, “followed with visits to Asian capitals by Tim Geithner and Ted Truman, the director of the Fed’s Division of International Finance, to lobby against Sakakibara’s plan” (Blustein 2003, 166)18. The US top economic diplomacy had mobilized against the AMF. It might be interesting to note that, although Chang and Ramkishen (2001, 103-4) argue that “the proposal was enthusiastically welcomed by many regional economies that were eager to see Japan taking on a bigger leadership role in the region”, reactions to the Japanese plan were positive only from Malaysia, Philippines, and Thailand. Very negative from Australia. China replied that it would take no position, neither positive nor negative; we will return on China’s attitude later. Hong Kong and Singapore were rather ambiguous. The plan was formally proposed at the meeting in Hong Kong, chaired by 14 In the later years they would publish several papers as IIMA Newsletter in which they denounced the US attempt to deeply change the economic policy structure of Japan. For example, Gyohten wrote on May 11, 1998: “U.S. government officials, scholars and journalists are the driving force behind criticism of Japan, with some corporate executives agreeing with them, and there is support from similar groups in Europe and Asia” (Gyothen 1998). 15 At that time U.S. Deputy Secretary of the Treasury, former Chief Economist at the World Bank, later US Secretary of the Treasury from 1999 to 2001, President of Harvard University from 2001 to 2006 and Director of the National Economic Council from 2009 to 2011. 16 Resentment between the two would increase in the following years to the point that in 2000, at the World Bank in Washington, Sakakibara publicly ironized on Summers’ claim (who in the meanwhile had become US Secretary of the Treasury) that greater attention should be given to the “danger of opening up to shortterm capital” (Sakakibara 2000, 12). 17 Sakakibara had nevertheless not mentioned that, in his mind, the AMF might act independently from the IMF (Blustein 2003, 166). 18 Robert Rubin was US Secretary of the Treasury and Alan Greenspan Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board of Governors. Timothy Geithner (later US Secretary of the Treasury) was at that time Assistant Secretary for International Affairs at the US Treasury. Edwin M. Truman was Director of the Division of International Finance at the FED. The US top economic institutions were joining forces to stop Sakakibara and the AMF. 12 Japan, at which the USA were admitted only as observers (Blustein 2003, 167). It envisaged an AMF capitalized with $100bn: $50bn from Japan, and the remaining $50bn from other regional powers, that collectively enjoyed (at that time) balance of payment surpluses of around $800bn (Narine 2003, 68). It was too late. The US diplomacy had already stopped any possible regional solution to the East-Asian currency crisis. 3. What next? The return of the IMF and the role of China As we already noted, the contagion kept spreading. Indonesia, at the end of October, asked for the intervention of the IMF. South Korea would come next. Without a regional safety net and with the USA being reluctant to join the rescue plans, the IMF reacquired a central role on the stage. Plausible reconstructions of the unfolding of the most critical events in the following months is provided by Blustein (2003) and Lipscy (2003). Blustein (2003, 25) suggests that the IMF was taken by surprise by a sudden change in the very nature of financial crises. While with Mexico it still was a matter of current account disequilibrium, that could effectively be tackled basically with a devaluation (to raise exports) and income reduction (to decrease imports), in the East-Asian case it was a capital account crisis, with hot money flying too quickly, first in and then out of these countries. This required a different set of instruments19 that the IMF did not possess or was not prepared to implement yet. As Narine (2003, 70) recalls: “in November 1997 Asian finance officials met in Manila and worked out the ‘Manila Framework' which stipulated that any bailout mechanism could only complement the IMF's supervisory role. The meeting called for a new ‘framework for regional cooperation' but it did not endorse the idea of an Asian rescue fund”. As Chris Downie (2004, 94) would underline: “recent moves towards financial integration in Asia recognise that the destabilising factors endemic within financial markets need to be addressed, and not just weaknesses of existing institutions. Asian governments are also realising that a regional arrangement may be more appropriate than existing international structures. For future crises to be averted, new institutions may be required”. Despite the failure of – and skepticism around – Japan’s AMF proposal, the need to increase regional cooperation was largely shared. As Kenen and Meade (2008, 152) suggest, this initiative (the Manila Framework) was perceived as being steered by the IMF and the USA, receiving lukewarm approval. In June 1998, the IMF issued an official statement20 on the East-Asian financial crisis in which a few critical points and policy prescriptions were highlighted, pretending the IMF was perfectly confident on how to manage the situation. A document that Japan presumably did not appreciate. On October 3, 1998, the Japanese Ministry of Finance 19 It probably would also require an increased capitalization and a more rapid instrument of active intervention, such as a massive issue of SDRs, as Camdessus had attempted in 1994. The problem with SDRs is that they are unconditional. There is no conditionality attached to their emission, which may result in moral hazard, and certainly runs against the interest of the big financial market players, all of them US-based. 20 Among them, the document argued: “Governance must be improved in the public and corporate sectors, and transparency and accountability strengthened. Many recent difficulties spring from extensive government intervention in the economy, as well as widespread political patronage, nepotism, and lax accounting practices. In order for confidence to be restored, political leaders must send unambiguous signals that such abuses will no longer be tolerated”; https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/1998/06/imfstaff.htm 13 took another unilateral initiative (Hamada 1999), called the New Miyazawa Initiative21, in which it was stated: “To assist Asian countries in overcoming their economic difficulties and to contribute to the stability of international financial markets, Japan stands ready to provide a package of support measures totaling US$30 billion, of which US$15 billion will be made available for the mediumto long-term financial needs for economic recovery in Asian countries, and another US$15 billion will be set aside for their possible short-term capital needs during the process of implementing economic reform” (Finance Ministry of Japan 1998). This was indeed activated in the following months to provide financial support to the Philippines, Korea, and Malaysia. After 1999 it was no longer in function. The search for a compromise between regional and global solutions was becoming the key issue in Asian integration. As Fred Bergsten, founder of the Peterson Institute for International Economics, wrote in December 1998: “Suitably elaborated and modified to include the United States and several other countries, however, an Asia Pacific Monetary Fund (APMF) could be extremely useful. An APMF could in fact provide a valuable regional complement for the International Monetary Fund in the same way that the Asian Development Bank (and the other regional development banks) complements the World Bank. It would respond to the strongly felt need, on the part of many Asians, for “their own institution” that will be more immediately responsive to their concerns. The subsequent deepening and broadening of the Asian economic crisis underlines the merit of creating such an institution”. A light but more structured institutional framework for regional cooperation would materialize a few years later, although in embryonic form, (after a generic commitment taken in December 1997 in Kuala Lumpur, Malaysia) with an initiative taken on May 6th, 2000 at the annual meeting of the Board of Governors of the Asian Development Bank held in Chiang Mai (Thailand) by the Finance Ministers of the “ASEAN+3” group (ASEAN + Japan, China, and South Korea). The agenda of the meeting was focused on the activation of a joint pool of reserves to face speculative attacks against the currencies and the creation of a system of bilateral swap agreements to be activated in case of financial stress. The proposal, that would be called the Chiang Mai Initiative (Sussangkarn 2010), was supported also by the IMF Managing Director Horst Köhler, as an instrument synergic to the action of the IMF, in case of need. The role of the Asian Development Bank was also crucial in those years, with the establishment of a Regional Economic Monitoring Unit as early as 1999. Until now, we basically neglected the role of China in this affair, which now requires some further enquiry. Considering the bailouts of Thailand, Indonesia, and South Korea, $35bn out of $114.2bn came from the IMF (and further $16bn from the WB), while Japan contributed with $19bn. China contributed only with $4bn. Table 1. IMF Financial Support Packages ($Bn) Thailand Indonesia 21 South Korea The initiative was named after Kiichi Miyazawa, who took office again – being in that position already in the 1980s (and later even Prime Minister, in the early Nineties) – as Minister of Finance in Japan since July 30, 1998 (until April 26, 2001). 14 Approved (1997) Total Pledged IMF U. S. World Bank Asian Dev. Bank Bank of Japan Others August 20 $17.2 $ 3.9 $ 0 $ 1.5 $ 1.2 $ 4.0 $ 6.6 November 5 $40 $10.1 $ 3.0 $ 4.5 $ 3.5 $ 5.0 $26.0 December 4 $57 $21.0 $ 5.0 $10.0 $ 4.0 $10.0 $ 7.0 Source: Nanto (1998) A small contribution, in absolute terms. A big one, if compared to the size of the Chinese economy at that time. We already noted that China was reluctant to support Japan’s proposal. As Sakakibara (2017) recalls: “I think it was because China was not in favor of a Japanese initiative. In retrospect, Japan lacked contacts with top Beijing officials. We asked their counterparts in Hong Kong to connect us with them so that we could explain our intention but it did not work. In short, Japan failed to lay the groundwork with China”. Amyx (2005) noted that the Japanese diplomatically failed by using the Hong Kong Monetary Authority to elicit Chinese support, only later seeking support from the People’s Bank of China. We are inclined to think that China’s negative attitude was not entirely due to a Japanese failure “to lay the groundwork with China”, but also to a precise Chinese interest. China in those years was an emerging economic and political power, negotiating its membership in the World Trade Organization, that crucially depended on a cooptation by the USA (eventually fulfilled in December 2001). This might be a reason for China’s cautious behavior: a matter of strategic pragmatism. Furthermore, both Eichengreen (2002) and Keijzer (2001), the latter from the Institute for International Monetary Affairs in Tokyo, suggest that China feared Japanese dominance with the AMF proposal, as did the United States. A further look at China’s macroeconomic performance might cast further light on this. China, in 1997, was starting booming in both exports and income. Hence the significant drop in foreign reserves relatively to its increasing import requirements during the period 1998-2000, until a record-low of less than one month of financing coverage while both GDP and imports were steadily increasing. In 1998, China’s GDP was slightly over one thousand billion dollars and imports 15% of GDP, so roughly $150bn, while reserves were only slightly above that figure. It is reasonable to imagine that China and the USA, at least implicitly, agreed on a common strategy in the area. The subsequent acceleration of China’s exports, that resulted in a skyrocketing accumulation of foreign reserves in US dollars until the building up of the global imbalances that characterized the first two decades of this new millennium, was also in the interest of the USA, thus allowed to run structural balance of payments deficits. 15 While in December 2011 the Japanese Masahiro Kawai (2011), Dean & CEO of the Asian Development Bank Institute, still believed in an unbelievable dream, based on a few (faulty) assumptions (that ASEAN+3 would become the largest block by GDP in the 2010 decade; that it would have its own currency; that that leading currency in an Asian monetary basket would be the yen), China had been emerging as a leader in the area. Under its impulse, the CMI would become multilateral in 2009, providing – de facto – an infrastructure very similar to the one unsuccessfully proposed by Japan in 1997. Concluding remarks In a Taiwanese publication designed as an explainer of the crisis, the Chinese Casper Shih, Chairman of the Global Chinese Competitiveness Foundation, talking about what he judged as a “Historical Inevitability”, wrote: “The East Asian financial crisis … came without early warning” (Wen 1999). We suggested here that this claim is largely untrue. Despite the crisis being dramatized by the behavior of the USA and IMF, there were several signs of local fragility in the region and misinterpretations of the evolution of international relations that should have suggested a more cautious approach to the first signals of financial turmoil. Many intertwined factors conjured to building up the crisis, that was the mirror of latent, major conflicts: between opposing views of the global and regional balance of power, of the (relative and evolving) weight of each major actor, of the role of country-specific institutions in controlling and steering the economy, and many more. A multifaceted and complex framework that cannot be reduced to single-causal correlations and needs several different layers to be disentangled and grasped. This is the reason why we attempted a detailed reconstruction of the evolution of the events, the main protagonists and their underlying theoretical assumptions, the relevant policy proposals. Optimism for the cooperative solution that had seen Japan and the USA bailing out Mexico, with the assistance of all major international institutions, had raised expectations that a similar solution might be replicable in Asia. An increasingly vulnerable Japan, whose financial and industrial fragility was in turn the outcome of an aggressive exchange rate policy imposed by the USA, was trying to maintain a leading role in the area, as the US had managed to keep their hegemonic role in the Mexican crisis. When the crisis erupted and the IMF imposed heavy conditionality on Thailand, the Japanese top officials at the Ministry of Finance tried to exploit resentment and attempted a 16 regional path to recovery, keeping both the USA and IMF out of the game. The global hegemonic ambitions of the USA, and their strategic use of the IMF, could not allow any such move. Hence the failure of the regional attempt, which eventually humiliated Japan’s hegemonic temptations in East-Asia, providing room for the rise of the Chinese influence. While writing these concluding remarks, we were made aware of an article published on August 31st by Jeffrey Sachs where he makes very similar considerations22. Ironically, the result of the increasing USA pressure for a penetration of capitals in all global markets (supported by an increasingly dominant neoliberal narrative) ended up weakening the US hegemony: Japan, US closest ally, was since then much more reluctant to play the watchdog of the area on behalf of the USA, while China took an increasingly hegemonic role in the area. The USA missed the chance to properly address the rising Chinese ambitions over the area and the global economy. It was certainly not easy to foresee this. Japan’s rampant behavior in the area probably seemed to endanger US hegemony more than China. Maybe, Clinton’s USA took it far too seriously the global responsibility generated by Fukuyama’s The End of History and the Last Man. Instead of struggling to weaponize the international monetary infrastructures, with the side-effect of challenging the legitimacy of the IMF, the USA had better look at the world in a more dynamic, problematic, and strategic way. If it was difficult to imagine that, 25 years later, China would challenge the US global hegemony and force the world into another bilateral confrontation, not too much different from the Cold War, the USA should have avoided humiliating Japan’s attempt – although clumsy and surely not well orchestrated – at regional leadership in the area. A more constructive, although difficult, dialogue with Japan might have softened the skyrocketing rise of China’s leadership and reduced the potentially devastating building up of the global imbalances, that we are currently experiencing at the world level. References Amyx J. 2002. Moving Beyond Multilateralism? Japan and the Asian Monetary Fund, Pacific Economic Papers, 331, September. Amyx J. 2005. What Motivates Regional Financial Cooperation in East Asia Today? Analysis from the East-West Center, 76, February. Bergsten C.F. 1998. Reviving the ‘Asian Monetary Fund’. Peterson Institute for International Economics Policy Briefs, 98(8), December. Bin Mohamad M. 1999. Revitalization of Japanese and East Asian Economies, in Institute for International Monetary Affairs. Revitalization of the Japanese Economy and the Future of Asia. IIMA Occasional Paper, 6(June), 4-12. Bird G., Rajan R. 2002. The Evolving Asian Financial Architecture, Centre for International Economic Studies Discussion Paper, 203. Blustein P. 2003. The Chastening: Inside the Crisis that Rocked the Global Financial System and Humbled the IMF. New York: PublicAffairs. Camdessus M. 2016. We Had a Chance. Thirteen Years at the Helm of the IMF, SAGE. Chang L.L., Ramkishen S.R. 2001. The Economics and Politics of Monetary Regionalism in Asia, ASEAN Economic Bulletin, 18(1), 103-118. Clift 2006. The Quiet Integrationist. Finance & Development, 43(1), March: https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2006/03/people.htm 22 The US economic war on China, The New World Economy, 31 August 2023. 17 Downie C. 2004. An Asian Response to the Asian Crisis: The Proposal for an Asian Monetary Fund. Journal of Australian Political Economy, 54(Dec.): 94-118. Eichengreen B. 2002. What to do With the Chiang Mai Initiative. Asian Economic Papers, 2, 1-52. Feldstein M. 1998. Refocusing the IMF, Foreign Affairs, March 1. Finance Ministry of Japan 1998. A New Initiative to Overcome the Asian Currency Crisis (New Miyazawa Initiative), https://www.mof.go.jp/english/policy/international_policy/financial_cooperation_in_asia/new_m iyazawa_initiative/e1e042.htm Goldar B. and E. Ishigami 1999. Foreign Direct Investment in Asia, Economic and Political Weekly, 34(22), M50-M60. Gyothen T. 1998. Why Japan is under fire from abroad, IIMA Newsletter, May 11; https://www.iima.or.jp/en/docs/newsletter/1998/NL-98-03_e.pdf Hamada K. 1999. From the AMF to the Miyazawa Initiative: Observations on Japan’s Currency Diplomacy, The Journal of East Asian Affairs, 13(1), 33-50. Hunsberger W.S. 1938. The Yen Bloc in Japan’s Expansion Program, Far Eastern Survey, 7(22), 251-258. Ibrahim A.R. 1961. ECAFE and Economic Cooperation in Asia, The Pakistan Development Review, 1(3), 1-28 Ikegami E. 1999 Democracy in an Age of Cyber-Financial Globalization: Time, Space, and Embeddedness from an Asian Perspective. Social Research, 66(3), 887-914. Ito T. 1999. Japan and the Asian Financial Crisis: The Role of Financial Supervision in Restoring Growth. IER Working Paper, 99/10, https://en.agi.or.jp/media/publications/workingpaper/WP1999-10.pdf. Kanaya A., Woo D. 2000. The Japanese Banking Crisis of the 1990s: Sources and Lessons, IMF Working Paper, 00/7, January. Kenen P.B., Meade E.E. 2008. Regional Monetary Integration, New York, Cambridge University Press. Keijzer C. 2001. Japan and Asia Regional Integration, Research Report, 1, Tokyo, Institute for International Monetary Affairs. Khan S. 2004. Contagious Asian Crisis: Bank Lending and capital Inflows. Journal of Economic Integration, 19(3), 519-535. Kindleberger C.P. 1969. American Business Abroad, Yale University Press, New Haven. Kwan C.H. 1993. Economic interdependence in the Asia-Pacific region: towards a yen bloc, London and New York, Routledge. Lee S.Y. 1973. The Economic Commission for Asia and Far East Monetary Co-operation Schemes, Abidjan, 26-28 February, https://repository.uneca.org/bitstream/handle/10855/42795/b11958194.pdf?sequence=1&isAllo wed=y Lee Y.W. 2006. Japan and the Asian Monetary Fund: an Identity-Intention Approach. International Studies Quarterly, 50, 339-366. Lincoln E. 1998. An American View of the Japanese Economy. In Institute for International Monetary Affairs 1998. Revitalization of the Japanese Economy and the Future of Asia, IIMA Occasional Papers, 6, June: 23-26. Lipscy P. 2003. Japan’s Asian Monetary Fund Proposal, Stanford Journal of East Asian Affairs, 3(1), 93-104. Murphy R.T. 2011. A Loyal Retainer? Japan, Capitalism, and the Perpetuation of American Hegemony. Socialist Register, 47, 147-173. Mussa M., Boughton J.M., Isard P. 1996. The Future of the SDR in Light of Changes in the International Financial System, Washington, International Monetary Fund. Nakaso H. 2001. The Financial Crisis in Japan during the 1990s: How the Bank of Japan Responded and the Lessons Learnt, BIS Papers, n° 6, October. 18 Narine S. 2003. The Idea of an “Asian Monetary Fund”: the Problems of Financial Institutionalism in the East-Asia, Asian Perspective, 27(2), 65-103. Rhee C., Sumulong L., Vallée S. 2013. Global and regional Financial Safety Nets: Lessons from Europe and Asia, Bruegel Working Paper, 6, November. Rimkus R. 2016. Asian Flu. CFA Institute, October 20, https://www.econcrises.org/2016/10/20/asian-flu/. Roubini N. 2009. Asia is learning the wrong lessons from its 1997-98 financial crisis. In Uzan M. (ed). The Macroeconomics of Global Imbalances, London and New York, Routledge, 83-102. Sakakibara E. 1993. Beyond Capitalism: the Japanese Model of Market Economics. University Press of America. Sakakibara E. 1998. Observations on Current Japanese and Asian Economies. In Institute for International Monetary Affairs 1998. Revitalization of the Japanese Economy and the Future of Asia, IIMA Occasional Papers, 6, June: 27-29. Sakakibara E. 1999. The End of Market Fundamentalism. Asiaweek.com, Nov. 30, 2000, http://edition.cnn.com/ASIANOW/asiaweek/99/0205/feat8.html Sakakibara E. 2000. East-Asian Crisis. Two Years Later. Washington, World Bank, https://documents1.worldbank.org/curated/ar/270091468770045719/820140748_200404131110 0432/additional/28161.pdf Sakakibara E. 2001. Interview. Commanding Heights, May 15, https://www.pbs.org/wgbh/commandingheights/shared/minitext/int_eisukesakakibara.html Sakakibara E. 2017 Interview. Looking back at the 'Asian IMF' concept, Nikkei Asian Review, June 22. Sohn B. 2004. Towards a New regionalism in East Asia, Journal of Economic Integration, 19(3), 499-518. Stiglitz J.E. 2001. From Miracle to Crisis to Recovery: Lessons from Four Decades of East Asian Experience. In Stiglitz J.E., Yusuf S. (eds). Rethinking the East Asia Miracle, New York, Oxford University Press, 509-526. Stiglitz J.E. 2002. Globalization and its Discontents. New York & London, Norton. Sussangkarn C. 2010. The Chiang Mai Initiative Multilateralization: Origin, Development and Outlook. ADBI Working Paper 230; http://www.adbi.org/workingpaper/2010/07/13/3938.chiang.mai.initiative.multilateralisation/ Thomsen S. 1999 Southeast Asia: The Role of Foreign Direct Investment Policies in Development. OECD Working Papers on International Investment, 01; http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/431857742281 Tobin J. 1998. Asian Financial Crisis, Japan and the World Economy, 10(3), 351-353. Triffin R. 1969. International Monetary Cooperation in Asia and the Far East. In Kojima K. (ed). Pacific Trade and Development, Tokyo, The Japan Economic Research Center, 243-283. Wen S. 1999. You too Can Understand. The East Asia Financial Crisis. Illustrated by Chih-Chung Tsai, Taipei, Locus. Woo D. 1999. In Search of Credit Crunch: Supply Factors Behind the Slowdown in Japan. IMF Working Paper, 99/3, January. 19